Strategic Management Journal Strat. Mgmt. J., 29: 593–616 (2008) Published online in Wiley InterScience (www.interscience.wiley.com) DOI: 10.1002/smj.676 Received 4 June 2006; Final revision received 4 December 2007 LEARNING HOW TO RESTRUCTURE: ABSORPTIVE CAPACITY AND IMPROVISATIONAL VIEWS OF RESTRUCTURING ACTIONS AND PERFORMANCE DONALD D. BERGH1 * and ELIZABETH NGAH-KIING LIM2 1 Daniels College of Business, Department of Management, The University of Denver, Denver, Colorado, U.S.A. 2 School of Business, Department of Management, The University of Connecticut, Storrs, Connecticut, U.S.A. This paper examines the role of learning in corporate restructuring. Drawing from two viewpoints of organizational learning, absorptive capacity and organizational improvisation, we examine whether experience with corporate restructuring modes (sell-offs, spin-offs) influences subsequent restructuring and financial performance. Consistent with an absorptive capacity view, cumulative and repetitive experience with sell-offs was related to the adoption of an ensuing selloff and to higher performance. Conversely, and consistent with an organizational improvisation view, short-term and contemporaneous experience with spin-offs was related to the subsequent use of spin-offs and to increases in financial performance. The findings contribute to a dynamic explanation of corporate restructuring and its influence on financial performance, illustrate differences between learning in a repetitive situation and learning when repetition is rare, and indicate when absorptive capacity and organizational improvisational views are most profitable. Overall, these findings show that different kinds of restructuring experiences were associated with different modes of restructuring and performance records. Considered collectively, the organizational learning perspective offers insights into why some corporate restructuring strategies appear as intentional and deliberate actions while others resemble more spontaneous and simultaneous responses. Copyright 2008 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. INTRODUCTION Corporate restructuring involves divesting, spinning off assets, and exiting business lines (Bowman and Singh, 1993; Johnson, 1996; Ravenscraft and Scherer, 1987). These actions are expensive, visible, and risky (Bergh, 1997; Gaughan, 1999; Hoskisson and Hitt, 1994). When making decisions about such events, managers would likely consider their organizations’ restructuring histories, as Keywords: corporate restructuring; organizational learning; absorptive capacity; organizational improvisation; spin-off; divestiture ∗ Correspondence to: Donald D. Bergh, Daniels College of Business, Department of Management, The University of Denver, 2101 S. University Boulevard, Denver, CO 80208, U.S.A. E-mail: [email protected] Copyright 2008 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. prior experiences could be drawn upon to reduce mistakes, improve decision making, and lower stakeholder anxieties (e.g., Allen, 1998; Donaldson, 1990). However, we have little knowledge of whether and how experience might matter to the restructuring decision; most research on experience and corporate strategic behaviors has focused on growth alternatives such as mergers, acquisitions, and alliances (Amburgey and Miner, 1992; Barkema and Vermeulen, 1998; Chang and Rosenzweig, 2001; Vermeulen and Barkema, 2001; Zollo, Reuer, and Singh, 2002). Does experience apply to restructuring decisions? If so, does it also influence profitability? Current understanding of the antecedents to and implications of restructuring is still in the developmental stages. Most research to date has portrayed 594 D. D. Bergh and E. N.-K. Lim restructuring as a purposeful response to governance, strategy, and industry pressures (Brauer, 2006; Bruner, 2004; Donaldson, 1990). For example, some have argued that firms use restructuring to improve internal efficiency in response to active takeover markets (Jensen, 1993; Kaplan and Weisbach, 1992; Shleifer and Vishny, 1991). Others have posited that shifts from weak to strong internal governance led to the use of restructuring to refocus corporate strategies (Chatterjee, Harrison, and Bergh, 2003; Hoskisson, Johnson, and Moesel, 1994; Johnson, Hoskisson, and Hitt, 1993). Another explanation proposes that restructuring reverses excessively diversified strategies to more optimal levels (Bergh and Lawless, 1998; Comment and Jarrell, 1995; Jones and Hill, 1988; Markides, 1992, 1995), and reduces information asymmetries between managers and owners (Bergh, Johnson, and DeWitt, 2008; Krishnaswami and Subramaniam, 1999). Furthermore, some have argued that restructuring discards unwanted parts of acquired asset bundles (Capron, Mitchell, and Swaminathan, 2001; Chang, 1996; Chang and Singh, 1999). Finally, theorizing from industrial organization economics has been used to link industry characteristics to corporate restructuring (Ilmakunnas and Topi, 1999; Harrigan, 1982). Few studies have considered the effects of experience on restructuring actions (e.g., Allen, 1998; Villalonga and McGahan, 2005), and even fewer examine how such experience might influence post-restructuring financial performance. Considered collectively, previous research provides insight into the reasons for and effects of restructuring, yet provides a limited explanatory framework for understanding how prior restructuring experiences might influence subsequent actions and performances. We currently have incomplete knowledge of whether and how experience matters with corporate restructuring. The present study develops and tests a theoretical model that relates experience to restructuring and to subsequent financial performance. Specifically, the model draws on two viewpoints of organizational learning to link restructuring experience heterogeneity to the adoption of different forms or modes of corporate restructuring actions. First, the model applies absorptive capacity arguments to relate cumulative and repetitive restructuring experience to the development of explicit knowledge that serves as the basis for routines and standardized procedures that, in turn, help facilitate Copyright 2008 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. efficient and economically beneficial restructuring by sell-off. Second, the model uses the organizational improvisation viewpoint to tie short-term, recent, and real-time experience heterogeneity to the development of tacit knowledge that leads to restructuring by spin-off. The different restructuring experiences, development of knowledge stocks, and subsequent use of sell-off and spin-offs are then related to post-restructuring financial performance. The study tests these alternative explanations and restructuring behaviors using different time intervals. The findings suggest several contributions. They extend explanations of corporate restructuring by integrating a dynamic construct—experience— into the restructuring process and to post-restructuring performance. In addition, by incorporating absorptive capacity and organizational improvisation into an organizational learning perspective of how firms restructure, the findings support a more expansive and comprehensive model of corporate restructuring and how it influences performance. Furthermore, the results integrate different approaches to corporate restructuring; some actions, particularly sell-offs, appear to reflect deliberate and intentional responses while others, especially spin-offs, reflect more of a spontaneous and contemporaneous adaptation. The findings contribute to the organizational learning perspective by offering insight into the absorptive capacity and organizational improvisation perspectives using different methods and conditions, by illustrating differences between learning in a repetitive situation and in a setting when repetition is rare, and by indicating a set of conditions when absorptive capacity and organizational improvisational views are most profitable relative to one other. THEORY AND HYPOTHESES The theoretical model applies arguments from two viewpoints of organizational learning, absorptive capacity and organizational improvisation, to explain how restructuring experience could influence mode adoption and post-restructuring performance. An organizational learning model is particularly appropriate because it provides a theoretical rationale for linking experience to actions and outcomes. More specifically, learning has been defined as a systematic change in behavior or Strat. Mgmt. J., 29: 593–616 (2008) DOI: 10.1002/smj Learning How to Restructure 595 Absorptive capacity . Repetition . Explicit knowledge . Routines Restructuring mode . Sell-off . Spin-off Performance . Accounting performance . Market performance Organizational improvisation . Real-time, novel . Experience heterogeneity . Tacit knowledge Figure 1. Theoretical model knowledge informed by experience (Cyert and March, 1963; Levitt and March, 1988). Learning is believed to occur when ‘experience generates a systematic change in behavior or knowledge’ (Miner, Bassoff, and Moorman, 2001: 315). The viewpoints of absorptive capacity and organizational improvisation represent opposite learning explanations (e.g., Levinthal and Rerup, 2006; Miner et al., 2001; Winter, 2003) and provide a complementary and integrative basis for hypothesizing how experience may influence restructuring actions and their effects on financial performance. We begin by reviewing the two most prevalent restructuring modes. Then, we present the theoretical logic of the two viewpoints of learning, apply the arguments to restructuring actions, and ultimately to post-restructuring financial performance. Figure 1 presents our theoretical model and indicates the hypothesized relationships. Sell-offs and spin-offs as alternative restructuring modes Corporate restructuring is generally used to downscope, downsize, or refocus diversification strategy (Hoskisson and Hitt, 1994; Johnson, 1996), and is conducted through a variety of alternatives or modes including liquidations, sell-offs, spin-offs, and equity carve-outs (Bruner, 2004; Gaughan, 1999). The most popular modes for implementing restructuring are the sell-off and spin-off (Khan and Mehta, 1996; Nixon, Roenfeldt, and Sicherman, 2000). A sell-off, also known as a divestiture, arises when assets are sold from one firm to another in exchange for cash and/or securities (Hite, Owers, and Rogers, 1987; Jain, 1985; Rosenfeld, 1984). A spin-off occurs when a firm ‘distributes on a pro rata basis all the shares it owns Copyright 2008 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. in a subsidiary to its own shareholders’ (Weston, Chung, and Hoag, 1990: 224; Miles and Rosenfeld, 1983; Schipper and Smith, 1983), and in the process creates a separate, publicly traded firm from the spun-off assets. Sell-offs and spin-offs represent substantially different ways to restructure. Sell-offs are used to transfer assets to other firms that might realize higher value from their acquisition or to rid the selling firm of assets that interfere with its operations or strategy (John and Ofek, 1995). In most cases, sold-off assets were not performing well, were not creating value that met expectations, or were used to raise proceeds that could be utilized to pay down debt and/or be reinvested in the restructuring firm’s strategy (Bergh, 1997; Brauer, 2006; Duhaime and Grant, 1984; Hoskisson et al., 1994; Taylor, 1988). Sell-offs involve a liquidation process, decisions about how the restructured assets will be marketed, and how the transaction will be managed. Investment banks often manage these processes: they locate buyers, arrange financing, and manage the exchange of the soldoff assets. Sell-offs usually involve assets residing in secondary and unrelated businesses relative to the primary and core lines of the parent firm (Bergh, 1995a; Bergh et al., 2008; Comment and Jarrell, 1995; Ravenscraft and Scherer, 1987). The sell-off ends with the transfer of asset property rights (Alexander, Benson, and Kampmeyer, 1984; Donaldson, 1990). By contrast, spin-offs are typically used to separate assets that have promising and high growth potential opportunities that cannot be realized within the parent firms’ structure (Aron, 1991; Bruner, 2004), oftentimes while maintaining postrestructuring relationships with the parent firm Strat. Mgmt. J., 29: 593–616 (2008) DOI: 10.1002/smj 596 D. D. Bergh and E. N.-K. Lim (Ito, 1995; Kudla and McInish, 1984). They reorganize ownership among existing shareholders, produce no cash proceeds, and reduce the level of assets under the control of the parent management. The spun-off assets become independent from the parent and require a new corporate governance system, including leadership and directory boards (Seward and Walsh, 1996; Walsh and Seward, 1990). In addition, spin-offs often involve assets residing in or related to the restructuring firm’s core business lines (Bergh et al., 2008; Nixon et al., 2000) and employ internal control systems that emphasize interface management, which coordinate ongoing strategic and organizational relationships after the restructuring has been completed (cf., Aron, 1991; Ito, 1995). For example, when PepsiCo spun-off its fast food division, Tricon (consisting of KFC, Pizza Hut, and Taco Bell), long-term contracts were designed to sustain continuing value-creating interactions among the firms. One such contract involved the assignment of soda fountain property rights and obligations. In this case, some Tricon firms were required to agree to continue to exclusively sell PepsiCo soda fountain products before the spin-off was finalized. Overall, sell-offs and spin-offs have unique motives and are used under different circumstances (Bergh et al., 2008; Bruner, 2004; Nixon et al., 2000). These dissimilarities provide conditions and opportunities for managers to develop specific and unique knowledge about how to formulate and execute each type of restructuring mode. The implications for learning and adoption of sell-offs and spin-offs are considered next. Two different viewpoints of organizational learning, absorptive capacity, and organizational improvisation are related individually to the restructuring actions. Absorptive capacity, sell-offs, and financial performance One research stream in the organization learning literature posits that experience creates knowledge that can be stored into and retrieved from an organization’s memory (Huber, 1991; Levitt and March, 1988; Fiol and Lyles, 1985). Managers and their firms have an ability to recognize the value of new knowledge, assimilate it, and apply it to commercial ends, a learning viewpoint known as absorptive capacity (Cohen and Levinthal, 1990; see Lane, Koka, and Pathak, 2006; and Zahra and Copyright 2008 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. George, 2002, for expanded definitions). Absorptive capacity is a function of prior organizational problem solving (Lane, Salk, and Lyles, 2001), and is developed through the accumulation of experiences (Cohen and Levinthal, 1990; Lane and Lubatkin, 1998; Pennings and Harianto, 1992). Specifically, the underlying premise of absorptive capacity ‘is that the organization needs prior related knowledge to assimilate and use new knowledge. . .accumulated prior knowledge increases both the ability to put new knowledge into memory. . .and the ability to recall and use it’ (Cohen and Levinthal, 1990: 129). The absorptive capacity view assumes that learning is cumulative and learning performance is highest when the object of learning is related to what is already known (Cohen and Levinthal, 1990; Lane et al., 2006; Zahra and George, 2002). Moreover, absorptive capacity also includes an organization’s ability to exploit information. From this view, a firm’s absorptive capacity is influenced through its level of prior related knowledge, repetition, and intensity of its exposures to similar events (Kim, 1998; Vermeulen and Barkema, 2001; Zahra and George, 2002). Firms draw from absorptive capacity to create explicit knowledge that can be developed, codified, and applied to improve decision making, revamp knowledge stocks, and overcome traps to knowledge development (Lane et al., 2006; Lane and Lubatkin, 1998; Zahra and George, 2002). Cumulative experiences would be translated into explicit knowledge that would guide organizational actions and behaviors (Amburgey, Kelly, and Barnett, 1993; Haleblian, Kim, and Rajagopalan, 2006; Shaver, Mitchell, and Yeung, 1997). Once developed, learning is then made explicit in operating procedures, formalized systems, and routines (Haleblian and Finkelstein, 1999; Cyert and March, 1963; March and Sevon, 1984). In addition, new search rules evolve slowly (Chang and Rosenzweig, 2001; Cyert and March, 1963; Miller and Friesen, 1980), so organizations tend to persist in the same activity over time (Miller and Friesen, 1980, 1982). Overall, the creation and maintenance of absorptive capacity is an iterative and repetitive process where firms learn from experiences, make inferences, and store knowledge that can be codified and applied to future decisions (Cohen and Levinthal, 1990; Hayward, 2002; Zahra and George, 2002). Hence, past experience can lead Strat. Mgmt. J., 29: 593–616 (2008) DOI: 10.1002/smj Learning How to Restructure to both greater absorptive capacity and greater learning. The absorptive capacity view of organization learning has been used to help explain growth and expansionary behaviors such as mergers and acquisitions (M&As). For example, when a firm engages in an M&A, it develops absorptive capacity for understanding that action (Barkema and Vermeulen, 1998; Baum, Li, and Usher, 2000; Haleblian and Finkelstein, 1999). Additional M&As of the same type allow ‘competencies to be refined, which [subsequently] increases the likelihood of even more acquisitions of the same type’ (Amburgey and Miner, 1992: 336). This experience creates absorptive capacity that in turn allows firms to learn how to become more efficient at clearly defined problems, such as those involving corporate strategy behaviors such as acquisitions and alliances (e.g., Hayward, 2002; Villalonga and McGahan, 2005). In addition, after accumulating knowledge with a particular M&A activity, managers tend not to welcome new risks associated with using a different type (Nelson and Winter, 1982; Pennings, Barkema, and Douma, 1994). Even negative consequences associated with prior experiences may not cause managers to change; indeed, poor performance may not deter the repetitive learning that can be ascribed to experience (Amburgey and Miner, 1992; March, 1991). Instead, M&A performance problems may be attributed to execution issues rather than evidence of mistaken actions or problems in learning (Haleblian et al., 2006). This reasoning can be extended to explaining exiting behaviors such as corporate restructuring and how managers might select between restructuring modes (Figure 1). Experience with restructuring could create absorptive capacity that would facilitate knowledge development that would be explicitly codified into systems, routines, and procedures that could help guide future behaviors. Repetition would also create momentum to repeat the same type of restructurings used in the past (Amburgey and Miner, 1992; Baum et al., 2000; Villalonga and McGahan, 2005). Furthermore, corporate restructuring is a vehicle for realizing an objective (Bowman and Singh, 1993; Johnson, 1996; Markides, 1992, 1995), so managers would likely focus on the desired outcome and might not want to reconsider how to restructure each time such an action was necessary. Managers would have incentives to exploit organizational memory Copyright 2008 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. 597 and absorptive capacity, and to make their decision and move forward as efficiently as possible to accomplish the objective of the restructuring. Past experiences lead to greater absorptive capacity and learning that would likely apply to restructuring decisions. The absorptive capacity view of learning pertains more to sell-offs than spin-offs because selloffs provide more of the conditions necessary for accumulating experience benefits, assimilating knowledge, and developing the explicit knowledge that can be codified into routines and standardized procedures (Figure 1). First, the process for selling assets involves more stages, parties, and decisions than spin-offs, thus presenting greater opportunities for identifying and realizing economies from repetition. For example, sell-offs involve the validation, liquidation, and replacement of assets, marketing, and management of transaction costs associated with searching, negotiating, and exchanging the assets with an external third-party buyer. Spinoffs do not require asset liquidation, replacement, or marketing, and involve parties affiliated with the restructuring firm, where the transaction occurs through a reorganization plan involving established relationships (Kudla and McInish, 1984). The selloff process involves more stages and complexities than the one used for spin-off, creating greater potential for experience and learning curve benefits (cf. Lieberman, 1987, 1989). Second, the control systems used to manage the assets in sell-offs would facilitate the communication necessary to create absorptive capacity. Specifically, and as noted above, sell-offs typically involve assets in unrelated business units and lines (Bergh, 1995a; Bergh et al., 2008; Nixon et al., 2000; Ravenscraft and Scherer, 1987). These assets are typically managed with arms-length financial controls and profit center accounting techniques that focus on general and objective measures such as return on assets, market shares, and profit margins (Hill, Hitt, and Hoskisson, 1992; Hill and Hoskisson, 1987; Jones and Hill, 1988). The use of observable measures create transparencies that enhance interpretation, communication, and knowledge transfer (Szulanski, 1996), while also providing managers with a clear understanding of the factors that influence the performance of the restructuring transaction. In addition, with greater transparency, absorptive capacity is increased and more learning can occur (Lane et al., 2001). Managers would have a higher quality knowledge Strat. Mgmt. J., 29: 593–616 (2008) DOI: 10.1002/smj 598 D. D. Bergh and E. N.-K. Lim basis for drawing correct inferences about the restructuring process and better understanding for future decisions (Hayward, 2002; cf. Haleblian and Finkelstein, 1999), both of which contribute to absorptive capacity. Spin-offs, by contrast, tend to involve idiosyncratic and related business assets and are structured on a case-by-case basis (Bergh et al., 2008; Ito, 1995; Nixon et al., 2000). The restructuring process for spin-offs would be more variable than that used by sell-offs, making it difficult to develop experience and repetition benefits, absorptive capacity, and the explicit knowledge that leads to routines and systematized procedures that can be leveraged for learning curve economies. Moreover, spun-off firms are more likely to have close relationships with their restructuring firms. These associations are managed using controls that focus on interface management and sharing and accounting of specialized resources, and ambiguity can exist about the communication of knowledge sharing and transfer between the two firms (Khan and Mehta, 1996; Kudla and McInish, 1984). These characteristics impede the benefits of experience, reduce the potential for developing absorptive capacity, lower the development of the procedures needed for standardization, and constrain the economizing potential associated with repeated actions (Cohen and Levinthal, 1990; Szulanski, 1996). Hence, the benefits and learning from long-term experience and absorptive capacity are likely to apply more to sell-offs than to spin-offs. In sum, greater experience with sell-offs would lead to higher absorptive capacity and to the development of explicit knowledge that can be codified into routines and standardized procedures. Managers would exploit absorptive capacity by applying the learning from past experience in similar choices to reduce risks in subsequent decisions (Chang and Rosenzweig, 2001). As firms therefore gain experience with restructuring by sell-offs, we predict that they will continue to use those methods. Changing to spin-offs poses additional costs. We hypothesize: Hypothesis 1: As firms gain experience with selloffs, they will continue to use sell-offs as a form of corporate restructuring strategy. The absorptive capacity view of organization learning may also help explain post-restructuring financial performance (Figure 1). Experience with Copyright 2008 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. corporate restructuring would increase absorptive capacity and knowledge (Hayward, 2002; Pennings et al., 1994; Zollo and Singh, 2004), which would provide a basis for more effective management. With subsequent increases in absorptive capacity there would likely be fewer errors, the development of specialized and standardized routines, and increased execution effectiveness (Ahuja and Katila, 2001; Levinthal and March, 1993). In addition, accumulating absorptive capacity in one period will permit its more efficient exploitation in the next (Cohen and Levinthal, 1990). It follows that firms with greater absorptive capacity gained through prior experience will have a better foundation to create knowledge, assimilate and interpret opportunities, and more effectively develop and apply explicit knowledge than firms with less experience. Furthermore, the potential to develop absorptive capacity is critical; firms with higher levels of experience can better ‘refine, extend, and leverage existing competencies or. . .create new ones by incorporating acquired and transformed knowledge into [their] operations’ (Zahra and George, 2002: 190) than firms with lower levels of experience. Firms having more experience and higher absorptive capacity would be able to use their resources more effectively and leverage their greater ability to transform experience benefits than firms with less. Absorptive capacity has been conceptualized as a dynamic capability that can lead to competitive advantage and above-normal performance returns (Narasimhan, Rajiv, and Dutta, 2006; Winter, 2003; Zahra and George, 2002; Zollo et al., 2002). Experiences with restructuring would help reduce process costs and competency traps. Moreover, by reducing costs associated with the processes and activities of assimilating and integrating newly acquired information, firms having more experience with restructuring are likely to have higher post-restructuring performance than those having less. This logic likely applies more closely to sell-offs because they have higher potential for absorptive capacity than spin-offs. Sell-offs have the potential for standardization of the restructuring process, are managed with financial control systems that present lower barriers to internal knowledge transfer, and offer conditions more favorable for generalization—none of which can be as easily realized by spin-offs. Firms having more experience with sell-offs can draw on their Strat. Mgmt. J., 29: 593–616 (2008) DOI: 10.1002/smj Learning How to Restructure absorptive capacity to develop explicit knowledge to codify routines and standardized procedures that can economically and advantageously guide the deal-making process, terms, and governance process. That experience translates into higher absorptive capacity and knowledge to apply to subsequent sell-offs. By contrast, firms with low numbers of prior sell-offs have lower absorptive capacity, less knowledge to exploit, and are more prone to procedural errors that can lead to disadvantageous situations. Firms with less experience are lower on the learning curve and do not have the explicit knowledge to develop economically valuable routines and standardized procedures. These firms are also likely to be less effective at managing the processes of developing and exploiting new knowledge. They stand to gain less financial benefits. We predict that those with the most repetition over time with sell-offs will have standardized procedures and routines for better formulating and executing the sell-offs resulting in higher performance. Hypothesis 2: Firms that have more experience with sell-offs will have higher financial performance after a subsequent sell-off than firms that have less experience with sell-offs. Improvisational learning, spin-offs, and financial performance Another research stream in the organizational learning literature describes how learning can occur in short-term, recent, and real-time settings. Based on observing musicians, actors, firefighters, and new product development teams (Berliner, 1994; Brown and Eisenhardt, 1995; Vera and Crossan, 2005; Weick, 1993), a much different conception of organizational learning known as organizational improvisation is emerging, one that applies to settings where planning models and prior and repetitive experiences play a smaller role. Some actions can occur without advanced planning or long-term experience (Cohen, March, and Olsen, 1972; Cyert and March, 1963; Moorman and Miner, 1998b), and the conception and logic of organizational improvisation has been developed in an effort to help explain learning in such settings (Crossan et al., 2005; Eisenhardt and Tabrizi, 1995; Hatch, 1997; Moorman and Miner, 1998a, 1998b). Organizational improvisation is a type of short-term learning, where experience and related Copyright 2008 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. 599 change occur at or near the same time (Miner et al., 2001; Vera and Crossan, 2005). It has been presented as a form of learning on the basis that experience heterogeneity and recombinations of stored knowledge, routines, and skills can lead to systematic changes in behavior (Hatch, 1997; Miner et al., 2001; Moorman and Miner, 1998a). Improvisation has several characteristics that distinguish it from other learning views (Miner et al., 2001). First, it has a reduced temporal gap between the planning and implementation of unique actions; the more temporally proximate the design and execution of a behavior, the more likely the action is improvisational (Crossan et al., 2005, 1996; Moorman and Miner, 1998a, 1998b). Improvisation has been described as spontaneous and ‘in-the-present’ (Crossan et al., 2005: 131), and has been used to explain how managers resolve a surprising problem and/or create value from an unexpected opportunity (Weick, 1996, 2001). It is not the repeating of a preexisting routine, nor is it pre-designed or standardized. Second, it applies to actions and decisions that are novel, or deviations from standard practices, and improvisers draw from information and resources available to them at the time the decision is necessary, also known as bricolage (Levi-Strauss, 1967). Improvisation is tailored to specific contexts and idiosyncratic to a time and place (Baker and Nelson, 2005; Miner et al., 2001; Vera and Crossan, 2005). Third, organizational improvisation pertains to fast and uncertain decisions (Brown and Eisenhardt, 1995; Moorman and Miner, 1998b; Vera and Crossan, 2005), requiring managers to draw from organizational memory, or ‘stored information from an organization’s history that can be brought to bear on present decisions’ (Walsh and Rivera, 1991: 61). Improvisation draws from experience heterogeneity and creatively recombining and applying learned routines and knowledge (Weick, 1993; Hatch, 1997; Miner et al., 2001). Greater memory enhances improvisation because it allows decision makers to apply retrospectives and real-time information to unanticipated situations (Crossan et al., 2005; Weick, 1998; Weick and Roberts, 1993). Organizational memory is a product of two parts: procedural memory and declarative memory. Procedural memory is ‘how things are done’ (Cohen and Bacdayan, 1994: 554) and ‘things you can do’ (Berliner, 1994: 102). It is derived from rich understanding of skills and routines, and a welldeveloped procedural memory allows managers to Strat. Mgmt. J., 29: 593–616 (2008) DOI: 10.1002/smj 600 D. D. Bergh and E. N.-K. Lim draw from declarative memory, or the ‘memory for facts, events, or propositions’ (Cohen, 1991: 137; Tippins and Sohi, 2003). When managers can combine well-developed procedural memory with declarative memory, they are likely to have higher tacit knowledge of how their organizations operate (Cohen, 1991; Cohen and Bacdayan, 1994; Winter, 1987), and can make improvisational decisions that are more coherent, novel, and timely (Moorman and Miner, 1998a). For example, Moorman and Miner (1998a) invoke the instance of a jazz musician being able to improvise when he/she has developed a large repertoire of relevant musical experiences, while Weick (1993) describes a master bricoleur as requiring preexisting routines to create a new tool to solve a novel problem. Weick (2001) goes another step by describing improvisation as ‘just-in-time strategy’ that is predicated less by investment in anticipation and more on the development of general knowledge, large skill sets, an ability to react quickly, and trust in intuition (Weick, 2001: 352). Winter (2003) notes that organizations can be ‘pushed into “firefighting” mode, a high-paced, contingent, opportunistic and perhaps creative search for satisfactory alternative behaviors. . .[where] problem solving is not routine. . .not highly patterned and not repetitious. . .it typically appears as a response to novel challenges. . .or other relatively unpredictable events. . .[and] typically arises from a foundation of patterned and practiced performance. . .’ (Winter, 2003: 992–993). Hence, improvisation requires tacit knowledge gained from having procedural memory of routines and skills that can access the declarative memory of the organization’s key knowledge stocks (Moorman and Miner, 1998a; Miner et al., 2001). Higher levels of tacit knowledge facilitate improvisation by materially reducing the time between the composition of a solution to a problem and the execution of the action to affect it. Organizational improvisation may describe corporate restructuring actions (Figure 1). Most theoretical perspectives depict restructuring as a response behavior (see Brauer, 2006; Haynes, Thompson, and Wright, 2003; Johnson, 1996, for reviews), used for quickly improving the firm’s economic and strategic conditions (Hoskisson and Hitt, 1994; Hoskisson, Johnson and Moesel, 1994; Markides, 1992). It is often driven by uncertainty (Bergh, 1998; Bergh and Lawless, 1998; Leiblein Copyright 2008 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. and Miller, 2003), and can be a punctuated and fast action rather than a continuous and evolving process (e.g., Donaldson, 1990; Hoskisson and Hitt, 1994; Ravenscraft and Scherer, 1987). Improvisation may apply to such actions, as ‘under conditions of time pressures and/or uncertainty, a planning orientation is insufficient. . .[and] [i]improvisation becomes an alternative or complementary orientation’ (Crossan et al., 2005: 133). In addition, restructuring tends to occur when needed, so the time interval between restructuring actions may be too long or too short to allow for absorptive capacity to be developed and sustained. Very long intervals make it difficult for managers to remember or apply the lessons and routines from prior experience, while short ones do not provide ample time for repetitive learning to occur (Argote, Beckman, and Epple, 1990; Baum and Ginsberg, 1997). Moreover, managers may be reluctant to codify learning and generate inferences from activities that they do not expect to repeat (Szulanski, 1996; Winter and Szulanski, 2001). Furthermore, a firm’s post-restructuring performance can vary (Cusatis, Miles, and Woolridge, 1993; Desai and Jain, 1999; Daley, Mehrotra, and Sivakumar, 1997), which could influence the intensity with which managers search for inferences from prior experiences (Hayward, 2002; Levinthal and March, 1993). Finally, restructurings that occurred in recent years are frequently integrated with ensuing actions that collectively represent a strategic reaction to resolving the matter that drove the restructuring (Donaldson, 1990; Hoskisson and Hitt, 1994; Hoskisson et al., 1994). Restructurings in more distant years may not be as pertinent or applicable. Even numerous restructurings spread over several prior years could play a weaker role, because they may not be part of the response that was created for resolving the motivating factors. Hence, some restructurings may not offer the conditions for constructing the routines and repetition necessary for developing absorptive capacity and may be influenced more by short-term and real-time experience that draws from stored knowledge, learned routines, and skills. The improvisation logic likely applies more to restructuring through spin-offs rather than sell-offs. First, spin-offs typically occur infrequently (e.g., Donaldson, 1990), and are less numerous than sell-offs (Gaughan, 1999; Bruner, 2004). Because of their lower occurrence, spin-offs offer fewer opportunities for developing repetitive routines and Strat. Mgmt. J., 29: 593–616 (2008) DOI: 10.1002/smj Learning How to Restructure may be seen as deviations from a firm’s planned corporate strategy. For example, spin-offs are not usually motivated by financial proceeds, as their financial implications are limited to possible tax savings and expected future gains associated with adjusting and making clearer the restructuring firm’s strategy (Allen, 2001; Cusatis et al., 1993; Daley et al., 1997; Desai and Jain, 1999; Krishnaswami and Subramaniam, 1999; see Bruner, 2004, for a review). Spin-offs would not likely be preplanned or anticipated as a method of value creation. However, by contrast, firms can buy and sell off units for profit, a value-creation process known as ‘arbitrage,’ where gain is realized by selling at a higher price than the original purchase amount. The differences in financial proceed potential may help explain why spin-offs are relatively rare compared to sell-offs. Second, the principal parties to a spin-off are directly related to the restructuring firm, while those associated with a sell-off are at least partly external (e.g., the buying firm and its stakeholders). When making a spin-off, there is less potential for temporal holdups between the design and execution of the restructuring action; the need for temporal delays would be minimized, as the restructuring firm’s managers would develop and implement a process that would transfer property rights to their owners. The separation and postrestructuring governance of the spun-off assets would all occur internally. By contrast, the selloff process involves several iterative stages that would serve to lengthen the temporal gap between design and execution, including finding an acquiring firm, negotiation, due-diligence, the approval of different sets of stockholders and government entities, and ultimately a ‘close’ of the deal. The time interval between the design and execution of the spin-off would likely be less than that for the sell-off. Third, managers can draw from rich organizational memory when making spin-off decisions. In particular, as noted above, spin-offs usually involve assets that reside within the core businesses of the restructuring firm (Bergh et al., 2008; Ito, 1995; Khan and Mehta, 1996; Nixon et al., 2000). These assets are typically managed with the face-to-face methods necessary for developing the memory necessary for improvisation (Eisenhardt, 1989; Moorman and Miner, 1998b; Sproull and Keisler, 1991). In such settings, managers tend to use control systems that involve close attention and Copyright 2008 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. 601 detailed and subjective judgment, and focus on the transaction level of analysis where performance is assessed by factors such as quality, transfer price, and productivity (Hill, Hitt, and Hoskisson, 1992; Hill and Hoskisson, 1987). This managerial intensity would create high procedural and declarative memory, as the managers have detailed knowledge of the operating affairs and control procedures used for managing the relationships with core business assets. Similarly, through having interfaced closely over time, managers develop a refined understanding of the restructured assets and a set of routines that guide their decision making. The operational-level detailed knowledge achieved through close and repeated interactions could create partner-specific experiences that in turn would contribute to tacit knowledge (Zollo et al., 2002). Finally, the top managers of the spun-off assets usually come from the restructuring firm (Aron, 1991; Seward and Walsh, 1996). The restructuring firm’s managers would have developed a rich set of routines for working with the leaders of the to-be restructured assets. With a higher degree of familiarity and likely face-to-face knowledge of the spun-off asset’s managers, the restructuring firm’s managers would have greater tacit knowledge to draw upon, enabling faster decision making and facilitating convergence in the time between planning and execution of a restructuring action (cf. Moorman and Miner, 1998a). In sum, the organizational improvisational view may help describe restructuring by spin-offs. These actions tend to be rare and novel, have less potential for temporal holdup between design and execution, and involve managers who can leverage learning from rich organizational memory and high-tacit knowledge. Short-term and contemporaneous experience would provide the impetus for generating organizational change and recombining stored knowledge and skills to act in real-time manner. We predict that recent spin-offs will have a more influential effect on subsequent spin-off adoption than those occurring in temporally distant years. Hypothesis 3: Recent experience with spin-offs is related more positively to the likelihood of a subsequent spin-off than temporally distant experience with spin-offs. Strat. Mgmt. J., 29: 593–616 (2008) DOI: 10.1002/smj 602 D. D. Bergh and E. N.-K. Lim Improvisation has been linked to financial performance, a relationship that is influenced by several factors, including expertise, teamwork skills, organizational memory, and real-time information and communication (Crossan et al., 2005; Tippins and Sohi, 2003; Vera and Crossan, 2005). When any of these factors is high, managers have more specialized knowledge, increased collaboration, and higher coordination that in turn facilitates adaptation and anticipation (Amabile, 1996; Weick, 1993; Weick and Roberts, 1993). With a more richly developed basis from which to draw upon, managers are better able to apply learning from recent and relevant events to improvisational decisions (Eisenhardt, 1989; Eisenhardt and Tabrizi, 1995). They have an increased ability to react to real-time information flows and can make improvisations of higher quality that lead to higher performance and effectiveness (Crossan et al., 2005; Vera and Crossan, 2005; Moorman and Miner, 1998b; Weick, 1993). This logic applies most closely to spin-offs, as spun-off assets are typically in business lines where restructuring managers have high expertise, have worked closely together and interfaced regularly with other managers, and are more likely to have developed open information sharing and fast and accurate communication routines (e.g., Bergh et al., 2008; Ito, 1995; Khan and Mehta, 1996; Nixon et al., 2000). The managers in these circumstances could apply their tacit knowledge of the assets to subsequent actions and make better informed and more effective decisions (Baker and Nelson, 2005; Winter, 2003). Their actions could be made in real time and based upon immediate feedback from recent information (Crossan et al., 2005; Moorman and Miner, 1998a). And, by drawing upon high degrees of expertise, teamwork, and open information-sharing, managers could implement the most appropriate spin-offs that provide effective and immediate resolution to the problem driving the restructuring, leading to a faster and more positive effect (e.g., Brown and Eisenhardt, 1995; Miner et al., 2001). In addition, since spin-offs tend to occur less frequently than sell-offs (Bruner, 2004; Gaughan, 1999; Nixon et al, 2000), managers would be less likely and less able to store information about them for long periods of time (e.g., Szulanski, 1996). Consequently, short-term experience from recent spin-offs and those in consecutive years would Copyright 2008 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. be more relevant and valuable for current decision making. Spin-offs occurring in years more distant to a focal restructuring event are less applicable because the learning from those events may not be directly associated with the idiosyncratic nature and problems of the current restructuring. When learning is rooted in more recent spinoff experiences, then those particular events will have the highest potential for influencing learning, tacit knowledge, decision making, and postrestructuring performance. Overall, financial performance would be influenced less by spin-offs occurring in the distant past and more by those that resolve the current issues facing the firm (e.g., Hamilton and Chow, 1993; Markides, 1992, 1995). Hypothesis 4: Recent experience with spin-offs is related more positively to financial performance following a focal spin-off than experience with spin-offs in temporally distant years. METHOD Sample Consistent with other empirical studies of restructuring (Bethel and Liebeskind, 1993; Markides, 1992, 1995; Hoskisson et al., 1994), the hypotheses were tested by a sample of restructuring firms. The sample was determined using several steps. First, we randomly identified 300 firms that made restructuring announcements between 1 January 1990 and 31 December 1997. This number and time period were selected to help ensure a large sample that was diverse enough for testing the hypotheses. The firms and restructuring announcements were found in the Securities Data Corporation’s Worldwide Merger & Acquisition Database (SDC), 2000. Second, we examined each restructuring firm to determine whether it was publicly held, that it resided in a nonregulated industry, that the restructuring was voluntary and completed, and that it was based in the United States. These screens were necessary to ensure data availability and consistency. Ninety-five firms were removed, and the final sample consisted of 205 firms that announced and implemented a restructuring action. Third, mean comparisons of the 205 retained firms with the 95 discarded firms indicated no significant differences in terms of the transaction size (dollar value of the restructuring event), profitability Strat. Mgmt. J., 29: 593–616 (2008) DOI: 10.1002/smj Learning How to Restructure (return on assets [ROA]), year, debt, and spin-off and sell-off occurrence. Dependent variables Restructuring mode represented how the focal restructuring event occurred. This variable was coded as 1 when the focal restructuring event was a spin-off and as a 0 when it was a sell-off. The classification of spin-off and sell-off was found in the SDC‘s Worldwide Merger & Acquisition Database, 2000. No restructuring events were a hybrid of the two alternatives or another type of restructuring. Financial performance was measured as the ROA and mean earnings per share (EPS) for each of the five years after the year of the focal restructuring event. ROA is one of the most common accounting-based performance measures and correlates highly (r = 0.9 or higher) with other such proxies, including return on sales (ROS) and return on equity (ROE). EPS reflects financial performance from the investor’s perspective. Using both measures reflects the multidimensional aspects of financial performance. The data were found in COMPUSTAT. Independent variable Experience was measured as the count of prior restructuring events; it was the number of spinoffs and sell-offs made by each restructuring firm during the 10 years prior to the year of the focal restructuring. The SDC Merger & Acquisition Database, 2000, reported the dates of the prior spin-offs and sell-offs for the 205 firms. These counts were summed for several different periods, including the number that occurred one year prior to the focal event, two years prior, three and four years prior, five to 10 years prior, and the sum over the entire 10-year period. These window lengths were used to separate immediate, short-term, and long-term counts from one another. The unit of analysis is the restructuring firm and its specific experiences over each of the 10 years prior to the focal restructuring event. Control variables We controlled for several explanations that represent motives for corporate restructuring and/or could influence the restructuring/performance relationship. First, we included control variables to Copyright 2008 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. 603 account for a financial distress hypothesis. We measured the restructuring firm’s financial performance (ROA) and debt (debt/sales) for the year prior to the focal restructuring year. Second, we included a control variable for strategy, defined in terms of the relatedness of the restructured assets. A dummy variable was coded as 1 if the restructured assets were in the same primary four-digit SIC as the restructuring firm and as 0 otherwise. Third, we used two variables to control for a managerial hubris hypothesis. We measured the size of the restructuring transaction (dollars, logged) and the size of the restructuring firm (total assets, logged). Fourth, we controlled for the agency hypothesis of owner/manager control. A variable called Blockholdings was measured as the percentage of outstanding common stock held in 5 percent blocks or larger. Fifth, we accounted for industry effects in three ways; by norming all financial variables relative to their industry averages (differences from the mean), by including the restructuring firm’s primary two-digit SIC as a dummy variable in the regression equations, and by subsample analyses that that either included or did not include the most popular industries (no industry influences existed, so the variables are not reported for space purposes). Sixth, we measured investor assessment of the quality and expected performance effects of the focal restructuring with the cumulative abnormal returns (CAR) variable. If the restructuring involved assets whose disposal are expected to raise the aggregate value of the restructuring firm, then this variable would be positive, and negative otherwise (Krishnaswami and Subramaniam, 1999; Montgomery, Thomas, and Kamath, 1984). CAR was operationalized using the standard event study methodology, whereby CAR was computed for the days surrounding the restructuring announcement. The standard event study approach estimates a market model for each firm and then calculates a cumulative abnormal return for the event. Specifically, the CARs were estimated as ARit = Rit − (ai + bi Rmt ), where ai and bi are the ordinary least squares (OLS) parameter estimates obtained for the regression of Rit on Rmt over an estimation period (T ) preceding the event; ARit is daily abnormal returns, Rit is the rate of return on the share price of firm i on day t and Rmt is the rate of return on the S&P 500 on day t. The parameter estimates were based on an estimation period of 200 days (−250 to −50) before the restructuring Strat. Mgmt. J., 29: 593–616 (2008) DOI: 10.1002/smj 604 D. D. Bergh and E. N.-K. Lim announcement. Abnormal returns were cumulated over the two-day window (day 0 is the announcement business day, +1 is the next business day) surrounding the announcement date. Stock market data were found in the Center for Research in Security Prices’2000 data tapes. In addition, we accounted for year-specific effects by recording the year the focal restructuring event occurred. Finally, continuing restructuring activity was measured as a dummy variable coded as 1 if a restructuring firm made additional restructuring actions after a focal restructuring and as 0 if not. Data for the control variables were found in the SDC database, COMPUSTAT, and proxy statements for the year of the restructuring. coefficients and model parameters. The coefficients are nonstandardized, range from positive to negative infinity, and are distributed as z-scores. The signs of these coefficients (+, 0, −) can be interpreted like those produced by OLS regression (+ is more, − is less). The model parameters are reflected in the Cox and Snell R 2 and the Nagelkerke R 2 . Like the R-square measure in OLS, these measures range from 0 to 1, approaching 0 as the quality of fit diminishes and 1 as it improves. Hypotheses 2 and 4 were tested using OLS regression. Standardized coefficients are reported. Multicollinearity was not apparent in the results (variance inflation factors were below 2, below the value of 10 where multicollinearity becomes an alternative explanation). Analyses The hypotheses were tested with hierarchical regression analyses. Logistic regression was used for testing Hypothesis 1 and Hypothesis 3 because the dependent variable in these hypotheses (restructuring mode) was dichotomous. Similar to ordinary least squares (OLS) regression analyses, hierarchical logistic regression analyses provide variable RESULTS Table 1 reports means, standard deviations, and intercorrelations for the study variables. Most of the restructuring events were sell-offs (59%, 123 of 205), the stock market reacted positively to the restructuring announcement (2.2% increase in Table 1. Means, standard deviations, and correlations Variables 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 Mean 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Restructuring mode 0.405 0.492 Focal CAR 0.022 0.047 0.186∗ Pre-restructuring ROA 1.682 10.213 0.125 −0.052 Debt/sales 0.429 0.559 −0.164∗ −0.028 −0.055 0.088 −0.048 Asset relatedness 0.610 0.489 0.191∗ −0.053 0.125 Transaction price (log) 2.504 0.838 0.049 0.074 0.284∗ 0.067 0.543∗ Total assets (log) 3.482 0.847 −0.080 −0.161∗ 0.210∗ 0.026 −0.021 Blockholdings (%) 21.683 20.563 −0.064 0.018 −0.058 0.043 0.055 −0.159∗ −0.273∗ Year 1994.107 2.119 −0.051 0.053 0.014 −0.024 −0.082 0.104 0.006 0.263∗ 0.487∗ Post-EPS 5 year average 1.627 1.985 −0.095 −0.057 0.228∗ −0.176∗ −0.114 Post-ROA 5 year average 4.095 5.570 −0.059 0.125 0.502∗ −0.214∗ −0.082 0.083 0.095 0.010 0.248∗ 0.358∗ Post-Restructuring dummy 0.223 0.278 0.067 −0.037 0.150∗ 0.012 Count of spin-offs 0.380 0.694 0.508∗ 0.039 0.068 −0.071 0.165∗ 0.083 0.011 Count of sell-offs 7.493 9.695 −0.074 −0.073 0.117 −0.084 0.012 0.225∗ 0.419∗ Variables 9 10 11 12 13 14 SD Year Post EPS average Post ROA average Post Restructuring dummy Count of spin-offs Count of sell-offs 8 9 10 11 12 13 0.078 −0.152 −0.076 −0.187∗ −0.057 −0.136 −0.040 −0.005 0.044 0.015 0.101 0.532∗ 0.139 −0.143 0.361∗ −0.021 −0.061 0.093 0.050 0.293∗ 0.149∗ Note: ∗ (p < 0.05); n = 205, except for n(EPS) = 149, n(ROA) = 118; Restructuring mode is for focal event. It is coded as 1 for spin-off, 0 for sell-off. Copyright 2008 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 29: 593–616 (2008) DOI: 10.1002/smj Learning How to Restructure 605 Table 2. Number of sell-offs and spin-offs per year before focal event year Table 3. Logistic regression analysis: restructuring mode regressed onto restructuring experience Year relative to focal event year Variables Model 1 ROA 0.040+ (0.021) −0.626+ (0.349) −0.846∗∗ (0.330) 0.111 (0.238) −0.316 (0.237) −0.011 (0.008) −0.063 (0.073) 9.286∗∗ (3.572) −1 −2 −3 −4 −5 −6 −7 −8 −9 −10 # of sell-offs 206 141 143 162 140 132 115 105 85 67 # of spin-offs 8 2 2 1 0 1 1 3 2 5 Debt/sales Asset relatedness Transaction price (log) Total assets (log) Blockholdings (%) Note: These figures represent the summed count of prior restructuring actions for all of the 205 restructuring firms. Year CAR), and the five-year post-restructuring mean return on assets was higher than the one-year pre-restructuring mean (4.09% versus 1.68%). In addition, most firms had far fewer pre-restructuring spin-offs (mean = 0.38) than sell-offs (mean = 7.49) during the 10 years prior to the year of the focal restructuring event. Table 2 provides additional insight into the 10year history of spin-offs and sell-offs prior to the focal restructuring event. Based on the entire sample of 205 firms, the data indicate that sell-offs far outnumber spin-offs for any of the years. For example, during the year immediately prior to the focal event year, the 205 restructuring firms made 206 sell-offs and eight spin-offs. Although the sample consists of 82 firms that restructured by spin-offs, this restructuring method was used considerably less often beforehand than sell-offs. The restructuring firms were not concentrated in any particular industry (results available upon request). Table 3 reports the results of the first set of logistic regression analyses. The values reported in the table are nonstandardized coefficients, and standard errors are reported in parentheses. The dependent variable, restructuring mode (spin-off, sell-off), is regressed onto the full set of controls (Model 1), and onto restructuring experience, as the summed restructuring counts over the entire 10-year period prior to the year of the focal restructuring event (Model 2). The results indicate that the 10-year count of sell-offs is associated with a subsequent sell-off (b = −0.066, p < 0.01; the negative coefficient is due to the coding of the mode variable as 1 for spin-off, 0 for sell-off). Count of prior spinoffs (10y) Count of prior selloffs (10y) Pseudo R 2 % correctly classified Log likelihood Log likelihood ratio test (df) χ 2 value (df) p-value Observations Copyright 2008 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Focal CAR 0.103 66.8% −124.067 — 28.590 (8) 0.000 205 Model 2 0.045+ (0.026) −0.856+ (0.499) −0.520 (0.390) 0.106 (0.285) −0.075 (0.294) −0.009 (0.009) −0.098 (0.087) 11.611∗∗ (4.299) 2.475∗∗ (0.432) −0.066∗∗ (0.025) 0.325 78.0% −93.373 61.389 (2) (p < 0.000) 89.980 (10) 0.000 205 Note: Dependent variable is restructuring mode (1 = spin-off, 0 = sell-off). Standard errors in parentheses. ∗∗ p < 0.01, ∗ p < 0.05, + p < 0.10 The sign and significance of the coefficient supports the absorptive capacity argument represented by Hypothesis 1, that as firms gain experience with sell-offs, they will continue to use sell-offs in the long term as a form of corporate restructuring strategy. The results reported in Table 3 also indicate that the 10-year count of spin-offs is associated with a subsequent spin-off (b = 2.475, p < 0.01). Although this relationship appears to support a long-term effect of spin-off count on the likelihood of subsequent spin-off adoption, a finding that appears consistent with an absorptive capacity argument, the results in Table 4 provide additional insights into the meaning of that association. In Table 4, we separated the 10-year summed counts of spin-offs and sell-offs into different temporal window intervals. We computed the numbers of spin-offs and sell-offs five to 10 years prior to the Strat. Mgmt. J., 29: 593–616 (2008) DOI: 10.1002/smj 606 D. D. Bergh and E. N.-K. Lim Table 4. Logistic regression analysis: restructuring mode regressed onto experience at different time intervals (n = 205) Variables Model 1 ROA 0.040+ (0.021) −0.626+ (0.349) −0.846∗∗ (0.330) 0.111 (0.238) −0.316 (0.237) −0.011 (0.008) −0.063 (0.073) 9.286∗∗ (3.572) Debt/sales Asset relatedness Transaction price (log) Total assets (log) Blockholdings (%) Year Focal CAR Count of spin-offs, prior years 5 to 10 Count of sell-offs, prior years 5 to 10 Count of spin-offs, prior years 3 to 4 Count of sell-offs, prior years 3 to 4 Count of spin-offs, prior year 2 Count of sell-offs, prior year 2 Count of spin-offs, prior year Count of sell-offs, prior year 0.103 Pseudo R 2 % correctly classified 66.8% Log likelihood −124.067 Log likelihood ratio test — (df) 28.590 χ 2 value (df) p-value 0.000 Observations 205 Model 2 0.050∗ (0.023) −0.806∗ (0.397) −0.877∗ (0.346) 0.097 (0.248) −0.316 (0.261) −0.013 (0.009) −0.064 (0.079) 9.689∗ (3.782) 0.024 (0.593) −0.030 (0.045) −0.614 (1.522) −0.177 (0.111) 1.204 (1.558) 0.222 (0.157) 2.129∗ (0.918) 0.046 (0.123) 0.153 69.1% −117.183 13.768 (8) (p < 0.10) (8) 40.543 (16) 0.001 204 Note: Standard errors in parentheses. Initial −2 Log Likelihood = 276.725. ∗∗ p < 0.01, ∗ p < 0.05, + p < 0.10. focal restructuring event, those during three and four years, two years and one year prior. Tests reported under Model 2 of Table 4 indicate that only the count of spin-offs during the year immediately prior to the focal restructuring event is associated with a subsequent spin-off (b = 2.129, p < 0.05). The counts of spin-offs (and sell-offs) during the other time intervals are not significant predictors. The closer examination offered by the Copyright 2008 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. tests of the alternative time windows reveals that more recent experience with spin-offs is associated with subsequent spin-offs. Collectively, these results lend support for the organizational improvisation argument represented in Hypothesis 3, that recent experience is related more positively to the likelihood of a subsequent spin-off than temporally distant experience. In addition, none of the sell-off counts for any of the windows within the 10-year period is associated with restructuring mode. Apparently, the effects of sell-off experience on focal restructuring sell-offs do not depend on any particular temporal window. This evidence lends additional support for the absorptive capacity hypothesis (Hypothesis 1) for sell-offs. Tables 5 and 6 report the results of regressing performance after the focal restructuring event onto restructuring experience levels. The coefficients in those tables are standardized. The two performance variables, ROA and mean EPS, were recorded at each of the five years after the restructuring event, and an average of each was calculated for that five-year period. The 10-year sum of prior sell-offs was related positively to ROA (b = 0.283, p < 0.01) and to EPS (b = 0.337, p < 0.01) at one year after the restructuring event (Models 2 in both tables). In addition, that long-term sell-off count variable was related positively to the EPS fiveyear average (b = 0.227, p < 0.01). These results are consistent with the second absorptive capacity hypothesis, Hypothesis 2, firms that have more experience with sell-offs will have higher financial performance after a subsequent sell-off than firms having less experience with sell-offs. (The negative relationship between long-term spin-offs and EPS is discussed below.) Tables 7 and 8 report the results of regressing financial performance onto the restructuring counts during the different time intervals. Standardized coefficients are again reported. Firms making higher numbers of spin-offs during a threeto four-year period prior to a focal restructuring event tended to have higher post-restructuring ROA (b = 0.333, p < 0.01 for one year after; b = 0.197, p < 0.05 for two years after, and b = 0.178, p < 0.05 for the five-year average). However, firms that made higher numbers of spinoffs in the period five to 10 years before a focal restructuring tended to have lower ROA for the year after the focal restructuring (b = −0.167, p < 0.05), but higher four years later (b = 0.290, Strat. Mgmt. J., 29: 593–616 (2008) DOI: 10.1002/smj Learning How to Restructure Table 5. 607 Ordinary least squares regression analysis: post-restructuring ROA regressed onto restructuring experience Variables Pre-restructuring ROA Debt/sales Asset relatedness Transaction price (log) Total assets (log) Blockholdings (%) Year Restructuring dummy Focal CAR Count of spin-offs Count of sell-offs R2 Adjusted R 2 F Observations Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5 Model 6 0.529∗∗ −0.112 −0.059 0.005 0.062 0.060 −0.173∗ −0.068 0.193∗ −0.092 0.134 0.340 0.272 4.971∗∗ 118 0.473∗∗ −0.167+ 0.065 −0.103 −0.027 0.036 −0.085 −0.010 0.236∗∗ −0.019 0.283∗∗ 0.345 0.277 5.066∗∗ 118 0.438∗∗ 0.016 0.009 −0.026 0.190 0.116 −0.043 −0.104 −0.040 −0.068 0.118 0.245 0.162 2.954∗∗ 112 0.191+ −0.118 −0.110 0.160 −0.187 0.009 −0.037 −0.014 0.039 −0.008 0.041 0.100 −0.005 0.949 106 0.336∗∗ −0.210∗ −0.182+ 0.039 0.129 0.030 −0.180 0.087 0.058+ 0.168+ −0.018 0.264 0.170 2.805∗∗ 98 0.377∗∗ −0.110 0.012 0.038 0.021 0.017 −0.257∗ −0.032 −0.121 0.026 −0.041 0.212 0.095 1.815+ 86 Note: Model 1 dependent variable is five-year ROA average; Model 2 dependent variable is the ROA at one year after focal restructuring year, Model 3 dependent variable is the ROA at two years after, up to Model 6, where the dependent variable is the ROA at five years after the focal restructuring year. ∗∗ p < 0.01, ∗ p < 0.05, + p < 0.10. Table 6. Ordinary least squares regression analysis: post-restructuring earnings per share regressed onto restructuring experience Variables Pre-restructuring ROA Debt/sales Asset relatedness Transaction price (log) Total assets (log) Blockholdings (%) Year Restructuring dummy Focal CAR Count of spin-offs Count of sell-offs R2 Adjusted R 2 F Observations Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5 Model 6 0.109 −0.192∗∗ −0.110 0.034 0.376∗∗ 0.026 −0.124+ −0.076 −0.007 −0.209∗∗ 0.227∗∗ 0.379 0.329 7.588∗∗ 149 0.159+ −0.137+ 0.000 −0.012 0.048 −0.019 0.076 −0.015 −0.021 −0.098 0.337∗∗ 0.211 0.148 3.339∗∗ 149 0.060 0.085 −0.063 −0.088 0.457∗∗ 0.079 0.009 −0.076 −0.006 −0.139+ 0.150+ 0.264 0.201 4.148∗∗ 139 0.089 −0.253∗∗ −0.090 0.158 0.194+ 0.059 −0.197∗ −0.022 −0.043 −0.087 0.107 0.226 0.153 3.107∗∗ 129 0.028 −0.288∗∗ −0.241∗∗ 0.015 0.350∗∗ −0.016 −0.237∗∗ 0.054 −0.036 0.002 0.044 0.294 0.221 4.044∗∗ 119 −0.020 −0.315∗∗ −0.114 0.099 0.223 0.045 −0.212∗ −0.037 −0.049 −0.129 −0.008 0.197 0.103 2.096∗ 106 Note: Model 1 dependent variable is the five-year EPS average; Model 2 dependent variable is the EPS at one year after the focal restructuring year, up to Model 6 where the dependent variable is the EPS at five years after the focal restructuring year. ∗∗ p < 0.01, ∗ p < 0.05, + p < 0.10. p < 0.01). None of the restructuring count intervals were related to EPS at any of the years after the restructuring. These results provide partial support for Hypothesis 4, that recent experience with spin-offs is related more positively to financial performance following a focal spin-off than experience with spin-offs in temporally distant years. In our findings, recent spin-offs (three to four Copyright 2008 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. years in this case) are related more positively to financial performance (ROA) following a subsequent spin-off than the count of spin-offs occurring in the years that do not immediately precede the focal event. Furthermore, none of the counts of sell-offs for the temporal windows are associated with either performance measure, lending additional support for the absorptive capacity effect Strat. Mgmt. J., 29: 593–616 (2008) DOI: 10.1002/smj 608 D. D. Bergh and E. N.-K. Lim Table 7. Post-restructuring ROA regressed onto experience at different time intervals Variables Pre-restructuring ROA Debt/sales Asset relatedness Transaction price (log) Total assets (log) Blockholdings (%) Year Restructuring dummy Focal CAR Count of spin-offs 5–10 years prior Count of sell-offs 5–10 years prior Count of spin-offs 3–4 years prior Count of sell-offs 3–4 years prior Count of spin-offs 2 years prior Count of sell-offs 2 years prior Count of spin-offs 1 year prior Count of sell-offs 1 year prior R2 Adjusted R 2 F Observations Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 0.556∗∗ −0.104 −0.072 −0.007 0.102 0.040 −0.151+ −0.051 0.190∗ −0.131 0.089 0.178∗ −0.055 −0.003 0.021 −0.083 0.013 0.380 0.275 3.607∗∗ 118 0.538∗∗ −0.148+ 0.062 −0.155 0.028 −0.014 −0.027 −0.008 0.215∗∗ −0.167∗ 0.159 0.333∗∗ −0.169 0.051 0.132 0.039 0.087 0.462 0.370 5.047∗∗ 118 0.483∗∗ 0.032 0.005 −0.065 0.232+ 0.081 −0.006 −0.097 −0.046 −0.142 0.049 0.197∗ −0.103 0.034 0.096 −0.024 0.009 0.294 0.166 2.303∗∗ 112 Model 4 0.188 −0.124 −0.119 0.167 −0.180 0.023 −0.040 −0.004 0.054 0.021 −0.001 0.041 0.041 −0.044 −0.020 −0.057 0.026 0.107 −0.066 0.619 106 Model 5 Model 6 0.289∗∗ −0.236∗ −0.218∗ 0.085 0.144 0.080 −0.208+ 0.139 0.109 0.290∗∗ −0.071 0.098 0.152 −0.031 −0.085 −0.138 −0.013 0.346 0.207 2.493∗∗ 98 0.310∗ −0.182 −0.048 0.089 0.011 0.058 −0.297∗ 0.033 −0.082 0.178 −0.009 0.031 0.046 −0.102 −0.188 −0.234+ 0.132 0.297 0.122 1.692+ 86 Note: Model 1 dependent variable is the five-year ROA average; Model 2 dependent variable is the ROA at one year after the focal restructuring year, up to Model 6 where the dependent variable is the ROA at five years after the focal restructuring year. ∗∗ p < 0.01, ∗ p < 0.05, + p < 0.10. Table 8. Post-restructuring EPS regressed onto experience at different time intervals Variables Pre-restructuring ROA Debt/sales Asset relatedness Transaction price (log) Total assets (log) Blockholdings (%) Year Restructuring dummy Focal CAR Count of spin-offs 5–10 years prior Count of sell-offs 5–10 years prior Count of spin-offs 3–4 years prior Count of sell-offs 3–4 years prior Count of spin-offs 2 years prior Count of sell-offs 2 years prior Count of spin-offs 1 year prior Count of sell-offs 1 year prior R2 Adjusted R 2 F Observations Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5 Model 6 0.111 −0.183∗ −0.109 0.028 0.380∗∗ 0.022 −0.112 −0.056 −0.008 −0.184∗ 0.098 −0.006 0.129 −0.057 0.048 −0.074 −0.041 0.389 0.310 4.908∗∗ 149 0.175∗ −0.140+ −0.001 −0.027 0.050 −0.038 0.105 −0.012 −0.030 −0.138+ 0.162 0.082 0.049 −0.005 0.049 −0.006 0.109 0.228 0.127 2.270∗∗ 149 0.068 0.092 −0.063 −0.096 0.466∗∗ 0.075 0.021 −0.070 −0.005 −0.112 0.041 0.009 0.030 −0.035 0.106 −0.073 −0.011 0.272 0.170 2.661∗∗ 139 0.069 −0.251∗∗ −0.091 0.170 0.204+ 0.084 −0.221∗ 0.001 −0.029 −0.041 0.120 −0.023 0.145 −0.098 −0.096 −0.043 −0.071 0.244 0.128 2.109∗ 129 0.010 −0.274∗∗ −0.247∗∗ 0.020 0.354∗∗ 0.012 −0.242∗∗ 0.092 −0.008 0.105 −0.084 −0.037 0.225 −0.031 0.025 −0.083 −0.103 0.331 0.219 2.944∗∗ 119 −0.043 −0.310∗∗ −0.114 0.119 0.226 0.087 −0.243∗ −0.003 −0.020 −0.002 −0.034 −0.094 0.134 −0.139 0.015 −0.106 −0.106 0.225 0.075 1.500 106 Note: Model 1 dependent variable is the five-year EPS average; Model 2 dependent variable is the EPS at one year after the focal restructuring year, up to Model 6 where the dependent variable is the EPS at five years after the focal restructuring year. ∗∗ p < 0.01, ∗ p < 0.05, + p < 0.10. Copyright 2008 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 29: 593–616 (2008) DOI: 10.1002/smj Learning How to Restructure of sell-offs on post-restructuring financial performance. DISCUSSION During the 1980s and 1990s, thousands of companies restructured their portfolios of business lines, spinning and selling off assets worth hundreds of billions of dollars (Bruner, 2004; Gaughan, 1999; Hoskisson and Hitt, 1994). To date, most knowledge on restructuring has focused on how restructuring is used as a mechanism to reduce overdiversification, reallocate resources, or improve internal efficiency in order to improve financial performance (see Bauer, 2006; Haynes et al., 2003; Johnson, 1996 for reviews of the restructuring literature). Although that research has provided important insights, we still have an incomplete understanding of the drivers and implications of corporate restructuring. In particular, we know little about the dynamic aspects of restructuring. Although managers would likely consider temporal factors such as prior history and experience in their restructuring decisions, previous research has not fully considered how such dimensions might influence restructuring and its implications for financial performance. The current study was designed to address these gaps by testing two questions: (1) Does experience apply to restructuring decisions? (2) If so, does it also influence profitability? The study finds that experience matters, but in different ways. First, the use of a sell-off is consistent with an absorptive capacity viewpoint of organizational learning. Having more experience with sell-offs over time makes them more likely to be used in subsequent events. By contrast, the use of spin-offs is consistent with an organizational improvisation view. The results indicate that a focal spin-off is related to the incidence of other spin-offs in immediately preceding years only; no other prior time intervals mattered for spin-offs. The adoption of a spin-off appears to be used more often as a short-term response than part of a long-term activity spread over multiple years, as spin-offs frequently occur close together in time. Second, restructuring experience has implications for financial performance following a focal restructuring event. Firms with more sell-off experience realized higher financial performance than firms having less. By contrast, those Copyright 2008 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. 609 having more recent spin-off experience tended to realize an increase in post-restructuring financial performance while those with older experience tended to achieve performance decreases. Overall, these findings suggest that different kinds of experience are associated with the adoption of different restructuring actions and their subsequent financial performance records. The results of testing the control variables further support the theoretical explanations; most spin-offs involved core business lines and sell-offs tended to occur when the restructuring firm had financial pressures due to lower financial performance and higher debt. Implications for corporate restructuring The study results suggest several potential contributions to explanations of corporate restructuring. First, current understanding of the temporal qualities of restructuring is mostly based on evolutionary models, where firms are depicted as using divestitures to move out of business lines as part of a search and selection sequential process (see Chang, 1996), or transaction cost explanations, where restructuring balances the costs and benefits of managing portfolios of business lines (Bergh and Lawless, 1998; Jones and Hill, 1988; Markides, 1992, 1995). Our study adds to the understanding of the dynamic properties of restructuring in several ways. First, a historical effect—prior restructuring experience heterogeneity—appears to influence the use of different restructuring modes. Second, the relationship between prior restructuring experience and subsequent restructuring appears to have different forms. Third, theoretical explanations of restructuring can be revised to include different time intervals; the absorptive capacity viewpoint of learning applies to sell-offs, while improvisation appears to describe spin-offs. Fourth, experience has a shortlived relationship with post-restructuring financial performance. Collectively, these implications suggest new theoretical insights because most current explanations do not account for prior historical relationships, how they might vary over time, or the amount and rate of temporal lag. Our study suggests that addressing temporal relationships, together with experience, restructuring alternatives, and performance, will add significantly to the restructuring literature. The findings offer Strat. Mgmt. J., 29: 593–616 (2008) DOI: 10.1002/smj 610 D. D. Bergh and E. N.-K. Lim new empirical evidence and explanations, suggesting possible contributions to a dynamic view of restructuring. More specifically, the results support an integrative explanation of corporate restructuring that is more expansive than prevailing perspectives. To date, most explanations imply that a planned, deliberate and intentional execution of restructuring actions is called for in order to meet a predetermined objective. Hence, a temporal delay is embedded between the composition and implementation of the restructuring action. However, the findings imply that this dominant explanation of restructuring may be incomplete. It appears that some restructurings may occur in a more simultaneous and contemporaneous manner where cumulative and repetitive prior experience plays a much smaller role. Other factors such as expertise and tacit knowledge may develop and shape corporate strategy as a continuous and adaptive process. The support for the organizational improvisational depiction of strategy may open new and different avenues of inquiry into the formulation and implementation of strategic actions and their effects on performance. Moreover, most prior research has portrayed restructuring as a method for improving internal control and efficiency (Hoskisson and Hitt, 1994; Hoskisson and Turk, 1990; Shleifer and Vishny, 1991), refocusing diversification strategies (Comment and Jarrell, 1995; Hoskisson et al., 1994; Markides, 1992, 1995), reducing information asymmetries (Bergh et al., 2008; Krishnaswami and Subramaniam, 1999), and generating internal liquidity (John and Ofek, 1995; Lang, Poulsen, and Stulz, 1995; Ofek, 1993). Our study adds to the literature by suggesting that different types of learning, which draw from cognitive and behavioral concepts, may provide insights into what has been primarily an economicbased perspective of the restructuring decision and outcome. Furthermore, the study indicates that an explanation of restructuring that appears to be valid for one time interval may not be valid for another. For example, the results initially showed that the adoption of a spin-off was related to a summed count of spin-offs over a 10-year window (Table 3), a finding consistent with the absorptive capacity learning argument. However, disaggregating the count of spin-offs into temporal windows revealed that the Copyright 2008 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. count of spin-offs occurring in the year immediately prior to the focal spin-off was more influential than any other time period within the 10-year window (Table 4). Simultaneously, a much different relationship existed for sell-offs; the 10-year count of sell-off was a significant predictor of selloff adoption while none of the windows within that period mattered. These findings indicate that the development of dynamic explanations needs to account for the length of time intervals. Because the length of the temporal intervals was varied, the explanations for one temporal concept, experience, also varied. The specified time interval may change the meaning of concepts, relationships, and interpretations and serve as a baseline condition for explaining restructuring actions. The use of temporal frames helps us build upon an earlier study of experience and restructuring. Villalonga and McGahan (2005) recently reported a consistent positive relationship between experience and the subsequent use of sell-offs, spin-offs, and equity carve-outs. Our findings are similar to theirs with respect to prior experience and sell-offs, but the results differ when it comes to spin-offs. These discrepancies appear due to how experience was measured; Villalonga and McGahan represent experience as the average number of events prior to a focal event, while we use temporal windows to break down experience into specific intervals. Had we summed prior spin-offs over a 10-year period only, our conclusions would have again been similar to those reported by Villalonga and McGahan (2005). However, by recognizing that different perspectives of learning can be represented with the use of the temporal windows, we find that spin-offs occur more spontaneously and in a shorter time frame, allowing us to posit a finer-grained construction of the experience concept. Hence, knowledge of the dynamic qualities of restructuring is therefore enhanced by theoretically and methodologically indicating the time intervals in which the events are most likely to exist (cf. Bergh, 1995b; Bergh and Holbein, 1997; Mitchell and James, 2001; Zaheer, Albert, and Zaheer, 1999). The findings also contribute to the understanding of the dynamic quality of restructuring by revealing that the effects of restructuring experience on financial performance appear to erode following the restructuring. This relationship was consistent across the different time intervals. Apparently, the benefits of experience are not only variable over time, but they do not last long. Strat. Mgmt. J., 29: 593–616 (2008) DOI: 10.1002/smj Learning How to Restructure Implications for organizational learning In general terms, the findings suggest a more diverse and integrative approach to viewing and testing learning constructs; by clarifying and including different learning perspectives in the same model, theory development can be expanded dynamically and comprehensively. The organizational learning literature has received considerable attention and is extensive and broad, and the absorptive capacity and organizational improvisational views are but two of several different perspectives within a voluminous research stream. However, most applications of organizational learning tend to focus on one learning view or process at a time and theoretical models typically do not sufficiently differentiate between alternative or complementary learning perspectives. Our findings imply that if one disaggregates temporal windows into different length periods, then more clearly defined learning views and arguments can be developed and tested. The choice of time scales could therefore influence the theoretical relationships and insights one will obtain (George and Jones, 2000; Zaheer, Albert, and Zaheer, 1999), and it is possible that reduced window lengths within longer intervals might yield support for more nuanced learning explanations. Hence, theoretical explanations of learning might be further developed, revised, and extended by recognizing complementary views of organizational learning and developing and testing them using different time window lengths. More specifically, the study findings suggest several possible implications for theory development on organizational learning. First, to the best of our knowledge, our study is the first to compare simultaneously the financial implications of absorptive capacity and organizational improvisation viewpoints of learning. To date, most conceptual developments and empirical tests have focused on one or the other separately, and the research streams on each appear to have mostly developed independently of one another. We have little explanation and evidence about when either is likely to better explain performance. Our study results may help to partly address this gap; by linking experience types to adoption of alternative actions and then to performance, our model provides an initial framework that differentiates these two learning viewpoints. Overall, the findings suggest that meaningful boundaries exist between different Copyright 2008 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. 611 viewpoints of learning and that there is theoretical value by considering separate views simultaneously. Furthermore, distinguishing between absorptive capacity and improvisation may have important theoretical implications. Most learning explanations imply that corporate behaviors are purposeful, deliberate, and planned. However, by differentiating between both views of learning, actions that may be more spontaneous are not inadvertently embedded within the absorptive capacity reasoning and method, allowing for a more refined, developed, and transparent explanation to be offered. We call for more research to further examine the possible linkages and distinctions between absorptive capacity and organizational improvisation. For instance, for those studies that link absorptive capacity to alliances and acquisitions and to performance (see Lane et al., 2006; Zollo et al., 2002, for recent reviews), we now wonder when improvisation might also apply. Are the different types of acquisitions and alliances associated with different learning perspectives? Since the theoretical models and empirical tests tend not to disaggregate long time periods into shorter ones, questions arise about whether the alliance and acquisition studies that support an absorptive capacity view might be obscuring shorter-term improvisational actions. These issues suggest that we may need to revisit the developments and applications of learning perspectives, especially when the need exists for managers to reduce the temporal proximity of design and action. Second, the study findings offer insights into the absorptive capacity and improvisational viewpoints using different methods and conditions than prior studies. The results can be interpreted as further evidence of the reach of both views, as each appears to now explain an exiting action that has a performance implication. In addition, the findings refine absorptive capacity to show that it may not explain settings where the need exists to reduce the time between design and action (Crossan et al., 2005; Levinthan and Rerup, 2006; Miner et al., 2001; Moorman and Miner, 1998a, 1998b; Winter, 2003). Moreover, many studies consider absorptive capacity, but fewer empirically examine its properties (Lane et al., 2006). As such, this study contributes to knowledge of absorptive capacity by explicating its temporal characteristics. To date, most interpretations of absorptive capacity do not account for temporal window lengths, Strat. Mgmt. J., 29: 593–616 (2008) DOI: 10.1002/smj 612 D. D. Bergh and E. N.-K. Lim implying that its properties and effects are constant or equal over time. Future research may provide new insights into absorptive capacity by testing its temporal conditions and assumptions. Such study may offer new insights into learning if it considers the relationships between the viewpoints of absorptive capacity and improvisation, or other viewpoints within the organizational learning literature. Third, the study represents one of the initial formulations and applications of organizational improvisation to a corporate strategy action and its possible performance effects. The findings extend this viewpoint’s logic to a much different setting than previous studies of musicians, actors, and new product developers, and imply that improvisation may have potential for offering insights into a variety of corporate behaviors. It appears that when managers need to make decisions based on real-time and short-term information, improvisation may help explain their actions. Interestingly, the results also indicate that the link between improvisation and performance is not as clear as expected. Although improvisation may apply to how managers select restructuring modes, it does not apply as robustly to financial performance, and the effects appear to be temporally delayed. This finding is consistent with other views of an equivocal improvisation/performance linkage (see Crossan et al., 2005). More study is needed to understand the financial implications of improvisation. The implications of this study should be considered in light of several limitations. First, the findings are based on large restructuring events. It is unknown how the results apply to smaller-sized restructuring firms. The proposed explanation of restructuring and its effects would seem to apply to smaller organizations, but no direct inference can be made given that the sample consisted of large firms. Second, the study examined voluntary restructuring efforts only, and it is possible that the proposed explanation might not apply to involuntary spin-offs and sell-offs. For example, a court-ordered restructuring might lead a firm to spin-off when a sell-off might be the best option. Third, the study does not identify how the restructured assets were originally created, either through internal growth or by acquisition. No inference can therefore be made that links entry and exit behaviors. A more complete explanation of restructuring Copyright 2008 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. behavior would include growth and exit alternatives. We hope that future research will test such a model. CONCLUSION During the 1980s and 1990s, firms restructured tens of thousands of business lines. The present study considers whether restructuring experience might have influenced restructuring actions and post-restructuring financial performance. The study tests a model that relates different viewpoints of organizational learning to help explain the adoption of different restructuring alternatives and their influence on profitability. The findings show that the absorptive capacity view is most pertinent to the use of sell-offs, while the organizational improvisation view better explains the selection of spinoffs. These explanations and findings add to the corporate restructuring literature and may further enhance understanding of organizational learning. In addition, our study probes unexplored aspects of the temporal dimensions of corporate strategy, such as time intervals, time lags, and the forms of longitudinal relationships. Of specific interest is the finding that the learning explanations for restructuring actions and performance vary over time. These findings contribute some new building blocks toward a dynamic explanation of corporate restructuring. Restructuring is a longitudinal phenomenon and, hopefully, the study will provide for improved understanding of how these actions are managed while encouraging additional inquiry into temporal dimensions. Most generally, the theoretical model helps explain why some corporate restructuring strategies appear as intentional and deliberate actions while others resemble spontaneous and simultaneous responses. Future research that integrates alternative learning views may produce a more dynamic and comprehensive understanding of strategy and its implications for firm performance. ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS We are grateful for the helpful comments from Editor Richard Bettis and the referees. We also thank Professor Richard Johnson for his contributions to the dataset and Professors Parthiban David and Ravi Madhavan for comments on an earlier Strat. Mgmt. J., 29: 593–616 (2008) DOI: 10.1002/smj Learning How to Restructure draft of this article. We thank the Krannert Graduate School of Management at Purdue University for its support of this research. REFERENCES Ahuja G, Katila A. 2001. Technological acquisitions and the innovation performance of acquiring firms: a longitudinal study. Strategic Management Journal 22(3): 197–220. Alexander GJ, Benson PG, Kampmeyer JM. 1984. Investigating the valuation effects of announcements of voluntary corporate sell-offs. Journal of Finance 39: 503–517. Allen J. 1998. Capital markets and corporate structure: the equity carve-outs of Thermo Electron. Journal of Financial Economics 48: 99–124. Allen J. 2001. Private information and spin-off performance. Journal of Business 74(2): 281–306. Amabile TM. 1996. Creativity in Context . Westview Press: Boulder, CO. Amburgey TL, Kelly D, Barnett WP. 1993. Resetting the clock: the dynamics of organizational change and failure. Administrative Science Quarterly 38: 51–73. Amburgey TL, Miner AS. 1992. Strategic momentum: the effects of repetitive, positional, and contextual momentum on merger activity. Strategic Management Journal 13(5): 335–348. Argote L, Beckman S, Epple D. 1990. The persistence and transfer of learning in industrial settings. Management Science 36: 140–154. Aron DJ. 1991. Using the capital market as a monitor: corporate spin-offs in an agency framework. RAND Journal of Economics 22: 505–518. Baker T, Nelson RE. 2005. Creating something from nothing: resource construction through entrepreneurial bricolage. Administrative Science Quarterly 50(3): 329–366. Barkema HG, Vermeulen F. 1998. International experience through start-up or acquisition: a learning perspective. Academy of Management Journal 41: 7–26. Baum JAC, Li SX, Usher JM. 2000. Making the next move: how experiential and vicarious learning shape the locations of chains’ acquisitions. Administrative Science Quarterly 45(4): 766–801. Baum JAC, Ginsberg A. 1997. The value of learning by doing: acquisition experience and profitability. Stern School of Business working paper, New York University. Bergh DD. 1995a. Size and relatedness of units sold: An agency theory and resource-based perspective. Strategic Management Journal 16: 221–239. Bergh DD. 1995b. Problems with repeated measures analysis: demonstration with a study of the diversification and performance relationship. Academy of Management Journal 38(6): 1692–1708. Bergh DD. 1997. Predicting divestiture of unrelated acquisitions: an integrative model of ex ante conditions. Strategic Management Journal 18(9): 715–731. Copyright 2008 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. 613 Bergh DD. 1998. Product-market uncertainty, portfolio restructuring, and performance: an informationprocessing and resource-based view. Journal of Management 24(2): 135–155. Bergh DD, Holbein GF. 1997. Assessment and redirection of longitudinal analysis: demonstration with a study of the diversification and divestiture relationship. Strategic Management Journal 18(7): 557–571. Bergh DD, Johnson RA, DeWitt RL. 2008. Restructuring through spin-off or sell-off: transforming information asymmetries into financial gain. Strategic Management Journal 29(2): 133–148. Bergh DD, Lawless MW. 1998. Portfolio restructuring and limits to hierarchical governance: effects of environmental uncertainty and diversification strategy. Organization Science 9: 87–102. Berliner PF. 1994. Thinking in Jazz: The Infinite Art of Improvisation. University of Chicago Press: Chicago, IL. Bethel JE, Liebeskind J. 1993. The effects of ownership structure on corporate restructuring. Strategic Management Journal Summer Special Issue 14: 15–31. Bowman EH, Singh H. 1993. Corporate restructuring: reconfiguring the firm. Strategic Management Journal Summer Special Issue 14: 5–14. Brauer M. 2006. What have we acquired and what should we acquire in divestiture research? A review and research agenda. Journal of Management 32(6): 751–785. Brown SL, Eisenhardt KM. 1995. Product development: past research, present findings, and future directions. Academy of Management Review 20(2): 343–378. Bruner RF. 2004. Applied Mergers and Acquisitions. John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.: New York. Capron L, Mitchell W, Swaminathan A. 2001. Asset divestiture following horizontal acquisitions: a dynamic view. Strategic Management Journal 22(9): 817–844. Chang S-J. 1996. An evolutionary perspective on diversification and corporate restructuring: entry, exit, and economic performance during 1981–89. Strategic Management Journal 17(8): 587–611. Chang S-J, Rosenzweig PM. 2001. The choice of entry mode in sequential foreign direct investment. Strategic Management Journal 22(8): 747–776. Chang S-J, Singh H. 1999. The impact of modes of entry and resource fit on modes of exit by multibusiness firms. Strategic Management Journal 20(11): 1019–1035. Chatterjee S, Harrison JS, Bergh DD. 2003. Failed takeover attempts, corporate governance and refocusing. Strategic Management Journal 24(1): 87–96. Cohen MD. 1991. Individual learning and organizational routine: emerging connections. Organization Science 2(1): 135–139. Cohen MD, Bacdayan P. 1994. Organizational routines are stored as procedural memory: evidence from a laboratory study. Organization Science 5(4): 554–568. Cohen MD, March JG, Olsen JP. 1972. A garbage can model of organizational choice. Administrative Science Quarterly 17(1): 1–25. Strat. Mgmt. J., 29: 593–616 (2008) DOI: 10.1002/smj 614 D. D. Bergh and E. N.-K. Lim Cohen WM, Levinthal DA. 1990. Absorptive capacity: a new perspective on learning and innovation. Administrative Science Quarterly 35(1): 128–152. Comment R, Jarrell GA. 1995. Corporate focus and stock returns. Journal of Financial Economics 37: 67–87. Crossan M, Cunha J, Vera D, Cunha M. 2005. Time and organizational improvisation. Academy of Management Review 30(1): 129–145. Crossan M, Lane HW, White RE, Klus L. 1996. The improvising organization: where planning meets opportunity. Organizational Dynamics 24(4): 20–35. Cusatis P, Miles J, Woolridge JR. 1993. Restructuring through spin-offs: the stock market evidence. Journal of Financial Economics 33(3): 293–311. Cyert RM, March JG. 1963. A Behavioral Theory of the Firm. Prentice-Hall: Englewood Cliffs, NJ. Daley L, Mehrotra V, Sivakumar R. 1997. Corporate focus and value creation: evidence from spin-offs. Journal of Financial Economics 45: 257–281. Desai H, Jain PC. 1999. Firm performance and focus: long-run stock market performance following spinoffs. Journal of Financial Economics 54: 75–101. Donaldson G. 1990. Voluntary restructuring: the case of General Mills. Journal of Financial Economics 27: 117–142. Duhaime I, Grant J. 1984. Factors influencing divestment decision-making: evidence from a field study. Strategic Management Journal 5(4): 301–318. Eisenhardt KM. 1989. Making fast strategic decisions in high-velocity environments. Academy of Management Journal 32(3): 543–576. Eisenhardt KM, Tabrizi BM. 1995. Accelerating adaptive processes: product innovation in the global computer industry. Administrative Science Quarterly 40: 84–110. Fiol CM, Lyles MA. 1985. Organizational learning. Academy of Management Review 10: 803–814. Gaughan PA. 1999. Mergers, Acquisitions, and Corporate Restructurings (2nd edn). John Wiley & Sons: New York. George JM, Jones GR. 2000. The role of time in theory and theory building. Journal of Management 26: 657–684. Haleblian J, Finkelstein S. 1999. The influence of organizational acquisition experience on acquisition performance: a behavioral learning perspective. Administrative Science Quarterly 44: 29–56. Haleblian J, Kim J, Rajagopalan N. 2006. Routinebased learning, performance-based learning, and their interaction: evidence from the U.S. commercial banking industry. Academy of Management Journal 49: 357–370. Hamilton RT, Chow YK. 1993. Why managers divest— evidence from New Zealand’s largest companies. Strategic Management Journal 14(6): 479–484. Harrigan KR. 1982. Exit decisions in mature industries. Academy of Management Journal 25(4): 707–732. Hatch MJ. 1997. Jazzing up the theory of organizational improvisation. Advances in Strategic Management 14: 181–191. Haynes M, Thompson S, Wright M. 2003. The determinants of corporate divestment: evidence from a panel Copyright 2008 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. of UK firms. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 52: 147–166. Hayward MLA. 2002. When do firms learn from their acquisition experience? Evidence from 1990–1995. Strategic Management Journal 23(1): 21–39. Hill CWL, Hitt MA, Hoskisson RE. 1992. Cooperative versus competitive structures in related and unrelated diversified firms. Organization Science 3: 501–521. Hill CWL, Hoskisson RE. 1987. Strategy and structure in the multiproduct firm. Academy of Management Review 12: 331–341. Hite GL, Owers JE, Rogers RC. 1987. The market for interfirm asset sales: partial sell-offs and total liquidations. Journal of Financial Economics 18: 229–253. Hoskisson RE, Hitt MA. 1994. Downscoping: How to Tame the Diversified Firm. Oxford: New York. Hoskisson RE, Johnson RA, Moesel DD. 1994. Corporate divestiture intensity in restructuring firms: effects of governance, strategy, and performance. Academy of Management Journal 37(5): 1207–1251. Hoskisson RE, Turk T. 1990. Corporate restructuring: governance and control limits of the internal capital market. Academy of Management Review 15: 459–477. Huber GP. 1991. Organization learning: the contributing processes and the literatures. Organization Science 2: 88–115. Ilmakunnas P, Topi J. 1999. Microeconomic and macroeconomic influences on entry and exit of firms. Review of Industrial Organization 15(3): 283–301. Ito K. 1995. Japanese spinoffs: unexplored survival strategies. Strategic Management Journal 16(6): 431–446. Jain PC. 1985. The effect of voluntary sell-off announcements on shareholder wealth. Journal of Finance 40: 209–224. Jensen MC. 1993. The modern industrial revolution, exit, and the failure of internal control systems. Journal of Finance 48(3): 831–880. John K, Ofek E. 1995. Asset sales and increase in focus. Journal of Financial Economics 37: 105–126. Johnson RA. 1996. Antecedents and outcomes of corporate refocusing. Journal of Management 22: 439–483. Johnson RA, Hoskisson RE, Hitt MA. 1993. Board of director involvement in restructuring: the effects of board versus managerial controls and characteristics. Strategic Management Journal , Summer Special Issue 14: 33–50. Jones GR, Hill CWL. 1988. Transaction cost analysis of strategy-structure choice. Strategic Management Journal 9(2): 159–172. Kaplan S, Weisbach MS. 1992. The success of acquisitions: evidence from divestitures. Journal of Finance 47: 107–139. Khan AQ, Mehta DR. 1996. Voluntary divestitures and the choice between sell-offs and spin-offs. The Financial Review 31: 885–912. Kim L. 1998. Crisis construction and organizational learning: capability building in catching-up at Hyundai Motor. Organization Science 9: 506–521. Strat. Mgmt. J., 29: 593–616 (2008) DOI: 10.1002/smj Learning How to Restructure Krishnaswami S, Subramaniam V. 1999. Information asymmetry, valuation, and the corporate spin-off decision. Journal of Financial Economics 53(1): 73–112. Kudla RJ, McInish TH. 1984. Corporate spin-offs. Quorum Books: London, UK. Lane PJ, Koka BR, Pathak S. 2006. The reification of absorptive capacity: a critical review and rejuvenation of the construct. Academy of Management Review 31(4): 833–863. Lane PJ, Lubatkin MH. 1998. Relative absorptive capacity and interorganizational learning. Strategic Management Journal 19(5): 461–4778. Lane PJ, Salk JE, Lyles MA. 2001. Absorptive capacity, learning, and performance in international joint ventures. Strategic Management Journal 22(12): 1139–1161. Lang L, Poulsen A, Stulz R. 1995. Asset sales, firm performance, and the agency costs of managerial discretion. Journal of Financial Economics 37: 3–38. Leiblein MJ, Miller DJ. 2003. An empirical examination of transaction- and firm-level influences on the vertical boundaries of the firm. Strategic Management Journal 24(9): 839–859. Levinthal DA, March JG. 1993. The myopia of learning. Strategic Management Journal , Winter Special Issue 14: 95–112. Levinthal DA, Rerup C. 2006. Crossing an apparent chasm: bridging mindful and less-mindful perspectives on organizational learning. Organization Science 17(4): 502–513. Levi-Strauss C. 1967. Structural Anthropology. Doubleday: Garden City, NY. Levitt B, March JG. 1988. Organizational learning. Annual Review of Sociology 14: 319–340. Lieberman MB. 1987. The learning curve, diffusion, and competitive strategy. Strategic Management Journal 8(5): 441–452. Lieberman MB. 1989. The learning curve, technological barriers to entry, and competitive survival in the chemical processing industries. Strategic Management Journal 10(5): 431–447. March JG. 1991. Exploration and exploitation in organizational learning. Organization Science 2: 71–87. March JG, Sevon G. 1984. Gossip, information and decision-making. In Advances in Information Processing in Organizations, Sproull LS, Larkey D (eds). JAI Press: Greenwich, CT; 95–107. Markides CC. 1992. The consequences of corporate refocusing: ex-ante evidence. Academy of Management Journal 35(2): 398–412. Markides CC. 1995. Diversification, restructuring and economic performance. Strategic Management Journal 16(2): 101–118. Miles JA, Rosenfeld JD. 1983. The effect of voluntary spin-off announcements on shareholder wealth. Journal of Finance 38: 1597–1606. Miller D, Friesen P. 1980. Momentum and revolution in organizational adaptation. Academy of Management Journal 23: 591–613. Copyright 2008 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. 615 Miller D, Friesen P. 1982. The longitudinal analysis of organizations: a methodological perspective. Management Science 28: 1013–1035. Miner AS, Bassoff P, Moorman C. 2001. Organizational improvisation and learning: a field study. Administrative Science Quarterly 46: 304–337. Mitchell TR, James LR. 2001. Building better theory: time and the specification of when things happen. Academy of Management Review 26: 530–548. Montgomery CA, Thomas AR, Kamath R. 1984. Divesture, market valuation, and strategy. Academy of Management Journal 27: 830–840. Moorman C, Miner AS. 1998a. The convergence of planning and execution: improvisation in new product development. Journal of Marketing 62(3): 1–20. Moorman C, Miner AS. 1998b. Organizational improvisation and organizational memory. Academy of Management Review 23(4): 698–723. Narasimhan O, Rajiv S, Dutta S. 2006. Absorptive capacity in high technology markets: the competitive advantage of the haves. Marketing Science 25(5): 510–524. Nelson RR, Winter SG. 1982. An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change. Belknap: Cambridge, MA. Nixon TD, Roenfeldt RL, Sicherman NW. 2000. The choice between spin-offs and sell-offs. Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting 14: 277–294. Ofek E. 1993. Capital structure and firm response to poor performance: an empirical analysis. Journal of Financial Economics 34: 3–30. Pennings JM, Barkema H, Douma S. 1994. Organizational learning and diversification. Academy of Management Journal 37: 608–640. Pennings JM, Harianto F. 1992. The diffusion of technological innovation in the commercial banking industry. Strategic Management Journal 13(1): 29–46. Ravenscraft D, Scherer FM. 1987. Mergers, Sell-offs, and Eeconomic Efficiency. The Brookings Institution: Washington, DC. Rosenfeld JD. 1984. Additional evidence on the relation between divestiture announcements and shareholder wealth. Journal of Finance 39: 1437–1448. Schipper K, Smith A. 1983. Effects of recontracting on shareholder wealth: the case of voluntary spin-offs. Journal of Financial Economics 12: 437–468. Securities Data Corporation. 2000. Worldwide Merger & Acquisition Dataset. Thomson Financials: www. thomsonfinancials.com. Seward JK, Walsh JP. 1996. The governance and control of voluntary corporate spin-offs. Strategic Management Journal 17(1): 25–39. Shaver JM, Mitchell W, Yeung B. 1997. The effect of own-firm and other-firm experience on foreign direct investment survival in the United States, 1987–92. Strategic Management Journal 18(10): 811–824. Shleifer A, Vishny RW. 1991. Takeovers in the 60s and the 80s: evidence and implications. Strategic Management Journal Winter Special Issue 12: 51–59. Sproull L, Keisler S. 1991. Connections: New Ways of Working in the Networked Organization. MIT Press: Cambridge, MA. Strat. Mgmt. J., 29: 593–616 (2008) DOI: 10.1002/smj 616 D. D. Bergh and E. N.-K. Lim Szulanski G. 1996. Exploring internal stickiness: impediments to the transfer of best practice within the firm. Strategic Management Journal , Winter Special Issue 17: 27–43. Taylor ML. 1988. Divesting Business Units: Making the Decision and Making it Work. Lexington Books: Lexington, MA. Tippins MJ, Sohi RS. 2003. IT competency and firm performance: is organizational learning a missing link? Strategic Management Journal 24(8): 745–761. Vera D, Crossan M. 2005. Improvisation and innovative performance in teams. Organization Science 16(3): 203–224. Vermeulen GAM, Barkema HG. 2001. Learning through acquisitions. Academy of Management Journal 44(3): 457–476. Villalonga B, McGahan AM. 2005. The choice among acquisitions, alliances, and divestitures. Strategic Management Journal 26(13): 1183–1208. Walsh JP, Rivera G. 1991. Organizational memory. Academy of Management Review 16(1): 57–91. Walsh JP, Seward JK. 1990. On the efficiency of internal and external corporate control mechanisms. Academy of Management Review 15: 421–458. Weick KE. 1993. The collapse of sensemaking in organizations: the Mann Gulch disaster. Administrative Science Quarterly 41: 301–313. Weick KE. 1996. Drop your tools: an allegory for organizational studies. Administrative Science Quarterly 41: 301–313. Weick KE. 1998. Improvisation as a mindset for organizational analysis. Organization Science 9(5): 543–555. Copyright 2008 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Weick KE. 2001. Making Sense of the Organization. Blackwell: Oxford, UK. Weick KE, Roberts KH. 1993. Collective mind and organizational reliability: the case of flight operations on an aircraft carrier deck. Administrative Science Quarterly 38: 357–381. Weston JF, Chung KS, Hoag SE. 1990. Mergers, restructuring, and corporate control . Prentice-Hall: Englewood Cliffs, NJ. Winter SG. 1987. Knowledge and competence as strategic assets. In The Competitive Challenge: Strategies for Industrial Innovation and Renewal , Teece DJ (ed). Ballinger: Cambridge, MA; 159–184. Winter SG. 2003. Understanding dynamic capabilities. Strategic Management Journal , October Special Issue 24: 991–995. Winter SG, Szulanski G. 2001. Replication as strategy. Organization Science 12: 730–744. Zaheer S, Albert S, Zaheer A. 1999. Time scales and organizational theory. Academy of Management Review 24: 725–742. Zahra SA, George G. 2002. Absorptive capacity: a review, reconceptualization, and extension. Academy of Management Review 27(2): 185–203. Zollo M, Reuer JJ, Singh H. 2002. Interorganizational routines and performance in strategic alliances. Organization Science 13(6): 791–713. Zollo M, Singh H. 2004. Deliberate learning in corporate acquisitions: post-acquisition strategies and integration capability in U.S. bank mergers. Strategic Management Journal 25(13): 1233–1256. Strat. Mgmt. J., 29: 593–616 (2008) DOI: 10.1002/smj
© Copyright 2024