Employability and Careers Centre International Careers Week 27 January – 31 January Postgraduate Study in the US with the Fulbright Commission Employability Skills for International Careers Paid Work Experience in the US with Parenthese International Talent Search with Universum Webinar International Volunteering Skills Talks Working in the UK after study Careers in EU Institutions and the Foreign and Open to all International, EU Commonwealth Office and home students Chinese CV Masterclass International Teaching book online atOpportunities www.essex.ac.uk/careers Get an exciting career using applied econometrics in advertising!! Wondering what career to pursue after your graduation? Ever considered Marketing Econometric Consulting? By 2015 marketers are forecast to spend $600bn globally. The multitude of channels available to advertise on generates tons of data, meaning big brands are looking for econometricians to give them the confidence to cut through the data and deliver invaluable insights for better decision making. If you have a degree in Economics, this is one of the most exciting times to work in advertising. To learn how you can use applied econometrics in the advertising world, join two University of Essex alumni on 5th February from 5pm in room 4.722. The two Essex Graduate presenters will be: Vaska Atta Darkua, Senior Analyst at Ohal Afo Babatunde, Project Manager at Ohal EC930 Theory of Industrial Organisation Week 3: Game Theory Review – Nash Equilibrium Product Differentiation I – Representative Consumer Models 2013-14, spring term Outline Review of Game Theory Nash Equilibrium – Cournot/Bertrand Subgame Perfect Nash Equilibrium -- Capacity Game/ Stackelberg Product Differentiation I: Representative Consumer Models Derivation of Demand/Basic Assumptions Cournot/Bertrand Equilibria Comparison Example 1: Exam Question Example 2: Unilever/Sara Lee Reading: Lecture notes 2 Problem Set 3: Q1, 2 Discussion and Support: Cabral ch 12, Tirole ch 7. (Game Theory Appendix) 4 Taxonomy of solution concepts Complete information Static game (normal form) Dynamic game (extensive form) Nash equilibrium Subgame perfect equilibrium E.g. Cournot competition; Public good provision E.g. Entry game; Capacity-building followed by pricing 5 Example of Nash equilibrium (1) “Prisoners’ dilemma” (payoffs: Andy, Bob) Bob Collude Defect Collude 2, 2 -1, 3 Defect 3, -1 1, 1 Andy Unique Nash equilibrium: (defect, defect) The Pareto dominant outcome (collude, collude) does not occur in equilibrium 6 Example of Nash equilibrium (1) Bertrand example (a=10, c=0, b=1 in earlier case) Firm 2 Firm 1 Collude Defect Collude 100/8, 100/8 0, 100/4 Defect 100/4, 0 0, 0 Nash equilibrium: (defect, defect) The Pareto dominant outcome (collude, collude) does not occur in equilibrium 7 Example of Nash equilibrium (1) Cournot example (a=10, c=0, b=1 in earlier case) Firm 2 Firm 1 Collude Defect Collude 100/8, 100/8 300/32, 900/64 Defect 900/64, 300/32 100/9,100/9 Nash equilibrium: (defect, defect) The Pareto dominant outcome (collude, collude) does not occur in equilibrium 8 Example of Nash equilibrium (2) “Battle of the sexes” Pat Chris Football Opera Football 2, 1 0, 0 Opera 0, 0 1, 2 2 Nash equilibria in pure strategies (football, football), (opera, opera) 9 Example of SPE Entry game Entrant enter stay out Incumbent fight fight accom (-1, -1) (1, 1) accom (2, 0) (2, 0) 10 Example of SPE Entry game Fight incumbent Accom Entrant Enter Stay Out -1, -1 2, 0 1, 1 2, 0 Payoffs: (incumbent, entrant) 2 NE: (enter, accom), (stay out, fight) One of these seems more reasonable than other, though. 11 Example of SPE Entry game Entrant enter stay out Incumbent fight fight accom (-1, -1) (1, 1) accom (2, 0) (2, 0) 2 NE: (enter, accom), (stay out, fight) Latter involves incredible threat and is not a SPE Only (enter, accom) is SPE 12 Example of SPE Stackelberg game: Incumbent chooses output…then entrant reacts to maximise profit. We solve this backwards: first, we obtain the best response to any output chosen by the incumbent…then we choose the best output for the incumbent, knowing what will follow. Q4 (2012 exam): P = 1-Q, MC = 0; 2 firms, homogeneous products. a. Firms choose quantities simultaneously. Obtain Nash equilibrium quantities/profits b. Firm A commits to quantity before firm B. Obtain subgame perfect Nash equilibrium. Are firms better/worse off than in (a)? c. Firm A chooses, but does not commit before B. What is the SPNE now? 13 Example of SPE Capacity/price game: Firms first choose capacities simultaneously…then firms then choose price to maximise profit simultaneously. We solve this backwards: first, we obtain the best response to any price chosen by the rival for any capacity level… then we choose the best capacity, knowing what will follow. 14 Product Differentiation (horizontal) Recall: At same price, some of both/all products purchased. Representative Consumer Models: Each consumer buys a single variety, all consumers have the same preferences (we model the “typical” consumer). Address Models: Each consumer buys a single variety, consumers differ (we model brand positioning in characteristics space). Eg: consumer products (shampoo, deodorant, toothpaste…) breakfast cereals petrol stations pubs 15 Product Differentiation – Representative Consumer Models (Singh/Vives Rand, 84) U = V(𝑞1 , 𝑞2 ) + 𝑦 𝑉 𝑞1 , 𝑞2 𝑏 𝑏 2 = 𝑎𝑞1 + 𝑎𝑞2 − (𝑞1 ) − (𝑞2 )2 − 𝑑𝑞1 𝑞2 2 2 y is “numeraire” good, sold in competitive sector. Consumer problem: Max U w.r.t. 𝑞1 , 𝑞2 ,y s.t. budget constraint, I = pq+y. Substituting the constraint: Max 𝑉 𝑞 + 𝐼 − 𝑝𝑞 , 𝑏𝑢𝑡 𝑎𝑠 𝐼 𝑖𝑠 𝑗𝑢𝑠𝑡 𝑐𝑜𝑛𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑡, ↔ 𝑀𝑎𝑥(𝑉 𝑞 − 𝑝𝑞) So V’ = p is the FOC (so that the problem is separable into q and p maximisation) All income effects concentrated into y. 16 Product Differentiation – Representative Consumer Models Consumer problem: Max V - [𝑝1 𝑞1 + 𝑝2 𝑞2 ] = CS 𝑏 2 𝑏 2 Max w.r.t 𝑞1 , 𝑞2 : 𝑎𝑞1 + 𝑎𝑞2 − (𝑞1 )2 − (𝑞2 )2 − 𝑑𝑞1 𝑞2 − 𝑝1 𝑞1 − 𝑝2 𝑞2 𝑃1 = 𝑎 − 𝑏𝑞1 − 𝑑𝑞2 𝑃2 = 𝑎 − 𝑏𝑞2 − 𝑑𝑞1 b>d usually assumed, all parameters positive. (b=d, d=0 special cases) will need some other parameter restrictions to ensure all prices, quantities remain positive. d < 0 means complementary. Note that demand slopes down in own price but shifts in/out/not at all depending on whether goods are substitutes, complements or independent. usually, 𝑑2 𝑏2 (ranging from 0 to 1) is used to express degree of homogeneity 17 Product Differentiation – Representative Consumer Models Firm Behaviour: Cournot, with constant marginal cost: firm 1: Max w. r. t. 𝑞1 : 𝑞1 (𝑝1 -c) 𝑞1 (𝑎 − 𝑐 − 𝑏𝑞1 − 𝑑𝑞2 ) FOC: 𝑎 − 𝑐 − 2𝑏𝑞1 − 𝑑𝑞2 = 0 𝑎−𝑐 𝑑 − 𝑞2 2𝑏 2𝑏 𝑎−𝑐 𝑑 − 𝑞1 2𝑏 2𝑏 𝑞1 = 𝑞2 = These are the reaction/best response functions. Reaction functions slope down as in homogeneous goods case. 18 Product Differentiation – Representative Consumer Models Cournot Equilibrium: 𝑞1 = 𝑎−𝑐 2𝑏+𝑑 = 𝑞2 Notice that if d = b, we have solution for homogeneous products, if d=0, we have solution for monopoly (independent goods in two separate markets) as d moves from 0 to b, we gradually increase each output as the markets meld. Little has changed, then, as diagrams look the same and a parameter moves us smoothly from two separate markets into a single integrated market. Notice that we can model (imperfect) complements with this method as well. 19 Product Differentiation – Representative Consumer Models Bertrand Equilibrium: Use same utility function and hence, same demands. Solve for quantity as a function of price: 𝑎(𝑏−𝑑) 𝑏 𝑑 − 𝑝 + 𝑝 𝑏2 −𝑑 2 𝑏2 −𝑑 2 1 𝑏2 −𝑑 2 2 𝑎(𝑏−𝑑) 𝑏 𝑑 𝑞2 = 2 2 − 2 2 𝑝2 + 2 2 𝑝1 𝑏 −𝑑 𝑏 −𝑑 𝑏 −𝑑 𝑞1 = Or…𝑞1 =∝ −𝛽𝑝1 + 𝛾𝑝2 𝑞2 =∝ −𝛽𝑝2 + 𝛾𝑝1 So that as the price of good 2 rises, the quantity of good 1 consumed increases …since they are substitutes. Notice that b>d still holds and ensures that these are positive parameters. 20 Product Differentiation – Representative Consumer Models Bertrand Equilibrium: Max (𝑝1 − 𝑐)𝑞1 𝑤. 𝑟. 𝑡. 𝑝1 max (𝑝1 − 𝑐)(𝛼 − 𝛽𝑝1 + 𝛾𝑝2 ) 𝛼+𝑐𝛽 𝛾 + 𝑝2 2𝛽 2𝛽 𝛼+𝑐𝛽 𝛾 𝑝2 = + 𝑝1 2𝛽 2𝛽 𝑝1 = These are upwards sloping reaction functions for d>0! In other words, as the price of good 2 rises, the price of good 1 rises as well. why? 21 Product Differentiation – Representative Consumer Models Marginal revenue (for linear demand case): 𝑀𝑅1 = 𝑝1 + 𝑞1 𝑝1 , 𝑝2 𝑑𝑝1 𝑑𝑞1 When 𝑝2 falls, this decreases 𝑞1 , so that for same 𝑝1 the second term of marginal revenue falls, (ie, if you make fewer sales, then the effect of an decrease in price on those “inframarginal” sales falls). This raises marginal revenue in total, increasing the incentive to increase sales (so that 𝑝1 should fall). 22 𝑝2 Reaction function of firm 1 • Reaction function of firm 2 equilibrium 𝛼+𝑐𝛽 2𝛽 𝛾 2𝛽 𝛼 + 𝑐𝛽 2𝛽 𝑝1 23 𝑝2 Reaction function of firm 1 Reaction function of firm 2 Profit rises p Profit increases along reaction function 𝑝1 24 Solving for equilibrium: 𝑝1 = 𝑝2 = 𝛼 + 𝑐𝛽 2𝛽 − 𝛾 And this exceeds marginal cost for 𝛼 > 𝛽 − 𝛾, which is equivalent to a>1 in the original model. Differentiation increases market power. In fact, as d increases, equilibrium prices fall towards marginal cost. Note that when d=0, we have monopoly pricing. When d approaches b, the solution approaches the homogeneous case. As in Cournot, we can also model imperfect complements with this method. 25 Comparing the two, for substitutes, Bertrand prices lower and quantities higher in equilibrium than Cournot, and consumer surplus higher in Bertrand (except where markets independent, where all these are equal) Profits lower in Bertrand than Cournot. Opposite holds for complements case. So what if firms can choose which they compete in (p or q)? Think of a two stage game: Firms non-cooperatively choose whether they compete in p or q Firms compete non-cooperatively, as above. If the goods are substitutes, it is a dominant strategy to select Cournot (compete on quantities), whereas if the goods are complements, it is a dominant strategy to compete in prices. 26 Firm 2 Price Price Quantity Bertrand Pr PQ Firm 1 Quantity Pr QP Cournot And PR QP > Bertrand Profit; Cournot profit > Pr PQ Why? A Bertrand firm raises price against a rival assumed to keep (lower) price fixed raising price cuts sales a lot. A Cournot firm assumes, implicitly, that rival will raise price when I do in order to keep sales constant raising price cuts sales much less. 27 How to interpret this result and this model? Not clear that firms “choose” which game they are in or strategic variable: this may be determined by technology of industry. Not clear that representative consumer model is a good representation of reality, as it assumes all products compete with each other equally In most markets, some substitutes are closer than others. For this, we would need a different type of model… 28 Example: Exam question (2012) Let demands for two firms, w and p, be: Dw(Pw, Pp) = ½ + (Pp-Pw) Dp(Pw, Pp) = ½ + (Pw-Pp) And marginal cost is constant at c 1. Derive the Bertrand equilibrium prices and profits Using our earlier notation: = 1/2 = = (substitutes -- only price difference “counts”) Substituting into our expression, we obtain symmetric reaction functions: 1 Pp = 4𝜇 + 𝑃𝑤 +𝑐 2 1 𝑐 (𝑎𝑛𝑑 𝑎𝑛𝑎𝑙𝑜𝑔𝑜𝑢𝑠 𝑓𝑜𝑟 𝑃𝑤 ) so slope upwards with intercept 4𝜇 + 2 1 And equilibrium prices are obtained by solving simultaneously: P*=2𝜇 + 𝑐 1 1 1 So that profits are: (P*-c)q* = (2𝜇)(2) = 4𝜇. 29 2. Let = 1= c. Now, suppose that at a cost of K = .3, W could obtain = 1/2 . Would it pay to make this investment? 1 Profit before = 4𝜇 = ¼. 1 1 Profit after = 4𝜇 = 2 . Net profit after = ½ - K = .2 Net profit after less than profit before, so don’t invest. If the two firms share the cost equally, does the answer change? Yes, since a cost of .15 means that net profit after = .35, which exceeds profit before (for both firms). Exercise: re-calculate your answers if = 1/(2t). (question 5a, 2012 exam) 30 Example: Unilever acquisition of Sara Lee Sara Lee Unilever EC concerned about effect in market for deodorants 31 Example: Unilever acquisition of Sara Lee Main relevant brands: Sara Lee – Sanex Deodorant Unilever – Rexona, Dove Deodorants Various formats (stick, roll on, spray) gender appeal (male, female, unisex) health appeal (skin-friendly, “no comment”) National markets Differentiated product within national markets. Market share of combined Sara Lee/Unilever brands = 35-70%, depending on national market. 4-5 other competitors in general. 32 Nested logit model using customer panels, switching analysis: deodorants Single nested model male Sub-nest non-male Skin-friendly outside good No comment Individual products 33 Nested logit used to estimate demands for the goods, including own and cross price elasticities. Merger simulation then conducted, removing Sara Lee as a separate firm in a Bertrand, differentiated product model. Find approximately 5% price increase, with higher effect in non-male segment. Compensating efficiencies in wide range depending on country (5-25%) Remedy: require divestment of Sanex brand 34 Critique: Much of the model is reasonable: Nested logit assumes same elasticities (cross and own) within categories. While nesting is somewhat arbitrary, good checks used beforehand. Statistical testing of nesting is possible, but only eliminates models: cannot identify a single “best” nest (and did not in this case). Clearly, parties choose “best for them”. The acquisition was based on expected development (growth) of market, not on static effects – but modelling purely static. In other words, not only is competition static in Bertrand model, but no changes in demand parameters occur over time in this simulation – only ownership of brands changes (number of firms decreases by 1). Results indicated a 40% price rise for Sara Lee brand in static model: but acquisition was specifically for the purpose of growing the brand! Final decision was the Unilever abandoned the acquisition, as the remedy completely eliminated the original reason for the acquisition. 35 Summary: Nash equilibrium and Subgame Perfect Nash Equilibrium are flexible concepts to be used to characterise games of the type we have discussed until now. Cournot, Bertrand – examples of Prisoner’s Dilemma class Stackelberg, Capacity Choice – examples of SPNE (Horizontal) Differentiation: Representative Consumer Model Works well for goods where a “typical” consumer choosing among a set of goods that are equally substitutable is a good description of reality. These are static models so miss any dynamics 36
© Copyright 2024