www.madariaga.org How to Switch from Jobless Growth to Growthless Jobs? Madariaga Report – 21 February 2012 Threatened by the constraints of austerity and the fears of a new credit crunch, the European economy seems unlikely to robustly recover over the next decade. In an era of growing unemployment, the consensus of the younger generations for European integration – increasingly perceived as being at odds with social justice and the European social model – is under growing strain. Is there room for further macroeconomic stimulus? If not, what kind of new paradigms should be found for structural reforms? A Citizen's Controversy with Stefano Scarpetta Deputy Director for Employment, Labour and Social Affairs, OECD. Joep Konings Professor at the Faculty of Business and Economics, Catholic University Leuven. Moderated by: Pierre Defraigne Executive Director, Madariaga – College of Europe Foundation. Reporter: Chiara Galluccio 14, Avenue de la Joyeuse Entrée B-1040, Brussels, Belgium Tel: +32 2 209 62 10 E-mail: [email protected] Launching the debate, Pierre Defraigne remarked that since Europe will be faced with a zero growth scenario for decades, the need to effectively fight against joblessness in a context of huge private and public debts and of the deficit of eurozone governance is the most challenging issue the EU has to face. *** Stefano Scarpetta began by analysing the impact of the financial and economic crisis on the labour market of OECD countries1 as well as the countries’ responses. The labour markets of the OECD countries reacted very differently to the financial and economic crisis, with different adjustment patterns in the recession and subsequent recovery. The different adjustment patterns were observable across OECD countries as well as within the EU. For instance, while the output decline in Spain was accompanied by large job losses, in Germany much of the adjustment took the form of a reduction in working hours; actually, employment in Germany slightly increased even during the recession. Other countries privileged wage adjustments, or followed a mixed policy, such as Canada, based on reducing both worked hours (labour input) and employment (jobs reduction). The feeble recovery from the 2008-09 recession had a limited impact on job creation in many OECD countries, as recorded by the OECD unemployment rate - 8.2% in December 2011 -, which is still very close to its historical peak. Moreover, there is a serious risk that what was initially a cyclical increase in unemployment will become structural: the, the share of long-term 1 List of OECD countries: www.oecd.org/document/58/0,2340,en_2649_201185_1889 402_1_1_1_1,00.html. 1 unemployment (meaning people unemployed for 12 months or more) is increasing rapidly, with inevitable consequences in terms of human capital deterioration and discouragement. Scarpetta explained that some of the very long-term unemployed workers are at risk of indefinitely dropping out of the labour market because of their skills deterioration and/or the discouraging feelings that derive from inactivity. In many OECD countries, a large portion of the long-term unemployed have been out of a job for one-two years and in many case they still are. Another set of alarming data concerns rising youth unemployment, with rates three to four times higher than the adult unemployment rates. Indeed, the analysis of the job losses among different groups – classified by gender, age, education and work status – shows that the youth have been hardest hit during the crisis, with an average job loss rate calculated over the 2008-2011 period of 13.3% in the EU15 and of 11.4% in the United Sates. Temporary, precarious and atypical workers have also been strongly hit by the crisis, with an average job loss rate of 2.4% in the EU15 compared to 0.6% for selfemployed workers. Given the rather gloom shortterm macroeconomic projections, the outlook for the labour market is not very encouraging; in a number of EU countries, in particular, it is difficult to expect significant improvement in the labour market before 2013. Scarpetta went on by explaining that, despite the fact that a stumbling economic recovery makes policy choices arduous and complex – since governments have to tackle budget deficits and, simultaneously, sustain the recovery and provide adequate support to the increasing numbers of the unemployed –, some key actions can be undertaken in order to kick start a virtuous circle of stronger and sustained economic growth and job creation. Firstly, labour market reforms are extremely urgent, especially in countries such as Greece, Portugal, Spain and Italy. Clearly, priorities vary from country to country, but there are some common policy challenges. In the short run, labour market demand can be stimulated in the through “net hiring subsidies” which support companies that | Madariaga Report – How to Switch from Jobless Growth to Growthless Jobs? (21 Feb 2012) “...some key actions can be undertaken in order to kick start a virtuous circle of stronger and sustained economic growth and job creation...” decide to expand their workforce. This costeffective tool could boost job creation in the shortrun, while over the medium- and long-term, structural reforms should promote the adaptability of labour markets, which implies ensuring effective protection of workers and encouraging firms to hire formally and to invest in human capital. Moreover, it is necessary to tackle different dualisms such as temporary versus permanent jobs, youth versus older workers, etc. Secondly, it is vital to create adequate safety nets focused on vulnerable groups, such as the longterm unemployed, and conditioned by active job seeking. To effectively support the integration of the unemployed and the inactive into the productive system, he explained that these networks should be based on a tight connection between social assistance on the one hand, and public work recruitment and training offices on the other hand. In order to minimise benefit dependency it is crucial to support job seeking and to prevent the risk of poverty and exclusion, and that is the reason why safety nets should be combined with enforced jobseeker requirements and re-employment services. To activate job seekers – both unemployed and inactive –, access to safety nets has increasingly been made conditional on active job seeking based on the “mutual obligations” principle. Scarpetta explained that one of the main difficulties consists in identifying effective re-employment programmes, especially for long-term jobless people. However, job-search assistance programmes tend to be more cost-effective, and well-tailored training programmes to local and national labour 2 market needs can also be very useful. Some countries have made participation in training and other job support programmes compulsory after a certain period of job seeking. Finally, Scarpetta insisted on human capital investment as the key to promoting employability, and it should be based on a “lifecycle” approach. This implies promoting early childhood education and care, improving the quality of learning provisions and securing equality of access. It is also necessary to strengthen vocational education routes through, for instance, dual schooling systems and to facilitate school-to-work transitions e.g. via apprenticeships. Last but not least, skills mismatches – which already existed before the crisis but which have been deeply aggravated – must be tackled by investing in technical and scientific education, and by expanding skill investments in mid-career. *** Joep Konings firstly analysed some stylised facts related to the crisis and unemployment trends. During the crisis, the negative correlation between GDP growth and unemployment – demonstrated by Okun’s law2 – was particularly strong in the EU15 as well as in the United States. However, when GDP started to grow again in late 2009, the employment rate did not automatically follow GDP trends, and increased slowly and gradually. 2 Okun’s law captures the relationship between unemployment and output. It is a statistical relationship that has received strong empirical support for a broad cross section of countries. As originally estimated by Arthur Okun, it has the following simple form: change in unemployment rate = α – β × change in real output Here α (alpha) is an intercept coefficient, and β (beta) is the elasticity of the unemployment rate with respect to output. Source: IMF, World Economic Outlook, 2010 (www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/weo/2010/01/pdf/text.pdf). | Madariaga Report – How to Switch from Jobless Growth to Growthless Jobs? (21 Feb 2012) “During the crisis, the negative correlation between GDP growth and unemployment was particularly strong in the EU15 as well as in the United States...” The beta indicator, which captures the elasticity of the unemployment rate with regard to output over time3, shows that there are significant differences among the EU countries. Indeed, while in Ireland there is a weak correlation between unemployment and output in Germany this correlation is very strong. These divergences are mainly due to institutional differences. Konings then showed how the crisis also revealed skills mismatches in some EU Member States. The Beveridge curve, which graphically represents the relation between unemployment rates and job vacancy rates4, demonstrates that during recessionary periods characterised by high unemployment rates open vacancies are low. But during the crisis, in some countries such as Belgium, both job vacancies and unemployment rates were high. This apparent paradox is explained both by a discrepancy between labour demand and available skills – this mismatch can be addressed through education reforms –, and by labour mobility obstacles. Focusing on employment reallocation, he showed that from 2008 to 2011 in the EU15, the huge losses of industrial manufacturing jobs were widely compensated by an important increase of the job rate in the public services sector. This trend, in his opinion, may put at risk both private initiative and the efficiency of the public sector. 3 For more information, see: www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/weo/2010/01/pdf/c3.pdf. 4 Job vacancy rates represent the number of unfilled jobs expressed as a proportion of the labour force. 3 Konings went on to explain the ‘jobless growth’ phenomena through various variables. He firstly focused on the institutional dimension. Labour market rigidity, characterised by excessively high employment protection, reduces the elasticity of the unemployment rate with respect to output (a beta within Okun’s law). And, while temporary work contracts increase the beta, firms can anticipate stricter regulation with regard to temporary work, and, consequently, will refrain from hiring. He added that in order to increase job seeker effectiveness, the duration of unemployment benefits should be decreased. Secondly, he pointed out that crisis measures have induced labour hoarding aimed at guaranteeing that skilled and experienced workers are available within the firm after the negative down turn. But keeping extra workers that are not needed with respect to the lowest level of output, implies a nonefficient resource allocation which subsequently slows down the economic recovery. With respect to public versus private employment, not only is the former trumping the latter – with potentially serious consequences for the overall efficiency of the economic system – but the public service increase implies more future taxes, with a negative impact on productive investments. Finally, he remarked that because of the credit squeeze firms are more prudent than proactive, and they are adjusting to the squeeze by reducing the number of available working hours. Konings then proposed some policy measures to reverse current trends, such as labour market reforms in OECD countries which are still characterised by huge rigidities in order to rapidly adapt to fluctuations and changes in economic and society environments; the implementation of austerity measures, which would lead to increased competitiveness (i.e. public employment replaced by private initiative); the establishment of on-the-job training, which improves productivity of both workers and firms and which enhances internal flexibility and employability; and, the guarantee of access to finance to avoid credit squeezes, which implies both access to education through loans – | Madariaga Report – How to Switch from Jobless Growth to Growthless Jobs? (21 Feb 2012) such as in the UK - and to focus on innovative firms as priorities. reform EU industrial policy innovation and green projects. He insisted on the fact that economic growth is a precondition for job creation and to guarantee the supply of public services, especially health care services. In this regard, he underlined three main actions that should be undertaken to tackle the ‘growthless jobs’ phenomena. The EU’s industrial policy should also take into account industrial back-shoring, which is a reality today since the wage cost issue is emerging in China and is eroding the country’s comparative advantage based on cheap labour. This can have a positive impact on the EU’s regional dimension through agglomeration economies, given that clustering creates value added not only for the firm which enters the cluster, but for all the firms agglomerated thanks to knowledge spill-overs, supplier linkages, etc. Human capital being the only “natural” resource abundantly available in Europe, the European skills agenda should be based on effective human capital investment (education and training). Firstly, the enforcement of eurozone governance. For Konings this would imply a move towards Eurobonds (despite the reluctance of German politicians) or, more precisely, towards a European financing agency whose creation would avoid the need to revise EU Treaties. This will immediately generate trust and stability in the eurozone and, as a consequence, in the EU as a whole. Assuring liquidity to systemic banks would allow them to provide the required credit to households and firms – a vital factor in supporting real economic growth. This would also imply a consolidation pact in which countries such as Germany and the Netherlands would follow expansionary policies, rather than austerity trajectories, while countries such as Italy, Greece or Belgium would engage in consolidation strategies since this is a crucial prerequisite to enhance their competitiveness and, consequently, stimulate their economic recovery. promoting Finally, labour market deregulation is a fundamental condition for increasing employment rates. Indeed, a flexible labour market would boost competitiveness (a higher beta within Okun’s equation), which would stimulate growth and, in turn, would lead to job creation. *** Second, the European growth agenda. According to Konings, the two main focus areas should be a smart industrial economic policy and on an EU skills agenda. Concerning industrial policy, he specified that a green economy along with the potential green job growth will not develop by itself unless incentives, sanctions and regulation are established by governments. Besides, emerging economies – such as China – are using active industrial policies and they also stimulate the development of their industries through subsidies, resulting in an unfair level playing field at the international level. In that context, the EU should not be naive, and thus should enforce its antidumping legislation. The temporary protection provided by anti-dumping duty resources – which has economically beneficial effects compared to permanent protection – should therefore be used to 4 by | Madariaga Report – How to Switch from Jobless Growth to Growthless Jobs? (21 Feb 2012) DISCUSSION Getting the discussion started, Pierre Defraigne noted that if each EU Member State undertakes a re-industrialisation policy separately, without any kind of coordination mechanism, this would seriously put at risk the integrity of the Single Market (de-liberalisation), which would worsen the already very critical European growth and employment situation. Moreover, he remarked how tax competition among EU Member States undermines Europe’s unity and slows down the economic recovery process since it provokes a significant distortion of efficient resource allocation. During the discussion, the audience raised key issues related to the role of external trade to boost growth and jobs, the link between fiscal facilitations and job creation (e.g. the Netherlands), and the demographic dimension – especially with regard to the decreasing active population due to the ageing phenomena, and the correlated matter of financing pensions. Regarding industrial policy and tax competition, Joep Konings explained that tax competition does not necessarily lead to industrial re-localisation, as demonstrated by Paul Krugman and Richard Baldwin. The clustering factor is far more relevant compared to tax competition in influencing firms’ strategies. For example, in Switzerland, where each canton can impose its own taxes, the cantons with the higher corporate tax rates coincide with the areas with the highest density of firms. In his opinion, harmonisation at the European level should focus on the tax base – in order to increase transparency – rather than on tax rates. An effective industrial policy does not call for subsidies, but for sound regulation. In the framework of Green economy, for instance, regulation on recycling generated completely new industries and jobs. Clearly, international trade plays a very important role in boosting growth and jobs. This is, according to the Konings, the reason why the EU should enforce its action against unfair competition (dumping and subsidies) through temporary protection measures that would allow 5 supporting technological restructuring of the EU industrial system based on green economy, in order to enhance European international competitiveness. The EU’s industrial policy should be decentralised at the regional level since evidence proves that de-centralisation is far more effective in terms of productivity. Focusing on the link between taxation and jobs, Konings asserted that, on the one hand, higher taxes are detrimental to employment; indeed, he argued that high corporate tax rates – especially for multinational firms – are a disincentive for longterm investments, which has a negative impact on growth, and consequently on job creation. On the other hand, he specified that some taxes are obviously needed in order to finance infrastructures that are a crucial element in stimulating investment. In Konings’ opinion, current and future demographic trends in Europe – which point to an ageing population and a decreasing work force - show that the EU will need to attract more labour immigrants in order to be able to fuel its economic growth. According to Stefano Scarpetta, the current crisis is triggering structural reform of the public sector. As evidence shows, some countries have already started significant reforms in public administration aimed at enhancing the efficiency of the public service sector. Furthermore, he said that uniform and better rules rather than the de-regulation of European goods and services markets are urgently needed, especially concerning the services sector. Action has been undertaken to remove the persistent barriers to entry imposed on new firms, but what is urgent needed now is to address barriers to expansion of successful firms, which are related to access to credit, access to technology, as well as sound labour regulations. Scarpetta thinks that the solution to these central issues is not only to act upstream through, for instance, regulations that allow setting up a business in one day – as is the case in Portugal or Italy – but to undertake radical structural reforms. He also highlighted that in order to foster the economic recovery and job creation, labour | Madariaga Report – How to Switch from Jobless Growth to Growthless Jobs? (21 Feb 2012) market reforms should be accompanied by access to credit, in particular for small and medium size enterprises. Obviously, labour market reforms do not lead to a "one size fits all" solution. The labour market clearly needs to be more flexible, argued Scarpetta, but reforms should also aim at creating stable and sustainable jobs, as well as increasing productivity levels through a better allocation of human resources. Finally, addressing the labour market de-regulation process Scarpetta specified that no “one size fits all” solution exists, and that labour market flexibility has often resulted in precarious jobs, with the expansion of fixed-term and involuntary parttime jobs. This is conducive neither to a stable and sustainable employment pattern nor to a better allocation of human resources. With respect to tax policy, he insisted on the fact what matters is not only the overall level of taxation, but rather tax composition. Indeed, a tax system more conducive to growth and potentially to job creation should address the questions such as the right balance between direct and indirect taxation and should aim at reducing taxes on labour use. Introducing the second round of questions, Defraigne raised the political and social issue of increasing inequalities. These inequalities not only exist between labour and capital revenue – the latter being much more mobile than the former, but also within the labour category (skilled versus unskilled workers) and within capital in terms of size (MNCs versus SMEs). In other words, Defraigne asked how can we ensure a flexible labour market and simultaneously address the phenomenon of the "working poor"? A participant noted that the debate in the EU was exclusively focused on economic growth, despite the fact that the causality link between growth and jobs creation has never been proved. Indeed, not only is "never-ending growth" a myth, but it is also totally unsustainable from an economic standpoint. The audience also raised the question of the potentially negative impact of the Fiscal Compact in terms of economic stagnation and unemployment rises. Scarpetta agreed with Konings on the fact that green economy is a sector that, at this stage, will not evolve by itself. Clearly, green investment in renewable energies can be encouraged, and the EU has elaborated a plan for renewable energy to make up 20% of the total EU energy mix by 20205. This sector can potentially create two million jobs. But the green economy will not solve EU labour market problems, because it will both imply job creation and job losses. Scarpetta pointed out that the OECD has elaborated some simulations using its general equilibrium models which suggest that, potentially, the transition to a green economy will not lead to large job creation. Policies aimed at reducing green house gas emissions - for example, by provoking a change in relative prices - will lead to an increase in energy prices which is likely to have a negative effect on GDP growth, and, consequently, a potentially negative impact on employment. So, a transition to green growth is vital but will not generate per se million of jobs; however promoting such transition will involve large reallocation of labour and policy should be in place to promote this process and support the affected workers. 5 For more information, see: http://eurlex.europa.eu/LexUriServ/site/en/com/2006/com2006_0848 en01.pdf. 6 Stefano Scarpetta firstly reminded the audience that rising inequalities is one of the main topics the OECD is working on, as testified by the Report “Divided We Stand: Why Inequalities Keeps Rising”, published on December 2011. The study has shown that inequalities – in terms of the GDP per capita divide – have not only been on the rise for 20 years among OECD countries, but that this phenomena also includes some of the countries – e.g. the Nordic countries, traditionally characterised by strong redistribution policies. Concerning growthless jobs, continued Scarpetta, some of the reforms undertaken over the past decade have contributed to make the labour market more inclusive by bringing more under-represented workers into the market. However, this has been | Madariaga Report – How to Switch from Jobless Growth to Growthless Jobs? (21 Feb 2012) achieved in some countries via the extension of atypical jobs – temporary jobs for example. The challenge today, argued Scarpetta, is to find a way to combine inclusiveness with the quality of jobs. Concluding, he then underlined that tax and transfer systems have not been able to fully compensate for the increase in market income inequality trends – e.g. in the US, 1% of the richest portion of the population holds 17% of the total national income, and 0.1% hold 7%. To tackle this issue, progressive taxation is not enough and other types of taxation should be elaborated, including property taxes and a fight against tax evasion. Addressing the growthless jobs question, Joep Konings explained that currently economists are trying to better define the notion of growth by moving away from the simplistic value added growth concept by integrating quality indicators, such as the happiness dimension. That said, he insisted on the fact that economic growth is the major source of social progress and has so far proved to be effective, as testified by the fact that, for example, a much larger portion of the population has access to higher education compared to 15 years ago thanks to sustained growth rates. *** RELATED REPORTS L'austérité est-elle la meilleure solution à la détérioration des finances publiques? 28 February 2011 With Henri Sterdyniak, Director of the Economics of Globalisation Department, OFCE, and André Sapir, Senior Fellow, Bruegel. Regarding rising inequalities, he claimed that greater unequal distribution of wealth at the global level is simply false. Indeed, inequalities among countries and regions have decreased globally, as testified by the diminishing gap between China and the Western countries, even if, he specified, inequalities have increased within countries. *** He also clarified the fact that moving towards a more technology-oriented society inevitably means a relative decline of the labour share compared to capital share within the economic system. This trend began with the industrial revolution, and was strengthened by the ICT revolution. 23 February 2011 Finally, with respect to the fiscal consolidation pact6 Konings said that the timing for the 6 The Treaty on Stability, Coordination and Governance was signed by twenty-five Member States on 2 March 2012. For 7 implementation of austerity measures, as well as policy orientations, should be diversified on the basis of the different economic situations characterising each Member State. From this perspective, countries such as Germany or the Netherlands should engage in fiscal expansionary policies while other countries, such as Spain, Portugal or Italy, should strictly implement austerity measures. The EU/IMF Rescue Packages: An "Attack on Social Europe" or a Necessary Step to Restore Confidence? With Philippe de Buck, Secretary General of Business Europe, and John Monks, General Secretary of the European Trade Union Confederation (ETUC). *** more information, see: http://europeancouncil.europa.eu/media/639235/st00tscg26_en12.pdf. | Madariaga Report – How to Switch from Jobless Growth to Growthless Jobs? (21 Feb 2012) www.madariaga.org CITIZEN'S CONTROVERSIES The Citizen's Controversies* series of lunchtime debates seek to address one of Europe’s most vital tasks: rekindling the citizen’s interest in EU matters. Much has been said about the ‘democratic deficit’, which is now felt to seriously hamper EU progress. This deficit, however, does not stem from undemocratic EU institutions, but from a lack of citizen participation in EU democratic life. Less an institutional deficit, therefore, than a citizenship deficit. The Citizen's Controversies strive to encourage citizens’ ownership of the pan-European political debate by securing fair and contrasting views on fundamental EU issues. Each debate confronts different points of view on a given topic to point out options and trade-offs and highlight the political stakes present in each necessary compromise. The objective, in sum, is to enhance the perception of a ‘European common good’, which is more than the sum of national interests. * The Citizen's Controversies are held under the Chatham House Rule. A report is then published after agreement with the speakers. SUPPORT US The Madariaga - College of Europe Foundation is a young and independent think-tank committed to free thinking on the European Union. The Foundation is only partially supported for its event organisation and research. In order to sustain the vital work of the Foundation into the future we rely on assistance in the form of donations and project collaboration. If you would like to make a contribution to the work of the Foundation there are a number of possible options: ABOUT US The Madariaga – College of Europe Foundation is dedicated to promoting original thinking on the role of the European Union in an era of global change, engaging citizens and international partners in a creative debate on the issues that shape Europe’s future. Through research and action, the Foundation pursues a three-fold mission of challenging the citizen, empowering Europe, and preventing conflict. Created in 1998 by former students of the College of Europe, the Foundation bears the name of the College of Europe founder: Spanish writer, historian, diplomat and philosopher Salvador de Madariaga (1886-1978). MCF continues to work in close cooperation with the College, which provides it with valuable access to a pool of academic expertise and a vast network of professors and alumni. Presided over by the former EU High Representative for the Common Foreign and Security Policy, Javier Solana, the MCF’s Administrative Council includes distinguished personalities from a variety of backgrounds, reflecting its privileged relationship with key European and transatlantic stakeholders. The Foundation’s Administrative Council includes as members the President, the VicePresident Jean-Luc Dehaene, the Rector of the College of Europe, high-level representatives of the European Commission and European Parliament, leaders of major European and American foundations, as well as several business partners. The Administrative Council appoints the members of the Executive Committee as well as the Executive Director, in charge of the daily management of the Foundation The views expressed in this paper are the speakers' own, and do not necessarily reflect those of the Madariaga – College of Europe Foundation or any other institutions with which the speakers are associated. To Donate One can make a financial donation to the Foundation by contacting Magali Auquier at [email protected] or phoning on +32 (0) 2 209 62 11. All donors will be acknowledged, thanked and listed in our Annual Report on the website unless they prefer to remain anonymous. 14, Avenue de la Joyeuse Entrée B-1040, Brussels Belgium Tel: +32 2 209 62 10 Fax: +32 2 209 62 11 Email: [email protected] www.madariaga.org Subscribe to our mailing list: Follow the Foundation on: [email protected]
© Copyright 2024