Options and Outcomes - Chapter 10 Chapter 10 How Are Costs Determined and What Do They Mean? In the previous chapter, we explored a little about production. We did that so that we can understand the supply decisions of sellers, by better understanding cost. Ultimately, supply decisions are based on cost. We've seen something of cost in the past, but now we introduce new shapes, sizes, and flavors (mouth watering flavors, at that). How Do We Determine Cost? Which costs are easy to count, and which are not? One way to think about cost is to simply add up the money payments that using resources (to make output) will entail. The costs of using resources that must be purchased, and thus require monetary payment are called explicit costs. However, as we have already seen, the cost of doing or using something can also mean the alternatives given up or the opportunity cost. The opportunity costs associated with using resources that are owned by a firm (producer), and which don’t involve a money payment, are called implicit costs. Obviously, finding out the implicit costs of producing a product can be difficult, since there are no receipts or cancelled checks to record. 115 116 One implicit cost that can be estimated is the implicit (normal) rate of return that must be earned by investors to continue to supply capital to a firm. This is called the opportunity cost of capital, equal to the amount of interest income that could be earned on alternative investments. This is roughly the interest that could be earned if the capital assets owned by the firm were sold, and the funds invested in some other way. Notice, it is not really the opportunity cost of the capital owned by the firm, as that would require an estimate of the rental value in its next best use, or some similar estimate, but it is an approximation at least. 117 Which costs change when output increases, and which do not? In the short run, some costs won't change when output is increased or decreased. We call the costs that cannot be (or don't need to be) changed in the short run fixed costs. Fixed costs are the costs associated with capital and similarly fixed inputs (in the short run). The costs that do change when output is increased or decreased in 118 115 116 117 118 explicit costs -money costs; expenditures for resources that must be purchased or rented, and thus require money payment implicit costs - opportunity costs of using resources that do not require money payment to obtain or use opportunity cost of capital -and estimate of the implicit costs of the firm's assets, based on the interest income that could have been earned if a similar sum had been invested at the going interest rate fixed costs -costs that do not change in the short run as output is changed; the costs associated with fixed inputs in the short run Copyright 2006 by Ray Bromley How Are Costs Determined? 93 Options and Outcomes - Chapter 10 the short run are called variable costs. Variable costs are the costs associated with labor and other variable inputs in the short run. Notice, fixed costs can be implicit or explicit, as can variable costs. 119 Which costs help us make decisions in the short run? Since only variable costs can change in the short run, all short run decisions are made based solely on variable costs (we will talk about the long run later in the chapter). Even so, there are different kinds of variable costs, each of which is helpful in making different kinds of short run decisions. As was pointed out on page 87, there are different kinds of sellers who may make different kinds of decisions. However, they all use the same measures of cost to do so. Just to get some idea of how the costs are used, we will start out showing the kinds of decisions that a seller would make if he or she were such a small part of the market that the price is outside of his or her control. This kind of seller is called a price taker, and we will examine the decisions of price takers in greater detail in the next chapter. 120 How does a seller decide whether to produce anything? Suppose a seller is trying to decide whether to make any product at all. If the seller decides not to make anything on a particular day (or week or month) the seller will still have her fixed costs, but can avoid the variable costs in the short run. She can do this by having all of the workers stay home and by not ordering any materials. This is still a short run decision, just a sort of big one. To make this decision the seller will weigh the utility of producing today, for example, against the cost. We assume that the utility would be today's revenue (you know, PxQ) and the cost would be the variable cost of operating today. When considering today’s variable cost against today’s revenue, if Revenue Variable Cost, then the seller will open up (produce), 121 because the utility is at least as great at the cost of opening up. In other terms, if PxQ Variable Cost, then the seller will open up. Dividing by the amount of output, Q, we get P Q Variable Cost , then open up, if Q Q or if P Variable Cost , then open up. Q We call the variable cost per unit of output average variable cost (AVC), Variable Cost in the above equation. which is simply Q 122 119 120 121 122 94 variable costs -those costs that do change in the short run as output is changed; the costs of using variable inputs price taker -a seller that takes the market price; a seller that is such a small part of the market that it cannot control the price or set a price much different from that of other sellers open up - to produce output in the short run; to operate average variable cost (AVC) -variable cost per unit of output How Are Costs Determined? Copyright 2006 by Ray Bromley Options and Outcomes - Chapter 10 So, the seller will find it worthwhile to open up if P AVC (Average Variable Cost). Otherwise, if price is less than average variable cost, the seller will chose not to open up, or will choose to shut down. 123 AVC will depend on the level of output that the seller produces, but as long as the price is greater than AVC at even its lowest point (its minimum), it will pay to open. How is average variable cost related to production? Variable Cost , and thus can always Q be determined if we know variable cost and the amount of output being produced, Q, it is also related to the measures of production that we explored earlier in the chapter. Specifically, it is related to average product. This is because the variable cost is the cost of the variable input. If we focus on labor as being the variable input, then the cost of using it is its price (or wage ) times the amount of labor being used. So, variable cost = wage x variable input or VC= wage x labor. Variable Cost wage labor = . Average Variable Cost = Q Q While average variable cost is defined as 124 But using some math... Average Variable Cost = wage labor labor variable input = wage x = wage x . Q Q output output , which is the variable input mathematical inverse of the last term in our average variable cost formula. variable input 1 In other words, is . output average product But, on page 91, we found that the average product is Thus, Average Variable Cost = wage x Average Variable Cost = variable input 1 = wage x or output average product wage . average product If you don't follow all of that, just remember the last line, and know that the average variable cost in inversely related to the average product. 123 124 shut down - decision to cease producing output; to not open or operate in the short run wage -the price of a unit of labor Copyright 2006 by Ray Bromley How Are Costs Determined? 95 Options and Outcomes - Chapter 10 Application: finding average variable cost Returning to our cake example (see page 91), if ten hours of labor are hired at $15 an hour, the variable cost (of labor) is $15x10=$150. If the ten hours of labor produce 21 cakes, the average variable cost of each cake is $150 21 = $7.14 (approximately). But to find the average variable cost of each cake, we could have instead used the average product. We found that the average product of labor is 2.1 cakes if 10 hours of labor is used. The wage $15 is thus average product 2.1 , which also gives us $7.14 as the average variable cost. Similar calculations can be found below. Labor input (hours) 0 Cakes (Q) 0 Average Product (AP) Variable Cost, VC (wage=$15) wage AVC calculation AP = 1 1 1 $15 VC 15 Q 1 Average Variable Cost or 2 3 1.5 $30 15 15 1 1.5 $15 or 4 9 2.25 $60 30 15 3 2.25 $10 or 6 14 2.33 $90 60 15 9 2.33 $6.67 or 8 18 2.25 $120 90 15 14 2.25 $6.43 or 10 21 2.1 $150 120 15 18 2.1 $6.67 or 150 21 $7.14 How much product is it worthwhile to produce and sell? Suppose a seller is trying to decide whether she can afford to sell a unit of a good at a particular price. If the price a buyer will pay is the only benefit she will receive for selling the good, then she will compare the price to her cost of selling one unit of the good to that buyer. We call the cost of making and selling one unit of a good the marginal cost. Yep, this is our old friend from chapter 2. Now, we are looking at marginal cost as the money cost of using the variable resource or resources to make one additional unit of a change in Variable Cost product. That means that marginal cost is . (Actually, it is also change in Q the change in cost divided by the change in output, but only variable cost can change in the short run). 125 Marginal cost can tell a seller how much output to make or sell. If the price of the good is at least as big as the marginal cost of making one more of the good, then it's worth making and selling that one more unit. The seller will find it worthwhile to make and sell every unit for which P Marginal Cost How is marginal cost related to production? change in Variable Cost change in Q Marginal cost is defined as , and thus can always be determined if we know how much variable cost is changing for a particular change in the amount of output being produced. However, just as the average variable cost is related to average product, the marginal cost of making a product is determined by the marginal product. Remember, variable cost = wage x variable input or VC= wage x labor. 125 96 marginal cost - the cost of producing or selling an additional unit of output How Are Costs Determined? Copyright 2006 by Ray Bromley Options and Outcomes - Chapter 10 So, Marginal Cost = change in Variable Cost change in (wage labor) = . change in Q change in output But, if the wage doesn't change, it turns out that... change in (wage labor) change in variable input Marginal Cost = = wage x . change in output change in output change in output But, remember that marginal product is change in variable input change in variable input matical inverse of the last term. So, marginal cost =wage x marginal cost = is change in output 1 marginal product , which is the mathe1 marginal product , and or wage . marginal product Application: finding marginal cost Returning to our cake example (see page 91), we can find the marginal cost of producing a particular cake, such as the 21st by noting that it takes 10 hours of labor (at a wage of $15) to produce 21 cakes, so the variable cost (of labor) is $15x10=$150. If three fewer cakes had been made, only 8 hours of labor would have been needed at a variable cost of $15x8=$120. So, the difference in variable cost is ($150-$120=) $30 to produce (21-18=) 3 additional cakes. We can thus calculate the cost of each individual (additional) unit of output as change in variable cost change in output = $30 3 =$10. . But to find the marginal cost of the 21st cake, we could have instead used the marginal product. We found that the marginal product of labor is 1.5 cakes if 10 hours of labor is used. The wage marginal product is thus $15 1.5 , which also gives us $10.00 as the marginal cost. Similar calculations can be found below (MC stands for marginal cost). Labor input (hours) 0 1 Cakes (Q) 0 1 Marginal Product (MP) 1 Variable Cost, VC (wage=$15) $15 calculation of MC as calculation of MC as Marginal Cost Copyright 2006 by Ray Bromley 2 3 2 $30 4 9 3 $60 6 14 2.5 $90 8 18 2 $120 10 21 1.5 $150 change in VC 15 - 0 30 - 15 60 - 30 90 - 60 120 - 90 150 - 90 change in Q 1- 0 3 -1 9-3 14 - 9 18 - 14 21- 18 wage 15 15 15 15 15 15 MP 1 2 3 2.5 2 1.5 $15 $7.50 $5 $6 $7.50 $10 How Are Costs Determined? 97 Options and Outcomes - Chapter 10 How are average variable cost and average total cost related? Figure 10-1 COST PER UNIT of OUTPUT minimums MARGINAL COST AVERAGE TOTAL COST AVERAGE VARIABLE COST Q = OUTPUT OUTPUT PER UNIT of INPUT diminishing returns maximum AVERAGE PRODUCT AVERAGE PRODUCT MARGINAL PRODUCT INPUT The rules we discussed for the relationship between marginal product and average product also work for marginal cost and average variable cost. If the marginal cost (of a particular unit of output) is greater than the average variable cost, the average variable cost will go up when that output is produced. You can see this relationship on the graph of marginal cost and average variable cost to the left (Figure 10-1). At the amount of input for which average variable cost is minimized, marginal cost is equal to average variable cost. At input levels where marginal cost is above average variable cost, the average variable cost is rising (the curve slopes up as more output is produced). At input levels where marginal cost is below average variable cost, average variable cost is falling (the curve slopes down). If the graph of marginal cost and average variable cost looks like an upside down version of the marginal product/average product graph, remember that marginal cost is inversely related to marginal product, and average variable cost is inversely related to average product. If marginal product is rising, marginal cost is falling, and vice versa. If average product is rising, average variable cost is falling, and vice versa. What have we learned about supply choices, so far? So far, we have learned that a producer (price taker) can decide whether to operate (produce, open up) by comparing the price to average variable cost at its lowest level. So, the question... "Should the seller produce ANY output?" is answered by asking "is PAVC at the minimum AVC?" If so, operate; otherwise, shut down. Also, a producer will find it adds to its profit by making and selling only those units of output that will sell for a price at least as great as the marginal cost of making or selling them. The question... "How much output should the seller make or sell?" is answered by asking the question "is P MC for this amount of output?" The producer then produces every unit of output for which the price is at least as great as the marginal cost. 98 How Are Costs Determined? Copyright 2006 by Ray Bromley Options and Outcomes - Chapter 10 Application: making short run decisions Using our cake example, and the costs that we have found… Labor input (hours) 0 1 2 4 6 8 10 Cakes (Q) 0 1 3 9 14 18 21 Average Variable Cost (of labor) $15 $10 $6.67 $6.43 $6.67 $7.14 Marginal Cost (of labor) $15 $7.50 $5 $6 $7.50 $10 Let’s add in the additional marginal cost of ingredients (materials). Suppose that, in addition to the labor costs shown above, every cake involves a materials cost of $1. This would add $1 to each calculation of average variable cost and marginal cost, making the cost table look like… Cakes (Q) 0 1 3 9 14 18 21 AVC $16 $11 $7.67 $7.43 $7.67 $8.14 MC $16 $8.50 $6 $7 $8.50 $11 What is the lowest that the price of a cake can be, if this producer is to make any cake? Remember, the price has to be at least as big as the minimum average variable cost, which is $7.43 (at least on the table). As long as the price is that high or higher, the producer will make output. This occurs at an output of 14 cakes, so if the producer makes any cake, she will make at least that many. Suppose that the market price of cakes is $9.00. The producer will make cakes, since the price is greater than the minimum AVC. We also know that she will make at least 14 cakes. In addition, she will make every cake for which the marginal cost is less than (or perhaps just) $9.00. The marginal cost of the 18th cake is $8.50 and the marginal cost of the 21st cake is $11, so the producer would be willing to make 18 cakes, but not 21. In fact, if we knew more about the individual cakes’ marginal costs, we might discover a different output for the producer, but given the jumps of output on the table, our best guess would be that the producer will make 18 cakes. How do we figure out profits? So far, we have not discussed profit much. In the short run, if a seller makes the decisions we outlined above, it will be making as much money as it can, given its costs. Since we have discussed all the decisions that the firm can make in the short run, calculating how big profit is will simply enable us to see, after the decisions are made, how well the firm is doing. In this sense, it is like the score of a game; you play the best you can, but if in the end you lose, there really isn't much else you could have done differently. Profit is calculated by finding the revenues of the firm minus its costs. Actually, there are two ways of computing profit. If profit is calculated by taking the firm’s total revenue and subtracting only the explicit costs, we find what is called accounting profit. When all costs (including the implicit) are deducted from revenue, the result is called economic profit, which is generally less than accounting profit. All costs (fixed and variable) that we consider in economics will include the implicit as well as explicit cost. So, when we talk of profit, we will mean economic profit, unless we specify accounting profit. 126 127 To figure out profit, we need to figure out all of the costs. If all of the costs of the firm are added together, we call the result total cost. Total cost is thus the sum of fixed costs (FC) and variable costs (VC). So far, since fixed costs can’t be altered in the short run, we have not done much with them here. However, they will play a role when we 126 127 accounting profit – profit calculated by subtracting explicit costs from revenue economic profit – profit calculated by subtracting both implicit and explicit costs from revenue Copyright 2006 by Ray Bromley How Are Costs Determined? 99 Options and Outcomes - Chapter 10 calculate profit. Total Cost (TC) = VC + FC Profit is Revenue minus Total Cost, or Profit= Revenue - Total Cost, or But, remember that revenues are the price (P) of the product times the amount of the product that is made and sold (Q), so Profit = PxQ - TC On a per unit basis, dividing by output (Q), profit per unit of output would be Profit P Q Total Cost Total Cost = =PQ Q Q Q Total Cost is average total cost (ATC), which is total cost divided by the amount of Q output. Thus, profit per unit of output is simply P - ATC. 128 If the price is bigger than the ATC, the profit will be positive. So, the question "is profit being made by the seller, at the output selected?" is answered by asking "is P> ATC for this amount of output?" To find profit, we can find the revenue of the amount of output being produced and subtract the total cost of making it. But another way would be to find profit per unit and then multiply the profit per unit by the amount of output actually being produced (designated as Q*). Profit per unit is calculated as the price minus the average total cost of producing the selected quantity of output (ATC*), since the amount of output will affect the size of average total cost. Profit = Q* x (P-ATC*) 128 100 average total cost (ATC)– total cost per unit of output being produced How Are Costs Determined? Copyright 2006 by Ray Bromley Options and Outcomes - Chapter 10 What is average total cost like? ATC will vary depending on how much output we produce. How does ATC change as output is increased? Remember that Total Cost (TC) = VC + FC, so Total Cost Total Cost Variable Cost Fixed Cost VC+FC = = = + ATC = Q Q Q Q Q But, we already know that Variable Cost is average variable cost (AVC). Q Fixed Cost is also a kind of average cost, which Q $ we call average fixed cost (AFC). What does average fixed cost look like? Well, the fixed cost (the numerator) won't change, but at bigger values of output (Q) we will be dividing by a bigger number, so AFC will get smaller as Q gets bigger, as can be seen at the right (Figure 10-2). Figure 10-2 129 If we add AVC to AFC, we get average total cost (ATC), which is also total cost divided by the amount of output. Knowing this will help us understand what ATC is like, since it will look like AVC with AFC added on. This means that ATC will be far above the AVC for small amounts of output, and will get closer to AVC as output is increased (as shown below in Figure 10-3). Notice that the relationship between the marginal cost and average total cost is similar to the relationship between marginal cost and average variable cost. If the marginal cost is above ATC, ATC is rising. If the marginal cost is below ATC, ATC is falling. Marginal cost crosses ATC at the minimum average total cost. COST PER UNIT of OUTPUT AFC= FC/Q Q Figure 10-3 minimums MARGINAL COST AVERAGE TOTAL COST AVERAGE VARIABLE COST Q = OUTPUT 129 average fixed cost (AFC)- short run fixed cost divided by the amount of output being produced Copyright 2006 by Ray Bromley How Are Costs Determined? 101 Options and Outcomes - Chapter 10 Summary of the uses of short run costs: 1. When deciding whether to produce anything in the short run: "Should the seller produce ANY output?" is really asking "is PAVC at the minimum AVC?" 2. When deciding how much to produce in the short run: "How much output should the seller make or sell?" is really asking "is P MC for this amount of output?" The amount of output for which every unit has a marginal cost no greater than the price will be the right amount to produce and sell. This amount can be called Q*. 3. When trying to learn whether the seller is making any profit: "is profit being made by the seller, at the output (Q*) selected?" is really asking "is P ATC for this amount of output?" If it is, then the amount of profit is Q* times P-ATC*, where the ATC* is the average total cost of producing exactly Q* units. Application: finding short run average total cost and profit Returning to our cake example, suppose we want to determine what the profit will be if our baker produces the profit-maximizing number of cakes. To find profit, we can find the income or revenue from selling cake, and subtract the total cost of the amount of cake being produced. We could also use the average total cost to help us. To find average total cost, we need to know fixed cost. Suppose that fixed costs are $20 per day. We can find average total cost by either taking the total cost of making each amount of output and dividing by output, or by finding average fixed cost and adding it to average variable cost. Labor input (hours) 0 1 2 4 6 8 10 Cakes (Q) 0 1 3 9 14 18 21 Variable Cost of Labor (VCL) 0 $15 $30 $60 $90 $120 $150 Variable Cost of Materials (VCM) 0 $1 $3 $9 $14 $18 $21 Fixed cost (FC) $20 $20 $20 $20 $20 $20 $20 Total Cost (FC+VCL+VCM) $20 $36 $53 $89 $124 $158 $191 calculation of ATC as Average Total Cost calculation of AFC as TC Q 36 1 53 3 89 9 124 14 158 18 191 21 $36 $17.67 $9.89 $8.86 $8.78 $9.10 FC 20 20 20 20 20 20 Q 1 3 9 14 18 21 Average Fixed Cost $20 $6.67 $2.22 $1.43 $1.11 $0.95 AVC (including materials @ $1 each) $16 $11 $7.67 $7.43 $7.67 $8.14 ATC as AVC+AFC $36 $17.67 $9.89 $8.86 $8.78 $9.09 Notice that the value of the ATC of producing 21 cakes will be a different number depending on how it is calculated, due to rounding error. As we already found, if the market price of cakes is $9.00, the producer would be willing to make 18 cakes (but not 21). One way to find profit is to determine revenue and subtract all costs. The revenue from making 18 cakes and selling them for $9 each would be 18x$9=$162. The total cost of making 18 cakes (from the table above) is $168. Thus, profit is $162-$158=$4. To calculate the profit using average total cost, we could find the profit per unit (price minus ATC) and multiply by the number of cakes being made (18). This gives us $9-$8.78=$0.22 profit per cake. Multiplying by 18 cakes gives 18 x $0.22 = $3.96, which is off a little due to rounding in the ATC calculation. 102 How Are Costs Determined? Copyright 2006 by Ray Bromley Options and Outcomes - Chapter 10 How do we show the long run? In the long run, costs are all variable. This means that even capital can be altered. Output can be changed by changing both capital and labor. We say that when a producer is changing the amount of capital and other inputs that it is using, the producer is changing its "scale." You can think of scale as an acronym (although it isn't) – Scale is Capital And Labor and Everything. 130 How do we show changing everything? Well, we sort of cheat. Since the short run cost curves show changing everything but capital, we think of changing scale in the long run as allowing the producer to pick which short run average total cost curve it wants to have. If a firm picks a different short run average total cost, it is doing so by acquiring a different amount of capital in the long run, to which it will apply its variable inputs in the short run. Any change in capital in the long run can be shown by picking a different short run average total cost curve. Changing other inputs in the long run can be shown (as they are in the short run) by picking a different point on a short run average total cost curve, or moving along a particular short run average total cost curve. If we draw all of the short run average total cost curves that a producer could select between, and then draw another curve containing all of these, the new curve is called the long run average total cost curve. It is also called long run average cost, since there is no meaningful distinction between fixed, variable and total cost in the long run. This is shown in Figure 10-4 below. 131 Figure 10-4 $ SRATC curves Long Run Average Total Cost Diseconomies of Scale Economies of Scale Increasing Returns to Scale Constant Returns to Scale Decreasing Returns to Scale Output SCALE 130 131 scale- the size of a firm or producing entity in the long run; increasing the output of a firm in the long run by increasing all of inputs, including capital, is increasing scale. long run average (total) cost- average total cost in the long run as output is increased by changing scale; the curve showing long run average total cost is the lower boundary of all of the possible short run average total cost curves. Copyright 2006 by Ray Bromley How Are Costs Determined? 103 Options and Outcomes - Chapter 10 The long run average total cost curve slopes down (indicating lower average costs) if the scale is increased from a very small scale to a little larger scale. These declining average costs as scale is increased are called "economies of scale" or "increasing returns to scale." 132 As output and scale are increased, a point is reached at which greater scale no longer decreases average costs. This begins the range of output for which we say there are "constant returns to scale;" average costs neither rise nor fall as scale is increased. 133 Eventually, larger scale will lead to average costs getting larger. This is referred to as "diseconomies of scale," or "decreasing returns to scale." 134 Remember, scale can only be changed in the long run, so any mention of scale means we are talking about the long run. $ SRATC curves Long Run Average Total Cost Diseconomies of Scale Economies of Scale Increasing Returns to Scale Constant Returns to Scale Decreasing Returns to Scale Output SCALE 132 133 134 104 economies of scale- the situation of decreasing average total cost as scale is increased; average total costs fall as more output is produced. Also called "increasing returns to scale." constant returns to scale- the situation in which changing scale does not alter average total cost diseconomies of scale- the situation of increasing average total cost as scale is increased; average total costs rise as more output is produced. Also called "decreasing returns to scale." How Are Costs Determined? Copyright 2006 by Ray Bromley Options and Outcomes - Chapter 10 Questions for Review and Practice 1 What is the difference between accounting profit and economic profit? Which will generally be larger? 2 If a firm is making accounting profit, will it necessarily make economic profit? If a firm is making economic profit, will it necessarily be making accounting profit? 3 If a firm is making zero economic profit, what does it mean? Will the firm go out of business in the short run? What about the long run? 4 What is marginal cost? How is it related to the marginal product of an input in the short run? 5 What is average variable cost? How is it related to average product of an input in the short run? 6 What is average total cost? How is it related to productivity of variable inputs in the short run? 7 What relationship does marginal cost have to average variable cost? What relationship does marginal cost have to average total cost? 8 Which kind of cost is relevant to a firm’s decision to increase output in the short run? 9 Describe the differences between diminishing returns to a variable input and diseconomies of scale. What do the two concepts have in common? 10 The following table shows production possibilities for a small business in the short run. Fixed costs are $200 and the wage (price of the variable input) is $10. Fill in the missing portions of the table, then answer the questions on the following page. labor price=$10 Fixed cost= =$200 Variable Input (Labor) Total Product (Q) Marginal Product (MP) Average Product (AP) 0 0 - - 1 5 5 5 2 20 15 10 3 33 13 11 4 44 11 5 54 10 6 63 9 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 71 78 84 89 93 96 98 99 99 8 7 6 Copyright 2006 by Ray Bromley 10 200 Average Variable Cost Total Cost (TC) $0 - $200 - - - $10.00 $2.00 $210 $40.00 $42.00 $2.00 $20.00 $1.00 $220 $10.00 $11.00 $0.67 $30.00 $0.91 $230 $6.06 $6.97 $0.77 11 $40.00 $0.91 $240 $4.55 $5.45 $0.91 10.8 $50.00 $0.93 $250 $3.70 $4.63 $1.00 10.5 $60.00 $0.95 $260 $3.17 $4.13 $1.11 10.1429 $70.00 $0.99 $270 $2.82 $3.80 $1.25 9.75 $80.00 $1.03 $280 $2.56 $3.59 $1.43 9.33333 $90.00 $1.07 $290 $2.38 $3.45 $1.67 8.9 $100.00 $1.12 $300 $2.25 $3.37 $2.00 8.45455 $110.00 $1.18 $310 $2.15 $3.33 $2.50 $120.00 $1.25 $320 $2.08 $3.33 $3.33 2 7.53846 $130.00 $1.33 $330 $2.04 $3.37 $5.00 1 7.07143 $140.00 $1.41 $340 $2.02 $3.43 $10.00 $1.52 $350 $2.02 $3.54 - 5 4 3 0 8 6.6 Variable Cost (VC) $150.00 Average Fixed Cost Average Total Cost Marginal Cost (MC) How Are Costs Determined? 105 Options and Outcomes - Chapter 10 10a 10b 10c 10d 10e 10f 10g 10h 10i 10j 10k 106 What happens to total product when marginal product is zero? What happens to average product when marginal product is greater than average product? What happens to average product when marginal product is less than average product? At what amount of input does marginal product begin to decrease? At what level of total product does marginal cost begin to increase? (In other words, at what level of output will the marginal cost first be higher than it was for smaller outputs on the table?) What is the approximate minimum marginal cost? (In other words, what is marginal cost before it begins to increase?) From the values on the table, describe how marginal product and marginal cost are related? What is happening to average variable cost when it equals marginal costs? Marginal cost equals average variable cost at what output level? What is happening to average total cost when it equals marginal cost? Marginal cost equals average total cost at what output level? 11 A finance professor recently criticized a local firm for including “normal return to capital (normal profit)” as a cost in its annual report. “How can profit be a cost?” he laughed. Using economics, how might you respond to the finance professor? 12 Which of the following statements are true and which are false? A. Since implicit costs do not involve payment, they should not be considered as costs when decisions are made. B. If the use of resources owned by the firm does not involve a financial transaction, accounting statements will generally fail to account for the opportunity costs of their use. C. The use of resources owned by the firm will have no opportunity cost, and thus should not be considered as contributing to cost. D. If use of a resource involves only a money payment, then it is not an implicit cost. E. Resources owned by a firm do not generally have alternative uses, and thus there are no implicit costs in real life. F. Use of factory space owned by a firm will usually involve an implicit cost. G. The payment for use of electricity by a firm is generally an explicit cost. H. The time put into a business by its owner has no cost. I. The time put into a business by its owner is an explicit cost. J. If a firm uses vehicles it owns, the gasoline and maintenance costs must be paid for in money, so all of the costs of using the vehicles are explicit. K. The effects of economies of scale can only be seen in the long run. How Are Costs Determined? Copyright 2006 by Ray Bromley
© Copyright 2024