“AGENCIFICATION”: PENDING QUESTIONS AND HOW TO ADDRESS THEM Paper for the Annual NIG Conference Workshop 5: Trust at arms’ length: How can politicians trust agencies? October 30-31, 2002, Rotterdam Koen VERHOEST & Bram VERSCHUERE Public Management Institute – KU Leuven [email protected] / [email protected] “Agencification”: pending questions and how to address them Introduction This paper is not aiming at presenting research results, it is to be seen as a discussion paper. We will present the early stages of a research project we are currently developing towards agencification and agencification processes in Flanders and in a later stadium also in an international context. First, we deal with the demarcation of our research topic. Here we will try to define the research objects that we will deal with. In a second part we will present the conceptualisation of agencification and agencification processes we developed. Third, we will pose some initial research questions and present some theoretical assumptions linked to these research questions. To conclude, we will present a preliminary research design that will also have attention to the research questions we posed earlier. Demarcation of the research Agencification often is placed under the umbrella of what is called ‘administrative decentralisation’. Decentralisation is a trajectory (an intentional pattern, or a route that one takes) of public sector reform (Pollitt and Bouckaert, 2000). It is to be classified under the umbrella of organisational reform1, that is, a pattern that links an initial organisational situation (of the public sector) and a desired or intended future public sector organisation. Pollitt and Bouckaert (2000) argue that in order to understand the concept of ‘decentralisation’, you have to see it as a process that contains at least three strategic choices. The first choice is this between ‘political’ and ‘administrative’ decentralization. Political decentralization is transferring authority to elected political representatives at a lower level in the state organisation (e.g. from central to local government), while administrative decentralisation is transferring authority to another body (e.g. an agency). The second choice is between passing authority to another body which is selected by competitive means (e.g. through competitive tendering) and transferring authority by non-competitive means. The third choice is between internal and external decentralization. Internal decentralization is transferring powers within an existing organisation, while external decentralisation is passing authority towards an independent external body or organisation (that is existing or newly created). Within the scope of this paper, we are mainly interested in administrative decentralisation, be it internal or external. Administrative decentralisation is sometimes referred to as agencification (Peters, 2002, Smullen et al., 2001, Verhoest, forthcoming) and can be defined as ‘standing besides decentralisation via markets and political decentralisation; it does not reject state delivery of services but seeks to create organisations more consumer responsive while retaining control ‘ (Hambleton, 1992). In the literature, there is commonly made a distinction between ‘internal autonomous agencies’ and ‘external autonomous agencies’. If decentralisation is the positioning of the state tasks in an existing or a new organisation outside of the former central government organisation, it is external decentralisation. If one talks about the creation of new organisational units or the enlargement of the autonomy of existing units within the former central government organisation, it is internal decentralisation (Bouckaert & Verhoest, 1997). Internal decentralisation also implies that the full political responsibilities of the minister and the hierarchical ties between minister and decentralised organisation remain unchanged, while in external decentralisation the relation between minister and decentralised body becomes a relationship that is legally described. Most often, an external decentralised body also has legal personality (Verhoest, forthcoming). From what has been written above, it should be clear that ‘agencification’ has to do with ‘organisational reform’. Our research objects are administrative decentralised public sector organisations, or agencies, or quango’s. These organisations however are not that homogenous a field as one could presume. It is indeed a variety of public sector and semi public sector organisations that covers a broad spectrum. Several authors did attempts to map the field. Greve et al. (1999) 1 Other organisational reform trajectories are according to the same authors: specialisation, co-ordination and scale adjustments. Koen Verhoest & Bram Verschuere (Public Management Institute – KU Leuven) 2 “Agencification”: pending questions and how to address them argue that most efforts to solve the definition problem have so far not been successful on two accounts. First, the attempt to make a deductive definition based on structural features of organisations failed because some organisations were not listed for purely formal reasons. Second, the studies that focused on government organisations which had their functions decentralized functionally left out bodies that developed on a bottom up basis like voluntaries. They come up with a continuum of quangos, ranging from departmental units over contract agencies, public bodies, the voluntary/charity and privatisation/semi-privatization to contracting out. For each type of organisation, five conditions are described: finances (how is the organisation financed?), ministerial responsibility (can the minister be held responsible?), control mechanisms (can the minister control?), public task (can the aim of the quango be considered as a public task?) and public domain (distinguishes government related organisations from private organisations). It is these conditions that are crucial to distinguish between quangos. Contracting out Private organisation contract with state Definition Finances Voluntary / Public Body Charity Bottom up Arm’s length body but publicly performing funded public function Market mechanism Privatization / semi-privat. Former state owned company, now wholly or partly privatized Capital market, stock Contract agency Quasi autonomous part of department Departmental unit Hierarchical unit under direct ministerial control Donation, subsidy State budget State budget or levying State budget ? no no partial yes yes Contract Market regulation Co-op, contract statutes Framework document Direct political ? ? yes yes yes yes No No yes yes yes yes British Rail Salvation Army Netherlands National Bank Prison service UK Home Denmark UK Office Ministerial Responsibility Control mechanism Public task Public domain Waste disposal Dutch communities Source: Greve et al. (1999) Example Pollitt et al. (2001) start from the idea that one may envisage a two dimensional spectrum of types of organisation running from the centre of government out across the public-private borderline. Along one dimension one moves from organisations with no commercial purposes to those that are largely suffused with commercial purposes (e.g. state enterprises) and privately owned, profit seeking companies. This is the ‘state-market’ dimension. The other dimension moves from wholly state owned and public law dominated institutions (e.g. a ministry) through arm’s length but still public bodies (agencies) to public private partnerships and finally to voluntary organisations that are part of the civil society. This is the ‘state – civil society’ dimension. It is argued that different definitions of agencies fence off more or less extensive strips along these two dimensions. Pollitt et al. (2001) see agencies as lying center left on both the state – market and the state – civil society dimension. At the left hand pole of both dimensions lie ministries. At the right hand pole of the state-market dimension state enterprises and private companies are excluded. At the right hand side of the state-civil society dimension voluntary associations are excluded. Bouckaert and Peters (2001) also Koen Verhoest & Bram Verschuere (Public Management Institute – KU Leuven) 3 “Agencification”: pending questions and how to address them provide a list of what they call ‘an increasingly large collection of other types of public bodies existing within the set of government with which we are concerned. They classify them in the following way, based on a descending order of proximity to the formal, legal authority of the state (also cf. supra): (1) components of ministries (hierarchically subordinated to ministry), (2) independent but within ministry (legal personality can, but yet legally subordinated), (3) legal entity but within ministry (American agencies are archetypically; status in public law, but for many purposes subordinated), (4) legal entity public law (autonomous or semiautonomous organisation founded under public law), (5) legal entity private law (private law organisations that yet perform public functions), (6) sui generis organisations (can be entirely free from executive control, responsible to parliament, quasi judicial state entities, …). So what are ‘agencies’ now for our purposes? What organisations will be included in our research project? This question is not totally clear yet, partly due to the fact that there is a lack of criteria that can identify the organisations that are interesting for our case. Therefore, up to now, we will have to rely on a pragmatic way to deal with this problem. We discern 4 concentric circles. The middle circle is the core government organisation, or the departmental unit in the terms of Greve et al. The next circles are the ‘internal autonomous (or decentralised) agencies’ and the ‘external autonomous (or decentralised) agencies’. This is also the distinction we made in the first part of this paper. The fourth circle is the most difficult one because of its heterogeneity. This is the circle within which the hybrid organisations, the private not-for-profit with links to governments, the public profit, … are situated. Ultimately, it is the aim to engage these four circles in our research. Still some close criteria about where we will draw the border need to be developed. We engage these four circles because we hypothesize that the centre of policy implementation (and perhaps also policy making) has been shifted from circle 1 (core government) to circles 2 and 3 (internal and external autonomous agencies), but also for a large part to the semi-public ‘grey’ zone of circle 4. It is these shifts that we want to detect as part of the research project (by doing longitudinal research). Conceptualisation of ‘agencification’ Administrative decentralisation (or ‘agencification’) is a trajectory within a scenario of public sector reform or modernisation. This means that the incentives for this decentralisation must lay somewhere in the desire of policy-makers to progress to a new, desired public sector organisation and/or in the distrust of the previous or existing public sector organisation. Agencification is a phenomenon that has been seen in all of the OECD countries but also in developing countries and in former Eastern European countries (Talbot, Caulfield, 2001, Beblavy, 2002). Some authors speak about an ‘apparent global convergence on the agency form’ (Pollitt et al., 2001). The agency form has become popular for executing a varied range of state functions in a large number of countries. For example in the UK (next steps agencies and non departmental public bodies), New Zealand (Crown Entities), Japan (Independent Administrative Corporations) and Jamaica (Executive Agency Programme) one went over to agencification (Smullen et al., 2001). However, despite the fact that there often is argued that one is ‘converging’ towards the agency-form all over the world, what is also the truth to a certain extent, one should recognize that the agency-form maybe is not that homogenous as one sometimes might think. It can be argued that although the numerous similarities among these organisations being created all over the world, there is also a great deal of variation among these organisations (Bouckaert and Peters, 2001). The variation occurs along a number of dimensions: (1) governance structure and the relation with ministerial authorities, (2) degree of autonomy these organisations have, (3) the variety of tasks these organisations have. Also the sometimes prevailing assumptions of homogeneity and convergence have to some extent reduced the development of analysis of and theory about the structural changes occurring in the public sector. These numerous changes have produced a need to ask a wide variety of questions about the number, variety and characteristics of the agencies. These questions (amongst others) point out very clearly the need for a structural research agenda on Koen Verhoest & Bram Verschuere (Public Management Institute – KU Leuven) 4 “Agencification”: pending questions and how to address them agencification. Hence we need to find a way to conceptualise and to operationalize the concept and relevant dimensions of the process of agencification in order to be able to answer our research questions. If we want to be able to solve these questions, we need to detect the main variables, conceptualise them and also make them measurable. How did we detect these variables? This was a matter of both a bottom-up and a top-down process. Prof. Bouckaert, prof. Peters, Koen Verhoest and Bram Verschuere had a brainstorm on what the most important aspects of the process of agencification are. Next to that we reviewed the literature in order to find the variables that are of importance for answering our questions. Ultimately we came up with five clusters of possible variables that constitute the process of agencification: (1) organisational identity (ORGID), (2) organisational autonomy (ORGAUT), (3) organisational steering and control (ORGSTC), (4) organisational culture (ORGCUL) and (5) organisational performance (ORGEP). These five items seem relevant if we put them next to some existing research on agencification. Wolf (1993) did a case survey in order to test some theories on their predictive value for explaining effectiveness of agencies. He used the case survey method to aggregate the collective judgements of previous case study researchers regarding effectiveness and other key characteristics of US cabinet agencies. He selected 14 independent variables on two criteria: to be crucial to one or more schools of thought2 on effectiveness and disagreement among theories as to their likely effect. These variables3 can all be placed under one of the five items we defined above and according to the theory they are linked at, they can have a positive or negative effect on the effectiveness of agencies: ORGID: age, government monopoly on mission, resources targeted on critical task, difficulty of agency mission, controversial mission, hierarchical structure ORGAUT: political autonomy, delegation of operational decision making authority ORGSTC: Formalization ORGCUL: leadership skills, identification with agency, sense of mission, adaptability ORGEP is the dependent variable here. Bouckaert and Verhoest (1997) did a similar exercise. They looked at what some theories say about conditions (independent variables) for an effective decentralisation. They grouped the conditions in three clusters: (1) features of activities (e.g. homogeneity of activities, asset specificity, …) which can be seen as having links with what we call ORGID, (2) accompanying provisions (e.g. performance agreement, output-related financing, …) which can be seen as having links with what we call ORGSTC and (3) conditions (e.g. market type mechanisms, borrowing capacity, internal management change, …) which can be seen as having links with what we call ORGAUT. No conditions were found that can be linked to ORGCUL. A last research project we will look at in the light of our conceptualisation of the notion of agencification is Van Thiel (2000). She did her doctoral dissertation on trends, causes and consequences of quangocratization (yet another terminology in the field of administrative and functional decentralization). She hypothesed4 on expected effects on the efficiency and effectiveness of policy implementation by quangos (her terminology). There were 7 variables detected, their hypothesized effect will be mentioned as well5: 2 He looked at 8 schools of thought: agency life cycle, leadership theory, Weberian institutionalism, professionalism, Wilson bureaucracy theory, economic responsibility, population ecology and political theory of the firm. He also added a non-theory that argues that luck is the best explanation for effectiveness. 3 The variable ‘presidential support’ is not in the list here, because we don’t know under which item it should be placed. 4 We will not go into the results here. 5 She also mentioned the notion of a performance paradox. This is a weak correlation between reported and actual performance. The seven variables, and four more (diversity of performance indicators, clear policy objectives, emphasis on efficiency and supervision) also influence the occurrence of such a paradox. Koen Verhoest & Bram Verschuere (Public Management Institute – KU Leuven) 5 “Agencification”: pending questions and how to address them 3 of them seem to have links with our ORGID cluster: • Competition (+); operationalised in the market position of the organisation, the allowance to engage in commercial activities, … • Corporatism (+); operationalised in the presence of interest groups in the boards of the organisations. • Size (-); operationalised in i.a. the size of the budget, the number of personnel, … 1 might have links with ORGAUT: • Ownership production rights (+); operationalised in i.a. the right to retain surpluses, ways of financing, determination of tariffs, the right of the minister to intervene. 1 seems to have links with ORGSTC: • Accountability requirements (+); operationalised in the number of accountability requirements 2 might have links with our ORGCUL cluster: • Closeness to politiciansn (+); operationalised in i.a. loyalty, commitment to politicians, intensity of contact between organization and department, • Risk perception (+); operationalised in the way of dealing with responsibilities and changes As one can see, our five clusters seem relevant to study the field of agencification, at least with regard to what we learned out of previous research. Therefore we will take a closer look at these five clusters and try to refine them and make them operational and measurable. Aspects of decentralisation Autonomy (ORGAUT) Together with ‘steering and control’, autonomy is the constituent element of agencification par excellence (Verhoest, 2002). There is little systematic work in the literature about the concept of autonomy. It is also often treated as a unidimensional concept, what is not totally correct we will argue. It is indeed a multidimensional concept; autonomy can be operational or strategic, and autonomy can be in relation to policy matters or management affairs (Verhoest, 2002, Bouckaert and Peters, 2001). First we have policy autonomy. This is the freedom to decide on content and/or results of the primary policy process. If an organisation has a low level of policy autonomy, this means that the oversight authority has the decision right on activities, conduct, policy instruments, outputs, outcomes and effects. Operational policy autonomy is about the set of activities and procedures in the primary process. Strategic policy autonomy is about the choice of policy instruments and outputs, the goals and effects. It is worth noting that it is possible that strategic policy autonomy can be combined with no operational policy autonomy in a particular organisation. We refer here in the first place to Neelen (1993), who made a classification of alternative divisions of power of decision making between principal and agent. On the one hand, he looks at where the authority to make a specific decision lays: (A) is it the agent (agency) or is it (P) the principal (oversight authority)? Second, he looks at the level of involvement of the principal in the decision making process: (a) only slight involvement and thus a relatively independent agent, (c) a moderate involvement and consultation between principal and agent, (p) a strong involvement and heavy constraints on the agent. If you combine these two scales, you get six possible combinations with a decreasing autonomy for the agency: (A,a); (A,c); (A,p); (P,a); (P,c); and (P,p). Another author is Christensen (1999) who talks about dimensions of ‘bureaucratic’ autonomy. He distinguishes three dimensions; structural autonomy, financial autonomy and legal autonomy. It is mainly the notion of ‘legal autonomy’ that is new for us here. It is defined as ‘the authorization by law of the agency head to make decisions in his own capacity, thus forbidding ministerial intervention in his decisions as well as his consultation with the minister or the ministers advisers on decisions that, according to the law, are Koen Verhoest & Bram Verschuere (Public Management Institute – KU Leuven) 6 “Agencification”: pending questions and how to address them delegated to him’. Christensen developed a scale that goes from less to more autonomy: (1) legislation leaves no or little discretion to departmental minister, contains no authorization to issue general regulations, (2) legislation authorizes minister to issue general regulations to fulfil the policy goals defined by the law, the agency head’s autonomy is a matter of ministerial delegation, (3) legislation authorizes agency head to decide on individual cases that cannot be brought to the minister, the minister is cut off from general and specific intervention in case processing and (4) legislation authorizes agency to issue general regulation to fulfil policy goals that are defined by goals. We also have management autonomy. This is the freedom to the choice and application of inputs in the primary policy process. Operational management autonomy is about decisions on choice and application of individual inputs, strategic management autonomy is about decisions on general principles and rules with regard to a kind of input. However, we not only have to deal with the question what autonomy is, we also want to measure the level of autonomy that a certain organisation has. We first deal with how to measure management autonomy. We withdraw here two types of management autonomy; financial management autonomy and personnel management autonomy. For personnel management autonomy, both on the strategic and operational level, we look at autonomy concerning (1) payment and rewards, (2) evaluation of personnel, (3) career management and development and (4) the selection and recruitment of personnel. However a finer operationalization is needed, indications on the level of autonomy on these 4 dimensions can already give us an estimate on the personnel management autonomy of an organisation. For financial management autonomy, again both on the strategic and operational level, we look at autonomy on following matters: (1) cash management, (2) budgeting, (3) income management and (4) investments or participations in other legal persons. Again, with this primary operationalization, first indications on financial management autonomy can be found. The whole picture of our conceptualization and embryonic operationalisation can be found in the drawing underneath: PERAUT FINAUT Strategic Operational POLAUT Strategic payme nt evalua tion payme nt evalua tion carr man Sel, Rec carr man Sel, Rec Operational Legislative Cash man Inco Man Cash man Inco Man Budge t other leg pers Budge t other leg pers Decision M aking Figure 1: chart organisational autonomy Steering and control (ORGSTC) Organisational steering and control (from oversight authority to agency) is often seen as the other side of the autonomy – medal. It is not an easy task to deal with because steering and control involve a lot of considerations to make (Verhoest, 2002). First, how is steered? This is the question to the mechanisms of steering. Generally spoken, there is (1) the bureaucratic mechanism based on rules and standards, (2) the market mechanism, based on the price mechanism and (3) the social mechanism based on socialisation and involvement of members of the group (Ouchi, 1980). Second, what to steer? One can steer on outputs, outcomes or effects, on processes and procedures and on inputs. Third, when to steer? One can steer (1) ex-ante with a focus on planning and also inputs and (2) ex-post with a focus on evaluation and monitoring of results. Fourth, on the basis of what criteria should we steer? These criteria can be very diverse but when applied they tell something about what aspects of ‘organisational performance’ are central in the steering and control process. Examples of criteria are legality, economy, efficiency, effectiveness, responsiveness, democratic values, … Finally, who is steering? Steering and control can be internal or external, or, within the Koen Verhoest & Bram Verschuere (Public Management Institute – KU Leuven) 7 “Agencification”: pending questions and how to address them organisation or out of the organisation. So, in order to conceptualise and operationalize the concept of steering and control we have to deal with all these questions. We preferred to work out a scheme that deals with the most important aspects of steering and control and which is also workable and reader friendly at the same time. First, we looked at the ‘when to steer’ question. So we split up between ex-ante steering (also called input-steering) and ex-post steering (or result steering). One can see that while doing so, we immediately also involved the ‘what to steer’ question to some extent (steering on results or inputs). Ex-ante steering and control for example can look at nullification rights on decisions of the agent organisation for the principal, at resources that are provided to the organisation, at conformity of organisational decisions with the legal framework, at representation of the principal in the governing board of the organisation, … Ex-ante is to be seen here as a priori oversight of the decisions of the organisation. Ex-post steering or result steering and control lays the focus mainly on measuring, reporting and evaluation of organisational results. It also can be operationalised by looking at whether there are rewards and sanctions for the organisation in case of good or bad results. An important aspect of result steering has also to do with setting objectives and targets and accompanying indicators that can be monitored ex-post. At a more detailed level, we look at the nature of these targets and indicators and possibly also at where these targets and indicators are specified. In the same run we look at what criteria the ex-ante and the result steering aim (the ‘criteria of steering’ question). Second, we also looked at two more specific ways of steering and control: financial steering and control and steering and control by having influence on the management and policy making units of the organisation. Financial steering is conceptualised along the lines of the financial cycle: budgeting, accounting and auditing. For the budget, relevant questions can be: has the organisation an own budget? Who approves and designs the budget? What articles are in the budget? What the accounts are concerned, one can ask the question towards what accounting system the organisation uses; cash based for example. The audit system finally raises questions towards who is auditing and what are the audits aiming at; finances, performance, … Steering and control towards management and policy making units is conceptualised along the lines of how the management in a certain organisation is structured. If there is a governing board and/or an executive in the organisation, than the question towards (1) who appoints it, (2) who evaluates it, (3) the accountability of the members of these boards and executives towards the principal and the question towards (4) the composition of these boards and executives will be posed. For a visual presentation of how we look at steering and control see the drawing below: Way FINSTC RESSTC EXASTC Meas &Rep Rewa rd Board Crit Way Crit Obj & Tar Eval Source Nature budg et Indic Accou nting Indiv Coll Decis Audit Acco unt Exec Appoi nt Nature Source Form/Cont Nature MANSTC Who Decis Figure 2: chart organisational steering and control Other variables After having explored the organizational autonomy and the organizational steering and control as the two most important constituent elements of the agencification process, we also have to consider two other clusters of variables that might play a significant role in studying agencification processes. These are organisational identification and organisational culture. Koen Verhoest & Bram Verschuere (Public Management Institute – KU Leuven) 8 Eval Com pos “Agencification”: pending questions and how to address them Organizational identification (ORGID) The aim of this cluster of variables is to provide a general DNA structure of the organisation to study. It can be seen as a list of variables that identify the organisation, but it can also be regarded to as a list of apparent relevant variables that cannot be placed under the umbrella of any of the four other clusters of variables. As expected, a lot of variables can be detected here. We try to list them here and to also provide a means to operationalise them here. We will start with the more general items. First we have the country, the name, the governmental level (on which the organisation is active) and the age of the organisation (when is it established?). Second, we can look at the size of the organisation. According to Hood and Dunsire (1981), ‘size’ can be measured in two ways. One can look at the number of personnel that is active in the organisation (in total or in full time equivalents) or one can look at the size of the budget of the organization. Other variables on a more general level are; the name and the size of the parent organisation of the agency, the policy field on which the organisation is mainly active and whether the organisation has legal personality. If it has legal personality; the legal form of the organisation (this can be public law, private law, or a hybrid form). If no legal personality; has it got another affiliation (e.g. part of core ministry, independent within the core ministry, …). The legal formats for public organisations have also been classified by Bouckaert and Peters (2001) into: components of ministries, independent but within a ministry, legal entity within a ministry, a public law legal entity, a private law legal entity and sui generis organisations. Finally one can also look as to whether the organisation has a (governing) board. If we look a little further, there are yet more variables to detect. These variables, however, are situated at a more detailed level. The first two are more or less linked to the age – variable. One variable is looking at how the organisation has been established: was it newly created, was it a split from another organisation, was it a merger, … If it was a split or a merger, what are the antecedent organisations? The other variable is looking at what institution created or established the organisation: was it parliament, was it the government, was it a royal or presidential act? The next variables are linked to the policy field on which the organisation is active: first, what kind of activities does the organisation perform and second, what is the phase in the policy cycle that the organisation is mainly situated in for her main tasks? Bouckaert and Peters (2001) identified seven major classes of activities: implementation, direct service delivery, transfer of funds, regulation, advice and policy development, information, research, tribunals and public enquiries and representation. The following variables at this more detailed level are connected to the management structure of the organisation: what kind of board has the organisation got? Who is in this board? What are the competences of the board and its members? We can also look at the top executive branch of the organisation (e.g. CEO): what does it look like (single leading officer, more leading officers, a leading committee, …). There are also some possible variables that have not yet been discussed here but that also can be situated on a more detailed level of organisational identification. A first one is the budget of the organisation, or better the budget structure. Similar to what Dunleavy (1991) did, we can look at the budget structure of agencies. Dunleavy analysed the budget structure of an organisation and then classified the organisations in 5 categories of agencies. The elements of budget are: core budget, bureau budget, programme budget and super-programme budget. The relative weight of each of these elements within an agency’s global budget is a reflection of the budget structure which in turn indicates the function-based role the agency performs: delivery, regulation, contracts, control or transfer. We do more or less a similar exercise here, be it that we take a more concrete typology, we define our budget structure in terms of: investments, working resources, personnel cost and transfers. Another variable might be the income structure of an organisation or agency. Possible income sources can involve: budget allocation by oversight authority, transfers of other authorities, taxes and fees, gifts sponsoring and membership fees, market income (services and products), … The next variable looks at the competitive environment the organisation is situated in: is there competition for delivering the services anyway? If yes, is it a market with a lot of suppliers? How can the clients be typed? Are they public or private? Are it individuals or groups of individuals (organisations)? Another Koen Verhoest & Bram Verschuere (Public Management Institute – KU Leuven) 9 “Agencification”: pending questions and how to address them variable looks at the network in which the organisation is involved. Or, the level of integrated co-operation of the organisation with other organisations. This level depends upon some characteristics (Vanhoren and Struyven, 2000): (1) the degree of formalisation of the relationship, (2) the commonness of goals, structure and planning, (3) the commonness of resources and (4) the level of collective identity and responsibility. On the basis of these characteristics, it is possible to develop a scale of integrated co-operation. Networks and competitive markets can also, however they are situated here under the umbrella of organisational identity, be regarded to as ways of steering and control, be it steering and control by the environment in which the organisation is active. A last variable looks at the internal structure of the organisation and deals with the sub-units the organisation has: how many sub-units are there and what do they look like. The flood of ORGID variables is (attempted to) visualised underneath (for a more detailed chart of the cluster of organisational identification data see annex). ID ORG COUNTRY SIZE LEG FORM BUDGET GOVLEV PARENT ORG BOARD COMPETIT ION POLFIE EXECUTIV E NETWORK AGE SUBUNITS Figure 3: chart organisational identity Organizational culture (ORGCUL) Because many theories that try to explain the reasons for, the process, the content and the consequences (effects) of agencification use variables that are closely linked with organisational culture, it seems fruitful to integrate the concept of organizational culture in the research project (also cf. supra). For example concepts like “leadership” (Leadership theory), “formalization” (Weberian Institutionalism), “sense of mission” (Professionalism, Theory o/t Firm), “professionalism” and “mission valence” can have a (positive or negative) influence on the effectiveness of organizations (see also Rainey & Steinbauer, 1999). Therefore it might be useful to develop the concept and to look for ways to measure the concept of organizational culture. In the past, already some attempts in this direction were made. For example Kastelein (1977) and Tepeci (2001) aimed at constructing scales. Kastelein conceptualised organisational culture along six dimensions: participation, socio-economic expressivity, adaptiveness, external orientation and value orientation. Tepeci will be discussed infra. We should also mention Hofstede (1998). This author did work in differentiating (organizational) culture along four 6 variables (dimensions). These dimensions are: process versus results, people orientation versus task orientation, organisational identity versus professional identity, openness versus closeness, loose versus tight and normative versus pragmatic. All these authors have more or less developed measure instruments along these variables. These instruments generally have proven to be well working (by piloting, testing and using them). Now it is the question what measure-instrument and scale is best suited for our research project. Primary idea is that we should choose the instrument (or the combination of instruments) that reflects best the public sector values. Tepeci (2001) used the instrument of O’Reilly (OCP, Organizational Culture Profile), but he extended it with some more values Koen Verhoest & Bram Verschuere (Public Management Institute – KU Leuven) 10 “Agencification”: pending questions and how to address them that better reflect the values of the sector he studied; the restaurant sector. O’ Reilly initially had seven dimensions of organisational culture: innovation, stability, respect for people, outcome orientation, attention for detail, aggressiveness and team orientation. Tepeci also introduced “service quality and customer orientation”, “honesty and ethics” and “employee development and empowerment” (inter alia). These values seem at first sight also relevant for the public sector. Moreover, the OCP has been used with success for studying the public sector. Construct validity has been found in samples including government employees (Tepeci, 2001). Here we will take over the framework of Tepeci. He developed his HICP (hospitality industry culture profile) that includes 36 value items that are hypothesised to measure 9 organisational culture dimensions (see drawing underneath). ORGCUL People Orient Team Orient Fair Compensation Valuing Cust / Serv Quality Innovation Employee Development Attention to detail Honesty & value ethics Result Orient Supp Empl Resp indiv Team atmo Co-op cow Fin Reward Equit Pay Serv Qual Give C exp Innovation Risk taking training Prom within Detail Orie Att detail Honesty truthfulne Result Orien Task accomp Care Empl fairnes empl Collaborat Team Orien Fair Comp Hi Pay Perf Valuing Cu Rel Cust Will Exper Creativity Advanc Opp P&C Devel Accuracy Precise Integrity Keep Prom Focus job Hard work Figure 4: chart organisational culture The dependent variable Organizational performance (ORGEP) As it is the main aim of all governments all over the world and on whatever governmental level to deliver good policies, services and products, organisational effectiveness and performance is a crucial concept in studying public administration. Also in the rhetoric of public sector reform – where decentralisation and agencification are part of, cf. supra – the concept of performance is important. Given the importance of this concept as a standing fact, there still remains the question about how to measure it. As Brewer and Selden (2000) put it: ‘improving the performance of government agencies is a central concern of public administration, and speculation about the factors related to agency effectiveness is abundant in the literature and elsewhere … little effort has been made to verify these factors empirically. One reason is that organisational performance is a difficult concept to measure’. Why is it difficult to measure? First, there is disagreement about what elements of performance are the most important. Second, some elements of performance are preventive (e.g. a disaster averted). Third, and especially in the public sector, performance has also strong political implications (Brewer and Selden, 2000). So how do we have to measure this ‘dependent’ variable? Dependent, because ultimately we want to detect the factors that are causing more or less performance of organisations like agencies. Only after we defined and conceptualised the dependent variable, we can start looking after which factors explain which outcomes (Tavits, 2002). Hence we need an instrument that allows us to say what organisation is performing and to what extent. Tavits (2002) identified three research traditions that have different conceptualisations of government performance: (1) The public administration view on government performance that has a great emphasis on the use of criteria that are judged to capture the essence of effective governments. Organisations meeting most of the criteria are considered to have the capacity to be effective and high performing. As this approach is also highly output driven, performance is understood as the existence of clear objectives and measurement of outputs in relation to these objectives. Performance measurement in this sense is about the performance of a programme, organisation or an individual, not about the performance of the government as a whole. This is often cited as a critique of this approach because this approach cannot answer questions of Koen Verhoest & Bram Verschuere (Public Management Institute – KU Leuven) 11 “Agencification”: pending questions and how to address them general government performance on policy activism. Another fundamental critique towards this approach is the measurability of services and programmes; not everything can be quantified. A last critique is this that organisation centered performance measurement can create a false sense of security by only paying attention to intended effects (ex-ante determined objectives). Thus it might be possible that an individual organisation improves performance, but at the expense of others or the government as a whole. (2) A second research tradition says that public opinion is the best indicator of government performance because in this view the ultimate aim of government is to satisfy the citizens. Also this approach contains several problems: first, citizens might lose confidence for other reasons than policy quality. Second, satisfaction with the work of an institution depends on the relation between personal expectations and performance so if the expectations increase confidence might erode although the performance remained the same. Third, the public might be prejudiced or have a distorted view. Fourth, other factors might influence the citizens’ evaluations of government performance. (3) A third approach is the democratic performance view. The most famous work in this approach is considered to be Putnam’s ‘Making Democracy Work’. His dependent variable is ‘institutional performance’ and he uses a 12 indicator index. The indicators are grouped under three categories: policy process, policy innovation and policy implementation. Here also some critics can be formulated: first, mainly the quantity of government activity is measured rather than the quality. Second, most criteria look at government efforts, only three criteria look at policy processes. After this short overview of different approaches, we will focus briefly on the typology that was developed by Tavits (2002). She discerns two dimensions of government performance: (1) administrative efficiency, or the capacity to use limited resources and to implement policies formulated with desired results. (2) policy activism, or the capacity to be responsive or considerate to demands of the citizenry. A combination of these dimensions lead to a four fold typology of situations: high activism/high effectiveness (dynamic government), high activism/low effectiveness (populist government), low activism/high effectiveness (efficient government), low activism/low effectiveness (unreformed government). She tested her typology empirically on 35 USA large cities. Therefore she operationalised her two dimensions into: Administrative efficiency: financial management capacity, HRM capacity, capital management capacity, managing for results, responsiveness. Policy activism: expenditure on highways, economic development activism, expenditure on health, expenditure on community development, legislative innovation. Factor analysis tests showed that the 10 variables seem to contribute to the two different concepts of government performance; the variables cluster rather consistently around the two different concepts. So the hypothesized dimensionality of government performance seems rather convincingly proven. Another interesting work is that of Heffron (1989). She starts with the statement that ‘there are as many definitions of performance as there are definers. Also the existence of such a diversity of organisations within a sector (the public sector e.g.) inhibits the use of universal criteria to measure government performance’. The result of this is that there exist no universal criteria for measuring effectiveness and performance and that multiple criteria have been developed. Campbell (in Heffron) has identified 30 criteria that have been used as measures of organisational effectiveness. When criteria for public organisations are added, we get 35 criteria. The criteria are grouped by approach into five clusters: Goal approaches: achievement emphasis, productivity, efficiency, profit, quality, planning and goal setting, goal consensus, internalisation of goals, readiness. HR approaches: job satisfaction, motivation, morale, value of HR, training and development, absenteeism, turnover, accident rates, role and norm congruence Koen Verhoest & Bram Verschuere (Public Management Institute – KU Leuven) 12 “Agencification”: pending questions and how to address them Internal process approaches: control, conflict/cohesion, managerial interpersonal relation skills, managerial task skills, info management and control, participation and shared influence Systems approach: stability/maintenance, growth, flexibility/adaptation, utilization of environment, evaluations by external actors Political approach (particularly relevant to the public sector): responsiveness, accountability, representativity, constitutionality, adherence to democratic values. As effectiveness is a multi dimensional concept, the criteria do not necessarily correlate. Thus an organisation cannot be effective on all criteria. The measurement of effectiveness is also further complicated by two factors: (1) time dimension; what means that the time frame chosen for assessment is a critical factor; also the age of the organisation should be considered. (2) necessity for comparison; because effectiveness criteria tend to be relative rather than absolute. So, what approach are we likely to follow for our research purposes. First we need to consider the multi facets of effectiveness and performance. Second, we need indications for both overall government performance as well as for organisation specific performance. Third we want to consider also the two dimensions that have been detected by Tavits. Therefore we will rely on the framework off Heffron, but not without considering the remarks made above. We will not, however, take over all the criteria (35) but only a sample. We will also add some other indications for organisational effectiveness and performance: e.g. the use of instruments, techniques and/or tools that are applied in the organisation (EFQM, CAF, ISO, balanced score card, …). One and other is made visual in the map underneath. ORGEP goal perspective HR perspective Inter Proc Persp System Perspect motiv mana g stabil Public Sect Persp effic effec satisf cohes ion respo ns flexib qual Use of tools acco unt demo cr Figure 5: chart organisational effectiveness and performance As one can see the multi criteria approach is respected here (Heffron). The problem with not considering the general government performance when looking at organizational performance can – if criteria and variables can be operationalised more detailed yet – be solved by the criteria that are in the public sector perspective and the system perspective (e.g stability and democratic values). When looking at Tavits’ two dimensions, we can see that the administrative efficiency dimension can be linked to our goal perspective and our HRM perspective. The policy activism dimension can be linked – to some extent – to our flexibilitycriterium in the system perspective (if we equal flexibility or adaptability to e.g. meeting needs or societal pressure). However, this dimension seems a little bit underrepresented in our design as it is now, we have no clear criteria for measuring quantity. To finish, also here we need a clearer operationalisation of our criteria in order to measure the concept of organizational effectiveness and performance more detailed and accurate. Koen Verhoest & Bram Verschuere (Public Management Institute – KU Leuven) 13 “Agencification”: pending questions and how to address them Research questions and theoretical assumptions Dealing here with all the potential research questions we want to address would take us too far. Nevertheless we will try to cluster them in some general categories and also want to link them to some assumptions that have been made in existing theories so far. Generally spoken, our research interests focus on three types of questions: Descriptive; these are mainly organisational identity research questions. Applied; what are the conditions for an effective agencification? Explanatory; • What is the effect of agencification on effectiveness and performance (causal relations)? • Why do these effects happen (explanation of causal relations)? Examples of descriptive questions are: in what policy domains and sectors are agencies established? To what extent (numbers)? In what forms (organisational as well as judicial)? What do these agencies look like, do they have boards, if yes, who seats in this board? How autonomous are they? How are they steered? Examples of applied questions are: what is the optimal (judicial and organisational) form the agency, given all the contingent factors it is subject to, should have in order to be as well working as possible? Examples of explanatory questions are numerous. What is the effect of a certain kind of autonomy on the performance of the agency? What is the effect of departmental steering? To what extent do cultural and/or identification factors explain the success (or failure) of agencies? How and why do these factors affect the results of the organisations we study? Ronness (2001) argues that institutional analysis of organisational change (or reform) has to meet at least two requirements: Identifying structural features and institutional characteristics of the organisation, if possible at different points in time Clarifying whether and how these features and characteristics actually affect and are affected by actions and outcomes6. affect structural features actions institutional characteristics outcomes affect Figure 6 a) Structural features 6 As one will see further in the paper, our research intrests are rather on the effect of structural features and institutional characteristics on actions and outcomes than the other way around. Koen Verhoest & Bram Verschuere (Public Management Institute – KU Leuven) 14 “Agencification”: pending questions and how to address them What are the structural features of organisations like agencies? As we mentioned above, the two most important structural characteristics of agencies are their level of autonomy (ORGAUT) and the way they are steered and controlled (ORGSTC) by their oversight authority. In this sense, organisational change or reform can be regarded to as changing organisational autonomy and/or organisational steering and control. Other structural characteristics of an organisation can be found in their identity kit (ORGID). For example the existence of a board, its composition and competencies. Another example can be the fact whether the organisation has legal personality or not, or, what the main tasks are that the organisation has (both in the policy cycle and substantive). Structural features can also be regarded to as ‘institutional arrangements’, this is the set of arrangements that empower and/or constrain the organisation. The arrangements tell us something about the relation between the principal and the agent. This relation is according to Jensen and Meckling (1976) a contract under which the principal engages an agent to perform some services on their behalf which involves delegating some decision making authority to the agent. According to Jensen (1983), the principal has three steering arrangements at its disposal to make sure that the agent complies with the principals demands: bonding, monitoring and rewards. According to these steering arrangements, Jensen (1983) argues that organisational institutional arrangements can be described along this three part taxonomy: (a) the performance measurement and evaluation system (monitoring), (b) the reward and punishment system (rewards) and (c) the system for partioning and assigning decision rights in the organisation (bonding; contractual restricting of agent’s discretionary powers to decide). b) Institutional characteristics Steunenberg (2001) gives a review of the definitions of ‘institutions’ that are used in the literature. A first definition sees institutions as rules that structure a decision-making situation, common to what North (1990, in Steunenberg) says: ‘rules of the game in a society or, more formally, the humanly devised constraints that shape human interaction’. A second definition sees institutions as procedures for decision making. In this sense, institutions make a relation between individual options for action and social outcome. A third definition states that institutions become visible through the behaviour of actors, both at individual as well at group level. For example Rowe (1989, in Steunenberg): ‘institutions are identical to some or other facet of human action and belief. A social institution is nothing more than a particular way of acting and believing for some agents who are thus said to be members of, or participants in, that social institution’. Institutions can thus be defined in various ways. Ostrom (1986, in Steunenberg) argues that there is no agreement in social sciences about what institutions are. They consist of a broad range of social phenomena that have to do with rules, procedures and behaviour of actors. Another author is Scott. He argues that institutions consist of (a) normative, cognitive and regulative structures and activities that provide stability and meaning to social behaviour. Institutions are transported by (b) carriers; cultures, social structures and routines (Scott, 2001). According to this definition, Scott argues that institutions can be found at three kind of pillars; a regulative, a cognitive and a normative one: Pillar → Basis of compliance Regulative Expedience Normative Social obligation Basis of order Mechanisms Logic Indicators Regulative rules Coercive Instrumentality Rules, laws, sanctions Binding expectations Normative Appropriateness Certification, accreditation Basis of legitimacy Legally sanctioned Morally governed Cultural-Cognitive Taken for grantedness Shared understanding Constitutive schema Mimetic Orthodoxy Common beliefs, shared logic of action Comprehensible, recognizable, culturally supported Koen Verhoest & Bram Verschuere (Public Management Institute – KU Leuven) 15 “Agencification”: pending questions and how to address them The importance of this classification for our research is the fact that each pillar can be linked to aspects of organisational structure. It should be noted that organisational structures can affect behaviour, but structure itself can also be affected by behaviour. For example, in the regulative pillar the organisational structure can influence the actor’s assessment of costs and benefits of alternative actions for example. In the normative pillar, the organisational structure can influence the assessment of what is appropriate for an actor to do in a given situation. In the cultural-cognitive pillar the importance of the organisational structure depends on the extent to which it corresponds to what is common and also history can be important since prevailing ideas in the environment will affect some aspects of the organisation. Scott continues by stating that institutions are embedded in various types of carriers. Or, how do these institutions manifest themselves? He discerns four types of carriers: symbolic systems, relational systems, routines and artefacts and shows for each of these carriers how they can be manifested in accordance to three pillars of institutions: Pillar→ Carrier↓ symbolic systems relational systems routines artefacts Regulative Normative Cultural-Cognitive Rules, laws Values, expectations Categories, typifications, schema authority Structural isomorphism Governance systems, power systems Protocols, standard operating procedures Objects complying with mandated specifications Regimes, systems Jobs, roles, obedience to Scripts duty Objects meeting Objects possessing conventions, standards symbolic value Another author, Peters (2000), gives us four features of institutions that are relevant for research: Institutions are structural features of a society and/or policy. These structures can be formal or informal. In this sense an institution transcends individuals to involve groups of individuals in some sort of patterned interactions. Institutions are stable over time. Institutions affect individual behaviour, it must constrain (formally or informally) the behaviour of the members of the institution. There should be some sense of shared value and meaning among the members of the institution. Our main concern is now how to integrate ‘(characteristics of) institutions’ in the research design. Therefore we should keep in mind what Aspinwall and Schneider (2000) state: Institutions encompass both formal and informal structures that influence human (organisational, bv) behaviour. The effects of institutions on human (organisational, bv) behaviour can be constraining or empowering. Institutions can function as independent, intervening and dependent variables. From a more theoretical point of view, we take a look here, very briefly, at what the different strands of institutionalism tell us about the structure-agency problem, or the way how institutions affect behaviour and vice versa. We follow here the classification of Peters (2000): Rational choice institutionalism: behaviour is a function of preferences that are constrained by rules and incentives. Institutions are systems of rules and inducements to behaviour in which individuals attempt to maximize their utilities. Also in this strand, and more functionalist, institutions are seen as emerging to meet (social and Koen Verhoest & Bram Verschuere (Public Management Institute – KU Leuven) 16 “Agencification”: pending questions and how to address them economic) needs. A sub theory is the principal agent theory. One of the main problems here is to design structures to ensure that the agent fulfils the principal’s demands. Institutional design is thus an attempt to resolve the principal – agent problem (and thus behaviour). Also game theories face the compliance problem (compliance of the agent with the principal’s demands). Agents and principals participate in a game in which they both attempt to commit the other to complying with the terms of their bargain. So all players have exogenous preferences, constrained by institutions, that shape their behaviour and interactions. According to Aspinwall and Schneider (2000), rational choice institutionalism sees institutions as providing a context within which individual decisions are set. They are equilibrium theories that seek to explain characteristics of social outcomes on the basis of agent preferences and optimising behaviour and on the basis of institutional features. Institutions provide a set of formal rules and procedures, or informal practices that structure relationships. As institutions in this strand are not assumed to precede human action, rationalists see institutions merely as intervening rather than independent variables. Historical institutionalism: in this strand initial and earlier made choices, and the institutionalised commitments that grow out of them, determine subsequent decisions. Policies are thus path dependent. Individuals accept the constraints imposed by the institution because they know it and individual behaviour is shaped by the decisions made earlier. This strand goes also into the role ideas play in shaping behaviour. Intra-organisational ideas are sold to members of the organisation and these members accept it. Institutions are seen as having mainly an independent role and individuals and organizations are seen as rooted in particular contexts. In this strand institutions can be defined as ‘formal or informal procedures, routines, norms and conventions embedded in the organisational structure of the policy or political economy (Hall and Taylor, 1996). According to Hall and Taylor, there are four features that distinguish this strand from the other schools: • • • • broad conceptualisation of the relationship between institutions and behaviour emphasis on the asymmetries of power associated with the operation of institutions view of institutional development that emphasizes path dependency and unintended consequences concern to integrate institutional analysis with the contribution that other kind of factors, such as ideas, can make to political outcomes. Sociological institutionalism: Peters argues that this strand appears much stronger in explaining the process of creating and changing institutions than in explaining the effects of institutions (on behaviour e.g.). Exemplary here is DiMaggio and Powell (1991) notion of isomorphism, or a convergence of organisational structure in an organisational field. Nevertheless, Peters argues that the emphasis on the creation of ‘meaning’ (Meyer and Rowan, 1977) and the relevance of ‘values’ in this strand (see also March and Olsen, normative institutionalism) can be useful in counterbalancing the individual and utilitarian values of the rational choice strand. The emphasis is then on the manner in which individuals within organisations become habituated to accepting the norms and values that apply to their organisation. Hall and Taylor (1996) see three features that distinguish this strand from other neo-institutionalist schools: • Institutions are defined more broadly by not only including formal rules, procedures or norms, but also symbols, cognitive scripts and moral templates Koen Verhoest & Bram Verschuere (Public Management Institute – KU Leuven) 17 “Agencification”: pending questions and how to address them • • that provide the frames of meaning guiding action and behaviour. This implies that there is a challenge to the (widespread in political science) distinction between institutional explanations based on organisational structures and cultural explanations. Another implication is that this approach redefines culture into institutions. A distinctive understanding of the relationship between institutions and individual action. Institutions affect behaviour along a normative dimension (internalised role or function-based norms) but also a cognitive dimension (scripts, categories and models that help to interpret the world and other behaviour). So institutions not only affect individual’s strategic calculations, but also their most basic preferences and identity. The third distinction applies to the explanation of how institutional practices originate and change. The three institutionalisms described above are used by several authors to classify between institutionalisms. In the literature, they constitute the core of institutionalist thinking (see also Ronness, 2001, Premfors, 1998, Aspinwall and Schneider, 2000, Hall and Taylor, 1996). Peters goes on by introducing some other strands of institutionalism: Empirical institutionalism: the structure of government makes a difference in the way in which policies are processed. The main question is whether institutions do matter. For example the difference between presidential and parliamentary systems. Or the difference between majoritarian and consensual parliamentary systems (Lijphart). For this strand the behaviour is largely influenced and determined by the institutions. Normative institutionalism: emphasis on norms of institutions as means of understanding how they determine and shape behaviour. Exemplary for this strand is the notion of ‘logic of appropriateness’, introduced by March and Olsen. In addition there should be some ‘enforcement’, formal or informal pressures to conform. As a conclusion to the relation between institutions and (individual) behaviour, we repeat the main question how institutions shape behaviour. There are differences in the emphasis the various strands put on this relation. In broad terms, new institutionalists provide two kinds of responses to this question; the ‘calculus’ and ‘culture’ approach (Hall and Taylor, 1996). The calculus approach focuses on the aspects of behaviour that are instrumental and based on strategic action. One wants to maximize the attainment of a set of goals that are driven by an exogenous (to the institutions) preference set. According to the same approach, institutions affect behaviour by providing actors with greater or lesser degrees of certainty about the present and future behaviour of other actors. The key point is that institutions affect action by altering the expectations an actor has about the actions that others are likely to take in response to or simultaneously with his own action. In the cultural approach, behaviour is bounded by an individuals worldview. Without denying that behaviour is rational or purposive, the cultural approach emphasizes the extent to which one turns to established routines or familiar patterns of behaviour to attain their purposes. Institutions provide moral or cognitive templates for interpretation or action. An actor is seen as embedded within a world of institutions, composed of symbols, scripts and routines that provide filters for interpretation. Similar to the ‘calculus-culture’ distinction, some other dichotomies can be made (see Ronness, 2001): Hall and Taylor (1996) March (1994) Peters and Pierre (1998) Calculus Logic of consequence in decision making: how is a choice to be made among the alternatives in terms of the values of their consequences Calculations as sources of institutional change Culture Logic of appropriateness in decision making: what decision, as the person I am, in this organisation given this situation Values as sources of institutional change Koen Verhoest & Bram Verschuere (Public Management Institute – KU Leuven) 18 “Agencification”: pending questions and how to address them c) Actions Actions can be regarded to here as the behaviour of an organisation, or what does an organisation do and how does the organisation do it. Actions are concerned with the application of the organisational means and resources, such as personnel, money, infrastructure, … in order to do the organisations job. d) Outcomes Outcomes are the effects of organisational action. Action can be effective, this is when the desired outcome is (for a substantial part) realised or ineffective when the desired outcome has not been realised. Preliminary analytical framework. Institutions: - regulative - normative - cognitive Demand Institutional arrangements: - way of steering and control - level of autonomy Structural features: - organisational identity Processing of demand: - Logic of appropriateness / culture Action / behaviour Outcome - Logic of consequence / calculus Institutions: - regulative - normative - cognitive Organizational culture Figure 7: preliminary analytical framework The drawing has to be interpreted in the following way: The principal wants a public function to be performed by an agent. Therefore some institutional arrangements are made. These arrangements structure the relationship between principal (demander) and agent (performer). They are a set of rules and contractually specified arrangements that depict the structural constraints and freedoms the agent has for performing the tasks. They mainly apply to the level of autonomy of the agent and to the way the agent is steered and controlled. These can be operationalised in e.g. the management contract, the foundation law, the performance contract, the organisational budget etcetera. Next to that there are the structural features of an organisation (see Ronness). These features are for example task features, the structural organisation of the management of the organisation, the legal form, … The demand of the principal then is translated in the organisational black box: the agent, subject to the institutional arrangements and the structural features of the Koen Verhoest & Bram Verschuere (Public Management Institute – KU Leuven) 19 “Agencification”: pending questions and how to address them organisation, processes the demands into organisational action and/or organisational behaviour. The result of this organisational behaviour is the policy outcome. A remark has to be made to the processing. This can be – in general terms – happen according to the logic of appropriateness and / or to the logic of consequence (or culture and calculus). There are according to Scott the external institutions that can be regulative (rules, laws, regulations), normative (norms and values) and cognitive (beliefs, symbols, …). An example might help to make things more clear about this distinction. Take the red traffic light. How does this institution (the rule of the red traffic light) influences my behaviour? In a regulative sense, I do not drive through it because I know I will get sanctioned by the police (institution as a traffic law). In a normative sense, I stop because I know that driving through is not allowed and I might cause damage to other people who come from the other direction (institution as a socialised traffic norm). In a cognitive sense, I do not drive through because the light is red and not green; I’ve always been told that you only can drive when lights turn green (institution as a traffic symbol). There is also the notion of organisational culture. This culture affects and is affected by all the elements described above. It can be affected by the institutional arrangements, the structural features of the organisation and the extra organisational institutions. In turn, organisational culture can itself have an influence on the way the principal’s demands can be transmitted into outcomes and on the institutional arrangements. This drawing contains a lot of relations and hypotheses. Perhaps too much. We tried to be as exhaustive as possible to integrate institutional theory into our research topic, but we nevertheless need a more specified research demarcation. If we go back to our initial categories of research questions, we can see that this framework can be suitable for answering some explanatory and applied research questions. Our main interest lays in the ways organisational structure features and institutional arrangements of the organisation can contribute to the performance of organisations. Therefore we will specify the drawing with regard to this question. Actually this question can be sub-divided into more specific questions: • • • • • • To what extent and how do institutional arrangements contribute to the organisational performance? Here institutional arrangements (internal institutions) are the independent variable and organisational performance the ultimate dependent variable. Why do institutional arrangements contribute to or have an effect on the organisational performance? To what extent and how do other structural features contribute to the organisational performance? Here structural features of the organisation are the independent variable and organisational performance the ultimate dependent variable. Why do structural features contribute to or have an effect on the organisational performance? Do external institutions have an impact, and if yes how and to what extent, on the way the organisation behaves (translates the principal’s demands into action and ultimately outcome)? Here institutions are seen as having an impact on the way the organisation behaves. Organisation’s behaviour is dependent on the institutions of which it is subject to. Can institutional arrangements and structural features of the organisation modify the adverse effects of these institutions (and enforce the positive Koen Verhoest & Bram Verschuere (Public Management Institute – KU Leuven) 20 “Agencification”: pending questions and how to address them effects of the institutions) in order to make the organisation perform better? Here institutional arrangements and structural features are intervening variables in the relation between institution and organisational behaviour. This framework has links with and tries to work out further on some conclusions that Verhoest made in his doctoral dissertation (Verhoest, 2002): NPM like institutional arrangements (e.g. result control, financial incentives, competition) as motivator for organisational results: the agent organization is motivated to achieve better results and more performance (with regard to the principals demands and goals) by means of certain steering mechanisms and levels of autonomy (or institutional arrangements) under certain conditions and under certain restrictions. Legitimacy building as motivator: a second and more fundamental motivation to better results is the incentive of the agent to build up trust following from the necessity to strengthen the legitimacy of the organisation towards the political principals and clients in response to legitimacy threatening factors in the environment. Here the question arises (Verhoest, 2002) whether the principal can steer the agent in the desired way by generating and structuring such a legitimacy need. The institutional arrangements - where steering by the principal is a part of - is partially a function of the trust the principal has in the agent but also of other factors such as capacity to steer, the variance of goals, … An agent can build trust by principal or customer oriented strategies, but it can also be stimulated or inhibited by institutional, cultural and other conditions. Preliminary research design The question is here; how will we deal methodologically with the research questions we pose? As said earlier in this paper, we have both research questions that go into more descriptive aspects and research questions that go into more explanatory aspects of agencification processes. Next to that, we conceptualised our five constituent clusters of agencification, as can be seen in the charts, on both a general and a more detailed level. This is to say, some variables are rather general and can be detected easily for a lot of organisations, while other variables stand at a more detailed level and can only be detected by a more in-depth scrutiny of the research object (organisations). We think that on a first, general level of detail of variables, our research field (this is the number of organisations to study) should be as exhaustive as possible. For all these organisations, we must be able to detect some general information. This means that we will have to do this by the survey method because the number of organisations is that large. For the more detailed analysis, this is exploring the level 2 and perhaps also level 3 variables, we cannot involve all the organisations. Therefore we need to apply another research strategy, for example the (multiple) case study method. How do these research strategies correspond to our research questions, or what answers do we want to find by applying these techniques? Koen Verhoest & Bram Verschuere (Public Management Institute – KU Leuven) 21 “Agencification”: pending questions and how to address them Datagathering 1: SURVEY answer to descriptive research questions Hypothesis formulation hypothesis adjustments hypo test Datagathering 2: CASES Theory building and refining answer to explanatory research questions Figure 8: preliminary research design The survey method should allow us to answer the more descriptive research questions. E.g. in what context (policy field, legal forms) are agencies established, or what are the ways in which they seem to be steered? Yin (1994) prefers the survey method for questions of the ‘what’ type (or who, where, how many). It is the aim to collect as much as possible empirical data. Although survey research is not entirely devoid of theory, surveys tend to focus more on data then on theory (Denscombe, 2000). The survey data also should allow us to formulate hypotheses about agencification processes. In the survey data for example strong indications can emerge that the more autonomy an organisation has, the better performing it is. Also indications why organisations perform better or less could emerge out of the survey analysis. Off course also hypotheses can be derived from existing theories and other research on agencification. To be able to test these hypotheses, we will have to look closer to the more detailed (level 2 and 3) variables. Therefore we use the case study method. Results of these case studies can help us to refine, adjust, reject or accept the hypotheses we formulated. Ultimately this strategy should lead us to theory building or theory adjustment. This will also allow us to answer our explanatory and applied research questions. Yin (1994) argues that the case study approach has a distinctive advantage to other approaches when the research question is a ‘how’ or ‘why’ question asked about a contemporary set of events over which the investigator has little or no control. How, to what extent and why do institutional arrangements, structural features and external institutions affect organisational behaviour, action and outcome? This whole design, in the end, is an emerging one. We will use empirical data as a starting point and build hypotheses around it. However, this does not mean that we are not aware of theory, existing hypotheses and research. The research will be an ongoing process of testing the hypotheses, refine them and test them again in order to build and refine theory. This design looks an ambitious one, however, there are still some questions about it that need to be cleared out. First, but already addressed supra, what organisations do we involve in the survey? Second, what cases do we have to study? We can think of individual organisations, but also of policy fields, or even countries. This question is linked to another question; can we distract general (generalizability) and valid conclusions out of case studies? This question is particularly relevant with regard to our explanatory research questions and even more with regard to our hypothesis adjustment and ultimately theory testing and building. Yin (1994) states that this critic is made when contrasting case studies to surveys. Survey samples generalise to a larger universe, but this is a statistical generalization. On the Koen Verhoest & Bram Verschuere (Public Management Institute – KU Leuven) 22 “Agencification”: pending questions and how to address them other hand, case studies rely on analytical generalizations. This means that the investigator strives at generalizing a particular set of results to a broader theory. However the generalization is not automatic. The theory should be tested through replication of the findings in a second or third case. When such a replication has been made, the findings might be accepted for a much larger number of cases even though further replications have not been performed. Denscombe (2000) makes a remark on this: although each case is in some respects unique, it is also a single example of a broader class of things. The extent to which findings from the case study can be generalized to other cases in the class depends on how far the case study example is similar to others of its type. References Aspinwall, M. and Schneider, G. (2000); Same menu, separate tables: the institutionalist turn in political science and the study of European integration. In: European Journal of Political Research, 38, pp. 1-36. Béblavy, M. (2002); Understanding the waves of agencification and the governance problems they have raised in Central and Eastern European countries. In: OECD Journal of Budgeting, 2 (1), pp. 121-139. Bouckaert, G. and Verhoest, K. (1999); A comparative perspective on decentralisation as a context for contracting in the public sector: practice and theory. In: La contractualisation dans le secteur public des pays industrialises depuis 1980, pp. 199-238. Bouckaert, G. and Peters, G. (2001); Autonomized public organisations: current research into agencies and quango’s. IRSPM 5, Barcelona. Brewer, G. and Selden, S. (2000); Why elephants gallop: assessing and predicting organisational performance in federal agencies. J-Part, (4), pp. 685-711. Christensen, J. (1999); Bureaucratic autonomy as a political asset. ECPR joint sessions, Mannheim, 25p. Denscombe, M. (2000); The good research guide for small scale social research projects. Open University Press, 248p. Dunleavy, P. (1991); Democracy, bureaucracy and public choice. London, HarvesterWheatleaf. Greve, C., Flinders, M. and Van Thiel, S. (1999); Quango’s: what’s in a name? In: Governance: an international journal of policy and administration, (12), pp. 129-146. Hall, P. and Taylor, R. (1996); Political science and the three institutionalisms. In: Political Studies, XLIV, pp. 936-957. Heffron, F. (1989); Organisation theory and public organisations – the political connection. Hofstede, G. (1998); Organisatieculturen, allemaal anders denken – omgaan met cultuurverschillen. Contact, 352p. Hood, C. and Dunsire, A. (1981); Bureaumetrics. London, 312p. Jensen, M. and Meckling, W. (1976); Theory of the firm: managerial behaviour, agency costs and ownership structure. In: Journal of Financial Economics, 3, pp. 305360. Jensen, M. (1983); Organisation theory and methodology. In: The Accounting Review, 58, pp. 319-339. Kastelein, J. (1977); Management in de Rijksdienst. Universiteit Amsterdam-Instituut voor Bestuurskunde, 77p. March, J. (1994); A primer of decision making. How decisions happen. New York, Free Press, xp. Meyer, J. and Rowan, B. (1977); Institutionalized organisations: formal structure as myth and ceremony. In: AJS, 83, pp.340-363. Koen Verhoest & Bram Verschuere (Public Management Institute – KU Leuven) 23 “Agencification”: pending questions and how to address them Neelen, G. (1993); Principal – agent relationships in non-profit organizations, Universiteit Twente, 289p. Ouchi, W.G. (1980); Markets, bureaucracies and clans. In: Administrative Science Quarterly, (25), pp. 129-141. Peters, G. (2000); Institutional theory in political science, Continuum, London, xp. Peters, G. and Pierre, J. (1998); Institutions and time: problems of conceptualisation and explanation. In: J-Part, 8, pp. 565-583. Pollit, C., Bathgate, K., Caulfield, J., Smullen, A. and Talbot, C. (2001); Agency fever? Analysis of an international policy fashion. In: Journal of Comparative Policy Analysis: research and practice, (3), pp.271-290. Powell, W. and DiMaggio, P. (1991); the new institutionalism in organisational analysis, University of Chicago Press, Chicago, 478p. Premfors, R. (1998); Reshaping the democratic state: Swedish experiences in a comparative perspective. In: Public Administration, 76, pp. 141-159. Rainey, G. and Steinbauer, P. (1999); Galloping elephants: developing elements of a theory of effective government organisations. J-Part, (9), 32p. Ronness, P. (2001); Historical explanations, structural features and institutional characteristics. Paper presented at 17th EGOS colloquium, Lyon, France, July, 20p. Scott, W. (2001); Institutions and Organisations. Foundations for Organisational Science, Sage, London, 255 p. Smullen, A, Van Thiel, S. and Pollitt, C. (2001); Agentschappen en de verzelfstandigingsparadox. B&M, 4 (28), pp.190-201. Steunenberg, B. (2001); Institutionele verandering – naar een bestuurskunde bewegend tussen ‘vloeibare’ en ‘gestolde’ voorkeuren. Coutinho, Bussum, 95p. Talbot, C. and Caulfield, J. (eds.) (2001); Hard agencies in soft states? A study of agency creation programmes in Jamaica, Latvia and Tanzania, University of Glamorgan. Tavits, M. (2002); Measuring the dependent variable: government performance. University of Pittsburgh. (not published paper). Tepeci, M. (2001); Diss.Doc. Pennsylvania State University. Vanhoren, I. and Struyven, L. (2000); Trajectbegeleiding en consortiumwerking: keurslijf of catalysator. HIVA, 68p. Van Thiel, S. (2000); Quango’s: trends, causes and consequences. Interuniversity Center for Social Science Theory and Methodology, 251p. Verhoest, K. (2002); Resultaatgericht verzelfstandigen. Een analyse vanuit een verruimd principaal agent perspectief. Diss.Doc, 353p. Wolf, P. (1993); A case survey of bureaucratic effectiveness in US cabinet agencies: preliminary results. J-Part, (3), pp.161-181. Yin, R. (1994); Case study research. Design and methods. Sage, 171p. Annexes Legend figure 1 - POLAUT : policy autonomy - PERAUT : personnel management autonomy - FINAUT : financial management autonomy - Carr man: carreer management - Sel, rec: selection and recruitment - Inco man: income management - Other leg pers: investing and participating in other legal persons. Legend figure 2 - EXASTC: ex ante steering and control - RESSTC: steering and control on results - FINSTC: financial steering and control - MANSTC: steering and control on managerial affairs - Way: way of steering and control - Crit: criteria on which to steer and control - Meas&Rep: measurement and reporting - Eval: evaluation - Obj&Tar: objectives and targets (of policy) Koen Verhoest & Bram Verschuere (Public Management Institute – KU Leuven) 24 “Agencification”: pending questions and how to address them - Indic: indicators - Decis: decision on - Form/Cont: form and content of - Exec: executive management - Account: accountability of - Appoint: appointment of - Compos: composition of Legend figure 3 - GOVLEV: governmental level on which the organisation is active - PARENT ORG: parent (oversight) organisation of the organisation - POLFIE: policy field on which the organisation is active - LEGFORM: legal form or affiliation of the organisation Legend figure 4 - People orient: people orientation - Supp Empl: supporting employees - Care Empl: care for employees - Resp indiv: respecting individuals rights - Fairness empl: fairness for employees - Team Orient: team orientation - Team atmo: team atmosphere - Collaborat: collaboration focus - Co-op Cow: co-operation among coworkers - Fin Reward: financial rewards - Fair Comp: fair compensation - Equit Pay: equitable pay - Hi Pay Perf: high pay for high performance - Serv Qual: focus on service quality - Valuing Cu: valuing customers - Give C exp: give customers what they expect - Rel Cust: focus on relation with customers - Will Exper: willingness to experiment - Advanc Opp: advancement opportunities for employees - Prom within: promotion from within - P&C Devel: personal and career development - Detail Orie: detail orientation - Att detail: attention for detail - Truthfulne: truthfulness - Keep Prom: keeping promises - Result Orien: result orientation - Task accomp: focus on task accomplishment Legend figure 5 - Effic: efficiency - Effec: effectiveness - Qual: quality - Motiv: motivation of employees - Satisf: satisfaction of employees - Manag: quality of management - Stabil: stability of the organization in the environment - Flexib: flexibility of the organization to meet new demands - Account: accountability towards citizen - Respons: responsiveness - Democr: democratic values Koen Verhoest & Bram Verschuere (Public Management Institute – KU Leuven) 25
© Copyright 2024