The Impact of Capital Gain Taxes and Transaction Costs on Asset Bubbles Yue Shen∗† Queen’s University May 29, 2015 Abstract In this paper we evaluate the effects of taxes and transaction costs on asset bubbles. We construct a model of asset bubbles by incorporating purchase into the framework of Abreu and Brunnermeier (2003) so that capital gains can be evaluated. We find that the capital gain tax has no effect on the size of the bubble when there is perfect capital loss tax credit, and the bubble size is decreasing in the capital gain tax when there is no tax credit. Therefore dealing with bubbles with the capital gain tax not only requires imposing the tax, but also requires tightening the policies on tax credit. In addition, the size of the bubble is decreasing in the transaction cost and the return from outside option. This implies that central banks’ low interest policies could induce bubbles in, for instance, real estate and stock markets. To show that our model can potentially be tested, we explore several historical bubbles and identify their actual sizes from data. After normalization, we compare these actual sizes of bubbles and fit them into theoretical results derived from the model. 1 Introduction Since the 2008 US subprime mortgage crisis, housing prices in certain major cities outside the United States have been steadily increasing at speeds higher than their historical norms, including those in London (UK), Vancouver, Toronto, Beijing, Shanghai, Hong Kong1 , and most capital cities in Australia. For example, house prices in London rose by 18% in 2013 alone. The upsurging prices have raised serious concerns that bubbles are developing in these cities. Although the ongoing discussion on macroprudential policies might help regulate domestic financial practitioners, these policies seem to be ineffective when international “hot money” and private investors contribute greatly to the bubbles, and there is no consensus on the implementation of these policy tools. A different choice would be a tax. There is a large literature on the ∗ I am grateful to James Bergin and Frank Milne for numerous valuable comments. I thank Ruqu Wang, Marco Cozzi, Rui Gao, Steve Kivinen, Marie-Louise Vierø, Tianyi Wang, Jan Zabojnik, Chenggang Zhou, and participants in CEA and department seminars at Queen’s. All errors are my own. † Department of Economics, Queen’s University, Kingston, Ontario, Canada. [email protected] 1 Housing prices in hundreds of smaller cities in China are also inflating rapidly. effects of financial transaction taxes on price volatilities, but to our knowledge the effectiveness of taxes on asset bubbles, especially capital gains tax, has not been studied by the existing literature. With or without economic theories, governments and law makers are ready to intervene, or have already done so. Chancellor George Osborne of the British parliament said that as of April 2015 he would introduce a capital gains tax on future gains made by non-residents who sell residential properties in the United Kingdom2 . In 2013 the Chinese government introduced a 20% tax on capital gains from selling residential properties if a family owns multiple properties. There is an urgent need to assess the effectiveness of these tax policies on reducing bubbles. We evaluate the effects of capital gains tax and transaction costs on asset bubbles. Our model incorporates purchases into the framework of Abreu and Brunnermeier (2003) (henceforth AB2003) and transforms the uncertainty from the dimension of time in AB2003 to the dimension of value/price. The bubble arises from the interaction between rational traders and behavioral agents. The asset fundamental jumps up to an unobservable value, which can be interpreted as a positive productivity shock. Rational traders have private belief about the new fundamental and their purchases continuously drive up the price. When the price rises above the underlying fundamental value, a bubble emerges. But since a rational trader does not know how many others have higher (or lower) beliefs than her, there is no common knowledge about the emergence of the bubble, which is the key ingredient that induces a bubble. When all rational traders believe that the price is too high and have stopped buying, the bubble bursts. The framework of AB2003 is shown to be consistent with recent empirical studies of stock market data. Temin and Voth (2004) show that a major investor in the South Sea bubble knew that a bubble was in progress and nonetheless invested in the stock and hence was profiting from riding the bubble. Brunnermeier and Nagel (2004) and Griffin et al. (2011) both study the tech bubble in the late 1990s. They show that instead of correcting the price bubble, hedge funds turned out to be the most aggressive investors. They profited during the upturn and unloaded their positions before the downturn. Our model features the following dynamics in equilibrium. At the beginning all rational traders try to buy the asset from a passive behavioral agent. As the price rises continuously, traders with the lowest beliefs stop purchasing and simply hold while others are buying. As the price is further driven up, lowbelief traders start to sell, intermediate-belief traders stop buying and simply hold, and only high-belief traders are still buying. The bubble bursts when the highest type stops buying. Rational traders can buy and sell at any time, but a bubble exists in the unique equilibrium and traders ride the bubble and try to 2 See Chancellor George Osborne’s Autumn Statement 2013 speech on 5 December 2013 at the UK Parliament. 2 sell before the crash to make a profit. Each trader uses a trigger strategy that consists of a threshold for selling and a threshold to stop buying. A trader holds the asset (if she has bought the asset) and waits, and when the price reaches her optimal selling threshold she sells all shares. The optimal selling threshold trades off the marginal benefit of waiting a bit longer to capture more price appreciation with the marginal cost from the risk of being caught in the crash. Knowing her selling plan, when the price reaches her stop-buy threshold, a trader stops buying (if she has not been able to buy due to the exogenous market friction). In the model rational traders first buy the asset and then sell, as a result of which we can calculate the net gains and evaluate the effects of capital gains tax. When imposing capital gains tax, we consider two cases: with perfect capital loss tax credit and without any tax credit3 . In our model, the capital loss tax credit is perfect if there is no dollar ceiling on the credit and the credit can be carried backward and forward indefinitely to offset capital gains4 . In this case, the tax benefit (tax exempted due to the credit) can be regarded as a profit5 . In the unique equilibrium, a bubble exists when the capital gains tax and fixed transaction cost are not too large. The first finding of our paper is that capital gains tax has no effect on the size of the bubble when there is a perfect capital loss tax credit, although the bubble size decreases in the tax rate when there is no tax credit. The reason is as follows. Consider first the case without tax credit. Recall that the selling strategies trade off the marginal benefit of waiting with the marginal cost of being caught. When the tax is imposed, traders face the same potential losses but smaller profits, which advises them to behave more cautiously and conservatively. In particular, when tax and transaction cost are small, the tax distorts a rational trader’s selling decision downwards, which in turn squeezes the stop-buy decisions downwards. Hence the bubble becomes smaller. This can be viewed as an indirect effect of the tax on the bubble. When the tax and transaction cost are relatively large, the tax does not distort the selling strategy, but a trader again has to stop buying early because the profit is eroded by the tax and she needs to maintain a 3 Capital loss tax credit is also called capital loss deduction or tax carryover. Due to the risky nature of investment, fluctuations in returns and profits are almost unavoidable in almost all markets, and most tax systems have a capital loss tax credit to help smooth these fluctuations. When an investor incurs a capital loss, she has to apply it against other capital gains for that year. If she still has a loss, then she is entitled to a certain credit to carry forward or backward across tax years. If she has a taxable capital gain next year, the credit can offset the gain on a dollar-to-dollar basis so that only the net gain (if any) is subject to tax. 4 In the United States, an individual who incurs capital losses can use the credit to offset any taxable income up to $3000 each year, and carry the unused credit forward indefinitely. A corporation can only offset capital gains (not other profit) with capital losses and carry it 3 years backward and 5 years forward, without a dollar limit. In Canada the tax code is similar, except that there is no $3000 limit on individuals, but only 50% of the capital gains/losses are included in the tax base for both individuals and corporations, and the tax credit can be carried 3 years backward and forward indefinitely. 5 Constantinides (1983) treats this tax benefit as a profit. 3 minimal expected payoff due to an outside option. This is the direct effect of tax on the bubble, which also deflates the bubble. When there is a perfect tax credit, the tax credit provides a compensation for the loss such that the loss is also “taxed” and becomes smaller. In this case, a perfect tax credit eliminates both the direct and indirect effects of the capital gains tax on the bubble, and the bubble becomes immune to the tax. Thus our paper suggests that to fight bubbles with capital gains taxes, tax authorities should also tighten their policies on tax credits. The second finding is that the transaction cost and an outside option (returns from alternative investment opportunities) can also depress the bubble. The cost and the outside option do not affect selling decisions, but a small cost or outside option has very large marginal depressing effect on stop-buy decisions. This result backs the practice in some countries to reserve a financial transaction tax (though at very low rates). Conversely, lowering the cost or the outside option when they are already small has a significant inflating effect on the bubble. This rationalizes the observations that stock markets and housing prices are inflated when central banks set very low interest rates (the outside option), and warns that further lowering interest rates (to fight shocks from the oil price changes, for instance) could induce even larger bubbles in these markets. Our model generates empirically testable predictions. To show how we can test the two main findings, we explore several historical bubbles. We identify the actual sizes of these bubbles as well as parameters in our model. To compare the actual actual bubble sizes we normalize by dividing them by the identified belief dispersion, which is an important factor that determines bubble size. From the identified parameters we can also calculate the theoretical bubble sizes and compare them to the actual ones. The results so far are inconclusive since currently the sample size is too small. Some of the implications are consistent with existing empirical evidences. When there is no tax credit, an increase in capital gains tax not only reduces demand from rational traders, but sometimes delays their selling and reduces supply (and hence decreases the trading volume). These effects are called “capitalization effect” and “lock-in effect”, respectively, in the literature and are documented in empirical studies of tax incidences such as the Revenue Act of 1978, the Tax Reform Act of 1986 and the Taxpayer Relief Act of 1997 in the United States. We will explore empirical evidences and discuss these implications in detail in Section 7. Our model is related to a large literature which studies the effects of taxes on asset prices. Constantinides (1983) shows that with capital gains tax and tax credit investors have incentives to sell assets with losses immediately and secure tax credits while deferring the selling of assets with gains to put off tax 4 payment. His research focuses on trading strategies under stochastic shocks whereas we focus on strategies facing asset bubbles and crashes with private beliefs. In terms of the effects of the transaction tax on the volatility of asset prices, Westerhoff and Dieci (2006) show that the transaction tax can stabilize prices, whereas others suggest that the tax actually amplifies volatility (e.g. Lanne and Vesala (2010)). Empirical evidences show that ability of the tax to reduce volatility is very limited (e.g. Umlauf (1993) and Hu (1998)). On the other hand, research on the effects of taxes on bubbles is scarce. Scheinkman and Xiong (2003) show that the financial transaction tax can substantially reduce speculative trading volume, but has only a limited impact on the size of the bubble. Our paper explicitly models an asset bubble and evaluates the effects of capital gains tax on trading behavior and the size of bubble, and is complementary to the above literature in understanding the effects of taxes on financial markets. From a modeling perspective, our paper is related to a quickly growing literature on bubbles. For surveys, refer to Brunnermeier (2008), Brunnermeier (2001), Brunnermeier and Oehmke (2012) and Xiong (2013). AB2003 relies on the asynchronous timing of awareness to generate bubbles, whereas we transform the uncertainty from time to value/price and remove their assumption of sequential awareness. AB2003 requires an exogenous exponential price path that grows at an accelerating rate, whereas our model allows for any continuous and strictly increasing price path and is therefore more robust in this sense. In AB2003 the price rises due to behavioral agents. Strategic traders do not raise the price directly but only “allow” the bubble to grow. Our model incorporates purchases into their framework such that the price keeps increasing exactly because rational traders are buying. The burst is triggered when no one wants to buy in our model, which is in contrast to AB2003 where an exogenous selling threshold is imposed. Doblas-Madrid (2012) removes behavioral agents from the framework of AB2003 and instead uses idiosyncratic liquidity shocks to force rational traders to sell and generates trades when the price is low and no one wants to sell. The price is determined in equilibrium every period. However, to support an increasing price path, endowments must also increase over time. Observing the noisy price, agents update their belief, and when the noise in the price can no longer conceal the downward selling pressure, the bubble bursts. The model with the price determined by a spot equilibrium every period is definitely realistic, but is difficult to apply to our setting because we do not have any noise in the price6 . The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, we introduce the model. Section 3 6 To conceal the very first strategic sale in our model, one must assume that there is an extra amount of money injected to balance the strategic sale at that moment, which can be difficult to justify. 5 shows how a trader’s strategy space can be reduced so that we have a simple game to solve. In Section 4 we solve an individual trader’s problem backwards, by first solving for a trader’s optimal selling price and then her stop-buy price. The equilibria with perfect tax credit and without tax credit are characterized in Sections 5 and 6, respectively. Section 7 provides empirical predictions, studies several historical bubbles and shows how we can potentially test the model. Section 8 discusses policy implications. Section 9 concludes. 2 The model Time t is continuous. There are two types of agents: risk neutral rational traders (henceforth traders) and a large passive (behavioral) agent, though the latter is not our primary interest. There is one asset (henceforth the asset) and rational traders also have an outside investment option. The asset has a total supply Q and all shares are held by the passive agent at the beginning. At t = 0 the asset’s fundamental value jumps up from p0 to θ and does not change henceforth. θ is uniformly distributed on [0, ∞)7 and is unobservable to both traders or the passive agent. Without loss of generality, we assume p0 = 0. The outside option provides an expected profit R ≥ 0 which is common knowledge and uncorrelated with θ. A trader cannot hold the asset and the outside option at the same time, and cannot switch to the other if she has bought one. Capital gains from both the asset and the outside option are subject to tax, and a trader will choose to hold the asset only when its expected profit is strictly higher than the outside option. Without loss of generality each trader’s asset position is restricted and normalized to [0, 1]8 . The inverse asset supply function of the passive agent is p(t) = α(Dr (t)) (1) where p(t) is the price at t which is publicly observable, α(·) is a continuous, strictly increasing function and Dr (t) is the total shares held by all traders (the aggregate position of all traders) at t. Since the initial price p(0) = 0, when the fundamental value jumps above 0, traders keep buying the asset from the passive agent which drives up the price continuously. The passive agent’s inverse supply function implies that, for every share she sells to traders, she must be compensated at a price higher than the previous share she sold. This behavior can be interpreted as portfolio diversification requirements or institutional frictions that make the risky asset more valuable to the passive agent when she holds less and less of the asset. 7 The improper uniform distribution on [0, ∞) has well defined posterior belief when we specify how signals are distributed. The uniform prior distribution gives tractable solutions and is adapted from Li and Milne (2014). 8 Limited short selling of the asset is allowed for traders. 6 Alternatively it can be interpreted as an adverse selection problem. When traders have private information about the asset fundamental value and keep buying the asset, it is natural for the uninformed passive agent to respond by raising the price when selling it, as in Kyle (1985). Similar behavioral asset supplies have also been adopted by De Long et al. (1990), where passive investors supply the asset at an increasing price when rational speculators are buying, and by Brunnermeier and Pedersen (2005) and Carlin et al. (2007), where long-term traders buy the asset when strategic traders’ liquidation pushes down the price and sell the asset when strategic traders’ buy-back pushes up the price. In addition, we assume that the price can be arbitrarily high when traders’ aggregate position approaches Q, i.e. lim α(x) = ∞. This guarantees that the price will not stop at a level lower than θ when x−→Q traders have bought all shares (recall that θ can be arbitrarily large). Each trader receives a private signal v which is uniformly distributed on [θ − η2 , θ + η2 ]. There is enough mass of traders (potentially infinite) for each type v, which is to guarantee that we will not run out of buyers while the price is still below θ 9 . Let Φ(θ|v) denote the cumulative distribution function of the belief of a trader v conditioned on v, and φ(θ|v) the corresponding probability density function. Given a signal v, the posterior belief of a trader is that θ is uniformly distributed on [v − η2 , v + η2 ]. Therefore φ(θ|v) = 1 η and Φ(θ|v) = θ−(v− η2 ) 10 . η Figure 1 depicts the posterior belief about θ for trader v, v 0 and v 00 in the case of uniform prior belief. These different posterior beliefs reflect different opinions about the asset Legend: φ(θ|s) φ(θ|v 0 ) φ(θ|v 00 ) v v0 s00 φ(θ|v) φ(θ|v 0 ) φ(θ|v 00 ) θ Figure 1: Posterior beliefs fundamental value. A trader is not sure about her signal’s position within [θ − η2 , θ + η2 ], i.e., a trader does 9 The assumption of infinite mass of traders and limx−→Q α(x) = ∞ together guarantee that it is always possible that the price could exceed θ. Otherwise, when θ is high enough, a trader (with a high enough signal) will foresee that, after traders have bought all of the asset from the passive agent, or after all traders have bought the asset to their maximal capacities, the price will be still below θ, then this trader will never sell the asset, while a trader with a low signal is not sure about this so she sells. The equilibrium strategy in this case will be much more complicated and the result that the asset price is stuck somewhere below its publicly recognized fundamental value simply because we are running out of asset supply or running out of buyers is unrealistic. 10 When θ < η2 , some traders will receive negative signals, which is perfectly compatible with the assumption that θ is non-negative. When θ < η, those with v < η2 will have a truncated belief support because θ cannot be below zero. This cause traders with very low signals different strategies, which will be characterized in Appendix D and G. The rest of this section will ignore this special case. 7 not know how many others’ signals are lower or higher than hers. This is an important element in the model because the lack of common knowledge about the belief of the population prevents traders from perfectly coordinating each other. In contrast, in the standard literature with a common posterior belief, perfect coordination rules out the existence of the bubble by backward induction. In addition, the above specifications are such that all traders’ posterior belief have exactly the same shape except for a horizontal shift. Hence, traders’ buying and selling strategies are dispersed because they have different beliefs, and they behave the same relative to their respective signals which gives simple form of solutions. To make traders enter the market gradually and steadily so that price path is smooth and strictly increasing over time, we add the following market friction. Traders finance their purchases entirely by borrowing, but loans are granted in a smooth stream over time (interest on loans is zero). If a trader wishes to buy, she must wait until she is granted a loan. At each instant, traders who wish to buy are uniformly randomly chosen and granted the loan, irrespective of their types (signals). Hence, traders with loans enter the market sequentially and the price increases steadily. Note that this friction is not essential in our model, and the bubble still exists without it 11 . Once chosen, a trader gets just enough of a loan to buy her desired amount of shares. If she wants to sell, she can do so right away. All her transactions are executed instantly at the current market price. The stream of loans is available long enough (everyone who keeps requesting a loan will eventually get one) so that we do not need to worry that the price may stop rising because loans are not available. Denote u(t) the rate of influx of loan (e.g. $ per second) at the instant t, with u(t) > 0, ∀t ≥ 0, which is exogenous and publicly known. After t = 0, because θ is above the initial price, traders’ purchases continuously drive up the price. When the price is high enough and no one wants to buy any more, the price stops rising. Denote this random stopping time T and the price pT . Given the strategy profile of all types of traders, pT is a function of θ and everyone can perfectly deduce θ from pT when the price stops rising. If pT > θ at this moment, then the existence of the bubble becomes a common knowledge. It is natural to assume that this triggers the bursting of the bubble endogenously (if a bubble exists). This is in contrast to the endogenous bursting in AB2003 where the crash is triggered by a threshold on accumulated sales. After that, the passive agent is willing to buy only at price p = θ, i.e., the price is fixed at θ after T . All traders who still hold the asset have to liquidate at price p = θ to the passive agent. In the end, no trader holds the asset and all shares go back to the passive agent. 11 If traders enter the market all at once at the beginning, they push the price up to the peak instantly, and then the price plummets back instantly. Though this infinitely fast price jumps look unrealistic, the bubble still exists. 8 Individual trader’s purchases and sales cannot be observed by others and only the price is publicly observable. There is no noise in the price, so if sales can affect the price, then θ can be deduced from the first strategic selling, given the strategy profile. To prevent the strategic selling from being inferred from the price and uncertainty resolved prematurely, we assume that a trader’s sale is instantly absorbed by other traders’ purchases, as long as there are traders willing to buy. Specifically, if a trader sells the asset to the passive agent and repay the loan, this repayment instantly becomes a loan available to others buyers. This internal loan transfer is not subject to loan control and thus is not part of the stream u(t). These transactions take place instantly. Hence, u(t) is the net injection of loans into the trader population at instant t, and the strategic selling is digested internally and is not reflected in the price12 . Since all transactions are executed at the current price prescribed by equation (1), the price path is determined by u(t). u(t) is known, hence the entire price path is fully anticipated13 , until the sudden crash. In this model we only require the price to be strictly and continuously increasing over time, so there is no restriction on u(t) as long as u(t) > 0, ∀t, and our model is flexible enough to replicate realistic price dynamics. This is in contrast to AB2003 which relies on an exogenous exponential price growth, and to Doblas-Madrid (2012) which requires exponentially growing endowments to support the price path. A trader incurs a fixed transaction cost c each time she changes her position, irrespective of price or shares traded14 . There is no proportional transaction tax, but there is a capital gains tax of rate τ . The capital gains tax is levied when a trader has a positive profit that has realized (after deduct the fixed transaction cost). A trader’s profit before tax is thus determined by her purchase prices and sale prices, minus the transaction costs. With the capital loss tax credit, when a trader suffers a capital loss L after sale, she is entitled a tax credit L. If she has a capital gain later and needs to pay tax, she will be exempted a tax payment up to the amount of τ L. The capital loss tax credit is said to be perfect if there is no ceiling on the credit and the credit can be carried backwards and forwards indefinitely to offset taxable profits, and therefore the tax benefit τ L can be regarded as a profit. We will discuss the case with perfect tax credit and the case without any tax credit. 12 Assume that the trading volume is not observable. This can be seen from the following steps.R At any time t, the instantaneous increment of traders’ aggregate position t u(ν) is u(t) p(t) , and the aggregate position is Dr (t) = ν=0 p(ν) dν. Combine this equation with p(t) ≡ α(Dr (t)) and the boundary condition p(0) = 0, we can solve qforR p(t). See Appendix A for details. For example, when p(t) = ρDr (t) (i.e. α(·) is linear), 2 t where ρ is a constant, p(t) = ρ ν=0 u(ν)dν. Therefore, the price will keep increasing in a predetermined manner, and there will be no deviation from the anticipated path until the bubble bursts. 14 The reason why we use a fixed transaction cost instead of a proportional transaction tax is that, with a proportional tax, we no longer have simple form of solutions and we have not been able to solve for them due to the existence of inverse of unknown functional Pb∗−1 (·). 13 9 To rule out the possibility that some types of traders never stop buying so that the bubble grows forever, we assume that the size of the bubble has an upper bound B. Once p(t) − θ > B, the bubble bursts exogenously. We are only interested in the case of endogenous burst. We will show that in the equilibrium with endogenous bursting the size of the bubble size is finite and constant so that, if B is large enough, B is never binding. In addition, we assume that all traders selling exactly at the instant when the bubble bursts receive the full pre-crash price. Figure 2 shows a simple example of the dynamics. In each panel, traders’ signals are continuously distributed between θ − η2 and θ + η2 along the horizontal axis, given θ, while the vertical axis measures the mass of traders (at each signal v). The shaded area is the measure of traders who hold the asset. If we assume that everyone who has bought has the same number of shares (which will turn out to be the case in equilibrium), the shaded area is also proportional to Dr (t). In panel (a) at t = 0, everyone wants to buy but none of them have bought any shares yet. In panel (b), some traders (of all types) receive loans and become shareholders, and all others (all types) are seeking to buy. In panel (c), the price is high enough such that low types no longer want to buy but simply hold (the shaded area of “hold” does not rise any more), while the rest are still seeking to buy. In panel (d), the price is even higher such that not only “no-buy” spreads to higher types of traders, but low types now start to sell. However, there are still types who wish to buy. Recall that each type has an infinite number of traders waiting to enter the market. In panel (f), the “no-buy” finally reaches the highest type, θ + η2 , who stops buying. As a result, no one buys any more and the price stops rising and the bubble bursts. Note that in Figure 2, we have assumed that all traders use a trigger strategy, where a trader will not restart buying once she has stopped buying and she will never re-enter the market once she has sold. This strategy will turn out to be the equilibrium strategy. 3 Preliminary analysis In this section, we will define the equilibrium, impose two technical assumptions on traders’ strategies and show that the dynamic game can be simplified to a static-like game by reducing traders’ strategy space. We will establish that in equilibrium traders use trigger strategies (Proposition 3.1) and their decisions are strictly increasing (Lemma 3.1). Readers who are not interested in these details can jump to Section 4. Definition 3.1. A trading equilibrium is a Perfect Bayesian Nash equilibrium in which traders hold the (correct) belief: whenever a trader v is not seeking to buy (temporarily or permanently), she (correctly) 10 number of traders buy buy buy hold θ− η 2 θ+ trader type η 2 θ− η 2 θ+ (a) t = 0 θ− η 2 θ+ (b) buy η 2 (c) buy hold hold hold sell θ− η 2 sell η 2 θ+ η 2 θ− (d) sell η 2 θ+ (e) η 2 θ − η2 θ + η2 (f) t = T , bubble bursts Figure 2: Dynamics of the mass of shareholders believes that all traders with signal equal to or smaller than v are not seeking to buy. This definition imposes a natural assumption on traders’ equilibrium beliefs, without which it will be difficult to characterize an equilibrium. With the positive fixed transaction cost c, a trader will trade only finite number of times. Due to the linearity of the problem and the cost c, it is optimal for traders to either hold the maximum long position or does not hold any asset at all. At any given price, a trader’s asset value is linear in her position. With the transaction cost, if buying is profitable, then it is optimal to buy to the maximum long position; conversely, if selling is profitable, then it is optimal to sell all shares15 . Hence, a traders’ position space in equilibrium is reduced to {0, 1}. Because we assumed simple linear tax rate, the profit or loss realized after sale (whether in current tax year or previous years) and realized tax payment and benefit are all sunk and will not affect decisions. The trading history affects decisions only when a trader is currently holding the asset and whether she can sell before the crash is uncertain, i.e. her most recent purchase price may affect her selling decision. At any given price, a trader has three options: seeks to buy to the maximum long position (buy), does not change 15 See Appendix A and proof of Lemma 1 in AB2003 for details. 11 her current position (hold ), and sells all her shares (sell ). Let A(p, v, h, Pp ) denote the strategy at price p of a trader v with current position h ∈ {0, 1} and the most recent purchase price Pp . Pp is a random variable and is relevant only when h = 1. Then A is defined on [0, ∞) × [− η2 , ∞) × {0, 1} × [0, ∞) → {buy, hold, sell}. Definition 3.1 immediately implies the following corollary, which states that when trader v’s action is not buy, the actions of all types weakly lower than trader v must not be buy, and when she is buying, all types weakly higher than her are still buying, irrespective of trading histories or current positions. This is because the belief in Definition 3.1 must be correct for all types of traders. Corollary 3.1. A(p, v, h, Pp ) 6= buy =⇒ A(p, v 0 , h0 , Pp0 ) 6= buy, ∀v 0 ≤ v and ∀p, h, Pp , h0 , Pp0 ; A(p, v, h, Pp ) = buy =⇒ A(p, v 0 , h0 , Pp0 ) = buy, ∀v 0 ≥ v and ∀p, h, Pp , h0 , Pp0 . Corollary 3.1 implies that traders’ strategies are symmetric in the sense that traders with the same signal are either all buying or all not buying. Now we can formally define the bursting price pT : η η pT = inf {p|A(v, p, h, Pp ) 6= buy, ∀v ∈ [θ − , θ + ], ∀h and ∀Pp } 2 2 That is, the bubble bursts when no one wants to buy. Let Pb∗ (v) denote the price at which the action of trader v is not buy for the first time. Let Ps∗ (v, Pp ) denote the price at which trader v sells her shares for the first time, given her purchase price Pp (since her position is either 0 or 1 and this is the first-time sale, Pp is well defined.). By definition, Pp < Pb∗ (v) ≤ Ps∗ (v, Pp ), ∀v and ∀Pp 16 To derive an equilibrium, we will need two technical assumptions: Assumption 3.1. Pb∗ (v) is continuous in v, ∀v and differentiable ∀v > η2 , and Ps∗ (v, Pp ) is continuous in both v and Pp . Lemma 3.1. Pb∗ (v) is strictly increasing in v, ∀v ≥ η2 . Then the inverse function Pb∗−1 (v), ∀v ≥ η2 , is well defined. Assumption 3.2. A trader cannot switch actions more than once in one instant. Then we have the following proposition. Pb∗ (v) < Ps∗ (v, Pp ) is because receiving the loan and becoming able to buy the asset does not involve any new information, a trader’s belief conditional on having received the loan and bought the asset must be the same as that conditional on having not received the loan. Hence it should not happen to any trader that, if she has never bought the asset she prefers buying at a price, while if she has bought the asset she prefers to sell at a lower price. 16 12 Proposition 3.1. (Trigger-strategy): In equilibrium, if a trader holding no shares stops buying, she will never restart buying again. If a trader has sold her shares, she will never return to the market. Proposition 3.1 implies that, when the highest type θ + η 2 decides to stop buying for the first time at Pb∗ (θ + η2 ), all other types have already done so. Since no one is buying at this moment, the bubble bursts at pT = Pb∗ (θ + η2 ). Then θ = Pb∗−1 (pT ) − η2 , and this is how everyone can perfectly infer θ from the bursting price pT . Proposition 3.1 further reduces a trader’s strategy space to {Pb∗ (v), Ps∗ (v, Pp )}. Right after t = 0, if the price ever rises above zero, then at least some traders want to buy, and some of them have received the loan and bought to the maximum position 1, and others are waiting for the loan. If a trader v has bought the asset at price Pp , she holds and waits until the price rises to Ps∗ (v, Pp ) then she sells all her shares. If she has not received the loan, then at price Pb∗ (v) she stops trying and gives up. In either case, she will never restarting buying again. Readers can review the price dynamics under this strategy profile in Figure 2. 4 Reduced form game After T , the price jumps to θ and stays there thereafter. If a trader v sells before the crash, she gets the selling price. Otherwise, she gets the post-crash price θ. Now we solve the individual trader’s problem backward, starting with the sale decision. In what follows we will focus on traders with v > strategies of those with v ≤ 4.1 η 2 η . 2 The will be characterized in Appendix D and G. Sale decision Consider a trader v who has bought at price Pp and plans to sell at Ps . A trader is taxed only if she has a positive profit, i.e. Pp + 2c < Ps (sell before the crash) or Pp + 2c < θ (sell after the crash) and not taxed otherwise. If there is a perfect tax credit, a trader also receives a benefit τ (Pp + 2c − θ) due to the tax credit when she incurs a loss Pp + 2c − θ, where Pp + 2c > θ17 . When a trader’s purchase price Pp is low enough such that Pp + 2c < Pb∗−1 (Ps ) − η2 , it is possible that the post-crash sale is still profitable and taxable (when θ > Pp + 2c). In this case, given that all other 17 In equilibrium, pre-crash sales always give positive profits. A pre-crash sale is a scheduled sale. If a trader buys at Pp and sells at planned Ps and incurs a loss, then he will not buy at Pp . 13 traders stop buying at Pb∗ (·), the expected payoff is Z "Z Pp +2c [θ−Pp −2c+τc (Pp +2c−θ)] φ(θ|v)dθ+(1−τ ) θ=Pb∗−1 (Pp )−η2 Pb∗−1 (Ps )−η2 (θ−Pp −2c)φ(θ|v)dθ θ=Pp +2c η i +(Ps −Pp −2c) 1−Φ(Pb∗−1 (Ps )− |v) 2 h # (2) where τc equals τ when there is a perfect tax credit and 0 when there is no tax credit. In the first integral the post-crash sale incurs a loss and is not taxable, and there is a tax benefit; in the second integral the post-crash sale is profitable and taxable. The third term is the expected payoff from selling before the crash which is also taxable. When Pp is high enough such that Pp + 2c > Pb∗−1 (Ps ) − η2 , in which case the post-crash sale always incurs a loss and is non-taxable, the expected profit is Pb∗−1 (Ps )− η2 h η i [θ−Pp −2c+τc (Pp +2c−θ)] φ(θ|v)dθ+(1−τ )(Ps −Pp − 2c) 1−Φ(Pb∗−1 (Ps )− |v) 2 θ=Pb∗−1 (Pp )− η2 Z (3) Let us call the case with perfect tax credit case C, and let ωC (Pp , Ps ) denote the expected payoff from having already bought at Pp and planing to sell at Ps in this case. In case C, where τc = τ , equation (2) and (3) can be rearranged and both be written as "Z ∗−1 Pb Case C : ωC (Pp , Ps ) = (1 − τ ) (Ps )− η2 h η i θφ(θ|v)dθ + Ps 1 − Φ(Pb∗−1 (Ps ) − |v) − Pp − 2c 2 θ=Pb∗−1 (Pp )− η2 # (4) When there is no tax credit, let us call the case in (2) case T , and the case in (3) case N T , and let ωT (Pb , Ps ) and ωN T (Pb , Ps ) denote the expected payoff from having already bought at Pp and planing to sell at Ps in case T and N T , respectively. Then equation (2) can be written as "Z ∗−1 Z Pp +2c Case T : ωT (Pp , Ps ) = [θ−Pp − θ=Pb∗−1 (Pp )−η2 Pb 2c] φ(θ|v)dθ+(1−τ ) (Ps )−η2 (θ − Pp − 2c)φ(θ|v)dθ θ=Pp +2c η i + (Ps −Pp − 2c) 1−Φ(Pb∗−1 (Ps )− |v) 2 h # (5) and (3) can be written as Z Case N T : ωN T (Pp , Ps ) = Pb∗−1 (Ps )− η2 [θ−Pp − θ=Pb∗−1 (Pp )− η2 2c] φ(θ|v)dθ+(1−τ )(Ps −Pp − 2c) h η 1−Φ(Pb∗−1 (Ps )− |v) i 2 (6) Without the tax credit, a trader must be either a case T trader or a case N T trader. Since Pp ∈ [0, Pb∗ (v)], if Pb∗ (v) + 2c < Pb∗−1 (Ps∗ (v)) − η2 in equilibrium, then it is impossible that Pp + 2c > Pb∗−1 (Ps∗ (v)) − η2 . Then N T trader does not exist and all traders are case T traders and use (5) to evaluate their expected payoff. If 14 Pb∗ (v)+2c > Pb∗−1 (Ps∗ (v))− η2 in equilibrium, then those buying at prices such that Pp +2c > Pb∗−1 (Ps∗ (v))− η2 are case N T traders and use (6), and the rest are case T traders and use (5). It will turn out that both cases, Pb∗ (v) + 2c ≷ Pb∗−1 (Ps∗ (v)) − η2 , can be supported in equilibrium (by different parameter values). Let ωX (Pp , Ps ) denote the expected payoff in the three cases, where X ∈ {C, T, N T }. A trader v faces a sale decision max ωX (Pp , Ps ) (7) Ps For a trader who considers selling at a current price Ps , if ∂ωX ∂Ps ∂ωX ∂Ps > 0, then she should not sell; when ≤ 0, then she should sell. Differentiating ωX (Pp , Ps ) w.r.t Ps and setting ∂ωX ∂Ps = 0 gives the first order condition (write all three cases in one equation): h i φ(Pb∗−1 (Ps ) − η2 |v) η 1 ∗−1 1 − τ = (1−τ )(Ps −Pp −2c)−(1−τct )(Pb (Ps )− −Pp −2c) 0 2 Pb∗ (Pb∗−1 (Ps )) 1−Φ(Pb∗−1 (Ps )− η2 |v) (8) where τct equals τ in case C and T , and equals 0 in case N T . This first order condition can be interpreted in terms of marginal benefit and cost. For a trader who evaluates selling at Ps vs. Ps + ∆ (∆ is small), the relevant marginal event is that the bubble bursts between Ps and Ps + ∆. On the left hand side, the marginal benefit of selling at Ps + ∆ over Ps is (1 − τ )∆ (the after-tax price appreciation). On the right hand side, the marginal cost is that she could get caught in the crash if the bubble bursts in between Ps and Ps + ∆, which equals the profit difference multiplied by the probability of bursting between Ps and Ps + ∆. In the brackets is the profit difference between pre and post-crash transactions, i.e. the loss due to crash. The first term in the brackets is the pre-crash profit which is always positive and taxable, and the second term is post-crash payoff which is positive and taxable in case T and is negative in case N T . Outside the brackets is the hazard rate of bursting at Ps . Dividing both sides by ∆ and letting ∆ → 0, we have equation (8). 4.2 Purchase decision Given that all other traders stop buying at Pb∗ (·) and trader v will sell at Ps∗ (·, ·), we solve for trader v’s optimal choice of stop-buy price, Pb . By Corollary 3.1 the bubble will not burst below Pb (v) for trader v. When trader v evaluates the expected profit from buying at the current price Pp and selling at at Ps∗ (v, Pp ), the expected profit is ωX (Pp , Ps∗ (v, Pp )). It is not difficult to verify that the higher the purchase price, the lower the expected profit, i.e. ∂ωX ∂Pp < 0. Then as long as ωX (Pp , Ps∗ (v, Pp )) > (1 − τ )R, buying the asset at Pp is preferred to buying the outside option, and a trader will stop trying to buy the asset only when 15 ωX (Pp , Ps∗ (v, Pp )) ≤ 0. Hence the the optimal stop-buy price Pb for trader v is defined by ωX (Pb , Ps∗ (v, Pb )) = (1 − τ )R (9) In equilibrium Pb∗ (v) = Pb (v). Recall that the crash is triggered by stop-buy decisions (of the highest type of traders). If a trader (who has just received a loan) decides to buy at the current price, then she is no longer a concern to others because all that matters is the stop-buy decisions of those who have not bought yet. Call a trader the break-even trader if she has not bought yet and finds that buying at current price Pp and selling at Ps∗ (·, Pp ) gives an expected profit equal to (1 − τ )R (equation (9)) so that she decides to stop buying at Pp . Only the break-even traders are important to solving the problem. So the equilibrium is defined by equations (7) and (9). 5 Equilibrium with perfect tax credit Proposition 5.1 shows that, when there is a perfect tax credit and if 2c+R η < 12 , i.e., when c and R are small relative to η, then there is a unique trading equilibrium with a positive bubble, which corresponds to an interior solution of equation (7). Proposition 5.2 shows that if 2c+R η ≥ 12 , the trading equilibrium has no bubble18 , which corresponds to a corner solution of (7). Proposition 5.1. (Tax credit with bubble) Suppose there is a perfect capital loss tax credit. When p 2c+R < 12 , there exists a unique trading equilibrium in which the bubble size is B = η − (4c + 2R)η > 0, η η p ∗ buy, if price < P (v) = v + − (4c + 2R)η; b 2 η η and the bubble bursts at θ + B, and a trader v > will sell, if price ≥ Ps∗ (v) = v + ; 2 2 ∗ ∗ hold, if Pb (v) ≤ price < Ps (v). For traders with v ≤ η2 , their strategies are more complicated but less important and are relegated to Appendix D. The equilibrium strategies (including strategies of traders with v ≤ η2 ) are depicted in Figure 3. In panel (a) of Figure 3, when c and R are very small, even the lowest type v = − η2 buy and sell. In √ panel (b) when 2 − 3 ≤ 2c+R < 12 , some of the traders with v ≤ v C < η2 never buy the asset, since their η stop-buy prices Pb∗ (v) ≤ 0. v C is defined in Appendix D. Proposition 5.1 prescribes that with a perfect tax credit and when 2c+R < 21 , a trader v > η2 always η p stops buying at Pb∗ (v) = v + η2 − (4c + 2R)η if she has not bought yet, and sells at Ps∗ (v, Pp ) = v + η2 if she already bought. The most important result is that the size of the bubble B is not affected by capital 18 It has a negative “bubble”. 16 Ps∗ (v) p p Ps∗ (v) v+ v+ η 2 Pb∗ (v) v+ η− η− p η 2 η 2 − p (4c + 2R)η Pb∗ (v) p (4c + 2R)η v+ η 2 − p (4c + 2R)η (4c+2R)η−2c−R − η2 η − 2 η 2 p (4c+2R)η (a) 2c+R η <2− √ v 3 (b) 2 − √ 3< v η 2 vC 2c+R η < 1 2 Figure 3: Equilibrium strategies under perfect tax credit and positive bubble gains tax. In a nutshell, the tax credit provides a compensation to the loss in crash and neutralizes the repressive effects of the tax on traders’ strategies. We will explain the intuition in more detail in Section 6 by comparing the case C, T and N T with the tax-free case. In contrast, the fixed transaction cost and the outside option can reduce the bubble ( ∂B < 0 and ∂c ∂B ∂R < 0). When c or R increases, the minimal margin between buying and selling prices for a trader to make a profit is larger, which lowers the stop-buy price and therefore deflates the bubble. Conversely, when c or R decreases, buying the asset at higher prices and incurring the cost are still preferable to receiving R (i.e. the minimum margin between purchase and selling prices narrows), and hence generates a larger bubble. Our model also shows that when c and R are small, they have very large marginal effect on the bubble. √ = −∞. The reason is as follows. Let b ≡ 2c+R, then the size of the bubble is B = η − 2bη, and limb→0 ∂B ∂b Because sale prices are not affected by c or R, bubble size is determined by Pb∗ (·). A trader’s stop-buy √ √ price is always 2bη lower than her selling price, so 2bη can be regarded as the effective transaction √ cost. The larger the gap 2bη between the stop-buy and sale prices, the smaller the bubble. When there is no risk of crash at all, b is a minimal margin between purchase and selling prices for a trader to buy the asset instead of the outside option. Since it is possible that the bubble bursts in between this gap, a trader needs to lower the purchase price and widen this profit margin to compensate for the risk. Larger gap means higher probability of bursting in between, which requires an even larger margin. But Pb∗ (·) 17 will not be shifted downwards infinitely, since bubble size is also decreasing as Pb∗ (·) decreases, and the loss of being caught in the crash diminishes. There is a stop-buy price where the expected profit equals the outside option. As a result, a small fixed transaction cost or outside option can induce a large gap between the stop-buy and sale prices, and can effectively reduce the bubble, although the marginal effect is decreasing. As can be seen from the explanation, this result does not rely on our choice of specific belief distributions. Figure 4 shows the relationship between the normalized size of the bubble B η and ηb . B η 1 1 b η Figure 4: Relationship between B η and b η The equilibrium bubble size B never exceeds η. B is also increasing in η, which means that the more dispersed the public opinion about the asset fundamental value, the larger the bubble size. B actually can be made arbitrarily large if we let η −→ ∞, and c and R be arbitrarily small. Conversely, if we can effectively reduce the belief dispersion η, the size of the bubble will decrease. When θ ≥ η2 , upon the bursting, traders with signals in the lower range [θ − η2 , θ + η 2 − p (4c + 2R)η] have fled the market successfully with positive profit, while the rest (v in the higher range [θ + η2 − p (4c + 2R)η, θ + η2 ]) are caught in the crash. Even with this lowest possible realization of θ, which generates signals distributed on [− η2 , η2 ], there are traders buying. So there is always a bubble and a crash when 2c+R η < 12 , no matter what is the realization of θ. For a trader v, the highest possible realization of θ is v + η2 . If the price rises above v + η2 , then she knows for sure that a bubble exists. Upon the bursting, the price is pT (θ) = θ + B and traders with p v ∈ [θ − η2 , θ + η2 − (4c + 2R)η] are sure that a bubble already exists, and they are exactly those who have fled the market before the crash. If τ = 0 and c = R = 0, then Pb∗ (v) = Ps∗ (v, Pp ) = v + η2 and B = η. In this case the stop-buy strategy equals the selling strategy. The following proposition states that when the transaction cost c and the return from outside option R are large, or traders’ opinions are sufficiently concentrated (η is small), there is a different equilibrium where there is no bubble (bubble size < 0). 18 Proposition 5.2. (Tax credit without bubble) Suppose there is a perfect capital loss tax credit. When 2c+R η ≥ 12 , there exists a “unique” trading equilibrium in which the bubble size B = η 2 − 2c − R ≤ 0, and a trader • v ≤ 2c + R will never buy the asset; buy, if price < v − 2c − R; • v > 2c − R will hold, if v − 2c ≤ price < v + η2 . sell, if price ≥ v + η 2 In this equilibrium, when the highest type stops buying, the price is still lower than θ. When the “bubble” bursts, the price jumps up to θ. This is because the fixed transaction cost and the return from outside option are too large compared to η, and the stop-buy strategy is pushed so low that the bubble becomes negative. With a negative “bubble”, if a trader sells before the “crash”, she forgoes the price appreciation that would have certainly realized had she waited till the “bubble” bursts. As a result, everyone has an incentive to hold the asset until the uncertainty is resolved. Obviously the strategy profile in Proposition 5.1 is no longer an equilibrium. Knowing that she will be selling at θ after the “crash” and the expected sale price is E[θ|v], a trader v should buy the asset if the current price is lower than E[θ|v] − 2c − R. Notice that when θ ≤ 2c + R − η2 , even the highest type θ + η2 stops buying at price zero, thus no one buys from the beginning and the price stays at zero throughout. This is the case where the asset fundamental has a small rise, but the price does not reflect it at all because transaction cost or the return from outside option is too large compared to the dispersion of traders’ opinion. This equilibrium is unique in the sense that the stop-buy strategy and “bubble” size are unique, but selling strategy is not unique. For trader v, since the bubble will burst below v + η 2 for sure and the price will be fixed at θ thereafter, price will never rise above v + η2 . So all strategies selling at any price above v+ 6 η 2 are optimal, although they will never be implemented. Equilibrium without tax credit When break-even traders are N T (T ) traders, we call the bubble an N T (T ) bubble. Proposition 6.1. (No credit but with bubble) Suppose that there is no capital loss tax credit. 1. N T bubble: When τ < 1 2 − 2R+4c η (1− 2c )2 − 4R η η and R η < 18 (1 − trading equilibrium in which the bubble size is B = 19 η 2 2c 2 ) η − c η and c η < √ 3−2 2 , 2 there exists a unique + DN T > 0, and the bubble bursts at θ + B, and a trader v > η2 will buy, if price < Pb∗ (v) = v + DN T ; h i η 1−τ τ 1 2c v− P + (1−τ )( −τ −τ )+τ d NT , 1−2τ p 1−2τ 2 η 1−2τ sell, if price ≥ Ps∗ (v, Pp ) = if Pp > v−2c−DN T ; v + η , if P < v − 2c − D p NT 2 hold, if P ∗ (v) ≤ price < P ∗ (v, P ). p s b h i q 2R+4c where DN T ≡ η 21 − τ − τ 2c − d and d ≡ (1 − 2τ )(1 − τ ). In particular Ps∗ (v, Pb∗ (v)) = NT NT η η h i 2τ v + η 12 − τ − τ 2c + d . All the break-even traders are N T traders. η 1−2τ N T 2. T bubble: When τ< 1− 4c − 2R η η (1− 2c )2 −2 R η η 1 2 − 2R+4c η (1− 2c )2 − 4R η η <τ < and 81 (1− 2c )2 − ηc < η R η 1− 4c − 2R η η (1− 2c )2 −2 R η η and < 12 (1− 4c ) and η c η R η < 18 (1 − 2c 2 ) η − c η and c η < √ 3−2 2 , 2 or when < 14 , there exists a unique trading equilibrium η η in which bubble size is B = 2 + DT > 0, and the bubble bursts at θ + B, and a trader v > 2 will 1+4τ c −2d buy, if price < Pb∗ (v) = v + DT ; T η η, if τ 6= 12 2(1−2τ ) η ∗ sell, if price ≥ Ps (v, Pp ) = v + 2 ; , where DT ≡ −c − 2c+R , if τ = 12 . 1+ 2c hold, if P ∗ (v) ≤ price < P ∗ (v, P ). η p s rb h i 2 + 2R (1 − 2τ ) + 4c . All the break-even trader are T traders. ) and dT ≡ (1 − τ ) τ (1 − 2c η η η For traders with v ≤ η2 , their strategies will be characterized in Appendix G. The equilibrium strategies with an N T bubble in Proposition 6.1 is depicted in Figure 5 (which also depicts strategies for v ≤ η2 ). This part is derived when the break-even traders are in case N T , i.e. their post-crash sales (if they purchase) are non-profitable for sure and they use ωN T to evaluate their expected profit. When τ , c and R are very low, only a small profit margin is required and the stop-buy price is close to the selling price. With such small margin, however, a break-even trader cannot make any profit if caught in the crash, even if θ turns out to be high (θ = v + η2 ), which makes her an N T trader. Actually, not only break-even traders are N T traders, but all traders buying above the dividing line v − 2c − DN T are N T traders, while those buying below the dividing line are T traders. For N T traders, since the tax is effectively imposed only on pre-crash transactions and there is no tax credit, in the first order condition the Ps∗ (v, Pp ) does depends on purchase price Pp . Hence different purchase prices lead to different selling prices, and these selling prices have an upper bound v + η2 and a lower bound Ps∗ (v, Pb∗ (v)). For T traders (buying below the dividing line), it is still possible that her post-crash sale is profitable so that she uses ωT to evaluate her expected profit. In particular, a T trader always sells exactly at v + irrespective of her purchase price. 20 η 2 (the upper bound), p Ps∗ (v, Pb∗ (v)) Pb∗ (v) v+ η 2 η 2 v + DN T + DN T v − 2c − DN T η +DN T −2c−R 2 − η2 Ps L P sH vN vN T T N oT vN T v η 2 Figure 5: Equilibrium strategies without tax credit and with positive bubble in case N T The bubble size is B = η 2 + DN T , and it can be verified that the B is decreasing in tax rate, fixed transaction cost and outside option payoff, i.e. ∂B ∂τ < 0, ∂B ∂c < 0 and ∂B ∂R < 0. As break-even traders are N T traders, the tax has a distortion effect which moves selling strategies down below the (undistorted) strategies in case C. In the first order condition (equation (8)), the relevant event is that the bubble bursts just before selling at Ps , i.e. θ = Pb∗−1 (Ps ) − η2 . The first φ =⇒ 1 = order condition in case N T is therefore 1 − τ = [(1 − τ )(Ps − Pp − 2c) − (θ − Pp − 2c)] P1∗0 1−Φ b h i φ p −2c 1 (Ps − Pp − 2c) − θ−P , while if there is no tax the first order condition is 1 = [(Ps − Pp − 2c) − (θ − Pp 0 1−τ P ∗ 1−Φ b Hence the payoff difference between pre and post-crash in case N T is larger than the difference without tax19 , which advises that traders sell more cautiously and conservatively, and all N T traders sell below the undistorted strategy v + η2 . h In comparison, when there is a perfect tax credit, the first order condition is 1−τ = (1−τ )(Ps −Pp −2c) i φ −(1 − τ )(θ − Pp − 2c) P1∗0 1−Φ , which, after normalization, is exactly the same as without tax. It is clear b that the tax credit provides a compensation, which scales the loss θ − Pp − 2c by a factor 1 − τ . Thus the tax credit reduces the payoff difference between pre and post-crash and restores it to its tax-free level. This encourages traders to sell aggressively as if there is no tax. Back to case N T , a trader’s stop-buy price is also lower than the tax-free stop-buy price. Combine (6) and (9), we find that positive profits are all scaled by a factor 1 − τ , but the negative ones are not, which implies that a trader has to lower her purchase price (stop buying earlier) to maintain the minimum 19 Recall that θ − Pp − 2c < 0. 21 reservation profit (1 − τ )R. This is a direct effects of capital gains tax on the stop-buy strategies. The direct and indirect effect of capital gains tax together depress the bubble so that it is smaller than the tax-free bubble. In comparison, when there is a perfect tax credit, both direct and indirect effects are eliminated and the tax fails to deflate the bubble. Also we observe that the selling price Ps∗ is reversely related to purchase price Pp for N T traders. This is because the marginal purchase cost of the pre-crash sale in the first order condition is scaled by factor (1 − τ ): when purchase cost Pp + 2c increases by ∆, tax payment reduces by τ ∆, so the marginal purchase cost in the pre-crash sale only increases by (1 − τ )∆, whereas the purchase cost of the post-crash sale does not enjoy this benefit. This implies that the tax, which is effectively imposed only on pre-crash sales, lowers the purchase cost in the pre-crash case compared to the post-crash case and makes the former relatively more attractive, and the larger the purchase cost (purchase price), the more attractive the former is. Hence, given a signal v, the higher the purchases price, the stronger an N T trader prefers to selling before the crash by selling earlier at a lower price. In particular the break-even traders’ who have the highest purchase prices (if they have purchased) sell the lowest (earliest) at Ps∗ (v, Pb∗ (v)). The equilibrium strategies with a T bubble in Proposition 6.1 is depicted in Figure 6. The difference is p p Ps∗ (v, Pb∗ (v)) v+ η 2 Ps∗ (v, Pb∗ (v)) v − 2c − DT v − 2c − DT Pb∗ (s) v+ η 2 Pb∗ (v) v + DT v + DT η 2 + DT η +DT −2c−R 2 − η2 v η P L vTDiv 2 vTPs H vT s vTN oT (a) Lowest traders sell together vTPb η 2 v (b) Lowest traders never buy Figure 6: Equilibrium strategies without tax credit and with positive bubble in case T that, the break-even traders are now in case T . Because the tax and transaction cost are higher now, the stop-buy price Pb∗ (v) = v + DT is now below the dividing line v − 2c − DT . Hence, not only break-even traders, but all traders (v > η2 ) traders are T traders and there is no N T trader in this case. They buy at 22 such low prices that, if caught in the crash, it is possible that the post-crash sales are still profitable, even for the break-even traders (if they buy). As such, they all use ωT to evaluate their expected profit and sell at v + η2 , irrespective of their purchase prices. The bubble size is B = η 2 + DT , and it can be verified that the it is decreasing in tax rate, fixed transaction cost and outside option payoff, i.e. ∂B ∂τ < 0, ∂B ∂c < 0 and ∂B ∂R < 0. In case T the selling price is undistorted, compared with the tax-free case, because in the marginal event the post-crash transaction is still profitable and taxable, just as the pre-crash transaction. Hence the normalized first order condition is the same as the tax-free first order condition. But the stop-buy price is again lower than its tax-free level, because the direct effect of the tax is still at work, which lowers the stop-buy strategies directly. In comparison, when there is a perfect tax credit, the direct effect is eliminated and the tax again fails to deflate the bubble. Compare Figure 5 and 6, we see that when τ , c and R are small, break-even traders (N T traders) sell lower than when τ , c and R are large (break-even traders are T traders). This is because in the former case, their stop-buy prices are high, which cause their post-crash sales unprofitable for sure. So their selling strategies are distorted downwards by the tax. In the latter case, low stop-buy prices make profitable post-crash sales possible, which leaves selling strategies undistorted. Because the bubble size in our model is determined by the stop-buy prices, the bubble is always larger in case N T than in case T . Figure 7 depicts the partitioning of the parameter space. Panel (a) is in the N T bubble is in the lower left corner where both bubble where -τ - R η c η and τ are larger. When c η c η c η - τ space with R = 0. and τ are small, and T bubble area surrounds N T and τ are even larger, there is no bubble. Panel (b) is in the space. N T bubble is in the lower left corner where ηc , τ and R η c η are all small, and T bubble area is in between the two surfaces. Outside the larger surface there is no bubble. From the fact that bubble size is decreasing in ηc , τ and R η N T and T areas (when τ = in both N T and T bubbles, and that DN T = DT on the boundary between 1 2 − 2R+4c η (1− 2c )2 −4 R η η ), we know that without tax credit bubble size in case N T is always larger than that in case T , and bubble size is decreasing in ηc , τ and R η across the boundary. This is depicted in Figure 8 (set R = 0). In the dark red part on the top are N T bubbles, and in the light blue part in lower area are T bubbles. Proposition 6.2. (No tax credit no bubble) Suppose there is no capital loss tax credit. When t ≥ 1− 4c − 2R η η (1− 2c )2 −2 R η η , or R η ≥ 12 (1 − 4c ), η or c η ≥ 14 , there exists a “unique” trading equilibrium in which bubble size N B = η + DN ≤ 0, and a trader 23 τ 1 τ= 1− 4c η (1− 2c )2 η t 1 2 τ= 1 2 − T bubble No bubble 4c η (1− 2c )2 η R __ N T bubble 3 √ − 2 2 1 4 1 2 h c η c __ h (a) In the c η (b) In the - τ space (R = 0) c η -τ - R η space Figure 7: Partitioning of the parameter space without tax credit Figure 8: Bubble size (R = 0) N • v ≤ −DN − η 2 will never buy the asset; v + η + DN , if 2 R ≤ 1; N 2 η NN buy, if price < P (v) ≡ b v − 2c − R, if 2 R > 1 η N • v > max( η2 , −DN − η2 ) will η hold, if PbN N (v) ≤ price < v + 2 . sell, if price ≥ v + η 2 24 N where DN ≡ − τη − 2c + η τ q (1 − τ )(1 − 2τ Rη ) This equilibrium is unique, again, in the sense that the stop-buy price and bubble size are unique, but selling strategy is not unique, by the same reason as in Proposition 5.2. 7 Empirical Predictions 7.1 Effects of Capital Gains Tax, Transaction Cost and Outside Option The results of our model provides some insights for empirical research. First, the two main findings from our model generate testable predictions. We showed that, the effect of capital gains tax on bubbles depends on tax credit: when there is no tax credit (or the tax credit is imperfect), the size of the bubble is decreasing in capital gains tax rate; when tax credit is close to perfect, the tax has little effect on bubbles. The bubble size is decreasing in the transaction cost and the return from alternative investment opportunities, which does not depend on tax policies. The equilibrium in our model is unique, so it should be able to test the above results without worrying about the issue of multiple equilibria. To demonstrate that our model can be empirically tested, we study several historical events of bubble. We identify actual sizes of bubbles in these events and normalize them for comparison. This could potentially show how tax, cost and outside option affect bubbles. We also fit normalized actual bubble sizes to theoretical results calculated from model parameters to test our model. But given the small sample size here, the results showed is far from conclusive. Further empirical study is expected. The four historical events of bubble we explore are the 1929 stock market crash, the Japan asset bubble in the 1980s, the Internet Bubble in the late 1990s and the Bitcoin bubble in 2013. For each event of bubble, we identify the following parameters: tax rate τ , transaction cost c, outside option R and belief dispersion of investors (about the asset fundamental) η, from which we calculate the theoretical size of the bubble. The tax credit of these events either falls in between perfect and no credit, or the information of which is difficult to find, so we compare these events to theoretical results in both perfect and no credit cases. In the case of no credit, we have to determine whether they are in the range of T or N T based on the value of parameters. In the real world there are so many factors that can affect asset bubbles (e.g. monetary policies, credit control, exchange rates, tax policies, productivity, market capitalization) that comparing the sizes of bubbles directly is essentially meaningless. To identify the effects of factors such as tax or interest rate on bubbles, we have to normalize the actual sizes of bubbles before we can compare. Our model suggests 25 that the extent to which investors’ beliefs differ is an important factor that determines the size of the bubble and is a candidate that can be used for normalization. However, the belief dispersion in a real market is usually very difficult to identify. So we use the following method to infer this dispersion, η. Rational traders’ belief in our model is distributed in the range [θ − η2 , θ + η2 ]. When the price rises to Ps∗ (θ − η2 ) rational investors with lowest belief θ − η2 start to sell. In addition, the specification of our model is such that the impact of this action to the price is perfectly concealed. The belief of investor in the real market is not necessarily uniformly distributed or symmetrically distributed around θ, but arbitrageurs (e.g. hedge funds) that hold significant shares and have various belief can be viewed as the rational traders in our model. When the major arbitrageur with the lowest belief among them starts to sell, the price impact should be felt by the market. Therefore we use the largest price drop in the data during the price run-up20 as a proxy for the initial attack of rational traders with lowest belief, θ − η2 . In particular, we treat the price right before the drop as Ps∗ (θ − η2 ) and calculate η by inverting Ps∗ (·).21 We also exclude episodes of price drop that coincide with major exogenous shocks to the market. We define the run-up of a bubble as a period of time up to the moment when the price hit the peak, and the crash starts right after that. The actual size of a bubble is measured from the peak of the price path to the average price within a certain period of time after the crash. This is because it usually took time for actual crashes to reach the bottom and the price paths after the peak were also quite noisy. In addition at the bottom there often existed downward price overshootings followed by slow recovery. The average balances the fact that investors have opportunities to sell before the price hits the bottom and the downward price overshooting which is usually lower than the true asset value. We set the length of this period half of the length of the run-up. The actual path of indexes of these events are presented in Figure 9, where in each panel the vertical dashed line is the cut-off between run-up and bursting and the horizontal line is the average value of post-crash index. The trading cost usually includes three components: broker’s commission, bid-ask spread and the market impact cost. For simplicity we only include broker’s commission, and we set c equal to the commission rate times the asset price at the peak. For the outside option, R, we use the 3-month rate of return of the treasury bond at 3 months before the crash multiplied by the asset price at the peak. Using conditions set in Proposition 5.1 and 6.1, we can verify that there existed a bubble when assuming 1 We use the largest price drop during a period of time, which is scaled to 20 of the length of the run-up. η ∗ The ex post identification of Ps (θ − 2 ) as such should not be viewed as traders being able identify true θ when the bubble event has not fully unfolded, since one does not know whether this price drop is the largest or not before the final crash, which has not realized yet. 20 21 26 5 4.5 5 4 3.5 4 3 2.5 3 2 2 1.5 1 1 0.5 0 1921−08−24 1923−07−27 1925−06−29 1927−05−24 1929−04−25 1931−03−26 1933−02−21 1935−02−01 1936−12−30 0 1982−01−01 1984−02−16 1986−04−02 1988−05−17 1990−07−02 1992−08−14 1994−09−29 1996−11−13 1998−12−29 (a) 1929 Stock Market Crash: S&P Stock Index Source: CRSP (b) Japan Asset Bubble: Nikkei 225 Stock Index Source: Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 5.5 5 200 4.5 4 150 3.5 3 2.5 100 2 1.5 50 1 0.5 0 1997−01−02 1997−08−15 1998−04−01 1998−11−12 1999−06−30 2000−02−11 2000−09−26 2001−05−11 2001−12−31 0 01/01/2012 (c) Tech Bubble: Technology Stock Index Source: calculated by data from CRSP 01/06/2012 31/10/2012 01/04/2013 31/08/2013 30/01/2014 01/07/2014 30/11/2014 01/05/2015 (d) Bitcoin Bubble 2013: Bitcoin Price Index Source: blockchain.info,bitcoin.org Figure 9: Price index paths of historical bubble events there is perfect tax credit and there existed an N T bubble when assuming there is no tax credit in each of the four events22 . For all events of bubble, their parameters, as well as actual bubble sizes, inferred η and theoretical bubbles sizes are listed in Table 1. Before we present the graphical comparison of theoretical and empirical results, we briefly discuss some aspects of these historical events and explain the calculation in more details. Parameters c Tech 0.00557 1929 0.0179 Japan 0.0355 Bitcoin 6.28 R 0.0144 0.0471 0.0730 0.0242 Data τ 0.35 0.12 0.375 0.15 B 2.02 3.82 2.33 130 η 4.61 4.71 3.62 256 c η Perfect Credit Theory Data R 0.0012 0.00380 0.00979 0.0245 η 0.00312 0.0100 0.0201 0.0001 B η B η 0.894 0.918 0.718 0.686 0.440 0.812 0.644 0.509 η 4.85 4.78 4.37 266 No Credit(Case NT) Theory Data c R η η 0.00115 0.00374 0.00811 0.0236 0.00301 0.00985 0.0167 0.00009 Table 1: Summary of parameters and results of historical bubble events 22 It can also be verified that the conditions for the T bubble are not satisfied when assuming no credit. 27 B η B η 0.604 0.727 0.518 0.606 0.417 0.800 0.534 0.491 1929 Stock Market Crash The Roaring Twenties witnessed great economic growth in the Unite States, evidenced by the large-scale use of automobiles, telephones, motion pictures, electricity. Technology innovations and the extreme optimism undergirded the stock market appreciation. People had the illusion that the bull market would last forever, which was broken in October 1929 and a decade depression ensued. This illusion held by some investors is characterized by the belief dispersion in our model. We define the run-up as the period from August 24, 1921 to September 3, 1929, with the latter being the peak. In all historical events we study, we set the S&P index at the beginning of the run-up to unity. Hence the index at the peak is 5.97. The mean index after the peak is 2.14 and the actual size of the bubble is therefore measured as 5.97-2.14=3.83. The largest price drop within a period of 90 trading days started on Mar 23, 1923 with a index value of 1.64. The broker commission rates around 1929 were about 0.3%23 , which gives c = 0.3% × 5.97 = 0.0179. The 3-month return from a 3 month treasury bond at June, 1929 was 3.16%, which gives R = 3.16% 4 × 5.97 = 0.047. We treat the main contributors of the price run-up as corporations and hence use the corporate tax rate 12%24 . The capital loss carry-over was first introduced in Revenue Code 1939, which was restricted to individuals only, and we were not able to find any information about capital loss carry-over around 1929. When assuming there was perfect tax credit, we calculate η from Ps∗ (θ − η2 ) = 1.64, where Ps∗ (·) is from Proposition 5.1. Then we calculate the theoretical B by using the inferred η and normalize both actual and theoretical bubble sizes by dividing them by the inferred η. When assuming there was no tax credit, the calculation is similar except we use Proposition 6.1. The calculations for all other events are the same as explained above. Japan Asset Bubble in the 1980s By the end of 1989, Japan has experienced an “economic miracle” that lasted more than three decades. Japanese industry gained its competitive advantage by improving technologies from Western products and selling them back to the West for cheaper prices. In the 1970s and 1980s Japanese high-quality and fuel-efficient automobiles gained significant market shares in the US and consumer electronics products (e.g. VHS recorder and the Sony Walkman) started to dominate global markets. Rapid accumulation of wealth by both corporations and households, as well as uncontrolled money supply and credit expansion greatly encouraged speculative trading and inflated real estate and stock market prices. Evidences show that corporations and investors’ opinion and expectations about stock prices were highly differentiated25 . Although the bubble in the stock market and real estate are 23 See Jones (2002). At that time the tax codes did not differentiate operation gains and capital gains. 25 See Shiller et al. (1996). 24 28 intertwined, the former burst a year ahead of the latter and so we choose to study the stock market due to the potential causality. The Nikkei 225 index reached a record high on Dec 29, 1989, which was 5.07 times of the index in 1982. After that the index plummeted to half its peak in eight months and the bursting of bubbles contributed to what many call the Lost Decade. We define the run-up starting from January 1, 1982 to the end of 1989. For the largest price drop within a period of 180 trading days, we ruled out the episode coinciding the 1987 stock market crash in the US and adopt the next largest one, which started on August 20, 1986 with a index value of 2.47. We use the corporate tax rate (37.5%)26 as the main contributors of stock market bubble were corporations27 . Unfortunately we were not able to find information about capital loss carry-over round the late 1980s. Tech Bubble in the late 1990s In the 1980s and 1990s computer started to become a consumer electronics due to the dramatic price declines in hardware and the progress in software development. The emergence of internet in the 1990s opened a door to an unlimited potential of how people could search for and retrieve information and knowledge and communicate with each other, and the information and computer related industries experienced sustained exponential growth during that time. As many other technology innovations in the history, the true value of internet remained unclear and opinions about how it can change our life and how soon it will happen differed substantially. Investors decide to buy in anticipation of further rises and many technology companies in the United States were significantly overvalued. At the height of the boom, it was possible for a promising dot-com to make an initial public offering of its stock and raise a substantial amount of money even though it had never made a profit. This bubble burst in March, 2000 and the technology sector in the United States suffered significant losses. We define the run-up as from January 2, 1997 to March 24, 2000 and and compose a technology stock index by using Nasdaq daily trading data in the technology sector (firms with SIC code 73728 and we restrict ourselves to ordinary common shares29 ). This index is treated the single asset representing the technology industry. For the largest price drop of this index during the run-up, we exclude the one at the beginning of January 2000 (caused by the concerns of putting off capital gains tax payment) and the episodes coinciding with the Russian sovereign debt default and the failure of Long-Term Capital Management, we use the next largest one, which started on October 27, 1997. As argued by Griffin et al. (2011), the main contributors 26 In 1989 the corporate tax did not differentiate ordinary corporate income and capital gains in Japan. See Stone and Ziemba (1993). 28 A SIC code starting with 737 means the firm engages in computer programming, data processing and other computerrelated services. 29 CRSP share code 10 or 11 27 29 to the Tech bubble were institutional traders. We use the short-term capital gains tax rate at the time for the highest tax bracket, 35%, given the fact that there were (unsuccessful) attack around April 1999 and many institutional investors may had repurchased the asset after the attack. As stated in the introduction, corporate capital losses in the United States can be carried 3 years back and 5 years forward without an dollar limit. This tax credit policy is somewhere in between null and perfect. Bitcoin Bubble in 2013 Bitcoin is an online payment system released as an open-source software in 2009. Users can transact directly without any financial intermediary. The system is a peer-to-peer one, meaning that it works without central administration and that transactions are executed and verified by randomly chosen network nodes and recorded in a public distributed ledger called the block chain. Any online computer installed with this software becomes a node. This feature ensures that no one can control the bitcoin system. There are many online merchants where one can purchase bitcoin with local currency. Once bought, the amount of holding is recorded in the ledger. Since a holder does not know where this information is stored and all data is encrypted and verified, it is impossible for a user to tamper the ledger. Users who install the bitcoin software and thus facilitates the distributed transactions, which is called mining, are rewarded by newly created bitcoin, though this reward is declining as more and more nodes are online. There is an upper bound of 21 million for the total bitcoin that can be circulated in the system. Bitcoin as a virtual currency and a form of payment for products and services has grown and merchants have an incentive to accept it because fees are lower than credit cards. The price for the bitcoin grew slowly before 2012. Since 2012 its price rose considerably from around US$5 and soared in 2013, hitting its record high at US$1151 on December 4. After that the price declined sharply and was around US$50 in May 2015. The market capitalization at the height of the bubble was close to 14 billion US dollars. The gains from investment on virtual currency such as bitcoin in the 2013 tax year became taxable in the United States30 . We define the run-up as between January 1, 2012 and December 4 2013, and scale the price on January 1, 2012, which was US$5.2, to 1. The nominal transaction costs are very low, but we need to take into account the impact of newly created bitcoin, which is similar to excess money supply that can cause inflation. As such, we use the miners revenue as a percentage of the transaction volume for the transaction cost. The largest price drop during the run-up within 35 trading days started on April 9, 2013. We conjecture that the majority of investors of bitcoin are individuals, and they are tech-savvy young people with moderate income. The tax rates applied to annul single income brackets between $8,926 and 30 See Internal Revenue Service Notice 2014-21. 30 $87,850 are 15% and 25%, but considering that personal capital gain can offset all other personal losses (not just capital gains) and tax carry-over never expires, we choose 15% in the calculation. In Figure 10 we depict these actual bubbles and compare them the theoretical results. Panel (10a) assumes a perfect tax credit and tax rates are irrelevant. Therefore we can use 2c+R η as a single parameter that determines the size of the bubble. In Panel (10b) we assume there is no tax credit, in which case tax can affect the bubble. Since it is very difficult to graphically illustrate the impacts of three parameters (τ , in DN T (hence in B) in Proposition 6.131 . As such we can illustrate c and R) on B, we drop the term −τ 2c η the theoretical bubble size as a function of two parameters, τ and 2c+R . η 1929 B η B η Japan B η Tech Bit Coin Tech τ τ 2c+R η 2c+R η (a) Assume there is perfect tax credit (b) Assume there is no tax credit Figure 10: Comparison: Theoretical and actual bubbles 7.2 Other Implications Second, our model shows that it is possible to detect trader’s private beliefs from high-frequency trading data. Suppose that we can identify the passive agent (usually long-term investors such as pension funds, insurance companies and other institutional traders that invest conservatively belong to this class) and rational (speculative) traders. Then when there is a perfect tax credit, or when there is no tax credit but ηc , τ and 31 R η are relatively large (T bubble), all traders with the same belief sell at the same price, which makes When τ is smaller than one and events we study here. c η is close to zero, the impact of this drop can be ignored. Indeed this is the case in all 31 2c+R η selling prices perfect indicators of private belief (signal). Investors’ private beliefs are highly interesting quantities in academic analysis, but are usually difficult to identify. Given high-frequency trading data, they become identifiable in the above areas of the parameter space in our model. When there is no tax credit in the N T bubble, this perfect relationship does not exist. Instead, a unique prediction is that, an N T trader’s selling price is decreasing in her purchasing price. When we have an acceptable proxy for private signal v, this negative relationship can be tested. Third, the response of the margin between buying and selling prices to model parameters can be tested. In our model, the gap between a trader’s stop-buy price and selling price is increasing in c η and R . η When there is no tax credit (or imperfect), this gap is also increasing in τ . With high-frequency trading data where traders’ action can be tracked (but identities can still remain anonymous), the minimum and average gaps between traders’ stop-buy price and selling price can be identified and above predictions are testable. Lastly, our model implies that the response of price dynamics and trading volume to the changes of certain model parameters in our model are not only empirically testable, but also consistent with existing evidences. When there is a perfect tax credit, τ has not effect at all. An increase in c, on the other hand, will not change selling strategies, but will shift stop-buy strategies downwards, which broadens the gap between purchase and selling prices of all future buyer (who have not bought yet). This implies that traders in the gray area in Figure 11 suddenly switch from buy to not-buy. Under the perfect capital inflow p Ps∗ (v) v+ old Pb∗ (v) = v + η 2 η 2 new Pb∗ (v) = v + √ −2 cη η 2 √ −2 c0 η current price v Figure 11: Downward shift of stop-buy strategies assumption, the increase in c will not affect the price path, because there are infinite traders on the right of the grey area willing to buy and continue to receive loans. But in the real market there are finite investors, and those who are willing to buy may need time to finance their trade either by selling other assets first or by borrowing. When a group of buyers suddenly lose their appetite, demand from the remaining buyers 32 will decrease, at least temporarily. With the supply side unaffected, the price appreciation will slow down (if the bubble has not burst), and the trading volume will decrease as well. When there is no tax credit, rises in τ and c will push the situation away from an N T bubble and closer to T bubble (if not already in T ), not only shifting stop-buy strategies Pb∗ (·) downwards but also shifting some traders’ selling strategies upwards. Specifically, the rises will shift the dividing line (v −2c−DT or N T ) upwards in both N T and T bubbles, causing some N T traders switch to T traders, so that now they sell at higher price v + η2 . The remaining N T traders’ selling strategies, as well as their lower bound Ps∗ (v, Pb∗ ), are all shifted up (those already in case T before the change will not alter their selling strategies). Consequently, under realistic market conditions (capital inflow is not perfect, and the behavioral passive agent does not adjust their supply and provide the asset quickly enough), rises in τ and c will (temporarily) decrease the market supply and demand. This results in a lower trading volume, although the net effect on asset price is ambiguous. If τ or c decreases, the results will be exactly the opposite. These results are consistent with empirical evidences. That a rise in τ or c causes N T traders to sell at higher prices and reduces supply is the lock-in effect, and that a rise in τ or c drives stop-buy strategy downward and reduces demand is the capitalization effect in the empirical literature. Seida and Wempe (2000) show that after 1986 Tax Reform Act (capital tax increase) individual investors were less willing to sell accrued gain stocks. Slemrod (1982) and Hanlon and Pinder (2007) find that after the Revenue Act of 1978 in US and Australia 1999 tax reforms, respectively (both involve capital gains tax reductions), trading volumes significantly increased. Dai et al. (2008) demonstrates that the equilibrium impact of capital gains taxes reflects both the capitalization effect and the lock-in effect, and both Dai et al. (2008) and Ayers et al. (2008) documented increased supply and demand after the 1997 Taxpayer Relief Act in US (capital gains tax reduction). 8 8.1 Policy Implications Capital loss tax credit Our paper shows that capital gains tax will lower speculators’ expected profit; but under perfect tax credit their behavior does not change at all, i.e. they behave as if there is no tax. To effectively curb a bubble, our results suggest that a tax authority should not grant overly favorable tax credits on capital losses, because they can entirely offset the suppressive effects of the tax on investors’ incentives and leave the bubble unaffected. One clarification about this suggestion is that it should be viewed as an ad hoc tax 33 policy instead of a long-run, regular optimal policy. For those who believe that capital gains taxes should be calculated on the basis of long-run average (net) capital gains, the recommendation to weaken tax credit may seem unfair because, without tax credit, investors are taxed whenever they have gains and are left alone when they incur losses, and hence the tax is not based on long-run average gains. So what we suggest is to apply such policy only when there is strong concern that a bubble may be in progress in a specific market. In this paper we do not intend to find an optimal tax policy that can automatically deflate bubbles when they arises and otherwise does not interfere the market. To weaken the capital loss tax credit and shift it away from being perfect and closer to no credit, tax authorities can set or tighten a dollar limit on the tax credit; set or reduce the inclusion rate of the capital loss, which lowers the rate τct in (8) so that τct < τ ; shorten the duration within which tax credits can be carried forward or backward. Other measures include targeting the tax at specific source of gains and imposing different tax rates and tax credit policies to gains from different sources. Although our model only analyzed the two extreme cases (perfect tax credit and no credit) and does not explore some of the practical issues (e.g. expiration of credits), the above suggestions are likely to strengthen the effectiveness of tax and help depress bubbles. The introduction of capital gains tax on overseas investors in April 2015 will close a tax loophole in the United Kingdom, before which these investors are exempt from this tax. Most analysts believe that foreign investors contributed the most to the the ongoing house price upsurge in London and that this change is targeting at them. To take the advantage of this change to its full extent, our paper suggests that, when imposing the tax, UK tax authority should also limit the the tax credits to foreign investors. In addition, if under tax treaties the introduction of this tax in UK exempts foreign investors from tax liabilities in their home countries, then the tax may has little or no effect. 8.2 Transaction taxes Our model also shows that the marginal effect of the transaction cost c in reducing the bubble is very large when c is small, although it diminishes as c increases. Many countries have had experimented financial transaction taxes on trades of shares, bonds, currencies and derivatives, and some countries have abolished the tax or lower the tax rate later. As mentioned earlier, empirical evidences show that these experiments tend to reduce trading volumes but not price volatilities. Although we use a fixed transaction cost instead of a proportional transaction tax, our results may nevertheless rationalize the fact that some countries still maintain financial transaction taxes at very low rates because of its high marginal effect at low rates. For 34 example, the US currently levies a 0.0034% tax on stock transactions, UK levies a rate of 0.5% tax on share purchases, Japan has a 0.1 − 0.3% tax on stock transactions. 8.3 Return from outside investment option and zero interest rate policy Another implication from our model is that, if the alternative investment opportunity has a higher payoff, it will help deflate the bubble. Conversely, a deterioration of the return on alternative investment reduces the opportunity cost of riding the bubble and hence induces a larger bubble. Consequently, governments should be alert on bubbles arising in domestic markets not only when major overseas markets are in booms, but also when markets like US (the alternative investment opportunities in our model) are experiencing recessions. The potential housing bubbles that we have observed in major cities outside US are partially the results of arbitrageurs switching their investments from US real estate markets plagued by the subprime mortgage crisis. Interests on savings are often viewed as outside options to other forms of investments. When central banks set very low interest rates, this encourages households to invest on riskier assets, such as buying a larger or a second house. Central banks often face a dilemma: low interest rates help fight recessions and unemployment (e.g. Federal Reserve’s responses to the 2001 recession), but also contribute to the inflation in housing prices. Although there is no agreement that Federal Reserve’s low interest rate policy during 2001-2005 caused the housing bubble that burst in 2008, the timing of the housing price run-up and bursting roughly coincide with the declining and rising of the federal funds rate. Our model backs the view that low interest rates can contribute to housing bubbles. Bank of Canada now also faces this issue. It has lowered the rates after the 2008 financial crisis and maintained an overnight rate at 1% since 2010. This seems to coincide with the rise of potential housing bubbles in Canada. In January 2015, the Bank surprisingly further lowered the rate to 0.75%, partially to fight the low expected economic growth rate due to the plunge in oil price. Our model warns that, at the already low interest rate, further lowering interest rates has a significant marginal effect of inflating bubbles. Such interest rate policy could be especially dangerous when there is strong suspicion that a large housing bubble already existed in Canada at this time. 8.4 Government bailout Our model can also be used to demonstrate that the expectations for government bailouts lead to larger bubbles. When large investors purchase risky asset in the boom, the expectations that they are “too 35 big to fail” and that the government will bail them out once they are in trouble give them incentives to take more aggressive positions. When the post-crash trade of a break-even trader incurs a loss for sure (Pb∗ (v) + 2c > Pb∗−1 (Ps∗ (v)) − η2 , i.e. Equation (3)), a bailout reduces the loss and the gap between pre and post-crash payoff in the first order condition becomes smaller, with or without the tax credit. A smaller loss encourages traders to wait and sell at higher price, and higher selling prices induce higher stop-buy prices and hence a larger bubble emerges. When the post-crash trade of a break-even trader can be profitable (Pb∗ (v) + 2c < Pb∗−1 (Ps∗ (v)) − η2 , i.e. Equation (2)), the expectation for bailouts does not change selling strategies (because it is profitable in the marginal event and there is no need for bailout), but the loss will be smaller due to the bailout (the first integral in (2)), which leads to higher stop-buy prices and a larger bubble. Again this is true with or without tax credit. Note that the bailout has a larger inflating effect on bubbles when there is no tax credit than there is credit, because the the bailout reduces the loss but also crowds out the tax credit, the there will be less loss to carry after the bailout. During the 2008 financial crisis, the U.S. Congress and government passed the Troubled Asset Relief Program funded at $700 billion and bailed out many large banks, insurance companies and auto companies. These bailouts have been highly controversial since day one, and one of the criticisms is that they create moral hazard and encourage firms to take reckless risks. Our paper formalizes this criticism in a model of bubble and demonstrates that the expectations for bailouts created from previous bailouts will clearly encourage agents to take excess risks which fuels the next bubble. 9 Conclusion We study the effects of taxes, especially the capital gains tax, on asset bubbles, which has not been explored by the existing literature. Our model incorporates purchases into the framework of Abreu and Brunnermeier (2003). In the unique equilibrium, we find that the capital gains tax has no effect on the size of the bubble when there is a perfect capital loss tax credit. Bubble size becomes decreasing in the capital gains tax when there is no tax credit. Therefore dealing with bubbles with the capital gains tax not only requires imposing the tax, but also requires tightening the policies on tax credit. In contrast, a small fixed transaction cost can also deflate the bubble considerably, with or without tax or tax credit. We also show that a lower return from alternative investment options may induce a larger bubble and demonstrate that further lowering an already low interest rate has a significant inflating marginal effect. The model also has an appealing dynamic in which the stop-buy decision and selling decision spread smoothly and 36 continuously from low types to high types and high types are still buying when low type already sold. It would be desirable to empirically verify these results. References Abreu, Dilip, and Markus K. Brunnermeier (2003) ‘Bubbles and crashes.’ Econometrica 71(1), 173–204 Ayers, Benjamin, Oliver Zhen Li, and John R Robinson (2008) ‘Tax-Induced Trading around the Taxpayer Relief Act of 1997.’ The Journal of the American Taxation Association 30(1), 77–100 Brunnermeier, Markus K. (2001) Asset Pricing under Asymmetric Information: Bubbles, Crashes, Technical Analysis, and Herding OUP Catalogue (Oxford University Press) (2008) ‘bubbles.’ In The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, ed. Steven N. Durlauf and Lawrence E. Blume (Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan) Brunnermeier, Markus K., and Lasse Heje Pedersen (2005) ‘Predatory trading.’ Journal of Finance 60(4), 1825–1863 Brunnermeier, Markus K., and Martin Oehmke (2012) ‘Bubbles, financial crises, and systemic risk.’ NBER Working Papers 18398, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc, September Brunnermeier, Markus K., and Stefan Nagel (2004) ‘Hedge funds and the technology bubble.’ Journal of Finance 59(5), 2013–2040 Carlin, Bruce Ian, Miguel Sousa Lobo, and S. Viswanathan (2007) ‘Episodic liquidity crises: Cooperative and predatory trading.’ Journal of Finance 62(5), 2235–2274 Constantinides, George M (1983) ‘Capital Market Equilibrium with Personal Tax.’ Econometrica 51(3), 611–36 Dai, Zhonglan, Edward Maydew, Douglas A. Shackelford, and Harold H. Zhang (2008) ‘Capital Gains Taxes and Asset Prices: Capitalization or Lock-in?’ Journal of Finance 63(2), 709–742 De Long, J. Bradford, Andrei Shleifer, Lawrence H. Summers, and Robert J. Waldmann (1990) ‘Positive feedback investment strategies and destabilizing rational speculation.’ Journal of Finance 45(2), 379–95 Doblas-Madrid, Antonio (2012) ‘A robust model of bubbles with multidimensional uncertainty.’ Econometrica 80(5), 1845–1893 Griffin, John M., Jeffrey H. Harris, Tao Shu, and Selim Topaloglu (2011) ‘Who drove and burst the tech bubble?’ Journal of Finance 66(4), 1251–1290 Hanlon, Dean, and Sean Pinder (2007) ‘An empirical investigation of whether Australian capital gains tax reforms influence individual investor behaviour.’ Pacific-Basin Finance Journal 15(5), 481–493 Hu, Shing-yang (1998) ‘The effects of the stock transaction tax on the stock market - Experiences from Asian markets.’ Pacific-Basin Finance Journal 6(3-4), 347–364 Jones, Charles M (2002) ‘A century of stock market liquidity and trading costs.’ Available at SSRN 313681 Kyle, Albert S (1985) ‘Continuous Auctions and Insider Trading.’ Econometrica 53(6), 1315–35 37 Lanne, Markku, and Timo Vesala (2010) ‘The effect of a transaction tax on exchange rate volatility.’ International Journal of Finance & Economics 15(2), 123–133 Li, Mei, and Frank Milne (2014) ‘The role of a large trader in a dynamic currency attack model.’ Journal of Financial Intermediation 23(4), 590–620 Scheinkman, Jose A., and Wei Xiong (2003) ‘Overconfidence and speculative bubbles.’ Journal of Political Economy 111(6), 1183–1219 Seida, Jim A., and William F. Wempe (2000) ‘Do capital gain tax rate increases affect individual investors’ trading decisions?’ Journal of Accounting and Economics 30(1), 33–57 Shiller, Robert J, Fumiko Kon-Ya, and Yoshiro Tsutsui (1996) ‘Why Did the Nikkei Crash? Expanding the Scope of Expectations Data Collection.’ The Review of Economics and Statistics 78(1), 156–64 Slemrod, Joel (1982) ‘Stock Transactions Volume and the 1978 Capital Gains Tax Reduction.’ Public Finance Review 10(1), 3–16 Stone, Douglas, and William T. Ziemba (1993) ‘Land and Stock Prices in Japan.’ Journal of Economic Perspectives 7(3), 149–165 Temin, Peter, and Hans-Joachim Voth (2004) ‘Riding the south sea bubble.’ American Economic Review 94(5), 1654–1668 Umlauf, Steven R. (1993) ‘Transaction taxes and the behavior of the Swedish stock market.’ Journal of Financial Economics 33(2), 227–240 Westerhoff, Frank H., and Roberto Dieci (2006) ‘The effectiveness of Keynes-Tobin transaction taxes when heterogeneous agents can trade in different markets: A behavioral finance approach.’ Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 30(2), 293–322 Xiong, Wei (2013) ‘Bubbles, Crises, and Heterogeneous Beliefs.’ NBER Working Papers 18905, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc, March The Impact of Capital Gain Taxes and Transaction Costs on Asset Bubbles Appendix A Anticipated price path p(t) R t u(ν) u(ν) dν and p(t) = α(D (t)) we have dν = α−1 (p(t)). Differentiating w.r.t t r ν=0 p(ν) ν=0 p(ν) dp/dt p on both sides, we have u(t) = α0 (α −1 (p)) =⇒ u(t)dt = α0 (α−1 (p)) dp. Integrating both sides w.r.t t and p, R p(t) R R p p respectively, we have u(t)dt + C = α0 (α−1 dp, where C is a constant. Let G(p) ≡ 0 (α−1 (p)) dp, then (p)) α R −1 From Dr (t) = Rt p(t) = G ( u(t)dt + C). Combine with boundary condition p(0) = 0, we can solve for p(t). Appendix B Proof of Lemma 3.1 We first prove the following lemma. Lemma B.1. lim Ps∗ (v, Pp ) = ∞, ∀Pp . v→∞ Proof. Assume there exists P such that P > Ps∗ (v, Pp ), ∀v. For a trader with signal v > P + η2 , she knows for sure that θ > P . Then selling at price Ps∗ (v, Pp ) < P < θ cannot be an equilibrium strategy, because she would rather sell at price v, for instance, if the bubble has not burst, or at θ, if the it has burst. A contradiction. 38 Lemma B.2. There exists v 0 (and Pp ) such that Ps∗ (v 0 , Pp ) = Pb∗ (v), ∀v ≥ η2 . Proof. The lowest possible θ is zero, hence the bubble cannot burst below Pb∗ ( η2 ), and no trader should sell below Pb∗ ( η2 ). For trader v = − η2 , she know for sure that θ = 0 and the bubble will burst at Pb∗ ( η2 ). Hence she will sell exactly at Pb∗ ( η2 ). Because both Pb∗ (·) and Ps∗ (·, ·) are continuous, and Ps∗ (·, ·) does no have an upper bound, the lemma holds. Corollary 3.1 implies that Pb∗ (·) is weakly increasing. Suppose that there exists η2 ≤ v < v such that Pb∗ (v) = Pb∗ (v). Then the probability of bursting at Pb∗ (v) is strictly positive. By Lemma B.2, there exists v such that Ps∗ (v, Pp ) = Pb∗ (v) + ε, where ε > 0. Consider trader v. When ε is small enough, the extra benefit, ε, from selling at Pb∗ (v) + ε instead of at Pb∗ (v) will be smaller than the loss from being caught in the crash at Pb∗ (v). Then trader v is strictly better off by lowering her selling price from Pb∗ (v) + ε to Pb∗ (v). A contradiction. Appendix C Proof of Proposition 3.1 Suppose trader v who does not hold the asset stops buying for the first time at Pb∗ (v) and then switches back to buy. Since price is continuously and strictly rising and Pb∗ (·) is continuous, there must be trader v + ε who does not hold the asset and has stopped buying before v could restart buying, by Assumption 3.2. By Corollary 3.1, trader v cannot restart buying before trader v + ε stops and then restarts buying, and trader v + ε cannot do so before trader v + 2ε does so. Proceeding this way, trader v is not buying until trader θ + η2 stops and then restarts buying. That trader θ + η2 stops buying is exactly what triggers the burst. If a trader v has previously sold the asset at Ps∗ (v, Pp ) and now tries to buy again, it contradicts the belief that all lower types have stopped buying, since Pb∗ (v) ≤ Ps∗ (v, Pp ). Appendix D If 2c+R η <2− Equilibrium strategies of trader v ≤ tax credit and positive bubble √ 3 <, a trader η 2 − p (4c + 2R)η < v ≤ η 2 with perfect η 2 buy, if price < Pb∗ (v) = HC (v); will sell, if price ≥ Ps∗ (v) = v + η2 ; , hold, if P ∗ (v) ≤ price < P ∗ (v). s b p and a trader v ≤ η2 − (4c + 2R)η p buy, if price < η − (4c + 2R)η − 2c − R; p will sell, if price ≥ η − (4c + 2R)η; hold, if η − p(4c + 2R)η − 2c − R ≤ price < η − p(4c + 2R)η. √ If 2 − 3 ≤ 2c+R < 12 , a trader v ≤ vC will never buy the asset, and a trader vC < v < η buy, if price < Pb∗ (v) = HC (v); will sell, if price ≥ Ps∗ (v) = v + η2 ; hold, if P ∗ (v) ≤ price < P ∗ (v). b s 39 η 2 v 2 +(η−2R−4c)v−2η √ (2R+4c)η+Rη+2cη+ 5 η 2 4 where HC (v) ≡ , and vC ≡ − η2 + 2c + R+ 2v+η q p 4c2 −η 2 −4cη+R2 +4Rc−2Rη+2η (4c+2R)η. p √ When 2c+R < 2 − 3, traders with very low signals (v ≤ η2 − (4c + 2R)η) all stop buying at the same η p p price η − (4c + 2R)η − 2c − R and sell at the same price η − (4c + 2R)η, because they know that the bubble will not burst before trader v = η2 stops buying. Hence, they all sell at Pb∗ ( η2 ) and maintain the p minimum gap 2c + R between their stop-buy and selling prices. For those whose v ∈ [ η2 − (4c + 2R)η, η2 ], it is optimal for them to sell at Ps∗ (v) = v + η2 , since their purchase costs are sunk and irrelevant. However, it is possible that the bubble bursts before they sell. In addition, since their belief support is truncated, they p have gaps between their stop-buy and selling prices that are larger than 2c + R but smaller than (4c + 2R)η. √ < 12 , traders with very low signals (v ≤ vC ) never buy the asset, because their When 2 − 3 ≤ 2c+R η stop-buy prices Pb∗ (v) ≤ 0. Appendix E Proof of Proposition 5.1 Part 1: Equilibrium verification for v > η2 Suppose that all other traders use strategies prescribed in Proposition 5.1. √ Sale decision: Since θ = Pb∗−1 (Ps ) − η2 = Ps − θ + 2 cη, then Φ(θ|v) = θ−(v− η2 ) η and φ(θ|v) = 1 . θ d2 ω dω dω = η1 (−Ps + η2 + v), and SOC is dP 2 = −1 < 0. Set dP = 0, Substitute into Equation (8), we have dP s s s η η ∗ ∗ ∗ we have Ps (v) = v + 2 . Therefore, given all traders stop buying at Pb (v), selling at Ps (v) = v + 2 is an equilibrium. √ Purchase decision: Because Equation (4) is decreasing in Pb , Pb∗ (v) = v + η2 − 2 cη is uniquely pinned down by (9). Under the strategy Pb∗ (·), B > 0 when ηc < 14 . Part 2: Equilibrium uniqueness for v > η2 We prove the uniqueness by four lemmas. Let p∗b (v) ≡ Pb∗ (v) − v. Suppose that B > 0 upon burst. Lemma E.1. Any equilibrium strategy must be that p∗b (v) is bounded. Proof. The continuity of P ∗ (·) implies that P ∗ (·) is finite for finite v. Recall that P ∗ (·) is an increasing function. If limv→∞ p∗ (v) = ∞, then ∀B > 0, there exists θ such that Pb∗ (θ + η2 ) − θ > B. Hence P ∗ (v) cannot be an equilibrium strategy. Lemma E.2. In any equilibrium, FOC = 0 holds for all traders in ( η2 , ∞). ∂ω Proof. Assume in an equilibrium strategy Pb∗ (·) and Ps∗ (·), there exists a trader v such that her ∂P 6= 0. s ∂ω If her ∂Ps < 0, that means she can increase her expected payoff by decreasing her selling price p. The only lower boundary for price is zero. But selling at zero is never optimal because θ > 0 for sure. Hence for all trader v > η2 , selling at the corner solution zero cannot be optimal. Therefore in any equilibrium a ∂ω ∂ω trader v’s ∂P cannot be strictly negative. If her ∂P > 0, that means she can increase her expected payoff s s ∂ω by increasing her selling price p. But there is no upper boundary for price, so ∂P > 0 itself implies this s strategy is not optimal. Therefore in any equilibrium a trader v’s FOC cannot be strictly positive. In ∂ω addition, those Ps at which ω(Pp , Ps ) is non-differentiable ( ∂P does not exist) cannot be in the equilibrium s ∗−1 ∂ω for the following reason. ∂Ps does not exists at two points: Pb (Ps ) − η2 = v ± η2 . But Ps at neither point can be equilibrium strategy, because Pb∗−1 (Ps ) − η2 = v + η2 =⇒ Ps = Pb∗ (v + η), which is not rational when bubble size is strictly positive, and Pb∗−1 (Ps ) − η2 = v − η2 =⇒ Ps = Pb∗ (v), which is not rational when transaction cost c > 0. Hence FOC= 0 holds for all traders v > η2 in equilibrium. 40 dω(P ∗ (v),P ∗ (v),v) ∂ω dPb ∂ω dPs ∂ω s b = ∂P + ∂P + ∂ω = 0. Since ∂P = 0 in From ω(Pb∗ (v), Ps∗ (v)) = (1 − τ )R we have dv ∂v s dv s b dv η η η ∂ω ∂ω 0 0 EQ, we have ∂Pb Pb + ∂v = 0 =⇒ −Pb − (v − 2 )φ(v − 2 |v) + Ps φ(v + 2 |v) = 0. For uniform distribution, this means η 0 Ps∗ (v) = ηPb∗ (v) + v − (10) 2 ∂ω(Pb ,Ps ) ∂Ps = 0 (partially) and for uniform distribution, we have η 0 0 Pb∗ (Pb∗−1 (Ps∗ (v))) − 1 = [Pb∗ (v) − 1] ∗−1 ∗ η + v − Pb (Ps (v)) Substitute (10) into FOC: (11) From Ps∗ (v) > Pb∗ (v) =⇒ Pb∗−1 (Ps∗ (v)) > v. From Ps∗ (v) ≤ Pb∗ (θ + η2 ) < Pb∗ (v + η2 + η2 ) = Pb∗ (v + η) =⇒ η Pb∗−1 (Ps∗ (v)) < v + η. Hence, 0 < η + v − Pb∗−1 (Ps∗ (v)) < η =⇒ η+v−P ∗−1 > 1. Therefore, from (11) (Ps∗ (v)) b ∗0 ∗−1 ∗ 0 0 Pb (Pb (Ps (v))) > Pb∗ (v), if Pb∗ (v) > 1 we know . 0 0 0 Pb∗ (Pb∗−1 (Ps∗ (v))) < Pb∗ (v), if Pb∗ (v) < 1 For ∀v1 , its “images” v2 , v3 , ... are defined as v2 ≡ Pb∗−1 (Ps∗ (v1 )), v3 ≡ Pb∗−1 (Ps∗ (v2 )), etc. Let xi ≡ 0 0 η η = η+vi −v and Xi ≡ Πij=1 xj . Then given any v1 , we have Pb∗ (vi )−1 = xi−1 [Pb∗ (vi−1 )−1] = η+v −P ∗−1 (P ∗ (v )) i+1 i b 0 s i Xi [Pb∗ (v1 ) − 1]. Lemma E.3. limi→∞ Xi = ∞ Proof. Suppose limi→∞ Xi converges to a finite value. This implies that limi→∞ xi = 1, which in turn implies that vi+1 → vi , i.e. Pb∗−1 (Ps∗ (vi )) → vi . Recall that Ps∗ (vi ) − Pb∗ (vi ) ≥ 2c. This means that the slope of the line segment (vi+1 , Pb∗ (vi+1 )) − (vi , Pb∗ (vi )) can be arbitrarily large, and this slope goes to infinity as i → ∞. Then Pb∗ (·) must diverge upward from 45◦ line, i.e. Pb∗ (v) − v is not bounded. A contradiction. 0 Lemma E.4. Pb∗ (v) = 1, ∀v > 1 2 0 Proof. Suppose ∃v1 such that Pb∗ (v1 ) < 1. Since xi > 1, ∀i, if Xi → ∞, then there must exist vi such 0 0 0 that Pb∗ (vi ) − 1 < −1 =⇒ Pb∗ (vi ) < 0, which violates the assumption that Pb∗ (·) > 0. Suppose ∃v1 such 0 0 0 that Pb∗ (v1 ) > 1, we have limi→∞ Pb∗ (vi ) = ∞. We know that in equilibrium Ps∗ (vi ) = ηPb∗ (vi ) + vi − η2 ≤ 0 0 Pb∗ (vi + η). Since Pb∗ (vi ) will grow unboundedly, we see that ηPb∗ (vi ) − 32 η ≤ Pb∗ (vi + η) − (vi + η), which implies that Pb∗ (vi + η) − (vi + η) will also grow unboundedly, which contradicts Lemma E.1 that p∗b (vi ) = Pb∗ (vi ) − (vi ) must be bounded. Let Pb∗ (v) = v + g, where g is a constant. We can solve for Ps∗ (·) through standard procedure and have Ps∗ (v) = v + η2 . Because Equation (4) is decreasing in Pb in any equilibrium with perfect tax credit, √ √ Pb∗ (v) = v + η2 − 2 cη is uniquely pinned down by (9), i.e. g = η2 − 2 cη. Then B > 0 requires that ηc < 14 . The belief that B ≤ 0 will lead to an entirely different strategy profile (Proposition 5.2), which cannot be equilibrium strategy when ηc < 14 . Part 3: Equilibrium verification and uniqueness for v ≤ η2 √ √ It is straightforward to verify the equilibrium strategies when 2 − 3 ≤ 2c+R < 12 and when 2c+R < 2 − 3, η η so we skip the procedure. Uniqueness: The equilibrium strategy of a trader v ∈ [− η2 , η2 ] is unique because her decision depends only on the strategies of those whose v > η2 , which have already been pinned down in Part 2. Specifically, for trader v ∈ [− η2 , η2 ], we can also calculate her expected profit from (7). The difference is that the lower bound of θ is zero instead of v − η2 , and her belief about θ is a uniform distribution over [0, v + η2 ]. The derived selling strategy is still Ps∗ (v) = v + η2 , with the restriction that Ps∗ (v) ≥ Pb∗ ( η2 ) since bubble will √ never burst blow Pb∗ ( η2 ). Pb∗ ( η2 ) = η − 2 cη is pinned down by Ps∗ ( η2 ) from (9). Hence Ps∗ (v) equals v + η2 √ √ √ for trader v ∈ [ η2 − 2 cη, η2 ] and equals Pb∗ ( η2 ) = η − 2 cη for trader v ∈ [− η2 , η2 − 2 cη]. A trader in the latter range will sell before crash without risk, and she will not sell strictly above Pb∗ ( η2 ) because it is not optimal marginally. Pb∗ (v) = H(v) can also be derived from (9) for a trader v ∈ [− η2 , η2 ). 41 Appendix F Proof of Proposition 5.2 We first verify that this is an equilibrium. When everyone else stops buying at price v − 2c − R, bubble bursts at pT = θ + η2 − 2c − R, which is smaller than θ when 2c+R ≥ 21 . As the bubble size is non-positive, η it is optimal for traders to sell after the burst, i.e. they will try selling as late as possible. For trader v, the largest possible θ is v + η2 , so selling at any price ≥ v + η2 is justified and is equivalent. We assume that in this case traders sell at v + η2 . Then everyone simply gets the after burst price θ, which means their expected sale revenue is E[θ|v]. Then the best response in purchase stage is to stop buying at Pb∗ (v) = E[θ|v] − 2c − R = v − 2c − R. Then for traders with v ≤ 2c + R, their stop-buy price is zero or negative, so they will never buy the asset. Uniqueness: If B < 0, then selling below Pb∗ (v + η2 + η2 ) = v + η + g is strictly dominated by at or above v + η + g, and the latter means that the trader will get θ for sure. Knowing that the expected sale price is E[θ|v] = v, a trader will stop buying at v − 2c − R to maintain a non-negative expected payoff. ≥ 12 . The belief that B > 0 will lead to an entirely different strategy profile Then B ≤ 0 requires that 2c+R η (Proposition 5.1), which cannot be equilibrium strategy when 2c+R > 12 . η Appendix G Equilibrium strategies of trader v ≤ credit and with positive bubble η 2 √ 2R+4c without tax η N oT 1. When τ < 21 − (1− 2c η)2 −4 R and Rη < 18 (1 − 2c )2 − ηc and ηc < 3−22 2 , a trader vN T < v ≤ 2 will η η η s v+η+DN T −2c− τ1 (2v+ 32 η+DN T )+ 2τ12 (2v+η−DN T) Ps L buy, if price < Pb∗ (v) = , if v > vN T ; η + D , if v < v Ps L ; NT NT 2 , η−(4c+2η+2DN T )τ τ 1−τ v − P + , if P > v − 2c − D ; p NT 1−2τ 1−2τ p 2(1−2τ ) sell, if price ≥ Ps∗ (v, Pp ) = v + η , if P < v − 2c − D ; p NT 2 hold, if P ∗ (v) ≤ price < P ∗ (v). s b v + η + D − 1 ( η + v) + DNs T , if v > v Ps L NT NT t 2 2t(1−2t) ∗ ∗ and in particular Ps (v, Pb (v)) = η + D , if v < v Ps L NT NT 2 buy, if price < Pb∗ (v) = η2 + DN T − 2c − R; sell, if price ≥ P ∗ (v, P ) = 1−τ v − τ P p s 1−2τ 1−2τ p Ps H N oT and a trader vN T < v ≤ vN T will η−(4c+2η+2D N T )τ + ; 2(1−2τ ) hold, if P ∗ (v) ≤ price < P ∗ (v, P ). b ητ +2DN T −2Rτ Ps H Ps L τ N oT where vN , T = DN T + 2c 1−τ , vN T = DN T + 2c, vN T = 2(1−τ ) p s DN T (v) ≡ (1−τ )(1−2τ )(2v+η) [η+2v−(3η+2v+4DN T −4Rτ )τ ]. 42 p s η and in particular Ps∗ (v, Pb∗ (v)) = 2 + DN T buy, if price < η2 + DN T − 2c − R; Ps H and a trader v ≤ vN sell, if price ≥ η2 + DN T ; T will hold, if η + D − 2c − R ≤ price < NT 2 η 2 + DN T . 2( 2c + R ) 2. When 12 − (1− 2cη )2 −η 4R < τ < η and 18 (1 − 2c 2 ) η (a) When c η η − c η R η < <1− (1− 2c )2 −2 R η η < 12 (1 − √ 3 2 1− 4c − 2R η η and a trader vTDiv < v ≤ η 2 4c ) η and and c η < √ 3−2 2 , 2 or when τ < 1− 4c − 2R η η (1− 2c )2 −2 R η η 2 R 1−8 ηc +4 c 2 + R2 +4 Rc 2 −4 η 2 ηc η η η 2 2 1−8 ηc +20 c 2 +2 R2 +12 Rc −4 R η η η η2 <2− 3− and τ < buy, if price < HTT Pb (v); will sell, if price ≥ Ps∗ (v, Pp ) = v + η2 ; , hold, if P ∗ (v) ≤ price < P ∗ (v). , s b vTN oT c η < 14 , 2 √ R η < 18 (1− 2c )2 − ηc and η R η < v < vTDiv and atrader H N T Pb (v), if v > v Ps L ; T T ∗ buy, if price < Pb (v) = ; η + D − 2c − R, if v < v Ps L ; T T (2 will η−(4c+2η+2DT )τ 1−τ τ v− P + if Pp > v−2c−DT ; 2(1−2τ ) sell, if price ≥ Ps∗ (v, Pp ) = 1−2τ η 1−2τ p v + 2 if Pp < v − 2c − DT ; ∗ ∗ hold, if Pb (v) ≤ price < Ps (v). v + η + D − 1 ( η + v) + DTs , if v > v Ps L ; T T τ 2 2τ (1−2τ ) , particular Ps∗ (v, Pb∗ (v)) = η P L + D , if v < v s ; T 2 vTPs H and in T v ≤ vTN oT and a trader < buy, if price < Pb∗ (v) = η2 + DT − 2c − R; 1 will sell, if price ≥ Ps∗ (v, Pp ) = 1−2τ v + η2 −τ (2c+η+v+DT +Pp ) ; , and in particular Ps∗ (v, Pb∗ (v)) hold, if P ∗ (v) ≤ price < P ∗ (v, P ). b η 2 s p + DT , buy, if price < η2 + DT − 2c − R; and a trader v ≤ vTPs H will sell, if price ≥ η2 + DT ; hold, if η +D −2c ≤ price < η +D . T T 2 2 T Pb buy, if price < HT (v); (b) Otherwise, a trader vTPb < v ≤ η2 will , sell, if price ≥ η2 ; hold, if H T Pb (v) ≤ price < η . T 2 a trader v < vTPb will never buy the asset. τ T −2Rτ where vTPs H ≡ DT + 2c 1−τ , vTN oT ≡ DT + 2c, vTPs L ≡ ητ +2D , vTDiv ≡ DT − (1 − τ )R+ 2(1−τ ) q (1 − τ ) (1 − τ )R2 + (2DT + η)R − 12 (2DT + η)2 , p DqTs (v) ≡ (1−τ )(1−2τ )(2v+η) [η+2v−(3η+2v+4DT −4Rτ )τ ], HTT Pb (v) ≡ v − 2c + η2 + 1−τ 1 (−2(c+DT )η+4Rv+4c(c+DT ))τ 2+(− 21 η 2+(R+4c−2v+2DT )η−2v(R+v))τ+41 (η+2v)2 ], τ 1−2τ [ HTN T Pb (v) ≡ v + η + DT − 2c − τ1 (2v + 32 η + DT ) + 2τ12 (2v + η − DTs ), vTPb ≡ 2c − η2 + R+ r [−(R+c+DT )η+2c2 +(4R+2DT )c+R2 ]τ 2 +[(2R+3c+2DT )η−6c2 −(6R+2DT )c− 32 R2 ]τ −(R+2c+DT )η+ 12 (R+2c)2 . (1−τ )(1−2τ ) 43 v−η 2τ + Appendix H Proof of Proposition 6.1 Part 1: Equilibrium verification for v > We can verify that Pb + 2c > Pb∗−1 (Ps ) − Pb∗−1 (Ps )− η2 when c η < 1 2 and 21 − 4c η (1− 2c )2 η η 2 η 2 when <τ < c η < 1− 4c η (1− 2c )2 η 3 2 − √ 2 and τ < 1 2 − 4c η (1− 2c )2 η , and that Pb + 2c < . Hence the first part of Proposition 6.1 corresponds to the Equation (6) and the second part corresponds to Equation (5), both with I = 0. Following essentially the same procedure in Part 1 of Appendix E, applied to Equation (6) and (5) respectively (both with I = 0), we can verify that Ps∗ (·) and Pb∗ (·) define the equilibria. Part 2: Equilibrium uniqueness for v > η2 The proofs for both case T and N T are essentially the same as Part 2 in Appendix E, so we skip them. Part 3: Equilibrium verification and uniqueness for v ≤ η2 The proofs for both case T and N T are essentially the same as Part 3 in Appendix E, so we skip them. Appendix I Proof of Proposition 6.2 Equilibrium verification is essentially the same as in Appendix F, except that the stop-buy price Pb is R Pb +2c R v+ η 2 pinned down by θ=v− η (θ − Pb − 2c)φ(θ|v)dθ + (1 − τ ) θ=Pb +2c (θ − Pb − 2c)φ(θ|v)dθ = (1 − τ )R and 2 q we have Pb∗ (v) = v + η2 − τη − 2c ± τη (1 − τ )(1 − 2τ Rη ). Since Pb∗ (v) + 2c ≥ v − η2 , we have Pb∗ (v) = q v + η2 − τη − 2c + τη (1 − τ )(1 − 2τ Rη ). Furthermore Pb∗ (v) + 2c ≥ v − η2 requires that 2 Rη ≤ 1. The proof of uniqueness is also the same as Appendix F. 44
© Copyright 2024