Improving the Trade-Development-Nexus: How to make EU trade policy more development-friendly A thesis submitted to the Bucerius/WHU Master of Law and Business Program in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the award of the Master of Law and Business (“MLB”) Degree Inez Freiin von Weitershausen July 16, 2010 13,888 words (excluding footnotes) Supervisor 1: Prof. Dr. Michael Frenkel Supervisor 2: Christopher J. Whelan, Ph.D. CONTENTS Abbreviations………………………………………………………………………iii Introduction……………………………………………………………………….. 1 I. The EU’s Policies of Development and Trade………………………………… 5 1. EU Development Policy…………………………………………….. 8 1.1. Characteristics and Shortcomings……………………….. 9 1.2. Grounds for Improvement……………………………….. 11 2. EU Trade Policy…………………………………………………….. 12 2.1. Revolutionising the allocation of competences…………..13 2.2. The multidimensional preference system………………...18 II. Linking Trade and Development: Case study of EU-ACP negotiations on EPAs………………………………. 22 1. EU-ACP relations: From Yaoundé to Lomé and Cotonou…………. 25 2. EPAs: An efficient tool to fight economic marginalisation? ………. 28 2.1. Capacity building………………………………………... 31 2.2. Reform of RoO and quality of market access…………… 33 2.3. Regional integration……………………………………... 35 3. Lessons from the EPA negotiations………………………………… 37 III. An Agenda for Action………………………………………………………… 40 1. De lege lata: The Treaty of Lisbon…………………………………. 40 1.1. Extending EU competences……………………………... 42 1.2. Structural improvements………………………………… 42 1.3. Institutional innovations…………………………………. 44 2. De lege ferenda: Potential measures to promote consistency………. 46 2.1. Consolidating EU und Members States’ activities……….46 2.2 Engaging developing countries…………………………... 47 Conclusion…………………………………………………………………………. 49 Boxes Box 1: The Eight Millennium Goals (MDGs)…………………………………. 6 Box 2: UN Millennium Declaration – Selected Paragraphs…………………… 8 Box 3: EU PTAs: 1957-2005…………………………………………………... 14 Box 4: Art. 133(1) TEC………………………………………………………… 16 Box 5: Art. 300(1) TEC………………………………………………………… 16 Box 6: EU Preferential Treatment: Pyramid of Priviledges……………………. 19 Box 7: Evolution of Regional Trade Agreements in the world, 1948-2008…… 20 Box 8: Objectives of the Cotonou Agreement, Art. 34………………………… 22 Box 9: The ACP regions……………………………………………………….. 24 Box 10: European Development Fund Cycles and Agreements……………….. 25 Box 11: The EU’s vision on development with respect to EPAs……………… 29 Box 12: Art 3(5) TEU………………………………………………………….. 41 Bibliography…………………………………………………………………... 51 ii Abbreviations AAMS Associated African Malagasy States ACP African, Caribbean, and Pacific AfT Aid for Trade AU African Union BIT Bilateral Investment Treaty CAP Common Agricultural Policy CCP Common Commercial Policy CFSP Common Foreign and Security Policy CSDP Common Security and Defence Policy DG Directorate General EBA Everything But Arms Initiative EC European Commission EDF European Development Fund EEC European Economic Community EP European Parliament EPA European Partnership Agreement EU European Union FASA Foreign Affairs and Security Policy FDI Foreign Direct Investment FTA Free Trade Agreement GATT General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade HR High Representative IMF International Monetary Fund LDCs Least Development Countries MDG Millennium Development Goal MFN Most Favoured Nation NDTPF National Development and Trade Policy Forum NGO Non-governmental Organisation OECD Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development OCTs Overseas Countries and Territories PTA Preferential Trade Arrangement RIA Regional Integration Agreement iii TEU Treaty of the European Union TFEU Treaty on the Functioning the European Union UN United Nations UNCTAD United Nations Conference on Trade and Development UNDP United Nations Development Programme WTO World Trade Organization iv Introduction A famous bonmot by the French political philosopher Baron de Montesquieu from 1749 suggests that “wherever there is commerce, manners are gentle”.1 Two hundred years later and after two disastrous world wars, this insight found new popularity among political leaders and was expressed in the various attempts to create closer connections between states through trade. Their aim was to reduce the risk for future conflict and create long-lasting stability and peace as prerequisites for development and prosperity. Among the most successful efforts in this regard was the initiative of six European countries to cooperate in various industrial sectors. Soon they were joined by neighbouring countries, they expanded the scope of their cooperation and today the European Union (EU) constitutes a group of 27 countries that cooperate on almost all levels which used to be solely a matter of sovereignty and responsibility of the individual nation state. Despite the EU’s short-comings and flaws with regard to democratic efficiency and legitimacy,2 the process of European integration on the basis of trade is generally seen as a success story3: countries opening-up their national borders let to growth and development, reduced poverty and nonmilitary ways of dispute-resolution, cohesion and regional integration. These observations might explain why trade (liberalization) today is often perceived as a ‘silver bullet’ for development, i.e. a simple, guaranteed solution for a difficult problem, also with regard to other regions in the world. Due to its own positive experiences and the fact that the Union is today the world’s largest trading block, accounting for 20 per cent of global imports and exports,4 the EU is indeed one of the main drivers in the evolution of trade policy. Under the unambiguous title ‘Trade benefits for all’, the European Commission (EC) accordingly recalls its history and states on its homepage: “Open trade among its members underpinned the launch of the EU nearly 50 years ago and has brought growing prosperity to 1 Cited in: Humphreys, Macaratan: Economics and Violent Conflict, Harvard 2003, p. 8. For an overview of the most discussed short-comings and state of the arguments, see: Mény, Yves: De la Démocratie en Europe: Old Concepts and New Challenges, in: Journal of Common Market Studies 2002, Vol. 41, No. 1, pp. 1-13. 3 Some critics argue however, that not all MS have benefitted from integration in an equal manner and fear a potential for social unrest if adequate policy measures are not taken. For an economic analysis, see: Malhotra, Davinder K./ Mariotz, Elizabeth: Performance of European Union Trading Bloc: Did Integration Help Nations?, in: Journal of Global Business and Technology, Vol. 1, No. 2, 2005, pp. 34-50. 4 European Commission: The EU and Trade, Brussels 2010. Available online: http://ec.europa.eu/ireland/about_the_eu/eu_in_the_world/trade/index_en.htm (22.6.2010). 2 1 all its Member States (MS). The Union therefore takes a lead in efforts to open up world trade for the benefit of rich and poor countries alike.”5 Together with multilateral institutions such as Worldbank, IMF and OECD, the EU has shared the credo that “more open and outwardoriented economies consistently outperform countries with restrictive trade and [foreign] investment regimes”6. Other voices, however, point out that trade alone is not a sufficient explanation for growth and that “trade has not always been at the core of the various paths that developed or developing countries have adopted towards development.”7 Accordingly, trade only became central to development thinking when export-oriented countries such as China, India, Brazil or Vietnam were able to overcome their development traps.8 Critics raise the points that trade liberalization does not necessarily lead to growth and can even be harmful for the liberalizing country9, or – and this is the more frequent argument – that rather than trade alone, a wide variety of factors, including the existing levels of development and education, the strength of domestic institutions and quality of governance, macroeconomic stability and the existence of measures to tackle corruption as well as the level of human capital are of immense importance when explaining economic growth and development.10 Central argument and objective This thesis does not aim at solving this debate or at discussing en detail the relationship between barriers to international trade and economic growth, although it is one of the most important issues for development theory and “few questions have been more vigorously debated in the history of economic thought.”11 Rather, it uses as its basic assumption the 5 European Commission: European Union in the World - Trade Policy, Brussels 2009. Available online: http://ec.europa.eu/world/what/trade_policy/index_en.htm (17.6.2010). 6 OECD: Open Markets Matter: The Benefits of Trade and Investment Liberalisation, Paris, 1998, p. 36. 7 Makhan, Davina: Linking EU Trade and Development Policies, Bonn 2009, p. 22. 8 For further information on the concept of development traps such as conflict, natural resources and bad governance, see: Collier, Paul: The Bottom Billion, Oxford 2008. 9 Bhagwati, Jagdish.: Trade Diverting Customs Unions and Welfare-Improvement: A Clarification, in: Economic Journal, Vol. 81, 1971, pp. 580-587..; Kemp, Murray/Wan, Henry: An Elementary Proposition Concerning the Formation Of Customs Unions, in: Journal of International Economics, Vol. 6 , No. 1, 1976, pp. 95-97.; Levy, Philip: A Political Economic Analysis of Free Trade Arrangements, in: American Economic Review, Vol. 87, No. 4, 1997, pp. 506-519. 10 Kneller, Richard / Morgan, C.W. / Kanchanahatakij, Sunti: Trade liberalisation and economic growth, in: The World Economy, Vol. 31, No. 6, 2008, pp. 701-719. 11 Rodríguez, Francisco./Rodrik, Dani: Trade Policy and Economic Growth: A skeptic’s guide to the crossnational evidence, in: Macroeconomics Annual, Vol. 15, 2000, pp. 261-325, p. 263. 2 common ground of academic discussions and the opinion shared by the EC12, that “trade can create opportunities for growth and human development” and that “trade liberalisation is a necessary, but not sufficient condition for development, and hence has a strong potential to serve development and poverty reduction objectives.”13 In order for trade to be an efficient instrument for Third World development, the different EU policies need to be coherent,14 i.e. they must “support, and (…) not undermine, specific efforts to help and sustain the development process.”15 On this basis, the aim of the thesis is to analyse how European trade policy can best be designed to make it a strong and consistent instrument in the EU’s overall policies towards developing countries and how it can enable those countries to follow the paths of the EU towards growth, peace and regional integration. This question is of particular interest when bearing in mind that the EU as a multilevel-system faces additional challenges in making its development and trade policies coherent and consistent. Therefore the thesis will address questions such as the (obstacles to) cooperation between the EU and its Member States, the coordination of trade and development policies and the EU’s capability of working together with the developing countries in identifying and meeting their needs. Structure The first part of the paper (I) will introduce the European Union’s policies of trade and development by presenting the relevant actors and instruments, milestones and problems, and classify them according to whether they are mostly determined by multi-, bi- and unilateralist policy approaches. The second part (II) will then analyse the negotiations of the EU-ACP Economic Partnership Agreements (EPAs) that are regarded as the “EU’s flagship endeavour to make better use of trade for development.”16 This case study shall provide insight on how linking the policies of trade and development has recently been improved but shall also point out where 12 European Commission: Trade, Brussels 2010. Available online: http://ec.europa.eu/trade/wider-agenda/development/ (16.6.2010). 13 Makhan 2009, p. 54. 14 According to the OECD definition policy coherence is the “systematic promotion of mutually reinforcing policy actions across government departments and agencies creating synergies towards achieving the agreed objectives.” OECD/DAC: The DAC Guidelines, Poverty Reduction, Paris 2001, p. 74. 15 OECD: Policy coherence: Vital for global development, in: OECD Observer, Vol. 7, 2003, p. 1. 16 Makhan, Davina: Coordinating EU trade and development policy-making in a new context, in: Trade Negotiation Insight, Vol. 9, No. 2, 2010. 3 unresolved challenges remain. The third and final part (III) will try to provide an outlook of how the relationship of trade and development policies in the EU will evolve with regard to institutional and personal changes after the implementation of the Lisbon Treaty and due to an increased need for consistency and efficiency in the context of the financial and economic crises. Research methodology and literature The thesis touches upon legal, economic and political issues and hence is an interdisciplinary attempt to examine the arguments that can be brought forward in order to stress the case for better linking EU trade and development policies. The legal realm is of particular importance for understanding the distribution of competences and institutional prerequisites of policy making. Economic understanding is required for the analysis of the EU trade preference system and the positions argued in EPA negotiations. Political factors are finally taken into consideration when asking which (other) impediments hinder EU Member States from working together more closely in improving the trade-development nexus. Both, primary and secondary sources were used to make the analysis as objective and precise as possible. With regard to the relevant development and trade activities, the thesis relies on information such as treaties, official documents and speeches provided by the EC, the EP and the OECD. Also of interest (until 2007) is the biennial publication by the WTO The Trade Policy Review of the EU as it provides insight into how trade specialists view the EU and, no less important, into how the EU sees its own role. The critical analysis of EU trade policy is mostly based on the works by Holland, Meunier and Nikolaidis. The development chapter mainly draws on the conclusions of Wanlin and Bartelt/Dann and on publications by the Overseas Development Institute in London. Of particular importance for the case-study on the EU-ACP negotiations is the work by Makhan in the context of the German Development Institute’s ‘European Policy for Global Development’ project as well as the analysis by Wright on contexts and strategies in the negotiations. Finally, the research by Koeb and Woolcock was essential for assessing the impact of the Treaty of Lisbon on the chances for improving the trade-development nexus. 4 I. The EU Policies of Development and Trade In 1992, in the context of the Maastricht Treaty, the European Community introduced the concept of the ‘3Cs’ (coordination17, complementarity18 and coherence19) as a means to increase the effectiveness of development cooperation of the EU Member States and the European Commission in general and to strengthen the relationship between their respective trade and development policies in particular. Until that point, development issues were only indirectly connected to trade, mainly addressed through the Community’s “long-standing trade competence and the construction of a complicated pyramid of preferences”.20 This weak link, however, did not appropriately reflect the case that trade had “arguably (become) the most important policy area influencing the developing countries.”21 Based on this previous system of (little) coordination, the ‘3Cs’-concept seemed very ambitious and hopes for actual improvements were rather limited. Hence, critical voices pointed to a number of structural conditions that so far have impeded the linking of EU trade and development policies.22 (i) Firstly, the respective policies are formulated on different levels and implemented by various actors: while trade policy is (with few exceptions) a communitarised area, i.e. the community has exclusive competence over this field, development issues are shared between the Union and its Member States.23 To make things even more complex, also on the Community level responsibility in development issues is split and different DGs (directorates general) aim at influencing development topics if they feel that their interests are touched upon.24 17 Defined as “activities of two or more development partners that are intended to mobilise aid resources or to harmonise their policies, programmes, procedures and practices so as to maximise the development effectiveness of aid resources.” (Definitions of footnotes 15-17 are taken from: The 3C evaluation initiative: 3Cs defined, Leiden 2008. Available online: http://www.three-cs.net/3Cs-Defined (29.6.2010). 18 Defined as intended to ensure that Community development policy “shall be complementary to the policies pursued by the Member States.” (See footnote 15.) 19 Defined as “the non-occurrence of effects of policy that are contrary to the intended results or aims of policy.” (See footnote 15.) 20 Orbie, Jan/Versluys, Helen.: The European Union’s international development policy: leading and benevolent?, in: Orbie, Jan (edt.): Europe’s global role: external policies of the European Union, London 2008, p. 72. 21 Van Reisen, Mirjam.: EU ‘Global Player’: the North-South Policy of the European Union, Utrecht 1999, p. 129. 22 Holland, Martin: The European Union and the Third World, Hampshire 2002. 23 Only very few commentators see the Community also as the driving force in the development area: Carbone, Maurizio: The European Union and International Development: The politics of foreign aid, London, 2007. 24 As an example hereof, no less than seven DGs took part in the discussion of development issues after the Maastricht-Treaty. 5 (ii) Secondly, although all European countries are members of the United Nations (UN) and hence support the overarching Millennium Development Goals25 (MDGs), each member state has its own priorities in development policy and focuses its trade and aid activities on different regions or countries due to historical connections, engagements or perceived responsibilities. Such diverse interests do not only impede the formulation of a joint development policy and a community trade policy that pleases all MS equally, but they make it even more difficult to merge all of these single policies into a single coherent one of trade and development. (iii) Thirdly, the complex structure of the EU decision-making can still be quite timeconsuming, which leads to inefficiencies and makes negotiations less flexible and coordination and coherence efforts rather complicated. The first two points will be analysed in greater detail in the respective chapters on trade and development policy while the last point will be of particular relevance in the second part of this paper, focusing on the EU-ACP negotiations on Economic Partnership Agreements. Box 1: The Eight Millennium Development Goals (MDGs) 1. Eradicate extreme poverty and hunger 2. Achieve universal primary education 3. Promote gender equality and empower women 4. Reduce child mortality 5. Improve maternal health 6. Combat HIV/AIDS, malaria, and other diseases 7. Ensure environmental sustainability 8. Develop a global partnership for development Source: United Nations: United Nations Development Declaration, Resolution by the General Assembly, New York 2000. Despite these challenges, especially since the year 2000 – and in line with the 1992 ‘3Cs’approach – efforts to create a coherent and thereby more effective development policy have increased, as can be observed by a number of key policy documents. The EU’s 2000 Development Policy Statement and the 2005 European Consensus on Development both support a common vision of a truly coherent development policy. The 2005 document in particular names twelve concrete policy areas26 “where the challenge of attaining synergies 25 See Box 1. Namely trade, environment, security, agriculture, fisheries, social dimensions of globalisation, employment and decent work, migration, research and innovation, information society, transport and energy. 26 6 with development policy objectives is considered particularly relevant.”27 Section 3.1.2. of the 2005 Consensus specifically addresses the relevance of EPAs for development consistency and will be analysed more deeply in the case study.28 Further written commitments for a harmonised and linked approach to development and trade (both, on an EU and on a global scale) include the Paris Declaration on Aid Effectiveness (2005), its follow-up, the Accra Agenda for Action29 (2008), the Aid for Trade (AfT) initiative30 launched by the WTO ministerial meeting in Hong Kong (2005), as well as the Code of Conduct on the Division of Labour in Development policy31 (2007), and as the basis of many of these initiatives the eight UN MDGs which aim at creating a global partnership for development (see especially MDG 8). While for a long time the focus of development initiatives very much “depended on the ideological flavour of the day”32, governments have finally committed themselves to the eradication of poverty in form of the UN Millennium Declaration.33 As remarkable as these documents and their underlying rationale are, critics fear that they will remain not much more but good intentions. And even more optimistic voices express their concern that despite “large amounts of work having already been put into operationalising these policy commitments (…) these are still recent and the targeted consistent approach has arguably yet to emerge in practice.”34 However, in order to further understand the prevailing impediments on a European level, it is vital to analyse in greater detail how EU development and trade policy have been constructed so far, what drives their respective agendas and where MS and the Community should try to tackle the issue most effectively in order to achieve improvements in the trade-development nexus. This will be done in the following. 27 Communication from the Commission to the Council, the European Parliament and the European Economic and Social Committee of 12 April 2005 - Policy Coherence for Development - Accelerating progress towards attaining the Millennium Development Goals, Brussels 2005. 28 See sec. 36, EU Consensus on Development. 29 OECD: The Paris Agenda for Aid Effectiveness and the Accra Agenda for Action 2005-2008, Paris 2008. Available online: http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/11/41/34428351.pdf (15.6.2010). 30 For the most current version of the initiative, see: WTO, Committee on Trade and Development: Aid-for-Trade Programme 2010-2011, New York 2009. Available online: http://www.wto.org/english/tratop_e/devel_e/a4t_e/aid4trade_e.htm (16.6.2010). 31 European Commission: EU Code of Conduct on Division of labour in Development Policy, Brussels 2007. 32 Makhan 2009, p. 17. 33 See Box 2. 34 Makhan 2009, p. 115. 7 Box 2: UN Millennium Declaration - Selected paragraphs [...] III. Development and poverty eradication 11. We will spare no effort to free our fellow men, women and children from the abject and dehumanizing conditions of extreme poverty, to which more than a billion of them are currently subjected. We are committed to making the right to development a reality for everyone and to freeing the entire human race from want. 12. We resolve therefore to create an environment – at the national and global levels alike – which is conducive to development and to the elimination of poverty. 13. Success in meeting these objectives depends, inter alia, on good governance within each country. It also depends on good governance at the international level and on transparency in the financial, monetary and trading systems. We are committed to an open, equitable, rule- based, predictable and non-discriminatory multilateral trading and financial system. […] 19. We resolve further: To halve, by the year 2015, the proportion of the world’s people whose income is less than one dollar a day and the proportion of people who suffer from hunger and, by the same date, to halve the proportion of people who are unable to reach or to afford safe drinking water. […] Source: United Nations: United Nations Development Declaration, Resolution by the General Assembly, New York 2000. 1. EU Development policy Part Five, Title III, Chapter I (Development Cooperation) of the Treaty of Lisbon states: “Union policy in the field of development cooperation shall be conducted within the framework of the principles and objectives of the Union's external action. The Union's development cooperation policy and that of the Member States complement and reinforce each other.”35 The treaty further lays down the foundations of the present European Union’s development cooperation as contained in the 2005 European Consensus on Development, as well as the objectives of poverty reduction, sustainable economic and social development, integration into the world economy, the consolidation of democracy and of the rule of law, and respect for human rights. Hence, development policy today is not only limited to Member States initiatives and since the Treaty of Maastricht, when development cooperation was 35 Treaty of Lisbon amending the Treaty on European Union and the Treaty establishing the European Community, in: Official Journal of the European Union (OJEU): 17.12.2007, No C 306. 8 formally incorporated into the European legal framework, the Commission has been entrusted with both, the implementation of its own development policy and the coordination of Member States activities in this area.36 Hence although both, the legal framework under which development cooperation shall take place and the objectives are therefore clearly stated. Yet the visibility of EU development policy remains limited. This fact becomes even more astonishing when taking into consideration that the EU with its Member States constitutes the largest donor of development aid worldwide37, providing more than half of the official development assistance (ODA).38 1.1. Characteristics and shortcomings Among the reasons for the small degree of visibility and recognition might be the fact that despite the existence of legal and institutional prerequisites “European countries and institutions have failed to join forces and work together in ways that allow them to play to their comparative strengths”39 so far. A good example hereof is the area of development funding: although common financial institutions, specifically set up for development purposes such as the EDF and the DCI40 exist, bilateral aid provided by the single EU Member States has by far exceeded the resources channelled through these institutions. Until the 1990s, EDF funds accounted for less than 10 per cent of total MS aid spending41 and even in 2009 the “EC is entrusted with a smaller share than one-sixth of the EU Member States aid, this constraining its level of influence and/or leverage in coordinating the whole set of policies compromising EU development cooperation.”42 Explanations for these shortcomings in linking national policies with regard to financing and other sectors are manifold: Firstly, Member States vary with regard to their abilities, traditions and willingness to provide development aid. While older MS such as France, the United Kingdom, or Germany often 36 Makhan 2009, p. 111. For the most recent numbers on development aid (2009, forecast 2010), see: OECD: Development aid rose in 2009 and most donors will meet 2010 aid targets, Paris 2010. 38 For an official definition of ODA, see: http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/26/14/26415658.PDF. 39 Wanlin, Aurore: What future for EU development policy?, London 2007. 40 Financing instrument for development cooperation - DCI (2007-2013) aims at improving the Community’s previous development cooperation framework by merging various geographic and thematic instruments into one single instrument. For further information, see: http://europa.eu/legislation_summaries/development/general_development_framework/l14173_en.htm (22.6.2010). 41 Holland 2002, p. 52. 42 Makhan 2009, p. 113. 37 9 have a long history of supporting less-developed countries and correspondingly can make use of large budgets and expertise, some of the new MS are only just starting to put in place development policies and therefore lack resources as well personal.43 Secondly, MS tend to focus on different parts of the world, depending on their geographical closeness or cultural and historical ties to the receiving country.44 The location phenomenon can be observed for example with regard to Greece which concentrates much of its development efforts on neighbouring countries such as the Balkans, the Black Sea area or the eastern Mediterranean. Historical relations, on the other hand, certainly play a role for countries such as France or Belgium that feel a stronger commitment to their former colonies of Algeria, Tunisia and Morocco or the Democratic Republic of Congo respectively.45 These different priorities do not need to be dismissed per se and can even be seen as an asset when valued as multifaceted expertise in countries and sectors. In order to provide for an efficient and equal distribution of development aid, avoiding so-called ‘aid darlings’ and ‘aid orphans’46, however, the various policies need to be supported by a sophisticated co-ordination process that so far has not been sufficiently put into place. Thirdly, co-ordination among MS with regard to a common development policy has proven difficult in the past because aid policies until today are often seen as an instrument of foreign policy that serve to improve a country’s international reputation and the chances of its representatives getting senior jobs in international organizations, such as the UN or the Bretton Woods institutions.47 As long as this level of competitions between donors is not overcome, no efficient development cooperation can take place. Finally, in the past, both Member States and the Community repeatedly have changed their attitudes towards the two economic paradigms of trade liberalization on the one hand, and internal market protection on the other,48 depending on the “ideological flavour of the day.” This inconsistent approach, however, has led to “contradictory policies that are incoherent with the objectives of EU development policy.”49 43 Wanlin 2007, p. 12. Wright 2005, p. 76. 45 Wanlin 2007, p. 8. 46 For typical characteristics of ‘aid orphans’, i.e. a fragile states with poor governance that fail to provide basic services to their people, see: Collins, Paul: The Bottom Billion, Oxford 2008. 47 Wanlin 2007, p. 13. 48 Holland 2002, p. 143. 49 Van Reisen 1999, p. 130. 44 10 1.2. Grounds for improvement However, there are a couple of circumstances that give reason to hope for an optimistic turn in the EU countries’ willingness to overcome the obstacles to policy coherence described above. (i) Change might occur because Member States simply cannot afford to keep up their uncoordinated behaviour anymore as “the complexity of the aid industry is rapidly increasing” and they are facing competition from emerging economies like China, Brazil or India. Although each additional donor of aid and trading partner for Third World countries should generally be welcomed, it is important to take a closer look at how their respective development strategies are designed. China, for example, has increasingly been criticised by Western donors for pursuing - what is at least perceived as - a rather self-interested, resourceseeking policy that focuses on bringing its own skilled citizens to developing countries rather than educating the local workforce which is considered essential for development.50 Such policies are also accused of undermining Western attempts to link financial support and good governance by promising a ‘no strings attached’ aid and trade policy.51 (ii) Furthermore, developed countries, especially in Europe, are faced with a growing migration movement of people who want to escape poverty and general underdevelopment in their home countries. Especially as one cannot fully dismiss an (at least shared) responsibility of Western countries for the very emergence of these conditions due to their previous support of autocratic and corrupt regimes (especially during the Cold War) and damaging effects of European trade policy, Western governments will have to contribute to improving the conditions through adequate policies fostering trade and development.52 This will be even more the case if European countries want to stop the wave of illegal immigration they have been faced with lately.53 50 For an extensive description of China’s development instruments in Africa and a critical analysis hereof, see: Goldstein, Andrea et al. (OECD Development Centre): The Rise of China and India. What’s in it for Africa?, Paris 2006.; Davies, Martyn: How China delivers development assistance to Africa, Beijing 2008. 51 For a critical analysis of the shortcomings of the Western “good governance” agenda itself (such as limited focus on procedural and institutional interpretations of governance that delegitimize other possible priorities), see: Abrahamsen, Rita: Disciplining Democracy: Development Discourse and Good Govenance in Africa, London 2001. 52 Kohnert, Dirk: African Migration to Europe: Obscured Responsibilities and Common Misconceptions, München 2007, p. 20. 53 Bade, Klaus J.: Legal and illegal immigration into Europe: experiences and challenges, in: European Review, Vol. 12, No. 3, 2004, pp. 339-375. 11 (iii) Additionally, the increasingly global dimension of security and environmental protection issues further account for the need to co-operate among developed and with un-developed countries to find reliable solutions for peace and sustainability.54 (iv) Finally, chances for increased policy coherence are said to have augmented with some structural and institutional changes deriving from the Lisbon Treaty. So far the number of major actors on the European supranational level was rather large and coordination little. In the Commission the Directorate Generals (DGs) for development, trade and external relations together with EuropeAid and the European Community Humanitarian Office (ECHO) formed the RELEX group, which again was only one of four cooperation groups in the Commission. So far the DGs wrote proposals for new policies and EuropeAid and ECHO were responsible for delivering the funds and the supervision of the implementation of the policies. However, there was no one person in charge of coordinating these policies, formulating one coherent approach and presenting it to third parties. This is likely to improve now through the new post of High Representative for Foreign Affairs and Security Policy and other institutional innovations. The impact of these and other changes will be further addressed in Part III of this paper. 2. EU trade policy Due to the EU’s immense role in the international trading system, its singular status as a truly successful model of regional integration and economic growth and because of its long history dating back to the 1950s, European trade policy is an extensively researched and highly debated topic. This part of the thesis therefore does not aim at providing an extensive analysis of European trade policy, including a detailed description of decision making processes, trade policy instruments and display of trading figures.55 Rather, the focus will be on the two issues that are of particular interest for the tradedevelopment nexus: the allocation of competences and the system of preferences. The former is essential as it is concerned with the internal prerequisites of policy formulation; the latter 54 European Think Thanks Group: New challenges, new beginnings: next steps in European development cooperation, London 2010, pp. 31-54. 55 For further information on these aspects, see: Baldwin, Richard/Wyplosz, Charles: The Economics of European Integration, 3rd ed., New York 2009; Brülhart, Marius/Alan, Matthews: EU External Trade Policy, in El-Agraa, Ali M. (ed.): The European Union: Economics and Policies, 8th ed., Cambridge 2007, pp. 921-967. 12 mainly reflects the international environment and power structure the EU operates within. Both levels have to be taken into account when asking how to “make trade work for development.”56 2.1. Revolutionizing the allocation of competences Ever since the creation of the European Community with the Treaty of Rome in 1957, when the European supranational authority, the European Commission, was given exclusive competence to formulate, negotiate and enforce all aspects of trade relations with regard to trade in goods,57 a common trade policy has lied at the heart of European integration. Trade and integration hereby had a special connection in two ways: In the fist decades (from the 1950s to the middle of the 1990s) the common trade policy was mainly aimed at deepening regional integration through the creation of a customs union, followed by a common/single market and eventually an economic/monetary union. With the exception of agreements with the neighbouring countries and former colonies (ACP), EU PTAs were aimed at the completion of a truly integrated internal market and the achievements of the four fundamental freedoms as set out in the Treaty of Rome.58 Especially since 1995/96 however, when the EU introduced its Market Access Strategy, it has reinforced trade relationships with third countries, i.e. widening integration, by bilateral and multilateral preferential trade agreements with the rest of the world.59 56 European Commission: Making trade work for development. Aid for Trade: A selection of case studies form around the world, Brussels 2008. 57 See: Art. 113 Treaty of Rome. 58 Free movement of goods, labour, capital and services. 59 See Box. 3. Agreements after 1995 differ from earlier agreements with regard to their geographical scope, level of development of the partners as well as more sophisticated form of commercial integration. See: De Santis, Roberta/Vicarelli, Claudio: The European Union trade strategy. An empirical evaluation of preferential trade agreements’ effects on EU import flows, Lausanne 2006. Available online: http://www.etsg.org/ETSG2006/papers/vicarelli.pdf (25.6.2010). 13 Box 3: EU PTAs: 1957-2005 1.) EU PTAs: 1957-1995 Agreement EC (Treaty of Rome) Further Accessions EC — OCTs EC — Iceland EC — Norway EC — Algeria EC — Syria EC — Bulgaria EC — Bulgaria EC — Romania Date of entry into force 1958 1973, 1981, 1986, 1995 1971 1973 1973 1976 1977 1993 1995 1995 Type of Agreement Customs union FTA FTA FTA FTA FTA FTA Services agreement Services agreement 2.) EU PTAs: 1995-2005 Agreement EC — Turkey EC — Faroe Islands EC — Palestinian Authority EC — Tunisia EC — South Africa EC — Morocco EC — Israel EC — Mexico EC — FYROM EC — Croatia EC — Jordan EC — Chile EC — Lebanon EU Enlargement Date of entry into force 1996 1997 1997 1997 2000 2000 2000 2000 2001 2001 2002 2002 2003 2003 2004 EC — Egypt EC — Chile 2004 2005 Type of Agreement Customs union FTA FTA FTA FTA FTA FTA FTA Services Agreement FTA FTA FTA FTA FTA Accession to customs union and services agreement FTA Services Agreement Source: WTO 2006. 14 Although today the phenomenon of countries delegating their negotiating power to a different level through a deepening as well as a widening intergration process seems like a rather unequivocal version of the classical principal-agent model60, “the very idea that nation-states could give up such a key area of their external affairs was, and continues to be, revolutionary.”61 Hence re-emerging political and ideological battles about the scope of these competences itself have occurred on numerous occasions.62 Armed with the relevant legal authority through the EEC Treaty, from “its very creation, the European Community had spoken in international trade negotiations with a single external voice”63, which made it a singular undertaking in regional integration processes around the world and distinguished it from other preferential trading systems. However, the transfer of competences to the supranational level is not only interesting per se but also has a significant effect on development issues: One the one hand it makes the EU a very strong party in negotiations, while on the other hand, the complex multi-level governance structure can lead to inflexibility and inefficiency. The analysis of the EU-ACP in part II of this thesis will provide an example of both of these phenomena. This multi-level governance structure results from the fact that although trade is mostly described as an exclusive competence issue, member states still can have various ways of playing a decisive role in the policy making process’ different stages, i.e. the acquisition of an initial mandate, ongoing representation, and ratification. So far, i.e. prior to Lisbon, decision-making concerning trade in goods under Article 133 EC Treaty has functioned on the basis of qualified majority voting in the Council, i.e. proposals are initiated by the Commission, which also is empowered to conduct negotiations 60 The Member States as principals delegate their authority to conclude trade agreement to the European Community, who is the agent and acts on their behalf. For a more detailed analysis, see: Pollack, M: Delegation, Agency and Agenda Setting in the European Community, in: International Organization, Vol. 51, No. 1, pp. 99134.; Nicolaidis, Kalypso: Minimizing Agency Costs in Two-level Games: The Controversies over Trade Authority in the United States and the European Union, in: Mnookin, Robert/Susskind, Larry (eds.): Negotiation on Behalf of Others, Thousand Oaks 1999. 61 Meunier, Sophie/Nikolaidis, Kalypso: Who speaks for Europe? The Delegation of Trade Authority in the EU, in: Journal of Common Market Studies, Vol. 37, No. 3, 1999, p. 477-501, p. 478. 62 On the debate among MS regarding the transfer of sovereignty to the supranational level, see: Meunier, Sophie/Nicolaidis, Kalypso: EU Trade Policy: the Exclusive versus Shared Competence Debate, in: GreenCowles, Maria/Smith, Michael (eds.): The State of the European Union, Vol. V, Oxford 2000, pp. 325-346 63 Ibid., p. 325. 15 in consultation with a special committee appointed for this purpose by the Council, the socalled Article 133 Committee.64 Box 4: Art. 133(1) TEC The common commercial policy shall be based on uniform principles, particularly in regard to changes in tariff rates, the conclusion of tariff and trade agreements, the achievement of uniformity in measures of liberalisation, export policy and measures to protect trade such as those to be taken in the event of dumping or subsidies Box 5: Art. 300(1) TEC 1. Where this Treaty provides for the conclusion of agreements between the Community and one or more States or international organisations, the Commission shall make recommendations to the Council, which shall authorise the Commission to open the necessary negotiations. The Commission shall conduct these negotiations in consultation with special committees appointed by the Council to assist it in this task and within the framework of such directives as the Council may issue to it. In exercising the powers conferred upon it by this paragraph, the Council shall act by a qualified majority, except in the cases where the first subparagraph of paragraph 2 provides that the Council shall act unanimously. This Committee composed of high-level member states’ civil servants and chaired by the country holding the EU presidency, however, is perceived to be the “real power and decisionmaking centre”65 for the EU’s trade policy. Here, the main discussions take place and, following a tour de table of Member States’ views, amendments to the Commission’s proposals can be made either by the Council, the Commission or the Member States.66 Hence, the Committee “has a key role in ensuring that the Council accepts the final results of negotiations, and therefore in the formation of unity.”67 However, there remains a risk that during the negotiation process interpretations of the mandate by the Commission lead to member states feeling that they are unsatisfactorily represented. This is a potential source of 64 See Art. 133, 300 TEU, Boxes 4-5. Leal-Arcas 2008, p. 374. 66 Kernohan, David/Schneider, Andreas: Fiche on EU Trade Policy, in: CEPS: Policy Coherence for Development in the EU Council. Strategies for the Way Forward, Brussels 2006, 51-61. 67 Leal-Arcas 2008, p. 375. 65 16 conflict, deriving from necessity “to weigh the need to ‘speak with one voice’ in multilateral trade negotiations against the accountability of the Commission to the Council.”68 Although in the end, the final say remains with the Member States, which reassert their power through veto rights and the ratification by the Council through QMV (or prior to the Lisbon Treaty: unanimity), it is important to notice that the EU can only be respected as an international actor if negotiations are not impeded by diverging interests and positions of Member States. Prior to the Lisbon Treaty the European Parliament (EP) did not have any formal power for trade policy even though its assent was required when issues demanded the codecision procedure or where important budgetary implications exist, and it was informed about the negotiations by the Commission. In some areas the EP has already played a particularly active role however, e.g. in the context of the EPA negotiations, by “calling on various occasions for more flexibility on part of the Commission and by providing a platform for ACP countries to voice their concerns and raise awareness in the negotiations.”69 Chances are high that increased power of the EP will therefore also have a significant impact on the orientation of trade policy towards development issues as whoever “has the competence to determine trade policy objectives will also have a considerable impact on related policy areas”70. Moreover, competence allocation is also important as it has not been stagnant over time and the range of topics covered by the CCP has expanded. At the beginning of modern European integration in 1957, international trade law had a clear focus on goods, which explains why the EEC Treaty made explicit reference to trade in goods at that time. In its opinion 1/7871 the Court stated that the CCP should be interpreted widely, leaving room for debates on the extension of exclusive competence to topics such as services, trade related aspect of intellectual property and investments. The Court brought only little clarification in this regard through its Opinion 1/9472 as it restated that while trade in goods fell under the exclusive competence of the Community, this was only partly the case for services and 68 Gillson, Ian/Grimm, Sven: EU trade partnerships with developing countries, in: ODI – EDC Briefing, No. 4, London 2004, p. 2. 69 Makhan 2009, p. 143. 70 Holland 2002, p. 144. 71 Opinion 1/78 (International Agreement on Natural Rubber) [1979] ECR 2871. 72 Opinion 1/94 (WTO Agreement and GATS) [1994] ECR I-5267, para. 85. 17 intellectual property issues. This lead to some services being of EU, some of member state and others of mixed competence. Especially these ‘mixed agreements’ are little desirable from a development point of view as they require ratification on the EU as well as on the national level, hence giving national parliaments which disagree with a certain part of the agreement the ability to veto it in its entirety. Neither the Treaties of Amsterdam nor Nice were able to satisfactorily solve this issue,73 and the result was a rather “unreadable unsystematic and complex system of competence rules.”74 As will be explained in detail later, the Lisbon Treaty brings relief in that regard as it clarifies and extends EU competences. A shift of competences in the trade area towards further integration will therefore most likely have “repercussions across – or linkages to – other policy areas”75 such as development and thereby enhance the chances for a coherent EU approach. 2.2. The multidimensional preference system While, as stated above, with regard to the allocation of competences, EU trade policy can to some degree be described as ‘revolutionary’, its trade preference system can best be characterized as ‘multidimensional’. As former Trade Commissioner Mandelson pointed out in 2008: “Examples of the way that the EU pursues its pro-development policy objectives are to be found at all levels: at the multilateral level through the WTO negotiations, at the regional and bilateral level through the negotiation of trade agreements with other countries or regions (…), and at the unilateral or autonomous level through the Generalised System of Preferences.”76 Although the EU claims that “maintaining the WTO system, and ensuring that it continues to adapt to a fast-changing world, is a central priority for Europe‘s trade policy”77, it literally has “dozens of agreements governing trade with developing countries, which often overlap”78 and have become a source of controversy in the WTO for they are seen to be incoherent. This (additional) focus on regional integration is hardly surprising when keeping 73 In 1997, the Treaty of Amsterdam modified Article 133 to grant powers to the Community to negotiate agreements on services and intellectual property, but only on the basis of unanimity. The Nice Treaty in 2001 further shifted the weight towards exclusive competence by extending majority voting to these areas. 74 Bungenberg, Marc: The Common Commercial Policy after Lisbon, Jerusalem 2008, p. 7. Available online: www.micro5.mscc.huji.ac.il/~iasei/.../Lisbon_Papers/iasei_bungenberg.doc (27.6.2010). 75 Holland 2002, p. 144. 76 European Commission: Putting Trade Policy at the Service of Development, Brussels 2008, p. 5. 77 European Commission: What is Europe’s Trade Policy?, Brussels 2009, p. 3. 78 Stevens, Christopher: Creating a development friendly EU trade policy, Brighton 2005, p. 1. 18 in mind that regionalism is at the core of European identity itself 79 and that preferential trade agreements have long been used by the Community as a “way of binding potential members, neighbours and former colonies of its Member States more closely to it.”80 By the beginning of the new millennium, however, the European network of PTAs did not only include the traditional group of ACP countries, but also the Mediterranean region, Central Europe and the Western Balkans, as well as South Africa (1999), Mexico (2000) and Chile (2002) and was often pictured as a pyramid of preferences. Here, the most favourable treatment was granted to those countries that either belonged to the ACP group of states, or that fell into the least developed category or had completed bilateral trade agreements with the EU. The next included low and middle income countries that benefited only from noncontractual discretionary preferences offered by the Union under the terms of its Generalised System of Preferences which had been initiated in 1971. At the bottom of the hierarchy were countries which are members of the WTO but not of the GSP and therefore would solely receive the ironically-named MFN treatment.81 Box 6: EU Preferential Treatment: Pyramid of Privileges ACP Agreemen Generalised System of Preferences (GSP) Most-favoured Nation (MFN) Source: Persson/Wilhelmsson 2007; Stevens 2005 The launch of the DOHA-Round and the Managed Globalism initiative of the EU, however, turned out to become an "informal self-imposed moratorium (that) virtually brought the 79 Makhan 2009, p. 28. Rollo, Jim: Global Europe: Old Mercantilist Wine in New Bottles?, in: Aussenwirtschaft, Vol. 61, Nr. IV, 2006, pp. 403-413, p. 403. 81 See Box 6. 80 19 pursuance of new agreements to a halt.”82 Henceforth, the EU became one of the main advocates of the multilateral trading system, strongly working on enlarging the Doha Round to countries like China and Russia and the broadening of the scope of trade issues, i.e. by incorporating the Singapore Issues.83 The rationale was “the more members, the more countries (are) subjected to the rules and therefore the less anarchy in the trading system.”84 However, this strong focus on the multilateral level soon came to an end despite the awareness that many aims were best to be achieved through widespread international cooperation, a standpoint especially supported by the former EC Commissioner for Trade and today’s Director-General of the WTO, Pascal Lamy. Especially “the increasingly bleak prospects for a successful outcome of the Doha Round”85, led many countries to actively pursue a new policy towards trade liberalisation. Rather than further relying on multilateralism, they now strove for the conclusion of preferential trade agreements at the regional or bilateral level.86 Box 7: Evolution of Regional Trade Agreements in the world, 1948-2008 Source: WTO Secretariat 2009. 82 Makhan 2009, p. 28. For further information on the Singapore issues of issues investment, competition policy, government procurement and trade facilitation, see: Khor, Martin: The ‘Singapore Issues’ in the WTO: Implications and Recent Developments, New York 2004. 84 Meunier 2007, p. 912. 85 Makhan 2009, p. 30. 86 See Box 7. 83 20 This trend even implied the United States of America which long had been the principal advocate of the multilateral trading system since the establishment of the GATT.87 Under its new EC Trade Commissioner, Peter Mandelson, who took office in 2004, the EU followed this trend and re-oriented its trade policy away from a solely multilateral focus towards a “new generation of carefully selected and prioritised FTAs.”88 In the framework of Global Europe: Competing in the world. A contribution to the EU’s growth and jobs strategy, the EU engaged in the negotiation of new WTO-compatible FTAs, replacing the pyramid by a complex web of trade agreements, using different instruments and incentive systems. One of those, the EPAs with the ACP states, was soon advertised as the “flagship endeavour to make (better) use of trade for development.”89 The design of these new, hopeful means as well as whether they actually met their target will be analysed in the following case study. 87 Sally, Razeen: The End of the Road for the WTO? A snapshot of international trade policy after Cancun, in: World Economics, Vol. 5, No. 1, 2004, pp. 1-14. 88 European Commission: Global Europe: Competing In The World. A Contribution to the EU's Growth and Jobs Strategy, Communication from the Commission to the Council, the European Parliament, and the Committee of the Regions, Brussels 2006. 89 Makhan 2009, p. 22. 21 II. Linking Trade and Development: Case study of the EU-ACP negotiations on EPAs Although the “trade relationship between the EU and the ACP, (…) has generally been conceived of as a development partnership”90, analyzing the most recent EU-ACP negotiations is of particular relevance for development purposes as they introduced a new ‘formula’ very different from previous approaches by strengthening the trade-development nexus in a so far unknown way. “Indeed, the ACP and EU were among the first developed and developing country partners to establish tight linkages between trade and development”91 and agreed to them by contract.92 Box 8: Objectives of Cotonou Agreement, Art. 34 1. Economic and trade cooperation shall aim at fostering the smooth and gradual integration of the ACP States into the world economy, with due regard for their political choices and development priorities, thereby promoting their sustainable development and contributing to poverty eradication in the ACP countries. 2. The ultimate objective of economic and trade cooperation is to enable the ACP States to play a full part in international trade. In this context, particular regard shall be had to the need for the ACP States to participate actively in multilateral trade negotiations. Given the current level of development of the ACP countries, economic and trade cooperation shall be directed at enabling the ACP States to manage the challenges of globalisation and to adapt progressively to new conditions of international trade thereby facilitating their transition to the liberalised global economy. (…) Source: Partnership Agreement between the members of the African, Caribbean and Pacific Group of States of the one part and the European Community and its Member States of the other part, Cotonou 2000. The most recent negotiations have thus focused on aspects such as reciprocity, comprehensiveness, capacity building and flexibility, and hereby stand in stark contrast to the earlier approach that relied mainly on non-reciprocity, trade in goods only, the Bretton Woods institutions as negotiation partners, and a ‘one-solution-fits-all-countries’-attitude. This new approach, expressed through the initiation of negotiations for EPAs, proved to be necessary when it became apparent that the previous instruments did not stimulate the expected increase 90 Makhan 2009, p. 31. Martí, Darlan F./Rampa, Francesco: Aid for trade: twenty lessons from existing aid schemes – ECDPM Discussion Paper No. 80, Maastricht 2007. Available online: http://www.ecdpm.org/dp80p. 14 (5.7.2010). 92 See: Box 8. 91 22 of exports and economic performance and only few countries had actually benefitted from the Lomé preferential trade regime. Hence, hopes were great for the new EPAs – and still are, as was expressed by the EC delegation in front of the WTO Trade Policy Review Body in 2009: “Overall, EPAs will ensure a transparent and more predictable framework for trade and investment and stimulate regional integration as well as domestic adjustment and development processes.”93 European Commissioner Karel de Gruch reaffirmed the special and long-term character of the agreements when he recently declared at the opening speech of a Trade for Development conference: “(…) EPAs are about more than just negotiations. They should be regarded as a process, involving a long-term partnership never set in stone. “94 However, when the set negotiation deadline of December 2007 approached, only the Caribbean had reached an agreement with the EU on a regional and comprehensive EPA. In Africa and the Pacific most countries were solely able to agree on partial ‘stepping stone’ or interim agreements with the EU. Here, with the exception of the East African Community (EAC) that was able to agree on a regional interim agreement, full and regional agreements have yet to be concluded. Successful negotiations certainly depend on the will and capacity of all parties to cooperate, and failure to reach an agreement can hardly be traced back to one side only. Keeping in mind, however, that the EU initiated the negotiations with the intention to foster development, and undoubtedly is the stronger party, it is especially interesting to analyse whether the EU was indeed prepared to act as a partner for development and adequately support the ACP countries. In the light of the high expectations on behalf of the EU but the so far disappointing outcome, “the case of the EPA negotiations thus provides a relevant setting for analysis and assessment of the EU’s capabilities in formulating and managing a relevant and coherent trade policy for development.”95 93 WTO Trade Policy Review Body: Trade Policy Review. European Communities. Record of the Meeting, 68.4.2009. 94 Karel de Grucht, Opening speech at the “EU Trade Policy Towards Developing Countries" Conference, 16.2.2010. Available online: http://trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2010/march/tradoc_145890.en%20-%20ftw.pdf (20.6.2010). 95 Makhan 2009, p. 18. 23 Box 9: The ACP regions Africa • Southern African Development Community (SADC) o Angola, Botswana, Lesotho, Namibia, Mozambique, Swaziland and South Africa o Main exports to the EU: diamonds, oil, fish, beef, sugar, tobacco o Main imports from the EU: machinery, vehicles, chemicals • Eastern and Southern Africa (ESA) o Comoros, Djibouti, Eritrea, Ethiopia, Madagascar, Malawi, Mauritius, Seychelles, Sudan, Zambia and Zimbabwe o Main exports to the EU: copper, raw cane sugar, textiles, tobacco, processed tuna, o Main imports from the EU: machinery, vehicles, chemicals • East African Community (EAC) o Burundi, Kenya, Rwanda, Uganda and Tanzania o Main exports to the EU: plants, cut flowers, coffee, vegetables, fish, tobacco o Main imports from the EU: machinery, chemicals, vehicles • West Africa o All 15 members of ECOWAS and Mauritania o Main exports to the EU: oil, cocoa, bananas, pineapples, wood o Main imports from the EU: machinery, vehicles o Most important region for trade – 40% of all EU-ACP trade • Central Africa o All six members of the Economic Community of Central African States (CEMAC), plus the Democratic Republic of Congo and São Tomé and Príncipe. o Main exports to the EU: oil, wood products, diamonds, cocoa, bananas o Main imports from the EU: machinery, vehicles, chemicals, iron and steel, Pacific • Pacific Islands Forum (PIF) o 14 island states (biggest are Papua New Guinea (PNG) and Fiji) o Main exports to the EU: palm oil, sugar o Main imports from the EU: machinery, transport equipment Caribbean • Caribbean Forum of Caribbean States (CARIFORUM) o EPA since January 2008 covering all Caribbean states (Haiti joined in December 2009) o Main exports to the EU: fuel, chemicals, agricultural products (e.g. mangoes, bananas, rice, rum, sugar) o Main imports from the EU: machinery Source: European Commission 2010. 24 1. EU-ACP relations: from Yaoundé to Lomé and Cotonou The history of cooperation96 between the European Community and what is now called the African, Caribbean and Pacific Group of States dates back to the origins of European development policy in the Treaty of Rome, 1957, when the Member States decided to create some level of common policy towards their colonies and overseas countries and territories (OCTs).97 Two years later they established a common financial instrument for support, the European Development Fund (EDF). After the first EDF ran out after a period of five years in 1964, the EEC and the then eighteen Associated African Malagasy States (AAMS) concluded their first agreement in Yaoundé, Cameroon. Ever since, EDF cycles have generally followed the partnership agreement/convention cycles.98 Box 10: European Development Fund Cycles and Agreements First EDF: 1959-1964 Second EDF: 1964-1970 (Yaoundé I Convention) Third EDF: 1970-1975 (Yaoundé II Convention) Fourth EDF: 1975-1980 (Lomé I Convention) Fifth EDF: 1980-1985 (Lomé II Convention) Sixth EDF: 1985-1990 (Lomé III Convention) Seventh EDF: 1990-1995 (Lomé IV Convention) Eighth EDF: 1995-2000 (Lomé IV Convention and the revised Lomé IV) Ninth EDF: 2000-2007 (Cotonou Agreement) Tenth EDF: 2008-2013 (Revised Cotonou Agreement) Source: European Commission 2010. The early agreements of Yaoundé I and II mirrored both, the limited membership of European states to the Community at that time, as well as the historical and traditional ties of these countries. Therefore the geographical focus was on Sub-Saharan Africa, which only changed with the accession of the United Kingdom to the Community in 1973. Hereby the geographic scope of overseas trade and development relations broadened, now including some of the Commonwealth nations. The 1975 Georgetown Agreement institutionalized this fact by 96 For a detailed description and historical overview of EU-ACP relations please see: Holland, Martin: The European Union and the Third World, Hampshire 2002. 97 See: Treaty of Rome, 1957, Art. 131-136. 98 See Box 10. 25 creating the ACP Group of States. For the subsequent 25 years EU-ACP relations were governed by the Lomé (I-IV)Conventions that were held up as a model for the future of North-South relations in general and EU development policy in particular. This evaluation derived from the fact that the conventions contained “many novel features which seemed to suggest that the EU was prepared to buck the trend in international development and take on board some of the arguments put forward by the Third World in its quest for a New International Economic Order (NIEO).”99 This new approach was expressed, for example, in the non-reciprocity of trade preferences for most exports from ACP countries, the Stabex100 and Sysmin101 mechanisms, as well as a promise of equality between partners, respect for sovereignty, mutual interests and interdependence, and a pledge to the right of each state to determine its own policies.102 Between 1996 and 2000, however, in the context of regional and global changes, both on the EU and ACP level,103 significant reform occurred with regard to (not only) EU development policy. Democratization processes and structural adjustment in ACP countries, European enlargement and increased attention to Eastern European and Mediterranean partners, as well major economic and political changes in the international environment resulting from the Uruguay Round Agreement, led to the need to reform the existing partnership agreements. Especially the finding that despite the high level of preferential access, the ACP countries’ export performance in the EU market had been disappointing and their market share of EU imports had even declined from 5.1% in 1970 to 1.5% in 2004104 led to the EU’s proposal of negotiations for regional economic partnership agreements, replacing the non-reciprocal access by FTAs. Deficiencies identified in particular were the large number of instruments and funds 99 Arts/Dickson 2004, p. 2. Stabex is a mechanism designed to give ACP countries some insurance against the problem of instability of commodity products supply or prices by guaranteeing them a minimum income for approx. 40 agricultural products. For a critical analysis of the mechanisms, see: Lister, Marjorie: The European Union and the South. Relations with developing countries, New York 1997, pp. 125-131. 101 Sysmin loans are designed for countries heavily dependent on a particular mineral and suffering export losses. 102 European Commission: Development and relations with African, Caribbean and Pacific States, Brussels 2009. Available online: http://ec.europa.eu/development/geographical/cotonou/lomegen/lomeitoiv_en.cfm (18.6.2010). 103 Holland 2002, p. 43. 104 Brülhart, Marius/Alan, Matthews: EU External Trade Policy, in El-Agraa, Ali M. (ed.): The European Union: Economics and Policies, 8th edition, Cambridge 2007, pp. 921-967, p. 948. 100 26 (especially the European Parliament contributed to an increasing number of special budget lines), poor coordination as well as transparency and accountability problems and a weak management structure on the Commission level.105 These shortcomings led to the dissatisfying evaluation that “overall the EC was an organisation with a focus upon administrative procedures and disbursement rather than results, with little effective monitoring or evaluation of EC aid.”106 Hence, reform had to occur in various realms,107 addressing, among others, the questions of reciprocity, regionalization108 and differentiation109, capacity building, and poverty reduction.110 In 2000, the Partnership Agreement between the members of the African, Caribbean and Pacific Group of States of the one part and the European Community and its Member States of the other part was signed in Cotonou, Bénin. It was concluded for a twenty-year period from March 2000 to February 2020, entered into force in April 2003 and was revised in 2005. Despite a considerable number of changes, Cotonou hence continues the characteristical history of institutionalism and policy development of EU-ACP relations, while Europe’s links with other developing states ”continue to be comparatively rudimentary and ad hoc in nature.”111 Furthermore Cotonou is based on both, a development dimension as well as a political dialogue, which makes respect for human rights, democratic principles, the rule of law legal obligations and good governance obligatory and a breach will result in a consultation procedure and as a last resort in the reduction of development cooperation. Among the more concrete innovations of the Cotonou Agreement were the (intention to) focus on civil society and the private sector, stressing the role of non-state actors, and most 105 Among the disappointing statistical results presented in a Commission ‘Green Paper’ in 1997 were findings such as: ACP countries' share of the EU market had declined from 6.7 per cent in 1976 to 3 per cent in 1998 with 60 per cent of total exports concentrated in only 10 products, with just a handful of nations registering economic growth as a result of the trade protocols and preferences. Per capita GDP in sub-Saharan Africa grew by an average of only 0.4 per cent per annum 1960-1992, compared with 2.3 per cent for developing countries as a whole and only 6 per cent of African trade was with other countries of the continent. See: The Secretariat of the African Caribbean and Pacific Group of States: The Cotonou Agreement. Historical Note by the European Commission, Brussels 2010. Available online: http://www.acpsec.org/en/conventions/cotonou/cotonou_historical_note_e.htm (22.6.2010). 106 Daerden 2008, p. 4 107 For a detailed analysis of the reform areas, see part III. 2 of this thesis. 108 The principle of regionalization is to be seen as a departure from the strategy of the Lomé Convention, in which a uniform economic strategy remained towards all ACP-countries despite World Bank and IMF economic structural adjustments during the last decade of the twentieth century. See: Lister, M. 1997, p. 153. 109 Differentiation refers to different treatment according to the level of development. 110 Holland 2002, p. 200. 111 Ibid., p. 51. 27 importantly, the establishment of Economic Partnership Agreements (EPAs), i.e. comprehensive free trade agreements between the EU and several ACP-regions, as a means to reduce poverty and promote sustainable development.112 Their potential and actual impact on development will be analysed in the following. 2. EPAs: An efficient tool to fight economic marginalisation? By addressing what were seen as the major shortcomings of the then existing EU-ACP relationship, EPAs were hoped not only to improve the effectiveness of EU development policy with regard to these countries, and ensure that their regime was WTO-compliant, but to increase the trade-development-nexus overall. Then EC Commissioner Peter Mandelson hence asserted: “EPAs are the European Commission’s most basic expression of the desire to put trade and development together.”113 In order to achieve this goal, EPAs were designed to provide a number of innovative elements that were hoped to create beneficial effects not only individually but also as a ‘development package’.114 Among these elements were (i) the improvement of the quality and value of preferential access to EU markets and the overcoming of the restrictive approach of a preferential regime focused on tariffs and quotas only. Furthermore hopes for general (development) improvements through EPAs were high as the negotiations were now designed to provide (ii) comprehensiveness in scope, i.e. extend trade in goods only. Also, EPAs were (iii) to demonstrate the negotiating partners’ flexibility and potential for differentiated approaches and (iv) to increase capacity building of the ACP countries. Finally, hopes were high that (v) EPAs would also promote regional integration.115 112 See: Art. 1 and Art. 34.1 Coutenou Agreement, Figure XI. On the basis of the WTO “Enabling Clause” however, Cotonou also leaves room for unilateral initiatives of the EU : LDCs can export under the “Everything But Arms” initiative while non-LDCs are granted access via the “new framework for trade that is equivalent to their existing situations and in corformity with WTO rules (Art. 37.6). 113 Mandelson, Peter: Address to the European Socialist Party conference on Economic Partnership Agreements, Brussels 2006. 114 Makhan 2009, p. 38. 115 See Box 10. 28 Box 11: The EU’s vision on development with respect to the EPAs “The EU strongly supports a rapid, ambitious and pro-poor completion of the Doha Development Round and EU-ACP Economic Partnership Agreements (EPAs). Developing countries should decide and reform trade policy in line with their broader national development plans. We will provide additional assistance to help poor countries build the capacity to trade. Particular attention will be paid to the least advanced and most vulnerable countries. The EU will maintain its work for properly sequenced market opening, especially on products of export interest for developing countries, underpinned by an open, fair, equitable, rules-based multilateral trading system that takes into account the interests and concerns of the weaker nations. The EU will address the issues of special and differentiated treatment and preference erosion with a view to promote trade between developed countries and developing countries, as well as among developing countries. The EU will continue to promote the adoption by all developed countries of quota free and tariff free access for LDCs before the end of the Doha round, or more generally. Within the framework of the reformed Common Agriculture Policy (CAP), the EU will substantially reduce the level of trade distortion related to its support measures to the agricultural sector, and facilitate developing countries’ agricultural development. In line with development needs, the EU supports the objectives of asymmetry and flexibility for the implementation of the EPAs. The EU will continue to pay particular attention to the development objectives of the countries with which the Community has or will agree fisheries agreements.” Source: Paragraph 36, The European Consensus on Development 2006. Conceptually, EPAs are “a kind of regional integration agreement (RIA),”116 which – due to its reciprocal character – has the advantage of preventing countries from government intervention and deviation from agreed terms in order to profit from short-term benefits. An RIA thus provides a strong incentive to overcome such temptations as the deviating country will be punished by other members and might even be excluded. With regard to trade, EPAs have similar implications as FTAs. Here, countries gain from preferences because of the trade creation and consumption effects which derive from 116 Faber Gerrit: Economic Partnership Agreements and Regional Integratin among ACP countries, in: Babarinde, Ulofemi/Faber, Geritt (eds.): The European Union and the Developing Countries. The Cotonou Agreement, Leiden 2005, pp. 85-110, p. 87. 29 tariff reductions, allowing high-cost domestic production to be replaced by more efficiently produced imports from the partner country. As long as these effects outweigh trade diversion and trade deflection, a country gains form the FTA. Trade diversion occurs if trade shifts from sources having a comparative advantage to sources having preferential access to markets. Trade deflection results from the absence of a common trade policy with regard to trade barriers. Heterogeneous tariffs cause products to enter the FTA through the country with the lowest barriers, including those that are actually intended for a purchaser with higher barriers. In practice, this results in a shift of tariff income, lowering the amount of government revenue in the consuming country.117 Hence, FTAs and regional integration have a considerable potential to better engage countries in global trade and fight economic marginalisation. However, “in order to reap these gains, certain conditions have to be met, be it in terms of initial conditions or policies.”118 The following paragraphs take a closer look at these conditions and policies, and aim at pointing out difficulties on the Community side in dealing with the specific characteristics that shaped the negotiating partners’ backgrounds and positions as well as the EU’s ability to overcome “intrinsic constraints and complexities.”119 As it would exceed the scope of this paper to analyse all of the problems that occurred before and during negotiations in the five areas identified above, the focus will be limited to two elements in particular. The first one addresses the issue of capacity-building and provides a useful example of how shortcomings in ACP countries were not addressed in an adequate and timely way. This part therefore focuses on the weak character of EU responses. The second area analyses problems of the EU in actively phrasing flexible and acceptable positions with regard to the reform of RoO and quality of market access. A third, and final evaluation will touch upon the issue of regional integration, analyzing whether EPA actually foster or hinder this principle which is promoted as one of the major concerns on the EU development and trade policy agenda and hence constitute an efficient instrument to fight economic marginalisation. 117 Faber 2005, pp. 87-92. Ibid., p. 92. 119 Makhan 2009, p. 21. 118 30 2.1. Capacity building Already before negotiations could start, it was obvious that the ACP states were going to face a major problem in successfully participating in the discussion process: they lacked the capacities to define common positions. Reasons were manifold: in the past their policies were often influenced or even shaped and formulated by external actors, mainly by the Bretton Woods institutions. Hence, experience in defining and defending positions was low. Countries lacked the practical knowledge and technical skills to overcome “problems pertaining to the shortage of staff or to the lack of internal coordination between the various ministries sharing responsibility on trade-related policies as well as difficulties in engaging in consensusbuilding activities with non-state actors.”120 Moreover, developing a common stance on certain issues was impeded by the heterogeneity of the countries affected, e.g. with regard to their trade interests and level of development and the lack of political will of state and nonstate actors in formulating a common strategy.121 Fear of restructuring and adjustments was another reason that accounted for ACP countries arguing that they could “not ‘a priori’ accept to provide reciprocity in EPAs with the EU”,122 another issue that was fiercly discussed but will at this point not be analysed any further. Even before entering into negotiations the parties were aware of the need for capacitybuilding activities. Therefore they included corresponding provisions in the Cotonou Agreement123 and intended to realize those through financial and structural support for capacity-building activities on behalf of the EU, e.g. by setting-up negotiation fora and providing resources through the 9th EDF.124 Especially in the light of criticism brought forward later during negotiations, claiming that the EU had failed to adequately meet the difficulties of the ACP by not sufficiently supporting them in finding common positions, it is interesting to ask at this point whether it was actually necessary and/or desired at all that the EU as one negotiation party engaged in the intra-group discussions of the party, especially as the Community was clearly the stronger one. 120 Makhan 2009, p. 83. Ibid., p. 6. 122 Faber 2005, pp. 85-110. 123 See Art. 37, Cotonou Agreement. 124 Among the several EPA support programs under the 9th EDF were a 24 million campaign for projects aimed at improving the trade policy formulation and negotiation techniques of the ACP countries, a12 million program to help ACP countries integrate into the multilateral trading system, focussing on the effective participation in global trade negotiations, as well as on the implementation of the agreements and another 50 million program approved to support all ACP countries’ capacities for the EPA negotiations. See Makhan 2009, p. 86. 121 31 In this case, however, apart from the ‘historic responsibility’ that might have be felt on both sides, the matter of discussion was not simply the negotiation of trade preferences but an improvement of overall development. This aim, one can argue, made this unusual behaviour generally both, adequate and desirable. Moreover, no serious alternatives, e.g. the support of other non-EU developed countries, were available (and would probably not have been tolerated by the Union anyway). Finally, the EU had an interest in not taking advantage of the situation as it certainly wanted to “avoid the embarrassment of being shown not to care about the developing world”125 – a fact that protected ACP interests. However, as was just pointed out, EU responses eventually faced heavy criticism. Firstly, financial support was not provided timely enough126 which was mainly due to the lengthy ratification process of all 15 EU Member States and of the relevant institutions, Commission, Council and Parliament. Secondly, the disbursement of the funds was executed on the basis of application by the recipient states. The procedure for obtaining these resources, however, demanded a high level of organisation and strategic identification of needs from the ACP countries. Fulfilment of the requirements was therefore a serious burden for many ACP countries, given the overall weak governance and supervision structures, especially in LDCs.127 Thirdly, criticism on EU measures also occurred in another area. Apart from providing financial support, the EU also advised ACP countries on the institutional set-up necessary for formulating negotiation positions. Here, the Union favoured a participatory approach of state and non-state actors to ensure wide support. This was expressed through the set-up of socalled National Development and Trade Policy Forums (NDTPFs) which were supposed to formulate national positions towards EPAs which then could be merged into regional positions and be presented to the EU. Although the establishment of NDTPFs was indeed successful in many countries, only in few cases they were able to effectively involve all stakeholders, meet regularly and systematically and formulate a workable position. Although the Community produced impact studies and assessments to monitor the success of the financial and structural instruments, they also faced shortcomings as they were either produced too lately to actually 125 Wright 2005, p. 79. The Cotonou Agreement and thereby the 9th EDF only entered into force in April 2003 while EPA negotiations had already been ongoing since 2002. 127 Makhan 2009, p. 84. 126 32 be able to trigger improvements or lacked the necessary follow-up.128 Thus, the overall evaluation of EU support in capacity building is rather disappointing: “Despite generous and considerable efforts specifically targeted at enhancing the ACP countries’ capacities (…) the EU system, (…) was not capable of reacting in appropriate time for the challenges ahead, or in an adequate enough manner to measure up to these challenges.”129 2.2. Reform of RoO and quality of market access The multi-level system of EU decision-making turned out to be another major impediment for the formulation of a coherent policy and negotiation position. As was explained earlier, although trade policy is an area of exclusive competence, member states still influence it, notably through the Article 133 Committee. Especially with regard to the reform of the Rules of Origin (RoO) and the quality of preferential access to EU markets, “complex dynamics and diverging interests within the EU have slowed and limited policy response”130, although the RoO reform was already envisaged in the Cotonou Agreement.131 The Rules of Origin establish that a large number of ACP exports (especially manufactured and semi-manufactured goods) can enter the EU market subject to no or reduced customs and other non-tariff preferences, provided that their origin is certified as homeland production. The Lomé set of RoOs was highly restrictive as integrating intermediate inputs, necessary for a competitive end-product, was rather cumbersome and the administrative paperwork necessary to demonstrate conformity with RoO, such as documentation and accounting, was costly and complex. Decreased quality of market access refers to the problem that due to the progressive lowering of tariffs in the context of multilateral trade agreements, existing EU-ACP preferences were loosing their relative advantage. This effect was further intensified by the fact that the types of preferences granted with regard to tariffs and quantitive restrictions had become increasingly outdated in the light of the growing role of other non-tariff and technical 128 UNECA (United Nations Economic Commission for Africa)/AU (African Union): Assessing regional integration in Africa II: rationalising regional economic communities, Addis Ababa 2006. Available online: www.uneca.org/aria2. 129 Makhan 2009, p. 85. 130 Ibid., p. 11. 131 See Art. 37.7, Cotonou Agreement. 33 barriers such as health, quality and safety standards.132 During negotiations, the ACP countries aimed at a common set of RoO that could be applied to all EU-ACP EPAs in order to allow for the cumulation of products between ACP regions, and wanted to reach an agreement with the EU in this regard as soon as possible. Problems were twofold. One the one hand, the ACP group itself was unsuccessful in agreeing on a number of crucial factors such as the priority of sectors or the methodology to adopt. The EU, on the other hand, was reluctant to make any commitment in the first phase of the negotiations and only presented its formal market access and RoO offers shortly before the end of the negotiation deadline and the expiry of the WTO waiver in 2007.133 The EU’s conduct is surprising in two ways. Firstly, due to the already fairly liberal access of ACP countries to the EU, it was clear that only a review of the RoO could make the EPA package more attractive for them – an important fact the EU had to be aware of. Secondly, already in October 2003 the EC had submitted a first proposal to the Article 133 Committee which had been rejected, however. The fact that it took more than three years for the EC to come up with a second offer in April 2007, resulting in a long period of time during which negotiations in some regions were plainly frozen,134 demonstrates the large impact member states can have (through the Article 133 Committee) on shaping trade policy. Another example of how the competence allocation can lead to inefficiencies with regard to trade and development policy occurred with regard to the ACP requests to include legal guarantees for additional development resources besides the EDF into the EPAs. The need for such funding was widely acknowledged and the Commission made clear that “market access without aid for trade is like putting a plate of food in front of a man while withholding the knife and fork.”135 However member states (through the Council) refused to negotiate development resources as part of EPAs, let alone provide any kind of guarantees in the legal texts by not including the negotiation of development cooperation into the Commission’s mandate.136 132 Makhan 2009, p. 47. Ibid., p. 91. 134 Ibid., p. 143. 135 Mandelson, Peter et al.: Europe’s aid for trade pledge, in. Diario Noticias, 16.10.2007. Available online: http://trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2007/october/tradoc_136451.pdf (5.7.2010). 136 Bilal, San/Rampa, Francecso: Aid for Trade by the European Union: preliminary insight form the Economic Partnership Agreements, in: Bartel, Sandra/Dann, Philipp: The Law of EU Development Cooperation, BadenBaden 2008, pp. 77-102, p. 79. 133 34 2.3. Regional integration Furthermore, the EPA process was at times perceived to hinder and damage rather than foster regional integration processes. Such criticism was in stark contrast to the Community’s affirmation that promoting regional integration outside Europe is one of the cornerstone principles of EU trade policy, especially under Cotonou. Hopes are that regional integration of ACP countries will lead to lower risk for conflicts, the establishment of larger regional markets that are more attractive for investors through economies of scale and scope, and an overall increase in development due to spill-over effects and political leaders adopting a more strategic approach to developing their economies.137 Yet there were a number of reasons of both political and economic nature, especially in Africa, that proved to be major impediments to regional integration. Among those obstacles were the fear of revenue losses through reduced trade tax income which is a significant source of fiscal revenue for many countries,138 practical obstacles at land borders such as custom procedures, delay and corruption139, structural issues such as weak transport and communication infrastructure and a lack of skilled workforce. Hence, “the result of such dynamics is that in some cases, the ‘block’ EPAs are supposed to build on is de facto absent: unresolved inter-country rivalries (…) or lack of solidarity and competing aspirations for leadership (…) often impede regional integration processes.”140 Critics argue that the EU did not sufficiently factor in these problems into its policy and did not address them adequately, e.g. by making South-South integration141 a necessary prerequisite for North-South integration between the EU and ACP-countries. A two level integration strategy was finally embraced when EPAs initiated parallel North-South and South-South integration, but so far “there are no clear answers to be found in theoretical discussions” as to whether this approach “can be taken as development-friendly, or rather development-unfriendly.”142 The main criticism with regard to regional integration, however, did not derive from the fact that the EU seemed to not sufficiently take into account the existing impediments. 137 Wright, Stephen: Negotiating Economic Partnership Agreements. Contexts and Strategies, in: Babarinde, Ulofemi/Faber, Geritt (eds.): The European Union and the Developing Countries. The Cotonou Agreement, Leiden 2005, pp. 65-84. 138 Lesser, Caroline / Moisé-Leeman, Evdokia: Informal cross-border trade and trade facilitation reform in SubSaharan Africa, OECD Trade Policy Working Papers, No. 86, Paris 2009, p. 24. 139 Stevens, Christopher/Kennan, Jane: Preparing for Economic Partnership Agreements, Brighton 2005, p. 4. 140 Makhan 2009, p. 101. 141 South-south integration refers to integration between countries of similar, i.e. low, levels of development. 142 Makhan 2009, p. 68. 35 Rather, it was argued, did the EU actively hinder regional integration by offering alternative solutions to EPAs, such as the EBA initiative143 which was unilaterally adopted by the Council in February 2001. Such measures were possible as the Cotonou Agreement had introduced the principle of differentiation in accordance with the WTO enabling clause, allowing for different treatment, e.g. unilateral trade preferences to the benefit of all or groups of developing countries identified on the basis of objective and non-discriminatory criteria, such as their respective levels of development. Although an important instrument for the LDCs, the “adoption of the instrument stood in contradiction with the policy objective of regional integration envisioned by the EPAs”144 as it provided only one group of countries, the LDCs, with a competing incentive to post Lomé-negotiations on preferential trade terms, thereby risking to divide the countries along the EBA eligibility-line. However, the dreaded effects were not as severe as expected. ACP countries, including LDCs, chose to engage in the EPA negotiations nonetheless as they offered a more stable and predictable version of preferential treatment than the unilaterally granted GSP, of which EBA was also a part. Firstly, in contrast to EBA, EPAs provided ACP states with the potential to influence the content and scope of the agreements through negotiations (despite the shortcomings discussed above. Secondly, reciprocal, WTO-compatible EPAs were more secure in that they, unlike PTAs favouring one group only, faced little risk of being legally challenged, which would imply ACP countries falling back to the standard GSP access to EU markets shared by 176 other GSP beneficiaries of which many had greater productive and trading capacities and less favourable overall terms. 145 Obviously, such a development could not be in the ACP countries’ interest. Although the EBA initiative in the end did not prohibit LDCs from entering into negotiations about EPAs, this alternative incentive certainly contributed to the vagueness and indecisiveness of some states and the slow speed characterizing large parts of the negotiations. Other shortcomings hindering regional integration were the unequal performance of the Commission delegations in various countries as well as the uncoordinated member states’ policies of preferences towards certain countries, which increased uncertainty among ACP- 143 Under EBA, LDCs are guaranteed non-reciprocal duty-free quota-free access to the EU markets for all products with the exception of arms and transition periods for very few agricultural products. 144 Makhan 2009, p. 106. 145 Ibid., p. 107. 36 countries on whether a joint position would only strengthen other countries’ positions while weakening their own. Hence, a ‘let’s rather keep the benefits we already have’-approach was not uncommon.146 3. Lessons learned from the EPA negotiations Although first EU-ACP EPA negotiations were launched in 2002, by the deadline of December 2007, ambitions had proven to be too high, with only the EU and the Caribbean reaching a comprehensive regional agreement (CARIFORUM). Other regions and countries were only able to formulate WTO compatible interim agreements or other temporary solutions, so-called ‘stepping stone’ agreements. However, negotiations kept going on towards the conclusion of regional and comprehensive economic partnership agreements. Today, six out of eight initialled EPAs have been signed so far: the full EPA with CARIFORUM states (October 2008) and the interim EPAs with Cote d'Ivoire (2008), Central Africa, the SADC EPA States, the Pacific States and Eastern and Southern Africa States - ESA (all in 2009). The signature of the two outstanding initialled EPAs (with Ghana and East African Community - EAC) is expected in near future, however. The fact that most of the EPAs were only concluded around two years after the expiry of the initial 2007 deadline and eight years after the start of the negotiations illustrates that despite the remarkable potential EPAs have for the development, a number of factors have prohibited them from becoming the new and efficient tool that would improve the overall situation for developing and developed countries alike. Among those shortcomings were the limited capacities and little political will of many ACP countries to shape and implement the relevant measures. Further impediments were the stark complexities of trade negotiations as such, the multilevel nature of the EU system of governance with the particular problem of inflexibility, and the incoherent approach, e.g. with regard to regional integration. Hence, when analyzing which lessons are to be learned from the EPA negotiations, the following factors must be addressed: 146 European Think Tanks Group: New Challenges, New Beginnings. New Steps in European Development Cooperation, London 2010. 37 (i) Prior and during negotiations, the Union as the stronger actor failed to act upon the shortcomings on the ACP side and provide the necessary support in overcoming obstacles that were not simply due to a lack of political will. Therefore it will be essential for future negotiations to analyse the specific problems within certain regions and countries and support capacity-building at the earliest stage possible. This includes assistance in at least three ways: Firstly, Member States will have to ensure adequate funding, e.g. through Aid for Trade. Secondly, they will have to provide timely support in setting-up and supervising the relevant institutions in the partner countries. Thirdly, MS need to harmonise their own practices, procedures and requirements. As experience has shown however, it is essential that all of these prerequisites are realized prior to entering into negotiations. (ii) Another problem was that diverging interests between ACP countries and regions were actually further emphasised rather than harmonised, e.g. through (what was at least perceived as) competing incentives. It is therefore crucial to ensure that different policy instruments are coherent. Furthermore, communication with the trading partners must be enhanced, clearly explaining what are the gains and risks of each policy and pointing out to which extend and in which ways the instruments will complement each other. (iii) Furthermore, the EU had based its EPAs on regional clusters or blocks that in reality did not – or only in very weak terms – exist. This was probably partly due to a wrong perception of the already existent level of integration in many regions, maybe resulting from the attempt to translate European conditions into, for example, an African context. To avoid such misperceptions it will be indispensable in the future to investigate in detail whether regional integration issues have at all been on the list of priorities or whether countries so far have rather focused on overcoming internal struggles. Provided that the EU is willing to take on a new, less comprehensive view on regional integration, the Community can actively support these regions in identifying areas where integration is feasible, based on its own experience. (iv) Although foreign assistance is necessary and desirable to some extend, it is essential that the EU leaves developing countries more room in determining their own trade (and development) agenda. Many of the problems discussed under the capacity-building section actually derived from the fact that in the past ACP countries had little ownership of their trade and aid policies and therefore lacked expertise, staff and experience when they 38 were to formulate positions in negotiations. Hence, in order to strengthen these crucial prerequisites for policy formulation and implementation in the future, developing countries must learn to independently identify what their strengths and competitive advantages are. Chances are that this will lead to some activities the EU as a major supporter of trade liberalization might not approve of, e.g. the often-claimed protection of infant industries or sensitive sectors.147 However, questions are whether the learning-process of making own experiences with (the drawbacks of) protectionist activities might actually turn out to be more helpful for developing countries than being subject to foreign trade policies they do not own and therefore sometimes show little motivation to implement. (v) Finally, during the EPA negotiations, the EU has – on several occasions – not been able to formulate positions timely and flexibly enough. Therefore the Union has to work on its governance structure to facilitate negotiations, and increase the speed and quality of proposals. Flexible responses to developing countries’ needs and concerns are essential and have been lacking in the past. Institutional reform is therefore a necessary step to increase the development-potential of trade policy. 147 For a detailed discussion under which circumstances infant industry protection can indeed have welfareincreasing effects, see: Melitz, Marc: When and How Should Infant Industries Be Protected?, Michigan 1999. Available online: http://www.fordschool.umich.edu/rsie/workingpapers/Papers451-475/r451.pdf (29.6.2010). 39 III. An Agenda for Action Throughout this paper the case has been made that improving the link between trade and development is essential not only for the developing countries’ progress, but also for the European Union’s role as a credible, visible and effective global player. However, there are a number of other, more practical reasons on the part of the Union why it should increase its efforts for policy coherence, one of them being efficiency. An improved connection of trade and development policies means benefiting form economies of scale for funding instruments and from the combination of expertise, i.e. knowledge and staff. Furthermore, it allows the EU it make use of the unique ability to effectively promulgate its values such as human rights, freedom, democracy and rule of law, as it is both a significant economic power and a political actor engaged in foreign policy. A number of measures to improve the trade-development-nexus have already been taken lately. The most relevant and binding ones have occurred in the context of the Lisbon Treaty and will be analysed in a first step. The second part will then focus on further ideas of how trade-development cooperation can be strengthened. 1. De lege lata: The Treaty of Lisbon The Treaty of Lisbon which entered into force on 1 December 2009 is intended to reform the Union in several ways: It aims at increasing the EU’s overall efficiency and making it more democratic internally and its policies more coherent globally.148 The general aim is to “ensure smooth and efficient functioning of the enlarged EU in the globalised and fast-changing world.”149 Many of the changes contained in the Treaty of Lisbon therefore are not only of great importance for the Union’s inner functioning but also “reflect the latest phase in the gradual transformation of the EU (…) to a global player.”150 The objectives of the EU with regard to the wider world are defined in Art 3(5) TEU and encompass the promotion of values, the commitment to the eradication of poverty and protection of human rights.151 148 Pollet-Fort, Anne: Implications of the Lisbon Treaty on EU External Trade Policy, in: EU Centre Singapore Background Brief No.2, 2010, p. 2. 149 Kaczorowska, Alina: European Union Law, London 2009, p. 43. 150 Koeb, Eleonora: A more political EU external action. Implications of the Treaty of Lisbon for the EU's relations with developing countries, in: European Centre for Development Policy Management InBrief, No. 21, 2008, pp. 1-16, p. 1. 151 See Box 12. 40 Box 12: Art. 3(5) TEU In its relations with the wider world, the Union shall uphold and promote its values and interests and contribute to the protection of its citizens. It shall contribute to peace, security, the sustainable development of the Earth, solidarity and mutual respect among peoples, free and fair trade, eradication of poverty and the protection of human rights, in particular the rights of the child, as well as to the strict observance and the development of international law, including respect for the principles of the United Nations Charter. Already before the institutional innovations of the Lisbon Treaty were put into place, important policy frameworks were introduced to make EU development policy more coherent with other policies such as trade, fisheries or agriculture, and more effective through the harmonisation of MS policies. Examples are the already mentioned Development Policy Statement, the European Consensus on Development and the Code of Conduct on the Division of Labour in Development policy. The new structures introduced through the Lisbon Treaty differ from these earlier initiatives in that they constitute a more reliable setting than simply an agenda or action plan that can be changed more easily when certain goals or commitments become inconvenient. In the context of the financial and economic crises, for example, some countries have already reduced or postponed the development pledges they have made for this year.152 Rather than leaving trade aid and development cooperation subject to the volatility of public opinion,153 the Lisbon Treaty embeds the objectives in a legal framework that grants them far greater chances of longevity. As a matter of course, this part of the thesis cannot and does not intend to explain en detail all changes with regard to the EU’s external relations, let alone provide an overview of all reforms envisaged in the Treaty. Rather, the focus will be on the concrete changes affecting the design, implementation and connection of development and trade policy. These occur mainly in two areas.154 Firstly, the Treaty extends and clarifies EU competences. Secondly, it provides improvements of the institutional set-up and hereby promotes the inclusion of various policies (such as external trade and investment policy, foreign and security, environment and development policies and humanitarian assistance) in the now more unified EU foreign policy. 152 OECD 2010. Paxton, Pamela/Knack, Stephen: Individual and Country-Level Factors Affecting Support for Foreign Aid, in: The World Bank Policy Research Working Paper, No. 4714, Washington D.C. 2008. 154 Woolcock, Steve: EU Trade and Investment Policymaking After the Lisbon Treaty, in: Intereconomics, Vol. 45, No. 1, 2010, pp. 22-25. 153 41 1.1. Extension and clarification of EU competence As was already mentioned earlier, Art 207 TFEU brings services, TRIPs and foreign direct investment (FDI) into exclusive EU competence. Especially the extension of exclusive competence to FDIs is of great importance as it allows the EU to negotiate comprehensive agreements on trade and investments. So far investment was an area of mixed competence: the EC conducted investment negotiations focused on liberalisation, on a bilateral or multilateral level, while MS negotiated Bilateral Investment Treaties (BITs) which aimed at protecting their companies' investments abroad. Chances are that due to the transfer of competences, eventually a model EU investment agreement for future FTAs will replace the prevailing BITs. These will, according to the treaty, soon have to be adapted to EU law and most likely be ‘grandfathered’155 for the time being. These changes and clarifications in the allocation of competences “are expected to contribute to a streamlining of the trade policy.”156 This will lead to a reduction of the number and need of mixed agreements and create comprehensive economic agreements. With regard to the development dimension of trade policy, increased EU competence and especially fewer mixed agreements are generally appreciated as they reduce the number of actors and especially the national governments say in negotiations which often leads to a slow-downs and increased complexity. 1.2. Structural improvements When it comes to the institutional set-up of the EU’s foreign policy, the Treaty of Lisbon is significant in two ways157: on the one hand, it clarifies the responsibilities of the existing institutions. On the other hand, it aims at improving external relations performance and visibility through the creation of new ones. (i) As a first step, however, it abolishes the European Community and grants legal personality to the EU,158 which so far has been a mere political concept, hereby simplifying international representation.159 This implies that the former Commission’s delegations become 155 I.e. an exemption might be granted allowing the existing BITs to be kept in place until the adoption of EU investment agreements. 156 Pollet-Fort, Anne: Implications of the Lisbon Treaty on EU External Trade Policy, in: EU Centre Singapore Background Brief No.2, 2010, p. 3. 157 Santopinto, Federico: Réforme des traités: Une ‘coopération structurée permanente’ pour mieux armer l’UE, Brussels 2007, p. 7. 158 See Art. 47 TFEU. 159 Leal-Arcas, Rafael: Theory and Practice of EC External Trade and Policy, London 2008, pp. 91-96. 42 EU delegations with increased representative and actual power. The increased ability of the EU to ‘speak with one voice’ is not only essential during negotiations and for its perception as a political power. It may also serve as a role model for successful regional integration, which as the EPA negotiations have shown, is considered to be a crucial in promoting development. (ii) With regard to the reform of the existing institutions, it is particularly important to take a closer look at the role of the European Parliament concerning trade and development issues.160 In general the EP becomes more influential through extended use of the co-decision procedure, making approval of EU legislation by the Parliament obligatory. Before, many issues could only be indirectly influenced by the EP as the consultation procedure granted the Council a lot of leeway in accepting or ignoring the opinion expressed by the Parliament. Furthermore, the Commission now has to report regularly to the EP Special Committee on the progress of trade negotiations, although the EP itself may not authorize the EU to engage in those, a responsibility that remains exclusively with the Council. Due to the increased role of the EP in trade negotiations though, chances are that more lead time for preparation is required as more actors on the EU level are involved. However, when looking at the Parliament’s broad approach to trade issues in the past, including social, environmental, human rights and development considerations, hopes are that these areas will generally be addressed more extensively and will result in greater policy coherence.161 (iii) The deletion of Art. 179(3) EC, which established that EDF funds are outside the general EU budget and hence hardly subject to the influence of the Parliament, is another step in this direction of greater coherence. Although the deletion does not entail a legal obligation to integrate the EDF into the budget, and development cooperation in general remains a matter of shared competence, it “clearly strengthens the political case for a budgetisation of the EDF”162 and an increased say of the Parliament in development issues. (iv) Another formal aspects As Art. 3(5), 21( 1) TEU demonstrate, all elements of the EU’s external action - from CFSP to trade policy for example - are from now on submitted 160 National parliaments overall role will increase as they shall verify whether EU legislation is dealt with at the right level, i.e. controlling the compliance of the subsidiarity principle. This task will only have little effect on trade issues, however. 161 http://www.delphl.ec.europa.eu/docs/100126%20ECCP%20Lisbon.pdf 162 Martenczuk, Bernd: EU cooperation with developing and other third countries and the Treaty of Lisbon, in: Bartelt, Sandra/Dann, Philipp: The Law of EU Development Cooperation, Baden-Baden 2008, pp. 36-51, p. 51. 43 to the same principles and objectives, and most of the external relations provisions of the existing treaties are now regrouped in a single Title V. This stands in stark contrast to the preLisbon situation when the EC Treaty had Title IX Common Commercial Policy, Title XX Development cooperation, Title XXI Economic, financial and technical cooperation with third countries, international agreements, restrictive measures, international relations and instruments among the general and final provisions (Part Six). But not only the structural set-up of the external relations in the Treaty signals that an attempts to better link policies and increase coherence. There seems to be an overall “growing realisation in Brussels and Member States capitals that development policy is central to EU external action and ranks alongside other areas such as security and trade” and hopes are that “the more external policies are harmonised, the more prominence development will have.”163 1.3. Institutional innovations The Treaty of Lisbon provides a number of institutional innovations to increase policy coherence and effectiveness with regard to external affairs. Among those are the post of new High Representative for Foreign Affairs and Security Policy (as de facto Foreign Minister and Vice-President of the European Commission), European External Action Service (EEAS) and the 2.5 years-termed EU Council President. Certainly the creation of these institutions alone does not provide any hindsight on whether and how they will cooperate and critics fear competition, especially among the EUHR, the President of the European Council and the President of the Commission. With regard to linking trade and development, however, the position of High Representative of the Union for Foreign and Security Policy (HR for FASA) can be of great importance as. After all, it was not only established to coordinate and promote the common foreign policy of the EU - especially the Common Foreign and Security Policy (CFSP) and Common Security and Defence Policy (CSDP) - but also to “ensure consistency with other external policies, especially development, enlargement and trade.”164 The High Representative will be appointed by the Council by QMV and subsequently his/her appointment must be approved of by the president of the Commission. Despite this double legitimacy, the Treaty 163 Furness, Mark/Makhan, Davina: The Barroso II Commission: one small step to European development policy”, in: German Development Institute – Current Column, March 1, Bonn 2010. 2010. 164 Ibid., p. 2. 44 emphasizes that foreign policy is not transferred to the Commission or the EP and untimately remains in the hands of the Member States in case they cannot agree on a common position. “However, if there is a agreement between the Member States to present a common form on a particular issue, the voice of the HR for FASA (being the voice of 27 countries) will carry enormous weight.”165 This effect is further intensified by the fact that the HR has at its service the EEAS, as diplomatic corps and pool of expertise in foreign affairs. Whether the trade-development-nexus really will be strengthened will also depend on the personalities and relations of those holding office, and it is worthwhile to take a closer look at their qualifications and experience on the one hand and their attitude towards each other on the other. In this regard the current staff of the Barroso II Commission seems quite promising, as High Representative Baroness Catherine Ashton dealt in her former capacity as EU Trade Commissioner extensively with the EPA negotiations. The new Trade Commissioner Karel de Grucht also has experience with development questions as he not only was interim Development Commissioner in 2009 but also is a former member of the EP’s ACP-EU Joint Parliament Assembly and has already underlined the role of the European Parliament in trade policy on various occasions. This approach is further supported by the Commissioner for Enlargement Stefan Füle who already “promised the Parliament that he would work to foster development based on economic and political reform in neighbouring countries.”166 Although the various reforms described above “have the potential to significantly improve the EU’s policy and actions towards development countries”167, there remains a threat of increased incoherence “through a proliferation of overlapping activities by a multiplicity of actors.” Generally, however, the changes are perceived in a positive way and are expected to increase the trade-development relation. 165 Kaczorowska 2009, p. 54. Furness/Makhan 2010, p. 2. 167 Koelb 2008, p. 1. 166 45 2. De lege ferenda: Potential measures to promote policy consistency To change policies in a community of 27 countries, in the context of an institutional structure that has evolved over decades and a global environment that poses new challenges on a constant basis, is certainly not an easy endeavour. If the issues to be discussed touch upon the sensitive areas of trade and development, the undertaking gets even more challenging. Keeping in mind the particular relevance of these policies, however, justifies the effort of analyzing how they can be improved with regard to each other. The Treaty of Lisbon has already addressed a number of issues that were repeatedly discussed in this regard. However, these changes will hardly be enough to make up for all deficiencies that still exist and there is always room for improvement. This part of the thesis will therefore try to propose further measures that can be taken in order to make trade policy work for development. They derive from the literature as well as conclusions drawn from the case study on the ACP countries. 2.1. Consolidating EU and Member States’ activities A primary request is that the EU combines its powers and moves away from the still prevailing Member States driven approach in the development area. As was pointed out in the first part of the thesis, linking trade and development policy is a particularly complicated task, because there simply is not one trade and one development policy, but several versions of each that need to be combined. From a policy coherence point of view, Member States still have too much say in the formulation of the CCP and coordinate too little with respect to their respective development policies. (i) As chances are low that Member States will voluntarily hold back their interests to the advantage of others, reducing the number of actors and stakeholders is therefore a crucial element in overcoming this problem. The foundation has already been laid down through the position HR for FASA. Now Members States have to be wise enough to allow for sufficient leeway in decision-making and acting on the supranational level. National politicians have to realise the necessity to not compete with European representatives for international recognition. (ii) Keeping in mind the dispersed character of the various development policies, one means to improve the performance in this area would be to make MS specialise and focus 46 their efforts on fewer core countries or choosing a couple of main sectors they would like to engage in.168 An example of such a strategy has already been the case of Austria, which established itself, and was chosen by its fellow EU countries, as a lead donor for water and sanitation because of its particular expertise in these areas.169 Harmonisation of policies has further already proven successful in some African countries, such as Malawi, “where Sweden put Norway in charge of its entire country programme.”170 (iii) Furthermore changes should occur with regard to funding instruments. One option would be a significant shift of budget from the MS towards the Commission which could then make use of “the breadth of its global network”171 and expertise and distribute the resources accordingly. (iv) Chances are however, that most MS would not approve of such a ‘centralisation’ of national policies. Therefore national governments need to find another way – one that enables the Commission to play a more useful role, but respects the current division of competences between EU and national levels. Hence, consistency of European development efforts does not necessarily need to imply a shift of funds form bilateral programs to the supranational level, but simply demands “a larger role for EU institutions in bringing together community-wide development strategies, setting standards, and creating enforcement mechanisms to ensure that standards are more than empty rhetoric.”172 2.2. Engaging developing countries One-sided changes on the EU and MS level however, will not be enough. Rather, it is crucial to actively engage developing countries in both, trade and development activities, and formulate EU policies that keep in mind their needs and abilities. Two important areas where developing countries’ requests should definitely be taken into account if the EU wants its efforts to be taken serious, both from developing countries and the rest of the world, are the policies of fishery agriculture policies. Especially the latter, reflecting “more than three 168 Grimm, Sven: EU Development Cooperation: Rebuilding a tanker at sea, in: FES Briefing Paper, No. 6, 2006, p. 5. Available online: http://library.fes.de/pdf-files/iez/global/50421.pdf (13.7.2010). 169 Makhan 2009, p. 112. 170 Wanlin 2007, p. 13. 171 Ibid., p. 14. 172 Lundsgaarde, Erik/Makhan, Davina: Time for European Unity in Development, in: German Development Institute – The Current Column, Bonn 2010, p. 2. 47 decades of intra-EU political compromises and incremental trade-offs”173, has been under heavy criticism for not paying attention to the actual needs of developing countries.174 (i) Generally, the EU should move away from a donor-recipient approach towards a genuine relationship of partners. This would imply trusting in developing countries’ capabilities to know best a) where they have a competitive advantage and b) how to deploy resources accordingly. Concretely, aid agencies would no longer be in charge of selecting projects and manage funds, but leave these tasks to the governments themselves. Aiming at enhancing ownership in partner countries would therefore entail favouring budget support over aid initiatives.175 Certainly control and oversight would be indispensible to ensure resources would be used effectively and not be abused by particular groups or powerful individuals. (ii) The EU could further provide developing countries with their expertise in building public-private partnerships, reliable institutions and engagement of civil society groups (especially with regard to social and environmentally-sustainable development). These areas were also addressed in the Cotonou Agreement but so far have shown only very little output. (ii) Finally, and in continuation to the already existing, but half-hearted efforts (as illustrated in the results of the EPA negotiations), the EU should further support regional integration and South-South partnerships by providing expertise and financial resources.176 In this regard the Union should remember its own history of integration that was so crucial for the area’s development. Just as the EU followed its own path and speed, however, the Union must now – with regard to other countries – ensure it respects the local political and historical conditions and does not create artificial entities to pursue its own interests. The task of identifying regional partners should remain with the respective countries – just as the EU itself chose when to accept whom and under which conditions into its Community. 173 Holland 2002, p. 144. Nelson, Michael/Halderman, Michael: The EU, CAP & Developing Countries, Chicago 2004. 175 Schmidt, Petra: Budgethilfe in der Entwicklungszusammenarbeit der EU, in: Deutsches Institut für Entwicklungspolitik Studies No. 10, Bonn 2005. 176 European Think Thanks Group 2010, p. 21. 174 48 Conclusion This paper has aimed at analysing how the EU’s policies of trade and development interact and which improvements can be made in order to make the former become more development-friendly. The recent economic and financial crises have illustrated the important truth that global problems need to be dealt with by collective action. By the same token, linking the trade policy of the world’s largest trading bloc to development aims is a task that requires cooperative and co-ordinated behaviour of a magnitude of actors. The analysis of the EU’s trade and development policies and the case study on the ACP-EPA negotiations have shown that shortcomings can be attributed to several levels: (i) inefficiencies in the EU multi-level governance system, (ii) failure to cooperate among Member States and (iii) structural and political deficits in developing countries. On the one hand, this observation paints a rather dark picture as none of these groups seems to be working satisfactorily. On the other hand, however, it provides many angles and areas where improvements can be made. The analysis in this paper has shown that on the supranational level co-ordination must be enhanced so the EU can speak and act as a single power when required and provide timely and adequate responses to developing countries needs. On the national level, Member States need to realize that their interests can also (or even better) be achieved through coordination and that European integration also implies letting go previous forms of sovereignty and changing them for shared, but overall increased political and economic power. Developing countries, finally, have to learn that they need to formulate and implement positions and policies of their own and defend them in negotiations rather than expecting European policies to be tailored to their needs. On all three levels, steps have already been taken into the right direction. The EPA negotiations and several trade and development initiatives have shown improvements in the areas of quality of market-access, comprehensiveness, reciprocity, capacity-building and – to a lesser degree – also with regard to regional integration. Furthermore, common development objectives were agreed upon and turned into legally binding commitments. Finally, important institutional changes through the Treaty of Lisbon set the prerequisites for a more coherent and united policy of trade and development and a vast list of recommendations for future improvements exist. What is still needed though is the understanding of the importance to 49 make these changes work in order to strengthen the inner legitimacy of the EU itself, to contribute to the assertion of the EU’s identity in the international arena, and to support developing countries on their way to growth. Maybe the outlook that increased effectiveness of collective EU action can make an important contribution to these three areas at once will eventually be convincing. This year’s United Nations summit in September will provide a new chance to globally implement these recommendations and realise the Millennium Development Goal of using trade as a tool for development. Based in its experiences with shortcomings – but also due to the progress it has already made, the European Union has the potential to make important contributions. 50 Bibliography Abrahamsen, Rita: Disciplining Democracy: Development Discourse and Good Governance in Africa, London 2001. Arts, Karin/Dickson, Anna K.: EU development cooperation. From model to symbol, Manchester 2004. Bade, Klaus J.: Legal and illegal immigration into Europe: experiences and challenges, in: European Review, Vol. 12, No. 3, 2004, pp. 339-375. Baldwin, Richard/Wyplosz, Charles: The Economics of European Integration, 3rd ed., New York 2009. Bilal, San/Rampa, Francecso: Aid for Trade by the European Union: preliminary insight form the Economic Partnership Agreements, in: Bartel, Sandra/Dann, Philipp: The Law of EU Development Cooperation, Baden-Baden 2008, pp. 77-102. Brülhart, Marius/Alan, Matthews: EU External Trade Policy, in El-Agraa, Ali M. (ed.): The European Union: Economics and Policies, 8th edition, Cambridge 2007, pp. 921-967. Bhagwati, Jagdish: Trade Diverting Customs Unions and Welfare-Improvement: A Clarification, in: Economic Journal, Vol. 81, 1971, pp. 580-587. Bungenberg, Marc: The Common Commercial Policy after Lisbon, Jerusalem 2008. Available online: www.micro5.mscc.huji.ac.il/~iasei/.../Lisbon_Papers/iasei_bungenberg.doc (27.6.2010). Carbone, Maurizio: The European Union and International Development: The politics of foreign aid, London, 2007. 51 Collier, Paul: The Bottom Billion, Oxford 2008. Daerden, Stephen: EU Development Policy: Delivering Aid Effectiveness, in: Jean Monnet/Robert Schuman Paper Series, Vol. 8, No. 10, 2008, pp. 3-11. Davies, Martyn: How China delivers development assistance to Africa, Beijing 2008. De Santis, Roberta/Vicarelli, Claudio: The European Union trade strategy. An empirical evaluation of preferential trade agreements’ effects on EU import flows, Lausanne 2006. Available online: http://www.etsg.org/ETSG2006/papers/vicarelli.pdf (25.6.2010). Elliott, Kimberley Ann: Making Trade Preferences Work for the Poorest Countries, Washington D.C. 2010. Available online: http://www.cer.org.uk/pdf/wp738_develop_wanlin_07.pdf (28.6.2010). European Commission: Trade, Brussels 2010(a). Available online: http://ec.europa.eu/trade/wider-agenda/development/ (16.6.2010). European Commission: The EU and Trade, Brussels 2010(b). Available online: http://ec.europa.eu/ireland/about_the_eu/eu_in_the_world/trade/index_en.htm (22.6.2010). European Commission: European Union in the World - Trade Policy, Brussels 2009. Available online: http://ec.europa.eu/world/what/trade_policy/index_en.htm (17.6.2010). European Commission: Development and relations with African, Caribbean and Pacific States, Brussels 2009. Available online: http://ec.europa.eu/development/geographical/cotonou/lomegen/lomeitoiv_en.cfm (18.6.2010). European Commission: What is Europe’s Trade Policy?, Brussels 2009. 52 European Commission: Putting Trade Policy at the Service of Development, Brussels 2008(a). European Commission: Making trade work for development. Aid for Trade: A selection of case studies form around the world, Brussels 2008(b). European Commission: EU Code of Conduct on Division of labour in Development Policy, Brussels 2007. European Commission: Global Europe: Competing In The World. A Contribution to the EU's Growth and Jobs Strategy, Communication from the Commission to the Council, the European Parliament, and the Committee of the Regions, Brussels 2006. European Commission: Policy Coherence for Development - Accelerating progress towards attaining the Millennium Development Goals, Brussels 2005. European Think Thanks Group: New challenges, new beginnings: next steps in European development cooperation, London 2010. Faber, Gerrit: Economic Partnership Agreements and Regional Integration among ACP countries, in: Babarinde, Ulofemi/Faber, Geritt (eds.): The European Union and the Developing Countries. The Cotonou Agreement, Leiden 2005, pp. 85-110. Furness, Mark/Makhan, Davina: The Barroso II Commission: One small Step for European Development Policy, in: German Development Institute – Current Column, March 1, Bonn 2010. Gillson, Ian/Grimm, Sven: EU trade partnerships with developing countries, in: ODI – EDC Briefing, No. 4, London 2004. 53 Goldstein, Andrea et al. (OECD Development Centre): The Rise of China and India. What’s in it for Africa?, Paris 2006. Grimm, Sven: EU Development Cooperation: Rebuilding a tanker at sea, in: FES Briefing Paper, No. 6, 2006. Available online: http://library.fes.de/pdf-files/iez/global/50421.pdf (13.7.2010). Holland, Martin: The European Union and the Third World, Hampshire 2002. Humphreys, Macaratan: Economics and Violent Conflict, Harvard 2003. Kaczorowska, Alina: European Union Law, London 2009. Kemp, Murray/Wan, Henry: An Elementary Proposition Concerning the Formation Of Customs Unions, in: Journal of International Economics, Vol. 6, No. 1, 1976, pp. 95-97. Kernohan, David/Schneider, Andreas: Fiche on EU Trade Policy, in: CEPS: Policy Coherence for Development in the EU Council. Strategies for the Way Forward, Brussels 2006, 51–61. Khor, Martin: The ‘Singapore Issues’ in the WTO: Implications and Recent Developments, New York 2004. Kneller, Richard / Morgan, C.W. / Kanchanahatakij, Sunti: Trade liberalisation and economic growth, in: The World Economy, Vol. 31, No. 6, 2008, pp. 701-719. Koeb, Eleonora: A more political EU external action. Implications of the Treaty of Lisbon for the EU's relations with developing countries, in: European Centre for Development Policy Management InBrief, No. 21, 2008, pp. 1-16. 54 Kohnert, Dirk: African Migration to Europe: Obscured Responsibilities and Common Misconceptions, München 2007. Leal-Arcas, Rafael: Theory and Practice of EC External Trade and Policy, London 2008. Levy, Philip: A Political Economic Analysis of Free Trade Arrangements, in: American Economic Review, Vol. 87, No. 4, 1997, pp. 506-519. Lesser, Caroline / Moisé-Leeman, Evdokia: Informal cross-border trade and trade facilitation reform in Sub-Saharan Africa, OECD Trade Policy Working Papers, No. 86, Paris 2009, p. 24. Lister, Marjorie: The European Union and the South. Relations with developing countries, New York 1997. Lundsgaarde, Erik/Makhan, Davina: Time for European Unity in Development, in: German Development Institute – The Current Column, March 10, Bonn 2010. Martí, Darlan F./Rampa, Francesco: Aid for trade: twenty lessons from existing aid schemes – ECDPM Discussion Paper No. 80, Maastricht 2007. Malhotra, Davinder K./ Mariotz, Elizabeth: Performance of European Union Trading Bloc: Did Integration Help Nations?, in: Journal of Global Business and Technology, Vol. 1, No. 2, 2005, pp. 34-50. Makhan, Davina: Coordinating EU trade and development policy-making in a new context, in: Trade Negotiation Insight, Vol. 9, No. 2, 2010. Makhan, Davina: Linking EU Trade and Development Policies, Bonn 2009. 55 Mandelson, Peter et al.: Europe’s aid for trade pledge, in. Diario Noticias, 16.10.2007. Available online: http://trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2007/october/tradoc_136451.pdf (5.7.2010). Mandelson, Peter: Address to the European Socialist Party conference on Economic Partnership Agreements, Brussels 2006. Martenczuk, Bernd: EU cooperation with developing and other third countries and the Treaty of Lisbon, in: Bartelt, Sandra/Dann, Philipp: The Law of EU Development Cooperation, Baden-Baden 2008, pp. 36-51, p. 51. Melitz, Marc: When and How Should Infant Industries Be Protected?, Michigan 1999. Mény, Yves: De la Démocratie en Europe: Old Concepts and New Challenges, in: Journal of Common Market Studies 2002, Vol. 41, No. 1, pp. 1-13. Meunier, Sophie/Nicolaidis, Kalypso: Who speaks for Europe? The Delegation of Trade Authority in the EU, in: Journal of Common Market Studies, Vol. 37, No. 3, 1999, p. 477501. Meunier, Sophie/Nicolaidis, Kalypso: EU Trade Policy: the Exclusive versus Shared Competence Debate, in: Green-Cowles, Maria/Smith, Michael (eds.): The State of the European Union, Vol. V, Oxford 2000, pp. 325-346. Nelson, Michael/Halderman, Michael: The EU, CAP & Developing Countries, Chicago 2004. Nicolaidis, Kalypso: Minimizing Agency Costs in Two-level Games: The Controversies over Trade Authority in the United States and the European Union, in: Mnookin, Robert/Susskind, Larry (eds.): Negotiation on Behalf of Others, Thousand Oaks 1999. 56 OECD: Development aid rose in 2009 and most donors will meet 2010 aid targets, Paris 2010. Available online: http://www.oecd.org/document/11/0,3343,en_21571361_44315115_44981579_1_1_1_1,00 .html (18.6.2010). OECD: The Paris Agenda for Aid Effectiveness and the Accra Agenda for Action 20052008, Paris 2008. Available online: http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/11/41/34428351.pdf (15.6.2010). OECD: Policy coherence: Vital for global development, in: OECD Observer, Vol. 7, 2003. OECD/DAC: The DAC Guidelines, Poverty Reduction, Paris 2001. OECD: Open Markets Matter: The Benefits of Trade and Investment Liberalisation, Paris, 1998. Orbie, Jan/Versluys, Helen: The European Union’s international development policy: leading and benevolent?, in: Orbie, Jan (edt.): Europe’s global role: external policies of the European Union, London 2008 Overseas Development Institute: Trading out of crises and reducing vulnerability, London 2010. Available online: http://www.odi.org.uk/resources/download/4846.pdf (28.6.2010). Paxton, Pamela/Knack, Stephen: Individual and Country-Level Factors Affecting Support for Foreign Aid, in: The World Bank Policy Research Working Paper, No. 4714, Washington D.C. 2008. Persson, Maria/Wilhelmsson, Fredrik: Assessing the effects of EU trade preferences for developing countries, in: Bourdet, Yves/Gullstrand, Joakim/Olofsdotter, Karin (eds.): The European Union and developing countries: trade, aid and growth in an integrating world, Cheltenham 2007, pp. 29 - 48. 57 Pollack, Mark: Delegation, Agency and Agenda Setting in the European Community, in: International Organization, Vol. 51, No. 1, pp. 99-134. Pollet-Fort, Anne: Implications of the Lisbon Treaty on EU External Trade Policy, in: EU Centre Singapore Background Brief, No.2, 2010. Rodríguez, Francisco/Rodrik, Dani: Trade Policy and Economic Growth: A skeptic’s guide to the cross-national evidence, in: Macroeconomics Annual, Vol. 15, 2000, pp. 261-325. Rollo, Jim: Global Europe: Old Mercantilist Wine in New Bottles?, in: Aussenwirtschaft, Vol. 61, Nr. IV, 2006, pp. 403-413. Sally, Razeen: The End of the Road for the WTO? A snapshot of international trade policy after Cancun, in: World Economics, Vol. 5, No. 1, 2004, pp. 1-14. Santopinto, Federico: Réforme des traités: Une ‘coopération structurée permanente’ pour mieux armer l’UE, Brussels 2007. Schmidt, Petra: Budgethilfe in der Entwicklungszusammenarbeit der EU, in: Deutsches Institut für Entwicklungspolitik Studies No. 10, Bonn 2005. Stevens, Christopher: Creating a development friendly EU trade policy, Brighton 2005. Stevens, Christopher/Kennan, Jane: Preparing for Economic Partnership Agreements, Brighton 2005, p. 4. The 3C evaluation initiative: 3Cs defined, Leiden 2008. Available online: http://www.three-cs.net/3Cs-Defined (29.6.2010). 58 The Secretariat of the African Caribbean and Pacific Group of States: The Cotonou Agreement. Historical Note by the European Commission, Brussels 2010. Available online: http://www.acpsec.org/en/conventions/cotonou/cotonou_historical_note_e.htm (22.6.2010). Treaty of Lisbon amending the Treaty on European Union and the Treaty establishing the European Community, in: Official Journal of the European Union (OJEU), 17.12.2007, No C 306. United Nations Development Declaration, Resolution by the General Assembly, New York 2000. Van Reisen, Mirjam: EU ‘Global Player’: the North-South Policy of the European Union, Utrecht 1999. Wanlin, Aurore: What future for EU development policy?, London 2007. Wright, Stephen: Negotiating Economic Partnership Agreements. Contexts and Strategies, in: Babarinde, Ulofemi/Faber, Geritt (eds.): The European Union and the Developing Countries. The Cotonou Agreement, Leiden 2005, pp. 65-84. WTO, Committee on Trade and Development: Aid-for-Trade Programme 2010-2011, New York 2009. Available online: http://www.wto.org/english/tratop_e/devel_e/a4t_e/aid4trade_e.htm (16.6.2010). WTO Trade Policy Review Body: Trade Policy Review. European Communities, Record of the Meeting, 6-8 April 2009. Woolcock, Steve: EU Trade and Investment Policymaking After the Lisbon Treaty, in: Intereconomics, Vol. 45, No. 1, 2010, pp. 22-25. 59
© Copyright 2024