How to integrate the European Energy Markets: a new vision Abel M. Mateus1 Portuguese Competition Authority The European Commission has today adopted the Final Report of its competition inquiry into the gas and electricity markets… Its disappointing conclusion is that more than a decade after having launched the drive for liberalisation, we are still far from having a single, competitive and well-functioning European energy market. Nelly Kroes, Press Conference, Brussels, 10th January, 2007. Prepared for Fordham University Conference New York, September 2007 Version: August 27th, 2007 1 I would like to acknowledge the assistance of João Lopes. We also thank information and comments from numerous persons in different agencies. European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 1 1- Introduction Starting in the 1980s, reform of energy markets addressed four major areas: (i) privatization of the parts of the system that could be subject to competition; (ii) introduction of wholesale and retail market competition, allowing for new entry into generation and retail supply; (iii) restructuring through vertical unbundling of generation, transmission, distribution and retail supply activities, as well as horizontal splitting of generation and retail supply; and (iv) regulation of the monopoly segments by establishing an independent regulator, provision of third party network access and incentive regulation of transmission and distribution networks. After almost two decades of reform, a number of EU governments and the Commission as well as competition authorities are dissatisfied with the results achieved so far. The paper deals with some of the major problems that need to be addressed, and assesses the policies required to solve these problems. We cannot cover all the issues, and questions like security of supply, emissions policies and supply mix are not addressed here. We concentrate on four major issues: (i) ownership unbundling; (ii) cross border trade and interconnection; (iii) merger policies; and (iv) competition policy in a world of concentration of energy resources. We start by showing that the EU is still a despairingly and segmented set of energy markets, and that the level of integration achieved so far is quite low. Moreover, we also show two things. First, that the level of competition in energy markets is still low in most of the countries, since they do not even pass the most primary tests and it is also quite dispersed. And second, that competition matters for energy prices. An important study for the Commission has shown that the latest price increases have sometimes been exploited for increases in margins. We also point out an issue that would merit a separate paper, e.g. that energy policy is sometimes tainted by serious flaws in planning systems. There is a need to develop and apply more widely computable general equilibrium models that replicate the market, and project evaluation would benefit from more use of real options theory. Governments and the Commission establish targets and European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 2 supply mixes, defining targets for renewable energy, without an in-depth study of its impact in consumer welfare and the competitiveness of the economy, as well as without a study of the policy instruments required for supporting the decisions of economic agents. Another tenet of the paper is that ownership unbundling with careful regulation and enforcement of third party access is necessary for reform. We demonstrate the benefits for investment and competition with empirical evidence for the UK and Portugal. We also show how to solve coordination problems in practice. However, and contrary to a number of positions, we also argue that unbundling is not sufficient. It is essential to create a competitive market in generation, which may require divestiture of assets, VPP caps on market power and other measures. Evidence in support of this position is provided from the UK, Portugal, the Nordic Market and the USA. The second pillar for creating an integrated market is to increase the level of interconnection. First, we show that this is no substitute for creating national competitive markets, but it is important for market integration. Second, our position is that there should be better regulation of interconnectors, and that the amount of required capacity needs to be addressed by economic modelling and not by a single rule that “fits all”. There are quite a number of strategic issues involved. An efficient incentives network based system could also provide a market solution for the problem. Third, a minimum harmonization across national regulations has to be carried out and the issue of an EUwide regulator should be addressed. Another important area of concern is the present merger policy at national and Community level. First, we start by dismissing the theory of national champions in the area of energy that seems to be gaining popularity in recent times. But we also dismiss the theory of European-wide champions. We also show that the present rule of 2/3 needs to be qualified, and that there is a need for harmonization of merger policy across the EU, largely as a result of the externalities across markets created by energy flows. Furthermore, there is European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 3 a problem of level-playing field in cross border mergers: state enterprises or state controlled undertakings can buy private enterprises in other countries, but these private enterprises cannot buy the former. Besides, there is a problem of governance and contestability in those cases. Finally, we also show that there is a need to improve merger analysis for national and cross-border cases due to the specific nature of electricity markets, to the definition of dominance, and to the shifting nature of those markets with interconnection and technological change. Finally, we show the importance of having a common external policy on energy trade by the European Union with our major trade partners, and especially in regard to energy. We defend that all bilateral deals between Member States and major producing countries, such as Russia or Algeria, should not be conducted in the absence of that common framework. The paper starts by identifying some major issues on integration of European Union energy markets. Section 3 discusses the problems and provides evidences on unbundling. Section 4 discusses the problems of cross-border trade. Section 5 discusses merger policies at national and community levels. Section 6 addresses competition policy in an environment of global concentration in natural resources, and section 7 concludes. There are also two Annexes on the UK and Portuguese experience2 in market liberalization and unbundling. 2- Issues in Integration of the European Union Energy Markets The EU electricity and gas markets are a despairingly association of almost closed national markets: substantial price differences persist among Member States and the problem has been aggravated with large increases in energy prices since 2003 (Figure 1). In the last five years there was hardly any progress in achieving a convergence process, demonstrating the 2 Annexes will be supplied upon request. European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 4 lack of integration of national markets. The European Commission Sector Inquiry3, carried out in 2005-06 identifies three major structural problems. Firstly, many energy markets are too highly concentrated, with dominant positions of incumbents prevailing in many markets. This has led incumbents to exploit their market power and raise prices, and to engage in various practices that make it harder for new entrants to compete. Secondly, many energy markets are characterised by a high degree of vertical integration. Bundling of network and supply activities allows incumbents to control the network and the supply market. They use them as strategic assets to exclude competition through discrimination. Moreover, in this case, there are too few incentives to invest in networks - a major obstacle to new entry and a threat to security of supply. Many of Europe's electricity interconnectors are chronically congested. The total amount of revenues collected by these Transmission System Operators (TSOs) between 2001 and 2005 was about 1.3 billion euros. However, only 250 million euros, e.g. less than 20% of these revenues, was invested back into increased capacity. There are insufficient tradable supplies on energy markets, e.g. they are illiquid. And long-term contracts contribute to locking-in the markets. Thirdly, there is an absence of cross-border integration and of cross-border competition. Incumbents largely keep to their traditional markets, and rarely enter other national markets as large scale competitors. The report reveals that the energy prices for commercial users vary significantly from Member State to Member State. These differences are not eroded through import competition. One of the reasons is that incumbents stick to their home markets. Different market designs between Member States contribute to the gloomy picture rendering it difficult to move energy from one point in Europe to another. Figure 1 3 European Commission, DG Competition report on Energy Sector Inquiry, January 2007 European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 5 Source: European Commission, DG Competition Report on Energy Sector Inquiry (2007). More recently, the London Economics (LE) price study4 has clearly revealed that the more concentrated wholesale markets are the higher the price-cost mark-up. More importantly, the LE study has shown the usefulness of a set of measures that characterize market power in electricity markets. Since electricity cannot be stored and generation must be balanced with demand at all time, the indispensability of power generation to meet demand gives a precise notion of how, in short-term markets, market power can be exercised. The more indispensable a specific generator is the higher its market power is. Thus, its market power depends on market conditions and can change dramatically across one trading day. Several institutions use a set of market indicators to characterize the level of competition, e.g. Oxera produces annually for the DTI a benchmark report about the degree of competition in the UK market, compared with other EU countries. Only countries that have third-party access to transmission regulated, and a certain degree of unbundling and supply-market opening, are considered. Then, batteries of indicators, aggregated in five sets 4 London Economics and Global Energy Decisions report to DG Competition, European Commission, Structure and Performance of Six European Wholesale Electricity Markets in 2003, 2004 and 2005, February 2007 European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 6 as indicated in Table 1, are considered for the electricity and gas markets. The results show three groups of countries in electricity: low level of competition (Ireland and Portugal), medium level (Spain, Italy, Austria and Germany) and high level of competition (Nordic countries), the UK having the highest score. The gas markets have systematically a lower level of competition, from Portugal that benefits from derogation to the UK, the only country scoring above 6. Table 1 7.2 2.0 3.3 4.4 8.7 5.7 1.5 5.7 7.8 0.0 10.0 10.0 10.0 10.0 0.0 Downstream supply 4.6 8.8 8.5 6.7 5.8 1.8 1.8 8.0 7.9 6.0 2.2 Score-all market areas 5.8 7.6 8.0 5.4 6.9 1.3 5.0 7.4 8.8 7.2 1.2 Score network area 10.0 10.0 10.0 10.0 10.0 10.0 10.0 10.0 10.0 8.0 8.0 Overall elctricity score 7.1 8.4 8.6 6.8 7.8 3.9 6.5 8.2 9.2 7.4 3.2 Germany Ireland Austria Ireland 3.9 10.0 Germany 5.8 10.0 UK Portugal 4.4 8.7 Sweden Netherlands 4.4 Wholesale Spain Italy Upstream market Denmark Finland Disaggregated scores for select EU electricity markets (preliminary 2005) 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 2.0 0.0 8.0 2.0 2.0 Wholesale 2.5 2.5 9.2 0.0 7.9 0.0 7.9 0.0 10.0 7.9 0.0 Downstream supply 3.8 1.8 0.0 5.4 3.2 0.0 2.3 0.7 4.9 0.4 2.3 Score-all market areas 2.1 1.4 3.0 1.8 3.7 0.0 4.0 0.2 7.5 3.4 1.4 Score network area 10.0 9.0 5.5 10.0 6.0 0.0 10.0 8.5 10.0 8.5 4.5 Overall elctricity score 4.5 3.7 3.8 4.3 4.4 0.0 5.8 2.7 8.3 4.9 2.3 UK Spain Sweden Portugal Netherlands Italy Upstream market Austria Finland Denmark Disaggregated scores or select EU gas markets (preliminary 2005) Source: Oxera. Energy market competition in the EU and G7: preliminary 2005 rankings. October 2006. Part of the price differences between the countries analysed in the LE study reflect the supply mix that may depend on the geographic characteristics of the country and most of the times on Government discretionary decisions (most follow a licensing scheme). The LE study has also identified market power as another major factor in price formation. In fact, entry in generation and retail supply has only to a limited extent eroded the incumbent’s market power inherited from the past monopolies framework. The study of LE was carried out for six MS: UK, France, Germany, Belgium, Spain and Netherlands. It used data from hourly observations and studied simulations and related European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 7 price to outcomes of output and marginal cost, and market structure for almost every generation unit in every hour for 2002-4.5 Besides estimating traditional measures of specific electricity market structure related to concentration, it calculated the PSI (Pivotal Supplier Index) that shows how “pivotal” is a firm to supply electricity at a given hour, and the RSI (Residual Supply Index) that shows how the market depends, on a continuous basis, on this company capacity to meet demand. In fact, in a tight market situation, even a small company can exert significant market power, and in an excess supply situation even a large company has to engage in a competitive game. The estimates show that France and Belgium are highly concentrated – only one company dominates the market most of the time; Germany, Spain and Netherlands have average levels – with two companies with significant market position 20 to 77 percent of the time; and the UK is moderately concentrated. Next, it calculated measures of market outcomes, like the Lerner Index and the Price-Cost Mark-up, estimating marginal costs based on the GED simulation model, used by the industry to compute the optimal market despatch. The highest margins are for France and the lowest for GB and Netherlands. The final step was to regress market outcomes to market structures. Figure 2 shows the plot of the data. The conclusion is that there is evidence of a high negative correlation between measures of concentration and margins. Moreover, it concludes that most of the price increases that occurred lately were not due to fuel costs but to exploitation of market power and environmental costs. Figure 2 5 Equivalent to 8 760 hours per year. European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 8 Source: London Economics, op. cit. Europe faces major challenges: (i) EU emissions may increase by 5 percent by 2030, rather than falling; (ii) EU energy import dependence will jump from 50 percent of today’s total energy consumption to 65 percent in 2030; and (iii) energy markets remain far from integrated markets. According to several policy statements by the European Commission, the “energy policy for a changing world” has a broad objective: “well functioning energy markets that ensure secure energy supplies at competitive prices as key to achieving growth and consumer welfare in the European Union”. There are three pillars: (1) building a true Internal Energy Market, which gives real choices for EU energy users, whether citizens or businesses, and that triggers the huge investments needed, in order to promote competitiveness, sustainability and security. To reach this aim it is necessary to achieve effective unbundling, to have an independent regulatory control, and to reach a certain minimum capacity in interconnection;6 (2) accelerating the shift to a low carbon energy, by cutting greenhouse gas emissions by 20 percent by 2020 through an expansion of renewables or expansion of 6 The Commission has set a 10 percent of total demand target. European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 9 nuclear power,7 and increasing energy research; and (3) increasing energy efficiency, by saving 20 percent of total primary energy consumption by 2020. These objectives would be complemented by an international energy policy: speaking with one voice, cooperating with the rest of the world on reducing emissions8 and developing effective solidarity mechanisms for solving any energy crisis. Despite the importance of these objectives of energy policy, we did not find a single estimate of the costs for the EU of reaching those targets. This paper concentrates on the first pillar, with a focus on competition issues. In fact, building an integrated energy market in the European Union requires: (i) confidence in the security of high quality supply involving adequate production capacity, security of primary fuel supply, and reliable and adequate networks; (ii) sustainable competitive outcomes, referring to ability of the sector to finance and deliver efficient and reliable energy, within a market mechanism that provides market signals for entry, that is efficient in location, timing, scale and fuel choice, with environmentally friendly processes, and at minimum costs to consumers; (iii) absence of market abuse and ability to mitigate market power; and (iv) credible regulation for efficient free entry and investment. According to Newbery9 and others, the preconditions for liberalising energy markets are: (i) guarantee a non-discriminatory and free third party access to entrants; (ii) total unbundling; (iii) adequate and secure supply involving an adequate and reliable network, enough production capacity and secure sourcing of primary fuels; (iv) sufficient competition; and (v) independent and appropriate regulation of monopoly segments. 7 At present nuclear represents 30 percent of EU electricity. 8 By strengthening the Energy Charter Treaty, review the post-Kyoto climate regime and extension of emissions trading to global partners. 9 Liberalizing Electricity Markets, Cambridge University, 2002. European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 10 Market integration means for most economists that European costs are minimized, trade takes place guided by comparative advantage, importing competition into more concentrated markets. To build an integrated EU market10 there are two important preconditions. The first is to build enough capacity in interconnectors in order to create a system of “connecting vases” such that flows of energy equilibrate the market and equalize the prices across the EU. Competition pressure arising from imports is then sufficient to discipline domestic incumbent’s behaviour. The second is to effectively reduce market concentration, either trough divestment or trough other remedies that reduce the possibility of incumbents to behave independently. However, less concentrated markets – and unbundling – also diminish the incentives to explore congestion bottlenecks by domestic players and therefore reduce the needed interconnection capacity in order to reduce the market power of incumbents. In the 2002 Barcelona European Council, EU Member-States agreed to increase minimum interconnection levels to 10% of domestic electricity production capacity. However, interconnection investment is lagging. The congestion rents are only to a limited extent used to invest in interconnection capacity expansion. Actually, as noted by the European Commission, only about 5% of total annual investment for electricity grids in the EU, Norway, Switzerland and Turkey was directed to increase interconnection capacity.11 Today a significant number of Member States have still not achieved the Barcelona target. 10 There is a difference in building a Single Market that presupposes similar prices throughout the EU, or an Integrated Market that refers to building a competitive market throughout the EU with enough interconnection. In the last case price differentials may persist because of different costs of production or transport. The paper concentrates on this last aim, which we think makes more economic sense. 11 European Commission, Communication from the Commission to the Council and the European Parliament, Priority Interconnection Plan, (2007) European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 11 The recent blackouts that occurred in Europe, like the Italian blackout of September 2003 and the German initiated blackout12 of November 4, 2006, also showed the need for a more intensified cooperation between TSOs and a minimum set of rules for managing the networks. Therefore, and following the Sector Inquiry conclusions, the European Commission, both in merger control and in anti-trust intervention, foresees the application of remedies in order to tackle the high concentration levels seen at the domestic level in most countries. These remedies range from large scale Virtual Power Plants (VPPs)13 to structural measures as divestitures.1415 Europe is not the only place were reform is taking place. There have been several energy reform policies throughout the world. There is a consensus that some of the most successful involve countries/regions of UK, Nordic countries, New Zealand, Victoria and South Australia, New York, Texas, PJM, Chile, and Argentina.16 In almost all cases ownership unbundling has played an important role. Let us state at the outset that there is still a need to inject better economic methodologies in project evaluation and in system planning. The field is still largely dominated by engineers and physicists. All the scenarios that have been published by the European Union, available in the site of the Commission, do not report the costs of those policies for the different economic agents (households, enterprises, electricity generators, etc.) and the instruments necessary to induce their behaviour in a market economy.17 12 Started within the E.On network and was caused by a boat reaping a power cable. In practice VPPs are not very effective because the power of the incumbent to accumulate reserve power and its need in the balancing system. 14 Another measure proposed by the Spanish Libro Blanco is to limit the market share of the large producers by time of the day. 15 The Spanish White Paper proposed the following measures to limit market power of Endesa and Iberdrola: plant divestiture, VPPs (following the Fench and Dutch experiences), and long-term contracts where both price and quantity are set by the regulator. The report is published as Libro Blanco, dated 30 June 2005 at http://www2.mityc.es/es-ES/index.htm?cultura=es-ES 16 For a description of each experience see Sioshansi and Pfaffenberger. 2006. 17 This problem does not seem to affect the DoE model. 13 European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 12 In some EU countries, governments intervene and substitute to the market in choosing the supply mix. And most of times they do not even have enough studies for justifying their decision, introducing heavy distortions and raising consumer prices. Naturally, governments should intervene in correcting externalities, like making the polluter pay the social cost. But they should intervene by distorting as less as possible the market mechanism. E.g. there is still no basic approach to the incentives for renewables in the EU. Several governments give a guarantee to the tariff18 and priority of access for wind power. However, in the US, the government gives a tax credit that is much less distorting.19 1- Vertical unbundling: solution or false start? What is unbundling? Electricity supply consists of four distinct activities: generation, high-tension transmission, lower voltage local distribution, and supply – contracting for and billing final consumers. In most countries generation accounts, on average,20 for about 65-70 percent of industry costs; transmission for 10-12 percent; distribution for 20 percent; and supply for the remaining 5-7 percent. Transmission and distribution (the “wires businesses”) are natural monopolies that require regulation. The first requires a national grid to transport energy from the production points to feed the local markets, but also requires balancing the network, a characteristic of electricity systems. Regional distribution networks are fed by the national grid and transport the energy to consumer homes or business sites. Generation and supply are potentially competitive. What is a liberalized and competitive electricity supply industry? It is a market(s) into which generators sell and from which final consumers and traders can buy, a transmission and distribution system that balances continuously the system and acts as a common carrier, with freedom of entry in generation 18 In Portugal the government guarantees an 8 percent rate of return on investment. And also a loan guarantee in some cases. 20 Although for households the part of distribution is higher than for an industrial large consumer. 19 European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 13 (subject to balancing and congestion in transmission) and freedom for final consumers to choose from whom to contract for supply. In countries that have gone through a process of liberalisation, it is recognized that incumbents have usually a large set of contracts with the national grid (e.g. rights of priority in transmission) that undermine competition and makes it difficult third party access. Thus, there is a need for a Network Code in order to level the playing field and establish good governance. In the case of gas markets, unbundling means separating the high-pressure network from the service of importing or taking gas from producer sources to supply customers. Competition in source intakes means that there should be enough players importing gas through an international pipeline or LNG plants. Storage facilities are also important parts of the network, for balancing in the short- and medium-term the market. Since they can be used as “essential facilities”, like points of intake of the gas for the country, its access should be regulated and there should be enough competitive capacity to prevent market foreclosure. Finally, market liberalization requires that there are enough suppliers to buy gas from “producers” and sell it to customers. The high pressure network constitutes a national monopoly and local distribution systems are regional monopolies. If there are few “points of entry” for gas and storage they should also be regulated. Competition occurs then between “producers” or in-takers and suppliers. After analyzing the present EU situation, we will look at the costs and benefits of unbundling and will support those with theoretical and empirical evidence. In the fourth section, we will survey briefly the status of the current policy debate. In the fifth section, we will discuss an alternative that is being proposed for the TSO, e.g. the Independent System Operator (ISO) model current in the USA.21 In the sixth section we will address the 21 As we will see below, the ISO being discussed in Europe is not the same as the one prevalent in the US. In the US is more like an extension arm of the regulator. European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 14 issue of public versus private ownership in the context of unbundling, with special reference to the Nordic situation, whereas in the final section we will discuss also briefly some legal issues. There has been a discussion if unbundling should also be applied to the regional distribution networks. In fact, the present EU directives also require legal and functional unbundling of the distribution network. Most of the present thinking in the EU considers that it is not justified to apply ownership unbundling to regional distribution networks, following the experience of the UK.22 The present EU situation The present second generation EU directives of electricity and gas23 impose minimum obligations on energy network operators with regard to legal and functional unbundling between transmission/distribution networks on the one hand and upstream (generation or production)/downstream (supply) functions on the other. The companies are obliged to: (i) create separate legal entities for network activities; (ii) separate executive management and decision-making; (iii) maintain separate accounts; and (iv) create information barriers between those activities (“chinese walls”). In addition, a regulated Third Party Access regime was introduced, and the creation of national regulators became mandatory. Network operators have to submit annual reports on the implementation of the compliance programmes to the regulatory authority. Finally, Regulations were introduced 22 This is the opinion of the Council of Regulators, expressed in several documents of the ERGEG. 23 Directive 2003/54/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 26 June 2003 concerning common rules for the internal market in electricity and repealing Directive 96/92/EC. (OJ L 176, p. 37-56), hereafter Electricity Directive. Directive 2003/55/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 26 June 2003 concerning common rules for the internal market in gas and repealing Directive 98/30/EC. (OJ L 176, p. 57-78), hereafter Gas Directive. European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 15 which allowed for the adoption of legally binding guidelines with the aim of facilitating cross border competition, and in particular interconnector activity.24 Among all the Member States less then ten have ownership separation of transmission25 from the incumbent for electricity and five for gas. In most of the cases, only a few years have passed thereof.26 Table 7 shows the status of unbundling vis-à-vis the present Directives. Source: European Commission27 24 Regulation (EC) No 1228/2003 of 26 June 2003 on conditions for access to the network for cross-border exchanges in electricity (OJ L 176, 15.7.2003, p. 1-10) and Regulation (EC) No 1775/2005 of 28 September 2005 on conditions for access to the natural gas transmission network (OJ L 289, 3.11.2005, p. 1-13) 25 UK (England and Wales), Netherlands, Sweden, Finland, Denmark, Spain, Portugal, Slovenia and Czech Republic for electricity; and Great Britain, Spain, Netherlands, Denmark and Romania for gas. 26 The situation of unbundling in the EU has been the object of a report for the Commission produced by Gómez-Acebo Pombo Abogados and Charles Russel, Unbundling of Electricity and Gas Transmission and Distribution System Operators, Final Report, December 1st, 2005 and updated in the Benchmarking reports. 27 European Commission, Commission Staff Working Document, Report on Progress in Creating the Internal Gas and Electricity Market, 2005 European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 16 Notwithstanding, the Energy Sector Inquiry demonstrated that legal and functional unbundling is not sufficient28. The same opinion has been expressed by the European Council of Regulators: “The ineffectiveness of the existing unbundling arrangements is a significant reason for the slow pace of market integration and the slow growth in cross border trade observed in EU electricity and gas markets. The “legal unbundling” regime … hasn’t worked. The rules were too vague and the implementation by Member States so far is patchy.” (ERGEG, Fact Sheet on Unbundling, May 2007). As noted by the European Commission, vertically integrated incumbents have incentives to discriminate new entrants. Investment incentives are also distorted. No incentives exist to develop the network in the overall interest of the market, namely for facilitating new entry or to rise import levels. It was also showed that there is considerable evidence that investment decisions of vertically integrated companies are biased to the needs of supply affiliates29. Also in the US, where unbundling had a legal basis, several court decisions against violation of anti-trust laws demonstrated the detrimental effects for competition of vertical integration. In the Otter Tail Power vs US, in 1973, the US Supreme Court ruled against the behaviour of a vertically integrated utility, which refused, through its transmission affiliate, to source cheaper electricity supplies. This case lead to a significant debate over the competition benefits of vertical de-integration of electricity utilities. More recently, FERC (Federal) Order 2000 was designed to resolve what it “perceived to be problems created by the balkanized control of transmission networks and alleged discriminatory 28 See the summary conclusions in Lowe, Pucinskaite, Webster and Lindberg. Effective unbundling of energy transmission networks: lessons from the Energy Sector Inquiry. Competition Policy Newsletter. Sping 2007, p. 23-34. 29 European Commission, Communication from the Commission to the Council and The European Parliament, Prospects for the internal gas and electricity market, January 2007 European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 17 practices of generators and energy traders seeking to use the transmission networks of vertically integrated firms”.30 Benefits and Costs of unbundling: theoretical and empirical evidence What criteria should we use to judge the importance of unbundling? The criteria used to sort out models should: (i) prevent discrimination in access; (ii) optimize use of infrastructure; (iii) incentivize economic investment; and (iv) enable effective regulatory oversight of monopolistic activities. More importantly, the main question to be analysed is to what extent full ownership unbundling leads to the loss of efficiencies, namely in what concerns the coordination of short run operation of the electricity system, long term planning, the quality of service, and grid losses. Since ownership unbundling has been established in a few countries for some time, it is important to analyse those national experiences. In this subsection, and after enunciating the major problems, we will address four major issues raised by a cost-benefit analysis: (i) impact on competition and potential for discrimination; (ii) transaction costs arising from short-run coordination problems; (iii) incentives and coordination of investments and cost of capital; and finally (iv) double marginalisation. What are the problems? The relative merits of these two approaches – bundling versus unbundling – depend on several factors, including the following: (i) the degree of common expertise required to operate in both activities; (ii) the size of the transaction costs, and in particular the difficulty in writing contracts; (iii) effect on incentive properties; (iv) effect on risk allocation; (v) 30 Joskow, Paul L., Transmission policy in the United States, Utilities Policy 13 (2005) 95-115. European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 18 effect on control over performance; and (vi) issues related to uncertainty.31 In fact, one of the main benefits of vertical integration—i.e. the protection of a specific investment against ex-post opportunistic behaviour and against market risks—can be replicated by long-term contracts. However, vertical integration can offer benefits relative to the use of contracts in several situations, as a result of transactions costs or information asymmetry. In some industries, including the electricity and rail industries, vertical unbundling has been undertaken, and coordination has effectively been reproduced through contracts rather than through ownership, and, in general, evidence has shown that transaction and coordination costs of an unbundled system are much lower than the deadweight loss of having a vertically bundled system. First, generation costs are almost five times higher than transmission and transportation costs in electricity and gas markets. Thus, a distortion in the generation market is much higher than in the national grid system. Second, the transmission system can be effectively used to foreclose market entry reverberating higher producer costs throughout the system and up to the final consumer. The remainder of this section will review the arguments for and against unbundling, and contrasting the evidence from theoretical models and empirical studies. The Council of Regulators and Pollitt do the same exercise. According to Pollitt there is a clear advantage for unbundling in terms of (i) impact on competition; (ii) ease and effectiveness of regulation; (iii) facilitation of privatisation; (iv) security of supply; and (v) specialization and focus of management. A negative net effect may come from transaction costs. He also considers that there is a reduced risk of arbitrary government intervention. Impact on competition and potential for discrimination 31 There is an extensive literature on vertical integration. For an excellent recent survey see Joskow, Paul. Vertical Integration, mimeo. Handbook of Industrial Organization, vol.3, North-Holland, forthcoming European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 19 According to a detailed study just published by the ERGEG32, possibility for discrimination is high in both electricity and gas grids, in the following decisions of the TSO/ISO: (i) access principles object of the grid code (access and financial rights, including connection of producers and costumers to the grid and sub-grids); (ii) market principles, including balancing market, intra-day market, provision of energy losses, day-ahead forecast, data exchange, metering and billing; (iii) security principles, including N-1 principle, monitoring, coordination, restoration, black start capability, load shedding, islanding, etc., as well as forecast of demand for winter in gas; (iv) schedule management: technical and financial organization to match physical delivery; (v) investment planning: long-term forecasts of supply and demand, investment planning, benefit-cost analysis of each investment project; dedicated transport network and extensions; (vi) procurement of balancing energy (flexibility): market model to procure energy for ancillary services (auction, merit order); (vii) transparency: necessary information to the market; (viii) capacity calculation (optimization over the all grid); (ix) capacity allocation through a market mechanism (coupling, auctioning, open season and contract); (x) congestion management; (xi) tariff methodology using methods like fair return on investment, benchmarking, allocation of costs to specific consumers, definition of deep and shallow connection charges, definition of entry and exit points and allocation of costs to these points; and (xii) maintenance scheduling. Another important instrument for discrimination used by vertically integrated incumbents is the use of their large supply mix in order to strategically manipulate entry into the network.33 32 33 Third Legislative Package … The Spanish case is an interesting one. Endesa and Iberdrola, the two major electricity producers are able to jointly dominate the market because they have complementary supply mixes. European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 20 On the empirical front, Lowe et al. cite several cases of discrimination that support the assertion that integrated firms not only have the potential for but they do discriminate against third party access. For example, top management of the supply branch, which are represented at the parent level, often have access to strategic business information of the transport company, either directly or as a result of their representation in the Supervisory or Administrative Board of the latter, and they often receive insights about activities of competitors. Network operators may inform the vertically integrated supply branch when a customer is considering switching supplier, and they do provide more detailed information on loads, outages, generation to their affiliate so they can better optimize their trading and production portfolio. The case of Portugal (Annex II) demonstrates that unbundling with a single supplier or with a high generation concentration does not allow a significant impact on consumer prices, since generation costs are dominant, and competition does not take place on any element of the chain. There might be a positive impact from cross-border trade, but the incumbent usually has the capability to congest the interconnector. On the other hand, if the case in point is a large country next to a small one, opening the border will allow the large country incumbent to exert pressure on the prices of the smaller country. The Commission gathered information during its Sector Inquiry that one TSO grants its affiliated supply company rebates for the transportation fees as compared to competitors. In another instance the supply company of an integrated gas company could nominate their capacity directly to the network’s dispatching centre while third parties with shortterm interruptible contracts still had to nominate their capacities in advance. European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 21 Econometric work has also confirmed the importance of unbundling for competition. According to a study by Copenhagen Economics,34 using data for 1990-2003, electricity prices across the EU were lower with higher levels of unbundling. On the theoretical front, Joskow and Tirole analyse the relationship between transmission rights ownership and market power and show that vertical integration increases the ability of generators to exercise market power by withholding transmission capacity. Transaction costs arising from short-run coordination problems Once third party access is granted then there is little difference between the costs of transaction and costs of information for regulation for an integrated or unbundled system. The main issue is to require opening the network to competitors on an equal basis and information sharing. However, one has to consider the potential benefits that can arise from what is the opposite case of perfect vertical integration –e.g. the case of competition in generation and retail supply. Open access to the transmission network is strategic for a workable competition framework. Once the electricity industry is open to competition the coordination problem arises. Perfect coordination can only be upheld if no competition exists. Opening access to transmission networks, even in the context of vertical integration requires regulatory solutions in order to disentangle the coordination problems that arise with free entry. The benefits from competition at the generation and retail supply levels may pose negative externalities to the transmission activities, which need to be internalized. In fact, these coordination problems have been one of the main arguments against the full ownership unbundling. 34 Market Opening in Network Industries, Report to DG Internal Market. September 2005. European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 22 The previous section described the different codes that are part of the Network Code, and give detailed information about the different aspects that requires agreement between contracting parties and supervision by the regulator. Thus, most of the discussion of Pollitt35 and others seem displaced, and the conclusion that coordination costs are higher than the benefits that can be gained by competition are simply wrong. The question and the answer given do not address the right issue. A preferable approach is always to find a workable system of market indicators that are not prone for distortion. To what extent the coordination that existed in the monopoly framework could be replicated by correct economic signals has been one of the key problems for regulatory authorities. Designing these signals is difficult and, until now, no common approach has emerged. Economic signals can be part of the wholesale market design (e.g. Location Marginal Pricing) or be part of the network charges (discriminating Generation – G – and Load – L – charges according to the externalities created by generation and load in each grid location). Locational marginal prices induce investment in higher priced locations. On the contrary, locational G charges, induce location where the G charge is lower. Since there may be an inverse correlation between locational G charges and Locational Marginal Prices, these two models can achieve in theory the same results in what concerns location signals for new generation. These economic signals can be used for short term operation of the transmission system and also to guide investment decisions, considering both the expansion of transmission capacity and the location of new generation plants and electricity-intensive consuming industries. The empirical evidence for countries that are even starting the road of functional unbundling shows that quite an amount of information is required to facilitate third party access. In the UK writing the Network Code took several years and hundreds of pages. Incentives and coordination of investments; cost of capital 35 See Pollitt, op. cit.. European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 23 In the electricity industry, vertical integration, as in the former monopoly framework, had the merit of facilitate the coordination between investments in generation and transmission which are highly specific and highly interdependent36. As a matter of fact, in some cases (e.g. removal of grid bottlenecks), investments in generation or in transmission capacity can be regarded as substitutes. Therefore, within the vertical integrated firm, coordination meant the ability to choose the least cost solution. The optimality of investments under perfect coordination could also achieve a better planning of grid networks, minimizing the need for new lines – often prone to resistance from environmental organizations and local populations. However, the EU Sector Inquiry and other empirical evidence show that making transmission asset ownership separate from generation ownership improves incentives for market expansion and deepening. The willingness of integrated generation and transmission asset owning firms to propose socially beneficial investments in the transmission networks is quite low, since they may benefit competition and invite entry or sustain operation of competitors. This problem is also felt by ISOs that face the approval of the supply owner in order to carry out those investments. This was the experience of Chile and the position taken by the incumbent. The vertically integrated monopolist, provided that there is sufficient generation capacity to meet demand, has no incentives to replace obsolete power plants. The returns on generation investments were guaranteed by long term Power Purchase Agreements for the life time of the plants. The costs of poor generation investment choices – the investments done in the past and the investments that were not made given the more efficient technologies – were passed through the consumers. The main objective of central planning was to guarantee the adequacy of generation capacity. 36 Robert Michaels, Vertical Integration and the Restructuring of US Electricity Industry, Policy Analysis, CATO Institute, July 2006 European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 24 With competition, the incentives of generators are modified. To compete, it is necessary to search for the more efficient technologies – both in terms of expected demand and total costs (short and long term, including environmental costs). The entry of new generation swiftly puts aside the obsolete power plants. The entry decision is not conditioned to zero risk PPAs. Free entry37 38 and competition have contributed for improved operating efficiency of power plants, increased innovation, increased transfer of risks from consumers to generators and the ability of consumers to choose their suppliers. Transaction costs may be higher – since the problem of dispatching generation plants in the past could be internally solved by the vertically integrated firm, by constructing the cost merit order of power plants, and now is dealt with by the market through a price merit order – however they are well below the efficiency gains from liberalization. New entry with more efficient plants and more incentives to minimize the procurement fuel costs are contributing to reduce overall costs of electricity production. However, how these benefits are shared between producers and consumers depends to a great extent on the existing level of market power, which still persists in many markets. European countries exhibit quite different approaches to define the economic signals for long term locational signals. Only a few countries have adopted Locational Marginal Pricing or G charges with locational discrimination. Charging new generators with grid investments also follows different approaches. In some countries, new generators are only required to finance the connection to the grid. In others, on the contrary, they are required also to finance grid upgrades in order to dispatch the new generation capacity. 37 GED (GlobalEnergyDecisions), Putting Competitive Power Markets to the Test the Benefits of Competition in America’s Electric Grid: Cost Savings and Operating Efficiencies, July 2005. 38 Newbery, D., Pollitt, M., The restructuring and privatisation of Britain’s CEGB – Was it worth it?, The Journal of Industrial Economics, September 1997 European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 25 Requiring the investors to pay for the grid upgrades needed to dispatch the new generation plants is another solution, providing incentives for investors to search for the grid’s least cost location. If grid reinforcement costs are correlated with the Generator charge in every location, then these two models will provide the same locational signs. However, differently from the Generator charge model, in this alternative model, since costs of grid upgrades are sunk costs, they do not interfere with short term operation of the power plants, ignoring some potential externalities of generation in different locations in transmission losses. Regulation EC 1228/200339 favours the use of Generation and Load charges to provide locational signs for new investments. However, under the current debate no consensus has emerged on how to harmonise Europe’s transmission policy. One of the main reasons for this lack of consensus relies on the impending uncertainty of how efficient and accurate G charge locational signals can be. In fact, investment in generation involves other sources of costs, either than the transmission charges, which must be considered. For example, in several markets in the United States, even though LMP is implemented, new generation facilities are also charged with the cost of network upgrades required to dispatch generation. As Joskow40 points out, under this framework, it is likely that these cost obligations play a more important role in generator location decisions than do variations in Locational Marginal Prices. On the other hand, the issue of investment in merchant transmission lines – lines that are built based on the expected returns related with traded transmission rights, which value is based on LMP’s differences between the points interconnected by the line– has until now been lower than the initially expected. 39 REGULATION (EC) No 1228/2003 OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND OF THE COUNCIL of 26 June 2003 on conditions for access to the network for cross-border exchanges in electricity. 40 Joskow, Paul L. Transmission policy in the United States, Utilities Policy 13 (2005) European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 26 At this point in time, the search for an optimal transmission policy that allows for better coordination between transmission and generation investments is still underway. However, this cannot be used as an argument against ownership unbundling. One of the merits of ownership unbundling is to disconnect the incentives of the Transmission Owner from generation and supply activities. Under the ownership independence framework, the incentives of the transmission owner depend on the adopted economic regulatory model, with the rate of return model being the most commonly used. Although it is arguable that this model may lead to overinvestment, one has to consider the burden to consumers that this overinvestment leads to and, on the contrary, the potential benefits that can be derived from overinvestment in transmission. The share of transmission costs on end customer’s price is in the range of 5 to 15 percent. On the other hand, the cost of energy production ranges between 60 and 80 percent. If over-investment in transmission network means lower restrictions for competition in generation and less grid bottlenecks, allowing effectively for less energy costs, on balance it is a welfare improving move. For instance, congestion costs represent a significant source of inefficiency in electricity markets performance. Congestion means that cheaper generation cannot reach consumers, requiring, in areas where the bottlenecks exist, to call more expensive power plants to generate. These costs may be very high, and represent a source of inefficiency far more important than the inefficiencies derived from overinvestment in transmission capacity. Coordination of investments in the Portuguese case has been largely solved (See Annex II) by entrusting the TSO with the function of producing medium and long-term plans of supply and demand for the generation system, as well as another plan for the required network infrastructure. Then, the regulator (ERSE) will have to supervise the network expansion plans, like the UK regulator, whereas the government grants licenses for production based on market needs. European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 27 Does unbundling lead to an increase in the cost of capital to the TSO and generation companies? Theory and empirical evidence do not give an affirmative answer. Firms may be smaller, but management will be more focussed and rip the benefits of a higher specialization. If some of the firms can merge with negatively correlated risks the cost of capital may even fall. However, as Pollitt (2007) states, it is difficult to believe that with efficient capital markets the effect may be significant. Moreover, separate market interest rates for the different businesses is important for financial efficiency. The European Commission Sector Inquiry shows, on the empirical front, that it is often in the interest of the integrated incumbent not to invest in infrastructure that would bring additional competition. As Lowe et al. point out (p. 27) “the interest in protecting the market power and profitability of their supply business trumps their interest in increasing their (regulated) network business. In 2006 there was an interesting case of abuse of dominant position brought by the Autorità against ENI, the Italian gas incumbent, because it delayed investment in a pipeline owned by one of its subsidiaries, the Trans Tunisian Pipeline Co. The increased capacity would have improved the ability for competitors to import Algerian gas to Italy and compete with ENI on the Italian wholesale market.41 In a number of cases, companies have invested only in capacity if their related supply arms had confirmed their interest. As ERGEG42 underlines, where generation and network business are integrated, potential for discrimination exists, namely in what concern “slowness to connect competitors, investment decisions (e.g. failing to invest to remove bottlenecks), and scheduling of maintenance.” 41 Bolletino of the Autorità Garante della Concorrenza e del Mercato no. 5/2006 (reference A358) Decision of 15/02/2006. 42 ERGEG, Fact Sheet on Unbundling, May 2007 European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 28 Econometric evidence on this subject is more controversial, especially contrasting data from the USA. However, it is important to say at the outset that the US is a much more competitive market with a lower level of concentration than Europe.43 The old literature on vertical economies in the electricity industry finds that are scope economies in the joint operation of generation and transmission.44 Michaels (2006) reviews 12 papers on vertical integration in electric power and finds that 11 show benefits from vertical integration, mainly derived from separability tests. Finally, on the investment front, there may be other barriers to an efficient market, derived from government licensing, subsidies or tax benefits, or land use permits. Double marginalisation This issue can be easily disposed off in theoretical terms. According to Pollitt45 the problem does not arise because in network service pricing the method used is a multipart tariff and marginal prices usually equal marginal costs. Moreover, since transmission prices are regulated the problem cannot be seen as the trivial question of integrated monopoly maximization versus two-monopolies maximization. The European debate At the European level a definitive proposal for the insufficient unbundling has not yet been defined. France is opposed because the Government wants to maintain EDF46 and GDF as the incumbents, with state control, fully integrated, and has shown a sign that wants to 43 This has resulted from antitrust positions taken during the 1930s. 44 Nemoto, J. and M. Goto. Technological externalities and economies of vertical integration in the electric utility industry. International Journal of Industrial Organisation, 2004, vol. 22 (1) p. 67-81. 45 The arguments for and against ownership unbundling of energy transmission networks, August 2007, CWPE 0737. 46 The ISO for France is RTE. It has only legal autonomy vis-à-vis EDF Transport, but the management is chosen by EDF in consultation with the government. European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 29 protect them as European energy champions.47 The following citation of the regulator shows that the situation is satisfactory with an integrated single monopoly and that regulation can solve all the problems raised above: Intervention of Phillippe de Ladoucette during the seminar “Politique Energetique: 2007, quells choix pour la France?”, Maison de la Chimie, January 17th, 2007. Germany wants to preserve its large energy firms, largely controlled by the Landers,4849 also fully integrated50. Until recently there were 12 regional TSOs, but now there are only four, after merging their networks.51 It has even resisted until two years ago in forming a sector regulator, and then it has given it very light powers. The problem of the level playing field in the ownership of firms in merger situations has been addressed recently by the Commission52 within the financial sector. For example, any Spanish Caixa, which are regional banks controlled by the Governos Autonomicos, can buy a private bank anywhere in the EU while the reverse cannot occur because of their statutes. 47 Centrica recently filled a claim with the Commission against the Continental vertically integrated firms because they were excluding from the market the non-integrated suppliers. This behaviour combined with the intervention of governments to regulate consumer prices for political reasons has led to the bankruptcy of quite a number of traders in Germany and Portugal, among other countries. 48 E.g. E.ON is normally considered to be controlled by the state of Baviera through its Cmmunal Funds. 49 In Spain Iberdrola is also controlled by the state of Cataluña, through its regional bank. 50 On March 7th, 2007, the Süddeutsche Zeitung reported that incumbent operators Eon, RwE, EnBW, Vatenfall and VDN planned to propose to the Commission to bundle transmission lines for electricity and gas within a region extending from Germany to France, Belgium, Netherlands and Luxemburg. 51 The same measure was taken by Switzerland after the great blackout of 2003, all TSOs have been merged into one. 52 See also the presentation of the Portuguese Competition Authority president to the Parliament in 2006. European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 30 In the last count, there are about ten countries that are against ownership unbundling. The arguments presented by all of them are just a perusal of the points raised above about the costs of unbundling. The resistance to structural unbundle Transmission System Operators53, led to the study of alternative unbundling provisions, namely to separate system operators without ownership unbundling – the ISO/TSO model. Choice between TSO and ISO Theoretically, ownership separation has an important impact on competition. It removes network bottlenecks and creates independence from the suppliers. The system can to a certain extent be replicated by an Independent System Operator that, even if it does not own the assets, dispatches and plans the investment in the network (ISO/TSO model). There are different types of ISOs. The Deep ISO model removes all of the functions of the system operator from the bundled company, leaving the bundled company only with the ownership of the assets. The ISO undertakes live network operation, arrange for network access, undertake network planning and make investment decisions, arrange for network connections, undertake emergency planning and levy for use of the network, maintain direct relations with the transmission customers and manage information flows to the outside world. The Shallow ISO entails all transmission functions remaining with the bundle company apart from the live operation of the transmission network during and close to real time. Some of the regulators in countries were the ISO/TSO model was implemented agree that conflicts between the owners of the asset and the system operator are difficult to manage, 53 In March 6th, 2007, in an interview to Financial Times, German Chancellor Angela Merkel stated: "I do not think the issue of competition can be reduced to the unbundling question. Stripping the energy producers of their networks is no guarantee that there will be more competition. What you need is a strong regulatory system to enhance competition and the right incentives to invest. In some countries, the separation of rail services and networks did not exactly improve the network’s quality." European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 31 and require a complex set of contracts. The principal/agent economic theory, that offers a model that can be referred to for similar circumstances, point out that the ISO (principal) will face transaction costs to ensure that the TSO(s) (agent) makes all the efforts necessary to realize his orders, since the TSO(s) interests, as part of the vertically integrated undertaking, are inclined to diverge from them. In fact, ERGEG argues that ownership unbundling has the advantage over the Deep ISO model of having the right incentives for investment: “The ISO model…adds the risk of conflicts as regards investing and sharing the profits resulting from transmission activity between the owner and operator of the assets, without any benefits to the network user.” (ERGEG op.cit.). The ISO/TSO model is the main solution adopted in the US to tackle the vertical integration issues under the open access to the transmission networks framework.54 Although it is politically simpler than the full unbundling, since it is less likely to face a significant resistance from the utilities, it requires extensive regulation and it is not yet a proven solution to create an efficient framework for the operation and planning of the electric transmission systems. As Joskow55 observes, in regional markets where the ISO/TSO governance model was implemented, like the PJM and New York regional markets, while congestion costs increased, the investment in transmission has not fully responded to alleviate this congestion costs. Moreover, the US markets are less concentrated than the European. Ownership unbundling not only is not affected by these transaction costs, but seems to have a positive impact, at least in terms of timing, on investment. Most of the MS 54 It is important to note that the ISO model of the US is not similar to the one being discussed in the EU. E.g. in the PJM region the ISO is like an extension of state power and regulation into the association of energy firms. 55 Joskow, Paul L., id.. European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 32 regulators that deal with ownership unbundled TSO(s), seem to agree that these TSO(s) reduced the time needed for planning, instructing authorization process and realizing the investments. The Portuguese case (Annex II) shows that it was the change from legal to ownership unbundling56 that led to increased investment in the transmission network and increased interconnector capacity with Spain. The UK case (Annex I) also shows that ownership unbundling led Transco to increase substantially investments. And Lowe et al. also cite the case of Netherlands. And in the case of Italy, the ISO experience deteriorated the efficiency of the system, and after the blackout of 2003 that affected North Italy for part of the summer, it adopted a TSO. Therefore, while ownership unbundling is the most effective means to ensure non discriminatory access to networks and to induce investment, many uncertainties can be raised about the effectiveness of ISO/TSO model. Public versus private ownership of the energy assets There is a wide consensus among economists and regulators that effective unbundling is both necessary either in the context of publicly or privately ownership of the networks.57 In fact, since the high voltage or high pressure networks are natural monopolies, the Nordic countries have decided to maintain them under public ownership. Since generators are mostly private firms, this arrangement does not preclude, and may even accentuate the benefits of ownership unbundling. 56 The decision was taken by the Government in 2000 after a black-out affected most of the Lisbon region with serious consequences. 57 See ERGEG. Third Legislative Package Input. Paper1: Unbundling. June 2007 and Lowe, Philip, et al.. Effective Unbundling of energy transmission networks: lessons from the Energy Sector Inquiry. Competition Policy Newsletter. Spring 2007. European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 33 The problem arises when both generation and transmission are publicly owned, because in this case it would be difficult to have the benefits of unbundling even when different assets are supervised by different ministries or different levels of government. Legal problems of implementation of the unbundling First, estimates of costs of unbundling, sometimes involving divestiture, have been exaggerated. The one-off cost of the British Gas de-merger in 2000 was around 3.2 percent of the company’s yearly turnover (Lowe et al., p.32). And the European Parliament, in its Resolution of June 19th, 2007, “19, underlines that the completion of ownership unbundling in the energy sector, alongside the dismantling of vertical conglomerates and guarantying conditions for effective market access should be given high priority.” Can the Commission impose ownership unbundling without a new Directive? The Commission is vested with the powers to impose structural remedies under Regulation 1/2003. However, contrary to the UK Competition Commission that can impose those remedies within the context of a sector inquiry, the Commission can only impose them under antitrust cases, where there is no equally effective behavioural remedy or where such a behavioural remedy would be more burdensome for the undertaking concerned. In fact, the Commission seems to interpret this power as an “atomic bomb”. Accordingly, Lowe et al. consider that antitrust instruments are not well suited to require ownership unbundling. In certain MS, like in the UK, there are limits in ownership links, introduced through licensing rules that prevent e.g. the same group to hold a license for network operation and to supply/production activities. Various legal objections have been voiced against introducing ownership unbundling – with the consequent divestiture – through EU legislation. One of the most frequently heard is that it constitutes a form of expropriation, running against article 295 EC or general principles of EC law, like the European Convention on Human Rights and Fundamental European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 34 Freedoms. But the argument against this position is that the property right may be limited by objectives of general interest pursued by the Community and not constitute a disproportionate and intolerable interference. Lowe et al. (p. 33) conclude that “the arguments brought forward for ownership unbundling, and the need to ensure a level playing field across an integrated EU energy market, clearly justify action at EU level”.58 2- Cross border trade and interconnection: building regional markets A full functioning integrated energy market requires high levels of cross-border trade between Member-States to take into account the welfare benefits of international trade and the impact of the rule of cost minimization. In order to do so, investment is needed to increase interconnection capacity, since traditionally interconnections were not dimensioned to allow significant trade patterns. However, as Newbery notes59 intensifying trade in gas also contributes to the integration of electricity markets. As gas transmission costs are relatively low, the price of gas should be more uniform. Thus, new entrants into electricity generation would face similar costs and would press for price convergence. 58 However the Commission has to convince two thirds of the Council. At this time there are still about ten countries against unbundling. On the other side, seven governments have sent to the Commission a letter pressing for the change (UK, Spain, Italy, Netherlands, Sweden, Denmark and Finland). 59 Market Design, 2006. European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 35 Source: European Commission60 Source: European Commission, Energy Sector Inquiry Expanding interconnection capacity requires a high degree of coordination between TSOs and depends on exogenous factors – like environmental impact studies, planning and authorization procedures. To meet certain expansion deadlines, TSOs must be highly committed to deal with the difficulties involving expanding existing interconnection capacity. One the major lessons of the European blackouts have been that building and managing properly interconnectors is fundamental for improving the security and reliability of the 60 European Commission, COMMUNICATION FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE COUNCIL AND THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT, Report on the experience gained in the application of the Regulation (EC) No 1228/2003 "Regulation on Cross-Border Exchanges in Electricity", May 2007 European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 36 national energy networks. Since then, there was already a Multilateral Agreement among EU TSOs (Synchronic Interconnected EU Network) and the adoption of an Operational Handbook. It was adopted the N-1 security rule for network simulations. However, none of these initiatives reflects competition concerns. In fact, the balancing agent has the sole power to use or exclude form access any domestic or foreign supplier.61 From a competition point a view, to determine the right level of interconnection capacity to integrate markets is a complex task. In fact, the amount of required capacity needs to be addressed by economic modelling and not by a single rule that “fits all”.62 There are quite a number of strategic issues involved, and the market is usually one of a sophisticated oligopoly. An efficient incentives network based system could also provide a market solution for the problem. The main objective of interconnection capacity is to guarantee that there exists sufficient capacity to efficiently arbitrage price differences between price zones, effectively integrating different zones in one single price zone, but without having necessarily a unique price. Price differences can be explained by differences in generation mix but also by differences in concentration levels among price zones. The higher the price differences the more interconnection capacity is required to effectively harmonize prices. If price differences attributable to market dominance in one price zone are higher than the perceived cost difference between generation mixes than, ceteris paribus, the higher is the optimal interconnection capacity to integrate markets.63 61 These problems are compounded by the physical characteristics of the generator. A nuclear power plant cannot be taken out of the system, wind is intermittent, a coal plant will take 6 to 12 hours to start injecting electricity and a gas fired about half an hour. Hydro power has the lowest connection lag. 62 Like the present rule of 10 percent of demand. 63 The interconnector between the Iberian Peninsula and France is almost permanently congested by Iberdrola, decoupling the Portuguese and Spanish markets from the rest of Europe. European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 37 However, the effects of trade between markets of different scale are necessarily asymmetrical. Integration leads to a higher external competitive pressure over the incumbent of the small country. The contrary is less evident. It may be particularly difficult to obtain from a vertically integrated firm the necessary level of commitment needed to develop interconnection capacity with its neighbouring country. Even using regulatory powers, it may be difficult to entrust the incumbent to invest, since incentives to invest in interconnection from a vertically integrated utility are low and interconnection capacity raises the perceived competition levels over its generation and retail supplier affiliates. Incumbents will always claim that do not have any incentives to abuse its dominant position, accepting or proposing levels of interconnection capacity lower than the optimal levels that would lead to perfectly integrated markets. Potential delays in fulfilling the timetable for the interconnection expansion can be easily justified with exogenous factors, like lengthy environmental authorization procedures or the lack of coordination with the neighbouring TSO. To put this claims to test one should analyse the Iberian example. Since 2000, full ownership unbundling exists both in Spain and Portugal. The two Iberian TSOs, supported by the political willingness by the Portuguese and Spanish governments to create an Iberian Electricity market, have set an ambitious investment programme in interconnections to more than double, by 2008, the interconnection capacity between Portugal and Spain. Despite the several delays in creating the market – firstly foreseen for the beginning 2003 but only launched in the second semester of 2007 – the two TSO maintained the investments schedule. Actually, the two TSO are foreseeing new lines to be constructed till 2010. On the contrary, within the same time frame, the interconnection between Spain and France – where RTE, the French TSO is owned by the incumbent EDF – has maintained European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 38 its levels, despite the commitment by RTE, after a merger decision64 to increase this capacity. The Iberian Peninsula is stated as an Electrical Island – since the France-Spain interconnection capacity is low. To create an energy internal market interconnection capacity is critical, however it is not sufficient. It is also needed to promote the use of existing capacity through market forces, which requires the development of the market mechanisms to manage congestions. At the European level, Regulation (EC) 1228/200365 requires that the mechanisms to manage congestion must be market based. According with the existing regulation, two mechanisms were accepted: explicit auctions and implicit auctions. Explicit auction have the consequence of separating energy and transmission markets, which limits the coordination and efficiency of this model. The European Commission Energy Sector Inquiry questioned, in particular, this model, considering the irrational outcomes it may provide. On the contrary, in an implicit auction interconnection capacity is managed by the clearing house in order to provide the most efficient outcome. Energy and transmission markets are unified. Energy price differences among zones reflect the shadow price of using the limited transmission capacity. Explicit auctions have poorer performances than implicit auctions, in what concerns efficient use of limited interconnection capacity but also in what concerns market integration. Implicit auctions have the merit of more effectively arbitraging price differences, interfering more heavily with price formation in domestic markets. However, in most of European borders between Member-States explicit auction is the adopted solution. Notwithstanding, the movement to adopt implicit auctions is significant. Market splitting can be observed in the Nordic market and in the Iberian Market, which 64 European Commission, merger case COMP/M.2684 - EnBW / EDP / CAJASTUR / HIDROCANTÁBRICO, decided in 26/09/2001. 65 REGULATION (EC) No 1228/2003 OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND OF THE COUNCIL of 26 June 2003 on conditions for access to the network for cross-border exchanges in electricity European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 39 started in the second semester of 2007. In the Iberian market, the market splitting mechanism is also combined with explicit auctions (where traded rights have use or sell it obligations). The similar market coupling solution was implemented in the first half of 2007 in the French, Belgium and Netherlands markets. The use of such market mechanisms will lead to a greater convergence of prices between countries, subject to the observed constrains in interconnection capacity. The more efficient use of existing transmission capacity will be translated in more efficient arbitrage. Even though existing limitations in transmission capacity will limit full price convergence, more trade between countries will influence domestic price formation. Nevertheless, the effects of this convergence will be asymmetrical regarding small and big markets. One same level of interconnection capacity can be distinctly interpreted depending on the market under analysis. The Iberian market clearly shows the different potential impacts of trade though the interconnections: by 2008, the import capacity from Spain will represent between 15% and 20% of the Portuguese peak demand; on the contrary, import capacity from Portugal will only represent about 3 or 4% of Spanish peak demand. The more interconnected markets are the more effects of trade will arise on domestic prices. However, these effects are likely to be higher in smaller markets. The London Economic price study clearly demonstrated that high levels of interconnection capacity in smaller markets (like in the Netherlands), can have a discipline effect on incumbents market behaviour in what concerns price formation. The contrary however is less evident. The larger the domestic market and the larger the concentration levels in that market the less likely the possibility for cross-border to promote competition and discipline incumbent behaviour. European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 40 An interesting study66 for the most advanced regional market in the EU, the Nordpool, shows a very significant increase in consumer prices due to the exercise of market power during certain periods of the day in which dominant positions are created. They are able to increase peak prices by about 30 percent and non-peak prices by 10 percent, on average. Simulations also show the detrimental impact that mergers of firms across countries can have in the Nordpool price, even when traditional measures of concentration do not show a serious problem. Integrating smaller and larger markets will lead to a price convergence that will be most likely dominated by the price level of the largest market. In this process, the market concentration levels of the largest market are determinant for the overall price level of the integrated market. For small countries bordering a large one, regional integration may pose particularly acute problems, if national markets are not competitive. The situation arises because a dominant position in the large country will be extended to the small one. On the other hand, a competitive market in a small country can not automatically be extended to the larger neighbour country. As a matter of fact, creating a competitive market in the small country requires that a competitive market be simultaneously created in the large country. Interconnection between the small and large country will not solve the problem of creating a two-country competitive market. Also suppose that the small country has been able to build a competitive market, than by linking-up with the large un-competitive market will clearly lower welfare. This example clearly demonstrates that it is not enough to build a competitive single market by building up an interconnection system. Simulations carried out for Netherlands regarding closer market integration with neighbouring countries following the experience of Nordic countries show how tricky are 66 A Powerful Competition Policy: towards a more coherent competition policy in the Nordic market for electric power. Report from the Nordic Competition Authorities nº 1/2003. European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 41 the problems, specially with strong cross-border ownership (Electrabel in Belgium and the Netherlands, E.On and RWE spanning Dutch-German border, in both cases owning transmission and interconnection).67 3- Merger policies at National an Community levels: questioning the 2/3 rule The US Department of Energy stated in 2000 that “antitrust remedies are not well-suited to address problems of market power in the electric power industry that result from existing high levels of concentration”.68 This is why structural remedies are usually required, as the UK experience abundantly shows. Merger policy is a preventive tool vis-à-vis the build up of dominant positions. Its correct implementation is thus essential. In fact, recent restructuring led to the emergence of panEuropean energy companies. But the path that is leading to this scenario shows several inconsistencies in merger control practice, and as we show below could lead to a defeat of the objective of building a EU-wide competitive market. At the national level, several pleas exist to support the creation of energy “national champions”. Large countries with large energy companies use their financial muscle to acquire smaller energy companies in other national markets, sometimes with the banner of building “European champions”. But aside transmission networks, which are natural monopolies, there are no efficiencies to gain from generation concentration. Different technologies allow efficient power plants of different sizes, as the US experience shows. Some defend the need to balance the scale disadvantage (from a conglomerate perspective) that some countries incumbents face against the larger countries national incumbents to concentrate their energy companies; others have fears of foreign take-overs and defend 67 This highlights the importance of merger control viewed too narrowly in national terms, and according to D. Newbery. Market Design, shows that the European Commission needs to have a deeper analysis of the issues. 68 We would say the same about all network industries. European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 42 that a larger national company would be more difficult (more costly) for a foreign firm to acquire. Still others support the idea that national companies are more prone to accept domestic political influence, or claim that energy is a strategic sector that should be sheltered from Community influence. At the same time, vertical relations between gas and electricity are clearly developing. Natural gas is an increasingly important source of energy for electricity production. New entrants in electricity production often choose natural gas as a production input. From this convergence between both industries, market players have identified merging opportunities to vertically integrate gas and electricity businesses. Recent merger case history shows clearly the type of competition problems that can arise from this vertical integration process, especially when undertaken between dominant players in each of the two industries, and that puts a barrier to a more competitive regional or EU-wide market. Finally, recent merger case history shows differences in approach and methodologies between the European Commission and National Authorities, and among different national jurisdictions. Let us review some of the recent cases. E.ON/Ruhrgas case The mergers between E.ON/Ruhrgas, dealt with by the Bundeskartellamt in 2002, and EDP/ENI/GDP, dealt with by the Commission in 2004, clearly show these inconsistencies. In both cases, it was clearly showed that without appropriate remedies, the vertical integration between gas and electricity dominant players could pose several constraints to competition, namely the removal of strong potential competitors at retail and wholesale levels and the potential foreclosure of access to natural gas for electricity generation. In both cases a prohibition decision was issued by the Competition Authorities on the grounds of its negative effects on competition. In the E.ON / Gelsenberg (Ruhrgas) case, Bundeskartellamt’s assessment demonstrated that the merger would have strengthened dominant positions both in the gas and electricity European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 43 retail supply markets. Indeed, Ruhrgas was the largest German grid gas company, accounting for nearly 60% of total natural gas demand, and the only German gas player with access to all the different sources of gas supplies for Germany (namely supplies from Norway, Russia, the Netherlands, Great Britain and also the existing domestic sources). As for E.ON, it was the second largest electricity player, vertically integrated and also present in the supply of natural gas, namely thorough its shareholder positions in regional electricity and gas distributors and in municipal utilities. According to the assessment of Bundeskartellamt, the merger of Ruhrgas and E.ON would structurally secure Ruhrgas’ sales to E.ON affiliates and holdings. The foreclosing of a significant share of the wholesale gas market would therefore strengthen Ruhrgas dominant position. E.ON affiliates that where located in Ruhrgas’ transmission area would also strengthen their dominant positions in supplying large gas consumers and local gas distributors, since Ruhrgas would be removed as a potential competitor. In electricity markets, the merger would also produce detrimental effects, contributing to strengthen the collective dominance of E.ON and RWE (which had also a gas subsidiary – Thyssengas), considering the potential foreclosure of natural gas access for new entrants in generation of electricity. The parties offered commitments in order to address the competition concerns raised by the merger, however, they were considered to be of little significance to prevent the strengthening of the dominant positions in the gas and electricity markets. Therefore the Bundeskartellamt decided to prohibit the merger between E.ON and Ruhrgas. Notwithstanding, after an appeal by the merging companies to the German Minister for Economy the permission was granted, on the grounds that overall economic advantages stemming from the merger had been demonstrated. European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 44 A number of experts have claimed the damage caused by this decision, e.g. David Newbery claims that the European Commission should have a jurisdiction on such a case, due to its impact on electricity and gas market in other countries of the EU.69 EDP/ENI/GDP Case On the contrary, in the merger EDP/ENI/GDP, which was supported by the Portuguese Government, with the main argument that the incumbent needed to gain scale to compete in the wider Iberian market, the prohibition by the European Commission in 2004 effectively blocked the merger, a decision that was uphold by the Court of First Instance in September 2005. The Case EDP/ENI/GDP concerned the proposed acquisition by Energias de Portugal (EDP) and ENI of joint control over Gás de Portugal (GDP). EDP is the Portuguese electricity incumbent in Portugal, at the time, with more than 70% of the Portuguese generation capacity and almost a monopolist in electricity distribution throughout the country, as well as present in the Spanish natural gas and electricity markets (through its Spanish affiliates Hidrocantabrico and Naturcorp). ENI is an Italian company active internationally at all levels of the energy supply and distribution chain. GDP is the incumbent gas operator in Portugal, active at all levels of the gas chain in Portugal, at the time with exclusive rights for import, storage, transportation, wholesale supply of natural gas and the control of five of the six Portuguese local gas distribution companies (the sixth being controlled by EDP).70 One of the main disputes in the case concerned the geographic market definition of the electricity wholesale market. Since the Iberian Wholesale Market was due to start in the 69 70 Newbery Market Design The Portuguese Competition Authority (PCA) had already anticipated the problems of this concentration in the study commissioned to Cambridge Associates of D. Newbery. See the site of the PCA: www.autoridadedaconcorrencia.pt European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 45 near future, the parties alleged that the wholesale electricity market would be Iberian (Portugal and Spain). However, considering the high congestion levels in the interconnection between Portugal and Spain, which would remain high in the future, despite the undergoing upgrade in interconnection capacity, the Commission ruled out the possibility that the wholesale electricity market would be Iberian in the future. The Commission assessment of the case demonstrated that the merger would strengthen EDP’s dominant position in the electricity wholesale and retail markets in Portugal. Indeed, it would remove GDP as a potential strong competitor in the electricity markets. Furthermore, since new entrants in generation chose natural gas as the primary source of energy, the concentration would have made the existing and possible new future power producers in Portugal dependent on their main competitor, namely EDP. The concentration would also strengthen GDP’s dominant position in the relevant gas markets in Portugal, through the foreclosure of a significant part of the gas demand (controlled by EDP) and the elimination of EDP as most likely entrant in the gas markets. Endesa/Gas Natural In 2005, in Spain, similarly, the vertical merger between Gas Natural, the gas dominant player in the Spanish market, and Endesa, the largest electricity player in Spain, would have allowed for strong impediments for competition in the Spanish natural gas and electricity markets. It would strengthen Natural Gas dominant position – being Endesa an entrant in the gas retail market with prospects of high growth of its market share. Since Gas Natural was previously the strongest new entrant in generation, the new merged entity would acquire a market share in the Spanish electricity wholesale market higher than the before held by Endesa, raising the concentration levels of the Spanish wholesale electricity. The European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 46 merger was also likely to raise vertical effects similar to the merger cases previously presented. 71 Notwithstanding, despite the Spanish Competition Authority recommendation to block the merger, the Spanish Council of Ministries decided to approve the merger, based on the recommendation of the sector regulator, subject to some mild conditions. Endesa appealed to courts of the Government decision. In the meantime E.On made a counterbid clearly above the one of Gas Natural. The merger was approved by the European Commission, but the Spanish sector regulator imposed a number of substantial remedies, after the Spanish government enact increased powers equivalent to almost a veto to its sector regulator. E.On appealed to the Commission that initiated procedures against the Spain. The arm twisting was lingering on, and the Spanish construction conglomerate, ACS, increased its share in the capital of Endesa to slightly below 30 percent, making it very difficult for E.On that required 2/3 of the capital to take control of Endesa. Two years later, the situation was finally resolved when the Italian state company Enel bought part of the stockholdings and jointly with ACS stroke a deal with E.On that remained with a small part of Endesa assets and thus withdrew the bid. GdF/Suez case The merger between Gaz de France (GDF) and Suez, approved by the European Commission in 2006, involved the dominant gas incumbents of France and Belgium, each vertically integrated, in two neighbouring countries and actively entering in each other 71 The PCA appealed to the Commission asking for a referral of the case from the national authorities to the Commission, which was opposed by the Spanish government. After a lengthy debate, revolving about some detailed accounting issues, the Commission accepted the position of the Spanish government. The tenet of the Commission vis-à-vis the request of the PCA was that the merger in Spain would not have any significant impact in Portugal, despite the projected increase in the interconnector that was to reach 20 percent of Portuguese electricity demand. European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 47 domestic market. Moreover, since Electrabel, the Belgium electricity incumbent, was a subsidiary of the Suez group, and GDF, along with Centrica, had joint control over SPE, the second player in the Belgian electricity and gas markets, the merger affected also the Belgium electric market, raising also vertical effects. As stated by the European Commission, concerns related mainly to the removal of the increasing competitive pressure that GDF and Suez had so far exerted (and would have exerted in the foreseeable future) on each other in both Belgium and France. In the Belgium gas market, the merger would have removed GDF as the strongest competitor of Distrigaz (Suez group). This merger would also remove GDF as a competitor to supply gas-fired power generators competing with Electrabel, the dominant Belgium electricity incumbent, therefore affecting the competition conditions in the supply of gas to power generation. Moreover, given the control of Fluxys, the Belgium TSO, the GDF/Suez merger would have allowed the parties to have privileged access to a very important transit gas network, where a gas hub is located, linked with several other markets and with an LNG regasification terminal. In France, since Distrigaz was a strong new entrant in the French gas markets, through the merger this competitive pressure over GDF’s dominant position would cease to exist. Since the Suez group was the largest player on the French market for district heating and GDF the second, the merger would raise the concentration level in this market. In order to address this competition concerns, a set of remedies were proposed, namely the divestiture of activities where a horizontal overlap was identified. In the Belgium gas market, Suez would divest Distrigaz, solving the horizontal concerns in the Belgium gas market and the vertical concerns related with access to gas for power generation. GDF would divest its SPE shareholding, solving the concerns in the Belgium electricity market, European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 48 and its subsidiary Cofathec-Coriance, to address the concerns in the district heating market in France. Suez would also relinquish its control of Belgian gas TSO Fluxys, namely by reducing its stake in its share capital to 45% and implementing an independent governance model. In this model, the merged entity would only be able to nominate 1/3 of the board of directors. A management committee, independent from the board, with full powers to manage all aspects of Fluxys activities, would be created. The rules for the management committee nomination would ensure its independence from the board of directors. In Fluxys International (owning the transit pipelines and the LNG terminal) the merged entity stake would be restricted to 60%, however, granting Fluxys the requisite rights to use installations and equipments of Fluxys International. The parties also presented the commitment to carry out a series of investment projects in Belgium and France in order to increase infrastructure capacities and facilitate entry. Through commitments, the Zeebrugge hub would also act as an aggregator and therefore increase market liquidity. As far as the Belgium market is considered, through the remedies, since Distrigaz and Fluxys would remain under the control of different entities there would be a structural separation of the dominant gas market player and the gas TSO. However, being France and Belgium both transit countries for Norwegian gas that flow from North to South (the Benelux Italy Axe, as identified in the European Commission Sector Inquiry), this will lead to the fact that two alternative transit routes (the one that crosses France and the one that crosses Belgium and Germany on the way to Italy) will cross two gas TSO with similar shareholders. Being transit flows strategic for the gas internal market construction, this framework might lead to competition problems in access to transit networks and new investments regarding transit pipelines. European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 49 It may be argued that the governance model implemented with the remedies for Flexys may solve the potential competition concerns in gas transit flows that might result from the merger. In fact, the commitments offered by the parties were designed in way to impede (or make it difficult) the future merged entity to block the independent management committee investment decisions over Fluxys and Fluxys international. Furthermore, some commitments were offered regarding gas transit. However, the adopted model for relinquishing the control over Fluxys are far from the ownership unbundling of the TSO model adopted in several countries, where market players are restricted to a maximum of 5% of the TSO’s share capital. In fact, the GDF/Suez group would still be able to appoint 1/3 of board of directors in Fluxys. And, as far as the Belgium gas market is concerned, will remain a market player (through GDF former market share) with a stake of 45% of the TSO’s capital. The standard of independence that this governance model presents has not yet been properly tested and shares the same concerns as referred elsewhere in this paper. European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 50 Problems with promoting European champions The flurry of cross-border acquisitions in EU markets that we have witnessed in the last decade, taking advantage of fragmented national markets is a serious obstacle to the functioning of competitive regional markets and an integrated EU-wide market. The problem can be illustrated by the following example with a large (X) and a small country (Y), and suppose the two countries have a limited volume of interconnection. In country X there are two major electricity generators and in country Y a dominant player. Suppose now that firm A from country X acquires firm C from country Y. Since it is a cross-border merger it goes to the Commission. Since firm A does not have business in country Y and the increase in its share in country X is low, the merger may be approved. Country X Firm A Firm B Firm C Others Total 20 30 5 45 100 20 30 20 25 10 48 30 130 Country Y Total Firm A+C merge Country X Merged Firm B 25 Firm C 30 Others Total 35 100 10 30 45 130 Country Y 20 Total 45 30 However, a crucial aspect is that the Commission will consider two separate national markets, since the level of interconnection is low. Now, let us consider two situations. If the level of interconnection is substantially increased and the market is integrated there is a serious problem of concentration: the HHI jumps from 4229 to 4950. But if the level of interconnection is reasonable and might even be high (the present required level is 10 percent of demand, but obviously 10 percent for country X is quite different from 10 percent of country Y), most of the time and at least in peak hours the interconnector would be congested, which means that the merged firm not only has the capability to European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 51 control the price in country Y but also either individually or in conjunction with firm B control the price in country C. In fact, in the regional market there was a reduction from 3 to 2 big players. The problem arises because we still have fragmented markets that require geographical national dimension and regional integration requires already a different approach. The problem is that the sequential analysis leads to inconsistencies. This is not purely an abstract example, simulations for the Nordic market show that a merger of a large Finish generator with a large generator in Denmark, even without any overlap of geographical markets could generate a substantial increase in prices in their home countries. Figure x shows an increase of about 50 percent in peak hours in Denmark. Source: Nordic Competition Authorities. A Powerful Competition Policy, op.cit.. The 2/3 merger rule for case allocation Analysing these cases one has to conclude that inconsistencies in merger control may undermine the efforts in smaller neighbouring countries to construct competitive frameworks. In effect, even though wholesale electricity market geographic definition may rule out that the markets are all the time integrated, if one accepts the geographic market European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 52 definition adopted by the European Commission and the Nordic Competition Authorities in the Nordpool72, where geographic markets are defined according to the market splitting congestion mechanism – e.g. wholesale market can be Nordic in some hours, with a single price for all the grid zones and regional in other hours, defined according to the price zones that are defined – the effects of a merger in one country might not be confined to the market where most of its effects are created. In larger countries/markets, the creation or strengthening of a dominant position might have effects, through cross-border trade, in its neighbouring countries.73 Allowing concentration levels to increase at the domestic level might have strong detrimental effects on internal energy market construction. Therefore, it is necessary to guarantee that merger control in the energy sector, whether appraised at the European level or at the national level, follows the same principles. The share of competences between the European Commission and the National Authorities in what concerns merger control should not allow for different interpretations. This share of competences should not serve the way to approve mergers that lead to the creation of energy “national champions”. Sorgard74 has also raised the problem of the “beggar-thy-neighbour” regarding national champions. Suppose a country forms an energy champion, then its neighbour also wants to form an equal energy champion in terms of countervailing power. Due to the externality involved he also favours a revision of the 2/3 rule. The EU energy internal market needs more infrastructures to integrate markets. But it also needs a coherent merger control practice within all member states. 72 See European Commission decisions on the cases M.3867 VATENFALL / ELSAM and E2 Assets, decided in 2005/12/22, and M.3868 DONG/ELSAM/ENERGI E2, decide in 2006/03/14. 73 Among EU energy firms the ones that have been buying most of the other EU countries companies are the French, German and to a less extent the public owned Italian incumbent. 74 Lars Sorgard. The Economics of National Champions. European Competition Journal, June 2007. He also refers a case where the champion might have some monopoly power on a larger market than the national market, and thus be able to appropriate consumer welfare from the foreign consumers. European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 53 The 2/3 Rule for allocating merger cases is in need of modernization. In fact, we can deduct the proposed new rule from a purely abstract model, in the best tradition of conceiving laws and regulations, without referring to any case in particular. No single case has been raised in the tradable sector. The problem arises in nontradables, with strong network and scale economies (infrastructure), which are usually regulated markets. In these markets, mergers have a local and national impact, but they can have also a strong cross-border effect, and will have an ever stronger impact as the European integration proceeds – as we all wish. Let us suppose we have a given undertaking, with a given Minimum Efficient Scale, that is relatively large, when compared with the size of a small economy market, due to scale, network and scope economies. Now, it is probable that the large country undertaking has most of the operations within the large country, and the small country undertaking has assets in other EU countries and/or a controlling part of its assets is owned by a firm of another EU country. And this probability will increase with financial and economic integration. However, a merger within two undertakings in a large country most probably would fall under the NCA, and the merger of two undertakings in a small country would go to the Commission. There would be no problem as to what jurisdiction decides on the case, if there was full harmonization in merger rules among EU countries. But, in contrast with antitrust rules, this is not the case. This is there are still countries whose merger control regime allows for decision criteria based on “national interest”, as an extraordinary appeal to the Minister of the Economy may be lodged in case of a negative decision by the PCA. We badly need some type of harmonization of merger rules, and this is the core of the problem. Let me say that there is now a clear imbalance between merger European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 54 cases and Regulation 1/2003 dealing with articles 81 and 82, where the Commission can take a case from a NCA in order to ensure coherence of the EC competition rules. Accordingly, the 2/3 Rule should be qualified, giving the Commission the right to avocate the case if it is a network sector, and the case is important for community policy reasons. Any MS competition authority or government should also have the power to ask the Commission to take the case or have the right of referral. This position has already been echoed by the European Parliament. In its Resolution of June 19, 2007, concerning Competition Policy, it states: “24. Recalls the Commission’s commitment to review the “two-thirds rule” as a threshold for finding a Community impact in regard to merger proposals, suggests that progress in this area and a more consistent approach in the evaluation of comparable merger operations would be welcome whenever decisions taken at national level could have a strong impact on the market structure of neighbouring Member States”. Methodologies used for merger analysis and its impact Mergers in electricity markets cannot be analysed with the traditional measures of concentration. The US FERC uses a screen consisting of two tests: a market share and the pivotal supplier test. The merger passes the pivotal supplier test if, assuming the merged entity is removed from the market, the remaining suppliers have sufficient capacity to meet the demand at a similar price. If it fails the test can still rebut the case offering evidence based on a delivered price test or filing a mitigating proposal accepting e.g. cost-based regulated rates. However, it is possible to prove that those tests are still unsatisfactory. The best merger test is the Competitive Residual Demand (CRD) analysis based on a simulation model of residual demand (the wholesale market demand less the aggregated uncommitted supply European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 55 from all the other firms), to test if the merged firm has an incentive to reduce output or raise prices relative to pre-merger levels. Obviously, market demand will differ at different points in time.75 There is quite diversity in the methods used in the EU. The Italian and Spanish authorities used the pivotal supplier test. The Commission uses a qualitative analysis that presupposes some of these methods, namely when it looks at its order in the supply schedule. However, in one case referring to the Swedish and Danish markets they used the MARS model, used by the Nordic competition authorities, to test its qualitative analysis.76 NMa has also used a sophisticated simulation model to study the Nuon-Reliant merger. Most of the applied case studies show that in each relevant market, for passing the tests of Newbery strategic supply function criteria and CRD we need to have at least four producer firms of similar capacity. This is clearly much more stringent than traditional market share analysis used by most of the competition authorities. Do mergers of electricity companies have a significant impact on improving firm efficiency? The track record is not encouraging. John Kowka and Michael Pollitt77 conducted an extensive study of 75 mergers in the US from 1994 to 2002, involving half of the customers of all investor-owned electricity companies. They test for the impact of the merger in efficiency using data envelopment analysis. Their conclusion is that are usually less efficient firms that buy more efficient firms and after the merger seller’s efficiency declines towards the norm. This is clearly not evidence that mergers in electricity increase efficiency.78 75 76 D. Newbery. Electricity Merger Policy in the Shadow of Regulation, October 2006. 77 COMP/M.3867-Vattenfall/Elsam and E2 Assets. Industry Restructuring, Mergers and Efficiency: Evidence from Electric Power. CWPE 0725. April 2007. 78 One specific example in Massachusetts, where Nstar bought some of the neighbour distributors promising a reduction in operating costs of 13.7 percent, that never materialized. (See Kowka and Pollitt, op. cit.) European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 56 4- Competition policy in an environment of global concentration in natural resources The trend for concentration of oil and gas supply in an ever smaller number of countries is a well known fact. According to the IEA proven oil reserves are concentrated in the Middle East and North Africa (62 percent of the world total). As a result, OPEC oil production will increase from 40 percent of world production in 2006 to around 50 percent in 2030, with Russia, Central Asia, Latin America and Canada the only regions to increase production. Although reserves of natural gas are more widely distributed, 56 percent are concentrated in Russia, Iran and Qatar. By contrast coal and uranium are more widely distributed. Besides this concentration of resources, there are factors that can limit investment and trade in the future: (i) resource nationalism, with the State assuming an increasing intervention in order to restrict or discriminate access to foreign companies; (ii) “national champions”, State or State controlled companies or even private companies protected by the State, that control the supply of energy or natural resources used for production of energy. These dominant companies lack a structure of governance that presses them to be efficient and responsive to the markets, leading either to under investments and/or overpricing. They are also more prone to political influence; (iii) abuse of market power, which can be used over reserves, use of pipelines for transport of energy or supply of electricity at peak hours, that enables States or enterprises to exert significant influence over production or prices for some period of time. Coordination or cartelization of suppliers about production, prices or investments can also increase their market power, reducing market effectiveness; (iv) threat of terrorism, war or accidents, can increase the likelihood of supply disruptions and industry risk, particularly when energy is being moved across large distances, hampering investment and increasing production costs. European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 57 Two other factors can compound those risks: (i) lack of information about market variables, like production, consumption and stocks of fuels that can exacerbate price volatility; and (ii) regulatory uncertainty, that can undermine confidence of investors. EU’s energy dependence will increase from 50 percent of total energy consumption today to 65 percent in 2030.79 In comparison, US imports of energy will increase from 30 percent in 2005 to 32 percent in 2030.80 Let us look at the concentration in gas production and how it will affect Europe. According to some estimates in the next 10 years Russia will increase its market share in total EU consumption from 26 to about 30 percent, Norway will remain at about 13 percent and Algeria will increase from 11 to 15 percent. It is possible that Russia plus Algeria will be supplying close to half of gas consumption by 2016. 79 Commission, An Energy Policy for Europe, Communication from the Commission to the European Council and the European Parliament, Brussels, January, 10th, 2007. 80 Reference scenario of the Department of Energy, Annual Energy Outlook, 2006. European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 58 International trade should be based on the functioning of open domestic market economies and the free movement of goods and capital. These are principles that economic theory has demonstrated for a long time that lead to maximization of world welfare and largely reflected in the charter of WTO. It is well grounded the fact that the exchange of goods between countries is a positive sum game. The period of protectionism between the two World Wars shows how detrimental to developing countries and the wealth of all nations the use of external trade as a political instrument can be. Energy is an input used in almost all economic activity, and we live in a society that is largely dependent on affordable energy resources. So energy is recognized as a strategic resource by all governments. So the use of energy as an arm of influence in international relations is an instrument that can lead quickly to the rise in political tensions and the threat of serious conflicts. How should the EU lower the risk of these threats? The Commission Green Paper on Energy establishes the need for a “coherent external energy policy” to enable EU “to speak European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 59 with one voice”.81 In this regard it points the need to (i) define a clear policy on diversifying the sources of energy, like new independent gas pipelines from the Caspian region, North Africa and Middle East to the centre of Europe, and new oil pipelines from the Caspian region through Romania, Bulgaria and Ukraine. LNG terminals in regions without an effective competition on gas; (ii) energy partnerships with major producers/suppliers, in particular a new EU-Russia partnership and cooperation agreement,82 efforts to secure Russia ratification of the Energy Charter Treaty83 and conclusions on the Transit Protocol, developing a pan-European Energy Community84 with strategic partners Norway, Turkey 81 If gas and oil are commodities they should be included in the external commercial policy of the EU. 82 Total trade between the Eu and Russia rechead 166 billion euros in 2005, with trade surplus for Russia representing 8 percent of its GDP. Russia is the third most important trade partner of the EU (7.3 percent of the total) and the EU is the most important trade partner of Russia. The EU is also the most important foreign investor in Russia. 83 The Energy Charter Treaty of 1994, entered into legal force in April 1998, is a multilateral framework for energy cooperation that is unique under international law. It focuses on “four areas: (i) protection of foreign investments, based on the extension of national treatment or mostfavoured nation treatment and protection against key non-commercial risks, (ii) non-discriminatory conditions for trade in energy materials, products and energy-related equipment based on WTO rules, and provisions to ensure reliable cross-border energy transit flows through pipelines, grids and other means of transportation, (iii) resolution of disputes between participating states and /or investors, and (iv) promotion of energy efficiency and attempts to minimize the environmental impact of energy production and use”. For more information see www.encharter.org. Twenty six countries have signed the Charter, besides the EU Member States, with Russian Federation and Belarus with a provisional status. The EU should aim for a full application of these two countries. 84 The Energy Community Treaty, signed in Athens on October 25, 2005, aims to extend the EU internal energy market to the South East Europe Region, with the following “goals: (i) to create a stable and European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 60 and Ukraine, Algeria and Caspian countries, and promoting long-term investment in transEuropean energy networks and their extensions to third partners; (iii) develop new and targeted instruments to react to external crisis; (iv) intensify the dialogue with major energy consumers, in particular with the US, China and India, on global issues on research and development of new technologies, global market access and investment trends, widening the geographic scope of the EU Emissions Trade Scheme and promote an international agreement on energy efficiency; and finally (v) use energy to promote development by developing micro-generation and renewable resources (e.g. only 7 percent of Africa hydropower has been developed). The Commission is taking the right approach: it “should speak at one voice” in negotiations with major supplier States, to establish the cooperation framework. Thus, negotiations with Russia, Algeria or OPEC should be conducted by the Commission and not by individual Member States (MS). It increases bargaining power, but also because what is at stake is the supply of energy to several countries and what the Commission can offer, in a bilateral trade agreement85 is much more than MS can. Moreover, multilateral initiatives like some of the ones cited above can also improve the world welfare. The IEA, OECD and WTO could provide an important contribution to the solution of some of the problems of security and competitiveness of supply. Linking energy problems with development is also an essential policy for the World Bank. regulatory market framework capable of attracting investment, (ii) to create a single regulatory space for trade, (iii) to enhance security of supply; and (iv) to improve the environmental situation and to develop electricity and gas market competition, and in particular prohibition of cartels, abuses of dominant positions and distorting public aid, on a broader geographical scale.” More information is provided in www.energycommunity.org. The following countries have signed the Treaty: Albania, Bosnia and Herzegovina, Croatia, FYR Macedonia, Montenegro and Serbia. 85 It is important that these States understand that bilateral and multilateral trade is a positive sum game. European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 61 Second, in the same vein, a country to country approach should be avoided, since it weakens bargaining position of MS. Only after the cooperation framework is established then individual MS and their companies should negotiate contracts with external suppliers. This strategy has not been followed and sometimes large MS have rushed to establish contracts with major suppliers, either foreclosing the role of other smaller companies or MS, or weakening the position of the EU. Third, the policy advocated by some large MS to build national champions in the field of energy is flawed from several viewpoints. This approach invites the same response from supplier countries,86 that will claim discrimination if they cannot have the same rights as the national champion either in that country or in a third country within EU. Second, a national champion policy by giving or protecting monopoly rights to an incumbent creates a monopoly rent that makes the company more prone to a foreign take-over.87 88 Since the EC Energy Charter Treaty establishes that foreign investors should have a treatment similar to national investors, respect of competition rules and open capital markets, it would be difficult for some MS to claim a “national champion status” for its 86 Russia, eg., has recently introduced a bill prohibiting foreign ownership above 49 percent in 31 strategic sectors, including the energy sector. This has been criticized by the EU Parliament (see its Resolution of 19th June, 2007). 87 In a more colourful note: “fattening the pig to entice other’s appetite”. 88 This position does not preclude blocking powers for national security reasons, established on an institutionalised and accountable basis as the US President and the Committee on Foreign Investments in the US (CFIUS) have. Germany is proposing a similar EU body. Although the UK is opposed to any controls, despite its merger law also established a veto by the secretary of state based on national security reasons; it also calls for reciprocal access to the investor’s capital markets. This might amount to blocking power for China, which is largely closed to foreign buyers, and Russia, where large strategic investments are difficult. Obviously the problem is particularly serious when handing the control of “critical infrastructure” like energy and banking to state-owned non-EU interests. There are some activities that are still protected by the public security exception. European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 62 incumbent and thus oppose an undertaking of a non-EU Energy Charter signatory to buy a stake or control of a its national energy company. Can EDF be treated in a different way by the French government than Gazprom? Or the other way around, can the Russian government89 block the acquisition of a stake or control of EDF in a Russian energy firm? There are currently some important clauses of anti-competitive practices in international trade: one is the territorial exclusivity in gas contracts that limit distribution within national boundaries, which is a serious limitation to cross-border trade. This is the case of long-term gas contracts between Sonatrach and some EU incumbents. The Commission reached an agreement on July 14, 200790 with Algeria covering all existing and future LNG and pipeline contracts including contracts where the gas transits another MS. The settlement includes the deletion of all territorial restrictions in existing and future contracts. As regards profit split mechanisms (PSMs) for both pipeline gas and LNG, the settlement is based on the passing of title and risk to the buyer. Once this occurs PSMs are no longer allowed. Sonatrach is free however to renegotiate a different delivery point in the contract. For new contracts the settlement takes effect immediately. For existing contracts, Sonatrach has to renegotiate and remove restrictive clauses within a reasonable period of time. This is an important achievement in promoting an integrated energy market. The overall conclusion is that the best response for security reasons and to build a cooperative framework with our energy partners is to build a competitive integrated EU market91 combined with a common approach to foreign matters. 89 Once it becomes a full member of the Charter. 90 IP/07/1074. 91 This also the view of the Commission Green Paper and UK White Paper. European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 63 5- Contrasting the energy scenarios in the USA and EU Crisis periods are usually the more appropriate for political action. However, the problem of building competitive markets may be swamped by the “command and control” decisions of the governments about energy supply. Government intervention may, in given circumstances, outweigh the benefits of competition. Let us analyse the present energy scenarios of the USA that do not imply any additional cost to the consumer and the EU´s that raise significantly the price for users. This also raises the problem of the level-playingfield between the European and American firms in terms of competitiveness.92 It is a fact that we need to prepare for a world with scarce oil and prevent global warming. However, the two largest economic blocks in the world are pursuing radically different strategies. The current US energy outlook from 2007 to 2030 is based on world oil price of 50 to 60 USD, at constant 2005 prices.93 According to the base scenario US energy dependency increases from 30%(2005) to 32%(2030); imports of oil products will increase from 22 in 2005 to 28.6 Quadrillions Btu (QBtu) in 2030. And natural gas imports will increase from 4.4 to 6.5 QBtu. The structure of supply changes in favour of solid fuels. Increased electricity generation is mainly based on coal (addition of 156 GW). Consequently, there is an increase in pollution: a 1.5% annual increase in CO2, reaching 8 billion tons a year. Non-hydroelectric renewables represent 3.5 percent of total energy 92 This is a problem for making these policies politically acceptable. At the time that energy prices will increase due to the switch to renewables – in the case of Portugal there are simulations that show an increase of 30 percent to the households – it is very difficult to politicians to show the benefits of introducing more competition: in fact, prices will keep rising. 93 In nominal terms would be about 90-100 USD. One important argument to consider is that if oil prices increase more than this reference scenario there would be quite a number of alternative technologies to produce oil. One possibility is the exploration of extensive reserves of tar sands in Canada. OPEC is certainly aware of those alternatives, although may not be able to control completely short-term prices. European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 64 production in 2005 and it is supposed to increase to 7.5 percent in 2030, with about 80 percent coming from biomass.94 Coal prices are assumed to remain constant in real terms, and natural gas prices to decrease at 1 percent per year (2005-2030). Thus, average delivered electricity prices are assumed to remain constant at 81 USD per MW. Both US and the EU assume the same increase in efficiency in production and use of energy: energy efficiency is due to increase by 1.5% per year. EU energy dependency in the current policy scenario of high use of renewables will increase from 52 percent in the present to 58 percent in 2030, about 6 percentage points below the “business-as-usual” scenario. In the structure of supply, renewables are supposed to increase from around 7 percent in 2007 to 20 percent in 2020, according to EU Council and Parliament targets, and a further 4 points until 2030. 95 Use of solid and liquid fuels decreases dramatically (from 17 and 37 percent in 2007 to 10.7 and 31.4 percent in 2030). Nuclear is also reduced by half (from 14 to 7.5 percent). The increase comes from natural gas (from 24 to 26 percent) and above all from renewables (from 8 to 24 percent). The share of renewables in electricity production increases from 23.5 percent in 2010 to 45.6 percent in 2030. As a result, CO2 emissions decrease by 11 percent in 2030 relative to the 1990 level, and about 9 percent below its present level. Wind generates already half of the non-hydro electricity production (above 40 GW), and its production is expected to more than double until 2030.96 The other large contribution comes from biomass and waste. Recently, the Commission has studied the costs of this scenario. Assuming that oil prices stay at around 48 USD per barrel, and a 25 euro per ton of CO2., the extra cost to reach a 20 percent renewables target, instead of the 12 percent in a business-as-usual scenario, 94 DOE. Annual Energy Outlook, 2007. 95 European Commission. Scenarios on Energy Efficiency and Renewables. European Energy and Transport, July 2006. 96 Representing about 15 percent of total electricity generation. European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 65 would be 24 to 31 billion euros per year.9798 Thus the total additional cost of this renewable intensive policy is a 40-60 billion euros a year, equivalent to 0.5 percent of GDP, which is a substantial burden on the competitiveness of European firms. However, Europe will be contributing to the reduction of global pollution. 6- Conclusions We need to build an integrated not a single market – let us be clear about the objectives. And the process will take a long time, may be more than 20 years. The EU is starting with regional initiatives for integration and progressively will establish the conditions for an EUwide market. In the end, energy prices should reflect costs and we need to avoid multiple charges throughout the transmission networks (peage multiples). What is required for full liberalisation of energy markets in the EU? The European Commission Energy Sector Inquiry concluded that insufficient unbundling, market concentration and lack of interconnection are undermining the energy internal market construction. Further intervention is needed to tackle these paramount issues. However, MS are at very different stages of the process to build competitive markets that normally involve privatization and liberalization, with structural concerns of competition. One of the lessons that governments forget time and time again, and that has been very costly for consumers, is that privatization should be undertaken in tandem with an appropriate industry market structure. Trying to solve structural problems with antitrust is at best a quixotesque exercise. 97 Commission Staff WP. Renewable Energy Roadmap, SEC(2006) 1720/2 using the PRIMES and GREEN- X models. 98 Another study by IFIEC. Promotion of Renewable Energies in EU Member States. October 2003, also calls attention for the decrease in the level of competitiveness of European industry due to the dramatic push for renewables. E.g. in Germany electricity costs are supposed to increase 8.9 euros/MW in 2010. European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 66 In fact, privatization can contribute to an increase in efficiency; the problem is to pass those gains to consumers. In 1997, Newbery and Pollitt99 have conducted a cost-benefit analysis of the liberalization of the England & Wales electricity market done in 1990, concluding that liberalization was beneficial for generation efficiency and for lower emissions. Producers benefited from efficiency gains, through higher profits. However, at the other side of the equation, consumers did not benefited from the cost savings in electricity generation in the prices that were charged. And the main reason was that competition was far from satisfactory. This is the present stage of market liberalization in most EU countries. Liberalisation is beneficial for efficiency and for fuel diversification, where natural gas is becoming an important source of energy for power production which is also environmentally positive. However, market power is precluding that this benefits are shared with consumers. More importantly, market power, in the sense that a full functioning open access regime to networks has not yet been put in place in most MS, is precluding further efficiency gains and passing those efficiency gains to consumers. The evidence for the UK is again revealing. In the late 1990s the government and regulators, dissatisfied with energy prices, forced the two largest producers to divest part of the generation capacity in England and Wales, leading to a decrease in the strategic HHI from 0.306 to 0.189. An econometric study100 based on supply functions shows a shift in those functions towards the marginal cost curves between 1998 and 2003, leading to a decrease in electricity prices of about 20 percent, ceteris paribus.101 Let us now conclude our analysis, giving our answers to the questions raised. 99 Newbery, D., Pollitt, M. (1997). 100 Evans, Joanne and Richard Green. Why did British electricity prices fall after 1998? Memo. July 2005. 101 Surprisingly they found that the introduction of NETA did not have any significant effect on the short- run. European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 67 (1) Is ownership unbundling really necessary, and do the costs outweigh the benefits?102 We have shown that ownership unbundling is necessary but not sufficient. First we have shown, using the study of ETSO, that there are numerous ways for an integrated incumbent to discriminate against third party access. Opening up access to a network requires a long process of regulation. Generally incumbents use long-term contracts, priority of access, pricing strategies, including margin squeeze and all instruments to make it difficult for entrants to have access and to compete in retail markets. Unbundling is usually not enough and requires a detailed Network Code that regulates and controls actions by the incumbent. We have also seen that it is impossible to align investment and shareholders incentives of the network operator and the generator/supplier. Moreover, the evidence shows that by decoupling the network from the generators and suppliers the regulation is able to get significant increases in efficiency from the TSO, resulting from specialization and a more focussed management. Investment levels in the network have increased and quality levels have also improved in the cases of unbundling – in the Portuguese and Italian cases were even measures taken to solve blackout crisis. There are coordination problems and costs. But these were low and solvable. The costs were low because any increase in transmission costs are largely outweighed by the benefits that can be gained in increased competition in generation – these are 4 to 5 times the first in global terms.103 In practice, coordination of 102 We had already defended most of the points expressed here in Portuguese Competition Authority, Refocusing the vision - towards a European energy market, 2004. See also João Lopes e João E. Gata, A Comparative Overview of the Progress Achieved to Date in the Construction of the EC Internal Energy Market, Portuguese Competition Authority for the ECA Working Group, 2005 103 More evidence is provided by the UK case. North Ireland is a clear example. In 1996 prices were about 23% higher than in mainland, and the gap increased to 42% by 1998 because of the lack of competition in generation and the protected long-term contracts with the generators, despite unbundling in 1993: NIE that just contained transmission and distribution was sold to the public in 1993. Four power stations were sold to European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 68 investments have been solved by two mechanisms: (i) system planning that is a joint work of the TSO, regulators and government; and (ii) a market based system of nodal or zonal pricing that has proved to be an efficient scheme in cases that have been implemented. The opinion expressed by the Commission, to accommodate the opposition of Germany and France, is to accept an ISO. Our opinion is that this solution will hardly improve the present situation of legal unbundling due to the arguments just referred. 2) Is there a need to increase interconnector capacity and to regulate their operation? At the European level, the central role of cross-border trade in internal market construction puts an emphasis on the future developments of interconnection capacity and market design. Regional initiatives, like the Iberian market, Nordpool and the trilateral market coupling in France, Belgium and Netherlands are certainly defining the path towards the creation of the EU’s internal energy market. Regional integration, with more interconnection capacity and more efficient rules regulating the use of interconnections, is strategic to create an internal market. But this has to go hand in hand with more effective unbundling. The evidence submitted in this paper proves that incumbents do not have incentives to increase interconnector capacity. Despite the doubts of the effectiveness of the ISO/TSO model, its implementation could lead to Regional Transmission Organizations, covering several countries, like in the US. Congestions costs can certainly be higher but improved coordination between TSOs would be beneficial to trade, since trade opportunities from the existing transmission capacity would be maximized. In fact, Europe has finally realized the importance of this measure for security reasons. Following the November 4, 2006 blackout the following was decided: (i) adoption of legally binding operational security rules by all network operators; (ii) improvement of the cooperation between EU electricity grid operators, presently under the three different companies in 1992. But there was no supply competition as the electricity is sold to the Power Procurement Business of NIE under long-term contracts. (Newberry chapter 6, p. 204). European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 69 ETSO umbrella, which should be publicly accountable for their actions; and (iii) development by the Commission of a framework for the electricity network as part of its energy strategy. Moreover, generation mixes among European countries are quite different – with at one extreme Norway with its full reliance in hydro power and at the other extreme France, where nuclear power is dominant. Following different incentives schemes to renewable sources of energy, and wind in particular, with its unpredictability, there would be additional reserve capacity required. To the extent that generation mixes will not fully converge among EU countries, prices might not fully converge in the long run. However, the mere fact that generations mixes are different underlines the welfare benefits of trade among EU member states. In this sense, reinforcing interconnection capacity among countries is strategic for the success of the internal energy market. However, the amount of interconnection required is not an engineering problem. It is above all a game played by the operators that are able to influence the flows in the interconnector. That is why we need to construct an oligopoly model with strategic behaviour. E.g. in the case of the interconnector Portugal-Spain, a capacity below 30 percent of Portuguese electricity demand was deemed insufficient for an approximate competitive solution. A one size fits all rule in this case is not a solution for the EU-wide market. The rules defined for regulation of interconnectors, based on an auction system and market coupling need now to be effectively enforced. (3) Is there a need to increase structural competition of electricity generators in national markets? The evidence shows that it is not enough to unbundle and create third party access with consumer defranchising. Final energy prices will not decrease without creating enough competition in the segment of generation of electricity. Suppose new suppliers come into the market with a TSO and with consumer defranchising. What we have documented here European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 70 is that traditional incumbents are able through they long association with the network to maintain a privileged relationship and continue to dominate the market. Besides, in all network industries we have witnesses that antitrust rules, like cases against abuses of dominant position, have been helpless to solve these access problems. Once again the British case shows with clear evidence that it was only after structural measures of divestiture and new entrants came into the market that consumer prices started to decrease. In this regard, an important policy to consider is to encourage electricity companies to start trading gas and gas companies entering into electricity production. This policy doubles immediately the number of competitors. Offering dual packages is a powerful competition instrument, especially if there are other competitors in the market. (4) Liberalization of electricity and gas markets have to go hand in hand Electricity liberalization has been boosted by new entry using natural gas as the primary source of energy and the combined cycle gas turbine technology. Entry opportunities were created by the inefficiencies that prevailed in the generation mixes inherited from the monopoly framework. However, after the first entry boom, many new entrants are facing financial losses. Many argue that new investment is lagging, and ask about the sustainability of the market framework, namely in what regards security of supply. Energy Regulators are developing regulatory solutions, like capacity markets, to induce investment. Some argue that “energy only” markets (e.g. with prices only for energy) do not efficiently guide investment decisions – only price spikes periods provide clean incentives to invest. This discussion clearly reflects the Newbery statement that “the central problem of energy liberalization is the tension between the desire for efficient, competitive and unregulated wholesale and retail markets, and long-term investment and security of supply”104. 104 Newbery, David. Regulatory Challenges to European Electricity Liberalisation. The Cambridge-MIT Institute, WP 12. September 2002. European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 71 Closely related is the question of long-term contracts in gas and its duration. The Commission has opened proceedings against Distrigas,105 EDF and Electrabel concerning downstream gas contracts with industrial consumers and electricity generators for the first, and contracts with industrial users of electricity in the rest, under article 11(6) of Regulation 1/2003 and article 2(1) of Regulation 773/2004. Distrigas106 has offered commitments, under article 82, ensuring that 70 percent of gas supplied each year would be subject to contestability. And no contract with industrial users and electricity generators would have a duration over 5 years.107 (5) EU regulators should dedicate more attention to design the appropriate wholesale market at national and EU-wide levels. The English experience shows that marginal single-priced pools have advantages in providing a reference price facilitating contracts and hence entry, and allowing scarcityresponsive capacity payments, although their transparency and repeated auction structure facilitate collusion. Newbery claims rightly that problems of gaming and collusion fall as the number of participants increase and the length of time for which bids must hold also increase. Efficient trade requires efficient pricing and allocation of transmission, best achieved by nodal pricing along the PJM standard market design. The next best solution is market coupling as practised in the Nordic market. Local power exchanges would then send their aggregate bid-offer curves to an international clearing stage, which would allocate transmission between countries along the synchronized auctions proposed by ETSO. Local 105 Memo 06/197 of May 2006. 106 IP/07/490 of April 11, 2007. 107 If these commitments were broken the Commission may impose a fine of 10 percent of total worldwide turnover without the need to prove an infringement of antitrust rules. European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 72 power exchanges would then schedule the corresponding international flows and clear local markets. Zones can be subdivided further if internal congestion levels are high. (6) Do we need new merger policies and merger regulation? Merger control, under the current merger wave that is leading to a significant restructuring of the European energy sector, is critical to the success of the internal market. A coherent approach should be put in place. First, criteria and methodology based on CRD and simulation models need to be implemented due to the complexity of energy markets. Second, the analysis should be tested with different geographical markets: national, regional and EU-wide markets, and if it fails in any of those should be rejected. Third, the 2/3 rule should be qualified for network industries, and ensure a consistent approach both at Commission and National Authorities level. It has also been widely proved that a policy of national energy champions, like all types of national champions, lowers social and consumer welfare. Moreover, there is a serious levelplaying-field between mergers of firms controlled directed or indirectly by some MS and private firms in other MS.108 We also proved that it is a mistake to create European energy champions, and that this policy will be a major step-back in building a EU-wide competitive market. (7) Should we create European energy champions in order to counteract the rising of energy giants in supplier countries? If it is wrong to build European energy champions from an internal perspective, it is even worse from an external perspective. This is one of the main points this paper makes. (8) Should there be a EU regulator? 108 Are we ready to adopt a decision that a public enterprise or enterprise controlled directly or indirectly cannot acquire a private enterprise in another MS? This rule would solve the problems of sovereign controlled funds and also third countries enterprises controlled by their respective states. European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 73 The Commission is proposing the creation of a EU-wide regulator which will have the mandate to regulate interconnectors, and specially the interconnection between regional markets, with a view to build a EU-wide integrated market. It could also take some of the functions of the US FERC. (9) What is the role of the Commission? The Commission is currently working in the Third Energy Package. However, the road to a political consensus is becoming very treacherous. Again, reaching such a consensus will lead to a “minimum common denominator”, which would be far from even a second best solution. But sometimes creating the foundations at the technical level can be even more important. E.g. regional integration of power exchanges (PXs), agreements among TSOs to integrate balancing markets to increase liquidity and enhance security, are effectively contributing more to market integration than political consensus-building. On the other hand, enforcement of antitrust rules could have an important signalling effect. The Commission seems inclined to let each country choose its own way: TSO or ISO, and then try to enforce in a more vigorous way articles 81 and 82 rules.109 But to go even further it can also use article 86, and apply “structural remedies” given to the Commission by Regulation 1/2003. (10) Competition can be increased by introducing suppliers and traders and enabling consumers to choose freely among suppliers. However defranchising consumers presuppose prices determined by the market mechanism, and the governments should refrain from regulating the final price. Switching mechanisms have to created and switching costs reduced to a minimum. Competition through market access puts pressure on consumer prices as the experience of UK shows. In the UK where more than 50 percent of the consumers have switched 109 After the Sector Inquiry the Commission launched a series of unannounced inspections at the premises of major energy companies in Germany on May 2006 and several antitrust cases have been initiated. European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 74 supplier, the data shows that incumbents with the highest prices have indeed experienced the largest switch of consumers to competitors. (11) Consumers should be charged the market price, hopefully in a competitive market, but in real-time The California crisis has clearly shown that politicians and regulators have to let the market work.110 The recent supply crisis in the UK after 2004 and in contrast with the Italian experience also prove this point. However, we are aware that European politicians with a long tradition of government intervention are prone to fix final consumer prices creating 110 A number of famous economists has rightly put the problem about the California crisis Manifesto on the California Electricity Crisis. January 30, 2003. European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 75 large “consumer budget deficits”, instead of the traditional public sector budget deficits, that sooner or later the users would have to pay painfully. Besides, the distortions have led to market disruptions (when prices do not adjust then rationing has to come in) and bankruptcies of traders making the liberalisation process more difficult. (12) We need a comprehensive and sequence approach for energy reform. A strategy based on establishing open access to networks and trade liberalization would establish, at the minimum, the following comprehensive policy package for integration: (i) Ownership unbundling between generation and transmission, in order to open access for any generator or trader; (ii) Establish independent regulators in every country. Tarification and regulation harmonization, in order to integrate the markets throughout the EU; (iii) Establish appropriate regulation for interconnector management and congestion management in all networks in order to enable trade throughout the networks; (iv) Guarantee conditions for competition at retail level in all Member States; and (v) Establish good Governance in the access by writing Network Codes for all Member States. This is largely the position adopted by the UK government in its White Paper: European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 76 111 We differ in a fundamental way. We have demonstrated that all those measures are necessary, but we also need (a) to adopt, at national and Union levels, structural measures to create a more competitive market in the generation of electricity and in the import of gas. Divestitures, VPPs, gas releases and other measures would need to be implemented; (b) a stricter merger policy to buttress these structural remedies; and (c) to mandate minimum capacity of interconnectors based on economic models of strategic behaviour. And a final thought about coherence and timing. We have seen that due to the political decision to increase dramatically the share of renewables in the energy supply, energy prices are going to increase substantially in the EU. It would be difficult to explain to consumers the benefits of competition when they see prices increasing. Antitrust policy once again is only part of the picture: we need a comprehensive overall energy policy that increases social welfare for the present and future generations. 111 They also advice the establishment of the Office of the Energy Observatory to collate and monitor data on energy supply and demand across the EU, in the short and medium term, and identify the potential need for future investment European Energy Markets Abel M. Mateus 77
© Copyright 2024