ΕΠΙθΕΩΡΗΣΗ ΟΙΚΟΝΟΜΙΚΩΝ ΕΠΙΣΤΗΜΩΝ - Τε ύχος 9 (2006) , 145-166 PATTERNS OF INDUSTRRIAL EXPORT SPECIALIZATION ΙΝ GREECE ΙΝ ΤΗΕ COURSE OF EUROPEAN ECONOMIC INTEGRATION: EMPIRICS AND DETERMINANTS KLIMIS V061ATZ06LOU Ph.D. Abstract Cιndldιtι Unlνιrιlty We analyze the degree and deνelopment of export specialization patterns of 35 Greek manufacturing industries in the period 1981-2002. The empirical analysis examines the impact of the European economic integration process on Greece's exports specialization within the EU and seeks eνidence on the determinants of obserνed specialization patterns. We find that labour-intensiνe and resource-intensiνe industries exhibit the highest leνe l of specialization. During the whole integration period these two industry categories remain the most important as regards intra-EU export specialization of Greece. Although in the course of European economic integration there has been a decline in the specialization degree of l abo ur-intensiνe industries, this deνelopment has not been followed by a significant upward trend in hightechnology sectors and increasing returns to scale industries. Thus, ίι seems that the oνerall result is a decreasing export specialization of Greece within the European Union. Furthermore, traditional factor endowments and comparatiνe adνantage considerations continue ιο determine Greece's export specialization, while determinants of the new theories of trade and economic geography seem to be less important in explaining the obserνed specialization patterns in Greece. Dιριrtmιnt ot Ριtrιι ot Βυιlπeιι Admlnlιtrιtlon Περίληψη Αναλύουμε το βαθμό και την εξέλιξη της εξαγωγικής εξειδίκευσης χανικών κλάδων στην περίοδο 1981-2002. Η 35 ελληνικών βιομη εμπειρική ανάλυση εξετάζει τις επιπτώσεις της ευρωπαϊκής οικονομικής ολοκλήρωσης στην εξαγωγική εξειδίκευση της Ελλάδας στην Ευ ρωπαϊκή Ένωση και αναζητεί εμπειρικές ενδείξεις για τους καθοριστικούς παράγοντες της παρατηρούμενης δομής εξειδίκευσης. Βρίσκουμε ότι οι μεταποιητικοί κλάδοι έντασης εργα σίας και έντασης φυσικών πόρων παρουσιάζουν το υψηλότερο επίπεδο εξειδίκευσης . Καθ' όλης της περιόδου οικονομικής ολοκλήρωσης αυτές οι δύο κατηγορίες παραμένουν οι πιο ση μαντικές όσον αφορά την ενδοκοινοτική εξαγωγική εξειδίκευση της Ελλάδας. Αν και κατά τη διάρκεια της οικονομικής ολοκλήρωσης υπήρξε μια μείωση στο βαθμό της εξειδίκευσης στους κλάδους έντασης εργασίας , αυτή η εξέλιξη δεν συνοδεύτηκε από μια σημαντική ανοδι κή τάση στους κλάδους υψηλής τεχνολογίας και στους κλάδους που χαρακτηρίζονται από οι κονομίες κλίμακος. Έτσι, φαίνεται ότι το συνολικό αποτέλεσμα είναι μια φθίνουσα εξαγωγι κή εξειδίκευση της Ελλάδας στην ΕΕ. Επιπλέον, οι παραδοσιακοί παράγοντες συγκριτικού πλεονεκτήματος συνεχίζουν να καθορίζουν την εξαγωγική εξειδίκευση της Ελλάδας, ενώ οι προσδιοριστικοί παράγοντες των νέων θεωριών διεθνούς εμπορίου και οικονομικής γεωγρα φίας εμφανίζονται να είναι λιγότερο σημαντικοί όσον αφορά τα παρατηρούμενα πρότυπα εξειδίκευσης στην Ελλάδα. JEL Classification: Fl; F14; FlS key words: European economic integration; Export specialization; Greece. 145 ΚΛΗΜΗΣ ΒΟΓΙΑΤΖΟΓΛΟΥ - ΕΠΙΟΕΩΡΗΣΗ ΟΙΚΟΝΟΜΙΚΩΝ ΕΠΙΣΤΗΜΩΝ - Τεύχος 9 (2006) , 145-166 1. Introduction Since the Treaty of Rome ίπ 1957, regional economic integration ίπ Europe has progressed with a rapid pace, which implies that a changing landscape and economic geography has been established ίη the European economic space. Along with theoretical thinking ίη international economic integration, which analyzes the effects of integration οη welfare and trade and specialization pattems, the literature has seen a great number of empirical studies that investigate empirically the effects of integration οπ the economic geography of regional integration areas. Since the sustained economic integration process ίπ Europe constitutes a form of natural research laboratory for trade economists, the great bulk of empirica1 analyses is devoted to this region (Amiti, 1999; Brulhart, 2001; Fontagne et al. , 1997; Haaland et al. , 1999; Midelfart-Κnarvik et al. , 2000; Sapir, 1992 and 1996; Storper et al. , 2002)(\ J_However, these studies take to a large extent either a general view of the European Uπίοπ or focus οη the "core" EU-countries - Belgium, Germany, France, Italy, and the UK - and thus the literature leaves a gap for some "peripheral" countries. This paper aims to fill this gap for the case of Greece. The Greek economy has been for over twenty years ίπ the European economic integration process and thus has s u staίned - and still undergoes major adjustments and changes as regards the industrίal structure and trade specίalization . Ιη this paper we investigate analytically quantitative (descriptive empirics) and qualitatίve ( characteristics and determinants) aspects of Greece's export specialization within the European Uπίοπ . Ιπ partίcular, we analyze the degree and development of export specialization pattems of 35 Greek manufacturing industries ίη the period 1981-2002 by calculating Balassa indices for each industry and year observation included ίη our sample. The remainder of the paper is organized as follows: Ιη section 2, the theoretical background of international trade and specialization is presented. Ιπ sectίon 3 we conduct the empirical analysis and present the magnitude and development of export specίa lίzation of Greece within the European Uπίοπ. Ιπ section 4 we take a closer look at the observed specialization patterns, by analyzing various relevant industry-specific characteristics and seek evidence οη the determinants of Greecι(' s export specialίzat ion . Finally, Section 5 summarizes the most important findi ngs and concludes. 2. Theoretical Background of International Trade and Specialization Trade theorίes can give us the necessary understanding of specialization patterns and information οη the effects of economic integration. Traditional comparative advantage models have long been criticized as an insufficient ( 1) For empirical studies on specialization pattems for the US economy see for instance, Dumais eι al. (1997), Hanson (1998), Κίm (1995), Κrugman (199lb). 146 KLIMIS VOGIATZOGLOU - REVIEW OF ECONOMIC SCIENCES - Νο 9 (2006) , 145-166 theoretical framework, which does not capture a considerable part of forces that are crucial ίη shaping and explaining trade patterns (Grubel, 1967 and 1970; Hufbauer and Chilas, 1974). Because of the empirical observation that since the post-war period intra-industry trade (ΙΙΤ) shares are consistently growing and that a Iarge proportion of world trade is between very similar countries, it had been suggested that other models need to be developed (comparative advantage models are incompatible with ΙΙΤ) . As a response to that fact, in the 1980's and 1990's we saw developments ίη trade and location theory, which have been labelled as the "new" theories of trade and economic geography. The models of Κrugman (1979; 1980; 1981) and Helpman and Κrugman (1985) , known as the "new trade theory", showed formally for the first time that economies of scale can be a basis and source of international trade and aggregate welfare gains. Theoretical advances ίη economic geography rnodels occurred ίη the 1990's (Κrugman , 1991a; 1991b; 1993; Κrugman and Venables, 1995a; 1995b; Venables, 1996). These rnodels, known as the "new economic geography" focus οη externaHties, technological spillovers, and input-output Iinkages among industries as the determinants of agglomeration and industrial concentration. Thus, at the present development the theory of international trade and specialization can be distinguished into three different strands or classes of models. 2.1. Tradίtional trade theory: Comparative advantage models Traditional trade theories (2) represented the dominant paradigm ίη intemational trade until the recent years, where alternative "non-conventional" models were developed and acquired importance and became the focus of trade economists. However, cornparative advantage rnodels still remain useful tools ίη international economics and explain a substantial share of world trade. Essentially, within the traditional neo-classical frarnework we can distinguish two distinct theories, which focus οη particular aspects of comparative advantage. The first of these theories is the Ricardian model, which is associated with David Ricardo, whereas the second one is known as the Heckscher-Ohlin (factor-proportions) model. The Ric~rdian theory focuses οη differences ίη technolqgies across countries as a cause of international trade. Comparative advantage is determined by differences ίη technology (production function). Here, only one factor of production (labour) is assumed and two goods are produced. Thus, differences ίη technology represent differences ίη Iabour productivity. Ιη addition, it is assumed that firms are perfectly competitive, which exhibit constant returns to scale ίη production. Each country specializes ίη the good ίη which it has a comparative advantage. Ιη the Ricardian model, countries specialize completely ίη the production of one good, which means that they produce and export only one commodity (comparative advantage) and import the other one (comparative disadvantage) (2) Ricardo (1817); Heckscher (191 9); Ohlin (1933). 147 ΚΛΗΜΗΣ ΒΟΓΙΑΤΖΟΓΛΟΥ - ΕΠΙθΕΩΡΗΣΗ ΟΙΚΟΝΟΜΙΚΩΝ ΕΠΙΣΤΗΜΩΝ - Τεύχος 9 (2006) , 145-166 from their trading partner. As lo ng as a pattern of comparative advantage exists, production efficiency gains from specialization can be achieved and free trade will be profitable for both countries <3>. The Heckscher-Ohlin model differs from the Ricardian model ίη that it assumes a second production factor and identical technology across countries. Ιη this model , comparative advantage and trade are determined by differences ίη relative factor endowments. Ιη particular, the model assumes the following: 1) two factors of production (Labour and Capital), 2) perfectly competitive firms with constant-returns to scale produce two goods (one capital-intensive and one labour-intensive good), 3) preferences are identical and homogeneous, 4) there are differences ίη relative factor endowments across countries. The model's prediction can be summarised by what is known as the HeckscherOhlin Theorem, which states that each country will export the good using intensively its abundant factor. UnJike the Ricardian theory, ίη this model countries do not specialize completely when free trade takes place, but continue to produce both commodities. Furthermore, the Heckscher-Ohlin model explicitly takes into account the effects of trade οη the distribution of income between the two factors. Specifically, free trade increases the relative price and real income of each country's abundant factor, whereas the opposite is true for each country's scarce factor. Ιη summary, the traditional trade theory is characterised by constant returns to scale, perfect competition, non-differentiated goods and identical-homogeneous preferences. Trade and location is determined exogenously by country characteristics. Countries specialize according to their comparative advantage, which is determined by differences ίη technologies or differences ίη relative factor endowments across countries. FinalJy, trade liberalization leads to inter-industry specialization, whereas high trade costs (tariffs, non-tariff baπiers, transport costs, etc.) lead to a dispersion of industries. 2.2. New trade theory The "new trade theory" provides alternative causes of trade and elements, such as increasing returns to scale, differentiated goods, imperfect competition, and domestic market size, which are able tq explain the trade that takes place between similar industrial countries that do not differ much ίη their production technologies or relative factor endowments. The main motivation (cause) for such a trade to take place, if increasing returns are present, is that firms, which operate under monopolistic competition and produce differentiated goods, will choose to produce only ίη one location (country) ίη order to take advantage of scale economies. There will be gains from trade, because, οη the one hand, the two economies combined will produce a wider range of differentiated goods (greater diversity), which leaves consumers with a wider range of choice, and οη the other hand, for each firm there will be an increase ίη the scale of production (Κrugman, 1979). (3) Although, one country might not capture these gains. 148 KLIMIS VOGIATZOGLOU - REV IEW OF ECONOMIC SCIENCES • Νο 9 (2006), 145-1 66 In Κru g m a n (1980), a slightly di ffe rent model is developed in order to make the analysis of the effects of transportation costs and home market on trade easier. In particular, it is assumed that monopolistically competitive firms di ffe rentiate their products without any cost and can free ly enter or exjt the industry (monopo ly profits in equilibrium are zero). At zero trade costs, each di ffe rentiated product will be produced in only one country and factor prices (wages) will be the same in all countries (only one factor is assumed, labour). In addition, the prices of diffe rentiated goods produced in di ffe rent countries will be equal. G ains fro m trade eχj s t in the fo rm of greater variety of products. As a second step, transpo rtation costs are included in the model, where these costs refer to the "iceberg" type. With this formulation, the prices of the diffe rentiated goods the wages in diffe rent countries will, in general, not be equal. Regarding the relative wage rate, the larger country, ceteris paribus, will have the higher wage. The presence of increasing retums and transportation costs leads to the result that production will tend to concentrate close to the larger market (greater demand) fo r that good. Increasing retums activities will tend to concentrate in one location in order to capture economies of scale, and locate near the largest market in order to minimize transportation costs. This leads countries to specialize in and export those goods fo r which they have a large domestic market. This result, known as the "home market" effect, is derived and shown in Κrugm a n 's (1980) extended model with a two-industry economy setting, where each industry produces one class of many diffe rentiated goods, and two groups of consumers derive utility fro m only one class of diffe rentiated products, who determine the demand for these two types of products. In addition, the model assumes the eχjs te n ce of two identical countries, which diffe r only in their proportion of these two types of consumers. This ensures that the demand (market) fo r a class of product is different in the two countries. Specifically, it is assumed that the foreign country is a mirror image of the home country. If free trade takes place, when the home country has, fo r instance, a larger percentage of consumers that derive utility from the "alpha" class, then the home country has the larger domestic market for that class of good, and therefore wiU specialize in the industry of "alpha" products. In other words, each country will specialize in the class of goods that it has the larger domestic demand, and thus, become a, net exporter of that good. This Ώo rm ally leads to inter-industry specialization, but ίntra -indus try trade and incomplete specialization can arise if transportation costs are high or if scale economies are less important. In summ ary, the new trade th eory inco rporates industry-specific characteristics, such as economies of scale, imperfect competition, transportation costs and differentiated goods, and draws attention to domestic market size, which is determined by the size of labour fo rce. The theory predicts the "home market" effect, where countries export those products in which they have a large domestic market. Production (industry) is concentrated in one location with large domestic demand in order to realize scale economies and minimize transport costs. This implies that trade liberalization wίll result in the concentration of increasing-returns industries in large countries. 149 ΚΛΗΜΗΣ ΒΟΓΙΑΤΖΟΓΛΟΥ - ΕΠΙθΕΩΡΗΣΗ ΟΙΚΟΝΟΜΙΚΩΝ ΕΠΙΣΤΗΜΩΝ - Τεύχος 9 (2006) , 145-166 2.3. New economic geography models Essentially, within the "new economic geography" \jteratυre we can distinguish two c\asses of models. One c\ass of models shows how countries can endogenously develop into an industria\ized "core" and an agricultural "periphery" (e.g. Κrugman , 1991a). IndustriaJ location becomes entirely endogenous, because inter-regional demand differences (distribution of demand between the two regions, where thjs distribution depends on the distribution of firms between the two regions) are endogenous through the assumed labour mobility. Firms will tend to locate ίη regions with the larger market in order to capture scaJe economies and minimize transport costs, but market size (of the two regions) depends on the distribution of manufacturing fjrms, wruch are themselves mobiJe and endogenous. Thus, there is a backward linkage, which creates a circular process. Industrial production will tend to be concentrated where there is a large demand, but the demand will be large where production is concentrated. In addition, there may exist a forward linkage. Labour wilJ have an incentive to concentrate at the "core", because the manufacturing goods are cheaper (without transportation costs ). Obviously, the geographical pattern (core-periphery) that will emerge depends on initial conditions. Α region with a large urban population (market) will attract firms because of the reasons that were mentioned previously. This fact, in turn, will cause the urban population of other regions to migrate toward the large region, which will become in that way an even larger urban area. This process continues until the non-ruraJ population of aJI other regions is concentrated in a few large urban areas. Scale economies, transportation costs and the fraction of income spent on manufacturing products play a crucial role. The implication of the above economic geography model regarding international trade is that economic integration can lead two identicaJ countries to become differentiated into an industriaJ core and an agricultural periphery and inter-industry trade will prevail. In the second class of the new economic geography models inter-regional demand differences become endogenous, because firms, which demand intermediate-goods, are themselves mobile (labour is assumed to be immobile) and thus, location patterns are formed endogenously (e.g. Venables, 1996). Here, industries are linked vertically through an input-output structure. In particular, '"downstream" industries, which produce final goods, demand and use intermediate goods from "upstream" industries, which produce the inputs for downstream firms. Thus, downstream industries represent the "market" for upstream firms, which will tend to concentrate near to locations with many downstream firms (the "home market" effect). This creates a backward linkage between these two types of industries. On the other hand, downstream industries will have an incentive to be located in an area with many upstream firms in order to obtain cheaper inputs (without transportation costs, cheaper intermediate goods because of higher competition between upstream firms). This represe nts the forward or cost linkage. These linkages, in turn , can be a cause of concentration 150 KLIMIS VOGIATZOGLOU - REVIEW OF ECONOMIC SCIENCES - Νο 9 (2006), 145-166 of vertically linked industries. The stronger these linkages are, the higher the degree of clustering of industries will be, and the larger the sha.re of intermediate goods ίη the production of final goods is, the stronger the inputoutput linkage will be. Hence, according to this model, intermediate goodsintensive industries are expected to be, ceteris paribus, more geographically concentrated. Regarding intemational trade, this means that vertically linked industries will be located ίη one only country rather than in different. The crucial point of the new economic geography models as regards the resulting specialization pattern is the level of transaction costs (transport costs, trade costs, etc.). Ιη particular, there is a U-shaped relationship between integration and geographical specialization. At high and very low transaction costs industries are dispersed across countries and thus intra-industry trade prevails. Οη the other hand, if trade costs are at an intermediate level, which is the critical value, agglomeration forces are relatively stronger and the geographical concentration of industries is ίη its highest level. Ιη this case, inter-industry trade will emerge between different countries. 3. Trade Patterns and Industrial Export Specialization ίο Greece 3.1. Intra- and extra-EU export patterns Although the process of economic integration between Greece and the European Union <4 ) began ίη the 1960s(5), the Greek economy experienced mainly after 1981 an opening up and thus entered into the increased European and world competition. This was a result of Greece's entry into the EU ίη 1981, which led to the reduction of the external protection of the Greek manufacturing industry f.rom European as well as from world markets, since the level of tariff protection of Greece before her accession was higher than the corresponding level of the EU (common external tariff) that applies to thirdparty countries. This opening up to international markets, implies that the degree of international economic integration of Greece must have risen . Indeed, there has been a consideral;>ly trade expansion. Since ίη this study we are mιainly interested ίη Greek exports we will take first a concise look at the exports side as regards the patterns of Greek exports and ίη the next subsection we examine analytically the export specialization of Greece. As ίt can be seen from Figure 1, exports as a percentage of Gross Domestic Product (GDP) show ίη general a significant upward trend between 1960 and 1980. More specifically, during this time period both intra-EU and extra-EU exports increase and reach in 1980 a level of 5,3% of GDP. (4) Αι that time ca ll ed European Econom ic Comm unity (EEC). (5) ln 1961 an associat ion agreement between the EEC and Greece was signed. 151 ΚΛΗΜΗΣ ΒΟΓΙΑΤΖΟΓΛΟΥ - ΕΠΙθΕΩΡΗΣΗ ΟΙΚΟΝΟΜΙΚΩΝ ΕΠΙΣΤΗΜΩΝ - Τεύχος 9 (2006) , 145-166 g lntro-EU Exports 6 7 6 5 Εχιτο-ΕU Exports 3 2 +---+---<~-+--+-~t---+---+~+---+---<~-+--+-~+---+---+~+---+---<f---+--+-~+---+---+---< ~~~~#~~~~~~~~~~~~,~#~~~#~ Fiμre 1. lntra-EU and extra-EU exports ofGreece as a percentage ofGDP Commimon (20Q4). Sl1flrCC Ειιrοpeαιι However, after 1980 the relative importance of intra-EU vis-a-vis extra-EU exports diverges. During the 1980s Greek intra-EU exports achieved a considerable growth, while extra-EU exports experienced a sign ificant decline. In 1987 intra-EU exports represented 8,1% of GDP, whereas the respective level of extra-EU exports was 3,4%. Thus, it seems that the export expansion that took place during that decade has been at the expense of extra-EU exports. While this may sound plausible due to the economic integration with the EU, this development is certainly not the norm. On the other hand, during the 1990s the opposite trend is observed, where the relative importance of intra-EU and extra-EU exports converges. Furthermore, in recent years extra-EU exports as a percentage of GDP exceed the respective level of intra-EU exports and Greek exports in general are becoming relatively less important in the Greek economy as evidenced by the low level of the exports to GDP ratios. lt is also instructive to look at the direction of extra-EU exports. Table 1 presents the share of Greek exports in total exports by geographical region. Again, an upward trend of intra-EU exports during the 1980s and in the beginning of the 1990s is evident, while after 1992 the share of intra-EU exports in total exports shows a significant decline. Extra-EU exports are mainly directed toward Asia and other Eu rope. However, during the 1990s Greek exports toward other Europe almost tripled (33,4% in 2000), whereas they dec\ined substantially in Asia and Africa-Oceania and remained at about the same level in America. 152 KLIMIS VOGIATZOGLOU - REVIEW OF ECONOMIC SCIENCES - Νο 9 (2006) . 145-166 Table 1. Grcek exports by geographical region (as a % oftotal exports) 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 20001 49,8 49,4 57,0 65,9 67,8 67,2 68,8 56,6 54,6 53,7 45,2 OtherEωope 15,3 13,3 11,1 10,5 11,2 13,5 14,2 21,4 26,8 27,9 33,4 Ameήca 6,5 9,5 9,1 8,3 7,7 7,2 5,5 8,0 6,0 6,9 8,3 Asia 17,3 17,3 13,8 9,0 8,2 6 ,5 6,6 9,3 8,9 6,7 8,7 Africa & Oceania 11,1 10,5 9,0 6,3 5,1 5,6 4,9 4,7 3,7 4,8 4,4 Emopean Uιιίοο 2 'Provisiooal dιιta, ΈU-15 . S.ιuα: Prrx:uHd datιιfrom tJιe Natiorιol StαtUtioal Servi~ ofGrwce {νariOtl.! iUMU). The fact of the huge export growth toward non-EU European countries in recent years may reflect the declining competitiveness of Greek exports within the European Union and thus are directed toward those European countries tha t are less developed and less technologically advanced (mainly toward Bulgaria and Romania) . 3.2. Industrial Export Specialization Patterns In this part we conduct the empirical analysis of export specialization in Greece. As regards the industrial export specialization patterns, the paper's resu lts are based on the calcu lated Balassa indices of specialization for each industry and year obseιvat i on included in our sample. This special ization index, which can be used for the determination of export specialization when export data are employed, is defined by the following equation: χίj n Σχίj BALASSA;j = i=I (1) ΠΙ Σ χίj j=I n ΠΙ Σ Σ xij i= I where Χ j= I denotes exports and subscripts i, j, n , and m denote industries, countries, total number of industries, and tota l number of countries in the country group (e.g. the EU), respectively. Hence, Χίj is exports of industry ί in country j , Σ Xij (summation across ί= 1, ... , n) is total exports in country j , Σ X;j (summation acrossj= 1, ..., ni) is exports of industry ί in the EU (all EU countries together) and Σ Σ Xij is total exports in the EU. Since in this 153 ΚΛΗΜΗΣ ΒΟΓΙΑΤΖΟΓΛΟΥ - ΕΠΙθΕΩΡΗΣΗ ΟΙΚΟΝΟΜΙΚΩΝ ΕΠΙΣΤΗΜΩΝ - Τεύχος 9 (2006) , 145-166 empirica] study we are concemed with manufacturing industries, exports of manufacturing industry ί. Χίj refers to The Balassa index, which is sometimes referred to as the "Revealed Comparative Advantage" index, is a measure of relative specialization, since it anaJyzes a country's export share of an industry (product) relative to the corresponding export share of the country group (the EU as a whole). This index takes values between zero and infinity and relates positively to a country's specialization in a particular industry. The analysis draws on the United Nations' COMTRADE Database, which provides export data for 35 SITC 2digit manufacturing industries in Greece and the other EU countries for the time period 1981-2002. The first step of the analysis is to reveal the export specialization pattern of individual manufacturing industries in Greece over the period 1981-2002. In Table 2 we report the empirical results for the years 1981, 1986, 1991, 1996, and 2002. At the beginning of the period, which is the year of Greece's entry into the EU, very high export specialization is found for the Clothing industry (Balassa index = 5,426), Leather industry (4,996), Textile industry (4,199), Footwear industry (3,398), and for Non-metallic mineral manufactures (3,262). For the year 1981, 10 manufacturing industries exhibit a value of the Balassa index above unity, which means that Greece was relatively specialized and had a "revealed comparative advantage" in those industries within the European Union at that time. However, most of the industries have a specialization index below unity, where especially the various machinery-producing industries (SITC section 7) exhibit a value close to zero. Specifically in 1981, Greece was least specialized in terms of exports in Office & automatic data-processing machines (Balassa index = 0,015), Metalworking machinery (0,022), Other transport equipment (0,046), Power generating machinery & equipment (0,053) , and Photographic apparatus & equipment (0,054). On the other hand, these rankings are changed in 2002, which points to the changing patterns of export specialization in Greece during her process of economic integration with Europe. In particular at the end of our sample period, the highest export specialization index is found again in the Clothing industry (8,347) followed by Non-ferrous metals (6,326), Fertilizers (3,944), Textile industry (2,761), and Plastics in non-primary forms (2,078). 154 KLIMIS VOGIATZOGLOU - REVIEW OF ECONOMIC SCIENCES - Νο 9 (2006), 145-166 Table 2. Export specializatioo σf Greek manufacturing industries, 1981-2002 (Balassa indices) srrc INDUSTRY DESCRIP'ΠON Code Sl υrαιιίc cbc:micals . cbc:micals S2 S3 .υyc:ίιιg tJmnίιur .ι: oolauriιw matαials . . • orocιucιs S-4 ss :ε-αιι οίl&. reιiιιoids .ι: nr:rfume ιιιιιt. S6 Fcrtilizς:q (odιer d8ι dιοιe σf ΙΙΠΙUΙΙ 272) S7 Plasιic:s in σήιιιιrv foιms S8 Plasιic:s in 111111-ριimιry formι S9 CΙισιιιίca1 ID8lσials aιιd nmι1ιιctιι D.C.S. D.C.S. 61 LcatlΩ. lcιdιer n.e.s. 62 ~ 63 Coιt aιιd wood nw••&dures Μ 68 69 71 72 73 74 7S 76 77 78 79 81 82 83 84 ss 87 88 89 1986 1991 0,136 0.11• OS7S ο s11 Ο l-4S ο 198 0708 0639 0-426 0281 0928 2227 2 3-46 3,860 07S8 ο 307 103-4 0 ....9 -4,996 S9S8 0.263 OS29 0.7S7 0.892 0,677 0,317 aιιd aιticles σf DllDσ' ΙΡ8Ρα'. Textile vam fabrics &: related nmdιιc:ts 4.199 3.781 " 'ιu. miDeral maιιιιfactures 3,262 2,279 l 3S7 l.77S Ιrοιι aιιd Sfcd ΙNon-feπous mctaJs 2778 2,S84 Μaιιιιf'ιι tures σf~ n.c.s 1 lS-4 066S aιιd eαuiD. OOS3 007S Power . .. . for naιticώar ind. O,OSS 0060 0022 0,029 . . Gc:ιιc:ιal ίιιdιιιιήaΙ aιιdMUiD. ο 168 0,099 Ο OlS ooos Offioc .ι: autom8tic dala maclιin. Telerom..,....;,.,,lioιιs 0.248 ο 191 0,693 0,391 .ι: aDDI. 0, 167 OOS6 Roιd νdιicles 0,0-46 0,137 OdιcrΡn:διbήαιιcd buίldinιιs 0297 0,1S8 ο 123 0,071 Funιίtιιre .ι: tlιemJ( fixtures Τιaνd ιιοιιιΙ&. .ι: ιimilar nmd 07S6 ο 31-4 Aιticla; σf- .ι: ClOUlinιι accc:ιιιoήcs S,426 10,03 Footwcar 3 398 18SO 0, 117 0,099 Pmfaιkoιl &: sciaιtific ίιιιsιnιmcιD • 81111• .ι: 0,0S-4 0018 Miιodlaιιoous maιιιιliιι:tιll'Cd articlcs OSS4 0,429 β 1 ά:οσΙt:s aonual 8\'a'l8C growth rale ( estimalal with a 1ίncιιr aιιd 6S 66 67 1981 ~ - .. •. - - - - 0.178 0266 0.9S6 0.718 0809 2,228 0.290 0809 ο 393 -4.26S Ο Sl4 1 101 0333 2843 2,378 l.91S 3,742 07S9 0,431 ο 136 ο 116 Ο IS9 006S 0269 ο 374 0,032 0,220 0,234 o, 1os 0.277 11,09 0.680 0,20S 0,073 0,487 1996 2002 Ο.173 0.3-4S 0.9SO 0.-477 l,20S s 110 0,3S3 1.219 0696 2080 0677 l 1S7 0492 2307 2,448 1.383 -4,S77 1.024 0,787 0300 ο 163 0276 0,102 0392 0610 0,077 0,470 0,7S8 0,-416 0.201 9,93S 0,774 0,-46S 0.218 0,888 βι 0,16-4 00046• 0276 -0 01ss•• 0,944 Ο,Ο-462•• 0.70-4 -0,0016 1,819 007~· 3.944 ο 1867•• l,16S -00903•• 2.078 0,0123•• -0027-4 Ο.679 1,378 -0 21os•• 0498 0007S 0682 -0.0070 OS66 0001s 2 761 -0,0979•• 1,466 ..()06()6•• -0,017S 1.498 6,326 0, 182~· 1.208 0.0116• 0,73S ο.ο~· 0.418 0.0202•• 0,16S 0.0096•• OS16 Ο 01S3•• 0,23-4 0,0111•• 0809 ο 031s•• 0,7S2 0023~ 0,062 -0,0007 ο 0332•• ο 719 l,OS9 00424•• 0,32S 0,0168•• ο 370 -0,00SS 8,347 0,08S7 os7s ..()0966•• 0,S03 0,0196•• 0.48S 0,0297•• 0,92S 0,033~· Ν.ιc time τφαsίοιι fιr eaclι induslιy ί: BALASSArllo+βιt+u;., t=I981 ,1982,1983, .. . ,2002). •stati.!ticalJy significam at the 5% leνel ( α:(),05), ••!llιιtisticalJy significant aι tbe ι % level ( <Α>,01 ). Industries with ι th e lowest specialization index are: Road vehicles (0,062), Organic chemicals (0,164), Metalworking machinery (0,165), Office & automatic data-processing machines (0,234) , and Inorga nic chemicals (0,276). For the year 2002, the Balassa index of 12 manufacturing industries is above unity. Furthermore between the years 1981 and 2002, 22 industries experienced an increase in the export specialization index, whereas 13 experienced a decline. However, to consider on ly two isolated data points could be misleading. Therefore, we estimated the annual average growth rate of each industry over the whole sample period with a linear time regression. The time trend of each industry is shown in Table2. Out of 35 industries, 23 show an upward trend in export specialization, though fo r 3 industries the increasing linea r time trend is not statistically significa nt at the 5% and 1% level. The 155 ΚΛΗΜΗΣ ΒΟΓΙΑΤΖΟΓΛΟΥ • ΕΠΙΒΕΩΡΗΣΗ ΟΙΚΟΝΟΜΙΚΩΝ ΕΠΙΣΤΗΜΩΝ · Τεύχος 9 (2006) , 145-166 highest annual average growth rate is found in the FertiLizers industry (18,67% ), Non-ferro us metals (18,2%) - see also Figures 2a and 2b, respectively - Clothing industry (8,57%, but not statistically diffe rent fro m zero; see also F igure 2f), Essential oils & perfume materials (7,6%), and Plastics in non-primary fo rms (7,23% ). On the other hand, the most pronounced decline in the degree of export specialization is found in the Leather manufacturing industry with an annual average decrease in the Balassa index of 21,08%, followed by the Textile industry (-9,79%) and the Footwear industry (-9,66%) - see also Figures 2c, 2d, and 2e, respectively. The development path of o ne particular industry as regards its degree of expo rt specializatio n bears a special interest and thus examination. The Clothing industry (SITC code 84) displays by far the highest Balassa indices over the whole sample period (Figu re 2f). For various years the calculated specializatio n indices take a value above 10. This reveals the great importance of this industry regarding the expo rts of the Greek economy. It seems that in this particular activity Greece is highly specialized and enjoys a "comparative a dν!lntage" within the E uropean Unio n. However, the magnitude of this advantage changes over time in an interesting way. Although before Greece's accession to the EU the Clothing industry exhibited a high Balassa index, just afte r the country's accessio n expo rt specialization rose radically and reached in 1988 a top value of 11,905. 5,6 6.75 4,8 ~ 6,00 ~4.0 :! 5,25 Ζ i3,2 14,50 ~2,4 ~ ~1 .6 3,00 0,8 ο .ο 3.75 .... .... i i ~ s 1 i §! ~ !11 1 ~ Figure 2a. Gro\\.1h ofExpoή Specialization in the Fertilizers lndustrχ in Greece 2,25 j i 81 !i §! 1 11 ~ 2 Figure 2b. Gro,,1h of Εχpοή Specialization in Non-ferrous Metal Products in Greece 6,4 5,6 ~ 4,0 ~4.8 :! 3,6 Ζ i4.0 13.2 ~3.2 ϊι 2,4 1,6 0,8 ~ 2.8 ϊι 2.4 +-<-...__._.....,......................__........,.....................................,>--ι-4 ! i 1! 1! ~ 1! ~ ~ 2,0 -l-+-+-1-+-+-+-+-+-+-1-+-+-+-+-+-+-+-+-~ i i ' ! 1! ~ 1! 1~ Figure 2c. Decreasing Εχpοή Specialization Figure 2d. Decreasing Εχpοή Specialization in Leather Manufactures in Greece in the Teλ1.ile Industry in Greece 156 KLIMIS VOGIATZOGLOU - REVIEW OF ECONOMIC SCIENCES - Νο 9 (2006) , 145-166 3,5 3,0 !!! 2.5 Ζ i~~ i 1,0 0,5 ο.ο +-+-+-f-+-+-+-+-f-+-+-+--+-<f-+-+-+-+-f-+-~ !i ·ι !ι! ~ ι ! 1~ Fiμre 2e. Decreasing Export Specialization Fiμre 2f. Export Specialization development in the Foot\vear Indu~, in Greece in the Clothing Industry in Greece After a period of relatjvely stable and high values of specialization (late 1980s and at the beginning of the 1990s), the Balassa index of the Clothing industry deteriorates significantly during the 1990s and at the beginning of the third millennium. Thus, the evolution of export specialization shows an initial rugh upward trend and afterwards a significant negative trend. Therefore, the time regression for this industry yields a non-statistica11y significant coefficient of the linear time trend. Trus development witnesses the decreasing trend in the comparative advantage of Greece's most specialίzed industry in terms of exports in relation to the other EU countries, which seems to continue in the future. 4. Determinants of Specialization Patterns In this section we conduct a more analytical examination by analyzing various industry characteristics and examining their impacts on the - resulting from the previous analysis - export specialization of Greek manufacturing industries within the E uropean Union. Econorruc theory has to a large extent analyzed the relatίonship between international trade, economjc growth, and technological progress <6J. Furthermore, in recent years a great number of empirical studies have focused on the export performance and competitiveness of countries .in connection with the development of domestic high-technology industries. These studies point out that high-technology oriented sectors exhibit a better performance, a higher export dynamism in international markets, a higher level of productivity, and promote the improvement of the competitiveness of other domestic sectors through the diffusion of knowledge and technology (OECD, 1997). Thus given the great importance of technology as regards international trade and growth of an open economy, we consider below the technology dimension of Greece's export specialίzation. In order to reveal and analyze the specialization pattern by technology level, we categorize our industry sample according to four technology levels, using the OECD's (2001) technology (6) For a good presentation ο η this subj ecι matter see for insta nce, Archibugi and Michie (1998). 157 ΚΛΗΜΗΣ ΒΟΓΙΑΤΖΟΓΛΟΥ - ΕΠΙθΕΩΡΗΣΗ ΟΙΚΟΝΟΜΙΚΩΝ ΕΠΙΣΤΗΜΩΝ - Τεύχος 9 (2006) , 145-166 classification of industries, and calculate group-wise Balassa indices over the whole sample period. Specifically, the analysis distinguishes the following technology-level categories: 1. High Technology Industries (4 industries ίη our sample) 2. Medium-high Technology Industries (11 industries 3. Medium-low Technology lndustries (10 industries 4. Low Technology Industries (10 industries ίη ίη ίη our sample) our sample) our sample) Ιη Figure 3 the evolution of Greece's export specialization by technology level is presented. As it becomes evident from Figure 3, the highest specialization is found ίη low technology industries and medium-low technology industries. These two technology categories exhibit very high Balassa indices over the whole period under investigation. Οη the other hand, Greece is least specialized ίη high technology and medium-high technology industries. Although this result may not seem surprising, the analysis highlights the magnitude of this fact, that is the particular low specialization indices (between 0,2 and 0,6), which shows that Greece has clearly a comparative disadvantage ίη these technology categories ίη the European Union. The development path is also worthy of consideration. Although low technology industries exhibit the highest Balassa indices, the degree of specialization shows clearly a decline ίη recent years. More specifically, while ίη 1981 the Balassa index was 2,478 it increased continuously up to the year 1987, reaching a level of 3,143, and thereafter it declined, reaching a value of 2,219 ίη 2002. As regards the medium-low technology industries, they show an upward trend ίη export specialization with an annual average growth rate of 1,81 %. Furthermore, both high technology and medium-high technology industries have ίη recent years experienced an increase ίη their export specialization levels with an annual average growth rate of 1,82% and 1,14%, respectively. However, although there is a relatively convergence of high technology industries vis-a-vis low technology industries, ίt is a weak convergence and not sufficient to reverse the specialization pattems ίη favour of the high technology activities ίη Greece. 158 KLIMIS VOGIATZOGLOU • REVIEW OF ECONOMIC SCIENCES • Νο 9 (2006) , 145-166 3,6 3,0 2,4 1,2 Higlι T«lι1tology l1tdιutήn 0 ,6 "" Μ~Τ«ΙΙ~ ο.ο +--+---t-+--+---t-+--f--+-+--f--+-t--+--+-t--+--+---it--+--+--t Another important industry characteristic, as regards the pattem of specialization and the effects of increased economic integration within a RegionaJ Integration Area, that has to be considered are scale economies, as emphasized by the new trade theory. ln fact, economies of scale are considered to be important determinants of overall welfare and economic growth and it is believed that the European economic integration process brings with ίt and creates gains for member states ίη the form of ίncreased scale economies. Thus, the next step of our analysis is to examine the specialization patterns of Greek manufacturing industries according to the importance of increasing retums to scale. The analysis draws on an industry classification of scale economies by Pratten (1988), where intemal increasing returns to scale are measured by engίneering firm-level cost functions on the basis of estimates given by engineers, managers and economists. We apply the Pratten (1988) classίfication of scale economies for our industry sample and calculate Balassa indices for the followίng ίndustry categoήes over the whole research period: 1. High Scale Economies (11 industries in our sample) 2. Intermediate Scale Economies (12 industries in our sample) 3. Low Scale Economies (12 industries in our sample) The results, which are reported in Figure 4, indicate clearly that the export specialization of Greece relies heavily on activities with low scale economies, whereas industries with high economies of scale exhibit low Jevels of 159 ΚΛΗΜΗΣ ΒΟΓΙΑΤΖΟΓΛΟΥ - ΕΠΙθΕΩΡΗΣΗ ΟΙΚΟΝΟΜΙΚΩΝ ΕΠΙΣΤΗΜΩΝ - Τεύχος 9 (2006) , 145-166 specialization. More specifically, the low scale economies category exhibits a high Balassa value ove r the whole period 1981-2002, but shows in recent years a downward trend with an estimated annual average rate of decline of 2,35% . In the other extreme lies the high scale economies category, which shows low specialization indices and remains relatively stable during the whole period. Interesting and important is the evolution of the intermediate scale economies industries. AJthough this category exhibited low levels of export specialization ίη the beginning of the period (a Balassa value of 0,578 in 1981), it achieved a signi ficant increase in the Balassa indices (a Balassa index of 1,149 in 2002) with an annual average growth rate of 3,15% . Thus as ίt is evident from Figure 4, there has been a convergence of the intermediate scale economies activities in Greece, which reveals an increasing comparative advantage in those activities within the EU. 3,0 2,5 2,0 lηtt!mf#!lditιle Scιι/e Ecoηomin 1.0 0,5 ο.ο +--+--+----t-+--+--t----t-+--+--t---+-+-+--+---+-t--+--+--+----ι~ ~~~;,~~~~#~#~;~,~,~~~~ Fiιure 4. Export specializ.ation in Greece by importance όf scale economies Thus far we examined industry characteristics, which concern the technology and scale economies dimension of export specialization. However, the analysis conducted so far is a one-dimensional examination, since it considers only one industry characteristic each time, where the industry sample is categorized according to one variable only. In order to take a closer look at the factors and determinants of the observed specialization patterns we next classify our industry sample according to various industry characteristics. Since we are interested in the driving forces of export specialization in Greece, these industry characteristics should reflect on the one hand, traditional sources of specialization, that is comparative advantage considerations which are the focus of the traditional trade 160 KLIMIS VOGIATZOGLOU - REVIEW OF ECONOMIC SCIENCES - Νο 9 (2006), 145-166 theory as regards international trade and specialization, and οη the other hand, characteristics that are associated with the new trade theory such as, scale economίes. Ιη addition, science-related industry-specific characteristics should also be included in the analysis, which partίally capture new econornic geography considerations, as science and high-technology sectors exhibit to a large extent input-output linkages and are geographically agglomerated(7)_ For the purpose of our analysis, a useful classification of industries is provided by OECD (1987), which is also used in Brulhart (2000). Specifically, the analysis dίstinguishes the following industry characteristics-categories (8) .: 1. Labour-intensive lndustries (11 industries ίη our sample) 2. Resource-intensive Industries (6 industries ίη our sample) 3. Scale-intensive Industries (14 industries ίη our sample) 4. Science-intensive Industries (4 industries ίη our sample) The results, which are depicted ίη Figure 5, indicate that labour-intensive and resource-intensive industries, which both relate to the traditional comparative advantage determinants of specialization, clearly dominate Greece's export specialization ίη the E uropean Union. 3,0 2,5 1,0 0,5 0,0 +--+--Ι-+--+--ΙΙ--+--+-Ι--+--+-+--+--+-+--+---+-+--+---+-+---1 ~,,,,~~~~~~~~,~~~~,~~~ Fiιure (7) In 5. Factors of export specialization pattems in Greece ιhis case a classic example is Silicon Valley in California, United Sιaιes . (8) In co nιra s ι wiιh the OECD ( 1987) s ιudy, in our analysis we do nοι distinguish "differenιia t ed goods industries" as a sepa ra ι e category, as the inclusion of this ca ι egory reduces significa nιly ιhe number of industries for some categories. H oweνer, th is is nοι a problem since we include the sca \ e-i nten siνe caιegory which captu res in our analysis ιhe effecιs and imporιance of ιh e new ιrade ιheory. 161 ΚΛΗΜΗΣ ΒΟΓΙΑΤΖΟΓΛΟΥ - ΕΠΙθΕΩΡΗΣΗ ΟΙΚΟΝΟΜΙΚΩΝ ΕΠΙΣΤΗΜΩΝ - Τεύχος 9 (2006), 145-166 Οπ the other hand, scale-intensive and science-intensive industries exhibit low levels of specialization. This result conforms with ou r previous findings , where high technology and medium-high technology industries and industries with high scale economies seem to play only a minor role ίπ Greece's specialization structure as witnessed by the low Balassa indices. Apart from the degree of specialization of Greek manufacturing industries, the evolution is also of great importance as we can have an appreciation of the effects of the European economic integration process οπ export specialization patterns. Ιπ particular, it is interesting to note that labour-intensive and resource-intensive industries exhibit opposing trends. Thus while the specia lization degree of labour-intensive activities increased until 1987 and decreased afterwards reaching ίπ 2002 a level which is close to that ofyear 1981- resource-i ntensive industries experienced a fall ίπ the specialization level up to 1989 and thereafter it steadily increased and converged toward the level of the labourintensive category. This development reveals that within the comparative advantage determinants labour has been playing a greater role ίπ the first years of Greece's entry into the EU and that one of the effects of European economic integration was the increase ίπ the relative importance of natural and other resources ίπ recent years as a factor of Greece's comparative advantage. Οπ the other hand, scale-intensive and science-intensive activities do ποt exhibit significant trends during the integration period. There is however, some increase ίπ the specialization level of science-intensive industries ίπ recent years. Thus, it seems that the "new" determinants of the new theories of trade and economic geography are not that "relevant" ίπ the case of Greece. However, it has to be stressed that these results are by πο means a direct test of different trade theories and their determinants and effects. Ιπ addition , this examination does not constitute a multivariate analysis as cond ucted ίπ a regression analysis, where the joint effect of various variables can be examined. Therefore, the final step of our exam ination of the determinants of the observed specialization patterns ίπ Greece is to transform our industry characteristics-categories ίπtο industry dummy variables and to regress these οπ the specialization indices, where the Balassa index serves as the dependent variable. Thus, we estimate the following regression : where, δ 1 , δ 2 , δ 3 , and δ 4 are the parameters to be estimated and u ; is the error term. 162 KLIMIS VOGIATZOGLOU - REVIEW OF ECONOMIC SCIENCES - Νο 9 (2006) , 145-166 Table 3. Determinants ofExport Specialίzarion p-value t-value Coefficicnt Vaήable LABOUR 1,909 16,935 0,000 RESOURCE 1,678 10,991 0,000 SCALE 0,612 6,130 0,000 SCJENCE 0,358 1,916 0,056 770 observaιioos used for estimatioιι from 1981 to 2002 R2 =0,369 R = 0,608 Adjusted R 2 = 0,366 Ana/ysis ofVariance Source of Vaήatioιι Rcgression Residual Total Sum ofSquares ofFrccdom 1.380,357 2.355,694 3.736,051 4 766 770 Νtιιe: Lincιιr Degrees Mean Square 354,089 3,075 Regrc:ssion through tJιe oήgin (the no-intcn:ept model). Tbe total coostant bccall9C tJιe consιanι is :zero fοι- regression through tJιe oήgin. sυm F-νalue p-νalue 112,213 0,000 of ιιqυιιres is not correcled for tJιe The results are reported ίη Table 3. It is evident that the Labour-intensity and Resource- intensity variables exert a significantly greater effect οη the observed export specialization ίη Greece than the Scale-intensity and Scienceintensity variables, which generally is ίη line with the situation depicted ίη Figure 5. Ιη particular, the first three variab les (LABOUR, RESOURCE, SCALE) are highly statistically different from zero, whereas the SCIENCE variable is statistically significant only at the 10% level (the p-value is slightly above the 5% level). These results confi rm that traditional sources of international trade and specialization have a strong impact οη export specializa tion patterns of Greek manufacturing industries, while sources and determinants associated with the new trade theory and the new economic geography have only a weak impact ο η the specialization patterns of Greece within the E uropea n U nion. 5. Conclusions The theory of international economic integration suggests that a process of regional economic integration leads to a substantial trade expansion, restructuring of econom ic activities, and increased specialization between member economies of the regional integration area. Ιη this paper we investigated the export specialization patterns of Greek manufacturing industries ίη the course of the European economic integration process and provided some evidence οη the underlying factors and determinants of specialization. Ιη particular, our empirical analysis revealed that although Greece indeed experienced a significant export growth within the E uropean 163 ΚΛΗΜΗΣ ΒΟΓΙΑΤΖΟΓΛΟΥ - ΕΠΙθΕΩΡΗΣΗ ΟΙΚΟΝΟΜΙΚΩΝ ΕΠΙΣΤΗΜΩΝ - Τεύχος 9 (2006) , 145-166 Union until the end of the 1980s, thereafter the relative importance of Greek intra-EU exports declined and continues to exhibit a decreasing trend. In view of the increased economic integration in the EU with the completion of the single European market in 1992, this finding is surprising and unexpected and could point to the significant deterioration of the competitiveness of Greek exports in the EU in recent years. Regarding the specialization patterns ίη Greece, which is the focus of this study, there is a number of important and interesting findings to note. The highest level of export specialization is found in labour-intensive industries followed by resource-intensive sectors. Notably, during the whole integration period these industry categories remain the most important as regards intraEU export specialization of Greece. However, in the course of European economic integration there has been to a large extent a decline ίη the specialization degree of labour-intensive industries - especially pronounced in the Leather, Textile, and Footwear industry - which has not been followed by a significant upward trend ίη the specialization of large scale producing and scale-sensitive industries and science and technology-intensive industries. Thus, it seems that the overall result is a decreasing export specialization of Greece within the European Union. Furthermore, although there is a decreasing trend of specialization and comparative advantage in labour-intensive activities, it is found that traditional factor endowments and comparative advantage considerations continue to determine Greece's export specialization. On the other hand, determinants of the new theories of trade and economic geography seem to be less important in explaining the observed specialization patterns in Greece. Finally, the fact that there is a decreasing comparative advantage and at the same time a relatively high specialization in traditional comparative advantage-related sectors in Greece, may explain the increased export diversion toward non-EU countries, which is observed ίη recent years. References Amiti, Archίv, νοl. Μ. (1999). "Specialisation Patterns 135, pp. 573-593. ιη Europe". Weltwίrtschaftlίches Archibugi, D. and Michie, J. (1998). Trade, growth and Carnbridge University press. technίcal change. Brulhart, Μ. (2001). ''Evolving Geographical Concentration of European Manufacturing lndustries". WeltwίrtschafιlichesArchίv, νοl. 137, Νο . 2, pp. 215-243. Dumais, G.; Ellison, G. and Glaeser, E.L. (1997). "Geographic Concentration as a Dynamic Process". NBER Working Paper, Νο. 6270. European Commission (2001). Broad Economic Guidelines. European Economy, no. 4, Brussels. Fontagne, L.; Freudenberg, 164 Μ. and Peridy, Ν. (1997) "Trade Patterns Inside KLIMIS VOGIATZOGLOU · REVIEW OF ECONOMIC SCIENCES · the Single Market". Document de travaίl, Νο. Νο 9 (2006), 145-166 97-07, CEPII, Paris. Grubel, H.G. (1967). "Intra-Industry Specialization and the Pattern of Trade". The Canadίan Joumal of Economίcs and Polίtίcal Scίence, νο l . 33, Νο. 3 (Aug., 1967), ρρ . 374-388. Grubel, H.G. (1970). "The Theory of Intra-Industry Trade". Ιη: Ι. Α. McDougall and R.H. Snape, (eds.) Studίes ίn Intema tίona l Econom ίcs. Amsterdam, 1970. Haaland, J.; Κind , H.J.; Midelfart-ΚnaΙΎik, Κ.Η. and Torstensson, J. (1999). "What Determ ines the Economic Geography of Europe?". CEPR Dίscussίon Paper, Νο. 2072. Hanson, G.H. (1998). "Market Potential, Increasing Returns and Geographic Concentration". NBER Workίng Paper, Νο . 6429. Heckscher, E.F. (1919) "The Effect of Foreign Trade Income" (ί η Swedish). Ekonomίsk Helprnan, Ε. and Cambridge (Mass.), Tίdskrίft , νο l. Κrugrnan, Ρ. ΜΙΤ 21, ρρ . οη the Distribution of 1-32. (1985) . Market Structure and Foreign Trade. Press. Hufbauer, G. and Chilas J. (1974). "Specialization by Industrial Countries: Extent and Consequences". Labour, Tubingen. Ιη : Herbert Giersch, ed. The lntemational Dίvίsion of Κίπι, S. (1995). ''Expansion of Markets and the Geographic Distribution of Econom ic Activities: The Trends ίη U.S. Regional Manufacturing Structure, 18601987". Quarterlyloumal of Economics, νοl. 110, ρρ. 881-908. Κrugrnan , Ρ. (1979) . ''Increasing Returns, Monopolistic Competition, and International Trade". Joum al of lntematίona l Econ om ίcs , νοl. 9, pp. 469-479. Κrugrnan, Ρ. (1980). "Scale Economies, Product Differe ntiation, and the Pattern of Trade". Amerίcan Economic Review, νοl. 70, pp. 950-959. Κrugman , Ρ. (1981) . ''Intraindustry Specialization and the Gains from Trade". Joumal of Political Economy, νο l . 89, pp. 959-973. Κrugrnan , Ρ. (1991a). ''Increasing Returns and Economic Geography". Joumal of Poliιical Economy, νοl. 99, pp. 483-499. Κrugrnan , Ρ. (1991b ). Geography and Trade . Cambridge (Mass.), ΜΙΤ Press. Κrugrnan , Ρ. (1993) . ' Όη the Relationship between Trade Theory and Location Theory". Review of Intemational Economics, νο l . 1, Νο. 2, pp. 110-122. Κrugrnan , Ρ. and Venables, A.J. (1995a) . "Globalization and the Inequality of Nations". Quarterly Joumal of Economics, νο l . 110, pp. 857-880. Κrugrnan , Ρ. and Venables, A.J. (1995b). "The Seamless World: Α Spatial Model of International Specialization". NBER Dίscussίon Paper, Νο. 5220. Midelfart-ΚnaΙΎik, Κ.Η.; Overman, H.G. and Venables, Α. (2000). "Comparative Advantage and Economic Geography: Estimating the Determinants of Industrial Location ίη the EU". CEPR Dίscussίon Paper, Νο . 2618. NSSG. Sιαιίsιίcαl Yearbook of Greece, National Statistical Service of Greece, Athens, (various issues). 165 ΚΛΗΜΗΣ ΒΟΓΙΑΤΖΟΓΛΟΥ - ΕΠΙθΕΩΡΗΣΗ ΟΙΚΟΝΟΜΙΚΟΝ ΕΠΙΣΤΗΜΟΝ - Τεύχος 9 (2006), 145-166 OECD (1987). Structural Adjustment and Economic Performance, Paris. OECD (1997). Revision of the high technology sector and product classification , internal document, Paris. OECD (2001). Science, Technology and Industry Scoreboard: Towards knowledge-based economy, Paris. α Ohlin, Β. (1933). Inteπegional and lntemational Trade. Cambridge (Mass.), University Press. HaΙΎard Pratten, C. (1988) . "Α S u ΙΎey or the Economies of Scale". Ιη : Commission of the E uropean Communities, Research on the "Cost of Non-Europe", Volume 2: Studies on the Economics of Integration, Luxembourg. Ricardo, D. (1817). On the Principles of Political Economy and Taxation . Penguin, Harmondsworth (1971 edition). Sapir, Α. (1992). "Regional Integration pp. 1491-1506. ίη Europe". Economic Joumal, νοl. 102, Sapir, Α. (1996). "The Effects of Europe's Internal Market Programme οη Production and Trade: Α First assessment". Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, νο l . 132, pp. 457-475. Storper, Μ.; Chen, Y-c. and De Paolis, F. (2002). "Trade and the location of industries ί η the OECD and E uropean Union". Joumal of Economic Geography, vol. 2, pp. 73-107. 166
© Copyright 2024