The Migration and Development Nexus: Looking for a Triple Win Kenneth Hermele Economist, Forum Syd, Stockholm, Sweden Foreword Migrants and diaspora groups are increasingly recognised as important actors promoting global, sustainable, human and economic development. Their contributions to welfare and economic growth are valuable both in countries of destination and origin, resulting in a more optimistic stance in relation to the role of migration. However, it is also clear that we are only in the beginning of fully understanding the potential of migration, migrants and diaspora groups. In this report, Forum Syd analyses the evidence on the Migration and Development Nexus, and highlights three main areas that need to be addressed in order to strengthen the benefits to be reaped from migration. In addition, the report examines the ‘triple win’ of migration – the contribution to the migrants themselves, to the countries of destination, and to the families, societies and countries of origin. For several years, Forum Syd has been supporting migrants’ diasporas; as part of this, we highlight their important efforts for their countries of origin. We hope the report will encourage discussions, develop a curiosity and raise awareness concerning migration and migrants and the crucial importance of migration for global development. Stockholm November 2015 Annica Sohlström, Secretary General, Forum Syd 2 Summary 250 million people are migrants today (excluding refugees and internal migrants), contributing to the development of their countries of destination as well as to the well-being of their families, societies and countries of origin. A migrant today is just as likely to be a woman looking for job in the social and domestic sectors, as a man working in industry or construction. SouthàSouth migration is as important as SouthàNorth migration. The global flows of remittances, a consequence of these migratory movements, are as significant within the South as from North to South. The view that migration constitutes a triple win – to the migrants themselves, to the countries of destination, and to the families, societies and countries of origin – although not entirely new has only recently come to permeate the Migration and Development discourse. Two drivers are behind this change in perspective: • Firstly, the understanding that migrant remittances are large – dwarfing Official Development Assistance – and resilient in times of crisis – compared to Foreign Direct Investments. • Secondly, the understanding of the benefits which could be reaped from the links existing between the diasporas of migrants in countries of destination and the social, political and economic processes of development of the societies of origin. But although the potential has been recognized, there still exist important weaknesses in today’s global migration regime, the most important being • One, the costs of transferring remittances, which although they have been reduced still absorb a chilling 36 billion USD annually. The ambition of the recently tabled Sustainable Development Goals of reducing transfer costs to 3 per cent still remains to be operationalized. • Two, steps to secure migrants social, economic and political rights at both ends of the migration trajectory remains to be guaranteed, such as the right of migrants to vote while remaining in their countries of destination, and the right to transfer their acquired social rights (such as pensions) if they choose to return to their country of origin. In addition, union rights and other social rights need to be secured. • Three, diaspora organisations and so called Home Town Associations need to be supported as they are crucial vehicles to bridge the Origin/ Destination divide and keep the migrants connected to their countries of origin while simultaneously facilitating their integration in the countries of destination. After surveying the evidence on the Migration and Development Nexus, sourced from academic studies and reports published by international organisations and Civil Society Organisations, this report concludes that migration in all its guises and directions will remain an essential component of the global economy, as ever more resources, goods, ideas and people cross borders. 3 Foreword.........................................................................................................2 Summary.........................................................................................................3 Introduction: Framing of Migration and development......................................................... 6 Migration: How many, origins, destinations..................................................................... 9 Remittances – the origin of the win-win view.................................................11 Migration: From “drain on” to “source of ” development – with a gendered gaze....................................................................................15 What does migration contribute? Individual perspectives.............................. 17 Cost of remitting.................................................................................. 19 What does migration contribute? National perspectives.................................22 Risks and drawbacks of migration: individual and national perspectives........26 Brain drain/gain/waste..........................................................................26 Charges imposed on migrants ..............................................................28 Putting the picture together ..........................................................................30 A new context, a new future.................................................................. 31 Win-Win I: Diasporas and Home Town Associations............................ 32 Win-Win II: Mutual interests ............................................................... 33 Win-Win III: Policy recommendations.................................................34 List of References.......................................................................................... 38 4 Boxes 1. Delimitations and definitions...................................................................... 8 2. Defining migrant remittances.................................................................... 11 Tables 1. Main phases in the framing of Migration and development������������������������ 7 2. Migrant stocks.......................................................................................... 10 3. The world’s most remittance dependent economies����������������������������������� 13 4. Mis- and preconceptions vs Facts.............................................................. 29 5. Improving the potential of migration for development������������������������������ 35 Figures 1. Financial flows to the South...................................................................... 12 2. Top receiving countries.............................................................................. 13 Cases 1. Forced remittances..................................................................................... 15 2. Roma migrants in Spain, Italy and Scandinavia��������������������������������������� 18 3. Migrating from Ethiopia........................................................................... 19 4. Migration and the SDGs............................................................................ 20 5. The Somali diaspora.................................................................................. 23 6. Migrants on Sweden’s labour market......................................................... 27 7. Kowsar Aden, Swedish-Somalilander........................................................ 32 Acronyms CSO Civil Society Organisations FDI Foreign Direct Investment GDP Gross Domestic Product HTA Home Town Associations IMF International Monetary Fund, Washington DC IOM International Organisation for Migration, Geneva Knomad Global Knowledge Partnership on Migration and Development, World Bank MDG Millennium Development Goals ODA Official Development Assistance OECD Organization of Economic Cooperation and Development, Paris OWWA Overseas Workers Welfare Administration, The Philippines SDG Sustainable Development Goals SEK Swedish kronor SSA Sub-Saharan Africa UN United Nations UNDP United Nations Development Programme USD United States dollar WWII World War Two 5 INTRODUCTION: Framing of Migration and development When the Swedish government summarized its stand on migration, the point of departure was quite optimistic. Migration was a win-win process, equally benefitting migrants and their societies of origin. Migrants, it was stated, increased their incomes fifteen-fold by moving from the South to the North – see Box 1 for definitions – the number of years their children spent at school doubled, and infant mortality decreased fourteen-fold, all in comparison to the circumstances they had left behind. At the same time, the remittances that migrants transferred back to their families lowered significantly the local level of poverty, leading to an improvement also in the health status of the children who had remained in the country of origin (GoS 2014). Against this background, a reader could be expected to ask her/himself why not everybody in the South would to try to – indeed ought to – migrate to the North, given the apparently indisputable benefits to themselves and to the countries of origin. The Swedish positive take on migration is brought even further by the UN Development Program, UNDP, which strongly argues that migration is a winwin proposition: migrants boost economic output, at little or no cost to locals [in the countries of destination]. Indeed, there may be broader positive effects, for instance when the availability of migrants for childcare allows resident mothers to work outside the home. […] In migrants’ countries of origin, the impacts of movement are felt in higher incomes and consumption, better education and improved health, as well as at a broader cultural and social level. (UNDP 2009:3) Or, to follow the lead of the World Bank, which concludes in similar jubilant terms that migration reduces poverty (although the poorest are not among the most frequent migrants), increases expenditure on health and education, intensifies construction activities, and reduces vulnerability as it is counter-cyclical (see the World Bank web site www.knomad.org). Such win-win arguments herald a new understanding of migration, migration is no longer only (or mostly) seen as a case of brain drain, where migrants take the education and the knowledge they have acquired at home and put them to use to their own benefit, and to the benefit of the countries of destination. While the countries and by implication, the people who have paid for the education, are left behind in abject misery. Piccture, for instance, the situation of Haiti – a case frequently referred to – with the world’s highest rate of high-skilled emigration. Today, migration is rather portrayed as a circular and mutually advantageous movement, whereby migrants after a (long or short) spell outside their native countries, and after remitting significant sums of money, return to their countries of origin, bringing rewards to both ends of the migration process. The varying takes on the phenomenon of migration, especially in connection with its impact on development of the countries of origin, have followed closely the changing understandings in development economics. In a Keynesian perspective, which dominated the first period after the Second world war (WWII) the functioning of the developmental state was considered key, and the fact that migration occurred was generally seen as indicating a failure on behalf of the state’s development efforts. 6 But with the advent of the neoliberal development agenda in the 1980s – the so called Washington Consensus – the importance of the private sector, and hence of individuals, as generators of development and growth took precedence. Migration now was recast as a generator of resources for the promotion of individuals and, indirectly, of societies. We may thus read the more recent win-win arguments in relation to migration – focussing as they do on migrant remittances – as a vindication of the neoliberal development view. See Table 1 for a summary of the main phases in the framing of migration and development. Table 1. Main phases in the framing of Migration and development post WWII Period Research community framing Keynesian until ca 1975–1980 Development optimism. Migration of surplus labour from underdeveloped to developed countries beneficial to both, but brain drain took a heavy toll on the developmental potential of poor countries. Neoliberal ca 1980–2000 Development pessimism: brain drain, weak governance, poor countries’ failure generates migration. But also rise of “New Economics of Labour Migration” stressing an integrated world economy, mutually beneficial relationships, agency of migrants. 2000 and beyond Win-win. Boom in attention and studies, more mixed positions but generally a positive view: remittances large and countercyclical, well used in countries of origin, circular migration, diasporas bring advantages to countries of origin. Adapted from De Haas 2008: Table 1. What is rarely discussed in this connection is the fact that migrants – we are here concerned with persons who migrate in order to find employment abroad, see Box 1 for delimitations – greatly contribute to the development of the destination societies. Indeed, an argument may be made to the effect that migrants “give” more than they “get”, and that therefore migration is part and parcel of a process of unequal exchange which will entrench the wide gaps in terms of social conditions, wealth, power, and general development characteristics separating the North from the South. This does not undermine the conclusion that migration may be beneficial to the migrants, to their families and to their societies of origin to the extent that economic, social and political “pay-back” occurs as a result of the migration. But reducing poverty does not amount to the same thing as closing the “development gap”. 7 Box 1. Delimitations and definitions In this report, migrants are defined following the 1990 UN “International Convention on the Protection of the Rights of All Migrant Workers and Members of Their Families” in the following way: “The term ‘migrant worker’ refers to a person who is to be engaged, is engaged or has been engaged in a remunerated activity in a State of which he or she is not a national” (Article 2.1). This delimitation has three implications. First, it disregards internal migration, which amounts to a little less than one billion people. It is the crossing of a border which constitutes the defining characteristic of the group of migrants which are focussed here. Secondly, this definition of migrants excludes refugees, that is, persons who are forced to leave their country of origin on account of persecution, war or catastrophes of various kinds. The rights of refugees are dealt with in separate international conventions, and their presence in safe havens should not be assessed in the same terms as migrant workers. Today, approximately 50 million people are refugees according to this definition, including internal refugees; most of them reside in the South. Lastly, the length of stay of the migrants are left out in contrast to other delimitations which require that a person in order to be considered a migrant spends at least 12 months in the country of destination. We need to be equally circumspect when deciding what to call the opposing poles of migration, from where it starts to where it (temporarily) ends: each dichotomy carries with it a statement of driver and logic of migration, an implicit identification of what it is that turns a person into a migrant. Are the countries from where migrants come to be called sender, home, or source countries? Are the countries at the other end of the migratory process to be branded receivers, host, or destination countries? By choosing the terms we want to apply, we may inadvertently make a statement of drivers and of agency, categorizing some countries as drivers while others become passive recipients which play no role in the migration process. For this report, the least loaded terms – countries of origin and countries of destination – are used, stressing the direction of movement, not the cause of migration. Similary, although imperfect and dated, I will use North to refer to countries of the OECD (including Europe, North America, Japan and Oceania), and South to denote the countries of Africa, Asia (with the stated exception) and Latin America. This partition is far from perfect, but statistical investigations mostly adhere to this, or similar, socio-geographical groupings of countries. Sources: UN 1990, UNESCO 2015. 8 MIGRATION: How many, origins, destinations Migration is certainly not a new phenomenon, but the attention given to migration and development by research and media has grown. In 1965, migrants totalled approximately 75 million persons (excluding internal migrants, 50 million of whom resided in what the South, with the remaining 25 million people living in the North (Hollifield 2006: Figure 2). At this stage, then, migration was primarily a movement of people from a poor country to one of its equally poor, and not too distant, neighbours. Over the following decades, the numbers increased, reaching almost 200 million by 2005; concomitantly, migration flows took on a clear South à North direction, with migrants to the North accounting for over half the total number. Migration thus increasingly mirrored the colonial pattern of sending minerals and agricultural products from the South to the North, and replicated, to state the obvious, the transfer of labour during the slave trade. In the period leading up to today, migration has continued to grow unabated, reaching 250 million by 2015. However, a new distinct geographic distribution of migrants has surfaced: today South à South is as important in terms of people (but not in remittances) as South à North migration, reflecting the growing economic importance of oil producing and fast growing economies of the South which import workers in large numbers for industrial and construction purposes as well as for domestic work. Hence, migration of our times is just as much a South à North as a SouthàSouth movement. 250 million migrants . . . with such an impressive figure it is easy to miss the point that migrants (as always, excluding internal migrants) do not account for more than 3 per cent of the global population, a share which in fact has remained stable since the aftermath of WWII. This indicates that in spite of the objective drivers of migration, almost everybody stays put in her or his jurisdiction of birth. The geographical distribution of migrant flows, however, is not the same thing as the distribution of migrant stocks, and the previous predominance of intra-regional and intra-continental migration still leaves its imprint on the geographical dispersal of migrant stocks. In four of the world’s continents, over half of the residing migrants have come from the same region, in Africa the share is as high as 82 per cent, see Table 2. Intra-regional, or intra-continental, migration is thus the rule rather than the exception, and migrants still live in proximity to their countries of origin, or at least on the same continent, the only exceptions being North America and Oceania. 9 Table 2. Migrant stocks in numbers and shares of intracontinental migration, 2013 Region Stock of migrants, millions Intra-continental migration, % Africa 19 82 Asia 71 76 Europe & Central Asia 72 52 Latin America 9 64 North America 53 2 8 14 Oceania Total 2013 232 Source: UN 2014: Table 1. Returning to the migration flows of today, “only” 43 per cent of Asian migrants stay in Asia, attracted primarily by South Korea, Hong Kong, China, Taiwan, as well as by Singapore, Thailand and Malaysia. This points in the direction of an increasing globalization of migration. On the other hand, in Africa most migration is still regional, Côte d’Ivoire being the most attractive destination country (receiving almost 8 per cent of all African migrants in 2010), followed by South Africa, Burkina Faso, Nigeria, Kenya, Sudan, Uganda, Tanzania, Libya, Ethiopia and Rwanda with 6 to 1 per cent of the migration flow. In fact, of the 20 most popular destination countries for African migrants, 11 were in Africa (Ratha & Plaza 2011:49). 10 emittances R – the origin of the win-win view Box 2. Defining migrant remittances Behind the growing interest, and the surge of the win-win migration discourse, there has been a growing realization of the importance of remittances which migration gives rise to; see Box 2 for definitions. The concept of migrant remittances is not difficult to grasp intuitively, and the International Organisation for Migration, IOM, simply defines it as “Monies earned or acquired by non-nationals that are transferred back to their country of origin”. A more technical definition is provided by the International Monetary Fund, IMF: “Personal remittances” are made up of transfers in cash or in kind by resident to non-resident households plus compensation to non-resident employees (that is to temporary or seasonal staff). Add social benefits (including future pension payments) and we get “Total remittances”, which is intended to capture all household income obtained from working abroad, including income to be received in the future. It should be noted that no distinction is made concerning the length of stay of the migrant, which is in conformity to the delimitation of Box 1 above. Sources: http://www.iom.int/key-migration-terms, http://www.imf.org/external/np/sta/bop/remitt.htm The amounts transferred have surpassed the growth in the number of migrants, compared to the early 1980s migrants’ official remittances had by the early 2000’s grown fivefold. The attention in the public sphere which this growth spawned is even more impressive: the number of journal articles increased 3o times ( 19802005, Carling 2007: Figure 1). The media attention thus grew six times faster than the actual remittances. Figure 1 sums up the picture. The most recent estimate of remittances to the South reaches the staggering sum of 450 billion USD for 2015 (World Bank 2015). Migrant remittances show three positive traits in comparison with other flows to the South. First, they are large and growing, today outdoing the volume of development aid three times over; the only sizeable flow which is even in the vicinity of the inflow of remittances are Foreign Direct Investments, FDI. Secondly, remittance flows are “unrequited”, that is they do not cause any reverse flow in the opposite direction. This compares favourably with FDI (where profits, dividends, and royalties may amount to just as much, or more, than the original investment) and debt (where interest and amortization likewise takes a heavy toll over the years, frequently surpassing the initial loan); not so when it comes remittances (Kapur 2005:333). 11 Figure 1: Financial flows to the South 1990-2014 Source: World Bank, http://blogs.worldbank.org/peoplemove/remittance-data-update-for-2011. Thirdly, migrants’ remittances are more stable and less sensitive to external shocks than most observers have postulated, not even the global financial meltdown of 2008 resulted in more than a minor dent in the rising remittance curve, much less volatile than FDIs and debt flows. It is therefore mysterious that the World Bank (2013), in its modelling of future financial flows to the South, pays but little attention to the role of migrants’ remittances (in contrast to the attention to migration paid by other branches of the World Bank). However, although migrants as a whole transfer impressive amounts, the macro data may hide the uneven distribution of remittances to receiving countries, see Figure 2. Two countries figure prominently, India and China, the two of them combined obtaining close to one third of total remittances globally. And the ten major remittance recipients together account for as much as 65 per cent of received remittance flows to the South, 281 billion USD out of a total of 435 billion USD in 2014. 12 Figure 2. Top receiving countries Source: World Bank 2015 But we should not focus only on the sums transferred, as remittances are most important to countries with limited resources (se Table 2). Although the absolute sums by comparison with the countries listed in Figure 2 are small, they nevertheless are crucial. Another way to gauge the importance of remittances is to compare them to export earnings: in over 20 countries of the South, migrant remittances exceed the foreign exchange earnings of their major commodity export (UNDP 2009:78). Table 3. The world’s most remittance dependent economies, 2013 Country Remittances received as share of GDP, % Tajikistan 49 Kyrgyz Republic 32 Nepal 29 Moldova 25 Tonga 24 Haiti 21 Armenia 21 Gambia 20 Lesotho 20 Samoa 20 Source: World Bank 2015 13 Another way of identifying the less-than-equal distribution of remittance flows is to register them according to the level of human development of the destination country (the yardstick used by the UNDP). Here, there exists an impressive mismatch between needs and available resources in the form of remittances: of total remittances 2007, only a meagre one per cent went to the countries with the lowest human development. This means that for this category of countries, aid dependency is still much more important than their reliance on remittances, with the latter accounting for only 15 per cent of the Official Development Assistance, ODA, they receive (UNDP 2009:78-9). 14 MIGRATION: From “drain on” to “source of” development – with a gendered gaze Case 1. Forced Remittances As noted, our attention should not only focus countries when it comes to assessing migration, as if states sent and received people, remittances, and returnees. Rather, we should pay attention to the fact that migration is about individuals moving, looking for work, and transferring part of their income to families and dependents in the countries of origin. It is the links between these processes, mostly driven by individual initiative and decisions, and the general implications for the societies of origin as well as destination, which should catch our attention. This may sound self-evident, but there has nevertheless existed a tendency, at least in the economics literature, to concentrate on whether migration is good or bad for development of countries and the economy as such. While the equally central issue of whether migration may be an effective way to improve living conditions of the migrants and the migrants’ families has been neglected, or added as a secondary consideration. Worse still, some governments have gone as far as to question the rights of migrants to keep the pay they receive for their work, wanting to make sure that (part of ) the income was spent in the country of origin rather than in the country where the migrants stayed, or that the migrants were forced to return “home” in order to reap what they had sown (see Case 1). Before and after WWII, many migrants were ruled by policies designed to ensure a return flow to the migrants’ countries of origin. For instance, US employers of Jamaican migrants were required to deposit 20 per cent of the wages due in a Jamaican savings bank, money which could only be accessed once the migrants had returned. Likewise, during the first years after WWII, 10 per cent of the wages of Mexican braceros (seasonal manual labour employed in Californian agriculture) were sent by the US employer to the Bank of Mexico in a scheme which combined forced savings with an attempt to secure that the braceros returned to Mexico after terminating their stint in the US. However, when the returnees demanded the money owed to them, the Bank of Mexico had no record of ever receiving it, nor could the handler, Wells Fargo, prove that transfers had in fact been made. It was to take until 2005 before the Mexican government agreed to pay compensation to 49 000 claimants (out of a total of over 200 000 migrants who claimed that their money had been seized, many of which could not provide the required documents to prove their case). Sources: IOM 2013, World Bank 2014. Realizing the potential of the remittance flows changed government attitudes towards migration and migrants. After spending decades lamenting the brain drain caused by the emigration of highly educated Indians, migrants were suddenly depicted as “angels of development” (Castles 2007: 271). Rajiv Gandhi, then prime minister of India, is reported to have claimed for his country the income earned by Indian migrants, in a stand which mirrors the effective forced remittance procedures described in Case 1, above: Indian migrants were considered as a bank “from which one could make withdrawals from time to time” (Carling 2007:58). Although it is certainly nicer to be seen as contributing to the development of one’s country of origin than as “draining” it, the migrants themselves run the risk of seeing the money they remit seized by the government in the name of the “national interest” or “development”. 15 In a similar turn, the World Bank has come around to championing migration as a boost to development, most recently in a “Global Knowledge Partnership on Migration and Development”, Knomad: At the household level, remittances have reduced poverty in many developing countries, and have raised expenditures on investment, health services, and schooling, while also enabling households to diversify their vulnerability to risks such as drought, famines and natural disasters. At the macroeconomic level, remittances can provide a relatively stable source of external finance compared to debt and portfolio equity flows (Knomad 2015) However, with phrases such as “At the household level”, the true complex nature of what takes place within a household is obfuscated. Most importantly, there is a tendency to counter-pose “productive” to “unproductive” expenses disclosing a clear gender bias. Reproductive costs of a family are relegated to the category “unproductive”, and thus seen as less “development-friendly” than spending migrants’ remittances on acquiring land, investing in agriculture, or starting a business (Mahler & Pessar 2006:45-6). Likewise, the household metaphor tends to hide the true nature of the gendered division of labour within households. On average, women make up half the number of migrants globally, and in many cases, such as Peru, Cape Verde, the Philippines, the Dominican Republic and Sri Lanka, they constitute the majority (Calavita 2006:118). Still, the “household” is constructed as an entity where men migrate and women stay behind (Mahler & Pessar 2006:27-28). The growing role of female migrants should be seen against the gendered global labour market, especially when it comes to the service sectors. This is especially clear in the “global care chain”: as retrenchments and cut-downs in the public sector take place in the North, migration provides domestic servants and public care-takers at affordable costs (to the employers, to the public sector), constituting a gendered and socially stratified global division of labour, fuelling migration for longer or shorter durations (Piper 206:145-6). Here, the governments of the countries of origin are often complicit in the establishment of this global network, most blatantly, perhaps. In the Philippines where recruiting agencies were established in order to provide “a hardworking, submissive and obedient domestic helper”, including promoting Filipina workers with light complexion, as the targeted employers might feel resistance, (it was assumed), to contract “dark-skinned” nannies (Mahler & Pessar 2006:49). 16 What does migration contribute? Individual perspectives One of the major factors driving migration is the large wage differences for jobs with similar qualifications in countries of origin and destination. These gaps are indeed significant, and “movers have much higher incomes than stayers”, according to the UNDP. A migrant who moves from a country with low human development (the indicator the UNDP uses to classify countries) to an OECD country increases her/his monthly income by over 1 000 USD. For high-skilled migrants – physicians, nurses, engineers, teachers – the prospects of migration are even better, and moving from low to high human development countries for one of these categories would increase monthly earnings by approximately 3 300 USD (income adjusted to purchasing power parity; UNDP 2009:50). No similar improvement by staying put in the country of origin is to be foreseen for poor people, even if we assume a pro-poor, anti-poverty policy implemented by a reliable, competent and benevolent government. To take but a few examples of the benefits reaped by the migrants (culled from Clemens et al. 2008, and IOM 2013): • Just through a couple of weeks on the US labour market, migrants from Bangladesh, Indonesia, Bolivia or Kenya will improve their lot by as much as: improved access to micro-credit, improved schooling, and improved health status combined could achieve in their respective countries of origin over their entire life spans. • A Bolivian worker moving to the USA will increase his/her estimated earnings by a factor 0f 2.7; an average Nigerian by as much as 8.4 times. • A nurse who moves to the USA from the Philippines will increase her/his earnings twentyfold compared to the urban areas of his/her country of origin, and by as much as 35 times compared to rural settings. One outcome of this is that Filipino physicians are said to be re-training in order to be able to emigrate as nurses and thus increase their income by a factor of four (compared with what they make as medical doctors in the Philippines). Similar drivers of migration also exist within the European union as well as in Ethiopia, see Cases 2 and 3. 17 Case 2. Roma migrants in Spain, Italy, and Scandinavia After the accession of Romania and Bulgaria to the European Union in 2007, Roma migrants have sought out EU countries for mostly short-term migratory moves. Surveys of Roma migrants in Spain and Italy, carried out in 2011, indicate that migrants remit significant amounts to their families, but they also show that the standing of Roma migrants differs in important ways from one destination country to another. The picture is far from clear: Roma in Spain transferred an average of 570 euro annually, while Roma in Italy remitted as much as 1 400 euros. One explanation for this difference may be that Roma in Spain are better integrated and live safer lives – judging from their housing situation, access to social security and legal status – compared to Roma in Italy. Thus, one may speculate, Roma in Spain may have a longer time horizon for their stay, leading them to adopt a more long-term strategy, while Roma in Italy may play it safe by transferring more at an early stage, as their situation may be more insecure. A recent survey of over 1 000 Romanian, mostly Roma, migrants in Oslo, Copenhagen and Stockholm, shows that the sums the migrants manage to get by street begging are quite limited, a daily average of 130 SEK (approximately 14 USD) was reported. Still, such amounts are enough to “make the difference between food and no food, health service and no health service, school or no school” in the migrants’ communities of origin in Romania. In addition to paying for essentials such as these, the migrants’ earnings were spent on food and clothes, and in maintaining their houses; a considerable share of the income was used to pay for the transfer from Romania to Scandinavia and back, and to pay off debt. Source: Vlase & Preoteasa 2011, Djufve et al. 2015. Although some of these examples may be exceptional, it is difficult to disagree with the following general conclusion, at least in the short run, which to most migrants probably is the most important consideration: no existing policy carried out [in the country of origin] can benefit the marginal poor household as much as one year of access to the US labor market. (Clemens et al. 2008:41) In fact, migration can be seen as an investment strategy pursued by people in poor countries, one with the highest possible rates of return: Migrants from poor to rich countries can multiply their real earning potential by between 3 and 10 times. […] the most lucrative investment available to many of the poor. (Clemens & Ogden 2014: 13, 17) The significance of viewing migration this way – as an investment, as a strategy used by people to improve their prospects and living conditions in the countries of origin as well as in the countries of destination – is brought home by comparing the real wage – i.e. the nominal wage expressed in purchasing power terms – for similar trades that the migrants can earn in the centres of origin and destination. For instance, a construction worker makes nine times as much in 18 London as in Nairobi, a skilled industrial labourer increases her/his wage fourfold by moving from New Delhi to New York, an engineer is rewarded four times more in London than in Beijing (Milanovic 2011: Table 1). This is one aspect of the potential win-win-win nature of international migration: it improves the living conditions of the migrants, at least in monetary terms, and simultaneously decreases the global income gap. Case 3. Migrating from Ethiopia According to a recent survey, emigration from Ethiopia has changed its characteristics, and thus that of the Ethiopian diaspora: what started out mostly as emigration of well-educated male political refugees has today increasingly become female migrants looking for domestic jobs in the Middle East and in neighbouring Sudan. The dominant reason stated for migrating to the Middle East and Africa was looking for work, while the migrants who opted for the OECD also gave education and family unification as driver for migrating. 60 per cent of surveyed Ethiopian migrants transfer money to their families in Ethiopia, the share is lowest for migrants in Africa. The remitting frequency increased with the time the migrants had spent abroad, indicating that the first use of migrants’ earnings is repayment of the cost of migration. Remittances received amounted to 875 USD per family on average, but twice that amount from migrants in the OECD, and less than that for migrants in Africa. 45 per cent of the remittances received were spent on daily consumption needs, and only small amounts were set aside for education or other investments; only rarely did remittances finance repayment of loans and social expenses (such as weddings, funerals). Source: Andersson 2015. Cost of remitting A drain on the resources which migration generates which is suffered by most migrants is caused by the high charges that banks and financial institutions levy on the transfer to the country of origin. A publicly embraced goal of reducing the costs in 5 years to 5 per cent has been set, but is yet to be realized. The Sustainable Development Goals – agreed by the UN in September 2015 – include an objective of further reducing the transfer costs to 3 per cent. See Case 4. 19 Case 4. Migration and the link to the Post 2015 Agenda: Sustainable Development Goals and Financing for Development The Post 2015 Agenda consists of the two processes of Sustainable Development Goals, SDGs, and Financing for Development, FfD, adopted in 2015. During the Post 2015 process, global civil society organisations, CSOs, have urged for an enhanced focus on migration and migrant’s rights in relation to development. Migrant’s remittances, migrant workers or migrant’s creation of jobs exemplifies areas where there is a prerequisite to advance towards a sustainable, people-centred development. Remittances are often defined as drivers of economic development, although neglected in the development context while linking social and personal costs with migration. Similarly, in the synthesis report “The Road to Dignity by 2030”, UN Secretary Ban Ki-Moon repeatedly emphasize the importance of migrants and migration. In September 2015, the UN member states agreed on the Sustainable Development Goals. In a large participatory process, a new set of goals was developed to replace the Millennium Development Goals, MDGs from 2000. Notably, the MDGs failed to fully include and integrate migrants and the link between development, human rights and migration. The SDGs will implement the MDGs that were not yet fulfilled and the new goals are universal and comprehensive, to be achieved by 2030. Commonly recognised as the ‘Agenda 2030’, the declaration includes 17 goals and 169 targets. In particular, Paragraph 29 incorporates migration and the rights of migrants in the declaration: “We recognize the positive contribution of migrants for inclusive growth and sustainable development. We also recognize that international migration is a multidimensional reality of major relevance for the development of countries of origin, transit and destination, which requires coherent and comprehensive responses. We will cooperate internationally to ensure safe, orderly and regular migration involving full respect for human rights and the humane treatment of migrants regardless of migration status, of refugees and of displaced persons. Such cooperation should also strengthen the resilience of communities hosting refugees, particularly in developing countries. We underline the right of migrants to return to their country of citizenship, and recall that States must ensure that their returning nationals are duly received.” (Draft outcome document of the United Nations summit for the adoption of the post-2015 development agenda, Paragraph 29) Despite civil society efforts, the declaration lacks a strong language in the perspective of labour rights, as fair treatment of migrants should have been incorporated into the declaration in order to meet the human rights obligations of the signatory states. In the overall declaration of the SDGs, migration and migrants are not fully capitalised nor put in the factual framework. Rather, the issues of migration and migrants are constrained to only be visible under Paragraph 29 and Goal 10 – ‘Reduce inequality within and among countries’. Goals 10 indicates that UN member states should: ”Facilitate orderly, safe, regular and responsible migration and mobility of people, including through the implementation of planned and well-managed migration policies” (Draft outcome document of the United Nations summit for the adoption of the post-2015 development agenda, Paragraph 10.7) 20 Subsequently under Goal 10, the only quantified objective to be found in the SDGs is regarding remittances. Goal 10 shows that: “By 2030, reduce to less than 3 per cent the transaction costs of migrant remittances and eliminate remittance corridors with costs higher than 5 per cent.” (Draft outcome document of the United Nations summit for the adoption of the post-2015 development agenda, Paragraph 10c) The Post 2015 agenda will design and implement a framework of indicators that will be a key to provide reliable information for follow-up and review. Indicators will be developed during Autumn 2015 and agreed upon during Spring 2016. The Third International Conference on Financing for Development was held in Addis Ababa in July 2015. The UN member states agreed on the outcome of the Financing for Development in the Addis Ababa Action Agenda (AAAA). AAAA is set to be the framework on how to finance the SDGs and development. AAAA makes two explicit references to migration in terms of remittances and transaction costs and as a multidimensional reality of development. Paragraph 111 initiates, in less concrete terms, to facilitate the portability of earned social benefits. These include circular migration and recognition of foreign qualifications and skills, which would ease access to the formal labour market. In comparison with the SDGs, remittances and transaction costs are further detailed in Paragraph 40 of the AAAA. Additionally, a positive contribution of migrants for inclusive growth are recognized as well as a statement that remittances cannot be equated to other international financial flows such as foreign direct investment, ODA or other public funding’s. Paragraph 40 indicates: “[…] We will work to ensure that adequate and affordable financial services are available to migrants and their families in both home and host countries. We will work towards reducing the average transaction cost of migrant remittances by 2030 to less than 3 per cent of the amount transferred. We are particularly concerned with the cost of remittances in certain low-volume and high-cost corridors. We will work to ensure that no remittance corridor requires charges higher than 5 per cent by 2030, mindful of the need to maintain adequate service coverage, especially for those most in need. We will support national authorities to address the most significant obstacles to the continued flow of remittances, such as the trend of banks withdrawing services, to work towards access to remittance transfer services across borders. […]” (Addis Ababa Action Agenda, Paragraph 40) Emelie Aho, Policy Advisor on Swedish Development and Aid, Forum Syd Today, the transfer cost is still 8 per cent on average (with a weighted average of 6 per cent), but the cost of remitting to poorer countries of origin is higher than the average Remittances to Sub-Saharan Africa are charged an average of 12 per cent, and some exceptional “transfer corridors” charge as much as 20 per cent. Although the situation has improved, the value lost in transfer is still huge, approximately 36 billion USD (World Bank 2015, 2015b). A related issue is how unfavourable and unforeseeable exchange rates moves, when the currencies of the major countries of destination fall, migrants lose significant amounts (World Bank 2015:6); this constitutes a clear risk borne by the migrants alone. 21 What does migration contribute? National perspectives Apart from the huge sums concerned in migration remittances, their rela-tive stability is a beneficial trait to the countries of origin (see Figure 1): remittances have proved more stable even during the global financial crisis than other flows (with the exception of ODA). The resilience of remittances is a general phenomenon. While capital flows decline on average by 15 per cent during the first year of a “sudden stop period” – a nice euphemism for “crisis” – and then goes on to fall another 10 per cent in the following year, remittances instead as a rule increase by 7 and 6 per cent, respectively (World Bank 2015a:177). A close examination, based on a case study of migrant remittances from Italy, bears this out in greater detail (Bettin et al. 2014). Firstly, and perhaps not so surprising, remittances from Italy 2005-2011 to 87 countries of origin turned out to be counter-cyclical and increased when conditions in the countries of origin deteriorated. Remittances thus managed to alleviate the distress at the point of origin, for instance when terms of trade moved against the exports of the economy of origin, or when a natural catastrophe had struck there. Secondly, and more importantly, when both the economies of origin and destination were affected by the same negative shock, migrants nevertheless upheld their solidarity with their place of origin. In fact, during the 2008 financial crisis and its aftermath, remittances grew a little faster than before. The conclusion seems unavoidable: remittances contribute to ease the consequences of financial turmoil and economic downturn as far as the impact on the countries of origin is concerned. Nevertheless, dependence on one source may constitute a risk for the countries of origin, in addition to the risk of fluctuating exchange rates noted above. For instance, when the value of remittances transferred by Moroccan migrants from the Netherlands fell by close to 60 per cent 2001-2004, the impact in Morocco was quite severe, just as when Turkish migrants in Germany transferred 80 per cent less in 2004 compared to two years earlier (Carling 2007:56-7). A related issue has to do with how remittances are spent, whether they are put to “good use” or not. As we have seen, from the perspective of the individual migrant, the evidence points in a favourable direction, migrants’ families spend the money well. How beneficial migrants’ remittances are for the general development of the country as a whole is however a different matter, and one that is not easy to address. From a national perspective, a way to assess the potential of remittances is to make the unlikely assumption that they would entirely be used to finance investments. Given the volume of migrant remittances, the potential is staggering: if remittances to Sub-Saharan Africa, SSA, were comprehensively turned into investments, the SSA investment rate would rise by as much as 40 per cent, from 21 to 30 per cent of GDP (World Bank 2011). However, to calculate the prospective benefits of migration for the general development of the countries of origin in this way is totally unrealistic, since the actual funds transferred rest – or should rest – in the hands of a multitude of migrants and their families, to be used as they see fit. One consequence of migrants transferring significant sums of money, is that the local banking system may develop, which would benefit also non-migrants who need to access finance for various investment purposes. The potential use of migrants to the societies of origin has however wrongly been focussed on the financial aspects of migration, while there are other circumstances to factor in when it comes to assessing the impact of existing migrant commun- 22 ities in countries of destination, so called diasporas. In addition to financial benefits, social and even political “remittances” can play a key role in stimulating development and positive change in the countries and communities of origin; see Case 5 for the Somali example. Case 5. The Somali Diaspora: monetary, social and political remittances The various diasporas of Somalia annually transfer approximately 1.6 billion USD, amounting to 45 per cent of the country’s GDP. This greatly exceeds the total sum for humanitarian aid to Somalia, which reached 800 million USD at its highest. Also in Sweden, the Somalian diaspora is active when it comes to mobilizing capital and human resources. More than 800 Diaspora Civil Society Organisations, CSO, which promote and engage in relief and developmental assistance in Somalia and Somaliland are registered in Sweden alone. Each year, the Somalian diaspora in Sweden remit 60 million USD to relatives in Somalia and Somaliland; this is almost twice as much as Swedish development assistance to the country, and enough to feed 100,000 families. Diaspora communities in the Netherlands, Germany, the United Kingdom, and the USA remit several times this amount each year. Remittances make a significant contribution to Somali household income and food security. In Puntland and Somaliland, an estimated 40 per cent of families depend on remittances to meet their daily food security needs. The money sent to Somalia by the diaspora have contributed to poverty reduction and thus to achieving the Millennium Development Goals, MDG. They have been used for food, health care, housing, development, training and support to family members. The diaspora is often the only body that continuously supports a specific area or community. Since members of the diaspora possess a deep understanding of the context and of their country of origin, their work is based on local needs and conditions. This is why many states and international organisations are turning their attention to the role of diasporas in the development of their countries of origin: diasporas constitute an efficient and effective complement to international cooperation to reduce poverty around the world Besides financial contributions, the diasporas also support development and poverty reduction by transferring new knowledge, experiences, techniques and contacts. When migrants return, for however short a time, they bring with them the knowledge and experience they have acquired. An example that illustrates the role of the Somalian diaspora in transferring knowledge is the work of the Somali-Swedish Researchers Association. The organisation is composed of Swedish Somalia medical researchers who work on a broad front with different local actors to influence clan leaders, birth attendants and religious groups to ban female genital mutilation. Again, the Swedish case is illustrative: the Somali-Swedish Researchers Association has together with the local organisation drafted a proposition for the Somaliland parliament on the prohibition of female genital mutilation. The proposition is currently under consideration by the parliament. Similarly, the doctors, psychologists and scientists within Swedish Somali Research Association, are continuing its efforts with Amoud University to improve health care for mothers and infants by producing a training programme for midwives. This will enable women to claim their fundamental rights to health, and to take part in the decisions that affect their own health and that of their children, as well as providing training to their colleagues with knowledge on providing affordable psychological treatment. 23 In addition to knowledge and contacts, diasporas contribute social and political ”remittances”, that is they bring political and social norms and standards to their countries of origin. For a long time, members of the diaspora have been returning to Somalia and Somaliland to take part in the development of the countries. The involvement of the diaspora in Somalia dramatically increased since the Arta peace conference held in Djibouti in 2000 which provided a real opportunity for the diaspora to play a meaningful role in Somali national politics. The Somalia and Somaliland diasporas have actively taken a role in this development process. The Diaspora is a driving force in steering the countries away from the monopoly of the armed groups and aiding in empowering unarmed civic actors and in supporting the growth of CSO. In the case of Somaliland, the diaspora has always played an important role in the political destiny of the country. For example, two of the main political parties in the were founded in the diaspora, Justice and Welfare Party, founded in 2001 by Faysal Ali who still is chairman of the party, and Wadani, founded by Abdirahman Mohamed Abdullahi, also today the chairman. In general, about half of the men who make up the governing bodies of Somalia and Somaliland – heads of state, prime ministers, ministers on national as well as on provincial level – come from the diaspora. The role of the diasporas in the parliaments is impressive, especially in Somalia where diaspora members constitute 50 per cent, although their presence is considerably less in the regional assemblies (Ismail 2011). Text: Mussie Ephrem, Project Support Officer, The Horn of Africa and Kenya, Forum Syd. 24 Risks and drawbacks of migration: individual and national perspectives Migrants lead dangerous and precarious lives. The migrant card is frequently played when countries enter dire straits, or when political discontent has to be re-directed: blame the foreigner, the migrant, the minority, for taking the job, or for eroding a supposedly homogenous culture by bringing “foreign” elements and concepts into the mainstream. Large-scale and sweeping expulsions may follow. For instance the ousting of Nigerians from Ghana in the late 1960s, the expulsion of Ghanaians from Nigeria in the 1980s, the closing of the border by apartheid South Africa to Mozambican and other Frontline states’ migrants to the South African mines and farms following the downfall of Portuguese fascism in the late 1970s and early 1980s, or the expulsion of 800 000 Yemeni migrants from Saudi Arabia. More recently, Singapore has tightened its immigration regulation and is now forcing employers to give priority to Singaporean labour before they turn to immigrants, an indication of what may come to pass also in Europe (World Bank 2015:7). However, the fact that migrant remittances were upheld in the aftermath of the financial crisis of 2008, in spite the many forecasts that migrants would be the first to lose their jobs, indicates that the global economy has entered a new phase where migrant labour simply is essential to the workings of the system, turning the idea of forcefully evicting millions of migrants from the economic centres of the world into an unrealistic proposition, no matter how much xenophobic sentiment in destination countries may be mobilized. Brain drain/gain/waste The most important – and studied – drawback in connection with migration is the cost of losing educated and resource-rich people, two assets which are much in demand in the countries of origin. Such “brain drain” has been a frequent argument against the potential benefits of emigration, basically arguing that it is only the countries of destination which profit from migration. In a classic economics textbook from the 1950s, Theory of Economic Growth, written by the Nobel laureate W Arthur Lewis, himself originally from Saint Lucia, the “economic difficulty” of emigration is framed thus: The largest proportion of emigrants consists of people in the twenties and thirties. The country has to bear the cost of rearing and educating them, only to lose them when they reach working age. (Lewis 1954:360) A mitigating factor, Lewis recognized, consisted of the flow of remittances arising from these educated and well-trained emigrants, thus presaging what later was to become the dominant strand in the migration-development discourse (see Table 1, above). It should also be noted that brain drain may not be permanent, that is educated and skilled emigrants return to their countries of origin, sometimes in a circular pattern of migration, at other times on a more permanent note. It has been assessed that about half of skilled migrants return after approximately five years abroad (UNDP 2009:77). Recent studies confirm the importance of the brain drain phenomenon (here defined as migrants with post-high school education, which probably is too narrow a definition since secondary school as well as vocational training qualifications in many instances must be considered a scarce resource) – to the countries of destination. In 2000, 62 per cent of the skilled migrants (that is, 25 migrants holding post-secondary school education) to the OECD came from the South. This also means that skilled persons in the South have higher emigration rates than the population in general, 7 per cent against 1.5 per cent of the respective groups. For some regions, the emigration rate for skilled migrants (following the above definition of highly-skilled) is striking, especially in the Caribbean with 43 per cent of the skilled population abroad stands out, but also Sub-Saharan Africa (with 13 per cent) and Central America (17 per cent) testify to the importance of the brain drain. A telling fact is that highly-educated women have a greater propensity to migrate than their male counterparts, this holds for Afghanistan as well as for Ghana and Guatemala; the explanation could be that women have greater difficulties than men of finding suitable employment without migrating (UNDP 2009:77). Brain drain is the most serious for countries with small populations: countries with less than 2.5 million people had a brain drain rate of 28 per cent (that is 28 per cent of their skilled population had emigrated), and for countries with 2.5 to 10 million people, the rate was 15 per cent. Similarly for individual countries, brain drain may be the dominating aspect of migration, for instance for Haiti (with 83 per cent of its highly skilled population abroad), Sierra Leone (49 per cent) and Ghana (45 per cent; Docquier et al. 2007, Docquier & Rapoport 2012). These are exceptional cases, however, and the significance of brain drain on countries of origin on average is still hotly debated (except in such extreme cases as mentioned above). For instance, if the alternative for high-skilled migrants is to remain at home without any prospects of finding a suitable employment, migration will be a win-win proposition. Today, the migration literature tends to consider not only brain drain but also brain gain: as the prospect of migration increasingly lies within the reach of ever more people. The drive to acquire the knowledge and training which is valued in the immigration countries strengthens the local urge to study and to gain practical experience, an indirect brain gain opened up through the prospect of future migration (Sandefur 2014). Thus, emigration may be accompanied by a boost in education in the country of origin. In addition, a study of 33 000 migrants in 11 major destination countries shows that higher education leads to larger remittances (Bollard et al. 2011, which contradicts the much quoted OECD 2007 report, which claimed that low skilled migrants remit more than higher skilled). The difference is substantial to the benefit of the higher educated: while the average annual sum remitted (the country studies are mostly from 2005–2007) is about 730 USD, the higher educated send 40 per cent more, approximately 1 000 USD. On the other hand, if well qualified and educated migrants do not end up holding appropriate jobs, the potential of brain gain will partly be lost. The evidence in this respect is that over-qualification – the OECD-term for having more education than a specific position requires – is common in countries of destination. Worse, and testifying to discrimination on the labour market: in every single one of 25 OECD countries, immigrants had higher rates of over-qualification than natives, most notably so in Sweden (see Case 6). Thus, we may talk of migration constituting a “brain waste” as the positions migrants get frequently do not match their qualifications (Castles & Ozkul 2014:45). But also here it must be remembered that similar situations of “waste” exist also in the countries of origin, irrespective of if people choose to migrate or not. 26 Case 6. Migrants on Sweden’s labour market One of the central issues concerning migrants and employment is whether the jobs migrants acquire match their qualifications. In Sweden, the degree of over-qualification (defined as a person having two more years of schooling than required for the position she/he holds) among migrants is frighteningly high: 7 out of 10 Latin American, and 6 out of 10 African and Asian immigrants were over-qualified in 2010-2012. The situation is not unique, but Sweden is exceptional in that the over-qualification rate for migrants was 2.5 times higher than for natives in 2000, and this gap is the widest in all of OECD. The explanation is that migrants in Sweden to a relatively high degree are political refugees, who are comparatively well-educated, while they for socio-psychological and xenophobic reasons, have difficulties to find jobs which match their qualifications. An important issue is how long it takes before migrants manage to get a foothold on the open labour market. Although most migrants – irrespective of their geographic origin – find employment eventually, migrants from Africa remain outside formal employment for twice as long as migrants coming from the EU, four as compared to two years on average. Sweden stands out also in the sense that migrants in Sweden may remain unemployed to a much greater extent than in most other European countries, also after living in Sweden for ten years. In addition to the high degree of refugees among migrants to Sweden – approximately twice as high as in other European countries – the structure of the Swedish labour market, with its low degree of unqualified jobs – keeps new migrants in unemployment to an unusually high degree. Still, there also exists an important component of discrimination, as evidenced by the practice of job seekers to adopt “Swedish-sounding” surnames, which has proven conducive both to gain employment and higher wages. Sources: Le Grand & Karlsson (nd), Andersson Joona et al. 2012, OECD 2007, Karlsson & Tibajev 2014, Szulkin 2012, Lundborg 2012. The main point here is not only the inequity of the situation but equally that over-qualification among migrants is common, albeit within a wide span. Of the foreign-born immigrants 20-25 per cent were over-qualified in Australia, Canada, Germany and Italy, while the worst cases were Greece and Spain with over 40 per cent; in the UK, USA, and Sweden, the over-qualification rate was below 20 per cent (OECD 2007: Table II.2). So, although the relative difference between natives and immigrants is the widest in Sweden when it comes to over-qualification, the overall level of over-qualification is not the worst. Charges imposed on migrants We have seen that migrants potentially stand to reap large, not to say huge, increases in earnings simply by moving from country of origin to country of destination, but there are also economic costs involved (leaving aside psychosocial and emotional downsides). Migrants frequently have to pay to arrange their transfer to the country of destination, (and we also know from daily catastrophes in the Mediterranean, that all too frequently they have to pay the highest price, death). Transfer charges are substantial, also for legal migrants who go through public channels. Adding the fees charged by recruitment agencies, transporters, medical examinations, passports and visas, the costs on average amounts to 3 000 USD (with variations, see World Bank 2012: Table 3). 27 Such costs take a considerable chunk off the earnings of each individual migrant, and the pay-back period can be as long as the entire first year’s income, or more. For instance, an average Indonesian migrant to Taiwan would need 14 months to pay for her/his transfer expenses, and a Bangladeshi construction worker in the Middle East will only be able to recover the transfer costs after 15 months (with a monthly wage of 200 USD). In the meantime, the migrants run up debts for accommodation, food, and other daily expenses, which all means that they will have to spend maybe the first two years just to reach break-even (UNDP 2009: Figure 3.6). Still, these figures are serious underestimates of the actual costs for some of the migrants. Evidence from Sweden point to the fact that migrants pay as much as 15 000 USD (120 000 SEK) in order to reach the Swedish border, most of this is the cost of obtaining a fake Swedish passport (DN 2015). The remainder of the cost is charged by the smugglers, who, as has become evident especially for the migration “corridor” over the Mediterranean, nevertheless endanger the very lives of the migrants they exploit. 28 Putting the picture together Table 4. Mis- and preconceptions vs Facts While the jubilant pro-migration position is far from the whole truth concerning the Migration – Development Nexus, it has nevertheless rightfully become part of – but not equal to – our understanding of the potential of migration in terms of its contribution to survival strategies for individuals, families and households, as well as for entire societies and nations. Table 4, below, is an attempt to put the picture together by debunking some mis- and pre-conceptions which are endemic in the literature, and above all in public discourses as it is reflected in media reporting on migration. Issue Mis- and Pre-conception Facts Migration and Development Poor countries are sending, rich countries are receiving. Some countries like China and India are simultaneously countries of origin and destination. Proximity between origin and destination countries is an important factor in deciding migratory flows. Gender of migrants Most migrants are men, women stay at home and receive in the best of cases remittances. Migrants are almost equally divided between men and women; some “migration corridors” are dominated by women, for instance domestic work in the Middle East, Ethiopian domestic workers in Sudan. Direction of migration Migration is South à North, driven by the pull of wealth and the push of poverty. South à South migration (37 per cent of total) is equally important in numbers as South à North (35 per cent) in 2013. North à North migration accounted for 28 per cent of total migration flows in 2013. Remittance flows Remittances flow North à South. Remittances South à South (34 per cent) are as important as North à South (38 per cent) in 2014. Remittances North à North accounted for 28 per cent of total in 2014. Importance of remittances The large receivers are the major emigration countries of the South. Yes, but remittances are more important to small economies which export a relatively large shares of their populations. Relative prominence of migration, I The number of migrants is high at 250 million. Yes, but the number of migrants has remained stable for decades at around 3 per cent of global population. Small countries are more dependent on migration than populous in relative terms. Relative prominence of migration, II Countries of origin are totally dependent on their emigrants. Emigrant stocks may reach 9 per cent of population of sending countries (Sri Lanka mostly to Saudi Arabia) but is usually much lower: The Philippines 5 per cent, South Korea 4 per cent (mostly to the USA). 29 Brain drain? Countries of origin loose high-skilled labour. Yes, but also in countries with the highest rates of skilled migration, the number of students in secondary and tertiary education increase. This also holds true for the worst case, Haiti. Sources: World Bank 2015, Sandefur 2014. A new context, a new future As we have seen, the attention accorded to the Migration and Development Nexus, although not novel, has grown concomitant with the realization that huge volumes of migrant remittances are flowing continuously from the North to the South (as well as within the South, a fact which however goes underreported), and that these flows continue also in the face of financial and economic crises. But this is not the only explanation why Migration and Development has become a hot topic. The resurgence of the debate concerning Migration and Development has also a lot to do with the growing nationalism which has made itself felt in Europe during the last decades (witness the rise of xenophobic and ultranationalist parties in Denmark, Finland, France, Hungary, Italy, the Netherlands, Norway, Sweden, unfortunately the list can be made longer). One prominent representative of the anti-migration trend is, surprisingly, the renowned development economist Paul Collier, known for his compassion for the poorest people on the planet, the bottom billion (to quote the title of one of his books). Collier has recently come out in favour of preserving the ethnic homogeneity of countries as “high diversity has been a handicap […] in most societies for most of history” (Collier 2013:272). Consequently, he advocates a cap on migration and that destination countries should select and favour the most productive and highest educated for admittance. This, he claims, is an act of “compassion”, as otherwise hundreds of millions of people would swamp the rich countries, and compete against each other for the few jobs there are. Collier reaches this conclusion with the help of a poll where 40 per cent of the respondents in the South say they would like to migrate to the North if only they could. It follows, he alleges, that emigration from poor countries will “accelerate” until the South is “substantially depopulated” (Collier 2013:251). At the other extreme, a pro-migration stance may be construed to reach the equally mis-leading conclusion that emigration always is beneficial, and that no positive moves are needed in order to protect the rights and interests of migrants. This is evident from the piece of advice offered by World Bank in a new study of what policies work to enhance the positive impact of migration. The recommendation provided by the World Bank is that countries of destination should abstain from according labour rights and minimum wage protection to migrants, since this “reduces the opportunity to migrate”. And following the same logic, both emigration and immigration countries are told to avoid spending too much time on language training of migrant workers as such support only comes “at relatively high costs” (McKenzie & Yang 2014: 31). The stance is difficult to square with the World Bank’s alleged commitment to promote human rights However, we need not end up in either of these camps – closing the borders to migration, or refusing migrants’ elementary social and human rights – a middle ground certainly exist, where migration can be made mutually 30 advantageous to migrants and their families as well as to the countries of origin and destination. Win-Win I: Diasporas and Home Town Associations One way to make sure there is a win-win-win situation concerning migratory flows is to stimulate the creation and activities of Home Town Associations. The diaspora organisations keep their social, cultural, economic and emotional links to their countries and communities of origin (see Case 5 for the Somali Case). Studies show that the will to keep the linkages with history and one’s origin do not wane significantly over time – at least not for the first generations of migrants– but may on the contrary be strengthened as immigrant communities become more established and better-off (Portes 2007: 25). Also, the increased frequency of circular migration – where migrants move back and forth between countries of origin and destination – testifies to the possibilities to keep up the contacts. The establishment of “migrant corridors” – more or less official routes of access for migrants from countries of origin to countries of destination– have often been combined with local community work. A characteristic noted already for the early waves of immigration to the United States, where mostly women, (for instance in Chicago in the late 19th and early 20th centuries, made sure that schools, churches and philanthropic groups were organised, thus creating a kind of “ethnic public sphere”, equally independent of the destination state as of charity organisations run by the majority population (Sinke 2006:92). Most advanced in this area are the countries where large migration movements have taken place for a long time, and where the governments of origin have come to embrace migration as a reality that is here to stay. Such networks not only ease the entry of new arrivals, but also increase mobility overall. For instance when Cape Verdean women establish inter-continental networks which enable them to escape from, and find alternatives to, abusive employers, with mobility as their “principal tool of resistance”. Also Somali female migrants have established “networks of solidarity”, connecting Somalia to neighbouring countries, and then onwards to the Middle East, Europe and North America (Calavita 2006:123, and Case 7). The step from seeing “ethnic resources” as primarily facilitating the first steps of migrants into the destination society to using these networks in order to re-connect with the places of origin, is not a long one. Home Town Associations, HTAs, and professional associations – such as “The Ghanaian Doctors and Dentists Association” in the United Kingdom – play important roles in various respects, from providing voter registration for migrants, thus strengthening their possibility to exercise their democratic rights, to the training in migrants’ native languages, in addition to channelling funds to the societies of origin. As always, however, we must beware not to overstate their importance, the participation in HTAs varies greatly among migrant collectives, from a dismal one per cent in the case of Bolivians in the USA, to an impressive 63 per cent for Filipinos in Hong Kong (Orozco & Rouse 2007). 31 Case 7. Kowsar Aden, SwedishSomalilander Kowsar Aden is a Swedish-Somalilander woman, 32 years old, a single mother with three children. She works as a consultant and supports, in addition to her own family, her mother and her siblings in Hargeisa. Since 1998 she has sent 200 USD each month. The money is used to cover the basic needs of eight of her siblings, covering the cost of food, water and school fees. Kowsar’s mother, a widow since 1988, supports her family by working as a midwife in Hargeisa, earning 50 USD per month. The remittances received from her daughter in Sweden thus constitute a crucial lifeline for the whole family, without them they would have difficulties to survive. Text: Mussie Ephrem, Forum Syd The sums transferred by HTAs can be quite substantial. Although Mexico may be an exceptional case, the high dependence of home towns is remarkable. For Mexican “home towns” with a population of less than 3 000, HTA-donations amount to 50 per cent of the local budget. On the one hand, this indicates a structural weakness of the home towns’ financial position; on the other hand, it shows how migration may simultaneously support individual migrants and their societies of origin. Already in the early 1990s, the Mexican state of Zacatecas tried to realize this potential by establishing the “Dos por Uno” programme, whereby the local administration contributed a dollar for each dollar that the HTA remitted to development projects. A few years later, the programme was extended to other Mexican states and also made more generous, Tres por Uno, three for one dollar. A similar programme has been instituted in El Salvador. As a follow-up, and probably to pre-empt allegations of greediness, one of the main transfer giants, Western Union, has volunteered to contribute with another dollar, thus reaching “four to one” (up to a maximum of 1.25 million USD, Orozco & Rouse 2007). Win-Win II: Mutual interests When migration, and the remittances which go along with it, have become significant enough to the economy of origin, public support systems may be established to smooth and facilitate emigration and the life as immigrant, as this now is seen to be in the interest of the country of origin. Thus, many Asian countries of origin have established diaspora institutions, and Bangladesh, China, India, Indonesia, Korea, Pakistan, the Philippines, Sri Lanka and Thailand are all examples of countries which have migrant welfare funds in order to protect the interests of “their” emigrants and simultaneously secure the continuous flow of remittances (Agunias & Newland 2012, World Bank 2008). In several instances, the support begins by the establishment of recruitment agencies in order to facilitate and speed up migration process. For instance, in the Philippines, the government Overseas Workers Welfare Administration (OWWA) provides – against a fee of 25 USD in 2007 – health and life insurance, assistance for settling work related disputes (including failure by the employer to pay agreed wages) plus training activities in preparation of departure. OWWA also provides loans to emigrants and their families as well as grants for college students and vocational training (World Bank 2008). Diasporas may also be accorded special voting rights in order to keep them 32 connected to their country of origin, going from the possibility to vote from abroad, to having an “extra-territorial citizenship” as emigrant. A survey of 198 countries found that there are three options which allow migrants to participate in the democratic processes (to some extent): they can vote in their district of origin, which requires them to return for voting; they may vote abroad and their vote will be counted as if it was cast in the district of origin; or they may vote abroad for their own special representation in the parliament. It is this last scheme which most openly acknowledges the continuous existence of migration, and which thus recognizes the need to keep migrants connected in order to secure the win-win-wins of migration over time. Countries where this is being implemented include Algeria, Angola, Cape Verde, Croatia, France, GuineaBissau, Haiti, Mozambique, Morocco, Panama, and Portugal (Collyer 2014). One reason behind this wish to keep the diaspora link – in addition to the hope of seeing remittances flowing in – is the positive impact on FDI and hightech industrial development which have accompanied emigration, especially high-skilled emigration. Two examples will have to suffice: • First, there exists a positive relationship between the existence of a diaspora in the USA, and US FDIs to the countries of origin of the respective diasporas: every percentage increase in the number of migrants tends to increase the FDI stock in the respective country of origin by 0.2-0.4 per cent (Kugler & Rapoport 2007, Javorcik et al. 2011). • Secondly, learning from the rise and success of the Indian information technology industry in the 1990s, countries of origin may learn the advantages of win-win-win policies: stimulating emigration, facilitating return migration – dubbed “brain circulation” – and introducing public policies to support the growth of a nascent information industry, all traits witnessed in India (Docquier & Rapoport 2012:716-8). But instead of stimulating migration, governments of countries of origin may be tempted to try to appropriate for their country (or themselves) a greater share of the remittances by taxing emigrants, or by levying duties and charges on money and goods transferred (as contemplated in a World Bank presentation discussing the potential of remittances from the African diaspora, see Plaza 2007, thus adding further to the World Bank dismal record – see above – of seeing migrants as simple conduits of money transfers and disregarding their rights). This basically negative stand concerning the potential of migration is also evident from the attempt to “harness diasporas” (see Ratha & Plaza 2011) – a revealing phrase – indicating that the World Bank and governments both worry that migrant remittances may be channelled in directions outside of their control unless they are “harnessed”, that is brought under control by a supposedly benevolent public power. Win-Win III: Policy recommendations The conflicting perspectives discussed in this report matter a great deal when it comes to migration policies. Conclusions and recommendations will be fundamentally different depending on which side of the dichotomies you position yourself regarding the Migration and Development Nexus: a curse/a blessing, a drain/an opportunity, unidirectional/circular, permanent/temporary, optional/ 33 unavoidable. For instance, if you hold that policy ought to be designed to limit migration at both ends of the migration chain, your recommendations will be profoundly at odds with what you would suggest if you believed that migration, remittance delivery and migrants’ circulation should be facilitated (De Haas 2008). See Table 5 for some policy measures proposed to enhance the positive impact for the peoples and economies of the countries of origin. The basic question that this report sets out to address is if migration may offer a win-win-win proposition of mutually beneficial relationships, connecting and linking migrants, their families, their countries of origin and destination in a “migration regime” (Tamas & Palme 2006). There exists an understandable apprehension among migration researchers that the increasingly common take on migration as a win-win proposition in fact obfuscates the neo-colonial and unjust exploitation of labour from poor countries by rich countries, and by corporations based equally in the North and the fast growing South (Wickramasekara 2011). The abuse of men and women – going from sweat shops, assembly lines, and domestic work to trafficking and prostitution – should remind us of colonial forms of taking advantage of and exploiting human labour. Similarly, “circular migration” may be seen to be euphemism which hides the fact that migrants are denied permanent right of settlement, the “temporariness” of migration carries the stigma of previous regimes of “Gastarbeiter”, Guest workers, where migrants essentially are seen as, and dealt with as “pure” manual labour without social or cultural needs nor rights. There are also good reasons to question the proposition that today’s migratory flows constitute an historical exception. Contrary to the argument that migration soon will wane, as population growth declines and as industrialization picks up in the South (Tamas & Palme 2006, Collier 2013), we are most likely entering a phase where migration is a permanent feature of globalization. This is so not only because the global divide in terms of welfare, freedom, security and safety will likely remain wide for the foreseeable future There is also the prospect of an increasing difficulty to find productive industrial employment in the countries of origin caused by a process which has been dubbed “premature deindustrialization”. Due to automation and robotization, industrial employment in the South has already peaked at lower levels of economic development (measured by GDP) compared to the historical record in the North While industrial employment began to level off in early industrializers, such as Britain and Sweden, at income levels of 14 000 USD (in 1990 USD), the peak now seems to be reached in India, Africa and Latin America already at 700 USD (in 1990 USD; Rodrik 2015:15). 34 Table 5. Improving the potential of migration for development. An agenda for action at various scales Objective Goal Measures Secure migrants’ human rights Guarantee and protect civil and political as well as economic, social, and cultural rights at both ends of the migration process. Support trade unions, diaspora organisations and political parties and organisations which target migrants in countries and communities of origin and destination. Increase remittances Subsidize migrants’ costs. Promote short-term and circular labour migration. Minimize transfer costs. Stimulate competition and establish subsidised alternatives. Transparency, trust. Foreign exchange accounts on favourable terms. Publicly supervised migration channels. Channel remittances to development purposes Support Home Town Associations, donations. Tax subsidies for donations to charitable and development organisations, match HTA support with public support. Stimulate investments Facilitate the establishment of small and medium sized enterprises. Secure availability of microcredits to match remittances. Improve situation of circular/temporary migrants Facilitate migrants’ property rights, protect migrants’ political rights in countries of origin. Benefit and social security “portability” between jurisdictions, extend short-term temporary migration to enable establishment, schooling, multiple entry visas, preferential re-entry procedures, simplified family reunification, voting rights. Stability, long-term consistency Promote circular migration. Bilateral labour migration agreements. Secure diaspora engagement. Exchange programmes for children between emigrant and immigrant communities, voting rights for migrants in elections of countries and communities of origin and destination. Adapted from Carling 2007, Wickramasekara 2011. 35 It is not far-fetched, then, to think that one effect of “premature deindustrialization” will be to further increase the pressure to migrate from the South. If this is indeed the predominant tendency, a previously much disseminated idea in the migration and development discussion – that today’s countries of origin will become tomorrow’s destination economies – must be questioned. The idea was based on the observation that some countries had performed a transition from “sending” migrants abroad to “receiving” migrants from other, less successful economies, cases in point being North Africa and Turkey (Castles 2007:2678). Today the same trend is much discussed in connection with the migration to the countries of the Arab Gulf and East Asia. But what seems to be occurring at a global scale is rather that many countries take on both roles simultaneously, as countries of origin and destination of migrants, as globalization advances and transport costs decline, witness especially India and China. Thus, migration in all its guises and directions will remain an essential component of the global economy, as ever more resources, goods, ideas and people cross borders. Therefore, the essential policy recommendation concerning Migration and Development boils down to improving the conditions for migrants. Recognizing the fact that many migrants’ residence in the countries of destination is permanent as well temporary and circular, that migrants straddle several social and cultural networks, that their visions and allegiances extend across borders and continents, and that migrants not only contribute to the development of their countries of destination, but equally promote the social, economic and political development of their societies of origin. 36 List of References Agunias, Dovelyn Rannveig & Newland, Kathleen (2012): Engaging the Asian diaspora, Issue in Brief No 7, IOM/Migration Policy Institute, http://www.migrationpolicy.org/research/ engaging-asian-diaspora Andersson Joona, Pernilla, Gupta Datta, Nabanita & Wadensjö, Eskil (2012): Overeducation among Immigrants in Sweden: Incidence, Wage Effects and State-Dependence, IZA DP 6695, Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit, Bonn Andersson, Lisa (2015): Internationell migration och remitteringar i Etiopien. Orsaker, effekter och subjektiv välfärd, Rapport 2015:1, Delegationen för migrationsstudier, Stockholm Bettin, Giulia, Presbitero, Andrea F & Spatafora, Nikola (2014): Remittances and Vulnerability in Developing Countries, Policy Research WPS 6812, World Bank, Washington DC Bollard, Albert, McKenzie, David, Morten, Melanie & Rapoport, Hillel (2011): “Remittances and the Brain Drain Revisited: The Microdata Show That More Educated Migrants Remit More”, The World Bank Economic Review 25(1):132-156 Calavita, Kitty (2006): “Gender, Migration, and Law: Crossing Borders and Bridging Disciplines”, International Migration Review 40(1):104-132 Carling, Jörgen (2007): “Interrogating Remittances: Core Questions for Deeper Insight and Better Policies”, in Castles, S & Wise, RD (eds): Migration and Development: Perspectives from the South. Geneva: IOM Castles, Stephen (2007): “Perspectives from the South: Conclusions”, in Castles, S & Wise, RD (eds): Migration and Development: Perspectives from the South. Geneva: IOM Castles, Stephen & Ozkul, Derya (2014): “Circular Migration: Triple Win, or a New Label for Temporary Migration”, in Battistella, Graziano, ed: Global and Asian Perspectives on International Migration, Cham: Springer Clemens, Michael A, Montenegro, Claudio E & Pritchett, Lant (2008): The Place Premium: Wage Differences for Identical Workers Across the US Border, Policy Research WP 4671, World Bank, Washington DC Clemens, Michael & Ogden, Timothy (2014): Migration as a Strategy for Household Finance: A Research Agenda on Remittances, Payments, and Development, WP 354, Center for Global Development, Washington DC Collier, Paul (2013): Exodus. How Migration is Changing Our World. Oxford: Oxford University Press Collyer, Michael (2014): “A Geography of Extra-Territorial Citizenship: Explanations of External Voting”, Migration Studies 2(1):55-72 De Haas, Henin (2008): Migration and Development. A Theoretical Perspective, WP 9, International Migrations Institute, University of Oxford Djufve, Anne Britt, Friberg, Jon Horgen, Tyldum, Guri & Zhang, Huafeng (2015): When poverty meets affluence Migrants from Romania on the streets of the Scandinavian capitals, FAFO, http://www.fafo.no/images/pub/2015/954-innmat-trykk.pdf DN (2015): ”Människosmugglare löper liten risk att åtalas”, Dagens Nyheter 2015-06-16 Docquier, Frédéric, Lohest, Olivier & Marfouk, Abdeslam (2007): “Brain Drain in Developing Countries”, The World Bank Economic Review 21(2):193-218 Docquier, Frédéric & Rapoport, Hillel (2012): “Globalization, Brain Drain and Development”, Journal of Economic Literature 50(3):681-730 GoS (2014): Genomförande av samstämmighetspolitiken för utveckling – focus: den globala utmaningen migrationsströmmar, Government of Sweden report to parliament Skr 2013/14:154 Hollifield, James F (2006): “Trade, Migration, and Economic Development: The Risks and Rewards of Openness”, in Proceedings from the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas 2006, http:// econpapers.repec.org/article/fipfeddpr/y_3a2006_3ap_3a249-284.htm IOM (2013): Migration and the United Nations Post-2015 Development Agenda, Geneva Ismail, Abdirashid A (2011): “Diaspora and Post-War Political Leadership in Somalia”, Nordic Journal of African Studies 20(1):28-47 Javorcik, Beata S, Özden, Caglar, Spatareanu, M & Neagu, Cristina (2011): “Migrant Networks and Foreign Direct Investment”. Journal of Development Economics 94: 231-241 Kapur, Devesh (2005): “Remittances: The New Development Mantra?”, in Maimbo, Samuel Munzele & Pratha, Dilip, eds: Remittances. Development Impact and Future Prospects, World Bank, Washington DC 37 Karlsson, Jonas & Tibajev, Andrey (204): “Utlandsföddas levnadsvillkor”, in Evertsson, Marie & Magnusson, Charlotta, eds: Ojämlikhetens dimensioner. Uppväxtvillkor, arbete och hälsa i Sverige. Stockholm: Liber Knomad (2o15): Remittances, including access to finance and capital markets, Global Knowledge Partnership on Migration and Development, World Bank, Washington DC, www. http://www.knomad.org/thematic-working-groups/remittances-including-access-to-finance-and-capital-markets Kugler, Maurice & Rapoport, Hillel (2007): ”International Labor and Capital Flows: Complements or Substitutes”, Economics Letters 94:155-162 Le Grand, Carl & Karlsson, Jonas (n d): Hur lever utlandsfödda I Sverige? Preliminära resultat från Levnadsnivåundersökningen 2010-2012, http://www.reglab.se/wp-content/ uploads/2012/07/utlandsfodda-LNU.pdf Lewis, W Arthur (1954): Theory of Economic Growth. London: George Allen & Unwin Lundborg, Per (2012): “Flyktingars långa väg till arbetslivet”, in Framtider 4/2012 Mahler, Sarah J & Pessar, Patricia, R (2006): “Gender Matters: Ethnographers Bring Gender from the Periphery toward the Core of Migration Studies”, International Migration Review 40(1):27-63 McKenzie, David & Yang, Dean (2014): Evidence on Policies to Increase the Development Impacts of International Migration, KNOMAD WP 2, World Bank, Washington DC Milanovic, Branko (2011): Global Inequality. From Class to Location, from Proletarians to Migrants, Policy Research WP 5820, World Bank, Washington DC OECD (2007): “Matching Educational Background and Employment: A Challenge for Immigrants in Host Countries”, in International Migration Outlook 2007, http://www.oecd. org/migration/mig/41561786.pdf Orozco, Manuel & Rouse, Rebecca (2007): Migrant Hometown Associations and Opportunities for Development: A Global Perspective, Migration Policy Institute, Washington DC, http://www.migrationpolicy.org/article/migrant-hometown-associations-and-opportunities-development-global-perspective Piper, Nicola (2006): “Gendering the Politics of Migration”, International Migration Review 40(1):133-164 Plaza, Sonia (2007): The Importance of the Remittances by the African Diaspora and Its Problems, World Bank, http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTPROSPECTS/ Resources/334934-1110315015165/LibyaDiasporaPresentationfinal_soniaplaza.ppt Portes, Alejandro (2007): “Migration and Development: A Conceptual Review of the Evidence”, in Castles, S & Wise, RD, eds: Migration and Development: Perspectives from the South. Geneva: IOM Ratha, Dilip & Plaza, Sonia (2011): “Harnessing Diasporas. Africa Can Tap Some of Its Millions of Emigrants to Help Development Efforts”, Finance and Development, September, IMF, Washington DC Rodrik, D (2015): Premature Deindustrialization, The National Bureau of Economic Research, NBER WP 20935, Cambridge Sandefur, Justin (2014): Migration and Development: Who Bears the Burden of Proof?, http:// oxfamblogs.org/fp2p/migration-and-development-who-bears-the-burden-of-proof-justinsandefur-replies-to-paul-collier-2/ Sinke, Suzanne M (2006): “ Gender and Migration: Historical Perspectives”, International Migration Review 40(1):82-103 Szulkin, Ryszard (2012): “Se upp för dörrarna, dörrarna stängs”, in Framtider 4/2012 Tamas, Kristof & Palme, Joakim (2006): ”Transnational Approaches to Reforming Migration Regimes”, Tamas, K & Palme, J (eds): Globalizing Migration Regimes. New Challenges to Transnational Cooperation. Surrey: Ashgate UN (2014): International Migration and Development. Report by the Secretary-General, A/69/207, 30 July 2014, New York UN (2014): The Road to Dignity by 2030. Ending Poverty, Transforming All Lives and Protecting the Planet. Report by the Secretary General, 4 December 2014, New York. http://www.un.org/disabilities/documents/reports/SG_Synthesis_Report_Road_to_Dignity_ by_2030.pdf UN (1990): International Convention on the Protection of the Rights of All Migrant Workers and Members of Their Families, http://www2.ohchr.org/english/bodies/cmw/cmw.htm 38 UNDP (2009): Overcoming Barriers: Human Mobility and Development, Human Development Report 2009, New York UNESCO (2015): Glossary of Migration Related Terms, http://www.unesco.org/new/en/socialand-human-sciences/themes/international-migration/glossary/migrant/ Vlase, Ionela & Preoteasa, Ana Maria (2012): Roma Migrants from Bulgaria and Romania. Migration Patterns and Integration in Italy and Spain 2011, in Tarnovschi, Daniela (ed: Roma from Romania, Bulgaria, Italy and Spain: Between Social Incslusion and Migration, Bucharest, Soros Foundation, https://www.gitanos.org/upload/19/58/Roma_in_Romania__Bulgaria__Italy_and_Spain_between_Social_Inclusion_and_Migration._Comparative_St.pdf Wickramasekara, Piyasiri (2011): Circular Migration: A Triple Win or a Dead End, DP 15, Global Union Research Network, ILO, Geneva World Bank (2015/2014/2013/2011/2008): Migration and Development Brief 24/23/22/14/7, Washington DC World Bank (2015a): Global Economic Prospects. Having Fiscal Space and Using It, Washington DC World Bank (2015b): Remittance Prices Worldwide, June 2015, https://remittanceprices.worldbank.org/sites/default/files/rpw_report_june_2015.pdf, Washington DC World Bank (2013): Capital for the Future. Saving and Investment in an Interdependent World, Washington DC ISBN 978-91-637-9941-9 Printed by Norra Skåne Offset Hässleholm 2015 39 250 million people are international migrants today, contributing to the development of their countries of destination as well as to the well-being of their families, societies and countries of origin. The view that migration constitutes a triple win – to the migrants themselves, to the countries of destination, and to the societies of origin – although not entirely new has only recently come to permeate the Migration and Development discourse. But in spite of the fact that the potential has been recognized, there still exist important weaknesses in today’s global migration regime. In this report Forum Syd highlights three main areas which need to be addressed in order to strengthen the benefits to be reaped from migration: secure migrants’ social, economic and political rights, reduce the costs of transferring remittances, and facilitating and supporting the work and services provided by diasporas and home town associations. The report is written by Kenneth Hermele, economist, Forum Syd, Sweden. Forum Syd is a politically and religiously unaffiliated development aid organisation with around 160 member organisations from Swedish civil society. Together we work with human and civil rights, and facilitate popular participation around the globe. Our work centres on enabling people to organise to claim their rights and take control of their lives; for it is only then that democracy can grow, resources can be distributed more fairly, and poverty can be reduced.
© Copyright 2024