6 Preferential trade agreements AND MULTILATERAL

PTAPD_121-142.qxd:inte_001-028_ch01 7/5/11 12:20 PM Page 121
6
Preferential trade
agreements AND
MULTILATERAL
LIBERALIZATION
Richard Baldwin and Caroline Freund
With the Doha Round of trade negotiations ailing, the
future of multilateral liberalization in the near term looks
bleak. By contrast, preferential trade agreements (PTAs)
continue to multiply (see Acharya et al., ch. 2 in this volume), making regionalism the most active mode of trade
liberalization. The regionalization of trade is of serious
concern to many international economists who view multilateralism as far superior to regionalism for improving
welfare. At issue is the preferential nature of regional agreements, which could divert trade and reduce the potential
for future multilateral liberalization.
The multilateralists argue that, although regionalism may
increase trade, its effects on welfare and on the world trade
system are likely to be harmful. There are two main concerns.1 The first is trade diversion: preferential trade agreements, by diverting trade away from the most efficient global
producers in favor of regional partners, may prove welfare
reducing. The second concern, which is of greater importance, is that regionalism may hinder multilateralism, leading to a bad equilibrium in which several regional trade
blocs maintain high external trade barriers. Regionalism can
also undermine multilateralism simply by diverting limited
government resources from multilateral negotiations.
These two concerns are related: in a highly regionalized
world, there is likely to be significant trade diversion and
hence lower welfare. Still, this feature of the bad equilibrium
makes it less likely in practice. It is precisely because the
trade diversion is costly to bloc members that there is an
incentive to reduce external tariffs. As tariffs fall, trade
diversion disappears, and regionalism becomes a force for
general liberalization. Thus, despite the potential for a grim
outcome from high-tariff regional blocs and for large
amounts of trade diversion, the theoretical literature shows
that incentives to reduce external trade barriers so as to
limit costly diversion are likely to be present.2 The nascent
empirical literature is tackling the question of how trade
liberalization has been affected by the formation of PTAs.
Although the verdict is not yet in, the evidence indicates
that regionalism is broadly liberalizing.
This chapter summarizes the available theoretical and
empirical evidence on the relationship between regionalism
and multilateralism, with the aim of discerning whether the
spread of regionalism is likely to be a threat to, or an opportunity for, broader trade liberalization. The next section
identifies the distortions that generate a need for regional
and multilateral trade agreements. There follows an
overview of the available theoretical work on whether
regionalism constitutes a stumbling block or a building
block on the path to trade liberalization. The effect of
regionalism on world welfare is then examined, the empirical literature is surveyed, and conclusions are drawn.
Reciprocal Trade Agreements
If there is one thing economists agree on, it is that free
trade is best. Why, then, do we need trade agreements to
lower tariffs? In fact, although global free trade may be
good for world welfare, countries nevertheless have reasons
to maintain tariffs. There ensues a prisoner’s dilemma:
each country may be unilaterally better off with a tariff, but
jointly they are worse off. Cooperation through a trade
agreement is necessary to liberalize trade.
121
PTAPD_121-142.qxd:inte_001-028_ch01 7/5/11 12:20 PM Page 122
122
Richard Baldwin and Caroline Freund
Countries have tariffs for three main reasons. First,
terms-of-trade considerations may induce a country to use
tariffs to drive down the price of its imports relative to the
price of its exports, thus raising welfare for the nation as a
whole. For example, suppose a large country exports wine
and imports cheese. By placing a tariff on imported cheese,
the country increases domestic demand for wine relative to
cheese, and if the country is large enough, this practice
raises the world price of wine relative to cheese. If both the
importing and the exporting country impose tariffs, however, the relative world prices of wine and cheese remain
roughly unchanged, leaving consumers in both countries
worse off because domestic prices are distorted. Consumers in both countries are consuming more of the
domestic good than is ideal (given world prices), terms-oftrade gains do not materialize, and world welfare is
reduced.
Second, there may be political constraints. Tariffs can be
used as an internal redistribution tool by governments—
typically to shift income to some favored industry, region,
or group of voters or political contributors. For example,
many economies tend to protect steel because production is
commonly concentrated regionally and the workers and
firm owners tend to be politically organized. This combination of political organization and geographic concentration
often means that the sector’s concerns may receive much
greater weight in political decisions than would be suggested by its share of employment or output. Similarly, certain industries may receive special treatment if the owners
of capital are connected to the government. Protection
reduces consumer welfare, since consumers are forced to
pay more than the world price, but governments cannot
credibly commit to withholding protection of the special
sectors.3 In addition, protection may be in place because of
historical reasons and can be politically difficult to remove
because industry has adapted to it.
Third, countries, especially developing countries, may
rely on tariffs for a share of the tax revenue they need to
fund general government expenditures. Border transactions are an easy way to collect revenue when income tax
systems are weak. This motive tends to be more important
in developing countries, where other forms of revenue collection are difficult.
Reciprocal liberalization helps neutralize the first two
forces described above: terms-of-trade motivations are
neutralized, and joint welfare is higher because, with lower
tariffs, consumption patterns are less distorted. Reciprocity
in tariff cutting makes it easier to form a proliberalization
coalition because the political strength of the domestic
losses from tariff cutting can be balanced against the political strength of the exporters that gain from foreigners’
reciprocal tariff cutting. Moreover, once the agreement is
in place, the reciprocity can help lock in the reform—can
tie the government’s hands, so to speak—in a way that
helps governments resist special-interest pressures for
protection. Even if domestic consumers do not object to
new protection, the export interests of the foreign trade
partner will.
The third reason for tariffs, revenue generation, is
slightly different, as the government faces a loss of income
with no offsetting added source of revenues if tariffs are
reduced. Trade agreements with the World Trade Organization (WTO), or bilateral agreements with industrial
countries, therefore often include provisions to help countries adjust to revenue loss.
Both the WTO and PTAs allow countries to cooperate
and commit to reducing trade barriers, but there is an
important distinction between the two types of agreements.
In particular, PTAs go against the principle of nondiscrimination that is at the heart of the multilateral system. The
first article of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade
(GATT) concerns nondiscrimination, or most favored
nation (MFN) treatment. MFN means that every time a
country lowers a tariff, it has to offer the same treatment to
all its trading partners. The purpose of this clause is to prevent trade diversion and the cumbersome tariff structure
that would likely prevail in the absence of MFN.
By offering preferences to specific countries, PTAs
definitively violate MFN treatment. Yet they are allowed, in
part, because the MFN clause creates a free-rider problem.
MFN means that countries in the WTO must offer the
same tariff to all members. But if only a subset of members
agrees on significant tariff reduction, other members can
“free ride”—they get expanded market access without new
commitments. If all members participated equally in MFN
tariff reduction, PTAs might not be needed. PTAs enable
countries that want to pursue deeper trade liberalization to
evade the free-rider problem. Snape (1993) discusses the
history of GATT Article XXIV, which allows for an exception to nondiscrimination, and argues that this article is
vital for maintaining the multilateral club because some
members might opt out if it were not included. (In particular, the United Kingdom, which was the largest importer
at the time, insisted on keeping its Commonwealth preferences.) Summers (1991) asserts that all types of liberalization, whether unilateral, bilateral, or multilateral, are very
likely to be good and that regionalism gives governments a
way to maintain progress on liberalization.
This section has shown that reciprocal liberalization is
usually necessary for removal of barriers to international
trade. Although multilateral liberalization is preferable,
regional liberalization is ubiquitous and cannot be
PTAPD_121-142.qxd:inte_001-028_ch01 7/5/11 12:20 PM Page 123
Preferential Trade Agreements and Multilateral Liberalization
ignored. The key question is whether this advancement of
regionalism is broadly beneficial or detrimental to global
trade and welfare (see box 6.1). In the next section, we discuss the recent rise of regional liberalization and how, in
theory, it may affect the multilateral trade system.4
Stumbling Blocks and Building Blocks
From 1960 to the late 1980s, regionalism was a simple
matter. It was represented by the European Economic
Community (EEC), which encompassed a third of world
trade in a highly effective customs union, and by a slew of
PTAs among developing nations that covered a trivial
fraction of world trade and in any case never operated
effectively. The systemic implications of regionalism were
simply not an issue.
Regionalism became complicated in the late 1980s
when Canada and Mexico changed their minds about
regionalism (Krugman 1991b, 7).5 The United States had
long been interested in regional preferential trade, but
Canada and Mexico had resisted, fearing domination by
their giant neighbor. In 1985, Canada proposed a free
trade agreement (FTA) with the United States that
entered into force in 1989. In 1990, Mexico, too, proposed
an FTA with the United States. This initiative evolved into
the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) at
the insistence of Canada, which wished to safeguard its
Auto Pact arrangement with the United States for tarifffree trade in automobiles and parts. The U.S.–Mexico initiative triggered a wave of Latin American requests for
bilateral trade agreements with the United States and gave
greater urgency to arrangements among Latin American
Box 6.1. Is Bilateralism Bad?
Paul Krugman, in a series of papers published in 1991,
reframed the 1950s national welfare question as a globallevel question. Krugman (1991a) introduced a new
approach by asking whether the spread of regionalism
raises or lowers world welfare. This discussion spawned a
decade-long literature and continues to influence research
even today. The “is bilateralism bad?” literature—also
known as multilateralism versus regionalism literature—
looks distinctly odd from today’s perspective in that it tries
to use simple theory to answer what is intrinsically a
complicated empirical question. At the time, however, it
was the best that economists could do; they had limited
access to the necessary data and lacked the panel
econometric techniques to exploit them. Moreover,
spreading regionalism was at the time more of a threat
than a reality, so there was little experience to support
empirical tests. Baldwin (2009) offers a full discussion of
the issue.
123
countries, most notably members of the Southern Cone
Common Market (Mercosur, Mercado Común del Sur).6
The rise of North American regionalism coincided with
two other major developments in the world trade system.
First, GATT negotiations lurched from crisis to crisis in the
late 1980s and then seemed to die with the acrimonious
collapse of the Uruguay Round’s “final” summit in December 1990. Second, European regionalism was reignited by
the Single European Act and the collapse of the Soviet
Union.
Many respected thinkers looked at this temporal correlation and saw causality. They feared that the spread of
regionalism might kill the world trade system. These fears
are easy to understand. Two-thirds of world imports went
to North America and Europe; 40 percent of this total was
intrabloc trade that was soon to be covered by discriminatory liberalization schemes. Still more worrisome, North
American and European countries were the stalwarts of the
GATT system. If regionalism weakened their support of
multilateralism, the GATT was indeed in deep trouble.
Spreading regionalism had become much more than a
small-think “should I join?” question.
These fears promoted regionalism to a prominence on
the world’s policy agenda that it had not enjoyed since the
1950s. The shift naturally attracted paradigm-setting efforts
by the profession’s leading international economists.
Krugman (1991b) is clearest in rejecting the relevance
of the 1950s small-think approach, which focused on static
welfare issues and delineating the outlines of a new line of
inquiry—what we call big-think regionalism:
In a fundamental sense, the issue of the desirability of free
trade areas is a question of political economy rather than
of economics proper. While one could argue against the
formation of free trade areas purely on the grounds that
they might produce trade diversion . . . the real objection is
a political judgment: fear that regional deals will undermine the delicate balance of interests that supports the
GATT. (Krugman 1991b, 14–15)
Krugman’s framing of what he identified as the key
issue—the impact of regionalism on support for the GATT
system—did not catch on, however.7
The focus of this part of the discussion is on what we
consider to be the central theoretical question: does
regionalism help or hinder multilateralism? Ultimately,
this question is also empirical, but given the relative
paucity of experience with the regionalism-multilateralism
interface (only one multilateral trade negotiation has been
completed since 1991), convincing empirics is at an early
stage, with some tantalizing results just beginning to
emerge (see “Welfare Consequences of PTAs,” later in this
PTAPD_121-142.qxd:inte_001-028_ch01 7/5/11 12:20 PM Page 124
124
Richard Baldwin and Caroline Freund
chapter). Moreover, given the complexity of the interlinkages, a clear theoretical understanding is a necessary condition for well-structured empirical work.
Are Regionalism and Multilateralism Friends or Foes?
Bhagwati, in The World Trading System at Risk (1991), does
not focus on regionalism. In the first part of the book, “The
GATT Architecture under Threat,” he lists regionalism as
one of four main threats. Nevertheless, his writing has
helped establish big-think regionalism as the new paradigm. In the first paragraph of his chapter on regionalism,
he writes, “These regional alignments have led to fears of
fragmentation of the world economy into trading blocs in
antithesis to GATT-wide multilateral free trade. Does such
regionalism truly constitute a threat to multilateralism?”
(Bhagwati 1991, 58). Although he does not set out an analytical framework for answering the question, his writing
influenced the intellectual paradigm for more than a
decade.
Theory requires explicit questions. Asking whether
regionalism and multilateralism are friends or foes is not
sufficient. Pure logic identifies three mutually compatible
ways that regionalism and multilateralism could interact:
• Regionalism could affect multilateralism.
• Multilateralism could affect regionalism.
• Both multilateralism and regionalism could be driven
by third factors.
The literature has looked at all three ways of framing
the issue, but the first has dominated since Krugman
(1991b, 1996) presented a simple analytical framework for
posing the question. His explicit question was, How does
an exogenous variation in regionalism (specifically, the
formation of a new PTA) affect nations’ incentives to cut
tariffs multilaterally? Although most of the literature has
followed Krugman’s lead in asking how exogenous variations in regionalism affect multilateralism, authors have
also discussed the specific effect of PTAs on multilateral
trade negotiations (MTNs); the deeper forces driving
PTAs and MTNs (Summers’ notion that all the “isms” are
good); and the effect of multilateralism on regionalism.
These are discussed below.
Three Kinds of Stumbling Block Logic
In its cleanest form, the stumbling block logic asserts that if
the stumbling block PTAs were forbidden, global free trade
would be achieved, but that since they are permitted, global
free trade becomes impossible. Weaker forms of this thesis
are put forward in the help-or-hinder literature (for example, PTAs may slow the achievement of global free trade),
but the desire for clarity has led the profession to focus on
the strong form.
In our opinion, only three forms of stumbling block
logic are currently relevant to real-world policy analysis:
the preference-erosion (exploitation), goodies-bag, and
cherry-picking variants. (Many more will undoubtedly be
illuminated in coming years.) For simplicity’s sake, these
possibilities are demonstrated under the naïve but transparent assumption that national governments choose tariffs to maximize national welfare.
Preference erosion, or exploitation. Starting from a world
in which all nations have MFN tariffs, the question is
whether some group of nations can raise its collective welfare above the free trade level by forming a trade bloc and
thus exploiting other nations. If the answer is “yes,” that
bloc is a stumbling block on the road to multilateral free
trade because the members would veto global free trade as
undermining their exploitation of third nations.
In trade models, the answer is almost always “yes,” but
the answer may depend on the level of MFN tariffs when
the bloc is formed.8 Given Smith’s certitude (briefly, that all
parties to a preferential trade arrangement benefit) and
Haberler’s spillover (postulating that third nations must
lose from such an arrangement), some combination of
nations is bound to be better able to exploit third nations
by acting as a bloc. This is almost trivially true if the bloc
can violate its WTO tariff bindings by raising external tariffs. After all, the bloc as a whole has more buying power
than its constituents do individually, so it can better exploit
foreigners. Less obvious, but equally true, is that stumbling
blocks can be found even when external tariffs are maintained (as has been the case for all the major postwar
PTAs).
Consider the simple model presented in chapter 3 of
this volume, with three symmetrical countries (Home,
Partner, and Rest of the World, or RoW) and three goods.
Home imports Good 1 and exports Good 2 to Partner;
Partner imports Good 2 and exports Good 1 to Home; and
Rest of the World exports Goods 1 and 2 to Home and
Partner, respectively, and imports Good 3 from both (see
figure 3.1, in ch. 3). The first welfare theorem tells us that
global free trade is efficiency enhancing (a move to the first
best), and symmetry ensures that each nation receives an
equal slice of the gains.
This conclusion, however, can be reversed when we start
from the situation in which Home and Partner have
formed a PTA by eliminating tariffs among them. Taking
the PTA as the base case, a move to global free trade eliminates the preference margin (P' – PFT) that Home exporters
PTAPD_121-142.qxd:inte_001-028_ch01 7/5/11 12:20 PM Page 125
Preferential Trade Agreements and Multilateral Liberalization
Figure 6.1. Net Welfare Effects, Preferential Trade
Agreement to Global Free Trade
border price
P'
PFT
Figure 6.2. Relationship between MFN Tariffs and Home
Welfare
internal price
C2'
XS
125
home welfare
P
A'
global free trade
0.60
C1'
C1'
D'
0.59
B'
P–T
P' – T
MD
0.58
0.57
stumbling block tariffs
exports
XR'
imports
0.56
MFN
PTA
Source: Author’s elaboration.
0
enjoyed in Partner, thereby leading to a terms-of-trade loss
of area C1' and a trade-volume loss of C2' (figure 6.1, lefthand panel).
On the import side, because of lower internal prices,
from P' to PFT, global free trade would win Home an additional trade volume gain of area A', a terms-of-trade
improvement with respect to Partner exporters of area C1',
and a terms-of-trade loss on imports from RoW, shown as
area B' (right-hand panel). Global free trade would also
improve Home exporters’ market access to RoW, and this
would boost Home welfare by area D'. Overall, the net welfare change of moving from the PTA to global free trade
is – C2' – B' + D' + A'; the sign of this is ambiguous.
It is straightforward to show that, in a simple model
with linear demand, a low MFN tariff and a PTA with zero
internal tariffs generate gains for the trade partners that
exceed those from free trade. (This is shown in figure 3.2,
in ch. 3; see Baldwin 2009, box 4, for further details of the
model.) Figure 6.2 presents the Home welfare levels for different values of the MFN tariff.
For initial MFN tariff levels that are sufficiently low, we
see that Home’s welfare is higher with the PTA than it is
with global free trade, even though Home would have
agreed to global free trade starting from the initial situation without the PTA. (The line marked MFN is completely below the line marked “global free trade,” but the
PTA line is above the global free trade line for sufficiently
low tariffs.)
Intuitively, the PTA allows Home to exploit RoW both
on the import side (by pushing down the price it pays RoW
exporters of Good 1) and on the export side (by raising
the price in Partner at the expense of RoW exporters of
Good 2). The move to global free trade undoes these two
0.05
0.10
0.15
tariff (T)
0.20
0.25 MFN tariff
(MFN T)
Source: Author’s elaboration.
Note: Home welfare is plotted against the most favored nation (MFN) tariff
for three trade regimes: MFN (all nations impose the same MFN tariff T on
all goods); PTA (Home and Partner form a preferential trade agreement,
PTA); and global free trade, which is the MFN regime with T = 0. The
parameters chosen are a = 1, b = 1/2; the qualitative results are unaltered
for other choices of parameters. Note that T = 1/4 is the prohibitive tariff
with a = 1, b = 1/2. In ad valorem terms, the Viner crossing occurs at a
tariff of about 27 percent of the free trade price, and the ad valorem tariff
threshold for a stumbling block occurs at about 9 percent; the prohibitive
tariff is about 42 percent for these parameter values.
forms of exploitation, but in exchange, it provides better
access to the RoW market and more liberalization in
Home’s import market.
When the initial tariff T is low, the market access and
home liberalization gains are modest, and so the net effect
is negative. In other words, the basic logic of the stumbling
block result turns on the way that a PTA allows the PTA
partners to exploit excluded nations.
The model presented here is very special, but the heart
and soul of the stumbling block effect—the exploitation of
excluded nations—is a general result, and one that is surely
an important consideration in the real world.
The opposition of small developing nations—especially
those that benefit from European Union (EU) unilateral
preferences—to agricultural liberalization in the WTO
Doha negotiations is a classic example of the preferenceerosion stumbling block. Had the EU not unilaterally
granted preferences to these nations, they would probably
have been pushing for opening of the EU market in sugar
and other goods.
Goodies bag. The goodies-bag version follows closely the
fundamental economic logic of the preference-erosion
stumbling block.9 Briefly, the rents corresponding to
PTAPD_121-142.qxd:inte_001-028_ch01 7/5/11 12:20 PM Page 126
126
Richard Baldwin and Caroline Freund
Smith’s certitude can be thought of as a set of “goodies”
that can be used by one or both PTA parties to buy
noneconomic benefits from its partners. Because the size
of noneconomic benefits that can be “purchased” is linked
to the richness of the goodies bag—that is, the margin of
preferences—PTA members have an extra incentive to
maintain high margins of preference by avoiding multilateral liberalization. The goodies-bag logic, however,
extends to a far greater range of issues than the tariffs that
are the focus of the preference-erosion stumbling block. In
the case of a PTA between very large and very small
nations—a case that is extremely common in the new century (e.g., the United States and Costa Rica; Japan and
Singapore)—the large country’s interest in the PTA can
hardly be thought to be preferential market access.
The EU, for example, grants extensive preferences to its
members’ former colonies by using the justification of
international solidarity. In other words, the economic gains
to the EU’s partners count as a plus inside the EU because
they advance one of the EU’s noneconomic objectives—
fostering development. Similarly, but more explicitly, the
United States justifies many of its PTAs with small, poor
nations on the basis of noneconomic objectives, typically,
antidrug or antiterrorism policies.
The earlier discussion illustrated how the desire to safeguard rents created by a PTA could make a nation reject
global free trade when it would have embraced MFN free
trade without the PTA. The goodies-bag stumbling block
logic amplifies this mechanism by making both nations
interested in each other’s export rents—the area corresponding to C1' in figure 6.1, with the link operating through the
pursuit of noneconomic (in the narrow sense) objectives.
Cherry picking. An entirely distinct mechanism is at
work in the cherry-picking stumbling block.10 Assume
that the trading environment is marked by both intraindustry trade in differentiated products and interindustry
trade. In this world, trade liberalization will produce gains
from trade because of the variety effect in the differentiated product sectors (as in Helpman-Krugman models)
and because of comparative advantage effects. The comparative advantage gains, however, come bundled with
politically difficult effects on domestic factor prices, which
will be lower (e.g., lower wages).11 Now suppose that two
large nations have similar factor endowments. If they form
a trade bloc, they will win a large share of the variety gains
that would come with global free trade, and because of
their similarity, they will experience little pain from lower
factor prices.
Taking the trade bloc as the base case, the bloc members may find a move to global free trade unattractive. It
would entail a good deal of pain in terms of factor prices
and only a modest amount of additional variety or comparative advantage gains. Depending on parameters, especially the political power of the sufferers, the gains may
not be sufficient to make global free trade attractive to the
bloc members.
Building Block Logic
Whereas many trade policy scholars, including Krugman
(1991b) and Bhagwati (1991), worried that regionalism
was a stumbling block to global free trade, others, such as
Summers (1991) and Bergsten (1991), viewed regionalism
as a largely benign or even constructive force in the world
trade system.
Here, we consider the economic logic of the assertion
that PTAs can foster multilateral liberalization. There are
four main arguments in the literature. We begin with the
one that permeates the rationales used by countries that
simultaneously pursue regional and multilateral liberalization: the notion that preferential liberalization creates a
political-economy momentum that makes multilateral liberalization easier (and vice versa).
Juggernaut. According to the juggernaut building block
logic, liberalization begets liberalization. The logic comes
in two parts that are most easily explained in the context
of multilateral liberalization. When the GATT began in
1947, import duties were high worldwide, since they had
been set without international coordination during the
tariff wars named for the U.S. Smoot-Hawley Act. The tariffs balanced the supply of and demand for protection in
the “political market” of each nation separately. The main
demandeurs of import protection were import-competing
firms and the workers they employed. Government was
the supplier of protection, but concern for the country’s
general economic well-being meant that the government
would set the protection level below what was lobbied for
by special interests (the supply of protection being not
perfectly elastic).
Starting from this situation of uncoordinated tariff
setting, announcement of an MTN based on the principle of reciprocity alters the array of political forces inside
each participating nation. The central point is reciprocity, which converts each nation’s exporters from
bystanders in the tariff debate to antiprotectionists. For
exporters, lobbying against domestic tariffs becomes a
means of lowering foreign tariffs. Because the MTN
rearranges the political-economy forces inside each
nation, all governments find it politically optimal to
choose tariff levels that are lower than the unilaterally
optimal tariffs.12 This is the first part of the juggernaut
theory.13 The logic is not new.
PTAPD_121-142.qxd:inte_001-028_ch01 7/5/11 12:20 PM Page 127
Preferential Trade Agreements and Multilateral Liberalization
Informed observers have long known that the GATT’s
reciprocal MTNs mostly had to do with helping nations
internalize a political-economy externality inside their own
polities, making it easier for national politicians to put
together a national coalition in support of freer trade.
Writers such as Robert Baldwin (1970, 1985) and Destler
(1986) are explicit on this point, but historical accounts of
the Cobden-Chevalier Treaties show that the use of external trade deals to realign domestic political forces was very
much in the minds of nineteenth-century thinkers (Irwin
1996, 96). Even Krugman writes that “the process of multilateral negotiation . . . sets each country’s exporting interests as a counterweight to import-competing interests; as
trade negotiators bargain for access to each others’ markets, they move toward free trade despite their disregard for
the gains from trade as economists understand them”
(Krugman 1991b, 17).
The second part of the juggernaut logic concerns the
effects of the tariff cuts on openness. The cuts make all
nations more open: export sectors expand with the foreign
tariff cuts, and import-competing sectors contract with
domestic tariff cuts. Assuming that political influence is
linked to industry size, this economic relandscaping
strengthens proliberalization forces and weakens antiliberalization forces in all nations—although, of course, such
industrial restructuring takes years. In other words, the initial reciprocal tariff cuts start a liberalization juggernaut
rolling. Because of the economic relandscaping that occurs
during the phase-in of the initial tariff cuts, all governments find that their politically optimal tariff in the next
MTN is below the levels that they found politically optimal
during the previous MTN. These fresh tariff cuts continue
the relandscaping, and the juggernaut continues to roll forward. Once the liberalization juggernaut starts rolling, it
crushes all tariffs in its path.14
To the extent that regionalism can start the juggernaut
rolling, PTAs can serve as building blocks.15 The precise
mechanism is a simple extension of the juggernaut logic.
PTAs reconfigure members’ economies, making export
sectors larger and import-competing sectors smaller. Thus,
the PTA can alter the member governments’ stance toward
MFNs, making it politically optimal to cut MFN tariffs to
levels that would not have been politically optimal without
the PTA. Of course, if a PTA results in higher external tariffs (as in the case of the EU’s agriculture tariffs), then it
can start the juggernaut rolling backward.
The basic idea is presented in figure 6.3. The two curves,
FE (free entry) and GFOC (government first-order condition), show how the size of the import-competing sector
depends on the tariff (free entry) and how that tariff
depends on the size of the import-competing sector (n, for
127
Figure 6.3. Juggernaut Logic
tariff (T )
FE
Eo
To
GFOCunil
GFOCMFN
Efinal
size of importcompeting
sector, n
Source: Author’s elaboration of figure 4 from Baldwin 2006.
Note: FE, free entry; GFOC, government first-order condition; MFN,
most favored nation.
number of firms), via politics. The politically optimal
tariff choice, which takes as given the size of the importcompeting sector, is plotted as GFOCunil, the solution to
the government’s first-order condition without MTN. The
politically optimal tariff rises with n because the larger the
import-competing sector, the higher the political benefit
from a marginal increase in the tariff. The free entry curve,
FE, relates the equilibrium number of firms to the tariff. As
the tariff rises, more firms find it optimal to enter the market. These two relationships assume that the government
and firms are shortsighted and that the government chooses
T, taking n as given, while firms choose n, taking T as given.
Note that the figure only captures the size of anti-trade
forces; the size of the pro-trade export sector is suppressed
to avoid the need for a three-dimensional diagram.
To see the two steps of the juggernaut effect, note that
announcement of the MTN shifts the GFOC curve to
GFOCMTN. This curve is lower because the government finds
it politically optimal to set a lower tariff for any given level of
n when domestic protection is linked to foreign protection
via reciprocity. As drawn, the new long-run equilibrium
Efinal entails free trade, but since entry and exit occur slowly,
the tariff and the state of the import-competing industry do
not jump to Efinal. The figure illustrates one possible adjustment path. Each MTN results in an instantaneous drop in
the tariff, but slow entry and exit mean sluggish movement
of the state variable, as indicated by the horizontal arrows.
The juggernaut effect acts as a building block if the PTA
reduces the importance of import-competing industry in
governments’ objective functions. In many models, a PTA
between Home and Partner does reduce the size of the
PTAPD_121-142.qxd:inte_001-028_ch01 7/5/11 12:20 PM Page 128
128
Richard Baldwin and Caroline Freund
Home import-competing sector, and then PTAs would be
building blocks on the road to global free trade.
The FE curve in figure 6.3 was drawn for symmetric
MFN tariffs. When the PTA is signed, the FE curve rotates
inward, as shown in figure 6.4, because the additional competition from Partner producers lowers the Home price
facing import-competing firms, and some of them exit.
Consequently, the GFOC under reciprocal trade will yield a
lower MFN tariff after a PTA (point E2) than before (point
E1). Of course, if the PTA somehow increases protection of
the Home import-competing sector, the effect is reversed,
and the PTA acts as a stumbling block.16
Frankel and Wei momentum. Frankel and Wei (1998)
illustrate another juggernaut-like mechanism. In their
model, imperfect information makes workers uncertain as
to whether they will win or lose from global free trade. Since
a PTA is an intermediate form of liberalization, the authors
show that a PTA could be politically feasible even when
global free trade would not be. After the PTA is signed, the
nation’s true comparative advantage is revealed, and workers
now know whether they will win or lose from free trade. If
the parameters are chosen carefully, the certainty resolution
may mean that global free trade is politically feasible only
after the PTA. Thus, the PTA is a building block, and since it
operates by altering the political-economy landscape, it
can be thought of as a momentum-generating mechanism.
The juggernaut logic exploits the fact that nations do have
preferences about trade arrangements, in the way that individual consumers have preferences about consumption
Figure 6.4. Juggernaut Building Block Logic
tariff (T )
FE (with PTA)
FE
Eo
To
E1
GFOCunil
GFOCMFN
E2
size of importcompeting
sector, n
Source: Author’s elaboration of figure 4 from Baldwin 2006.
Note: FE, free entry; GFOC, government first-order condition; PTA,
preferential trade agreement.
bundles. The nature of the proposed trade deal can affect a
nation’s ranking of choices (unilateral versus reciprocal, for
example). These rankings, unlike the rankings of a standard
consumer, are path dependent because historical liberalization can affect the current political strength of various protrade and anti-trade special interest groups. A number of
building block arguments assume, however, that nations, like
consumers, have exogenous preferences about outcomes. We
next consider the easiest of these arguments, which assumes a
representative consumer and a government that acts to maximize the individual’s well-being.
Kemp-Wan theorem. The assertion that trade blocs may
be building blocks in a static world is as easy and as general
as the assertion that they may be stumbling blocks. Starting
from a world in which all nations have MFN tariffs, the
question is: can some group of nations always raise its collective welfare by forming a trade bloc? If the answer is
“yes,” then a piecemeal enlargement of the bloc will raise
bloc members’ well-being monotonically. Bloc members
attain the highest welfare when all nations are part of the
bloc. In this world, the formation of a single bloc should
trigger a domino effect that leads to worldwide free trade.
As seen in chapter 3, the Kemp-Wan theorem tells us
that the answer to the above question is always “yes” when
nations have access to international lump-sum transfers
(Kemp-Wan 1976) or to a complete set of commodity taxes
and subsidies (Dixit-Norman 1980). Kemp and Wan
(1976), in probably the first formal contribution to the
building block–stumbling block discussion, make exactly
this point. (See Aghion, Antràs, and Helpman 2007 for an
elaboration of the Kemp-Wan argument that uses modern
cooperative game theory concepts.)17
Although the Kemp-Wan building block logic is flawless,
it falls down in the face of the real-world problem that
nations do not have access to massive lump-sum transfers.
Indeed, the assumption that such international transfers are
a realistic possibility basically assumes away most of the
core difficulties facing the international trade system (and
international relations more broadly). Without international transfers, the logic of preference-erosion stumbling
blocks and cherry-picking stumbling blocks suggests that in
many blocs, some members would eventually veto some
enlargements.
Veto avoidance. The preference-erosion stumbling block
logic discussed above rests on the fact that bloc members
can veto the move to global free trade. The veto-avoidance
building block logic points out that, although bloc members can veto multilateral trade liberalization, they cannot
veto further PTAs that may eventually eliminate all tariffs
globally. The explosion in the number of PTAs among
small nations witnessed in the new century may very well
PTAPD_121-142.qxd:inte_001-028_ch01 7/5/11 12:20 PM Page 129
Preferential Trade Agreements and Multilateral Liberalization
be attributable to a combination of the juggernaut effect
and veto-avoidance logic.18
We start by considering the development of an extremely
common form of regionalism, hub-and-spoke PTAs. Here,
one partner (e.g., the United States, the EU, or India) has a
network of radial bilateral PTAs with some of its trading
partners, but these trading partners do not have PTAs with
each other. Simplicity dictates our continued use of the
symmetric framework shown in figure 3.2 in chapter 3, so
we arbitrarily bestow hub status on Home.
Roughly speaking, Home found the bilateral PTA with
Partner attractive because the improved market access for
Home exporters in Partner’s market more than outweighed the potential welfare losses from trade diversion in
Home’s import market. This suggests that Home might
also find a second bilateral PTA with RoW to be welfare
enhancing.19
As it turns out, in the PTA diagram framework, Home
always gains from signing a second PTA with RoW. Intuitively, the point is that Home gains the same preferential
market access as it did from the first PTA, and it undoes the
potentially harmful trade diversion by fully liberalizing its
import market. To see this in more detail, we reinterpret
figure 6.1. On the export side, Home’s second PTA wins its
preferential access to RoW’s market without giving up its
preferences in Partner; this has a net welfare value of areas
D' + C1' + C2' in the left-hand panel.20 On the import side,
the second PTA brings the price in Home’s market for
Good 1 to the global free trade level, PFT. The welfare
impact of this is the positive trade volume effect area A'
plus the conflicting terms-of-trade effects, areas –B' and +
C1'. (See Baldwin 2009, box 5, for a mathematical proof.)
Would RoW accept Home’s offer of a second PTA? As it
turns out, RoW gains from such a PTA as long as T is not
too high (see Baldwin 2009 for details). That is, the huband-spoke situation is better for RoW than the initially disadvantaged position, when it was excluded from the
Home-Partner PTA. On the export side, a PTA with Home
would improve RoW’s market access a great deal (its
export price would rise from the depressed level of P'– T to
the free trade price, PFT). The liberalization on the import
side would have the usual positive trade volume effect and
conflicting terms-of-trade effects, identical to those experienced by Home in its first PTA.
Plainly, Partner will be harmed by the formation of the
hub-and-spoke system around Home; its preferences in
Home are eroded, and it receives nothing in compensation.
Partner would thus like to veto Home’s second PTA, but
except in extraordinary circumstances, third nations cannot veto PTAs. The main exception is customs unions, but
functioning customs unions are quite rare in the modern
129
world. Customs unions require supranational decisionmaking capacity to keep all external tariffs in line in the
face of changes in antidumping duties; special unilateral
preferences to third nations, such as the generalized system
of preferences; and tariff changes in multilateral trade
talks. The groups of nations that manage such coordination are of just two types: the EU, and nations involved
in superhegemon relations (e.g., France and Monaco;
Switzerland and Liechtenstein; and the South African Customs Union). Given that the real world is covered with
hub-and-spoke trade arrangements, we assume henceforth
that Partner has no veto over Home’s PTA policy, and the
hub-and-spoke system is indeed set up.
The story, however, is not finished. As it turns out, the
two spokes may find a spoke-spoke PTA to be advantageous, and this would achieve global duty-free trade.
(Trade, however, would not necessarily be free because of
the exclusion of various sensitive sectors, rules of origin,
and cumulation.)
The hub-and-spoke PTA puts Home in an enviable
position, giving it the benefits of free trade for its imports
and preferential market access for all of its exporters. In
this sense, hub-and-spoke bilateralism might be thought of
as another example of the preference-erosion stumbling
block logic: Home would veto WTO talks aimed at achieving global free trade. This simple world, however, can
attain global duty-free trade without multilateral talks—a
PTA between Partner and RoW would do the job. So,
would Partner and RoW be interested in a PTA?
Taking hub-and-spoke bilateralism as the point of
departure, the spokes (in this case, Partner and RoW)
clearly have a very different view of global free trade than
does the hub. A move to global free trade would do nothing
to erode Partner’s preferences in Home, since those were
already eroded by Home’s second PTA. For Partner, the
shift to the global free trade regime would involve a standard exchange of market access with RoW; Partner would
see its export price to RoW rise from P' – T to PFT for
Good 3, and RoW would see a symmetric border price rise
for its exports of Good 2 to Partner (see figure 3.2) The
attendant liberalization of the two nations’ import markets would have the usual conflicting trade volume and
terms-of-trade effects, but overall, the two nations could
find the exchange to be welfare enhancing. In fact, Partner
and RoW would always prefer global free trade to the huband-spoke situation.
This is certainly not to be taken as a general result. It
does, however, illustrate how regionalism could be a building block in a world in which overall free trade would be in
the interest of all nations, but achievement of the goal is
blocked by nations that fear erosion of their preferences.
PTAPD_121-142.qxd:inte_001-028_ch01 7/5/11 12:20 PM Page 130
130
Richard Baldwin and Caroline Freund
Related Logics: Induced Liberalization and Protection
Before ending this review of the helps-or-hinders literature,
it should be useful to cover two economic mechanisms that
link PTAs and MFN tariffs without formally making the
connection with multilateral trade talks. Both consider the
impact of PTAs on a nation’s MFN stance in the absence of
a new MTN. The first mechanism links PTAs to unilateral
MFN liberalization; the second looks at how a PTA can
lower or raise a nation’s effective MFN tariff rate.
Unilateral liberalization. The building block logics
examined earlier directly address the issue of whether PTAs
help or hinder the attainment of global free trade. Here, we
look at a related but logically distinct question: what is the
impact of a PTA on the tariffs a nation would find unilaterally optimal to impose on third nations? Intuitively, the
question is whether preferential tariffs are complements to
or substitutes for MFN tariffs.21 The easiest way to organize
the various mechanisms is to start from the Meade (1955)
formula for the welfare impact of any trade policy change
in a Walrasian economy:
Net home welfare effect = (p – p*)dM – (M)dp*
(6.1)
where p and p* are the vectors of internal and border prices
(and p – p* = T, the tariff), M is the vector of bilateral
imports (exports are negative imports), and dM and dp*
are the vectors of changes in bilateral trade volumes and
border prices, respectively.
A nation choosing its bilateral tariffs optimally would
view this formula as a first-order condition and set it
to zero to find its optimal tariff. The optimal bilateral
tariffs are:
 dp* 
Tod = M od 

 dM od
(6.2)
where o indicates the origin nation and d the destination
nation (the nation choosing the tariffs). In general, anything can happen to Tod when the nation signs a free trade
agreement, because, according to the Slutsky equation, the
direct and cross-good income and substitution effects of the
PTA-induced price changes could raise or lower the righthand side of the equation (6.2). Real income is expanded
because the price of the preferential good fell, raising
demand and hence the optimal external tariff. However,
there is also substitution toward the low-cost preferential
good, reducing demand for other foreign goods and pushing the optimal external tariff down. Attempts to resolve the
inherent ambiguity have led to the emphasis on several economic mechanisms in the literature.
Preferential and MFN tariffs as complements. If the PTAinduced price changes have little impact on the equilibrium
slopes of the third-nation import supply curves, Tod is
likely to fall because PTAs typically reduce PTA members’
trade with third nations (Harberler’s spillover); that is, Mod
is likely to fall. For example, in the simple PTA diagram
model presented in figure 3.2 in ch. 3, the import supply
curves are linear, and so dp*/dM does not change with
preferential liberalization. However, Haberler’s spillover
effect lowers third-nation trade (Mod), and so Home’s optimal tariff on RoW exports falls.
Another mechanism that yields complementarity turns
on the general principle that taxes become more distortionary when the variance of rates across products
increases. This is termed the uniform tax rate principle,
and it is a feature of many economic models, especially
when administrative and enforcement considerations are
taken into account. It explains why most nations impose
fairly even indirect tax rates across products. Since the PTA
automatically makes the import tax structure more
uneven, there is some presumption that the PTA makes
the third-nation tariffs more distortionary. In models
where this is true, nations are likely to lower third-nation
tariffs when they reoptimize their trade tax structures. That
is, PTAs encourage nations to reduce applied MFN tariffs.
Preferential and MFN tariffs as substitutes. The most obvious mechanism that suggests the substitutes result (i.e.,
nations find it optimal to raise third-nation tariffs after
having signed a PTA) concerns the market power of the
new bloc. If the PTA allows PTA members to better coordinate their third-country tariffs, the members are likely to
raise external tariffs because they will have more purchasing
power than before. This effect is only likely to be relevant in
customs unions, where countries set tariffs jointly. Even so,
two fairly unrealistic assumptions are required: that the governments share sufficiently similar objective functions, and
that their external tariffs are not subject to WTO bindings (or
that they are willing to violate their WTO commitments).
Since most of the effective PTAs are among developed countries whose tariffs are almost universally bound at near-zero
levels (apart from a few low-volume items) and since such
countries rarely violate their WTO bindings, this mechanism
is probably of little real-world relevance except for a few commodities (agriculture before the Uruguay Round) and a few
low-trade-volume PTAs among developing countries.
Imported MFN liberalization and protection. A closely
related line of reasoning considers the automatic impact of
PTAs on the external protection of PTA members, when
members impose different tariffs on third countries. Under
some circumstances, the PTA effectively lowers the higher
MFN tariff (imported MFN liberalization); in other circumstances, the PTA effectively raises the lower MFN tariff
(imported MFN protection).22
PTAPD_121-142.qxd:inte_001-028_ch01 7/5/11 12:20 PM Page 131
Preferential Trade Agreements and Multilateral Liberalization
The feasibility of this outcome is established by noting
that the U.S. supply at Po is more than sufficient to cover
the entire Mexican import demand (point 2 is to the right
of point 1). Note that there is a secondary effect on world
prices as the United States expands its imports. The new
price is at the intersection of the dotted MD curve and the
XSRoW curve. For simplicity’s sake, this second-order
impact is not shown in the two leftmost panels.
If one combines this imported MFN liberalization with
the juggernaut logic, the PTA can eliminate all the firms in
Mexico that would otherwise have opposed MFN liberalization. That is, Mexican industry has no interest in lobbying for the maintenance of high Mexican MFN tariffs,
which provide no protection to Mexican industry. In the
case at hand, the Mexican government signed a vast array
of PTAs to exchange its now politically useless MFN tariffs
against preferential access for its exporters.
Since developed countries (the North) tend to have
much lower MFN tariffs on most manufactured goods
than developing countries (the South), the mechanism
suggests that an important implication of North-South
PTAs for the world trading system is their potential to
lower the southern country’s resistance to further liberalization. Given that most of the South does not participate
in MTN tariff-cutting exercises on the basis of reciprocity,
the North-South PTAs are one of the few ways of triggering
juggernaut effects in developing countries.
Rules of origin and imported MFN protection. The opposite result, in which a PTA imports MFN protection to a
country with low MFN tariffs, can occur when highly
restrictive rules of origin are imposed. The argument can
be illustrated with reference to NAFTA. Since the first U.S.
foray into regionalism, the 1965 U.S.–Canada Auto Pact,
U.S. and Canadian rules of origin on autos have been
A good example of imported MFN liberalization can be
found in North-South PTAs. The concept can be explained
intuitively with reference to Mexico’s experience. In 1994,
Mexico, along with Canada and the United States, formed
NAFTA, which phased in tariff cuts over 10 to 15 years.
Mexican MFN tariffs were (and still are) much higher than
U.S. and Canadian MFN tariffs, but as NAFTA brought
Mexican prices down to the U.S. internal level, domestic
prices in Mexico came to resemble those that Mexico would
have observed if it had lowered its MFN tariffs to U.S. levels.
To put it differently, the high Mexican MFN tariffs became
irrelevant because the same goods could be purchased from
the United States duty-free, and the U.S. internal price was
linked to the world price via its low MFN tariff (leaving
aside the small sectors still protected by high U.S. MFN tariffs, such as clothing, textiles, and footwear). In this sense,
Mexico ended up “importing” the low U.S. MFN tariffs.23
The argument can be illustrated more precisely by using
figure 6.5, which shows import demand by the United
States (left-hand panel), Mexico (middle panel), and the
world market for the good under consideration (right-hand
panel). The U.S. total supply curve is shown in Mexico’s
panel, for reasons that will become clear. The United States
initially imposes a zero tariff on imports from the rest of
the world, whereas Mexico imposes a tariff of TMX on
imports from both the United States and the rest of the
world. When Mexico eliminates duties on U.S. imports,
U.S.-made goods can enter Mexico duty-free. Since the
Mexican internal price is initially above the U.S. internal
price, U.S. firms sell to the Mexican market and, in doing
so, drive down Mexico’s internal price to the U.S. internal
price—which, of course, is just the world price. U.S. production entirely displaces Mexican imports from the rest of
the world, and the Mexican MFN tariff becomes irrelevant.
Figure 6.5. Imported MFN Liberalization
Partner
Home
Mexican price
U.S. price
RoW border price
XSRoW
Po + TMX
SUS
1
Po
2
Po
MDUS
MDUS+MX
MDMX
imports
Source: Authors’ elaboration.
MoMX
131
imports
imports
PTAPD_121-142.qxd:inte_001-028_ch01 7/5/11 12:20 PM Page 132
132
Richard Baldwin and Caroline Freund
highly restrictive. One of Canada’s motives in pushing for
the trilateralization of the U.S.–Mexico free trade agreement was to extend its restrictive rules of origin to Mexico
and thereby avoid the undermining of the Auto Pact. The
rules of origin forced Mexican-based car producers to
import parts and components from the United States or
Canada instead of from third countries. As before, NAFTA
equalized U.S. and Mexican internal prices, but this meant
that the Mexican prices were linked to the world prices via
the higher MFN tariffs in Mexico’s partners. In this way,
“imported MFN protection” occurred. NAFTA, with its
rules of origin, had effects that mimicked a rise in the
Mexican MFN tariffs to U.S. and Canadian levels.
Although the distortionary impact of rules of origin is
limited by the level of the MFN tariff, the all-or-nothing
feature of rules of origin for final goods can lead to large
effective rates of protection. For example, if a US$20,000
NAFTA-origin automobile pays zero tariff and the same
non-NAFTA auto would pay 5 percent, a rule of origin
stipulating that a particular component must be made
within NAFTA could make it economical to pay up to
US$1,000 more for the local versus the imported component. Although the distortion in the final good market is
limited to 5 percent, the distortion in the component market can be much larger. (This distortion represents the traditional logic of effective rate of protection.)
Bargaining-Model Stumbling Block–Building Block Logic
The stumbling block–building block mechanisms discussed
earlier resonate strongly with real-world considerations
because they take advantage of the simple institutional features of real-world tariff cutting in PTAs and MTNs. This,
however, is not how big-think regionalism started reasoning
about the issue (Krugman 1991b, 1996).24
When Krugman wondered how regionalism would
affect the GATT, the tool he grabbed for was simple
bargaining-game theory, with two countries that are considering setting tariffs cooperatively (under GATT), or
noncooperatively (Nash tariffs). As figure 6.6 shows, both
countries prefer the cooperative outcome. Krugman
observes, “Trade bargaining . . . is characterised by a Prisoners’ Dilemma. This Dilemma arises in part from the terms
of trade effect of conventional optimal tariff analysis, but
also (and presumably in practice mostly) from the effect of
each country’s tariff on the other country’s producer interests” (Krugman 1996, 72). He goes on to invoke all the
usual theorems of repeated games to think about the building block–stumbling block issue and concludes, “Trade liberalisation must be supported by the belief of countries that
if they cheat they will lose from the subsequent collapse
Figure 6.6. An Economic Theory of the GATT
nation 2’s tariff, t2
Nash tariffs
t2*
GATT tariffs
efficient bargaining curve tariffs
t1*
nation 1’s tariff, t1
Source: Krugman 1991a.
of the cooperative outcome” (Krugman 1996, 72).25 The
crux of his analysis is to examine the impact that an
exogenously formed PTA has on the costs and benefits of
cheating.
Much of Krugman’s reasoning is informal, so it is worth
spelling it out explicitly. The whole analysis turns on three
equilibrium welfare levels:
• WGATT is the level of a nation’s welfare with global cooperation (GATT tariffs)
• WNash is national welfare under noncooperative tariffs
• Wcheat reflects the nation’s welfare when its government
“cheats”—that is, chooses a tariff to maximize its own
welfare when the foreign government embraces its
GATT tariffs.
There are two logical steps in the approach. The first step
consists of the obvious point that, from a global perspective, tariffs are worse than a zero-sum game. Therefore,
some form of cooperation could be Pareto improving, yet
nations have an incentive to cheat. Formally, this is a prisoners’ dilemma, and it arises when Wcheat > WGATT > WNash.
The second step involves a dynamic game that models the
circumstances under which cooperation is sustained. As
Krugman notes, cooperation is self-enforcing when
the gains from cheating are more than offset by the
losses from the (infinite) punishment. Taking d as the discount factor, the present value of cooperating forever is
WGATT/(1 – d ). If cooperation is to be sustained, its value
must exceed the one-period gain from cheating, Wcheat,
plus the present value of the infinite sequence of the Nash
outcomes that are felt in the next period, after the foreigners realize that cheating has occurred, d WNash/(1 – d ).
PTAPD_121-142.qxd:inte_001-028_ch01 7/5/11 12:20 PM Page 133
Preferential Trade Agreements and Multilateral Liberalization
Clearing the (1 – d ) terms, the condition for self-sustaining global free trade is:
WGATT > (1 – d )Wcheat + d WNash
In words, each nation compares the value of welfare
under cooperation with a weighted average of the cheating
outcome and the Nash outcome.
The contribution of this approach comes in considering
how a PTA changes the three levels, Wcheat, WGATT, and
WNash. Krugman (1996) asks whether the formation of a
trade bloc among nations makes them more or less able or
willing to cooperate. His answer is that it can cut either way.
Krugman’s core insight—one that has been followed up
in a dozen subsequent articles—is that PTAs typically act
to reduce their members’ trade with the rest of the world
and so reduce both the cost and the benefit of cheating.
Since these work in opposite directions, some bargainapproach papers find that PTAs are building blocks (i.e.,
they make cooperation more likely), whereas others find
they are stumbling blocks.
This approach works well for explaining strategic interactions among private agents, but it may be less useful for
explaining trade negotiations among large countries. In
particular, it requires two assumptions: that the cheating
period is long enough to make it tempting, and that punishment can be usefully modeled as consisting only of tariff
changes. Since tariff changes are immediately observable,
the first assumption is problematic unless partner countries are very slow to respond, which may well reflect policy
in small developing countries. Punishment is likely to
include more than just tariffs; it may affect external development aid, treatment of expatriates, migration, military
aid, political support in the international arena, participation in the North Atlantic Treaty Organization, and other
concerns. With a shorter period of deviation and more
tools of punishment available, as is the case for large developed countries, it is therefore likely that all welfareimproving agreements are enforceable. Thus, the effect of
PTAs on the cost and benefit of deviating from cooperation
is unlikely to have a first-order impact on multilateral
cooperation when the major countries are involved. This
type of model may help explain why some agreements
among developing countries are never implemented and
why some do not survive when external conditions change.
Other Links from PTAs to MTNs
A number of points made in the literature do not fit neatly
into the stumbling block–building block framework as we
have delineated it. One line of reasoning views a nation’s
MFN tariffs, or its stance favoring or against multilateral
133
cooperation, as depending on the strength of various
domestic special interest groups. The question here, in the
big-think framework, is whether a PTA weakens or
strengthens pro-trade and anti-trade interest groups. At
one end, Winters (1993) argues that regionalism (e.g., in
the EU, on agriculture) strengthened the hand of protectionists, since it worsened Olsen’s asymmetry (which
holds that winners from protection are few in number and
are easy to organize, whereas losers are dispersed, numerous, and difficult to organize politically). Winters terms
this the “restaurant bill” problem. Just as diners at a table
where the bill will be split equally tend to order too much,
the EU tended to grant too much protection to farmers. At
the other end, Richardson (1994) and Panagariya and
Findlay (1994) argue that a PTA tends to dilute the influence of special interest groups via various mechanisms.
Another important line of thinking asserts that the formation of PTAs creates forces that induce nations to begin
or complete multilateral trade talks. For example, Lawrence
(1991), WTO (1995), and Sapir (1996) all argue that the
threat of regionalism was a critical element in inducing
GATT members to initiate the Uruguay Round and to
accept the final Uruguay Round agreement. Bergsten (1996)
dubs this effect “competitive liberalization” and asserts that
regionalism fosters multilateralism, and vice versa. Formalizing regional agreements as a force for competitive liberalization, Saggi and Yildiz (2008) study the role of PTAs in
multilateral liberalization in the presence of a nondiscrimination constraint, such as the MFN rule in the WTO.
They show that if PTAs are not permitted, a country with
special interests aligned against free trade may oppose a
multilateral free trade agreement because it can ride for
free on the liberalization efforts of others. Nondiscrimination means that when any small group of countries liberalizes, all WTO members benefit from lower tariffs on
their exports. The threat of PTAs can reverse that situation
by offering the liberalizing countries a way to stop the outsider from free riding. In this model, competition to the
multilateral system in the form of PTAs can make multilateral free trade feasible when it would not be feasible in
the absence of that competition.
A somewhat related idea, which has not been formalized, is that PTAs are a testing ground for the GATT/WTO
(Bergsten 1996; Lawrence 1996). The prime example here
is the EU, which dealt with deeper-than-tariff-cutting liberalization for decades before the issues arrived on the
GATT agenda in the Tokyo and Uruguay Rounds. (See
Ludema 1996 for a partial formalization of this idea.)
Another line of thinking suggests that PTAs can provide
commitments that boost the credibility of a country’s policy
reforms (Fernandez and Portes 1998). This was explicitly
PTAPD_121-142.qxd:inte_001-028_ch01 7/5/11 12:20 PM Page 134
134
Richard Baldwin and Caroline Freund
mentioned by Mexico in its request to the United States for
an FTA and has been highlighted as an important reason that
Eastern European countries have been keen to join the EU.
Finally, studying how regionalism affects multilateralism
is not the only way to look at the relationship between the
two. A few authors have examined it from the other direction: how multilateralism affects regionalism. Both Ethier
(1998) and Freund (2000a) view regional initiatives as a consequence of the success of multilateralism. Ethier asserts that
it is a benign consequence, since PTAs intensify world investment and create incentives for economic reforms in less
developed countries. Freund studies the incentives for and
the sustainability of preferential liberalization when multilateral tariffs are lower and finds that deeper multilateralism
provides greater incentives to form PTAs. The intuition
draws from the complementarity effect between internal and
external tariffs. When external tariffs are low, the loss from
trade diversion is small, but the gains to producers from
preferential access and to consumers from lower prices
remain. This reasoning could help explain, at least in part,
the large increase in PTAs since the conclusion of the
Uruguay Round and the formation of the WTO in 1995.
Regionalism Versus Multilateralism:
Empirical Evidence
The empirical literature on regionalism as a building
block or stumbling block with respect to free trade is
small, compared with the theoretical literature, but interesting results are beginning to emerge. To date, there is no
evidence that regionalism has been a major stumbling
block to free trade and some evidence that it has promoted
broad liberalization. On the question of whether regional
agreements alter countries’ willingness to move to free
trade, there is only anecdotal evidence. PTA members have
continued to participate in the WTO, with little evidence
of a distinct change in priorities. Finally, on the welfare
impact of regionalism, evidence of trade creation exceeds
evidence of diversion.
History points to complementarity between PTAs and
external liberalization. Irwin (1996) shows that bilateral
agreements during the nineteenth century induced
broader liberalization. The Anglo-French treaty of 1860
led to a host of bilateral agreements that were ultimately
linked by the inclusion of an unconditional MFN clause.
Precisely because trade diversion associated with high tariffs was costly, the French negotiated numerous such
MFN-style agreements.
Using data on trade and trade policy in 50 countries
between 1965 and 1995, Foroutan (1998) provides a general account of how countries forming regional trade blocs
have adjusted their external tariffs. She finds that both integrating and nonintegrating countries have reduced their
trade barriers, suggesting that regionalism is benign. However, Foroutan does not control for other factors that may
have induced countries to behave as they did, making it
impossible to disentangle the effects of trade agreements
from those of other global, regional, or sectoral trends.
Baldwin and Seghezza (2010) study the relationship
between preferential and MFN tariffs in 23 developed and
developing countries and find a positive relationship, suggestive of the tariff complementarity discussed earlier.
Because their dataset is a cross-section (for 2005), the
authors note that they cannot assess whether their result
arises from a causal relationship or is just a consequence of,
say, fixed effects that affect both preferential and multilateral
tariff levels. Still, their findings indicate that regionalism has
not led to significantly higher external tariffs.
Using a detailed cross-industry dataset on Argentina for
1992, 1993, and 1996, Bohara, Gawande, and Sanguinetti
(2004) examine the influence of imports from Mercosur’s
partner Brazil on Argentina’s external tariffs. They find that
increased preferential imports vis-à-vis the value added of
the domestic industry led to lower external tariffs in
Argentina, especially in industries that experienced trade
diversion. This, again, is consistent with the complementarity of tariffs. Trade diversion is costly, and to minimize
it, tariffs were lowered in precisely those industries with the
most diversion. One issue is that the study concentrates on
the effects of increases in preferential imports and does not
address the direct effect of preferential tariffs.
Estevadeordal, Freund, and Ornelas (2008) offer the
first attempt to evaluate empirically the effect of preferential tariffs on external trade liberalization in a large group
of developing countries. They examine changes in preferential tariffs and MFN tariffs in 10 Latin American countries and 100 industries over 12 years. When countries
form a PTA, they lower the tariffs they apply to each other,
but the duties on imports from outside countries can
increase, decrease, or remain unchanged. The authors look
at how countries in Latin America, where regionalist forces
have been particularly strong since the early 1990s, altered
their trade policies vis-à-vis bloc outsiders after forming
PTAs and, specifically, whether sectors with relatively large
preferences have been liberalized or protected to the same
extent as other sectors. If countries raise their external tariffs (or reduce them by less) as a result of regional liberalization, such preferential arrangements should indeed raise
concerns about the recent trend. If, instead, preferences
lead to relatively lower external tariffs, regional agreements
should be accorded a more benign reputation than they
currently have.
PTAPD_121-142.qxd:inte_001-028_ch01 7/5/11 12:20 PM Page 135
Preferential Trade Agreements and Multilateral Liberalization
The results imply that regionalism is a building block
for free trade. There is no clear evidence that trade preferences lead to higher tariffs or smaller tariff cuts, and there
is strong evidence that preferences induce a more rapid
decline in external tariffs in free trade areas. For example, if
a country that follows a strict policy of nondiscrimination
offers free access to another country in a sector in which it
applies a 15 percent multilateral tariff, the country would
tend to subsequently reduce that external tariff by more
than 3 percentage points. As in the study by Bohara and
colleagues, Estevadeordal, Freund, and Ornelas (2008) find
that the complementarity effect is stronger in sectors where
trade bloc partners are more important suppliers, which is
precisely where trade discrimination would be more disruptive. Using a similar methodology for the Association of
Southeast Asian Nations, Calvo-Pardo, Freund, and
Ornelas (2009) also find evidence that regionalism is associated with unilateral tariff reduction.
Recent studies by Limão (2006) and Karacaovali and
Limão (2008) address a related question: whether preferential liberalization by the United States and the EU hindered
multilateral trade liberalization at the Uruguay Round. In
the context of the theoretical literature described earlier,
they examine the goodies-bag stumbling block and, specifically, whether commitments to liberalize were significantly different in goods that offered preferences and in
goods that did not. These papers, however, do not take into
account the size of the preferences or the importance of
trade in the products that received preferential treatment.
Both papers find that liberalization was relatively smaller
in products where preferences were used. They argue that,
intuitively, because the United States and the EU offer preferences on a unilateral basis to extract concessions from
recipients in nontrade areas, they tend to resist liberalization to prevent erosion of preferences.
The evidence in Limão (2006) is widely misrepresented as
showing that the United States raised tariffs in the Uruguay
Round for items on which it granted PTA preferences. Of
course, this cannot be correct, since MTN market access talks
only involve tariff bindings, and the United States did not
violate any of its bindings in the Uruguay Round. Indeed, the
data show U.S. tariffs decreasing for all but 12 of the
thousands of tariff lines, defined at the Harmonized
System–8 product level in the WTO’s database. Formally,
Limão estimates an econometric model of U.S. tariff cuts
during the Uruguay Round. His famous stumbling block
finding is that the United States cut tariffs by less than his
econometric model predicted they should have on items for
which the United States had granted PTA preferences before
the Uruguay Round. In short, he shows that the U.S. preferences acted as a “slowing block,” not as a stumbling block.
135
The findings of Foroutan (1998), Bohara, Gawande, and
Sanguinetti (2004), Estevadeordal, Freund, and Ornelas
(2008), and Calvo-Pardo, Freund, and Ornelas (2009)—all
of which imply that regionalism is a building block for
external liberalization in developing countries—contrast
sharply with those of Limão (2006) and of Karacaovali and
Limão (2008), who find that the United States and the EU
liberalized less during the Uruguay Round in sectors in
which preferences were granted. One reason for differing
results is that that the countries analyzed are very different.
Since the multilateral system has not enforced much tariff
reduction on developing countries, tariffs are relatively
high among that group, creating a large potential for trade
diversion. Lower external tariffs moderate that loss. The
results of the first group of researchers named above suggest that this force is important in explaining changes in
MFN tariffs of developing countries involved in free trade
areas. In contrast, Limão’s work focuses on industrial
countries. Tariffs were already quite low in the United
States and the EU at the onset of the Uruguay Round, thus
reducing the importance of this channel. In addition, the
theoretical underpinnings of Limão’s analysis, which is
used to justify the importance of preferences in NorthSouth agreements, rely on the formation of PTAs for
noneconomic reasons; preferential treatment is extended
in return for noneconomic benefits, such as cooperation
on migration, drug trafficking, or a global political agenda.
This is not the case in South-South PTAs, where the goal is
to exchange access to markets and improve regional economic cooperation.
Welfare Consequences of PTAs
A large portion of the empirical literature on trade diversion versus trade creation has attempted to provide answers
to the question of whether bilateralism is bad (see box 6.1,
above). If regionalism is moving world trade away from
natural trade patterns, thus reducing world welfare, more
diversion will be observed; if regionalism is pushing trade in
the right direction, we should observe little diversion. The
analyses also offer an indirect check on the effect of regional
agreements on trade liberalization. If regional members
tend to raise barriers to nonmembers, there should be
strong evidence of trade diversion—increased trade with
members at the expense of nonmembers. By contrast, if
regional members tend to lower barriers to nonmembers in
concert with PTAs, diversion should be limited.
Unfortunately, estimating trade diversion is no easy
task. It requires knowledge of the counterfactual: what
would have happened to trade if there were no trade agreement? Since this is unknown, assumptions must be made.
PTAPD_121-142.qxd:inte_001-028_ch01 7/5/11 12:20 PM Page 136
136
Richard Baldwin and Caroline Freund
Most studies use a gravity equation (which predicts
bilateral trade on the basis of income and other characteristics) and focus on variables that capture the extent to
which PTA partners trade more or less than would otherwise be expected.26 The key trade creation variable is a
dummy that is equal to 1 if both countries are members of
a common PTA; the key trade diversion variable is a
dummy that is 1 if one country belongs to a PTA and the
other does not. (See Frankel, Stein, and Wei 1995; Carrère
2006; Lee and Shin 2006.) A positive coefficient on the former offers evidence of trade creation; a negative coefficient
on the latter offers evidence of diversion. Overall, the message from such studies is that trade creation predominates.
In fact, a concern is that the estimates of the creation effect
may be implausibly large, as well as too dependent on the
sample of countries and variables included (Haveman and
Hummels 1998).
Magee (2008) expands on the traditional approach with
insights from the literature on the proper estimation of
gravity models. He uses panel data for 133 countries
between 1980 and 1998 and includes country-pair fixed
effects, exporter-year fixed effects, and importer-year fixed
effects to capture the counterfactual more accurately than
standard gravity specifications would. The dyad effects
pick up what is natural about the trade partners, and the
exporter-year and importer-year effects pick up countryspecific dynamics. Magee finds that the average impact of
agreements on trade flows is small, only 3 percent. Moreover, on average, trade creation dominates trade diversion
by about one order of magnitude.
Another strand of the literature uses more disaggregated data to examine specific agreements. Clausing (2001)
develops an analysis at the product level of the 1988
Canada–U.S. Free Trade Agreement (CUSFTA). Using variations in liberalization across industries to identify trade
creation and diversion, she finds that in most sectors trade
creation tends to be the rule and trade diversion the exception. Taking a similar approach, Trefler (2004) finds both
trade creation and trade diversion in CUSFTA but calculates positive welfare effects for the average Canadian.
Romalis (2007) finds that the expansion of CUSFTA to
Mexico, through NAFTA, has been trade diverting. Romalis’s
exercise is similar to Clausing’s and Trefler’s, but he uses
changes in EU trade over the period to capture what would
have happened in the absence of the agreement. Although
this might create a better counterfactual if the NAFTA countries were very similar to the EU, it could lead to overestimates of trade diversion in NAFTA if the EU’s trade with its
own new and existing trade agreement partners were to
expand more rapidly. Even so, Romalis’s results suggest that
the welfare costs of the agreement are tiny.
A different perspective is taken by Chang and Winters
(2002), who study the effects of Mercosur—a trading bloc
formed by Argentina, Brazil, Paraguay, and Uruguay in
1991—on export prices to Brazil. They find that
Argentina’s export prices increased, whereas the export
prices of countries outside Mercosur fell. These price
effects indicate that Mercosur has hurt outsiders while
helping Brazil, a Mercosur partner.27
As Krugman (1991b) shows, whether an agreement is welfare improving also depends on trade costs. To determine
whether nature plays a role in PTA formation, Frankel, Stein,
and Wei (1995) examine whether regional trade is
greater than could be explained by natural determinants—
proximity, size, per capita gross national product, common
border, common language, and so on. They find in favor of
the formation of “natural” trade blocs.
Krishna (2003) tackles the natural trade bloc question
by using detailed U.S. trade data to estimate the welfare
effects from 24 hypothetical bilateral trade agreements in a
general equilibrium framework and then correlating the
estimated welfare changes with geographic variables and
trade volumes. Neither geography nor trade volume is
found to be significantly correlated with welfare gains,
indicating that they are not good indicators of the gains
from trade, as the natural trade bloc approach would suggest. Still, Krishna finds that 80 percent of the potential
agreements he examines are welfare improving. Given the
predominance of trade creation, it is not clear that a correlation between distance or trade volume and welfare is
necessary to indicate that blocs are formed naturally. To
determine which agreements are most natural, the costs of
forming an agreement should also be included, and such
costs are plausibly lower with a neighbor or with a large
trade partner, as the relationship between the two countries is likely to be well developed.
Baier and Bergstrand (2004) develop a general equilibrium model to determine which country pairs would gain
the most from forming PTAs. They then examine whether
these dyads were actually linked by a PTA in a sample of
53 countries in 1996. They find that the likelihood of a PTA
is larger the closer the two countries are to each other, the
more remote they are from RoW, the larger their gross
domestic products (GDPs), the smaller the difference
between their GDPs, the larger their relative factor endowment difference, and the wider the (absolute) difference
between their and RoW’s capital-labor ratios. These variables predict the formation of 85 percent of the bilateral
PTAs in their sample. Their results thus offer support for the
natural trade bloc view.28 In subsequent work, Baier and
Bergstrand (2007) use the same approach to estimate the
impact of PTAs on trade flows. Their key finding is that,
PTAPD_121-142.qxd:inte_001-028_ch01 7/5/11 12:20 PM Page 137
Preferential Trade Agreements and Multilateral Liberalization
once one takes into account the endogeneity of the agreements, the positive impact of PTAs on bilateral trade
becomes more robust and much larger—in fact, five times
larger—than in estimates that take agreements as exogenous. Thus, countries seem to form PTAs when there is
much to be gained from liberalizing bilateral trade.
Proving that agreements are natural or unnatural is
daunting, as it requires an assessment of many potential
agreements and their welfare consequences—and calculating trade diversion and creation in even one agreement is
already difficult. Nevertheless, there is solid empirical support for the more general premise of the natural trade bloc
view: that trade blocs are formed by countries that have
much to gain from freer trade.
The theoretical literature on static effects of trade agreements highlights the potential costs of preferential liberalization and the possibility that trade-diverting agreements
may be more viable politically. The empirical literature is
not entirely conclusive, but it does suggest that trade diversion is not a major concern, although in some agreements
and sectors it may matter. Trade diversion may be less relevant than was initially thought because countries form
trade agreements with “natural trading partners,” where
trade creation is the norm, or because governments may
respond to trade diversion by reducing external tariffs.
Overall, the empirical literature shows that countries in
regional agreements tend to liberalize trade broadly. There
is evidence that regional agreement members tend to
reduce external tariffs, and that this is especially true of
members of free trade agreements (as opposed to customs
unions). In addition, trade diversion tends to be small or
nonexistent, which is consistent with endogenous tariff
changes that reduce costly diversion. There is, however,
some evidence that regional agreements may limit trade
liberalization in the multilateral setting.
Conclusions and Rules for PTAs
In this chapter, we have examined the effect of regionalism
on the multilateral trade system. The theoretical literature
underscores the diverse mechanisms by which regionalism
can be helpful or harmful to that system. So far, there is little evidence that regionalism is overwhelmingly bad for the
multilateral trade system, as some had feared, and there is
some evidence that regionalism is associated with general
liberalization.
To ensure that regionalism is a positive force in the
future, four ideal guidelines can be kept in mind:
1. Bind tariff rates at applied rates, leaving no room for tariff increases following a trade agreement. This measure
137
prevents countries from backtracking on previous liberalization. Although this would be difficult to accomplish, it is a worthwhile goal. Tariffs in most developing
countries are set well below their bindings (by 20 to 30
percentage points!), making the term “binding” meaningless. A move toward more restrictive bindings would
make regionalism less dangerous and would give member countries a lever against a potential increase in the
political forces favoring protection.
2. Agree to lower multilateral tariffs partway, through the
use of preferential tariffs. Even though empirical work
has shown that regionalism tends to be a force for general liberalization, irrespective of restrictions, a commitment in this direction would ensure that regionalism
serves as a building block for free trade.
3. Redefine North-South agreements to incorporate
preferences from the North in response to MFN liberalization on the part of the South. In the developing
countries, where tariffs are generally higher, this
would prevent sizable diversion. In addition, it would
be far easier to implement than a range of tariffs across
various agreements.
4. Keep regional agreements open, extending eligibility to
all countries willing to follow the rules.29 This helps
ward against a global outcome dominated by a handful
of protective trade blocs.
Trade negotiators should have these guidelines in mind,
but the WTO should also do its part to ensure a positive
spread of regionalism. This can be accomplished by monitoring regional agreements among members, publishing
reports on regional agreements that call attention to bad
behavior, and securing the authority to impose more
restrictions on regional agreements.
Given the concerns about regionalism, it is important
to highlight where the long-run potential benefits can be
found. The best way to ensure that regionalism is welfare
improving is for countries to pursue serious deep integration agreements. Real resource gains are obtainable if
countries integrate labor markets, combine regulatory
institutions, harmonize standards, and cooperate extensively on trade facilitation. Removal of behind-the-border
barriers will enhance trade and welfare without the traditional costs of PTAs in tariff revenue and trade diversion.
The benefits of deep integration include real resource
gains that will accrue to nonmembers as well as members.
The focus should be on the quality, not the number, of
agreements. There is a danger, however, that the present
wave of PTAs is being generated by minor agreements that
will not produce significant benefits, especially given their
cost to the world trading system. How to achieve deeper
PTAPD_121-142.qxd:inte_001-028_ch01 7/5/11 12:20 PM Page 138
138
Richard Baldwin and Caroline Freund
integration in services, agriculture, transport, and other
sectors will be the focus of most of the remaining chapters
of this volume.
Notes
The authors are grateful for comments from Jean-Pierre Chauffour, Jaime
de Melo, and Jean-Christophe Maur.
1. Bhagwati (1993, 2008) and Panagariya and Bhagwati (1999) provide in-depth discussions of these concerns.
2. Grossman and Helpman (1995), Levy (1997), and Krishna (1998)
show that regionalism can lead to a reduction in support for multilateral
liberalization. However, Bagwell and Staiger (1999), Freund (2000b), and
Ornelas (2005b) find that the formation of a PTA can cause its members to
lower tariffs. Panagariya (2000) offers an excellent survey of the literature.
3. A tariff can theoretically be used optimally to protect an infant
industry until it is strong enough to compete. It is difficult, however, to
identify the infants that have potential to grow, and it is often difficult to
drop protection after it has served its purpose. Moreover, it is typically
politically connected sectors, rather than growing sectors, that obtain
protection.
4. The next two sections draw heavily on Baldwin (2009).
5. Bhagwati (1991, 71) ascribes the shift to the United States’ conversion to regionalism, but this contradicts the judgments of trade policy
scholars who were engaged in the details of policy at the time (Wonnacott
1987, 17; Schott 1988, 29; Whalley 1996; Hufbauer, Schott, and Clark
1994, 100). It also contradicts the facts. Bearing witness to the longstanding U.S. interest in regionalism is a string of deals that were struck,
or almost struck, in 1854, 1874, and 1911. In March 1948 the United States
and Canada concluded a secret draft protocol eliminating most tariffs and
quotas bilaterally, but this was ultimately rejected by the Canadians. In
1958, U.S. government procurement was preferentially liberalized in
Canada’s favor, and in 1965, the U.S.–Canada Auto Pact came into force.
The 1974 Trade Act authorized the U.S. president to negotiate an FTA
with Canada, and the 1979 Trade Agreements Act required the president
to study an FTA in North America.
6. See Baldwin (1993, 1997) and Serra et al. (1997) for an account of
this domino effect.
7. Krugman argued that the multilateral process had run aground
with the December 1990 failure of the Uruguay Round and was unlikely
to get afloat any time soon because the system was plagued by profound
problems. “While some kind of face-saving document will probably be
produced, in reality the [Uruguay Round] has clearly failed either to significantly liberalize trade or to generate goodwill that would help sustain
further rounds of negotiation” (Krugman 1991b, 5). Regionalism, however, was not one of those fundamental problems. “But while the move to
free trade areas has surely done the multilateral process some harm, it is
almost surely more a symptom than a cause of the decline of the GATT. . . .
The problems of the GATT are so deep-seated that it is unlikely that a
world without regional free trade agreements would do much better”
(Krugman 1991b, 20). He closed his essay with a prediction that history
falsified and with a faute de mieux view of regionalism:
The world may well be breaking up into three trading blocs; trade
within those blocs will be quite free, while trade between the blocs
will at best be no freer than it is now and may well be considerably
less free. This is not what we might have hoped for. But the situation would not be better, and could easily have been worse, had the
great free trade agreements of recent years never happened.
(Krugman 1991b, 20–21)
8. The logic of the preference-erosion or exploitation stumbling
block was demonstrated in a Walrasian setting by Riezman (1985) and
Kennan and Riezman (1990) and in a Brander-Krugman setting by
Krishna (1998) and Freund (2000a). See also Goto and Hamada (1995),
Nordström (1995), and Bond and Syropoulos (1996a, sec. 3) for examples
of preference-erosion stumbling blocks.
9. The theoretical notion was formalized by Limão (2007).
10. Levy (1997) illustrates a cherry-picking stumbling block in a highly
stylized setup, but his main result is surely more general than his model.
11. This is called the Stolper-Samuelson effect in the economic
literature.
12. More formally, without MTNs, governments maximize a politically weighted objective function that includes matters affected by the
nation’s own tariffs: profits of import-competing sectors, consumer
surplus, and tariff revenue. During the negotiations, a nation’s tariff
affects all those things, but foreign tariff levels are linked to domestic
tariffs via reciprocity, and the objective function now includes the
effect of foreign tariffs on exporter’s profits. Since this new impact is
negative (higher domestic tariffs reduce exporter’s profits via reciprocity), announcement of the MTN leads the government to find it politically optimal to choose a tariff that is lower than the politically optimal
tariff before the MTN.
13. The word “juggernaut,” defined as “any massive inexorable force
that advances crushing whatever is in the path,” stems from a British
mispronunciation of the name of the Hindu deity of the Puri shrine,
Jagannath. A festival held in Puri involves the “chariot of Jagannath,” an
enormous and unwieldy construction that requires thousands of people
to get it rolling. Once started, however, it rolls over anything in its path.
14. The juggernaut logic is from Baldwin (1994, ch. 2.5); it is elaborated in Baldwin and Robert-Nicoud (2005) and Baldwin (2006) and
formalized in part by Freund (2000b). The first part of the juggernaut
mechanism—realignment of domestic special interests through
reciprocity—has long been recognized in histories of trade liberalization—
for example, by Bergsten (1996) and Destler (2005), under the name “bicycle theory and export politics.” The point was also made by many others,
including Robert Baldwin (1985). The basic idea dates much further
back, as Irwin (1996) points out. More recently, the first half of the juggernaut logic has been studied formally by Grossman and Helpman (2001)
and by Bagwell and Staiger (2002). Juggernaut-like mechanisms were discussed independently by Hufbauer, Schott, and Clark (1994, 164) and by
Richardson (1993). Bergsten (1998) mentions an alternative source of
political-economy momentum (“modest liberalization begets broader liberalization by demonstrating its payoff and familiarizing domestic politics
with the issue”). Staiger (1995) uses a repeated game setting, with workers
moving slowly out of the import-competing sector to generate gradualism, but MTNs and GATT reciprocity play no role. Milner (1997) and
Oye (1992), working independently in the international political-economy
context, discuss mechanisms by which PTAs can create a proliberalization political-economy momentum. More recently, Hathaway (1998)
presents a similar logic in her positive-feedback model.
15. But multilateral tariff cutting may also lower tariffs to a level at
which PTAs become feasible, when previously they were not; this may
have been the case with the Canada–U.S. FTA.
16. Agriculture in Europe is a good example. Formation of the customs union realigned special interests in the European Economic Community (EEC) in a way that fostered higher agricultural tariffs. EEC tariffs
on agricultural goods were not bound until the 1990s, and so the community was free to raise its agricultural tariffs without appealing to the Article 24 exception. Since EEC tariffs were bound for manufacturing goods,
EEC members needed the Article 24 exception to establish the common
external tariff (CET), and this led them to respect the article’s requirement that the CET not be higher, on average. Roughly speaking, France
lowered its tariffs; Germany raised its tariffs; and Belgium, Luxembourg,
and the Netherlands did little, as their tariffs were initially between the
French and German levels. In this way, the formation of the EEC customs
union probably reduced the overall size of the EEC import-competing
sector in manufacturing but raised it in agriculture.
17. The key concepts are “coalition externalities” (Haberler’s spillover)
and “grand-coalition superadditivity” (global free trade is first-best). The
authors assume that one nation is the undisputed agenda setter and that
PTAPD_121-142.qxd:inte_001-028_ch01 7/5/11 12:20 PM Page 139
Preferential Trade Agreements and Multilateral Liberalization
unlimited international transfers (transferable utility, in game theory
parlance) are possible.
18. See Lloyd (2002) for a clear development of the veto-avoidance
logic. This line of thinking is one strand in the widely discussed competitive liberalization logic advanced by Bergsten (1996).
19. This is especially true given all the separability that rules Meade’s
secondary and tertiary effects (see Meade 1955).
20. Given the separability of the markets, the second FTA with RoW
would yield a price for Good 3 equal to P'.
21. Contributions to the literature that have looked at the complementarity versus substitutes effects include Riezman (1985), Kennan and
Riezman (1990), Krugman (1991a, 1991b, 1996), Richardson (1993), Bond
and Syropoulos (1996a), Freund (2000a), and Ornelas (2005b, 2007).
22. Shibata (1967), Vousden (1990), Krueger (1993), Richardson
(1993, 1994, 1995), and Grossman and Helpman (1995) are all important
contributors to or users of this line of analysis.
23. Extension of this analysis led to the proposition of the unsustainablity of FTAs. Vousden (1990, 234) argues that Home would be tempted
to lower its MFN tariff to just under that of Partner in order to recapture
the tariff revenue and that Partner would have an incentive to reply, with
the resulting race-to-the-bottom tariff making FTAs “unsustainable.”
Richardson (1995) extended and popularized this result. The main results
in Shibata (1967), Vousden (1990), and Richardson (1995)—the irrelevance of rules of origin and the unsustainability of FTAs—are of little relevance to real-world policy concerns. (Rules of origin are at the heart of
many current policy debates, and FTAs, not customs unions, are by far the
most prevalent form of PTA.)
24. This approach came to be known as the terms-of-trade approach
after Kyle Bagwell, Robert Staiger, and their students formally modeled
the issues, starting with Bagwell and Staiger (1993). For examples of this
sort of application to regionalism questions, see Bond and Syropoulos
(1996b); Bond, Syropoulos, and Winters (1996); Campa and Sorenson
(1996); Yi (1996); Bagwell and Staiger (1999); Conconi (2000); Conconi
and Perroni (2000); Freund (2000b); and Ornelas (2005a, 2007).
25. This is not a new point. It is very clear in the discussion of Johnson
(1953) but probably dates much further back. Indeed, the notion that a
quid pro quo would be mutually advantageous was probably well understood by trade diplomats as far back as Roman times.
26. An alternative is to use computable general equilibrium models to
identify counterfactuals, but the results are highly dependent on the parameters assumed. See, for example, Brown, Deardorff, and Stern (1992).
27. Schiff and Chang (2003) find that the threat of duty-free exports
from Argentina to Brazil, measured by Argentina’s exports of the same
good to another country, also lowers prices of exports by nonmembers of
Mercosur to Brazil.
28. Egger and Larch (2008) confirm those findings in a larger sample,
finding also that preexisting nearby PTAs increase the probability that a
country pair will form a PTA.
29. Baldwin (2006) argues that the WTO can be involved, as was done
in the Information Technology (IT) Agreement, which bound IT tariffs at
zero for all countries willing to join. This is a way of “multilateralizing
regionalism.”
References
Aghion, Philippe, Pol Antràs, and Elhanan Helpman. 2007. “Negotiating
Free Trade.” Journal of International Economics 73, no.1 (September):
1–30.
Bagwell, Kyle, and Robert W. Staiger. 1993. “Multilateral Tariff Cooperation during the Formation of Regional Free Trade Areas.” NBER
Working Paper 4364, National Bureau of Economic Research,
Cambridge, MA. http://www.nber.org/papers/w4364.
———. 1999. “Regionalism and Multilateral Tariff Cooperation.” In
International Trade Policy and the Pacific Rim, ed. John Piggott and
Alan Woodland. London: Macmillan.
139
———. 2002. The Economics of the World Trading System. Cambridge,
MA: MIT Press.
Baier, Scott L., and Jeffrey H. Bergstrand. 2004. “Economic Determinants
of Free Trade Agreements.” Journal of International Economics 64, no.1
(October): 29–63.
———. 2007. “Do Free Trade Agreements Actually Increase Members’
International Trade?” Journal of International Economics 71, no.1
(March): 72–95.
Baldwin, Richard. 1993. “A Domino Theory of Regionalism.” NBER Working Paper 4465, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge,
MA. http://www.nber.org/papers/w4465.
———. 1994. Towards an Integrated Europe. London: Centre for Economic Policy Research.
———. 1997. “The Causes of Regionalism.” World Economy 20 (7):
865–88.
———. 2006. “Multilateralising Regionalism: Spaghetti Bowls as Building
Blocs on the Path to Global Free Trade.” World Economy 29 (11):
1451–1518.
———. 2009. “Big-Think Regionalism: A Critical Survey.” In Regional Rules
in the Global Trading System, ed. Antoni Estevadeordal, Kati Suominen,
and Robert Teh. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.
Baldwin, Richard, and Frédéric Robert-Nicoud. 2005. “Juggernaut
Model—The Lego Version.” Graduate Institute of International Studies, Geneva.
Baldwin, Richard, and Elena Seghezza. 2010. “Are Trade Blocs Building or
Stumbling Blocks?” Journal of Economic Integration 25, no.2 (June):
276–97.
Baldwin, Robert E. 1970. Non-Tariff Distortions of International Trade.
Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.
———. 1985. The Political Economy of U.S. Import Policy. Cambridge,
MA: MIT Press.
Bergsten, C. Fred. 1991. “Commentary: The Move toward Free Trade
Zones.” Economic Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, 76
(November–December): 27–35.
———. 1996. “Globalizing Free Trade: The Ascent of Regionalism.” Foreign Affairs 75, no.3 (May–June): 105–20.
———. 1998. “Fifty Years of the GATT/WTO: Lessons from the Past for
Strategies for the Future.” Working Paper 98-3, Peterson Institute
for International Economics, Washington, DC. http://www.iie.com/
publications/wp/wp.cfm?ResearchID=144.
Bhagwati, Jagdish N. 1991. The World Trading System at Risk. Princeton,
NJ: Princeton University Press.
———. 1993. “Regionalism and Multilateralism: An Overview.” In New
Dimensions in Regional Integration, ed. Jaime de Melo and Arvind
Panagariya. Oxford, U.K.: Oxford University Press.
———. 2008. Termites in the Trading System. Oxford, U.K.: Oxford University Press.
Bohara, Alok K., Kishore Gawande, and Pablo Sanguinetti. 2004. “Trade
Diversion and Declining Tariffs: Evidence from Mercosur.” Journal of
International Economics 64 (1): 65–88.
Bond, Eric, and Constantinos Syropoulos. 1996a. “The Size of Trading
Blocs: Market Power and World Welfare Effects.” Journal of International Economics 40 (3–4): 412–37.
———. 1996b. “Trading Blocs and the Sustainability of Interregional
Cooperation.” The New Transatlantic Economy, eds. Matthew
Canzoneri, Wilfred Ethier, and Vittorio Grillli. Cambridge, U.K.:
Cambridge University Press.
Bond, Eric W., Constantinos Syropoulos, and L. Alan Winters. 1996.
“Deepening of Regional Integration and External Trade Relations.”
CEPR Discussion Paper 1317, Centre for Economic Policy Research,
London.
Brown, Drusilla K., Alan V. Deardorff, and Robert M. Stern. 1992. “North
American Integration.” Economic Journal 102, no.415 (November):
1507–18.
Calvo-Pardo, Hector, Caroline Freund, and Emanuel Ornelas. 2009. “The
ASEAN Free Trade Agreement: Impact on Trade Flows and External
PTAPD_121-142.qxd:inte_001-028_ch01 7/5/11 12:20 PM Page 140
140
Richard Baldwin and Caroline Freund
Trade Barriers.” Policy Research Working Paper 4960, World Bank,
Washington, DC. http://www-wds.worldbank.org/servlet/WDSCon
tentServer/WDSP/IB/2009/06/10/000158349_20090610085729/Ren
dered/PDF/WPS4960.pdf. Forthcoming in Quantifying the Costs and
Benefits of Regional Economic Integration in Asia, ed. Robert Barro
and Jong-Wha Lee. Manila: Asian Development Bank.
Campa, José Manuel, and Timothy L. Sorenson. 1996. “Are Trade Blocs Conducive to Free Trade?” Scandinavian Journal of Economics 98 (2): 263–73.
Carrère, Cèline. 2006. “Revisiting the Effects of Regional Trade Agreements on Trade Flows with Proper Specification of the Gravity
Model.” European Economic Review 50: 223–47.
Chang, Won, and L. Alan Winters. 2002. “How Regional Blocs Affect
Excluded Countries: The Price Effects of Mercosur.” American Economic Review 92 (4): 889–904.
Clausing, Kimberly A. 2001. “Trade Creation and Trade Diversion in the
Canada–United States Free Trade Agreement.” Canadian Journal of
Economics 34: 677–96.
Conconi, Paola. 2000. “Trade Bloc Formation under Imperfect Competition.” The Warwick Economics Research Paper Series (TWERPS) 571,
Department of Economics, University of Warwick, Coventry, U.K.
Conconi, Paoli, and Carlo Perroni. 2000. “Issue Linkage and Issue Tie-In
in International Negotiations.” The Warwick Economics Research
Paper Series (TWERPS) 558, Department of Economics, University of
Warwick, Coventry, U.K.
Destler, I. M. 1986. American Trade Politics. Washington, DC: Peterson
Institute for International Economics.
———. 2005. American Trade Politics. 4th ed. Washington, DC: Peterson
Institute for International Economics.
Dixit, Avinash, and Victor Norman. 1980. Theory of International Trade.
Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.
Egger, Peter, and Mario Larch. 2008. “Interdependent Preferential Trade
Agreement Memberships: An Empirical Analysis.” Journal of International Economics 76 (2): 384–99.
Estevadeordal, Antoni, Caroline Freund, and Emanuel Ornelas. 2008.
“Does Regionalism Affect Trade Liberalization toward Nonmembers?” Quarterly Journal of Economics 123, no.4 (November): 1531–75.
Ethier, Wilfred J. 1998. “Regionalism in a Multilateral World.” Journal of
Political Economy 109 (6): 1214–45.
Fernandez, Raquel, and Jonathan Portes. 1998. “Returns to Regionalism:
An Analysis of Nontraditional Gains from Regional Trade Agreements.” World Bank Economic Review 12, no.2 (May): 197–220.
Foroutan, Faezeh. 1998. “Does Membership in a Regional Preferential
Trade Arrangement Make a Country More or Less Protectionist?”
World Economy 21: 305–35.
Frankel, Jeffrry A., and Shang-Jin Wei. 1998. “Regionalization of World
Trade and Currencies: Economics and Politics.” In The Regionalization
of the World Economy, ed. J. A. Frankel, ch. 7. Chicago, IL: Chicago
University Press.
Frankel, Jeffrey A., Ernesto Stein, and Shang-Jin Wei. 1995. “Trading Blocs
and the Americas: The Natural, the Unnatural, and the Super-Natural.”
Journal of Development Economics 47: 61–95.
Freund, Caroline. 2000a. “Different Paths to Free Trade: The Gains from
Regionalism.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 115 (4): 1317–41.
———. 2000b. “Multilateralism and the Endogenous Formation of Preferential Trade Agreements.” Journal of International Economics 52: 359–76.
Goto, Junichi, and Koichi Hamada. 1995. “EU, NAFTA, and Asian Responses:
A Perspective from the Calculus of Participation.” NBER Working Paper
5325, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.
Grossman, Gene, and Elhanan Helpman. 1995. “The Politics of Free Trade
Agreements.” American Economic Review 85: 667–90.
———. 2001. Special Interest Politics. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Hathaway, Oona. 1998. “Positive Feedback: The Impact of Trade Liberalization on Industry Demands for Protection.” International Organization 52, no.3 (Summer): 575–612.
Haveman, Jon D., and David L. Hummels. 1998. “What Can We Learn
from Bilateral Trade? Gravity and Beyond.” Krannert School of
Management—Center for International Business Education and
Research (CIBER), Purdue University, West Lafayette, IN.
Hufbauer, Gary C., Jeffrey Schott, and Diana Clark. 1994. Western Hemisphere Economic Integration. Washington, D C: Institute for International Economics.
Irwin, Douglas. 1996. “Multilateral and Bilateral Trade Policies in the
World Trading System: An Historical Perspective.” In New Dimensions
in Regional Integration, ed. Jaime de Melo and Arvind Panagariya.
Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.
Johnson, H. 1953. “Optimum Tariffs and Retaliation.” Review of Economic
Studies 21 (2): 142–53.
Karacaovali, Baybars, and Nuno Limão. 2008. “The Clash of Liberalizations: Preferential vs. Multilateral Trade Liberalization in the European Union.” Journal of International Economics 74: 299–327.
Kemp, Murray C., and Henry Y. Wan, Jr. 1976. “An Elementary Proposition Concerning the Formation of Customs Unions.” Journal of International Economics 6 (1): 95–97.
Kennan, John, and Raymond Riezman. 1990. “Optimal Tariff Equilibria
with Customs Unions.” Canadian Journal of Economics 23 (1):
70–83.
Krishna, Pravin. 1998. “Regionalism and Multilateralism: A Political
Economy Approach.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 113, no.1 (February): 227–50.
———. 2003. “Are Regional Trading Partners ‘Natural’?” Journal of Political Economy 111 (1): 202–26.
Krueger, Anne O. 1993. “Free Trade Agreements Versus Customs Unions.”
Journal of Development Economics 54: 169–87.
Krugman, Paul. 1991a. “Is Bilateralism Bad?” In International Trade and
Trade Policy, ed. Elhanan Helpman and Assaf Razin. Cambridge, MA:
MIT Press.
———. 1991b. “The Move toward Free Trade Zones.” Economic Review,
Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, 76, no.6 (November–December):
5–25.
———. 1996. “Regionalism versus Multilateralism: Analytic Notes.” In
New Dimensions in Regional Integration, ed. Jaime de Melo and Arvind
Panagariya. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.
Lawrence, Robert Z. 1991. “Emerging Regional Arrangements: Building
Blocs or Stumbling Blocks?” In Finance and the International Economy
5: The AMEX Bank Review Prize Essays, ed. Richard O’Brien, 23–35.
New York: Oxford University Press.
———. 1996. Regionalism, Multilateralism, and Deeper Integration.
Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press.
Leamer, Edward E. 1990. “The Structure and Effect of Tariff and NonTariff Barriers in 1983.” In The Political Economy of International
Trade: Essays in Honor of Robert E. Baldwin, ed. Ronald W. Jones and
Anne O. Krueger. Cambridge, MA: Blackwell.
Lee, Jong-Wha, and Kwanho Shin. 2006. “Does Regionalism Lead to More
Global Trade Integration in East Asia?” North American Journal of Economics and Finance 17: 283–301.
Levy, Philip I. 1997. “A Political-Economic Analysis of Free-Trade Agreements.” American Economic Review 87 (4): 506–19.
Limão, Nuno. 2006. “Preferential Trade Agreements as Stumbling Blocks
for Multilateral Trade Liberalization: Evidence for the United States.”
American Economic Review 96 (3): 896–914.
———. 2007. “Are Preferential Trade Agreements with Non-trade Objectives a Stumbling Block for Multilateral Liberalization?” Review of
Economic Studies 74 (3): 821–55.
Lloyd, Peter John. 2002. “New Bilateralism in the Asia–Pacific.” World
Economy 25 (9): 1279–96.
Ludema, Rodney D. 1996. “Increasing Returns, Multinationals and Geography of Preferential Trade Agreements.” Journal of International Economics 56 (2): 329–58.
Magee, Christopher S. P. 2008. “New Measures of Trade Creation and
Trade Diversion.” Journal of International Economics 75 (2): 340–62.
Meade, James E. 1955. The Theory of Customs Unions. Amsterdam. NorthHolland.
PTAPD_121-142.qxd:inte_001-028_ch01 7/5/11 12:20 PM Page 141
Preferential Trade Agreements and Multilateral Liberalization
Milner, Helen V. 1997. Interests, Institutions and Information: Domestic
Politics and International Relations. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Nordström, Håkan. 1995. “Customs Unions, Regional Trading Blocs and
Welfare.” In Expanding Membership of the European Union, ed.
Richard E. Baldwin, Pertti Haaparanta, and Jaakko Kiander, 54–78.
Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.
Ornelas, Emanuel. 2005a. “Trade Creating Free Trade Areas and the Undermining of Multilateralism.” European Economic Review 49: 1717–35.
———. 2005b. “Rent Destruction and the Political Viability of Free Trade
Agreements.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 120: 1475–1506.
———. 2007. “Exchanging Market Access at the Outsiders’ Expense:
The Case of Customs Unions.” Canadian Journal of Economics 40
(1): 207–24.
Oye, Kenneth A. 1992. Economic Discrimination and Political Exchange:
World Political Economy in the 1930s and 1980s. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Panagariya, Arvind. 2000. “Preferential Trade Liberalization: The Traditional Theory and New Developments.” Journal of Economic Literature
38: 287–331.
Panagariya, Arvind, and Jagdish Bhagwati. 1999, “Preferential Trading
Areas and Multilateralism: Strangers, Friends or Foes?” In Regionalism
in Trade Policy: Essays on Preferential Trading, ed. Arvind Panagariya,
47–111. Singapore: World Scientific Publishing.
Panagariya, Arvind, and Ronald Findlay. 1994. “A Political Economy
Analysis of Free Trade Areas and Customs Unions.” Policy Research
Working Paper 1261, World Bank, Washington, DC.
Richardson, Martin. 1993. “Endogenous Protection and Trade Diversion.”
Journal of International Economics 34 (3–4): 309–24.
———. 1994. “Why a Free Trade Area? The Tariff also Rises.” Economics
and Politics 6 (1): 79–96.
———. 1995. “Tariff Revenue Competition in a Free Trade Area.” European Economic Review 39: 1429–37.
Riezman, Raymond. 1985. “Customs Unions and the Core.” Journal of
International Economics 19 (3–4): 355–65.
Romalis, John. 2007. “NAFTA’s and CUSFTA’s Impact on International
Trade.” Review of Economics and Statistics 89 (3): 416–35.
Saggi, Kamal, and Halis Murat Yildiz. 2008. “Bilateral Trade Agreements
and the Feasibility of Multilateral Free Trade.” MPRA Paper 17561,
Munich Personal RePEc Archive, Munich, Germany. http://mpra.
ub.uni-muenchen.de/17561/.
Sapir, André. 1996. “Discussion” of ch. 7, L. Alan Winters, “The European
Community: A Case of Successful Integration?” In New Dimensions
in Regional Integration, ed. Jaime de Melo and Arvind Panagariya,
Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.
141
Schiff, Maurice, and Won Chang. 2003. “Market Presence, Contestability,
and the Terms-of-Trade Effects of Regional Integration,” Journal of
International Economics 60, no.1 (May): 161–75.
Schott, Jeffrey. 1988. “The Free Trade Agreement: A US Assessment.” In
The Canada–United States Free Trade Agreement: The Global Impact,
ed. Jeffrey J. Schott and Murray G. Smith. Washington, DC: Institute
for International Economics.
Serra, Jaime, et al. 1997. Reflections on Regionalism: Report of the Study
Group on International Trade. New York: Carnegie Endowment for
International Peace.
Shibata, Hirofumi. 1967. “The Theory of Economic Unions: A Comparative Analysis of Customs Unions, Free Trade Areas and Tax Unions.” In
Fiscal Harmonisation in Common Markets, ed. Call S. Shoup, vol. 1,
145–264. New York: Columbia University Press.
Sinclair, P., and D. Vines 1995. “Bigger Trade Blocs Need Not Entail More
Protection.” University of Birmingham, U.K.
Snape, Richard. 1993. “History and Economics of GATT’s Article XXIV.”
In Regional Integration and the Global Trading System, ed. Kym
Anderson and Richard Blackhurst, 273–91. New York: Harvester
Wheatsheaf.
Staiger, Robert W. 1995 “A Theory of Gradual Trade Liberalization” In New
Directions in Trade Theory, ed. Alan V. Deardorff, James A. Levinsohn,
and Robert M. Stern. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.
Summers, Lawrence. 1991. “Regionalism and the World Trading System.” Economic Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City,
76, no.6 (November–December): 295–302.
Trefler, Daniel. 2004. “The Long and Short of the Canada–U.S. Free Trade
Agreement.” American Economic Review 94 (4): 870–95.
Vousden, Neil. 1990. The Economics of Trade Protection. Cambridge, U.K.:
Cambridge University Press.
Whalley, John. 1996. “Regional Trade Arrangements in North America:
CUSTA and NAFTA.” In New Dimensions in Regional Integration, ed.
Jaime de Melo and Arvind Panagariya, 352–81. Cambridge, U.K.:
Cambridge University Press.
Winters, L. Alan. 1993. “The European Community: A Case of Successful
Integration?” CEPR Discussion Paper 755, Centre for Economic Policy Research, London.
Wonnacott, Paul. 1987. “U.S. and Canadian Auto Policies in a Changing
World Environment.” Canadian-American Committee, C. D. Howe
Institute and National Planning Association, Toronto, Canada.
WTO (World Trade Organization). 1995. Regionalism and the World Trading System. Geneva: WTO.
Yi, Sang-Seung. 1996. “Endogenous Formation of Customs Unions under
Imperfect Competition: Open Regionalism Is Good.” Journal of International Economics 41 (1–2): 151–77.
PTAPD_121-142.qxd:inte_001-028_ch01 7/5/11 12:20 PM Page 142