The Journal of the Civil War Era JCWE 5.2 2nd pages.indd i volume 5, number 2 june 2015 Contents Editor’s Note william blair, 193 Tom Watson Brown Book Award ari kelman Remembering Sand Creek on the Eve of Its Sesquicentennial, 195 Articles cathal smith Second Slavery, Second Landlordism, and Modernity: A Comparison of Antebellum Mississippi and Nineteenth-Century Ireland, 204 d. h. dilbeck “The Genesis of This Little Tablet with My Name”: Francis Lieber and the Wartime Origins of General Orders No. 100, 231 millington w. bergeson-lockwood “We Do Not Care Particularly about the Skating Rinks”: African American Challenges to Racial Discrimination in Places of Public Amusement in Nineteenth-Century Boston, Massachusetts, 254 Review Essay scott reynolds nelson Who Put Their Capitalism in My Slavery?, 289 Book Reviews, 311 Books Received, 343 Notes on Contributors, 346 4/15/2015 5:01:51 PM cathal smith Second Slavery, Second Landlordism, and Modernity A Comparison of Antebellum Mississippi and Nineteenth-Century Ireland In May 1839, John A. Quitman, a planter from Natchez, Mississippi, set out on a journey to Europe. His first destination was supposed to be England, but when his ship encountered storms off the south coast of Ireland, he disembarked near Cork and completed his journey by traveling overland to Dublin and sailing from there to Liverpool.1 Soon after reaching London, he attended a session of the House of Lords and subsequently wrote of his experience, “Some of their first orators spoke and I assure you they are not equal to our first men.”2 While he compared Americans favorably with the British aristocracy, Quitman might also conceivably have reflected upon some of the striking parallels between southern planters and Irish landlords. Both groups were conservative, regionally distinctive, agrarian elites deemed “backward” during the 1800s by many influential contemporaries, including John Elliott Cairnes and John Stuart Mill.3 Arguably, the perception that American planters and Irish landlords were backward classes resulted from their implicit comparison with a particular understanding of modernity that took England as its exemplar. Since nineteenth-century political economists usually considered industrialization and urbanization indicators of “progress,” most agrarian regions fell short of classically defined modernity and accordingly won “backward” status. Backwardness, in this sense, implied deviation from a “normal” pattern of economic development. Yet, that industrial capitalism was the only form that modernity could take is open to question. As Walter Johnson has written, “to ask why Mississippi wasn’t more like Manchester . . . presupposes that there is a reason it should have been, that there is a natural course of historical development.”4 Instead of pursuing such teleological narratives, it is more helpful to consider modernity as Christopher Bayly does: as a process of believing oneself to be modern and an active attempt to keep up with the times.5 If this provides a definition of modernity, then it is possible to recognize that many supposedly backward agrarian elites—including American 204 JCWE 5.2 2nd pages.indd 204 4/15/2015 5:02:02 PM slaveholders and Irish landlords—attempted to modernize their socioeconomic systems during the nineteenth century. Since they did so while simultaneously endeavoring to retain traditional, hierarchical social relationships, their efforts were often dismissed at the time and in subsequent historiographies. Despite their qualified and selective nature, elite attempts to effect forms of agrarian modernization deserve to be considered on their own terms, rather than in negative relation to a British standard.6 Viewing the antebellum U.S. South and nineteenth-century Ireland in comparative perspective reveals that, to a greater or lesser extent, the elites in both locations attempted to modernize their economic behavior in response to transformations in global capitalism associated with the Industrial Revolution. From the late eighteenth century onward, British industrialization and urbanization increased demand for agricultural raw materials and foodstuffs, which affected agrarian regions throughout the Euro-American world. Since U.S. southern plantations provided most of the cotton used in British textile mills and Ireland’s landed estates provided much of the grain, dairy, and livestock that fed the populations of Britain’s cities, these regions both facilitated and were affected by the Industrial Revolution. Competition on international markets and fluctuations in prices for the different agricultural commodities produced in either location prompted responses from the elites, who embarked on systematic drives for economic reform during the nineteenth century. As a result of these developments, a modern form of slavery emerged throughout the New World beginning in the 1790s—in a rejuvenation of American slave-worked plantation agriculture that recent scholarship has called “the second slavery.” This geographical expansion of slavery went hand in hand with the adoption of capitalistic behavior on the part of those slaveholders who engaged in cotton, sugar, and coffee cultivation.7 In Ireland, however, landlords increasingly sought to reform their estates in the decades after 1815.8 Representing a break with their behavior during the eighteenth century, when Irish landlords often relinquished the direct management of their properties to middlemen and played a more passive rentier role, it can be said that this trend constituted a “second landlordism.” In other words, transformations in global capitalism, related to the Industrial Revolution and its consequences, fostered an improving mindset among the elites in the U.S. South and Ireland, prompting them to rationalize their estate management practices, modernize agricultural production, and diversify their economic interests. In many respects, these drives toward improvement constituted modern behavior, notwithstanding that their societies also retained arguably archaic features. se con d slav ery, se con d la n dl o r di sm , a n d m o de r n i t y 2 0 5 JCWE 5.2 2nd pages.indd 205 4/15/2015 5:02:02 PM As he surveyed the aristocracy of the United Kingdom assembled at Westminster in 1839, Quitman may have observed Robert Dillon, third Baron Clonbrock, a young member in attendance and a landlord who lived and owned estates in the west of Ireland.9 These two individuals were prominent agrarian elites whose behavior did not align with the backward stereotypes with which they have often been identified, for both attempted to manage their estates profitably, pursued agricultural improvement, and invested in speculative ventures. As such, they can be taken as representatives of the economically progressive milieus that emerged in the U.S. South during the second slavery and in Ireland during the second landlordism. To illustrate the comparable effects of these phenomena in two local contexts this essay first delineates the theoretical basis for the comparison of a society based on slavery and plantation agriculture with one based on free labor and tenancy, by considering U.S. southern slaveholding and Irish landlordism as labor systems that participated in global capitalism. Second, it examines similarities and differences among some modern features exhibited by Quitman and Clonbrock—modern in the sense that they represented adaptive responses to international market developments. Comparing the management of Quitman’s and Clonbrock’s estates, their pursuits of agricultural modernization, and their nonagricultural investments will demonstrate that both progressive southern slaveholders and Irish landlords embraced certain capitalistic attitudes during the nineteenth century. Recognition of this moves beyond ahistorical dichotomies that posit “backwardness” in fixed and diametric opposition to “modernity”; rather, modern features could and did emerge in supposedly “backward” contexts, including the American South during the second slavery and Ireland during the second landlordism. ■ The U.S. South has been usefully compared with agrarian regions of Europe by Peter Kolchin, Shearer Davis Bowman, and Enrico Dal Lago, who have respectively examined similarities and differences with Russia, Prussian East-Elbia and the Italian South.10 Much can be learned from adding Ireland to this list, especially in light of the historical tendency to equate Ireland’s free peasantry with slaves.11 This agenda is aided by the fact that, in A Sphinx on the American Land (2003), Kolchin has discussed the possibilities for comparing the American South with what he calls “other Souths”: regions external to the United States with which the U.S. South is comparable.12 Nineteenth-century Ireland can be seen as one of several “other Souths,” especially if we accept the proposition that—with important distinctions between the free and unfree nature of the agrarian labor systems and the crops produced in either region—its landed 206 j o u r n a l o f t h e c i v i l wa r e r a , volum e 5 , i s s u e 2 JCWE 5.2 2nd pages.indd 206 4/15/2015 5:02:02 PM estates, oriented toward the export of agricultural commodities, fulfilled a comparable peripheral role within global capitalism to that of American plantations. This assumption relies on the work of Immanuel Wallerstein, according to whom a capitalist world economy emerged, starting in the sixteenth century, with the Euro-American world divided into core, semi-peripheral, and peripheral regions, each defined by its economic function within a transnational system of trade. By this view of history, peripheries were regions geared toward the growth and export of agricultural commodities and provided markets for manufactured goods produced in economically and politically stronger core regions. In the eighteenth century, England emerged as the core of the capitalist world economy, with its ongoing industrialization thereafter. These developments affected, and were affected by, agriculture in the U.S. South and Ireland, both of which, in a fundamental economic sense, functioned as peripheries.13 It would be a mistake to reduce the U.S. South and Ireland to undifferentiated peripheral status, however, and this is not necessary if we follow Dale Tomich’s suggestions on how to refine Wallerstein’s model.14 While American slavery and Irish tenancy both owed their origins to the expansion of the capitalist world economy in the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries, they were very different agrarian labor systems: one based on slavery, the other on free labor. In the New World, with land abundant and labor scarce, plantations were established from the late 1500s onward as a suitable means of mass producing staple crops in demand on world markets, and, through a process of elimination of other labor arrangements, African slaves were increasingly favored to work them. Although there were many important variations within New World slavery in different times and places, it was everywhere a form of legal servitude characterized by racial exploitation, compulsion, and violence.15 Irish landlordism, by contrast, relied on more indirect methods of labor control. In Ireland, landed estates—based on an English model introduced during the 1500s and 1600s—saw a bipartite division between the landowner’s demesne and tenancies. While landlords sometimes engaged in commercial farming on a portion of their estates, most of their wealth derived from the cash rents that they charged free tenants in return for access to land. To pay these rents, tenants subsisted mostly on potatoes and farmed grain and livestock as cash crops; they sold this produce at local markets and fairs, from whence the majority was exported, primarily to Britain from the 1750s onwards. In general, Irish peasants had no property rights to the land they farmed and were subject to a variety of exploitative leasing arrangements.16 This arguably rendered them a dependent secon d slav ery, se con d la n dl o r di sm , a n d m o de r n i t y 2 0 7 JCWE 5.2 2nd pages.indd 207 4/15/2015 5:02:02 PM workforce and called into question the practical significance of their legal freedom. Despite the many differences between unfree plantation agriculture and “free” tenancy, then, American slavery and Irish landlordism are comparable as systems of rural subjection that operated within global capitalism. The raison d’être of these systems was to generate wealth from the production of agricultural commodities in demand on international markets—markets dominated by industrializing Britain during the nineteenth century. As such, the common dependent status of American slaves and Irish peasants was a function of the development of global capitalism. Put another way, African American slaves and Irish tenant-farmers were exploited in very different ways, but they were also part of a wider system of exploitation that characterized a global and capitalist division of labor.17 Yet, despite the commercialized nature of agriculture on their estates, U.S. slaveholders and Irish landlords were considered by many nineteenth-century commentators to have been “backward” groups. *****End of excerpt ***** If you are not already a subscriber, please visit our subscription page. The Journal of the Civil War Era also is available electronically, by subscription, at Project Muse. 208 j o u r n a l o f t h e c i v i l wa r e r a , vo lum e 5, i s s u e 2 JCWE 5.2 2nd pages.indd 208 4/15/2015 5:02:02 PM
© Copyright 2024