Subprime Predatory Lending: How to Protect Consumers without Harming the Market? Par Anibal Zarate, Doctorant à l'Université Panthéon-Assas Paris II, Promotion 20042005. Predatory lending abuses, particularly rampant in the subprime residential mortgage market1, have not only shadowed the positive results obtained in granting low and moderate homeowners with some of the same financial options and resources that had been previously reserved for prime borrowers2 , but equally constitute today’s most pressing consumer protection issue in the United States. It appears, however, that predatory lending practices were not a major topic for federal and state bank regulators until recent problems erupted in the subprime mortgage sector3 (i.e., deterioration in credit quality, continuing rise in mortgage delinquencies and foreclosures4); to the extent that this issue happens today to have been left almost exclusively to the activity of attorney generals, law enforcement agencies, and private litigation. In the absence of a single definition, regulators, industry and advocates employ the term individually to refer to different practices that fall between proportionate risk-based credit pricing and blatant fraud5. Although difficult to define, predatory lending does target certain disadvantage classes of borrowers6. Whether affecting the elderly, or minorities, predatory lending creates social problems as well as market disruptions, and may also constitute a violation of our civil rights laws7 . As more Americans continue to lose their homes, the perception that predatory lending is an increasing problem intensifies; despite competition and selfregulation in the industry. And, although markets tend to self-correct, the immediate effect on consumer protection of the ongoing demand by investors of complex structured credit instruments to originators to employ tighter underwriting standards and improve loan quality remains byzantine. This comment briefly looks at the efficacy of current federal and state legislative and regulatory responses to protect consumers: What states and federal financial regulators do to monitor and prevent predatory lending abuses in the mortgage sector? Is their activity effective in combating such practices or are lenders successfully evading both oversight and accountability? An overview of existing remedies is therefore necessary, prior to understanding alternative solutions to current challenges. I. Existing remedies for subprime predatory lending Enforcement of consumer protection statutes represents, together with private litigation, a traditional response to predatory lending abuses8. As part of its mandate to protect consumers9, the FTC response to the growing predatory lending problem in the subprime market encompasses a wide-range of activities such as increasing, individually or through coordinated efforts with other federal agencies and the states, enforcement of section 5 of the Federal Trade Commission Act (FTC Act)10. The Commission also enforces several laws specifically governing lending practices, like the Truth in Lending Act (TILA)11, the Home Ownership and Equity Protection Act (HOEPA)12, and the Equal Credit Opportunity Act (ECOA)13. Likewise, the Office of the Comptroller of the Currency (OCC), the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (Board), the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC) and the Office of the Thrift Supervision (OTS), enforce section 5 of the FTC Act under section 8 of the Federal Deposit Insurance Act14. In addition to their enforcement duties, federal and state regulators like the OTS, the Board, and the FDIC have issued a broad array of supervisory guidance to the institutions under their respective jurisdictions on the subject of deceptive or unfair acts or practices. They have notably issued principles-based guidance describing safety and soundness and consumer protection standards for non traditional mortgages, such as interest-only and negative-amortization mortgages15. Similarly, in July 2007, federal financial agencies issued a final interagency statement on subprime mortgage lending to address problems relating to certain adjustable rate mortgages (ARMs)16 products that can cause payment shock. The main purpose of this guidance, in fact, was to set standards that banks should follow to ensure that borrowers obtain loans that they can afford and repay and that give them the opportunity to refinance without payment penalty for a reasonable period before the interest rate resets17. To this end, an interagency statement on loss mitigation strategies for servicers of residential mortgages, which followed a previous statement encouraging federally regulated institutions and state-supervised entities to work-out solutions with borrowers at risk of default18, urged servicers of securitized mortgages to review the governing documents for the securitization trusts in order to determine the full extend of their authority to pursue strategies such as loan modifications or deferral of payments19 . As far as misleading advertising is concern, the OTS has, for instance, prohibited savings associations from using advertisements or other representations that are inaccurate or misrepresent the services or contracts offered20. In turn, the NCUA has proscribed federally insured credit unions from using any advertising or promotional material that is inaccurate, misleading, or deceptive in any way concerning its products, services, or financial condition21. The supervisory activity of federal financial regulators has also been the object of a considerable number of speeches and testimonies by members of these agencies22. As concern of accountability persists among regulators, a higher scrutiny surfaces in their remarks on how they have dealt with predatory lending abuses, especially when they describe how they have evaluated institutions’ securitization activities in the subprime mortgage market. One main concern of federal financial regulators has certainly been to improve the mortgage information consumers receive, so they could be in a better position to make decisions that are in their best interest. The FTC and several federal financial regulators have therefore intensified educational programs oriented to consumers to help them avoid predatory lending practices. Beyond the actions underway at the regulatory agencies, some state23 and local24 initiatives were designed to control unscrupulous brokers and lenders that originate predatory loans. Nevertheless, since the “privileged” 25 raters (Standard & Poor’s, Moody’s and Fitch) paid particular attention to the impact of such predatory lending statutes on RMBS pools, and refused to rate transactions containing mortgage loans from some jurisdictions; states and local communities were compelled to standardize their predatory lending initiatives26. Were privileged raters putting aside general interest, while advocating for investors? Many commentators have denounced the lack of transparency and independence of the raters, as well as the negative impact their response is having on the public interest. Accordingly, they call for a limitation of the raters’ excessive power by mainly taking away their regulatory status, so as to enhance competition in the sector, whilst submitting them to greater regulation all together27. However, criticism has not only risen with regard to “privileged” raters and regulators of rating agencies. A large number of commentators have, as a matter of fact, complained that neglect and relaxation of consumer protection statutes and regulation has emboldened a portion of personal finance industry to engage in a variety of abusive, misleading, and unfair practices28. As described, recent coordinated supervisory guidance activity was in reality aimed to address these critiques. But, was it too little, too late? And yet, are agency guidelines merely a cluster of suggestions as to how lenders might do a better job not appearing like “predators”29 ? This soft-law could have a positive impact in the credit industry such as raising the quality of underwriting practices of all lenders to a uniformly high standard; albeit supervisory and public and private enforcement activity remain vital. As enforcement and supervisory activity produce results, lenders will effectively find themselves implementing principles and guidelines in order to avoid both government action and private litigation, along with improving the quality of the services and products they provide in a competitive market that is continuing to readjust. As we suggested early, some commentators may argue that predatory lending practices have not declined, despite the positive results produced by enforcement and supervisory actions30. As for us, since the situation was due in part to the sharp growth in the subprime mortgage industry, it is likely to ask whether such arguments are still valid considering the current financial turmoil and housing market down turn. II. Which response for current challenges? In large part as a result on these complaints, momentum is building on several fronts to standardize the operations of the subprime mortgage market, mainly through federal regulation and legislation. For this purpose, the federal financial agencies have issued regulations implementing such laws. The Federal Reserve has, for example, issued regulations regarding HMDA loan price information and, in cooperation with the OTS, produced a revised version of the Consumer Handbook on Adjustable Rate Mortgages (CHARM booklet)31. Broadly speaking, a series of controversial federal regulations have already preempted the application of tighter state consumer protection laws directed at the prevention of predatory lending abuses to a large series of lending institutions, in particular to national banks and thrifts32. Some of these rules have though created legal and regulatory ambiguity and have the unintended effect of substantially reducing legitimate subprime lending. In fairness, federal regulators have levied persuasive arguments justifying their decisions as necessary in an increasingly national financial services marketplace33. Beyond the vivid legal debate involving the federal government’s constitutional authority to regulate financial institutions34, partisans of federal preemptive regulation argue that federal regulation is necessary in order to harmonize the rules, standard of quality and practices used by thrift institutions, banks and their agents. In their view, strengthening and increasing federal regulation would simply bring 50 individual mortgage markets into a one more efficient system; successfully ending with the distressing uncertainty and inconsistency in the current model of regulation35. On the contrary, opponents of federal preemption challenge the efficacy of the regulatory apparatus of the United States to regulate the abusive and predatory practices of depository institutions themselves. They fear federal regulators have only token intentions to police actors lending through tenuous, shifting, and volatile agency relationships36. But, even if federal regulation containing bright lines favors with the welfare of American people and not with that one of the banking industry, the vagueness of the term “predatory lending” could lead federal financial agencies to an erroneous regulatory response, which could significantly harm the subprime mortgage market and, since rules are a more rigid tool than principle-based guidelines, any foreseeable adjustment or remedy will be arduous to operate. In any event, it is expected that the compliance costs and burdens associated with the myriad of state and local predatory lending laws that have been adopted, as well as the ongoing assignee liability debate37 will continue to exert pressure for federal action. In the same vein, if Congress acts to arbitrarily freeze mortgage interest rates to alleviate foreclosures, lenders will start guarding themselves against the chance that lawmakers might do the same thing again someday38. To avoid scarce and expensive mortgages in the future, a legislative response should instead focus in reforming consumer protection laws and in modernizing unsuccessful programs, like programs currently administered by the Federal Housing Administration (FHA)39. In turn, the two government-sponsored enterprises (GSEs) could not only apply tighter standards to their current policy consisting in refusing to purchase loans that contain certain terms they deem abusive, such as harsh prepayment penalties, but equally require loans originators to observe principle-based guidance40. Any hasty response would produce the opposite effect; aggravating the investors’ loss of confidence in an already largely shaken market. Commentators have also worried that federal preemption of various aspects of the consumer finance system will undermine a reform of consumer protection laws41. In the United States alone, there are significant federal, state, and private consumer protection, enforcement, and education mechanisms. In our view, since resources devoted to the problem are scarce and usually target particular post hoc systems, regulators must seek schemes that influence unscrupulous lenders’ behavior at minimal incremental cost to attain the maximum effect upon the predatory lending problem42. Conversely, allowing judges to tear up and rewrite loan contracts not only raises serious constitutional questions regarding the autonomy of private parties in contracting, but will equally increase mortgage interest rates; because the risk of loan losses inevitably will increase as mortgage contracts become junk43. While consumer information is an instrument for party autonomy, public responses limiting the autonomy of private parties to determine the content of a contract must be constitutionally justified so as to complete, not exclude, market solutions for consumers information problems. As a result, policymakers should continue to advantage their activity in writing principle-based guidance and interpreting existing regulations; in reviewing bank compliance with such regulations; in investigating complaints from the public about fulfillment of consumer protection laws; and in conducting community development and educational consumer programs. In doing so, they must improve data collection and share relevant and accurate data analysis of mortgage delinquencies with Congress, community groups and enforcement authorities44 to efficiently and effectively target resources to areas most in need. As more researchers and academics study and report about predatory mortgage lending abuses, we expect research and articles to assist in fueling and defining the ongoing public policy debate in a positive way45. -1/ See Dan Immergluck, "Stark Differences: Explosion of the Subprime Industry and Racial Hyper-segmentation in Home Equity Lending", in Housing Policy in the New Millennium: Conference Proceedings, 257, 259 (Susan M. Wachter & R. Leo Penne eds., 2001) at 237. 2. No one doubts the positive results reached through the expansion of the subprime mortgage market over the last two decades. Indeed, “while in 2006, 69 percent of households owned their homes; in 1995, just 65 percent did”; Remarks by Chairman of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve, Ben S. Bernanke, at the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago’s 43rd Annual Conference on Bank Structure and Competition, Chicago, Illinois, May 17, 2007. Literature containing a detailed explanation on the impact of the subprime mortgage market on the access of low and moderate income borrowers to residential mortgages, credit card and other consumer lending is considerable, See e.g., Cathy Lesser Mansfield, “The Road to Subprime “Hel” was Paved with Good Congressional Intentions: Usury Deregulation and The Subprime Home Equity Market”, in South Carolina Law Review, Spring 2000, 51 S.C. L. Rev. 473; 3. The practice of selling mortgages to investors may have played a role in the weakening of underwriting standards. The securitization of residential mortgages is in fact attractive to loan originators because these mortgages themselves are not easily traded in the secondary market and, since each mortgage usually has its own unique terms and risks, secondary markets rely on standardization to reduce transaction costs and expensive evaluation. Investors have therefore become quite comfortable investing in residential mortgage-backed securities (RMBS). Cathy Lesser Mansfield, supra note 2, at. 531; An empirical analysis conducted by Yuliya Demyanyk and Otto Van Hemert document that the poor performance of the vintage 2006 loans was not confined to a particular segment of the subprime mortgage market. The study shows that during the dramatic growth of the subprime (securitized) mortgage market, the quality of the market deteriorated dramatically. It concludes that subprime market experienced a classic lending boom-bust scenario with rapid market growth, loosening underwriting standards, deteriorating loan performance, and decreasing risk premiums. Yuliya Demyanyk and Otto Van Hemert, Understanding the Subprime Mortgage Crisis, February 4, 2008, Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1020396; A deceleration in the housing market, together with the moderation in economic growth, has also contributed to produce some deterioration in credit quality. Remarks by Chairman of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve, Ben S. Bernanke, at the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago’s 43rd Annual Conference on Bank Structure and Competition, supra note 2 at 2. 4. According to the Board, mortgage delinquency and foreclosures rates have increased considerably over the past few months. At the end of last year, more than one in five of the roughly 3.6 million outstanding subprime adjustable-rate mortgages (ARMs) were seriously delinquent, meaning they were either in foreclosure or ninety days or more past due. Lenders initiated roughly 1-1/2 million foreclosures last year, up from an average of 950,000 in the preceding two years and more than one-half of the foreclosure starts in 2007 were on subprime mortgages; Speech by Chairman of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve, Ben S. Bernanke, at the National Community Reinvestment Coalition Annual Meeting, Washington, D.C. March 14, 2008. 5. Certain practices have been consistently identified as predatory lending, such as, excessive fees, loan flipping, excessive interest rates, single-premium credit insurance, lending without regard to ability to repay, prepayment penalties, balloon payments, packing and steering. See e.g., U.S. General Accounting Office (GAO), Consumer Protection: Federal and State Agencies Face Challenges in Combating Predatory Lending 21 (2004), available at: http://www.gao.gov/new.items/d04280.pdf. Likewise, consumer advocacy groups complain of bait and switch advertising in which lenders unilaterally change contract terms shortly after origination. Finally, the increasing use of mandatory arbitration clauses and waivers of the right to pursue remedies in a class action may deprive consumers of a realistic opportunity to create cease law inhibiting these sharp practices. Christopher L. Peterson, “Preemption, Agency Cost Theory, and Predatory Lending by Banking Agents: Are Federal Regulators Biting off more than they can Chew?”, in American University Law Review, February 2007, 56 AMULR 515, at 518. 6. More than half of all loans in predominantly African-American and Hispanic borrowers together make up about 6% of all prime conventional refinance mortgages and 17% of subprime refinance mortgages. And more than a half of all loans in predominantly African-American communities are subprime, compared to only 9% of loans in predominantly white communities. U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development (HUD), Unequal Burden: Income and Racial Disparities in Subprime Lending in America (2000), electronic copy available at http://hud.gov/library/bookself18/pressrel/subprime.html/. 7. See e.g., John Rao, “Fair Housing: Predatory Loan Practices”, in Association of Trial Lawyers of America (ATLA), ATLA Annual Convention Reference Materials, Volume 1, Civil Rights Section, July 2001, 1Ann.2001 ATLA-CLE 349 (2001). For illustrative purposes, in March 2000 the Commission in conjunction with the United States Department of Justice (DOJ) and the Department of Housing and Urban Development (HUD), announced a settlement with Delta Funding Corporation, a national subprime mortgage lender. The complaint alleged that higher broker fees were charged to African American females than to white males in violation to of the ECOA and the Fair Housing Act, 42, U.S.C. §§ 3601-3619. See United States v. Delta Funding Corp. and Delta Financial Corp., Civ. Action No. 001872 (E.D.N.Y. April 2000). 8. Currently, U.S. agencies approach consumer protection from three perspectives: First, the perpetrator perspective via direct enforcement of consumer protection and fraud laws and the combat of specific schemes. Secondly, the individual consumer perspective through the provision of tools for self-protection and consumer education. Finally, the third approach defining a protected consumer group. For a detailed description of these mechanisms, an analysis of their effectiveness and an alternative scheme of consumer protection see David Adam Friedman, “Reinventing Consumer Protection”, in DePaul University Law Review, Fall 2007, 57 DePaul L. Rev. 45. 9. The Federal Trade Commission (FTC) has an extensive competence on antitrust and consumer protection issues in nearly all segments of the economy, including jurisdiction over most non-bank lenders. See, e.g., 15 U.S.C. § 45(a); 15 U.S.C. § 1607. In practice, the FTC has increased its enforcement actions, most of them concluded in settlement agreements (i.e., in the area of “packing”, loans sold with credit insurance, the FTC settled in 1997 a case against the Money Tree, a Georgiabased consumer finance lender. See The Money Tree, 123 F.T.C. 1187 (1997)). 10. Institutions offering mortgages by means of predatory lending practices face an elevated risk that their conduct will violate section 5 of the FTC Act, which prohibits unfair or deceptive acts or practices in or affecting commerce; See, 15 U.S.C. § 45(a). 11. 15 U.S.C. § 1601-1667(f); In July 1999, as part of “Operation Home Inequity”, the Commission settled cases against seven subprime mortgage lenders, including Barry Cooper, a California-based creditor, for violations of TILA, including HOEPA, and section 5 of the FTC Act. See consent judgment and order, F.T.C v. Barry Cooper Properties, No. 99-07782 WDK (Ex) (C.D. Cal. July 30, 1999). In F.T.C. v. Fleet Fin. Inc., the Commission settled charges that Fleet Finance Inc. had failed to provide accurate, timely disclosures of the costs and terms of home equity loans to consumers and had failed to provide accurately consumers with information about their right to cancel their transactions. The settlement provides for $ 1.3 million in consumer redress as well as injunctive relief. See F.T.C. v. Fleet Fin. Inc., C3899 (F.T.C. October 5, 1999). 12. 15 U.S.C. § 1639. HOEPA violations often include failure to provide required disclosures and the use of prohibited terms. 13. 15 U.S.C. § 1691. The Equal Credit Opportunity Act (ECOA) has three important aspects. First, it sets out a general rule that creditors cannot discriminate in any way against any applicant in any stage of a credit transaction on any of the following grounds: race, color, religion, national origin, sex, marital status, age, public assistance income, or exercise of rights under the Consumer Credit Protection Act. Second, the ECOA sets out various specific actions which creditors must or must not take, as well as factors that may not be considered in determining credit worthiness. Third, the ECOA imposes certain notice requirements on the creditor when the loan application is approved, denied or when the creditor makes a counteroffer. Moreover, bait and switch tactics can state a claim under the ECOA. Finally, the ECOA definition of creditor includes assignees as long as they regularly participate in the decision of whether or not to extend credit. 14. 12 U.S.C. § 1818. 15. See Interagency Guidance on Nontraditional Mortgage Product Risks of October 4, 2006, available at: Federal Register/ Vol. 71, No. 192, Wednesday, October 4, 2006/Notices 58609. 16. According to the regulators’ final statement on subprime mortgage lending, ARM products generally offered to subprime mortgage borrowers have one or more of the following characteristics: (1) Limited or no documentation of borrowers’ income; (2) Low initial payments based on a fixed introductory rate that expires after a short period and then adjusts to a variable index rate plus a margin for the remaining term of the loan; (3) Very high or no limits on how much the payment amount or the interest rate may increase on reset dates; (4) Substantial prepayment penalties and/or prepayment penalties that extend beyond the initial fixed interest rate period; (5) Product features likely to result in frequent refinancing to maintain an affordable monthly payment. See Final Interagency Guidance-Statement on Subprime Mortgage Lending, of July 10, 2007, available at: Federal Register / Vol. 72, No. 131 / Tuesday, July 10, 2007 / Notices 37569. 17. See Final Interagency Guidance-Statement on Subprime Mortgage Lending; of July 10, 2007 supra note 16. 18. See Interagency Statement on Working with Borrowers; of April 17, 2007; See OTS Memorandum for Chief Executive Officers of April 17, 2007 regarding the Interagency Statement on Working with Mortgage Borrowers. 19. See OTS See OTS Memorandum for Chief Executive Officers of September 4, 2007 regarding the Interagency Statement on Loss Mitigation Strategies for Servicers of Residential Mortgages. 20/ See OTS regulation 12 CFR 563.27 21. See NCUA regulation 12 CFR 740.2 22. See e.g., Speech by Vice Chairman Donald L. Kohn of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve, Condition of the U.S. Banking System; before the Committee on Banking, Housing and Urban Affairs, U.S. Senate March 4, 2008; Speech by Governor Randall S. Kroszner of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve; at the Consumer Bankers Association 2007 Fair Lending Conference, Washington D.C., November 5, 2007; 23. See Ohio Senate Bill 185 effective January 1, 2007 (S.B. 185, 126th Gen. Assem., Reg. Sess. (Ohio 2006)); See Rhode Island Home Loan Protection Act effective December 31, 2006. The Rhode Island legislation provides for assignee liability for high-cost home loans. 2006 R.I. Pub. Laws ch. 569 (to be codified at R.I. GEN. LAWS §§ 34-25.2-1 to 34-25.2-15); See the Tennessee Home Loan Protection Act, 2006 Tenn. Pub. Acts ch. 801 (H.B. 3597) (Codified at Tenn. Code. Ann. §§ 45-20-101 – 45-20-111 (West 2000 and Supp. 2006)). Under the Tennessee Act, assignees of a high-cost loan are subject to all claims and defenses that the borrower could assert against the lender unless the assignee can demonstrate due diligence. 24. See Montgomery County, Md., Bill No. 36-04 (enacted Nov. 29, 2005), available at: http://www.montgomerycountymd.gov/content/council/pdf/bill/2004/3604.pdf. 25. The term “privileged” describes the fact that the dominant rating agencies enjoy privileged regulatory status as nationally recognized statistical rating organizations. For a detailed analysis of the use of the term see e.g., David Reiss, “Subprime Standardization: How Rating Agencies Allow Predatory Lending to Flourish in the Secondary Mortgage Market”, in Florida State University, summer 2006, 33 Fla. St. U. L. Rev. 985. 26. This weakened the standards some states had taken. All of the “privileged” raters review such statutes in particular to determine whether they are ambiguous, allow for assignee liability, or allow for unquantifiable damages. In states where there is both assignee liability and unquantifiable damages, some of the privileged raters have refused to rate RMBS transactions, banning, in consequence, loans originated in such jurisdictions, or have implemented expensive credit enhancements to achieve the ratings desired by the securitizers of pools having loans from such jurisdictions. Since the secondary market injects great amounts of resources to the subprime industry, these actions can effectively shut down the entire subprime residential mortgage market of a state that passes strong predatory lending legislation. For an in depth analysis on the problem; See; David Reiss, supra note 25. 27. See e.g., David Reiss, supra note 25 at 1013; See Donald C. Lampe; Predatory Lending Initiatives, Legislation and Litigation: Federal Regulation, State Law and Preemption, Symposium: Predatory Lending, Part Three, Consumer Finance Law Quarterly Report, winter, 2002, 56 Consumer Fin. L.Q. Rep. 78. 28. See e.g., Helen P. Howell, Inattentive Regulators Make It Easy for Biased Mortgage Lenders, Association of Trial Lawyers of America, ATLA Annual Convention Reference Materials, Volume 2, Civil Rights, 2 Ann. 2006 ATLA-CLE 1465 (2006); Kathleen C. Engel & Patricia A. McCoy, “Turning A Blind Eye: Wall Street Finance of Predatory Lending”; in Fordham Law Review, vol. 75, 101, electronic copy of this paper is available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=910378, at 117. 29. Part of the problem is that the rules that apply to banks and thrifts do not apply to mortgage brokers and mortgage bankers. Most of the worst abuse was indeed perpetrated by unregulated or virtually unregulated entities outside the federally insured regulatory depository institutions. For a detailed description of this issue, see e.g., Christopher L. Peterson, supra note 5. 30. See e.g., Ronald H. Silverman; “Toward Curing Predatory Lending”, Banking Law Journal, Vol. 122, pp. 483-669, June 2005. See also, Helen P. Howell, supra note 28 at 2; David Reiss, supra note 25. 31. The revised version of the CHARM booklet mainly includes additional information about non traditional mortgage products, including hybrid ARMs. 32. See e.g., Christopher L. Peterson, supra note 5, at 515. 33. See OTS Legal Opinion on Ratings of Structured Finance Transactions of February 20, 2008. 34. For illustrative purposes see, Eric C. Bartley, “And Federal Regulation for All: Federally Regulating the Mortgage Banking Industry”, in Michigan State Law Review, summer 2006, 2006 Mich. St. L. Rev. 477. 35. See e.g., Eric C. Bartley, supra note 34 at 486. 36. See e.g., Christopher L. Peterson, supra note 5, at 528. 37. As private litigation is concern, a federal legislative solution would have to carefully deal with the ongoing legal question regarding the holder in due curse (HDC) doctrine. Should we grant a civil action against the assignee? Permitting claims against assignees could aid in general policing of abusive loans, as well as benefit investors by operating as a signaling mechanism for the bond market. For a detailed analysis of this question see Siddhartha Venkatesan, “Abrogating the Holder in Due Course Doctrine in Subprime Mortgage Transactions to more effectively Police Predatory Lending”, in NYU Journal of Legislation and Public Policy, 2003-2004, 7 N.Y.U. J. Legis. & Pub. Pol'y 177. 38. Alan Reynolds, Housing Horrors, this article appeared in the New York Post on February 26, 2008; available at: http://www.cato.org/pub_display.php?pub_id=9247. 39. Congress could allow, for instance, more flexibility to the FHA to design new products and encourage it to collaborate with the private sector to expedite the refinancing of creditworthy subprime borrowers facing large resets. 40. Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac are the largest purchases of residential mortgages on the secondary market and are becoming more significant players in the subprime market. See e.g., Fannie Mae, Announcement 04-06, at 3 (Sept. 28, 2004), electronic copy available at: http://www.mortgagebankers.org/resident/2004/fannie-04-06.pdf; Letter from Michael C. May, Senior Vice President, Freddie Mac, to All Freddie Mac Sellers and Servicers (Nov. 26, 2003), available at:http://www.freddiemac.com/sell/selbultn/112603indltr.html. 41. See e.g., Christopher L. Peterson, supra note 5, at 516. 42. Given the fact that consumer protection has been a difficult, perpetual challenge for U.S. policymakers and institutions, David Adam Friedman proposes a mechanism based on selecting a random group for protection, so as to increase the risk of the perpetrator’s action. In his opinion, policymakers may select a group according to any of three criteria: unique vulnerability, reticence to report victimization, or susceptibility to specific schemes. In unlocking the power of the citizenry in transactions that are often hidden from sight and in situations where enforcement can be excessively expensive, policymakers could effectively respond to fraud; David Adam Friedman, supra note 8, at 65. With regards to the application of such mechanism to predatory lending practices, the definition and random assignment of special status of an “invisible” group of subprime borrowers could certainly be an alternative, although it should be done carefully as to increase abusive lenders’ risk, but up to a point where legitimate subprime mortgage lending practices would not be affected. 43. Alan Reynolds, supra note 36. 44. Some States and Federal Authorities have even initiated criminal investigations on the control activity and participation of the raters, mortgage lenders and investments banks in the current “credit crunch”. See e.g., “Subprime: La Justice de New York s’intéresse aux pratiques des banques”, Les Echos du 06, 12, 2007. 45. A Treasury's Blueprint for Financial Regulatory Reform (TBFRR) was indeed released on March, 2008. This initiative seeks to increase the powers of some of main federal banking agencies to oversee banking, market stability, and consumer and investor protection. For a detailed description of the content and objectives of this initiative see Remarks by Secretary Henry M. Paulson, Jr. on Blueprint for Regulatory Reform of March 31, 2008. Electronic copy available at: http://www.treasury.gov/press/releases/hp897.htm. For comments on this initiative see, Washington Post staff writers David Cho, Neil Irwin and Carrie Johnson, “Long Fight Ahead for Treasury Blueprint. Consumer Groups, Agencies Criticize Regulatory Overhaul”, in the Washington Post, Sunday, March 30, 2008; Page A01.
© Copyright 2024