Global Economic Policies and Developing Countries NiGEM Scenarios for the Post-2015 Agenda Tatiana Fic National Institute of Economic and Social Research May 2014 Contents Summary ................................................................................................................................................. 3 Introduction ............................................................................................................................................ 5 Section 1: The global macroeconomic environment for development – a modelling approach ........... 7 Section 2: Summary of Scenarios.......................................................................................................... 10 Scenario 1: Quantitative easing – effects of changes to bond yields reflecting withdrawal from unconventional monetary policy .......................................................................................................... 10 Scenario 2: Basel III – effects of changes to bank capital and liquidity ratios ...................................... 15 Scenario 3: Tackling tax evasion – effects of changes to transfer pricing ............................................ 19 Section 3: Conclusions .......................................................................................................................... 21 Bibliography .......................................................................................................................................... 22 Summary This paper analyses the macroeconomic impacts of global economic policies on developing and developed countries in relation to three global scenarios: withdrawal from quantitative easing (QE), introduction of higher capital and liquidity requirements (Basel III) and tackling tax evasion. Our key findings suggest that: The withdrawal of QE has been accompanied by a substantial rise in bond yields, both in developed and developing countries. Increases in long-term interest rates can be expected to be up to several times higher in developing than in developed countries. Reasons for this include the greater volatility of developing countries’ financial markets. Our calculations show that the 2013 announcement of a withdrawal of QE in the USA led to a rise in bond yields by about 80 basis points in the USA and 100–300 basis points in emerging markets. Our simulations show that the macroeconomic impacts of the withdrawal from unconventional monetary policy are greater in developed than in developing countries. The macroeconomic impact on developing countries is more muted (approximately half of the developed countries’ response), with the exception of Latin America, and in particular Brazil. This results from the fact that the Brazilian financial markets are very sensitive to monetary actions taken by the major central banks, and in particular those of the US Federal Reserve (US FED). Although the impacts on developing regions are smaller on average, the greatest impacts are seen in sub-Saharan Africa (SSA). The more restrictive monetary policy pursued by the US FED may result in a 0.8% fall in GDP in SSA countries. In Latin America and the Commonwealth of Independent States (CIS), GDP may decline by about 0.25%. The smallest effects are likely to be seen in the Middle East and North Africa (MENA) and the Far East. (The regional groupings are based on the International Monetary Fund (IMF) categories. Please see Table 1 for the countries included in each region.) Overall, the higher bond yields result in a decrease of about 1% in the US GDP and of about 0.5% in developing countries. The introduction of Basel III – higher capital and liquidity requirements – brings both costs and benefits. Basel III, intended to prevent a repeat of the crisis that started in 2007, introduced new capital standards concerning both the quantity and quality of capital held by banks, as well as new liquidity benchmarks. The tighter regulation brings costs in terms of reduced output since it leads to an increase in borrowing costs, but it also limits the likelihood of future financial crises. Our calculations show that in GDP terms the costs of introducing tighter rules are several times less than the benefits of higher capital and liquidity requirements – crises are very costly and it pays to insure against them. The costs of the insurance measured in GDP terms are similar across the largest developed and developing countries at around 0.25%. In smaller developing countries, there would be fewer capital and liquidity effects, which would lead to a small decline in GDP, for example up to 0.1% in SSA. The benefits of tighter regulation may vary depending on the structure of the economy, and amount to up to several percentage points. Overall, the costs are much smaller than the benefits of avoiding financial crises by establishing more stable banking rules. In SSA, the impacts of a crisis may be up to 10 times greater than the introduction of tighter capital requirements. There is a growing awareness among developing countries, and globally, of the risks posed by the abuse of transfer pricing. About 60–80% of trade takes place within multinational companies (MNCs). Incorrect pricing, such as lowering export prices and export revenues, can lead to a reduction in the earnings and reported profits in locations with high tax rates, while boosting profits in low-cost tax jurisdictions. This leads to tax evasion. Tax evasion results in significant losses of tax revenues that could be spent on improving health care, education systems and infrastructure in developing countries. Our stylised simulations show that if there were policies designed to tackle tax evasion and transfer pricing, output in the developing countries would rise. For example, assuming that export prices increase by 10% in SSA, accompanied by a rise in profits and hence taxes, GDP in SSA could increase by up to 0.35%. Global policies that encourage more appropriate pricing strategies can boost GDP in developing regions. To summarise, global economic policies – quantitative easing, new financial regulations, and tackling tax evasion – may have a significant impact on the prospects of developing countries. The scale of the impact on individual countries depends on their structural features and the strength of real and financial linkages with developed economies. Introduction Financing development beyond 2015 will require a stable global environment, international co-operation, domestic resource mobilisation (DRM), assistance to developing countries and innovative sources of finance. Developed and developing countries are becoming more interconnected, offering opportunities for new partnerships, but also generating space for policy spillovers and the cross-border transmission of shocks, both positive and negative. The 2007–2008 global financial crisis led to an economic slowdown in many countries, and turmoil on the global financial market. As a result, the growth prospects for a number of countries have been reviewed and the post-crisis macroeconomic policy landscape has changed in several dimensions. First, in the face of the severity of the crisis and inadequate conventional monetary measures, with interest rates reaching the zero bound, central banks turned to unconventional monetary policies and started making major purchases of assets, both government bonds and asset securities. This has significantly affected bond and equity markets, and the wider economy, not only in developed countries but also in the developing countries that have experienced increased volatility in capital flows, making macroeconomic management difficult. Second, after the banking meltdown, it became evident that the global financial architecture required fundamental changes. Left to their own devices, banks did not hold the capital and liquidity that was commensurate with the level of risks they were taking. The crisis released the systemic risks embedded in the global banking sector, with wide-ranging repercussions both for the financial sector and the real economy, in the light of which a set of new regulatory rules, Basel III, has been introduced. Third, the feedback loop between the banks and the sovereigns resulted in a worsening of the recession-ravaged fiscal situation in many countries. The fiscal crisis was particularly salient in the Eurozone. This has affected the speed of convergence of individual economies towards a post-crisis equilibrium. The crisis put the spotlight on the lack of public resources to deal with the recession as well as difficulties in the banking sector. This is predominantly attributable to the crisis itself, but, especially in the case of developing countries, it was also exacerbated by tax evasion. The ability to finance a post-2015 development agenda will depend on many factors, of which the post-crisis policy landscape is one. This paper does not explore the possibilities of global development co-operation but looks at the macroeconomic environment that may significantly shape the scale of the financial gap in developing countries and of financial capacities in developed countries. All countries confront the task of generating growth, and this paper attempts to quantify the effects of policies that will shape the global macroeconomic landscape in the medium term. The paper examines the impact of three types of global policies on the prospects for developing countries. We simulate the impacts of three global scenarios that may affect both the scale of the financing needs in developing countries and the financial capacities in developed countries and analyse the impacts of the following policy shocks: Changes to bond yields resulting from a withdrawal from unconventional monetary policies Changes to capital adequacy and liquidity ratios – reflecting the new Basel III rules Potential changes to transfer pricing resulting from actions aimed at tackling tax evasion The simulations use the global economic model, NiGEM, developed by the National Institute for Economic and Social Research (NIESR). The model covers the global economy, with most countries modelled separately and others modelled by region. In particular, regions such as SSA, MENA, LAC, the CIS and the Far East are modelled separately. (Further details on the NiGEM model are available at: http://nimodel.niesr.ac.uk/ and the regional groupings are given in Table 1). The paper is structured as follows. Section 1 highlights the role of global developments for official development assistance (ODA) and briefly describes the methodological approach. Section 2 presents the results of simulations and discusses their implications. Section 3 concludes. Section 1: The global macroeconomic environment for development – a modelling approach The global financial crisis placed economic and financial pressures on all countries. Developed countries have experienced a major drop in incomes, unmatched by any recession since the 1930s. This has been accompanied by rising unemployment and debt levels, and an unprecedented plunge in global trade. The crisis has also revealed that the global financial and fiscal architectures require stronger regulation, and the design and implementation of new policies to prevent future financial crises. The direct effects of the crisis were manifested in reduced private financial flows and official development assistance (ODA) to developing countries (in terms of the volume of ODA and aid programmes (te Velde and Massa, 2009)), as well as a decline in remittances from migrant workers and falling prices for export goods (Das and Dutta, 2012). Although 2013 saw a record level of ODA, more volatile ODA flows pose a severe macroeconomic management problem for aid-receiving countries. They lack the resources to smooth crisis-related shocks by adopting fiscal stimulus packages as developed countries did, and are therefore forced to rely more on ODA. Crisis-driven cuts in ODA disbursements are likely to aggravate the problems already imposed by the crisis and delay the development process. This paper examines the macroeconomic impacts of global developments that could potentially affect the economic prospects of developing countries. To assess the impacts of global developments on growth in developed and developing countries – which determines the scale of the financial gap in the aid-receiving countries and the degree of financial capacity in donor countries – we conducted a series of macroeconomic simulations. The analysis was based on NiGEM, a large-scale quarterly macroeconomic model of the world economy developed by the NIESR. Most OECD countries are modelled separately, and other countries are modelled at the regional level. By incorporating the models for individual countries into the global context the aim is to ensure that the impacts of global policy changes are, via links between countries, detected for all analysed economies. All country and regional models in NiGEM contain the determinants of domestic demand, a supply side, export and import volumes, prices, current accounts and net foreign assets. Output is determined in the long run by factor inputs and technical progress interacting through production functions, but is driven by demand in the short to medium term. Economies are linked through trade, competitiveness and financial markets and are fully simultaneous. Table 1 shows the list of countries and regions in NiGEM. Table 1. NiGEM country and regional coverage NiGEM countries and regions Countries Australia, Austria, Belgium, Brazil, Bulgaria, Canada, China, Czech Republic, Denmark, Estonia, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Hong Kong, Hungary, India, Indonesia, Ireland, Italy, Japan, Latvia, Lithuania, Mexico, Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, Poland, Portugal, Romania, Russia, Slovakia, Slovenia, South Africa, South Korea, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, Taiwan, UK, USA and Vietnam Regions (based on IMF categories) Sub-Saharan Africa (SSA) (IMF’s ‘Africa’ category): Angola, Benin, Botswana, Burkina Faso, Burundi, Cameroon, Cape Verde, Central African Republic, Chad, Comoros, Democratic Republic of Congo, Republic of Congo, Côte d’Ivoire, Equatorial Guinea, Eritrea, Ethiopia, Gabon, Gambia, Ghana, Guinea, Guinea-Bissau, Kenya, Lesotho, Liberia, Madagascar, Malawi, Mali, Mauritius, Mozambique, Namibia, Niger, Nigeria, Rwanda, São Tomé and Príncipe, Senegal, Seychelles, Sierra Leone, Swaziland, Tanzania, Togo, Uganda, Zambia and Zimbabwe. Far East (IMF’s ‘Developing Asia’ category) (excluding China, India, Indonesia and Vietnam, which are modelled separately): Republic of Afghanistan, Bangladesh, Bhutan, Brunei Darussalam, Cambodia, Fiji, Kiribati, Lao People’s Democratic Republic, Malaysia, Maldives, Myanmar, Nepal, Pakistan, Papua New Guinea, Philippines, Samoa, Solomon Islands, Sri Lanka, Thailand, Democratic Republic of Timor-Leste, Tonga and Vanuatu. Middle East (IMF’s category of the ‘Middle East and North Africa’ (MENA) plus advanced economies in the region that are not modelled separately (i.e. Israel)): Algeria, Bahrain, Djibouti, Egypt, Islamic Republic of Iran, Iraq, Israel, Jordan, Kuwait, Lebanon, Libya, Mauritania, Morocco, Oman, Qatar, Saudi Arabia, Sudan, Syria, Syrian Arab Republic, Tunisia, United Arab Emirates and Republic of Yemen. Latin America and the Caribbean (LAC) (IMF’s ‘Western Hemisphere’ category (excluding Brazil and Mexico, which are modelled separately)): Antigua and Barbuda, Argentina, Bahamas, Barbados, Belize, Bolivia, Chile, Colombia, Costa Rica, Dominica, Dominican Republic, Ecuador, El Salvador, Grenada, Guatemala, Guyana, Haiti, Honduras, Jamaica, Nicaragua, Panama, Paraguay, Peru, St. Kitts and Nevis, St. Lucia, St. Vincent and the Grenadines, Suriname, Trinidad and Tobago, Uruguay and Venezuela. Commonwealth of Independent States (CIS) (excluding Russia, which is modelled separately): Armenia, Azerbaijan, Belarus, Georgia, Kazakhstan, Kyrgyz Republic, Moldova, Mongolia, Tajikistan, Turkmenistan, Ukraine and Uzbekistan. The simulations in NiGEM are undertaken with reference to a baseline scenario. A set of shocks makes it possible to quantify the effects of three global developments – withdrawal from quantitative easing, implementing Basel III requirements and tackling tax evasion – and then compare the baseline and alternative scenarios. Section 2: Summary of Scenarios Scenario 1: Quantitative easing – effects of changes to bond yields reflecting withdrawal from unconventional monetary policy We analyse the macroeconomic effects of international movements of capital that may be attributed to withdrawing unconventional monetary policy measures. In particular, we look at changes to bond premiums in developed and developing countries that have materialised in response to the US FED’s tapering of quantitative easing (QE). Following the US FED announcement concerning withdrawal of unconventional monetary policies, government bond yields have gone up not only in the USA but also worldwide. Long rates have increased in developed countries as well as in countries such as Brazil, China, India, Russia and South Africa (the so-called BRICS). Figure 1 shows 10-year government bond yields for four of the developed countries with the largest economies – France, Germany, the UK and the USA – and for four of the largest developing economies – Brazil, China, India and Russia. Figure 1. Government bond yields in four developed and developing countries Government bond yields in four developed countries FED's tapering announcement 6 5 4 3 2 1 France Germany US UK 01/01/2014 01/09/2013 01/05/2013 01/01/2013 01/09/2012 01/05/2012 01/01/2012 01/09/2011 01/05/2011 01/01/2011 01/09/2010 01/05/2010 01/01/2010 01/09/2009 01/05/2009 01/01/2009 01/09/2008 01/05/2008 01/01/2008 01/09/2007 01/05/2007 01/01/2007 0 Government bond yields in four developing countries India Russia 01/01/2014 01/09/2013 01/05/2013 01/01/2013 01/09/2012 01/05/2012 01/09/2011 01/05/2011 01/01/2011 01/09/2010 01/05/2010 01/01/2010 01/09/2009 01/05/2009 01/01/2009 01/09/2008 01/05/2008 01/01/2008 01/09/2007 01/05/2007 01/01/2007 China 01/01/2012 FED's tapering announcement 20 18 16 14 12 10 8 6 4 2 0 Brazil Source: DATASTREAM The increases in government bond yields have been much stronger in developed than in developing countries. Between May 2013 and February 2014 the long rates increased by about 80 basis points in the USA, 90 in the UK, 50 in France and 30 in Germany. Among the developing countries, the long rates increased most strongly in Brazil – by about 300 basis points, by 150 in India and Russia, and about 100 in China. While it is important to note that the increases in government bond yields are not solely the effect of the US FED’s tapering announcement (they may also reflect a plethora of other factors, including an improved global macroeconomic situation), it seems that financial markets in countries such as Brazil, China, India and Russia have reacted more strongly to the announcement of withdrawal from the bondbuying programme, for which several factors are likely to be responsible. First, capital outflows from developing countries generate more volatility in the financial markets, with the result that their currencies depreciate. The international portfolio rebalancing leads to a decline in equity prices and a rise in government bond yields. Second, the cyclical position of developing countries is currently less advantageous than that of the developed countries. While the economies of developed countries have been gradually gaining momentum, the larger developing economies have been slowing down. The exit from QE can thus be more painful and generate more volatility in the latter since capital outflows deepen their output gaps. Third, developing countries can be more affected by the volatility in the financial markets resulting from the tapering of QE if they have large external imbalances and corporate and household debt. Sizeable current accounts and high debt levels can thus pose a risk factor for some developing countries. Below we quantify the macroeconomic impacts of the higher bond yields in developed and developing countries. We apply stylised shocks to term premium in the USA, Brazil, China, India, Russia and South Africa. The size of the shocks is shown in Table 2. We assume that the shocks are close to permanent.1 We also assume that US monetary policy is switched off for the first year to reflect the central bank strategy of withdrawing unconventional monetary policy instruments first, before switching to the conventional measures (it also conforms to market expectations concerning increased interest rates by the US FED (as of February 2014)). Table 2. Stylised bond yield shocks Country USA Brazil China India Russia South Africa Shock to bond 80 bp 300 bp 100 bp 150 bp 150 bp 100 bp yields Note: The shocks reflect changes in yields between May 2013 and February 2014. These changes result from the FED’s tapering announcement and other factors, and the shocks should be interpreted as stylised rather than as responding exclusively to tapering. Figure 2 and Table 3 show the results of the simulation. The higher bond yields translate into a modest weakening of growth prospects both in developed and in developing countries. The impact on the real economy in developing countries is relatively small, with the strongest response in Brazil. The sensitivity of the Brazilian economy to global portfolio shifts is higher since the Brazilian financial markets respond more to global financial shocks than is the case in other countries. 1 We apply the shocks over the period of 10 years (to avoid problems with model convergence in the long run). Results are reported for the next eight years. Figure 2. GDP effects of changes in bond yields – the impacts on the US and largest developing economies GDP change (% deviation from baseline) 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 years 9 0 -0.2 -0.4 -0.6 -0.8 -1 -1.2 -1.4 -1.6 Brazil China India Russia South Africa US Table 3. GDP effects of changes in bond yields – the impacts on the US and largest developing economies (percentage deviation from baseline) Year 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Brazil -0.40 -0.94 -0.95 -0.87 -0.81 -0.79 -0.78 -0.76 -0.66 China -0.16 -0.28 -0.35 -0.39 -0.43 -0.47 -0.54 -0.60 -0.65 India -0.13 -0.34 -0.41 -0.45 -0.51 -0.60 -0.71 -0.82 -0.89 Russia -0.35 -0.48 -0.45 -0.49 -0.56 -0.63 -0.71 -0.78 -0.80 South Africa -0.12 -0.32 -0.42 -0.49 -0.56 -0.61 -0.65 -0.68 -0.69 USA -0.38 -0.97 -1.06 -1.07 -1.13 -1.21 -1.29 -1.31 -1.22 Next, we look at the impacts of US FED’s tapering on the least developed regions: SSA, LAC, MENA, CIS and the Far East. Since the financial markets in the least developed countries (LDCs) are shallow, the effects of the taper will materialise mainly in trade channels. Figure 3 and Table 4 show the results. The largest effects are seen in SSA – the US FED’s taper may shave off up to 0.8% of GDP in these countries. In LAC and the CIS the more restrictive monetary policy announced by the US FED may have spillovers representing up 0.25% of their GDP. The smallest effects are likely to be in MENA and the Far East. The relatively larger impacts in SSA result from the greater estimated elasticity of African domestic demand with regard to external shocks. Figure 3. GDP effects of changes in bond yields – the impacts on the least developed regions: SSA, LAC, MENA, CIS and the Far East GDP change (% deviation from baseline) 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 years 8 9 0.2 0 -0.2 -0.4 -0.6 -0.8 -1 Sub-Saharan Africa Far East Latin America Middle East CIS Table 4. GDP effects of changes in bond yields – the impacts on the least developed regions: SSA, LAC, MENA, CIS and the Far East (percentage deviation from baseline) Years 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 SSA 0.02 -0.12 -0.39 -0.62 -0.75 -0.78 -0.75 -0.69 -0.60 Far East 0.04 0.06 0.04 0.01 -0.01 -0.03 -0.04 -0.07 -0.08 LAC 0.05 -0.07 -0.17 -0.17 -0.19 -0.22 -0.24 -0.26 -0.26 MENA -0.02 -0.04 0.00 0.02 -0.01 -0.05 -0.08 -0.10 -0.10 CIS 0.01 0.01 0.03 -0.01 -0.07 -0.12 -0.17 -0.21 -0.23 To recap, the slightly weaker prospects for both developed and developing countries resulting from a withdrawal from QE may affect both the scale of financing capacities in advanced economies and of financing needs in emerging economies. Higher bond yields alone result in a decrease in the US GDP by about 1% and by about 0.5% in developing countries. The impacts on the least developed regions are probably slightly smaller than those in the developed and the largest developing economies. Their financial markets are shallower and the propagation of shocks is experienced mainly in trade channels (in SSA the impacts are slightly larger than in the other developing regions because of the region’s greater elasticity of domestic demand to external trade shocks). Scenario 2: Basel III – effects of changes to bank capital and liquidity ratios Our second scenario analyses the impact on growth of Basel III – the new regulatory capital and liquidity requirements. In 2011 the Basel Committee introduced a set of new rules for banks aimed at strengthening their resilience to crises. Capital standards concerning both the quantity and the quality of capital were redefined and new liquidity benchmarks were introduced. Table 5 shows changes to capital requirements that banks must adopt by 2019. Such a relatively long timespan is expected to give banks the chance to use retained profits earned during boom periods, which should minimise the adverse impact of higher capital requirements on the economy. The Basel III requirements apply to banks worldwide. According to the new rules, core equity – the highest quality capital – increased to 4.5% of risk-weighted assets. Along with a capital-conversation buffer of 2.5% above this, the common equity requirement increased to 7%. The high quality Tier 1 capital was set at 6% with the overall minimum capital ratio at 8%. Basel III also introduced a counter-cyclical buffer of up to 2.5% – it is designed to be monitored nationally and increased if bank risks increase – in particular during periods of excessive economic growth or property price bubbles. Table 5. Basel III Basel III capital requirements (in percentages) Common Tier 1 capital equity (after deductions) Minimum 4.5 6.0 Conservation 2.5 buffer Minimum + 7.0 8.5 conservation buffer Countercyclical 0-2.5 buffer range Source: BIS, 20102 Total capital 8.0 10.5 The tighter regulation brings costs in terms of reduced output, and benefits in terms of reduced bank risk-taking and less likelihood of banking crises. We attempt to quantify the impacts of Basel III rules and look at both the macroeconomic costs and benefits. 2 BIS (2010) Annex 1 to Group of Governors and Heads of Supervision announces higher global minimum capital standards, press release. We assume that Basel III implies a small but permanent increase in borrowing costs. In the model we approximate it by a small, permanent increase in investment premium, which results in an increase in the cost of capital for the user. This approach is based on Barrell et al. (2009) who simulate the impact of higher capital ratios and liquidity standards on bank borrowing costs and the user cost of capital. Next, we compare this scenario with a crisis scenario – where financing conditions tighten abruptly and very significantly in all countries. This is approximated by a temporary, but very significant, rise in risk premium. Under the costs scenario, the higher costs of borrowing for households and enterprises stifle domestic demand, and hence GDP. In response to a 0.5% increase in investment premium, reflecting tighter regulation in the area of bank capital and liquidity, 3 GDP in all analysed countries would be lower by up to 0.25 basis points (see Figure 4 and Table 6). The responsiveness of the USA and the UK is slightly less than that of the other countries, which may result from smaller role of the banking sector in business financing in those countries (businesses finance themselves via the stock market rather than the banking sector). Under the benefits scenario we simulate the effects of a significant, but temporary, increase in risk premium. We assume that the risk premium increases by 4% and remains at the higher level over a period of two years – which corresponds to a financial crisis. This results in an significant instantaneous drop of GDP for about three years. It should be mentioned that our crisis scenario does not envisage a permanent change of the risk premium (since risk was underpriced before the crisis), which would imply a permanent scar on output in the long run, and augment the costs of crises. The size of the shock was calibrated on the basis of studies analysis the impacts of Basel III on GDP – see Barrell et al. (2009) and BIS (2010). 3 Figure 4. GDP effects of Basel III and GDP effects of a financial crisis – the impacts on the largest developed and developing economies (percentage deviation from baseline) Crisis-driven change in risk premium effects 1.00 0.50 0.00 -0.50 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 years -1.00 -1.50 -2.00 -2.50 -3.00 Brazil Germany South Africa China India UK France Russia US GDP change (% deviation from baseline) GDP change (% deviation from baseline) Higher capital and liquidity effects 1.00 0.50 0.00 -0.50 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 years -1.00 -1.50 -2.00 -2.50 -3.00 Brazil Germany South Africa China India UK France Russia US Table 6. GDP effects of Basel III and GDP effects of a financial crisis – the impacts on the largest developed and developing economies (percentage deviation from baseline) Higher capital and liquidity effects Years 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 Brazil -0.11 -0.14 -0.11 -0.09 -0.09 -0.10 -0.10 -0.12 China -0.07 -0.15 -0.18 -0.21 -0.23 -0.25 -0.27 -0.29 France -0.07 -0.18 -0.21 -0.22 -0.23 -0.24 -0.25 -0.26 Germany -0.09 -0.17 -0.17 -0.17 -0.18 -0.20 -0.22 -0.25 India -0.05 -0.14 -0.17 -0.19 -0.20 -0.21 -0.24 -0.27 Russia -0.11 -0.20 -0.21 -0.21 -0.22 -0.24 -0.26 -0.30 South Africa -0.05 -0.16 -0.21 -0.23 -0.23 -0.23 -0.24 -0.25 UK -0.04 -0.06 -0.04 -0.03 -0.04 -0.06 -0.08 -0.10 USA -0.07 -0.13 -0.11 -0.09 -0.09 -0.10 -0.13 -0.16 UK USA -0.54 -1.38 -0.96 0.23 0.62 0.57 0.36 0.17 -1.07 -2.46 -1.42 0.34 0.59 0.45 0.26 0.11 Crisis-driven change in risk premium Years Brazil China France Germany India Russia South Africa 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 -1.14 -2.06 -0.77 0.62 0.81 0.62 0.44 0.34 -0.62 -1.71 -1.66 -0.80 -0.27 0.03 0.16 0.20 -0.85 -2.16 -1.61 -0.31 0.02 0.05 0.04 0.04 -0.96 -2.11 -1.41 -0.36 -0.16 -0.14 -0.13 -0.14 -0.46 -1.74 -1.94 -0.84 -0.13 0.19 0.28 0.26 -1.08 -2.69 -1.99 -0.24 0.28 0.38 0.35 0.27 -0.41 -1.63 -1.82 -0.60 0.23 0.45 0.32 0.13 Figure 5 and Table 7 show the impacts of Basel III on developing regions. In qualitative terms the impacts are the same as in the largest developed and developing economies. Higher capital and liquidity effects lead to a small decrease in the GDP, of up to 0.1%. These costs are, however, much smaller than the benefits associated with avoiding financial crises (compare charts in Figure 5). The biggest impacts are seen in SSA, where the impacts of a crisis are more than 10 times greater than the introduction of tighter capital requirements. The size of the premium shocks corresponding to tighter regulation and the crisis is the same across countries (see above) – the differences result from structural differences between regions. Figure 5. GDP effects of Basel III and GDP effects of a financial crisis – the impacts on least developed regions: SSA, LAC, MENA, CIS and the Far East (percentage deviations from baseline) Crisis-driven change in risk premium effects 1 1 GDP change (% deviation from baseine) GDP change (% deviation from baseline) Higher capital and liquidity effects 0.5 0.5 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 -0.5 9 years -1 0 1 2 3 4 -0.5 5 6 7 8 9 years -1 -1.5 -1.5 -2 Sub-Saharan Africa Far East Middle East -2 Sub-Saharan Africa Far East Middle East CIS Latin America CIS Latin America Table 7. GDP effects of Basel III and GDP effects of a financial crisis – the impacts on least developed regions: SSA, LAC, MENA, CIS and the Far East Higher capital and liquidity effects Years 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 SSA -0.03 -0.08 -0.11 -0.11 -0.10 -0.09 -0.09 -0.09 CIS -0.03 -0.05 -0.03 -0.03 -0.03 -0.03 -0.04 -0.06 Far East -0.01 -0.01 -0.01 -0.01 -0.02 -0.02 -0.03 -0.04 LAC -0.01 -0.03 -0.03 -0.03 -0.03 -0.03 -0.04 -0.05 MENA -0.02 -0.03 -0.01 0.00 0.00 -0.01 -0.03 -0.04 9 -0.11 -0.07 -0.05 -0.06 -0.04 LAC -0.19 -0.54 -0.37 0.12 0.17 0.10 0.08 0.07 0.05 MENA -0.18 -0.47 -0.31 0.17 0.28 0.14 0.01 0.02 0.08 Crisis-driven change in risk premium Years 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 SSA -0.47 -1.52 -1.55 -0.37 0.43 0.83 0.90 0.75 0.49 CIS -0.46 -0.92 -0.34 0.35 0.36 0.25 0.14 0.04 -0.05 Far East -0.22 -0.46 -0.23 0.14 0.19 0.15 0.08 0.03 0.00 To sum up, the introduction of Basel III brings both costs and benefits. On the one hand, higher capital and liquidity requirements imply slightly higher borrowing costs, which result in a weakening of growth across developed and developing countries. On the other hand, more stable and resilient banking systems are less prone to financial crises which, as the recent experience shows, can be very costly. Our simulations show that in the case of all countries and regions the benefits substantially outweigh the costs. Scenario 3: Tackling tax evasion – effects of changes to transfer pricing Our final scenario models the effects of tax evasion. Tax evasion is a major issue in developing countries since they lack the capacity and resources to collect tax revenues (HMRC, 2013).4 MNCs often manipulate transfer prices by changing the sale or purchase prices in order to transfer the revenues and profits to tax havens. Our scenario investigates the potential impacts of a reduction in tax evasion in developing countries. Assuming that transfer pricing affects relative terms of trade, in a situation in which transfer pricing can no longer be manipulated, export prices, profits and tax revenues in developing countries would all increase. As an example, we simulate a scenario where we raise export prices in two developing regions – SSA and LAC. Our stylised scenarios assume a 10% increase in export prices in developing countries. This is calibrated on the basis of Bernard et al. (2006), who find that the wedge between the arm’s-length price and the related party price is about 40%. Product characteristics 4 The recent decision of the G20 concerning an automatic exchange of fiscal information does not affect developing countries. are influential in determining this gap – while the wedge for commodities (undifferentiated goods) is about 10%, the gap for differentiated goods amounts to about 70%. Given that most developing countries export commodities,5 we use the lower band estimated by Bernard et al. (2006) and shock the export price of commodities by about 10%. Next, we assume that profits in SSA and LAC increase in proportion to the value of their exports (the increase in profits amounts to the additional value of exports resulting from higher export prices). Finally, we assume that all the additional profits are taxed6 and the money raised through taxes is spent on boosting growth in the two regions. Figure 6 and Table 8 show the results. Figure 6. GDP effects of tackling tax evasion – the impacts on SSA and LAC 0.18 GDP change (% deviation from baseline) GDP change (% deviation from baseline) 0.35 0.3 0.25 0.2 0.15 0.1 0.05 0 0.16 0.14 0.12 0.1 0.08 0.06 0.04 0.02 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 years 1 Sub-Saharan Africa 2 3 4 5 6 7 Latin America Table 8. GDP effects of tackling tax evasion – the impacts on SSA and LAC Year 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 5 SSA 0.330 0.296 0.271 0.250 0.231 0.219 0.211 0.207 0.204 Year 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 LAC 0.159 0.124 0.109 0.107 0.105 0.103 0.102 0.102 0.102 We assume that the share of commodities in exports from SSA and LAC corresponds to 70% and 50% respectively. 6 We assume that the tax rate is 50%. 8 9 years Policies aimed at reducing the abuse of transfer pricing have the potential to improve growth prospects in developing countries. In our stylised scenario, a 10% increase in export prices in the countries of SSA and LAC, accompanied by a proportional increase in profits and hence taxes can lead to 0.35% increase in GDP in SSA. The responsiveness of small developing countries in LAC is slightly smaller – GDP improves by up to 0.15%. The regional differences result from different price elasticities of exports and imports. In SSA these elasticities are slightly higher, which implies that tackling the abuse of transfer pricing would be particularly beneficial for this region. While the quantitative impacts may be surrounded by uncertainty, in terms of the qualitative results, our simulations suggest that policies encouraging pricing of exports and imports at an arm’s-length rather than related party price may have macroeconomic benefits for developing countries. Section 3: Conclusions The global financial crisis, and its severe economic consequences – a significant slowdown in global economic activity, a collapse in global trade, and debt- and unemployment-related problems many developed economies – have led to a re-evaluation of global prospects and also prompted a re-design of the global regulatory and economic policy frameworks. First, the major central banks started using unconventional monetary policy instruments, such as major purchases of assets. This has had implications for the financial markets and the real economy in developed countries, and has also had spillovers affecting developing countries. An exit from QE will not only have a local impact, but through international financial and trade channels will spread to developing countries. Second, after the banking meltdown, international regulators have strengthened banking regulations, introducing a set of new capital and liquidity requirements, Basel III. Basel III brings costs and benefits for all countries. Third, in the light of the international debate on tax evasion, it has been acknowledged that in order to sustain prosperity it must be shared more equally worldwide. The LDCs still lose billions of dollars in taxes that could be used to tackle poverty and boost their economies. This paper has sought to quantify the macroeconomic effects of these three types of policies. We looked at the impacts of a withdrawal from QE that induced a rise in bond yields in developed and developing countries. Our simulations show that an increase in bond premium results in a moderate weakening of GDP – in the USA by about 1% and in the largest developing economies by up to 0.5%; in the least developed regions, since their financial markets are shallower, the impacts are likely to be smaller. All banks must introduce higher capital and liquidity requirements and Basel III by 2019, and these measures bring costs and benefits. Our analysis shows that the benefits should significantly outweigh the costs – in terms of output across all countries the benefits are at least several times greater than the costs. Finally, tackling tax evasion would be particularly beneficial for the LDCs. Our stylised simulations show that while introducing new tax rules would have a minor negative impact on countries where tax evasion is high, they would have a significant positive impact on the LDCs, enabling them to tackle poverty and boost their economies. Bibliography Barrell, R., Davis, P., Fic, T., Hollan,d D., Kirby, S. and Liadze I. (2009) ‘Optimal regulation of bank capital and liquidity: how to calibrate new international standards’. FSA Occasional Paper 38. London: Fiscal Services Authority. Barrell R., Holland D. and te Velde, D.W. (2009) ‘A fiscal stimulus to address the effects of the global financial crisis on sub-Saharan Africa’. NIESR Discussion Paper 331. London: National Institute of Economic and Social Research. Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (BCBS) (2010) ‘An assessment of the long-term economic impact of stronger capital and liquidity requirements’. Basel: BCBS. Bernard, A., Jensen, J. and Schott, P. (2006) ‘Transfer pricing by US-based multinational firms’. Available at: http://www.bde.es/investigador/papers/sie0620.pdf Brambila-Macias, J., Massa, I. and Salois, M. (2011) ‘The impact of global crises, trade finance, and aid on export flows: a developing country perspective’. Working Paper. London: Overseas Development Institute. Cali, M., Massa, I. and te Velde, D.W. (2008) ‘The global financial crisis: financial flows to developing countries set to fall by one quarter’. Working Paper. London: Overseas Development Institute. Das, D.K. and Dutta, C.B. (2012) ‘Global financial crisis and foreign development assistance shocks in least developing countries’. MPRA Paper 40281. Bonn: Bonn University. Fic, T. (2013) ‘The spillover effects of unconventional monetary policies in major developed countries on developing countries’. Working Paper 131. New York: DESA United Nations. Hai-Anh, D., Knack, S. and Rogers, H. (2009) ‘International aid and financial crises in donor countries’. Policy Research Working Paper 5162. Washington, DC: World Bank. HMRC (2014) Policy documents on reducing tax evasion and avoidance. Available at: https://www.gov.uk/government/policies/reducing-tax-evasion-and-avoidance/. International Monetary Fund (2009) The Global Financial Crisis and Low-income Countries. Washington, DC: IMF. Available at: http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/books/2009/globalfin/globalfin.pdf/. International Monetary Fund (2009) Export and Import Price Index Manual: Theory and Practice. Washington, DC: IMF, Chapter 19. Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) (2010) ‘The impact of the financial crisis on fragile states and the response’. Available at: http://www.oecd.org/dac/incaf/46043358.pdf/. Macias, J.B. and Massa, I. (2010) ‘The global financial crisis and Sub-Saharan Africa: the effects of slowing capital inflows on growth’. Working Paper 304. London: Overseas Development Institute. te Velde, D.W. (2009) ‘The global financial crisis and developing countries: taking stock, taking action’. ODI Briefing Paper. London: Overseas Development Institute. te Velde, D.W. (ed.) (2010) The G-20 framework for strong sustainable and balanced growth: What role for low-income, small and vulnerable countries? London: Overseas Development Institute. World Bank (2013) Financing for Development Post-2015. Washington, DC World Bank. World Bank (2012) Global Development Finance: External Debt of Developing Countries. Washington, DC: World Bank.
© Copyright 2024