Chapter 11 PURE MONOPOLY Learning objective LEARNING OBJECTIVES On completing this chapter you should be able to: er 11.1 Review the nature of barriers to entry into an industry, and their form and likely occurrence. pl e 11.4 Compare the outcome of a monopoly industry–in terms of allocative and productive efficiency–with that of a perfectly competitive industry. ch a 11.3 Understand how monopoly adjusts price and output in shortrun and long-run situations. pt 11.2 Examine demand from a monopolist’s viewpoint. Sa m 11.5 Discuss whether government can play a role in modifying monopoly behaviour. The material is for promotional purposes only. No authorised printing or duplication is permitted. (c) McGraw-Hill Australia jac98674_ch11_292-319.indd 292 17/06/11 1:39 AM INTRODUCTION ch a pt er We now move from pure competition to the opposite end of the industry range– pure monopoly. In this chapter we examine the characteristics, bases, price–output behaviour and social desirability of the pure monopoly model. Does the monopolist achieve the allocative and productive efficiency observed in perfect competition? As we saw in Chapter 8, absolute or pure monopoly exists when a single firm is the sole producer of a product for which there are no close substitutes. By definition, there will be no other firms producing the same product or products that vary only in very minor ways from that of the monopolist. For example, there is no close substitute for water supplies. Nor is there a good substitute for regular postal services. On the international scene, the De Beers diamond syndicate controls much of the world’s supply of diamonds. In small and geographically isolated towns, the single local hardware store or cinema may approximate pure monopoly. Pure monopoly is a rare phenomenon, but the study of pure monopoly is important for at least two reasons: Sa m pl e • Some industries are reasonable approximations of monopoly. Often, we can explain, with considerable accuracy, the behaviour of firms with 80 or even 70 per cent of a market through the pure monopoly market model. • A study of pure monopoly gives us valuable insights into the more realistic market structures of monopolistic competition and oligopoly (which will be discussed in Chapters 12 and 13). These two market situations combine in differing degrees the characteristics of perfect competition and pure monopoly. The material is for promotional purposes only. No authorised printing or duplication is permitted. (c) McGraw-Hill Australia jac98674_ch11_292-319.indd 293 17/06/11 1:39 AM BARRIERS TO ENTRY pure monopoly a one-firm industry, where a single firm is the only producer/supplier of a given product/service. Barriers to entry any obstacles that prevent the entry of firms into an industry. In Chapter 8 we noted that pure monopoly is characterised by the absence of competitors, and this absence can largely be explained in terms of barriers to entry into an industry. Such barriers prohibit additional firms from entering an industry. Barriers to entry imply the presence of monopoly power in a market. These barriers are also important in explaining the existence of oligopoly and monopolistic competition between the market extremes of perfect competition and pure monopoly. In pure monopoly, entry barriers completely block all potential competition. Less formidable barriers permit the existence of oligopoly–that is, a market dominated by a few firms. Weaker barriers permit the fairly large number of firms that characterises monopolistic competition. The absence of entry barriers helps explain the very large number of competing firms that forms the basis of perfect competition. The point to observe is that barriers to entry are relevant both to the extreme case of pure monopoly, and also to the ‘partial monopolies’ that are so characteristic of Australian capitalism. pt Natural monopoly occurs in industries whose technological and economic realities rule out the possibility of competitive markets. In many industries, modern technology requires that efficient, low-cost production can be achieved only if producers are extremely large both absolutely and in relation to the market. Where economies of scale are very significant, a firm’s average cost schedule will decline over a wide range of output (see Figure 9.7(a)). For a particular market demand, achieving low unit costs (and therefore low unit prices for consumers) depends on the existence of a small number of firms or–in the extreme case–only one firm. The motor vehicle and steel industries are among the many heavy industries that reflect such conditions. Let’s say three firms (the ‘Big Three’) currently enjoy all available economies of scale and each has approximately one-third of a market. Small-scale producers entering the market have little chance to survive and expand. They will be unable to realise the cost economies enjoyed by the existing ‘Big Three’ and unable to obtain the profits necessary for survival and growth. New competitors in the steel and motor vehicle industries will not emerge from the successful operation and expansion of small producers–they will not be efficient enough to survive. The other option is to start out big–that is, to enter the industry as a large-scale producer. In practice, this is very difficult. It is unlikely that a new and inexperienced firm will be able to secure the money capital needed to obtain capital facilities comparable to those of the ‘Big Three’. The financial obstacles in the way of starting big are usually so great that they are prohibitive. In some industries, economies of scale are significantly prominent at all possible output levels. Competition is impractical, inconvenient or simply unworkable. Such industries are called natural monopolies. Most of the formerly public utilities in Australia–the electricity and gas supply industries, railways, water and communication facilities–can be classified in this way. OWNERSHIP OF ESSENTIAL RAW MATERIALS ch a Economies of scale the forces that reduce the average cost of producing a product as the firm expands the size of its output in the long run. er ECONOMIES OF SCALE m pl e Private property can be used by a monopoly as an effective obstacle to potential rivals. A firm owning or controlling an essential raw material can withhold its availability and thus prohibit the creation of rival firms. Therefore other firms have little chance of entering that industry (unless new resource supplies or substitutes are discovered). There are several typical examples of monopolistic ownership. world’s known nickel reserves. Sa • In the 1940s and 1950s, BHP controlled all the known available iron ore deposits in Australia. • The International Nickel Company of Canada (INCO) once controlled approximately 90 per cent of the The material is for promotional purposes only. No authorised printing or duplication is permitted. (c) McGraw-Hill Australia 294 Part 3 jac98674_ch11_292-319.indd 294 The economics of markets 17/06/11 1:39 AM • Most of the world’s known diamond mines are owned or effectively controlled by the De Beers Company of South Africa. LEGAL BARRIERS Patent and copyright laws give inventors the exclusive right to control a product for some specified period of years. These laws are aimed at protecting inventors from their product or process being appropriated by rival enterprises that have not shared in the time, effort and money outlays of the product development. Patents also provide the inventor with a monopoly position for the life of the patent. Patents and copyrights have been important to many modern-day international industrial giants–such as, 3M, Sony and Microsoft. Research underlies the development of patentable products. Firms that gain a measure of monopoly power by their own research (or by purchasing the patents of others) are in a strategic position to consolidate and strengthen their market position. The profits provided by one important patent may be used to finance the research that is required to develop new patentable products. Monopoly power achieved through patents and copyrights may be cumulative. TWO IMPLICATIONS Our discussion of barriers to entry suggests two notable points. • The rarity of pure monopoly: Barriers to entry are rarely completely effective. Research and technological advance may strengthen the market position of a firm, but technological advance may also undermine existing monopoly power. Existing patent advantages may be circumvented by the development of new and distinct, yet substitutable, products. Additionally, new sources of strategic raw materials may be found. We could say that monopoly in the sense of a one-firm industry can persist over time only with the sanction or aid of government (e.g. postal services fit into this category). • Desirability: We implied that monopolies may be either desirable or undesirable from the standpoint of economic efficiency. The arguments regarding public utilities and economies of scale suggest that market demand and technology signify efficient low-cost production as a characteristic of monopoly. However, our comments on materials ownership, patents and copyrights as sources of monopoly point to the more undesirable elements of monopoly. pt 11.1 Sa m pl e ch a • Barriers to entry exist in the following forms: – economies of scale, requiring substantial investment and therefore operation at high levels of output to achieve low-cost production–natural monopolies provide extreme examples of this type of entry barrier – the ownership or control of essential raw materials, preventing competitors from acquiring the necessary inputs to compete in the market – patent ownership and research and licences that provide a legal barrier to entry and provide the owner with exclusive rights to use an idea, process or technology. • Barriers to entry help to explain the existence not only of pure monopoly but also of other imperfectly competitive market structures. • Barriers to entry that are very formidable in the short run may prove to be surmountable in the long run due to technological and regulatory changes over time. er Learning objective Checkpoint The material is for promotional purposes only. No authorised printing or duplication is permitted. (c) McGraw-Hill Australia Pure monopoly jac98674_ch11_292-319.indd 295 Chapter 11 295 17/06/11 1:39 AM MONOPOLY DEMAND ASSUMPTIONS We begin our analysis of the price–output behaviour of a pure monopolist with three assumptions: 1. The monopolist’s position is guaranteed by, say, patents or control over raw materials. 2. There is no prospect of government takeover or a government agency regulating the firm. 3. At any output level, the firm sells all that output at the same price. The monopolist does not discriminate between buyers by charging them different prices. OVERVIEW The crucial difference between a pure monopolist and a purely competitive seller lies on the demand side of the market. Recall from Chapter 10 that the purely competitive seller faces a perfectly elastic marginal revenue line (or ‘demand’ schedule) at the market price–determined by industry supply and demand. The competitive firm is a ‘price taker’ that can sell any amount at the current market price. Each additional unit sold will add a constant amount–that is, its price–to the firm’s total revenue. In other words, marginal revenue is constant and equal to product price. This means that total revenue increases by a constant amount–that is, by the constant price of each unit sold. (Looking back at Table 10.1 and Figure 10.1 will remind us the price, marginal revenue, and total revenue relationships of the perfectly competitive firm.) The monopolist’s demand curve–and the demand curve for any imperfectly competitive seller–is very different. The pure monopolist is the industry. Therefore, its demand (sales) curve is the industry demand curve. The market (industry) demand curve is in fact downward-sloping. This is illustrated in columns 1 and 2 of Table 11.1. There are three implications of a downward-sloping demand curve that must be understood. PRICE EXCEEDS MARGINAL REVENUE With a downward-sloping demand curve, the pure monopoly can increase its sales only by charging a lower unit price for its product. Because the monopolist must lower price to boost sales, marginal revenue is less than price (average revenue) for every level of output except the first. Why? Price cuts will apply both to the extra output sold, and also to all other units of output that could otherwise have been sold at a higher price. Each TABLE 11.1 REVENUE AND COST DATA OF A PURE MONOPOLIST (HYPOTHETICAL DATA) REVENUE DATA 4 8 PROFIT (ⴙ) OR 5 6 7 MARGINAL COST ($) PRICE (AVERAGE REVENUE) ($) TOTAL REVENUE ($) MARGINAL REVENUE ($) AVERAGE TOTAL COST ($) TOTAL COST ($) 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 172 162 152 142 132 122 112 102 92 82 72 0 162 304 426 528 610 672 714 736 738 720 162 142 122 102 82 62 42 22 2 –18 190.00 135.00 113.33 100.00 94.00 91.67 91.43 93.73 97.78 103.00 100 190 270 340 400 470 550 640 750 880 1030 90 80 70 60 70 80 90 110 130 150 Sa m pl e QUANTITY OF OUTPUT er 3 pt 2 LOSS (ⴚ) ($) ch a 1 COST DATA ⫺100 ⫺28 ⫹34 ⫹86 ⫹128 ⴙ140 ⫹122 ⫹74 ⫺14 ⫺142 ⫺310 The material is for promotional purposes only. No authorised printing or duplication is permitted. (c) McGraw-Hill Australia 296 Part 3 jac98674_ch11_292-319.indd 296 The economics of markets 17/06/11 1:39 AM additional unit sold will add to total revenue its price less the sum of the price cuts that must be taken on all prior units of output. For example, in Table 11.1 the monopolist can sell 3 units at $142 or 4 units at $132. By increasing output from 3 to 4 units, the monopolist will enjoy a revenue gain equal to the $132 received for the 4th unit. However, there will also be a revenue loss equivalent to the loss per unit on the first 3 units of $10 ($142 – $132) multiplied by the number of units (3). This means a revenue loss of $30 on the 3 units already sold. The net gain in revenue is the revenue gain minus the loss ($132 – $30) or $102. Note that this is the difference between the total revenue figures for 3 and 4 units ($528 – $426). This net change in revenue of $102 is the marginal revenue of the fourth unit, since it is the change to total revenue by adding the fourth unit. Similarly, the marginal revenue of the second unit of output in Table 11.1 is $142 rather than its $152 price–because a $10 price cut must be taken on the first unit to increase sales from 1 to 2 units. Similarly, to sell 3 units the firm must lower price from $152 to $142. The resulting marginal revenue will be just $122 (or a $142 addition to total revenue from the third unit minus $10 price cuts on both the first 2 units of output). This explains why the marginal revenue data of column 4 of Table 11.1 fall short of product price in column 2 for all levels of output except the first. You will notice that total revenue is increasing at a diminishing rate–as shown in column 3 of Table 11.1. This is because MR is, by definition, the increase in TR for each extra unit of output. The relationships between the demand, marginal revenue and total revenue curves are illustrated in Figure 11.1(a) and (b). In these diagrams, we have extended the demand and revenue data of columns 1 to 4 of Table 11.1 by continuing to assume that successive $10 price cuts will each mean one additional unit of sales–that is, 11 units can be sold at $62, 12 at $52 and so on. The marginal revenue curve lies below the demand curve, and there is also a special relationship between total revenue and marginal revenue. Marginal revenue is, by definition, the change in total revenue. Therefore, we observe that–as long as marginal revenue is positive–total revenue is increasing. When marginal revenue is zero, total revenue reaches its maximum. And when marginal revenue is negative, total revenue is diminishing. Further, note that because price is average revenue–and since it declines with output–then marginal revenue must be less than average revenue. Remember that marginal must be less than average revenue for the average to fall. PRICE ELASTICITY pt m • when demand is elastic at the initial price a decline in price will increase total revenue • when demand is inelastic at the initial price a decline in price will decrease total revenue. pl e The total revenue test for price elasticity of demand is the basis for our third conclusion. In Chapter 6, that the total revenue test told us that: ch a In all imperfectly competitive markets in which such downward-sloping demand curves are relevant–that is, purely monopolistic, oligopolistic and monopolistically competitive markets–firms have a price policy. The output decisions of such firms necessarily affect product price because of their ability to influence total supply. This is most evident in pure monopoly, where one firm controls total output. Faced with a down-sloping demand curve (where each output is associated with some unique price), the monopolist unavoidably determines price in deciding what volume of output to produce. The monopolist simultaneously determines both price and output. In columns 1 and 2 of Table 11.1 we find that the monopolist can sell an output of only 1 unit at a price of $162, an output of only 2 units at a price of $152 per unit, and so on. Wea are not suggesting that the monopolist is ‘free’ of market forces in establishing price and output, nor that the consumer is somehow completely at the monopolist’s mercy. In particular, the monopolist’s down-sloping demand curve means that the monopolist cannot raise price without losing sales (or gain sales without charging a lower price). er ‘PRICE MAKER’ Sa Beginning at the top of the demand curve in Figure 11.1, observe that for all price reductions from $172 down to $82, total revenue increases (and marginal revenue is therefore positive). This means that demand is elastic in this price range. However, for price reductions below $82, total revenue decreases (marginal revenue is negative)–which indicates that demand is inelastic in that price range. The material is for promotional purposes only. No authorised printing or duplication is permitted. (c) McGraw-Hill Australia Pure monopoly jac98674_ch11_292-319.indd 297 Chapter 11 297 17/06/11 1:39 AM FIGURE 11.1 DEMAND, MARGINAL REVENUE AND TOTAL REVENUE FOR AN IMPERFECTLY COMPETITIVE FIRM $ 200 Elastic 150 Unit elasticity 100 Inelastic MR 50 0 2 4 6 D 8 10 12 14 16 18 16 18 Q (a) Demand and marginal revenue curves $ 750 TR 500 250 0 Q 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 ch a pt Because an imperfectly competitive firm must lower price to increase its sales, its marginal revenue curve (MR) lies below its down-sloping demand curve (D). Total revenue (TR) increases at a decreasing rate, reaches a maximum, and then declines. Note that, because MR is the change in TR, a unique relationship exists between MR and TR. When we move down the elastic segment of the demand curve, TR is increasing and, hence, MR is positive. When TR reaches its maximum, MR is zero. And when we move down the inelastic segment of the demand curve, TR is declining, so MR is negative. A monopolist or other imperfectly competitive seller will never operate in the inelastic segment of its demand curve: MC must intersect MR in the latter’s positive range. er (b) Total revenue curve Learning objective Checkpoint pl e 11.2 m • The monopolist’s ‘own’ demand curve is down-sloping, as it faces the demand curve for the Sa market as a whole. The monopolist is a price maker not a price taker, as it can choose its price–output combination on the market demand curve. • The presence of a down-sloping demand curve causes the marginal revenue curve of the monopolist to lie below its demand curve–that is, MR ⬍ AR (⫽ P) at all relevant output levels. • Marginal revenue for the monopolist is negative beyond the point of unit elasticity of demand. The material is for promotional purposes only. No authorised printing or duplication is permitted. (c) McGraw-Hill Australia 298 Part 3 jac98674_ch11_292-319.indd 298 The economics of markets 17/06/11 1:39 AM PRICE AND OUTPUT DETERMINATION What specific price–quantity combination on the demand curve will the pure monopolist choose? This depends on both demand and marginal revenue data, and on the costs of production. COST DATA The firm is a monopolist in the product market but–on the cost side–we assume that it hires resources competitively and employs the same technology as the competitive firm. This assumption permits us to use the cost data developed in Chapter 9 and applied in Chapter 10, thus allowing a comparison of the price–output decisions of a pure monopoly with those of a perfect competitor. Columns 5 to 7 of Table 11.1 restate the relevant cost concepts of Table 9.3. MR ⴝ MC RULE A profit-seeking monopolist will use the same rationale as a profit-seeking firm in a competitive industry. It will produce each successive unit of output as long as it adds more to total revenue than it does to total costs. The firm will produce up to the output at which marginal revenue equals marginal cost (MR ⫽ MC). A comparison of columns 4 and 7 in Table 11.1 indicates that the profit-maximising output is 5 units. The fifth unit is the last unit of output whose marginal revenue exceeds its marginal cost. What price will the monopolist charge? The downward-sloping demand curve of columns 1 and 2 in Table 11.1 indicates that there is only one price at which 5 units can be sold: $122. This analysis is presented graphically in Figure 11.2, where the demand, marginal revenue, average total cost and marginal cost data of Table 11.1 have been drawn. Comparison of marginal revenue and FIGURE 11.2 THE PROFIT-MAXIMISING POSITION OF A PURE MONOPOLIST 200 175 MC 100 er ATC Profit pt 125 122 Pm 94 A 75 AR ch a Unit costs ($) 150 D 50 pl e MR 25 Qm 2 3 4 5 6 Quantity 7 8 9 10 Q m 1 Sa 0 The pure monopolist maximises profits by producing the MR ⫽ MC output. In this instance profit is APm per unit, and total profits are measured by the shaded rectangle. The material is for promotional purposes only. No authorised printing or duplication is permitted. (c) McGraw-Hill Australia Pure monopoly jac98674_ch11_292-319.indd 299 Chapter 11 299 17/06/11 1:39 AM marginal cost confirms that the profit-maximising output is 5 units or, more generally, Q m. The unique price at which Q m can be sold is found by extending a perpendicular up from the profit-maximising point on the output axis and then horizontally across to the vertical axis from the point at which it hits the demand curve. The indicated price is Pm. By charging a price higher than Pm, the monopolist must move up the demand curve–meaning that sales will fall short of the profit-maximising level Q m. Specifically, the firm will be failing to produce units of output whose marginal revenue exceeds their marginal cost. If the monopolist charges less, it would involve a volume of sales in excess of the profit-maximising output. Columns 2 and 5 of Table 11.1 indicate that, at 5 units of output, the product price of $122 exceeds the average total cost of $94. Economic profits are therefore $28 per unit; total economic profits are then $140 (⫽ 5 ⫻ $28). In Figure 11.2, per-unit profit is indicated by the distance APm. Total economic profits–the shaded area–are found by multiplying the per-unit profit by the profit-maximising output Q m. The same profit-maximising combination of output and price can also be determined by comparing the total revenue and total costs that are incurred at each possible level of production. You should use columns 3 and 6 of Table 11.1 to verify all the conclusions we have reached through the use of marginal revenue– marginal cost analysis. Similarly, an accurate graphing of total revenue and total cost against output will also show the greatest differential (the maximum profit) at 5 units of output. INDUSTRY CONCENTRATION AND (ACCOUNTING) PROFITS PRACTISING ECONOMIST The discussion of this chapter suggests that under ideal conditions firms with an element of monopoly power should be able to maximise their economic profits. A problem in testing for the presence of monopoly is that economic profits are not readily observable. However, we can observe estimates on accounting profit margins. While it has been long recognised that high accounting profits need not mean economic profits are being generated in any given situation, an examination over a range of businesses or activities may still provide us with some insight into the benefits accruing to firms from increased market power. Here we present further data on concentration ratios and profit margins derived from data produced by the Australian Bureau of Statistics for a range of industries. Agriculture, Forestry and Fishing 8.2 66.8 34.7 pt 3.7 EBITDA-TOINCOME (%)** 16.0 40.3 62.8 6.4 70.3 13.6 Construction 24.6 10.4 Wholesale Trade 41.4 4.9 5.6 3.8 4.5 7.5 11.4 8.3 13.2 9.5 29.8 43.8 Accommodation and Food Services 20.8 Transport, Postal and Warehousing 45.8 Information, Media and Telecommunications 78.9 pl Sa Retail Trade 9.2 e Manufacturing Electricity, Gas, Water and Waste Services m Mining OPERATING PROFIT BEFORE TAX-TOINCOME (%)* ch a INDUSTRY LARGE BUSINESSES SHARE OF SALES REVENUES (%) er SHARE OF INDUSTRY SALES BY LARGE FIRMS* AND INDUSTRY PROFIT MARGINS (%) 22.5 12.6 The material is for promotional purposes only. No authorised printing or duplication is permitted. (c) McGraw-Hill Australia 300 Part 3 jac98674_ch11_292-319.indd 300 The economics of markets 17/06/11 1:39 AM LARGE BUSINESSES SHARE OF SALES REVENUES (%) OPERATING PROFIT BEFORE TAXTO-INCOME (%)* EBITDA-TOINCOME (%)** Rental, Hiring and Real Estate Services 13.8 16.2 37.2 Professional, Scientific and Technical Services 26.7 20.4 10.6 Administrative and Support Services 33.4 7.2 11.7 Public Administration and Safety*** 33.8 10.1 9.4 24.0 5.5 4.0 29.2 15.4 15.2 INDUSTRY *** Education and Training Health Care and Social Assistance *** Arts and Recreation Services 36.5 14.1 12.4 Other Services 10.8 12.5 5.9 Total selected industries 42.9 10.6 13.3 * Large firms are those with 200 or more employees. ** EBITDA is earnings before interest, tax, depreciation and amortisation. *** Measures refer only to the private sector. Source: Authors’ estimates derived from Australian Bureau of Statistics, Counts of Australian Businesses, including Entries and Exits, June 2007–June 2009, Cat No. 8165.0, and Australian Bureau of Statistics, Australian Industry, 2008-09, Cat No. 8155.0. QUESTIONS 1. Graph the relationship between industry concentration and each of the measures of profit margin, labelling each industry in your graphs. 2. Is a higher level of industry sales concentration associated with higher profit margins? 3. Are there obvious exceptions to the relationship that you observed in developing your answer to question 2? What reasons might account for any exceptions? 4. Given the dictum that ‘higher risk requires higher return to compensate’, might some of the relatively high profit margins observed in the associated table be a normal part of the economic cost of keeping resources in high-risk industries? Are the industries in which returns are highest obviously high risk? Discuss. NO SUPPLY CURVE FOR MONOPOLY Two important observations about the price–output behaviour of monopoly should be emphasised. pt ch a Sa m pl e where price declines cause total revenue to decrease (and marginal revenue to be negative). The profitmaximising monopolist will always avoid the inelastic segment of its demand curve in favour of some price– quantity combination in the elastic segment. In other words, profit maximisation occurs where MR ⫽ MC. Since MC is positive, MR must also be positive at any profit-maximising output. If MR is positive, then we know that demand is elastic in this range of prices. • We found in the analysis of a perfectly competitive firm that its marginal cost curve, above close-down, was the firm’s supply curve. Each possible market price was associated with a specific output, so defining the supply curve. The notion of a supply curve does not, however, apply in a purely monopolistic (or any other imperfectly competitive) market. At any given demand and cost conditions, there will be only one profit-maximising price–output combination. Further, there is no unique relationship that can be established between price and quantity supplied. It is possible for the monopolist to supply different quantities at the same price or the same quantity at different prices. er • A generalisation that emerges is that a monopolist will never choose a price–quantity combination Figure 11.3 illustrates that the monopolist has no unique supply curve. The monopolist chooses to supply different quantities at the same price or the same quantity at different prices. The monopolist does not have a supply curve but chooses a price–output combination, given current demand conditions. The material is for promotional purposes only. No authorised printing or duplication is permitted. (c) McGraw-Hill Australia Pure monopoly jac98674_ch11_292-319.indd 301 Chapter 11 301 17/06/11 1:39 AM FIGURE 11.3 THE MONOPOLIST HAS NO UNIQUE SUPPLY CURVE $ $ MC P MC P1 P2 AR 2 AR 2 MR 2 MR 1 Q1Q AR 1 AR 1 2 MR 2 MR 1 Q Q Q It is possible for the monopolist to supply different quantities at the same price or the same quantity at different prices. The monopolist does not have a supply curve but chooses a price–output combination, given current demand conditions. MISCONCEPTIONS CONCERNING MONOPOLY PRICING Our analysis refutes some popular fallacies concerning the behaviour of monopolies. NOT HIGHEST PRICE A monopolist can manipulate output and price, thus it is often claimed that a monopolist ‘will charge the highest price it can get’. This is a misguided assertion. There are many prices above Pm in Figure 11.2, but the monopolist avoids them solely because they entail a smaller than maximum profit. Total profits are the difference between total revenue and total costs, and each of these two determinants of profits depends on the quantity sold as much as on the price and unit cost. ch a pt The monopolist seeks maximum total profits, not maximum unit profits. In Figure 11.2 a careful comparison of the vertical distance between ATC and price at various possible outputs indicates that per-unit profits are greater at a point slightly to the left of the profit-maximising output Q m. This is seen in Table 11.1, where unit profits are $32 at 4 units of output, as compared with $28 at the profit-maximising output of 5 units. The monopolist is accepting a lower-than-maximum per-unit profit because the additional sales more than compensate for the lower unit profits. A profit-seeking monopolist would obviously rather sell 5 units at a profit of $28 per unit (for a total profit of $140) than 4 units at a profit of $32 per unit (for a total profit of only $128). er TOTAL, NOT UNIT, PROFITS e LOSSES Sa m pl Pure monopoly does not guarantee economic profits. It is true that the likelihood of economic profits is greater for a pure monopolist than for a perfectly competitive producer. (In the long run the perfectly competitive is likely to achieve merely a normal profit due to the free and easy entry of new firms.) Barriers to entry permit the monopolist to perpetuate economic profits in the long run (but do not guarantee it).1 Like the perfect competitor, the monopolist cannot persistently operate at a loss. It must realise a normal profit or better in the long run, or it will not survive. However, if the demand and cost situation faced The material is for promotional purposes only. No authorised printing or duplication is permitted. (c) McGraw-Hill Australia 302 Part 3 jac98674_ch11_292-319.indd 302 The economics of markets 17/06/11 1:39 AM FIGURE 11.4 THE LOSS-MINIMISING POSITION OF A PURE MONOPOLIST Price and unit cost MC ATC A Pm AVC Loss MR 0 D Qm Output If demand D is weak and costs are high, the pure monopolist may be unable to make a profit. It will minimise its losses in the short run by producing at the output where MR ⫽ MC. Loss per unit is APm and total losses are indicated by the shaded rectangle. by the monopolist is less favourable than that shown in Figure 11.2, it may realise short-run losses. The monopolist shown in Figure 11.4 is dominant in the market but realises a loss in the short run because of a weak demand and relatively high costs. It may continue to operate for a while because variable costs are covered and a contribution is being made towards fixed costs. Learning objective Checkpoint 11.3 pt ch a Sa m pl e revenue and marginal cost–that is, by choosing to produce at the output level where MR ⫽ MC, and then charging the appropriate price. • Because marginal cost is positive, the monopolist will always prefer to choose a price–output combination in the elastic range of the demand curve. • As there is only one optimum price–output combination, the monopoly seller has a supply point, but not a supply curve. • Because the monopolist faces a down-sloping demand curve, P ⬎ MC at equilibrium for the monopolist. • Barriers to entry may permit a monopolist to choose price–output combinations that provide economic profits even in the long run. • Misconceptions about monopoly pricing can be dispelled as follows: – The monopolist does not charge ‘the highest price it can get’. It charges a profit-maximising price. – The monopolist seeks maximum total profits, not maximum unit profits. – Pure monopoly does not guarantee economic profits–high costs and a weak demand may prevent the monopolist from realising any profit at all. er • Like the competitive seller, the pure monopolist will maximise profits by equating marginal The material is for promotional purposes only. No authorised printing or duplication is permitted. (c) McGraw-Hill Australia Pure monopoly jac98674_ch11_292-319.indd 303 Chapter 11 303 17/06/11 1:39 AM GOVERNMENT-GRANTED MONOPOLY AND RETURNS PRACTISING ECONOMIST That government legislation is one of the primary sources of monopoly power has been discussed in some detail in this chapter. However, it is rare to find relatively unambiguous evidence on the impact of this source of monopoly power. Here we present data from a study on the impacts of state versus private ownership and monopoly power on profitability in the telecommunications industry. Our data relates to telephone companies in the Americas, Asia, the Caribean, Eastern Europe and the Indian subcontinent. The time in this example is 2000 to 2001. Our measure for profitability is return on sales (ROS)– profit before interest and tax are deducted relative to sales revenues. Again this is an imperfect indicator of the impact of monopoly power in any one situtation, but we can hope that over a set of data it may provide some indication of the producer benefit of monopoly. FIRM, OWNERSHIP/CONTROL, MARKET SEGMENTS IN WHICH COMPETITION IS PRESENT AND RETURN ON SALES (ROS) COMPETITION PRESENT IN FIRM (COUNTRY) OWNERSHIP/ CONTROL* MOBILE TELEPHONE SERVICES LOCAL TELEPONE SERVICES LONGDISTANCE TELEPHONE SERVICES ROS (%) Telecom Argentina (Argentina) private yes yes yes 18.6 Telefonica de Argentina (Argentina) private yes yes yes 20.5 Belize Telecom (Belize) private no no no 48.7 state yes no no 27.4 CTC (Chile) private yes yes yes 27.4 ENTEL-Chile (Chile) private yes yes yes 22.9 SPT (Czech Republic) yes yes yes 18.9 state yes no no 9.6 GUATEL (Guatemala) state yes yes yes 43.9 private yes no no 24.1 MTNL (India) state yes yes no VSNL (India) state no n.a. n.a. PT Telekomunikasi (Indonesia) state yes no no Cable & Wireless (Jamaica) private yes no no Korea Telecom (Korea) state yes yes Telekom Malaysia (Malaysia) state yes yes TELMEX (Mexico) private yes Telefonica del Peru private yes 33.4 e pl m 21.2 28.5 yes 31.4 12.4 yes 31.7 yes yes 37.7 yes yes 32.0 Sa pt MATAV (Hungary) er private EMETEL (Ecuador) ch a BTC (Bulgaria) The material is for promotional purposes only. No authorised printing or duplication is permitted. (c) McGraw-Hill Australia 304 Part 3 jac98674_ch11_292-319.indd 304 The economics of markets 17/06/11 1:39 AM FIRM (COUNTRY) TPSA (Poland) OWNERSHIP/ CONTROL* private MOBILE TELEPHONE SERVICES yes LOCAL TELEPONE SERVICES yes LONGDISTANCE TELEPHONE SERVICES ROS (%) yes 11.0 ROMTEL (Romania) private yes no no 6.4 CANTV (Venezuela) private yes yes yes 15.3 * as of 2000/2001. Source: Table 2 (p. 227) and Appendix (p. 240) in Viani, Bruno E 2004, ‘Private Control, Competition, and the Performance of Telephone Firms in Less Developed Countries’, International Journal of the Economics of Business, Vol. 11, No. 2, July 2004, pp. 217–40. QUESTIONS 1. Prepare two tables. In each you should calculate the average return and range of returns for the telephone companies in the above table. The first table should contain data by presence (or absence) of competition, the second information by form of ownership. 2. Are companies with greater monopoloy power in segments of the telecommunications market more or less profitable on average than those that face greater competition? Do your findings fit with your expectations? 3. Prepare another table. In this table you should calculate the average return for the telephone companies in the above table split first by form of ownership then by the presence (or absence) of competition in given market segments. 4. Of the four groups of companies that you identified in question 3, which is the most profitable? Can you provide reasons for this result? What other factors beside monopoly power will influence proitability in any market? 5. For the privately controlled companies in the above table does monopoly power offer large benefits? er ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF MONOPOLY e PRICE, OUTPUT AND EFFICIENCY ch a • price, output and efficiency • the distribution of income • some difficulties involved in making cost comparisons between competitive and monopolistic firms • technological advance. pt We now evaluate pure monopoly from the standpoint of society as a whole. Our emphasis will be on: Sa m pl In Chapter 10 we concluded that perfect competition would result in both ‘productive efficiency’ and ‘allocative efficiency’. Productive efficiency is realised because the free entry and exit of firms would force firms to operate at the optimum rate of output where unit costs of production would be at a minimum. Further, competitive equilibrium would also entail allocative efficiency; production would occur up to the point at which price (the measure of a product’s marginal benefit to society) equals marginal cost (the measure of the alternative products forgone by society in the production of any given commodity). The material is for promotional purposes only. No authorised printing or duplication is permitted. (c) McGraw-Hill Australia Pure monopoly jac98674_ch11_292-319.indd 305 Chapter 11 305 17/06/11 1:39 AM PRODUCTIVE AND ALLOCATIVE INEFFICIENCY Figure 11.5 indicates that–given the same costs–a pure monopoly firm will produce far less desirable results. The pure monopolist will maximise profits by producing an output of Q m and charging a price of Pm. At Q m units of output, it is clear that product price is considerably greater than marginal cost. This means that society values additional units of this monopolised product more highly than it does the alternative products that resources could otherwise produce. In other words, the monopolist’s profit-maximising output results in an underallocation of resources. The monopolist finds it profitable to restrict output and therefore employ fewer resources than are justified from society’s standpoint. Further, the monopolist will not tend to be pushed to produce the minimum average cost output, thus contradicting our concept of productive efficiency. Finally, the monopolist will find it profitable to sell a smaller output and to charge a higher price than would a competitive industry. Does monopoly lead to smaller output? In Figure 11.5, we start with the perfectly competitive industry of Figure 10.7(b). The competitive industry’s supply curve SS is the horizontal sum of the marginal cost curves of all the firms in the industry. Comparing this with industry demand DD, we obtain the purely competitive price and output of Pc and Q c. Now suppose that this industry becomes a pure monopoly as a result of a wholesale merger (or one firm buying out all its competitors). Assume that no changes in costs or market demand result from this dramatic change in the industry’s structure. What was formerly, say, 100 competing firms is now a pure monopolist consisting of 100 branch plants. The industry supply curve is now simply the marginal cost curve of the monopolist, the summation of the MC curves of its many branch plants. The important change, however, is on the market demand side. From the viewpoint of each individual competitive firm, price was given, and marginal revenue was therefore equal to price. Each firm equated MC to MR (and therefore to P) in maximising profits (see Chapter 10). But industry demand and individual demand are the same to the pure monopolist–the firm is the industry, and thus the monopolist correctly envisions a down-sloping demand curve DD. This means that marginal revenue MR will be less than price; graphically, the MR curve lies below the demand curve. In choosing the profit-maximising MC ⫽ MR position, the monopolist selects an output Q m which is smaller and a price Pm which is greater than if the industry were organised competitively. INCOME DISTRIBUTION Business monopoly tends to contribute to inequality in the distribution of income. Because of their market power, monopolists charge a higher price than would a perfectly competitive industry with the same er FIGURE 11.5 MONOPOLY AND INDUSTRY EQUILIBRIUM D pt P ch a S Pm pl e ⌺MCs Pc D Sa MR m S Q 0 Qm Qc The material is for promotional purposes only. No authorised printing or duplication is permitted. (c) McGraw-Hill Australia 306 Part 3 jac98674_ch11_292-319.indd 306 The economics of markets 17/06/11 1:39 AM costs. In effect monopolists are able to levy a ‘private tax’ on consumers and realise substantial economic profits. It should be noted that these monopolistic profits are not widely distributed because company share ownership is largely concentrated in the hands of upper income groups. The owners of monopolistic enterprises therefore tend to accummulate wealth at the expense of the rest of society. COST COMPLICATIONS Our evaluation of pure monopoly has led us to conclude that–given identical costs–a purely monopolistic firm will find it profitable to charge a higher price, produce a smaller output, and foster an allocation of economic resources inferior to that of a perfectly competitive firm. These contrasting results are founded on the barriers to entry that characterise monopoly. Now we must recognise that costs may not be the same for purely competitive and monopolistic producers. Unit costs incurred by a monopolist may be either larger or smaller than those facing a perfectly competitive firm. Several potentially conflicting considerations are involved: • economies of scale • the notion of ‘X-inefficiency’ • the ‘very long run’ perspective that allows for technological advance. We examine the first two issues here. (Technological advance is covered in the next section.) ECONOMIES OF SCALE REVISITED We have assumed that the unit costs available to the perfectly competitive and the purely monopolistic firm are the same–but this may not be true in practice. Given production techniques and, therefore, production costs, consumer demand may not be sufficient to support a large number of competing firms producing at an output that permits each of them to realise all existing economies of scale. In such instances a firm must be large in relation to the market–that is, it must be monopolistic–to produce efficiently (at low unit cost). This is the natural monopoly case discussed earlier. Most economists feel that the natural monopoly (or public utilities) case is not significant enough to undermine our general conclusions concerning the restrictive nature of monopoly. Evidence suggests that the giant companies that populate many manufacturing industries now have more monopoly power than we can justify merely on the grounds of existing economies of scale. X-INEFFICIENCY ch a pt er X-inefficiency the failure to produce any given output at the lowest average (and total) cost possible. Sa m pl e Economies of scale may argue in favour of monopoly in a few cases. But the notion of X-inefficiency suggests that monopoly costs might be higher than those associated with more competitive industries. What is X-inefficiency? Does it adversely effect monopolists more than competitive firms? All the average cost curves used in this and other chapters are based on the assumption that the firm chooses the most efficient of the existing technologies. In other words, the firm chooses the technology that permits it to achieve the minimum average cost for each level of output (see Chapter 9). X-inefficiency is the notion that a firm’s actual costs of producing any output are greater than the minimum possible costs. Why does X-inefficiency occur when it obviously tends to reduce profits? The answer is that managers may often have goals–such as firm growth, an easier work life, the avoidance of business risk, providing jobs for incompetent friends and relatives–that conflict with cost minimisation. Or X-inefficiency may arise because a firm’s workers are poorly motivated. Or a firm may simply become lethargic and relatively inert. It may rely on past experience and reliable methods in decision making–as opposed to actively making relevant calculations of costs and revenues. For present purposes, the relevant question is whether monopolistic firms are more susceptible to X-inefficiency than are competitive producers. Presumably the answer is ‘yes’. Firms in competitive industries are continually under pressure from rivals, which theoretically forces them to be internally efficient as a matter of survival. But monopolists and oligopolists are sheltered from competitive forces, and such an environment is conducive to X-inefficiency. Empirical evidence on X-inefficiency is largely anecdotal and sketchy–but it does suggest that the smaller the amount of competition, the greater is X-inefficiency. The material is for promotional purposes only. No authorised printing or duplication is permitted. (c) McGraw-Hill Australia Pure monopoly jac98674_ch11_292-319.indd 307 Chapter 11 307 17/06/11 1:39 AM TECHNOLOGICAL ADVANCE: DYNAMIC EFFICIENCY Dynamic efficiency the ability to develop the most efficient production techniques over time. We have noted that our criticisms of monopoly must be qualified in those instances where existing massproduction economies may be lost if an industry comprises a large number of small, competing firms. Now we consider the issue of dynamic efficiency–which focuses on the question of whether monopolists are more likely to develop more efficient production techniques over time than are competitive firms. Are monopolists more likely to improve productive technology–thus lowering (shifting downwards) their average cost curves–than are competitive producers? We will concentrate on changes in productive techniques but the same question applies to product improvement. Do monopolists have greater means and incentives to improve their products and thus improve consumer satisfaction? This is a discussion that allows great scope for valid differences of opinion. THE COMPETITIVE MODEL Competitive firms certainly have the incentive–a market mandate–to use the most efficient known productive techniques. Their very survival depends on their efficiency. But competition deprives firms of economic profit–an important means and a major incentive for developing new products and improving production techniques. The profits of technological advance will be short-lived to the innovating competitor. An innovating firm in a competitive industry will find that its many rivals will soon duplicate or imitate any technological advance it may achieve. Rivals will share the rewards but not the costs of successful technological research. ch a pt In contrast, thanks to entry barriers, a monopolist may persistently realise substantial economic profits. Thus, the pure monopolist will have greater financial resources for technological advance than will competitive firms. But what about the monopolist’s incentives for technological advance? It is not easy to anser this question. There is one persuasive argument that suggests that the monopolist’s incentives to develop new products and new techniques will be weak. The absence of competitors means that there is no automatic stimulus to technological advance in a monopolised market. Due to its sheltered market position, the pure monopolist can afford to be inefficient and lethargic. The keen rivalry of a competitive market penalises the inefficient–but an inefficient monopolist does not face this penalty because it has no rivals. The monopolist has every reason to become satisfied with the advantages and to become complacent. It may benefit the monopolist to delay technological improvements in both product and production techniques in order to exploit existing capital equipment fully. New and improved products and techniques, may be suppressed by monopolists to avoid losses caused by sudden obsolescence of existing machinery and equipment. And, when improved techniques are later introduced by monopolists, the accompanying cost reductions will accrue to the monopolist as increases in profits–and only partially to consumers in the form of lower prices and an increased output. Proponents of this view state that in some industries which approximate the pure monopoly model, the interest in research has been minimal. Instead, many advances have come largely from outside the industry or from the smaller firms that make up the ‘competitive fringe’ of the industry–that is, the ‘competitive’ firms just outside the monopoly. Basically, there are at least two counter-arguments: er THE MONOPOLY MODEL • Technological advance lowers unit costs and so expands profits. As our analysis of Figure 11.2 implies, Sa m pl e lower costs will lead to a profit-maximising position that involves a larger output and a lower price than previously. Any expansion of profits will not be of a transitory nature; barriers to entry protect the monopolist from profit encroachment by rivals. In brief, technological progress is profitable to the monopolist. • Research and technological advance may be one of the monopolist’s barriers to entry. Thus, the monopolist must persist and succeed in the area of technological advance–or eventually they will be successfully challenged by new competitors (including those overseas). Technological advance, it is argued, is essential to the maintenance of monopoly. The material is for promotional purposes only. No authorised printing or duplication is permitted. (c) McGraw-Hill Australia 308 Part 3 jac98674_ch11_292-319.indd 308 The economics of markets 17/06/11 1:39 AM A MIXED PICTURE How can we generalise on the economic efficiency of perfect monopoly? • In a static economy, where economies of scale are equally accessible to perfectly competitive and to monopolist firms, perfect competition will be superior to pure monopoly–because pure competition compels the use of the best known technology and allocates resources to meet society’s wants. • Where economies of scale are available to the monopolist and unavailable to small competitive producers–and when changes in the rate of technological advance are important–this gives the monopolist a great advatage. Subsequently, the inefficiencies of pure monopoly are mostly not apparent. Variations between industries are likely to be significant. Learning objective Checkpoint 11.4 • Given the same costs, the pure monopolist will find it profitable to restrict output and charge a higher price than will a competitive industry. This restriction of output causes allocative inefficiency. This is evidenced by the fact that price exceeds marginal cost in monopolised markets. Production inefficiency is also a likely feature of monopoly due to the lack of incentive to produce at minimum average cost. • Monopoly tends to increase income inequality, due to concentration of the payment of economic profits to a few individuals. • The costs of monopolists and a competitive industry may not be the same. The ability to exploit economies of scale may reduce per-unit costs for the monopolist; however, X-inefficiency–a failure to produce any output level at the lowest average or total cost–may increase them. • Economists disagree about the degree to which pure monopoly is conducive to technological advance. Some feel that pure monopoly is more progressive than pure competition because its ability to realise economic profits provides the financing of technological research. Others argue that the absence of rival firms and the monopolist’s desire to exploit fully existing capital facilities weaken the monopolist’s incentive to innovate. pt e CONDITIONS Price discrimination when a given product is sold at more than one price and the price differences are not justified by cost differences. ch a So far we have assumed that the monopolist charges a uniform price to all buyers. Under certain conditions, the monopolist might be able to exploit its market position more fully by charging different prices to different buyers. In doing this, the seller is engaging in price discrimination. This occurs when a given product is sold at more than one price and the price differences are not justified by cost differences. er PRICE DISCRIMINATION pl The opportunity to engage in price discrimination is not available to all sellers. Price discrimination is workable when three conditions are realised: that is, some ability to control output and price. m • Monopoly power: The seller must be a monopolist or, at least, possess some degree of monopoly power– Sa • Market segmentation: The seller must be able to segregate buyers into separate classes where each group has a different willingness or ability to pay for the product. This separation of buyers is usually based on different elasticities of demand (as later illustrations will make clear). The material is for promotional purposes only. No authorised printing or duplication is permitted. (c) McGraw-Hill Australia Pure monopoly jac98674_ch11_292-319.indd 309 Chapter 11 309 17/06/11 1:39 AM • No resale: The original purchaser cannot resell the product or service. If those who buy in the low-price segment of the market can easily resell in the high-price segment, the resulting increase in supply would lower price in the high-price segment. The price discrimination policy would be undermined. This correctly suggests that service industries–such as the transport industry or legal and medical services, where resale is not possible–are especially susceptible to price discrimination. ILLUSTRATIONS Price discrimination is widely practised in our economy. The sales representative who must communicate important information to company headquarters has a highly inelastic demand for long-distance telephone service and pays the high daytime rate. The relative who has moved interstate and makes a periodic long distance call to ‘home’ has an elastic demand and defers the call to take advantage of lower evening or weekend rates. Electricity and gas utilities could segment their markets by end uses, such as lighting and heating. The absence of reasonable substitutes means that the demand for electricity for illumination is inelastic and the price per kilowatt hour for this use is high. But the availability of natural gas and petroleum as alternatives to electric heating makes the demand for electricity relatively elastic for this purpose, and the price charged could be lower. Similarly, industrial users of electricity may be charged lower rates than residential users because the former may have the alternative of constructing their own generating equipment whereas the individual household does not. Cinemas and golf courses vary their charges on the basis of time (higher rates in the evening and on weekends when demand is strong) and age (ability to pay). Railways may vary the rate charged per tonne of freight according to the market value of the product being shipped. The shipper of 10 000 kilograms of television sets or costume jewellery will be charged more than the shipper of 10 000 kilograms of gravel or coal. Doctors and lawyers may set their fees for a given service on the basis of ability to pay–so a rich person may pay a higher fee for a divorce or an appendectomy than a poor person. A manufacturer might sell the same brandy at a high price under a prestige label but at a lower price under a different label. Airlines charge high fares to travelling executives, whose demand for travel tends to be less elastic–but offer a variety of lower fares such as student rates and ‘standby fares’ to attract holiday makers and others whose demands are more elastic. CONSEQUENCES There are two economic consequences of price discrimination: pt discriminating monopolist. er • A monopolist will be able to increase its profits by practising price discrimination. • Other things being equal, a discriminating monopolist will produce a larger output than will a non- ch a MORE PROFITS Sa m pl e The simplest way to understand why price discrimination can yield additional profits is to look again at our monopolist’s dowward-sloping demand curve in Figure 11.2. Although the profit-maximising uniform price is $122, the segment of the demand curve lying above the profit area in Figure 11.2 tells us that there are buyers of the product who would be willing to pay more than Pm ($122) rather than go without the product (there is consumer surplus present for each of these consumers). If the monopolist can identify and segregate each of these buyers and so charge the maximum price each would pay–extracting this consumer surplus–the sale of any given level of output will be more profitable. In columns 1 and 2 of Table 11.1 we note that the buyers of the first 4 units of output would be willing to pay more than the equilibrium price of $122. If the seller could somehow practise perfect price discrimination by extracting the maximum price each buyer would pay, total revenue would increase from $610 (⫽ $122 ⫻ $5) to $710 (⫽ $122 ⫹ $132 ⫹ $142 ⫹ $152 ⫹ $162) and profits would increase from $140 (⫽ $610 – $470) to $240 (⫽ $710 – $470). The material is for promotional purposes only. No authorised printing or duplication is permitted. (c) McGraw-Hill Australia 310 Part 3 jac98674_ch11_292-319.indd 310 The economics of markets 17/06/11 1:39 AM MORE PRODUCTION Other things being equal, the discriminating monopolist will choose to produce a larger output than will the non-discriminating monopolist. Recall that when the non-discriminating monopolist lowers price to sell additional output, the lower price will apply not only to the additional sales, but also to all prior units of output. As a result, marginal revenue is less than price and, graphically, the marginal revenue curve lies below the demand curve. The fact that marginal revenue is less than price is a disincentive to increase production. But when a perfectly discriminating monopolist lowers price, the reduced price applies only to the additional unit sold and not to prior units. Thus, price and marginal revenue are equal for any unit of output. Graphically, the perfectly discriminating monopolist’s marginal revenue curve will coincide with its demand curve, and the disincentive to increase production will be removed. Refer to Table 11.1, and imagine that marginal revenue now equals price. Now the monopolist will find that it is profitable to produce 7, rather than 5, units of output. The additional revenue from the sixth and seventh units is $214 (⫽ $112 ⫹ $102). Thus total revenue for 7 units is $924 (⫽ $710 ⫹ $214). Total cost for 7 units is $640, so profits are $284. Learning objective Checkpoint 11.4 • Price discrimination occurs when a given product is sold at more than one price to different sections of the community and these price differences cannot be justified through the presence of cost differences. • Price discrimination requires three conditions to be met–monopoly power, market segmentation and no resale of the product. The monopolist can segregate buyers on the basis of their different elasticities of demand, charging higher prices to those with more inelastic demand–provided that the product cannot be readily transferred between the segmented markets. • Price discrimination allows the monopoly to extract greater profit from consumers, and will usually lead to higher levels of output. • Under perfect discriminating monopoly, the output of the monopoly will be the same as that of the purely competitive firm, because the demand and marginal revenue curves will coincide. pt ch a Sa SOCIALLY OPTIMUM PRICE: P ⫽ MC m pl e Historically, many purely monopolistic industries in Australia have been either directly operated by federal or state boards or commissions–railways, telephone, gas, electricity and water supplies–or have a degree of regulation exercised by government over their monopolies (as is the case with private monopolies). Figure 11.6 shows the demand and cost conditions of a natural monopoly. Because of heavy fixed costs, demand cuts the average cost curve at the point where average cost is still falling. It would be inefficient to have many firms in such an industry because–by dividing the market–each firm would move further to the left on its average cost curve so that unit costs would be substantially higher. The relationship between market demand and costs is such that the attainment of low unit costs presumes only one producer. We know that Pm and Q m are the profit-maximising price and output the unregulated monopolist would choose, following the MR ⫽ MC rule. Because price exceeds average total cost at Q m, the monopolist enjoys a substantial economic profit. Further, price exceeds marginal cost, which indicates an underallocation of resources to this product or service. Can government production or regulation bring about better results from society’s point of view? er THE ECONOMIC REGULATION OF MONOPOLY If the objective of our regulatory commission is to achieve an efficient allocation of resources, it could attempt to establish a legal (ceiling) price for the monopolist that is equal to marginal cost. Remembering The material is for promotional purposes only. No authorised printing or duplication is permitted. (c) McGraw-Hill Australia Pure monopoly jac98674_ch11_292-319.indd 311 Chapter 11 311 17/06/11 1:39 AM FIGURE 11.6 REGULATED MONOPOLY Price and unit costs ($) Pm F Pf ATC MR 0 MC R Pr Qm D Qf Qr Quantity pt ch a ‘FAIR-RETURN’ PRICE: P ⴝ AC But the socially optimum price Pr is likely to pose a problem of losses for the regulated firm. The price that equals marginal cost may be so low that average total costs are not covered (see Figure 11.6). The inevitable result is losses. The reason for this lies in the basic character of public utilities. Because they are required to meet ‘peak’ demands (both daily and seasonally) for their product or service, they tend to have substantial excess production capacity when demand is relatively ‘normal’. This high level of investment in capital facilities means that unit costs of production are likely to decline over a wide range of output. In technical terms, the market demand curve in Figure 11.6 cuts marginal cost at a point to the left of the intersection of marginal cost and average total cost. Thus, the socially optimum price is necessarily below ATC. Therefore, to enforce a socially optimum price on the regulated monopolist would mean short-run losses, and, in the long run, bankruptcy for the utility. Sa m pl e socially optimum price the price that achieves allocative efficiency (P ⫽ MC). that each point on the market demand curve designates a price–quantity combination, and noting that marginal cost cuts the demand curve only at point R, we find that Pr is the only price that is equal to marginal cost. The imposition of this maximum or ceiling price causes the monopolist’s effective demand curve to become PrRD. Demand curve is perfectly elastic on the first section of the demand curve, and Pr ⫽ MR up to the point R, where the regulated price ceases to be effective. The important point is that–given the legal price Pr–the monopolist will now maximise profits by producing Q r units of output, because it is at this output that MR (⫽ Pr) ⫽ MC. By making it illegal to charge more than Pr per unit, the regulatory agency has eliminated the monopolist’s incentive to restrict output in order to benefit from a higher price. In brief, by imposing the legal price Pr and letting the monopolist choose its profit-maximising output, the allocative results of pure competition can be simulated. Production takes place where Pr ⫽ MC, and this equality indicates an efficient allocation of resources to this product or service.2 The price that achieves allocative efficiency is called the socially optimum price. er Price regulation can improve the social consequences of a natural monopoly. The socially optimum price Pr will result in an efficient allocation of resources, but is likely to entail losses and therefore call for permanent public subsidies. The ‘fair-return’ price Pf will allow the monopolist to break even, but will not fully correct the underallocation of resources. The material is for promotional purposes only. No authorised printing or duplication is permitted. (c) McGraw-Hill Australia 312 Part 3 jac98674_ch11_292-319.indd 312 The economics of markets 17/06/11 1:39 AM What to do? One option would be a public subsidy sufficient to cover the loss the socially optimal price could create. Another possibility would be to condone price discrimination in the hope that the additional revenue gained would permit the firm to cover costs. A third option would be to establish what is known as a ‘fair-return’ price. Remembering that total costs include a normal, or ‘fair’, profit, we see that the ‘fair’ or ‘fair-return’ price in Figure 11.4 would be Pf, where price equals average cost. Because the demand curve cuts average cost only at point F, it is clear that Pf is the only price that permits a fair return. The corresponding output at regulated price Pf will be Q f and normal profit will be realised. ‘fair-return’ price the price that equals average cost (P ⫽ AC). DILEMMA OF REGULATION A comparison of results of the socially optimal price (P ⫽ MC) and the fair-return price (P ⫽ AC) suggests a policy dilemma sometimes known as the dilemma of regulation. When price is set to achieve the most efficient allocation of resources (P ⫽ MC), the regulated utility is likely to suffer losses. Survival of the firm would presumably depend on permanent public subsidies out of tax revenues. On the other hand, although a fair-return price (P ⫽ AC) allows the monopolist to cover costs, it only partially resolves the underallocation of resources the unregulated monopoly would foster–that is, the fair-return price would increase output only from Q m to Q f, whereas the socially optimum output is Qr. Despite this problem, the basic point is that regulation can improve on the results of monopoly from the social point of view. Price regulation can simultaneously reduce price, increase output and reduce the economic profits of monopolies. dilemma of regulation the choice of whether to use taxation revenue to subsidise the monopoly’s fixed costs under marginal cost pricing (P ⫽ MC), or to accept a lower than socially optimal output under ‘fair-return’ pricing (P ⫽ AC). Learning objective Checkpoint 11.5 • Price regulation can be used to eliminate, wholly or partially, the tendency of monopolists to Sa m pl e ch a pt er underallocate resources and to earn economic profits. Price regulation usually comes in two forms: socially optimum pricing and ‘fair-return’ pricing. • Under socially optimum pricing, the government sets a ceiling price equal to marginal cost. The profit-maximising choice for the monopoly is then to set output at the point where P ⫽ MC. • Under ‘fair-return’ pricing, the government sets a price equal to average cost, allowing the monopolist to achieve normal profit on investment. • The dilemma implied by regulation of monopoly involves the choice of whether to subsidise the monopoly’s fixed costs from taxation revenue under marginal cost pricing, or to accept a lower than socially optimal output under ‘fair-return’ pricing. The material is for promotional purposes only. No authorised printing or duplication is permitted. (c) McGraw-Hill Australia Pure monopoly jac98674_ch11_292-319.indd 313 Chapter 11 313 17/06/11 1:39 AM 6. 7. 8. 9. 10. 11. 12. 13. 14. 15. pt 5. m 17. Sa 16. pl e Summary 4. ch a 3. monopoly, the ownership or control of essential raw materials, patent ownership and research and licences. Economies of scale imply that production requires substantial investment and operation at high levels of output to achieve low-cost production. Natural monopolies provide extreme examples of this type of entry barrier. The ownership or control of essential raw materials may preclude competitors from acquiring the necessary inputs or processes required to provide substitute products and therefore to compete against the monopolist in the market. Patent ownership and research and licences are legal barriers to entry and provide the owner with exclusive rights to use an idea, process or technology over a specified time. The argument for this form of protection against competition is that it allows the firm to recoup its investment in the research and development required for bringing the product to market. Barriers to entry help to explain the existence not only of pure monopoly but also of other imperfectly competitive market structures. Barriers to entry that are very formidable in the short run may prove to be surmountable in the long run due to technological and regulatory changes over time. Like the competitive seller, the pure monopolist will maximise profits by following the marginal rule– that is, by equating marginal revenue and marginal cost (MR ⫽ MC) and choosing to produce at that output level, which then determines price. Because marginal cost is positive, the monopolist will always prefer to choose a price–output combination in the elastic range of the demand curve. As there is only one optimum price–output combination, the monopoly seller faces a supply point, but not a supply curve in the sense seen under pure competition. Because the monopolist faces a down-sloping demand curve, P ⬎ MC at equilibrium. Barriers to entry may permit a monopolist to choose price–output combinations that provide economic profits even in the long run. The following misconceptions exist about monopoly pricing: (a) The monopolist charges the highest price possible. Rather, the monopolist charges a profitmaximising price. (b) The monopolist maximises profit per unit. The maximum total profit is sought by the monopolist and this rarely coincides with maximum unit profits. (c) The monopolist always generates economic profit. High costs and a weak demand may prevent the monopolist from realising any profit at all. The costs of monopolists and a competitive industry may not be the same. The ability to exploit economies of scale may reduce per-unit costs for the monopolist; however, X-inefficiency–a failure to produce any output level at the lowest average or total cost–may increase them. Economists disagree about the extent to which pure monopoly is conducive to technological advance. Some feel that pure monopoly is more progressive than pure competition because its ability to realise economic profits finances technological research. Others argue that the absence of rival firms and the monopolist’s desire to fully exploit existing capital facilities weaken the incentive to innovate. Given the same costs, the pure monopolist will find it profitable to restrict output and charge a higher price than would a competitive industry. This restriction of output causes allocative inefficiency, as evidenced by the fact that price exceeds marginal cost in monopolised markets. Productive inefficiency is also a likely feature of monopoly, due to the lack of incentive to produce at minimum average cost. This is especially likely in the presence of economies of scale. Monopoly tends to increase income inequality, due to concentration of the payment of economic profits to a few individuals. Price discrimination requires three conditions to be met: monopoly power, market segmentation, and no resale of the product. The monopolist can segregate buyers on the basis of their different elasticities of demand, charging higher prices to those with more inelastic demand, provided that the product cannot be readily transferred between the segmented markets. er 1. A pure monopolist is the sole producer of a product for which there are no close substitutes available. 2. Barriers to entry exist in a number of forms and include economies of scale, the presence of natural The material is for promotional purposes only. No authorised printing or duplication is permitted. (c) McGraw-Hill Australia 314 Part 3 jac98674_ch11_292-319.indd 314 The economics of markets 17/06/11 1:39 AM 18. Price discrimination allows the pure monopoly to extract greater profit from consumers than under standard monopoly. This will usually lead to higher output levels, due to the change in the relationship between the demand and marginal revenue curves under price discrimination. Under perfectly discriminating monopoly, the output of the monopoly will be the same as that of the perfectly competitive firm because the demand and marginal revenue curves coincide. 19. Price regulation can be used to eliminate, wholly or partially, the tendency of monopolists to underallocate resources and to earn economic profits. Price regulation comes in two main forms, socially optimum pricing and ‘fair-return’ pricing. 20. Under socially optimum pricing, the goverment sets a ceiling price equal to marginal cost. The profitmaximising choice for the monopoly then becomes to set output at the point where P ⫽ MC. Under ‘fair-return’ pricing, the government sets price equal to average cost, allowing the monopolist to achieve normal profit on investment. 21. The dilemma implied by regulation of monopoly involves a choice between a number of alternatives. The first is whether to subsidise a monopoly’s fixed costs from taxation revenue and to regulate for marginal cost pricing to provide a socially optimal output level. The second is to accept an output at a level lower than the level which is socially optimal and to use ‘fair-return’ pricing regulation. A third alternative is to allow price discrimination between segments of the community to encourage an increase in the monopoly’s output towards the socially optimum level. KEY TERMS AND CONCEPTS 313 294 309 293 2. (a) (b) 3. (a) (b) 4. (a) 6. 7. 8. 9. 10. 11. er 5. pt (b) Explain how each barrier can foster monopoly or oligopoly. Which barriers give rise to the presence of monopoly power that may be socially justifiable? Explain your reasoning. [11.1] How do the demand and marginal revenue curves faced by a purely monopolistic seller differ from those confronting a purely competitive firm? Why do they differ? What is the significance of the difference? [11.2] How does a monopolist determine its optimal output level? Explain why a monopolistic seller will not find itself in the inelastic range of its demand curve. [11.2, 11.3] Carefully contrast the social efficiency of output under perfect competition and pure monopoly. Tabulate your findings. (b) What do the differences between the two market structures imply for the achievement of efficiency? (Consider the two main definitions of efficiency.) [11.4] (a) What is X-inefficiency? (b) What are the reasons it exists? [11.4] ‘A monopoly may not be subject to pressures to develop new products or to innovate.’ Is this true? Explain. [11.4] Explain how a monopolist can use price discrimination to increase its profits. [11.2] (a) How do output and efficiency differ under pure monopoly and perfectly discriminating monopoly? (b) What is the key reason for this difference? [11.2, 11.4] What fallacies exist about the character and implications of monopoly pricing? [11.4] (a) Briefly describe the two main forms of price regulation for controlling monopoly. (b) In what areas do they differ in their outcomes? [11.4] What is the ‘dilemma of regulation’? [11.5] ch a 1. (a) Discuss the major barriers to entry in an industry. 312 307 e CONCEPTUAL QUESTIONS socially optimum price X-inefficiency pl fair-return price natural monopoly price discrimination pure monopoly m 294 313 308 294 Sa barriers to entry dilemma of regulation dynamic efficiency economies of scale The material is for promotional purposes only. No authorised printing or duplication is permitted. (c) McGraw-Hill Australia Pure monopoly jac98674_ch11_292-319.indd 315 Chapter 11 315 17/06/11 1:39 AM 1 2 5.50 3 5.00 4 4.50 5 4.00 6 3.50 7 3.00 8 2.50 9 3. Suppose a pure monopolist (Firm M) is faced with the demand schedule shown below and the same cost data as the competitive producers discussed in Analytical question 3 in Chapter 10. [11.2, 11.3] 4. Let’s say that Firm M in question 4 could engage in perfect price discrimination–that is, if it could charge each buyer the maximum acceptable price. [11.2, 11.3] (a) What would be the level of profits? (b) What would the level of output be? 5. Critically evaluate and explain: [11.3] (a) ‘Because they can control product price, monopolies are always assured of profitable production simply by charging the highest price consumers will pay.’ (b) ‘The pure monopolist seeks the output that will yield the greatest per-unit profit.’ (c) ‘An excess of price over marginal cost is the market’s way of signalling the need for more production of a product.’ (d) ‘The more profitable a firm, the greater its monopoly power.’ (e) ‘The monopolist has a price policy; the competitive producer hasn’t.’ (f) ‘With respect to resource allocation, the interests of the seller and of society coincide in a purely competitive market but conflict in a monopolised market.’ (g) ‘In a sense, the monopolist makes a profit for not producing. The monopolist produces profits more than it does goods.’ 6. Explain both verbally and graphically how price regulation may improve the performance of monopolies. Distinguish between ‘fair return’ and ‘socially optimum’ prices. [11.5] 7. Assume a monopolistic publisher agrees to pay an author 15 percent of the total revenue from text sales. Will the author and the publisher want to charge the same price for the text? Explain. [11.2] er 6.50 6.00 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 pt 0 100 83 71 63 55 48 42 37 33 29 MARGINAL REVENUE ($) ch a $7.00 QUANTITY DEMANDED (Q) QUANTITY DEMANDED e PRICE (P) PRICE ($) pl competitive firm and industry have the same unit costs. Contrast the two with respect to: (i) price (ii) output (iii) profits (iv) allocation of resources (v) impact on the distribution of income. (b) Both monopolists and competitive firms follow the MC ⫽ MR rule in maximising profits, so how do you account for the different results? Why factors cause their costs to be different? [11.3, 11.4] 2. Use the demand schedule that follows to calculate total revenue and marginal revenue at each quantity. [11.2] (a) Plot the demand, total-revenue, and marginal-revenue curves and explain the relationships between them. (b) Explain why the marginal revenue of the fourth unit of output is $3.50, even though its price is $5.00. Use Chapter 6’s total revenue test for price elasticity to designate the elastic and inelastic segments of your graphed demand curve. What generalization can you make regarding the relationship between marginal revenue and elasticity of demand? (c) Suppose the marginal cost of successive units of output were zero. What output would the profit-seeking firm produce? (d) use your analysis to explain why a monopolist would never produce in the inelastic region of demand. m 1. (a) Assume that a pure monopolist and a perfectly (a) Calculate marginal revenue and determine the profitmaximising price and output for this monopolist. (b) What is the level of profit? Verify your answer graphically. Sa ANALYTICAL QUESTIONS The material is for promotional purposes only. No authorised printing or duplication is permitted. (c) McGraw-Hill Australia 316 Part 3 jac98674_ch11_292-319.indd 316 The economics of markets 17/06/11 1:39 AM ENDNOTES Sydney Morning Herald, 20 March. 2. AAP 2011, ‘Supermarket chain Coles promises not to 3. 4. 5. 6. 7. 8. 9. 10. import bananas after Cyclone Yasi’, The Sunday Telegraph, 5 February, www.dailytelegraph.com.au/money/ supermarket-chain-coles-promises-not-to-import-bananasafter-cyclone-yasi/story-e6frezc0-1226000623280. Ainsworth, Michelle 2011, ‘Prices to go bananas’, Leader– Maroondah Mail, Melbourne, Australia, 8 February. Australian Bureau of Statistics, Australian Industry, 2008-09, Cat No. 8155.0. Australian Bureau of Statistics, Counts of Australian Businesses, including Entries and Exits, June 2007–June 2009, Cat No. 8165.0. Campion, Vicki, Stolz, Greg & Murray, David 2011, ‘Returning to pick up pieces–Fruit and veg set to go through the roof as yachtie’s relieved mates really go bananas’, Daily Telegraph, Sydney, Australia, 5 February. Hartsukyer, Luke 2011, ‘Cyclone Yasi’s devastation of banana crop is no excuse for allowing Filipino imports’, 4 February, www.lukehartsuyker.com.au/mediacentre/ mediareleases/2011/418-cyclone-yasis-devastation-ofbanana-crop-is-no-excuse-for-allowing-filipino-imports .html. Ife,Holly & Hudson, Phillip 2011, ‘Bananas rationed, prices climbing’, Herald Sun, Melbourne, Australia, 5 February. Statham, Larine 2011, ‘Science may save nation’s bananas’, The Advertiser, Adelaide, Australia, 9 February. Viani, Bruno E 2004, ‘Private Control, Competition, and the Performance of Telephone Firms in Less Developed Countries’, International Journal of the Economics of Business, Vol. 11, No. 2, July 2004, pp. 217–40. er (a) Conduct an Internet search to find recent information on this argument. On what bases has Microsoft been attacked? (b) Based on your study of monopoly and its sources, on what theoretical principles do you think critics of Microsoft based their cases? Are these arguments valid? 4. US pharmaceutical companies charge different prices for prescription drugs to buyers in different nations, depending on elasticity of demand and government-imposed price ceilings. Explain why these companies, for profit reasons, oppose laws allowing reimportation of drugs to the United States. [11.2, 11.5] 5. It has been proposed that natural monopolists should be allowed to determine their profit-maximizing outputs and prices and then government should tax their profits away and distribute them to consumers in proportion to their purchases from the monopoly. Is this proposal as socially desirable as requiring monopolists to equate price with marginal cost or average total cost? [11.4, 11.6] 1. AAP 2006, ‘Cyclone devastates Australia’s banana crop’, pt [11.3, 11.4] REFERENCES ch a compete for the dollars of consumers. Pure monopoly, therefore, does not exist.’ [11.1] (a) Do you agree? Detail your reasoning and the limits to your arguments (e.g. use Chapter 6’s concept of crossprice elasticity of demand in thinking about whether monopoly exists). (b) Does this make the study of monopoly redundant? 2. Price discrimination is frequently viewed as exploitation of the consumer. [11.2] (a) When is price discrimination considered socially desirable? (b) Provide five or more examples of price discrimination with which you are familiar? Discuss whether each is desirable or undesirable socially. (To find some examples, you may wish to examine the following sectors: public transport, telecommunications, electricity supply, retail services and education.) 3. Microsoft has often been accused of engaging in monopoly practices, yet it is only one of a number of Internet service providers and companies producing operating systems. e 1. ‘No firm is completely sheltered from rivals. All firms competition. With perfect competition, the entry or exit of firms guarantees that economic profits will be zero in the long run. But, with monopoly, barriers to entry prevent the competing away of profits by new firms. 2. Allocative efficiency is achieved, but productive efficiency would be achieved only by chance. In Figure 11.6, production at Q r is less than that associated with minimum average cost. For the larger (minimum cost) output to occur would require the demand curve DD to intersect MC exactly at the minimum point of ATC. pl DISCUSSION QUESTIONS Sa is less important under monopoly than under perfect m 1. The distinction between the short run and the long run The material is for promotional purposes only. No authorised printing or duplication is permitted. (c) McGraw-Hill Australia Pure monopoly jac98674_ch11_292-319.indd 317 Chapter 11 317 17/06/11 1:39 AM ECONOMICS IN REALITY Cyclone Yasi drives up banana prices ch a pt er In the wake of Cyclone Yasi, reverberations were felt as far away as Neutral Bay as shoppers at Woolworths found the price of bananas almost doubled in the same time it took the cyclone to cross land, rising from $3 per kg on Wednesday night just before the cyclone crossed the Qld border to $5.98 per kg on the following Friday morning. IGA specialist, Gary Groves, expects the price of bananas to increase further in coming weeks up to as high as $15 a kilo . . . The category five cyclone dealt the banana industry a huge blow, flattening 75% of the nation’s banana crops in far north Queensland. In Tully and Innisfail, two major banana growing areas, 95% of crops were damaged according to the Australia Banana Growers Council. 80% of crops were damaged in the Kennedy area. Cyclone Yasi also added further to the pain of Queensland banana growers, many of whom have only relatively recently recovered from Cyclone Larry in 2006, which destroyed fruit crops and left 4 400 out of work. There will almost certainly be some growers who do not have the resources to ride the storm out this time. However if there is any light from the shock of Cyclone Yasi it is that many growers received better advance warnings of the cyclone’s arrival and were at least able to harvest green crops before the cyclone arrived. Some growers cut down their banana crops before the cyclone arrived, as crops regrow much faster from being cut down, than being knocked over by the cyclone. James Dale, Director of Queensland University’s Technology Centre for Tropical Crops and Biocommodities, warned of the importance of having alternative multiple banana supplies in the aftermath of the disaster. Scientists are currently working on genetically modified banana plants which may also assist in ridding [the soil] of the soil-borne fungus that destroyed Northern Territory plantations. Following Cyclone Larry, some supermarkets imported frozen bananas from Asia however this proved a controversial decision as local growers were trying to re-establish their crops and the impost of additional import competition at that time was not welcomed by local growers because of its depressing effect on prices. Federal member for Cowper, Luke Hartsuyker, reacting to reports that Filipino banana growers were moving to access Australian markets in the wake of the disaster, said ‘Although there will be a short-term shortage of Australian bananas, we should be doing everything we can to get these farmers back in production. The risks associated with Filipino bananas are as relevant today as they were before Cyclone Yasi. It is essential that Australia remains free of exotic diseases such as Moko, Black Sigatoka and Freckle which are prevalent in Philippine bananas. Unless the Government stands behind the Australian banana industry, many growers may walk off their farms and not replant’. Supermarket giant Coles, [which was] selling bananas for $4.48 a kilo, recently announced it will not seek to import bananas to cover the expected shortage this time around and the Federal Government has also indicated it will not relax Australia’s strict quarantine laws, which would be of benefit to foreign growers. However, in the short term for consumers, price rises are immediate and expected to rise as much as $15 a kilo in the coming weeks. . . . Ritchies Supa IGA supermarkets had bananas on special for $1.99 kilo but customers were limited to buying 3 kilos. Consumers should be looking at local markets, which were among the cheapest places to buy bananas and other tropical fruit. Authorities have vowed to hold those retailers accountable who are [predatory, taking advantage of] the recent floods and cyclone Yasi in Northern Queensland. Sa m pl e Sources: AAP 2011, ‘Supermarket chain Coles promises not to import bananas after Cyclone Yasi’, The Sunday Telegraph, 5 February, www.dailytelegraph.com.au/ money/supermarket-chain-coles-promises-not-to-import-bananas-after-cyclone-yasi/story-e6frezc0-1226000623280; AAP 2006, ‘Cyclone devastates Australia’s banana crop’, Sydney Morning Herald, 20 March; Hartsukyer, Luke 2011, ‘Cyclone Yasi’s devastation of banana crop is no excuse for allowing Filipino imports’, 4 February, www. lukehartsuyker.com.au/mediacentre/mediareleases/2011/418-cyclone-yasis-devastation-of-banana-crop-is-no-excuse-for-allowing-filipino-imports.html; Ife,Holly & Hudson, Phillip 2011, ‘Bananas rationed, prices climbing’, Herald Sun, Melbourne, Australia, 5 February; Campion, Vicki, Stolz, Greg & Murray, David 2011, ‘Returning to pick up pieces–Fruit and veg set to go through the roof as yachtie’s relieved mates really go bananas’, Daily Telegraph, Sydney, Australia, 5 February; Statham, Larine 2011, ‘Science may save nation’s bananas’, The Advertiser, Adelaide, Australia, 9 February; Ainsworth, Michelle 2011, ‘Prices to go bananas’, Leader–Maroondah Mail, Melbourne, Australia, 8 February. The material is for promotional purposes only. No authorised printing or duplication is permitted. (c) McGraw-Hill Australia 318 Part 3 jac98674_ch11_292-319.indd 318 The economics of markets 17/06/11 1:39 AM Questions Sa m pl e ch a pt er 1. What market structure most appropriately describes the banana growing industry? 2. Explain and illustrate what the likely short run effect of the cyclone is on the cost curves of a banana growing firm in the cyclone affected region? 3. Explain and illustrate using the perfect competition model what the likely short run effect of the cyclone is on the profits and quantities produced by banana growing firm in the cyclone affected region 4. What is the long term response in the Industry to the existence of economic losses, economic profits or normal profit? How will the changes from Q.2 and Q.3 affect the firm’s profit position in both the short run and long run? The material is for promotional purposes only. No authorised printing or duplication is permitted. (c) McGraw-Hill Australia Pure monopoly jac98674_ch11_292-319.indd 319 Chapter 11 319 17/06/11 1:39 AM
© Copyright 2024