A possible SACU/China Free Trade Agreement (FTA): Implications for the South African manufacturing sector by Hans Grinsted Jensen and Ron Sandrey tralac Working Paper No 8/2006 July 2006 Note: For more background on the South Africa/China trading relationship the reader is referred to tralac Working Paper No 3/2006, South African Merchandise Trade with China, at www.tralac.org Contents Summary of the Trading Relationship 2 1 Introduction 6 Structure of the report 7 The Model 7 Modelling framework and scenarios used 7 FTA scenarios 10 The database 13 Results: the economic Implications of the FTA 14 The big picture 14 Bilateral trade – the big picture 17 The sectors in detail 18 The supply response 19 Sensitivity analysis – employment closure 20 The scenario analysis 22 The Doha outcome 23 2 3 Tables 1 Macroeconomic projections, annual growth rates, 2001–2015 9 2 Ad valorem equivalent tariff barriers to trade, pre-FTA, 2015 percent 13 3 Assumed quantification of China’s NTB 14 4 Percentage change in TOT, real GDP and factor income 15 5 Changes in national welfare 17 6 % change in the quantity of total imports/exports & trade balance, 2015 18 7 Change in bilateral trade China-South Africa, 2015 18 8 Impact of the FTA on RSA industrial sectors, percentage change 20 9 Percentage change in wages and employment in South Africa 21 10 Percentage change in TOT, real GDP, and factor income South Africa 21 11 Welfare from the 30% Doha outcome 23 Figures 1 Scenario Construction 12 1 Summary and key points SACU and China are considering entering into a bilateral free trade agreement (FTA). The objective of this paper is to analyse the possible implications of this FTA for South Africa. The summary of the paper includes a short background to the trading relationship between the respective parties and provides a scene-setting analysis. A fuller account of that trading relationship is provided in the tralac Working Paper No3/2006, South African Merchandise Trade with China at www.tralac.org. The second part of this paper describes the computer model used and discusses the results of simulating the FTA. The trading background This data analysis in the tralac Working paper above examines South African imports into China and Chinese imports into South Africa. Data through to December 2005 is sourced from the respective countries using the commercially obtainable World Trade Atlas data. During 2005 imports into China from South Africa totalled some US$3,444 million, a figure that increased by 16.5 percent from 2004. In ‘real’ terms, this represented 0.52 percent of Chinese global imports, a figure that has been relatively stable over the last ten years. By commodities, the main imports were iron ores ($967 million), precious metals and stones ($957 million), a particular Chinese classification of ‘small lines’ ($462 million) and iron and steel ($427 million). The average duty on these imports was calculated to be 3.45 percent. South African imports into China are highly concentrated, with the top ten lines at the HS1 2 chapter level accounting for 92.5 percent of the total trade, and in several of the main imports at the more detailed level (precious stones in particular) these imports held a major share in the Chinese market. Detailed analysis showed that both Australia and Brazil, two countries of potential ‘FTA (Free Trade Agreement) defensive interest’ into China, are major competitors in several important trade lines. 1 Where HS is the Harmonised System of merchandise trade classification that operates in a sequentially more detailed level from internationally harmonised (hence the name) HS 2 to 4 and 6 levels, and often down to even HS 10 for individual countries. 2 South Africa is doing relatively well into China, with some 40 percent of the imports (the ‘Stars’) gaining market share in Chinese imports sectors that are themselves growing. Chinese imports into South Africa have increased dramatically over the last ten years, and by December 2005 they were $4,926 million or 9.0 percent of the total, with the latter figure up from a 2.1 percent market share in 1996. These 2005 imports were up 37 percent on the 2004 figure, much higher than the global increase into South Africa of 15.5 percent. Chinese imports are not as highly concentrated as South African imports into China, with the top 10 HS chapters making up a lesser 72 percent of the imports. Although 45 percent of the trade enters duty-free, the average duty that would have been assessed on these imports in the absence of any rebates was 12.52 percent. These duties are mostly paid by the 30 percent of the imports that enter where the duties are assessed at 20 percent or more, a grouping that is dominated by textile/clothing/footwear (TCF) products. A look at revealed comparative advantage shows that apart from the spectacular growth, a remarkable feature of Chinese imports is their domination of the market where they do compete, with most of the TCF chapters holding a market share of at least 50 percent. Associated with this are the equally remarkable growth rates to achieve this dominance, as some 97 percent of the individual HS 4 import lines have increased their market share over the last ten years. Data reconciliation shows that, as expected with South African imports into China valued at two and a half times the reported exports from South Africa to China, there is little coherence in reconciling the trade flows to China. Some of this is accounted for in the transport costs (iron ore) given that imports are valued at cost, insurance and freight (cif) and exports at free on board (fob), while another large difference is that there are almost no reported exports of platinum and diamonds from South Africa, but these are major imports into China. Much remains unexplained. ‘Trade chilling’ suggests that there may be potential areas where South Africa could export to China and where an FTA could help. By value, the main potential export 3 items from South Africa may be motorcars and aircraft (duties of 15 and 5% respectively), as these are both massive imports into China. Other lines include apples, apricots, pineapples and avocados, chocolate products and processed fish and meats in agricultural goods, titanium oxide and other ores, and some lines of iron and steel and other manufactured products in general. Finally, an analysis of the so-called intra-Industry trade between South Africa and China shows that, as expected between two developing countries, these index values are low at about the 6 (out of a 100) level. This index compares trade between partners in like-products, and is a feature of trade between developed countries. However, the more interesting feature is that these index values are steadily increasing from very low levels over the last ten years, suggesting an increasing sophistication in the trading relationship. The model Version 6 of the Global Trade Analysis Programme (GTAP) model has been used to simulate the FTA. Key findings of the economic analysis are: The FTA will lift economic growth and welfare in both South Africa and China, but the impacts on economic growth and welfare in the BLNS countries (Botswana, Lesotho, Namibia and Swaziland), while positive, are very small or negligible. • By 2015 South Africa’s national welfare, measured by the money metric value of the Equivalent Variation (EV), will be US$121.6 million above what it would have been in the absence of the FTA. • China’s National Welfare is estimated to be $181 million above baseline as a result of the FTA. • Botswana’s National Welfare will be $4.1 million greater, while the Rest of SACU will gain an almost insignificant $2.5 million. Removal of China’s tariffs accounts for an increase in South Africa’s welfare of $112 million, while the removal of China’s non-tariff barriers account for an additional $50 million. The removal of South Africa’s own barriers against Chinese imports 4 results in a loss of $22 million (mostly through terms of trade loss). These same terms of trade loss are also hurting Botswana. Expressing the gains in terms of changes in Real Gross Domestic Product (GDP) highlights the differences in the relative sizes of the economies involved. For South Africa, the change is an increase of 0.0399 percent; for Botswana it is an increase of 0.0882 percent; for the rest of SACU it is 0.0536 percent; while for China it is an insignificant 0.0009 percent. China gains more in absolute terms, as its economy is considerably larger. These findings are premised on the FTA that has the complete removal of tariffs on bilateral trade and the removal of an estimate of China’s non-tariff barriers (NTBs) on SACU imports at 2015. There has been no liberalisation of service trade, and as the model used is the standard static GTAP model, there are no dynamic productivity gains associated with the trade liberalisation carried out under the FTA. These results represent a ‘snapshot’ of the changes at a disaggregated sectoral and regional level when modelled using the standard GTAP model. By definition, economic models are a simplification of reality and rely on assumptions about economic parameters, behaviour and relationships. Some sensitivity analyses have been undertaken by examining (a) the impacts of the FTA following a successful WTO Doha outcome and (b) a less than comprehensive FTA as proxied by a 50 percent cut in tariff barriers only in all goods trade. The results of (a) are gains of about 70 percent of the full pre-Doha FTA to both South Africa and China, while in the results of (b) the comparable results are only 50 percent of the GDP gains to South Africa. Overall, with the full FTA, South African global exports increase by 1.0 percent while global imports increase by 2.1 percent. The trade balance is reduced by (negative) $257.4 million. countries. A similar slightly negative picture is observable for the BLNS China has a positive increase in total exports over imports. China increases it bilateral total exports by $1,733 million compared to an increase in South African exports to China by $889 million. This leads to deterioration in the South African bilateral trade balance with China of $850 million. As expected, trade liberalisation carried out under the FTA has very limited impact on bilateral trade flows 5 in the agricultural sectors, although these agricultural products go some way towards mitigating the overall negative forecast for the bilateral trade balance following an FTA with China, with Chinese imports having a major impact upon the TCF sectors in South Africa (with the output of the clothing sector declining by 20 percent). The standard GTAP closure on employment is that the number of workers remains constant and the adjustment is through wages. Sensitivity analysis examining the alternative of keeping wages constant and adjusting employment (a more accurate reflection of a developing country) results in an increase in welfare for South Africa that is $278 million above the standard closure. 1. Introduction Regional trade agreements are becoming an increasingly popular trade policy tool in many countries, and SACU/South Africa is embracing this concept with a view to furthering its bilateral trade. The stage became a more active place during 2005. Pending the resolution of a few outstanding issues, the preferential trade deal with the South American Mercosur countries signed in December 2004 seems to be on track, and the free-trade agreement between SACU and EFTA (Switzerland, Norway, Iceland and Liechtenstein), has virtually been concluded after a long wait. Talks with the US are scheduled to resume after a yearlong time-out period, and SACU members are in serious discussions with the European Union about EPAs. Discussion about a trade deal with India is imminent, and SACU is considering starting free-trade talks with China. Others on the horizon include an examination of free-trade partners in Africa, and other countries such as Singapore, Thailand, Sri Lanka and Turkey have expressed interest in discussions with SACU. Meanwhile, the Sixth World Trade Organization (WTO) ministerial conference in Hong Kong in December put limited new life into the Doha Development Round, and all countries generally recognise that FTAs are a second-best option to global trade liberalisation. The negotiating dynamics have become more complex following the introduction of the new SACU Agreement, as South Africa can no longer negotiate in its own right, as was the case with the EU TDCA, but only with the full cooperation and consent of fellow SACU members. This means that the wider SACU perspective needs to be considered in future FTA negotiations. The current study undertakes a close look at 6 the potential bilateral FTA with China, a nation that is itself also enthusiastically embracing the ideas of bilateral FTAs although without actually consummating any; New Zealand became the first country to begin bilateral talks with China late 2004/early 2005, and these talks are still in progress; and in recognition of the need to be in conformity with the new SACU agreement the wider SACU perspective is considered. Structure of the report Section 2 will outline the details on the model used and its associated database before providing and then discussing the results of a full FTA whereby all bilateral duties and some NTBs in China are abolished. A limited analysis of alternative scenarios is also considered: the partial FTA of a 50 percent cut in the FTA duties, but with NTBs in China remaining unchanged; a 30 percent cut across the board globally in all duties from Doha round outcome; and combinations of implementing both the full and partial FTAs taking into account this Doha outcome. 2. The model Modelling framework and scenarios used The analysis undertaken in this paper is based upon the Global Trade Analysis Project (GTAP) model (Hertel 1997) and database (Dimaranan et al. 2005). The database is the most recent version 6, and this has been slightly modified to reflect more recently available trade and tariff data. Also, the standard model has been adjusted by introducing a new import tax to represent Chinese non-tariff barriers (NTBs) to trade, and the initial ad valorem equivalents (AVEs) of these trade barriers have been incorporated into the GTAP version 6 database2. These NTBs were shown to be important in the case of the modelling work undertaken by New Zealand and China in assessing their potential FTA: 'the Gains would, for instance, still be significant and positive from a tariff only arrangement, but they would increase substantially if key non-tariff measures were also covered by any agreement’3. 2 The Alter tax program (Malcolm 1998) has been used to adjust tax rates in the initial GTAP version 6 database. 3 Ministry of Commerce et al. 2004. 7 The GTAP model is a standard multi-regional, static computable general equilibrium (CGE) model. Like any other applied economic model, this model is, of course, based on assumptions, both in terms of theoretical structure as well as the specific parameters and data used. In this model, regional production is produced according to a constant return to scale technology in a perfectly competitive environment, and the private demand system is represented by a non-homothetic demand system (a Constant Difference Elasticity function)4. The foreign trade structure is characterised by the Armington assumption implying imperfect substitutability between domestic and foreign goods. The latest GTAP model allows the option of 87 country/regional possibilities, and 57 sectors (with 42 of these productive sectors, and the remaining ones, services). For the sectors we opted for the full range of productive sectors, aggregating only the natural resource sectors as these sectors are seldom affected by an FTA since constraints to their trade are limited. For the country/regional aggregation we opted for the three SACU (the South African Customs Union) possibilities of (1) South Africa, (2) Botswana and (3) the rest of SACU, i.e., with Namibia, Swaziland and Lesotho combined. This latter aggregation is not ideal, as the three countries have very differently structured economies and production sectors, but it is the only possibility. We are also conscious that the nature of intra-SACU trade will distort the databases for the BLNS, as most of their Chinese imports may not actually be recorded as imports from China but rather imports from China into South Africa. The other countries/aggregations are China, India, EU 25, Brazil, USA, rest of SADC (the Southern African Development Community), rest of Africa, and the rest of the world (ROW). Before analysing this, a baseline for the period 2001– 2015 is constructed to provide a benchmark against which the FTA is compared. It features projections of the world economy (cf. Table 1 below), plus incorporation of the effects of China’s accession to the WTO, the enlargement of the European Union’s customs union, Everything But Arms (EBA) adopted by the EU, the abolishment of the MultiFibre Agreement (MFA), and the completion of the Uruguay Rounds commitments for the developing countries. In short, it represents the best estimate of what the bilateral trading 4 Hence, the present analysis abstracts from features such as imperfect competition and increasing return to scale, which may, however, be important in certain sectors. 8 relationship would look like in 2015 based upon all known factors in the absence of an FTA. Table 1: Macroeconomic projections, annual growth rates, 2001 – 2015. Real Labour Force GDP Pop. Total Unskilled Skilled Capital TFP* South Africa 3.2 0.4 0.5 0.5 0.6 3.2 0.7 Botswana 4.7 0.6 0.7 0.7 2.1 4.7 0.9 Rest of SACU 3.8 1.0 1.1 1.1 1.5 3.8 0.7 China 7.2 0.7 0.8 0.8 3.2 7.2 1.3 Rest of SADC 4.3 2.6 2.5 2.5 3.1 4.3 0.6 Rest of Africa 4.0 2.4 2.7 2.7 3.1 4.0 0.4 India 5.8 1.4 1.9 1.8 4.9 5.8 1.1 EU25 2.1 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 2.1 0.6 USA 3.2 0.9 1.0 1.2 0.7 3.2 0.7 Brazil 3.3 1.2 1.2 1.0 3.7 3.3 0.4 Rest of World 3.0 1.2 1.8 1.6 2.6 3.0 0.3 Sources: World Bank forecasts, ILO (1997) and own assumptions. Note: * The annual growth rate in Total Factor Productivity is determined endogenously – determined by the exogenous variables (GDP, unskilled, skilled labour force, capital), the model and the associated database. The projection of the world economy using the exogenous assumptions listed in Table 1 is important in shaping the baseline scenario. The GTAP model determines changes in output through both an expansionary and a substitution effect in each country/region of the model. The expansionary effect represents the effects of growth in domestic and foreign demand shaped by income and population growth and the assumed income elasticities, while the substitution effect reflects the changes in competitiveness in each country/region shaped by changes in relative total factor productivity, cost of production as well as any policy changes. Therefore, the relative growth rates between each country/region for GDP, population, labour, capital and total factor productivity play an important role in determining the relative growth in output of the commodities when projecting the world economy from 2001 to 2015. 9 FTA scenarios These are outlined in detail in Figure 1. The FTA primary scenario (S2 in Figure 1) considered in this paper entails the immediate and comprehensive removal of merchandise trade barriers between China and the member countries of the SACU and the outcome in the year 2015 in a world shaped by the baseline scenario. This implies that all ad valorem tariffs and ad valorem equivalent of specific tariffs between China and the SACU are abolished, as well as the abolishment of estimated NTBs faced by SACU exports to the Chinese market. Differences between the so-called baseline scenario and this so-called primary scenario are therefore the results of implementation of the FTA. In addition, it is always possible to do an almost endless number of ‘what if?’ scenarios. For this study we have limited these to two basic assumptions/possible outcomes. One is that there will be a successful conclusion to the Doha Development Round of the WTO, and we have proxied that by assuming that the outcome will be a uniform cut in all applied tariffs for all WTO parties across all products of 30 percent and the abolishment of all export subsidies (S3 below – obviously this is a shotgun approach, but it may well turn out to be a reasonable approximation if there is an optimistic outcome). The second assumption is that the SACU/Chinese negotiators will fail to negotiate a fully comprehensive FTA, and we have proxied this possibility by assuming the outcome will be a 50 percent cut in bilateral tariff rates (S1 below). Although in reality it is more likely that sensitive sectors for either party will be isolated from any final agreement, we have opted for this blanket 50 percent option. To complete the picture we have combined these latter two scenarios into a combined one of a successful 30 percent WTO cut from Doha and a less than comprehensive bilateral as represented by the 50 percent tariff cut (S4 below). Only in the post-Doha Full FTA scenario do the benefits that accrue to SACU exporters from the reduction of NTB measures in China remain; in the partial FTA scenarios (a) the tariff cuts for the FTA are 50 percent across the board and (b) there are no NTB gains available to SACU as there are from the full bilateral FTA. Operationally, these are represented as follows: 10 • Firstly, scenario S2 (the primary scenario) is run to simulate the effects of the comprehensive FTA in a post-UR environment where all other known international commitments are fully implemented. • Then Scenario S3 is run. This is a simple implementation of a much stylised outcome of a possible DDA round of the WTO represented by a 30 percent reduction in all applied AVE tariffs and a 100 percent reduction of all agricultural export subsidies found in the GTAP version 6 database. • Next Scenarios S4 and S5 extend S3 by also including the post-Doha FTA between SACU and China in the scenario with respectively a 100 and 50 percent removal of AVE tariffs between the FTA countries as well as the removal of NTB in China faced by SACU counties in scenario S4 (but not in the partial 50 percent FTA of S5). In order to find the isolated effects of creating the FTA in a post-DDA round (-30 percent on all applied AVE tariffs and 100 percent removal of agricultural export subsidies), scenario S3 is subtracted from scenario S4 and S5 respectively, quantifying the effect of the FTA. Therefore the results shown later for the FTA (in an environment where the DDA has been completed) are technically the results of scenarios (S4 – S3) and (S5 – S3). Not shown in Fig 1 is that we have also undertaken a scenario looking at the closure of wages fixed and employment adjustments. 11 Figure 1: Scenario construction GTAP Database 2001 EU Enlargement EBA MFA Quota Elimination China’s WTO Accession Implementation of final UR commitments Macro Economic-Projections 2001 – 2015 Up Dated GTAP database 2015 Partial FTA SACU China Simulations 50% reduction of S1 AVE tariff barriers (no change to NTB) Full (and Comprehensive) FTA S2 SACU China Simulations 100% removal of trade barriers (AVE tariffs and NTB) DDA –30% reduction of all applied AVE S3 Tariffs & 100% removal of agricultural export subsidies in all countries/regions S3 & Full FTA) SACU China Simulations 100% removal of S4 trade barriers (AVE tariffs and NTB) S3 & Partial FTA S5 SACU China Simulations 50% reduction of AVE tariff barriers (no change to NTB) 12 The database Although this study examines the implications for the non-agricultural or manufacturing sector, sometimes there is not a clear one-for-one mapping between the GTAP model product groups and the WTO agricultural and non-agricultural products. For example, although wool is a separate agricultural commodity in GTAP, it is then used as an intermediate good into textiles, a manufacturing sector; another is where fisheries products and agricultural products are both included in GTAP 'Food Products'. Therefore, some overlap between agricultural and non-agricultural products is possible, but this is not a major issue. As outlined above, we have used the most recent GTAP version 6 data, updated where necessary. Tables 2 and 3 show the import tariff equivalents and NTB rates assumed in this analysis respectively, with the data representing a percentage of world market prices in 2015. Table 2: Ad Valorem Equivalent tariff barriers to trade, pre-FTA, 2015, percent Commodities Natural Resources Chinese tariff barriers on imports from RSA 0.6 Tariff barriers faced by Chinese exports to RSA 1.0 Textiles 18.1 23.2 Wearing apparel 17.2 37.8 Leather products 12.8 28.6 Wood products 2.9 18.7 Paper products, publishing 1.7 8.6 Petroleum, coal products 8.0 0.4 Chemical, rubber, plastic products 8.0 4.9 Mineral products n.e.c. 10.5 14.6 Ferrous metals 4.1 4.1 Metals n.e.c. 3.4 1.4 Metal products 8.5 10.3 Motor vehicles & parts 7.7 10.8 Transport equipment n.e.c. 4.6 1.4 Electronic equipment 6.6 3.1 Machinery & equipment n.e.c. 6.8 5.9 Manufactures n.e.c. 9.2 7.2 Services 0.0 0.0 Source: GTAP Version 6 database and tariff data constructed by CEPII from MacMap-HS6 tariff database (CEPII/ITC) and from bound tariffs from WTO Consolidated Tariff Schedules. 13 We note the high protection on many of these imports into South Africa, with the textile, apparel and leather sector rates of up to 37.8 percent. The tariffs on vehicle imports from China into South Africa seem low, but that is most likely a function of the composition of the current (low) trade in this sector. Note also that while the barriers to service trade are listed as zero, this does not reflect the reality of non-tariff barriers in these sectors. Table 3: Assumed quantification of China’s NTB Sector Tariff % Non-agricultural Natural Resources 0 Wearing apparel 3 Leather products 3 Wood products 5 Paper products, publishing 5 Petroleum, coal products 3 Chemical, rubber, plastic 3 Mineral products n.e.c. 3 Ferrous metals 3 Metals n.e.c. 3 Metal products 3 Motor vehicles and parts 3 Transport equipment n.e.c. 3 Electronic equipment 3 Machinery and equipment 3 Manufactures n.e.c. 3 Source: Own assumption. 3. Results: the economic implications of the FTA The big picture Table 4 shows the main changes in national welfare from the proposed FTA. These changes, while not large, are generally positive in most cases. The table shows (1) terms of trade (TOT), (2) change in real GDP measured in quantity terms, (3) total factor income, and (4) the changes in the price of endowments. These results are 14 discussed in detail below, and refer to changes from a comprehensive FTA with China. Table 4: Percentage change in TOT, real GDP and factor income Quantity Total Land Unskilled Skilled labour labour Capital Natural resources 0.0399 0.31 2.45 0.17 0.25 0.25 0.32 Botswana -0.0819 0.0882 0.12 0.90 0.07 0.10 0.11 0.08 RSACU 0.0236 0.0536 0.32 6.59 -0.06 0.03 0.08 0.33 China 0.0298 0.0009 0.05 0.08 0.05 0.05 0.05 -0.08 TOT South Africa 0.1091 Of GDP Factor income Percentage price changes on endowments If an economy experiences allocative efficiency (measured as a better allocation of the resources that a country has) then the quantity of real GDP would increase (a country produces a larger quantity of goods contributing positively to increased factor prices in a country). This is the case in South Africa where the real GDP increases by 0.0399 percent due to the creation of the FTA, as shown in the 3rd column. The other SACU partners of Botswana and RSACU show increases in excess of this as a percentage of GDP, while China has a positive change, but this hardly registers in percentage terms. The FTA improves the TOT (terms of trade) for South Africa, as increased demand from China generally increases export prices more than import prices in South Africa through increases in the export price to both China and the ROW. In the latter case the quantity of export declines but the price and hence the TOT increases. China’s gains come about from the better TOT as South Africa in particular removes its tariffs. Again, the final outcomes, as shown in the right hand column, are positive for all, but marginal for BLNS. The welfare gains found in South Africa in the full FTA of $121.6 million originate mainly from allocative efficiency and terms of trade changes. The allocative efficiency increases by $62 million due to a better allocation of endowments in the South African economy, and some $38 million of this gain stems from a better allocation of resources in manufacturing excluding TCF products (with another $21.4 million coming from a better allocation in these latter three sectors, with little from agriculture and natural resources). 15 With regard to the gains in Terms of Trade improving welfare by $50.9 million, this gain is mainly generated by raising South African export prices ($49 million) due to the improved market access into the Chinese market. These increased export prices improve the terms of trade for many products, but in particular for natural resource exports and non-ferrous metal manufactures. The exceptions are the TCF sectors (and to a very minor extent, lumber) where the export prices decline by between 3.4 and 4.7 percent in response to the increased competition from Chinese imports. A summary decomposition of the changes by dollar value is shown in Table 5. This breaks the welfare changes into those resulting from (a) allocative efficiency in the different countries, (b) terms of trade in the different countries, and (c) the capital goods or investment effect in the different countries to put it all in perspective. Furthermore, the result of the removal/reduction of non-tariff barriers in China is also displayed to put these in perspective. For South Africa, the latter provides about 40 percent of the total welfare gains, while for China this contribution is mildly negative and the gains come mostly from terms of trade gains that result from South Africa removing tariffs. Similarly, most of South Africa’s gains result from terms of trade gains from China removing tariff barriers (note both lose in total from the removal of their own tariffs, emphasising the value of bilateral negotiations). As the tariff barriers are reduced in Botswana and the Rest of SACU, China gains marginally while South Africa loses by a similar small amount. 16 Table 5: Change in national welfare, million US$ Allocative Efficiency Terms of Trade Capital Goods Total South Africa Removal of tariff barriers by South Africa 32.5 -81.0 26.9 -21.6 Botswana -3.3 -7.4 1.6 -9.1 RSACU -3.0 -8.9 1.8 -10.2 China 23.0 103.8 -14.6 112.2 China 12.8 44.5 -7.0 50.3 Total 62.0 50.9 8.7 121.6 Removal of tariff barriers by South Africa 35.3 243.1 -68.7 209.7 Botswana 1.3 10.5 -3.2 8.6 RSACU 3.5 18.1 -4.8 16.9 -12.1 -37.7 12.1 -37.7 China -5.5 -15.8 4.7 -16.6 Total 22.5 218.3 -59.8 181.0 Removal of NTB by China China Removal of NTB by Bilateral trade – the big picture The creation of the FTA between China and SACU increases the amount of trade taking place in these countries (Table 6). In the case of South Africa the total quantities of exports increase by 1.0 percent while the total quantities of imports increase by 2.1 percent. The trade balance is reduced by (negative) $257 million. A similar slightly negative picture is observable for the BLNS countries, while China has a positive increase in exports over imports. Overall, China is exporting more to SACU than SACU is exporting to China. China increases it value of total exports by $1,733 million compared to an increase in South African exports to China by $889 million. This leads to deterioration in the South African trade balance of $850 million. 17 Table 6: % change in the quantity of total Imports\Exports & trade balance, 2015 South Africa China Botswana RSACU* Exports 1.0 0.1 0.1 0.4 Imports 2.1 0.1 0.1 0.7 45 -4 -15 Trade balance mill US$ -257 * Where ‘RSACU’ is the rest of SACU (Namibia, Swaziland and Lesotho aggregation) The sectors in detail In manufactured goods China increased its trade balance by $1,010 million, notably in TCF and electronic equipment. Table 7 shows the sector breakdown of these changes in manufacturing trade. The big increases in Chinese exports to South Africa are coming in the TCF sectors, along with the catch-all machinery and equipment n.e.c. (not elsewhere classified) sector. Conversely, South African export increases are slightly less concentrated, with the natural resources and general manufacturing sectors featuring prominently. Note that in both cases, but especially in the case of South Africa’s exports, the large percentage figures are off a small base when the percentage increase and the dollar value of that increase are compared. Table 7: Change in bilateral trade China-South Africa, 2015 18 We must keep in mind that the implementation of the FTA leads to trade creation (good) and trade diversion (questionable). There is technically trade diversion in the South African market for manufactured goods, with TCF goods being the most outstanding, but as China is almost certainly the world’s most efficient producer of these commodities, this trade diversion should not be a concern. Where the big changes are taking place in South Africa, they are mostly occurring in the TCF sectors, where the exports from China to South Africa roughly triple. This has the consequential effect of reducing clothing output by 20 percent and leather products by 14 percent. Consumers gain through price declines in the order of 2 percent, but officials will need to carefully weigh losses in these sectors against gains elsewhere in the economy. The supply response In table 8 the aggregate supply response of South Africa is shown together with changes in the quantity of exports/imports and the changes in domestic market prices. South Africa’s industrial sectors as defined by GTAP are shown. In particular, the impacts upon the TCF products are dramatic. For the apparel sector imports overall increase by 23.5 percent, and production declines by 20.3 percent, while for the leather sector the comparable changes are 40.4 and 14 percent respectively. These changes would have an important impact upon the local industry, although there is some compensatory reduction in the market price for consumers. Another sector to face the winds of Chinese competition is the electronic equipment sector, while the big gainer is the ‘machinery and equipment n.e.c.’ sector. Note that there is little impact upon the motor vehicles and parts sector, as the Chinese are not (yet) internationally competitive in this sector. 19 Table 8: Impact of the FTA on RSA industrial sectors, % change Change in Production Exports Imports Natural resources 0.0 -0.3 0.5 Textiles -5.4 4,6 16.6 Wearing apparel -20.3 -4.9 23.5 Leather products -14.0 8.7 40.4 Wood products -0.6 1.2 6.4 Paper products, publishing 0.1 0.7 0.5 Petroleum, coal products 0.1 0.1 0.4 Chemical, rubber plastic 0.1 1.6 0.7 Mineral products n.e.c. -1.2 0.7 3.8 Ferrous metals 1.0 1.8 0.9 Metals n.e.c. 0.2 0.2 0.9 Metal products -0.6 -0.4 6.3 Motor vehicles and parts 0.3 0.2 0.8 Transport equipment n.e.c. 0.0 -0.1 0.3 Electronic equipment -4.2 -7.3 1.2 Machinery & equipt n.e.c. 1.1 4.3 1.4 Manufacturing n.e.c. 9.7 14.9 2.6 Services 0.1 -0.5 0.4 Market price 0.2 -0.9 -2.1 -1.4 -0.3 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.0 -0.1 0.1 Not surprisingly, the creation of the FTA has minimal effects on the Chinese market prices and production structure. Very few sectors record significant changes, emphasising of course that China is more important to South Africa than the converse. Leather products show the largest increase in production (0.36%), exports (0.64%) and imports (0.48). The largest price effects in China are a 0.04 percent increase for wearing apparel, leather products and services as production patterns move ever so slightly. Sensitivity analysis – employment closure The standard GTAP model gives the option of two possible labour force closures: a long run or medium/short run closure. In the analysis presented in this paper, the standard so-called 'long run' labour market closure has been used where the amount of employment is fixed and the wage rate adjusts endogenously in the model. This is the standard closure of the model, given the assumption that the labour market is initially in a steady state of employment and in the long run wages will adjust, bringing the economy back to the initial level of employment. In the alternative medium/short run closure, wages are sticky (exogenous), and the amount of labour force employed adjusts to changes in the economy. In reality, if the initial economy is not in a steady 20 state of employment and there is a large pool of unemployed labour force, one would expect that both employment and wages would adjust so that the true effect of the creation of the FTA on employment and wages would lie somewhere between the long run and medium/short run labour market closure. Therefore a sensitivity analysis has been made with regard to the labour market closure in South Africa. In order to allow for unemployment in the labour force, the standard GTAP closure for South Africa has been changed in such a way that the wage rate for both skilled and unskilled labour is fixed and the quantity supplied is allowed to adjust to changed market conditions post-liberalisation. This alteration more accurately reflects labour market conditions in developing countries, where typically an excess supply of unskilled labour is prevalent, labour which can be employed by industry at the going wage rate in the event of an expansion of production. Table 9 presents a comparison of the short run closure and the standard long run closure used in this analysis, comparing results from the full FTA in the absence of a Doha outcome. Table 9: Percentage change in wages and employment in South Africa Long run closure Wage Medium/short run closure Employment Wage Employment Unskilled labour 0.17 0.00 0.00 0.43 Skilled labour 0.25 0.00 0.00 0.56 Table 9 shows that fixing the wage rate exogenously in the model would result in an increase of employment by roughly 0.5 percent in the South African economy, but by definition, the wage rate remains constant this time. Table 10: Percentage change in TOT, real GDP, and factor income South Africa Percentage change in the price of endowments Labour market Quantity of Total Factor Unskilled Skilled closure Terms trade GDP income Land labour labour Capital Natural resources Long run 0.1091 0.0399 0.31 2.45 0.17 0.25 0.25 0.32 Short run 0.1055 0.2959 0.57 2.89 0.00 0.00 0.42 0.44 The increased amount of employed labour force due to the creation of the FTA increases the total factor income in the South African economy by an additional 0.26 percent compared to the standard labour market closure (Table 10). This 21 increase in income then translates into an increased consumption in the economy and therefore increasing South African welfare, measured by the money metric value of the Equivalent Variation (EV), from $122 to $520 million. The increase in employed labour force accounts for $278 million. Thus, an increase in the number of persons employed should, according to these results, be a priority for South Africa over an increase in the general wage rate. There is hardly any change in income in the other countries due to the changed labour market closure in South Africa and therefore little change in their demand for South African exports This outcome from an alternative labour market closure seems to be a constant feature of GTAP analysis in developing countries (Keck and Piermartin 2005) where an abundance of unskilled labour is a feature of the economy. The scenario analysis A 50 percent cut in all SACU/China Bilateral Tariffs with no NTB changes This scenario proxies an FTA that is not comprehensive by reducing all bilateral applied tariffs by 50 percent rather than the full 100 percent and not addressing Chinese NTBs. Brief summary results that place the 50 percent cuts in perspective will be given rather than a full and comprehensive discussion – and this format will be followed for all scenario analyses. When the removal of Chinese NTBs is not simulated there is a reduction in the benefits to South Africa; as we discussed in the main FTA report, these NTB impacts were significant. While the real GDP gains for South Africa were almost as much as in the full FTA, overall welfare shows just over 50 percent of the benefits to South Africa and China that the full FTA gives, with the difference in South Africa’s case being equivalent to (a) what the Republic gained in the full FTA from the removal of Chinese NTBs and (b) the terms of trade changes. There are, therefore, some compensatory factors at work here, and one is that South Africa’s gains from its own tariff removal are higher with less adjustment. This is so because a 100 percent removal of South African import tariffs increases the demand for Chinese commodities increasing its export price slightly, contributing negatively to South Africa’s TOT. With a 50 percent reduction in tariffs the negative contribution from the 22 TOT loss is reduced due to a lower demand for Chinese goods. The rest of SACU is marginally worse off than with the full FTA, while Botswana is slightly better off in welfare terms. The Doha outcome The manner in which the modelling has been undertaken enables us to present the results from an outcome from the Doha Development Round as proxied by a 30 percent cut in applied tariff rates across all countries for all products and a complete elimination of export subsidies. We present these results with some limited discussions. We leave it to history to judge how realistic this particular WTO outcome will prove to be. Table 11: Welfare from the 30% Doha outcome, $million Efficiency TOT Investment Total South Africa 230 116 48 394 Botswana 11 -1 8 18 Rest SACU 22 24 -1 45 2/015 850 -91 2,774 Rest SADC 264 -182 22 105 Rest Africa 2,997 -1,175 42 1,864 India 3,107 -677 135 2,565 EU 3,950 1,107 255 5,313 USA 69 -933 -894 -1,758 Brazil 666 295 5 966 Rest world 14,215 563 471 15,252 Total 27,551 -12 0 27,538 China Table 11 shows the global gains from an overall across-the-board 30 percent cut in global applied tariffs as representing a possible Doha Development Round outcome to be in the order of $27.5 billion. It is interesting that the overall welfare gain for South Africa of nearly $400 million from a modest Doha outcome is more than three times the gains of $121.6 million as shown in Table 5 from a full FTA with China. China, as expected, is a big gainer overall, as are the fellow developing nations of both India and Brazil. Interestingly, the rest of Africa is also shown as being a 23 substantial beneficiary of this outcome, with gains of almost $2 billion – a figure that is reduced by around $1 billion from the efficiency gains of better domestic resource allocation when the terms of trade go against the continent. This same pattern is also shown by rest of SADC, as the efficiency gains are almost negated by terms of trade losses. An interesting feature of the 30 percent Doha is that the outcome for the South African clothing and leather (footwear) sectors is very close to that of the full FTA with China outcomes. Production declines by around 20 percent in both cases – this is not surprising given the dominance of China in the unconstrained clothing markets of the world. The production and price of motor vehicles also decline, but only by one percent. The other manufacturing sectors face greater changes (some positive, some negative) relative to the Chinese FTA, but these adjustments are not large either way. Natural resources show no change, as this sector faces few barriers to trade. A full FTA following Doha, with NTB reductions This scenario proxies a comprehensive FTA by reducing all bilateral applied tariffs by 100 percent and addressing Chinese NTBs, but does so in a global environment following the Doha Round Agreement described above. In other words, how much will a modestly successful Doha outcome detract from the full FTA, or, conversely, what are the expected outcomes of a comprehensive FTA with China following such an outcome? In welfare terms, this scenario results in welfare gains to both South Africa and China that are just over 70 percent of the original full FTA gains. South Africa’s bilateral trade balance with China deteriorates by $185 million, while China’s trade balance also deteriorates but by a lesser $83 million. 50 % cut in all SACU/China bilateral tariffs after Doha 30% (and no NTM changes) Quite frankly, this FTA is not worth negotiating from a purely economic perspective. Firstly, consider that we have no gains from the removal of NTMs in China, and secondly, we have a less than comprehensive FTA following a global outcome from Doha. In welfare terms the results for both South Africa and China are 21 percent of 24 the full FTA in the absence of an outcome from Doha. South Africa’s bilateral trade balance with China deteriorates by $37 million, while China’s improves by $15 million. The scenarios – comments These scenarios add little to the overall picture, and are largely straight-line reducing extrapolations of the full FTA. Bibliography Keck, A. and Piermartini, R. 2005. Economic impact of EPAs in SADC countries. Geneva: World Trade Organization (WTO). Ministry of Commerce, China; and the Ministry of Foreign Affairs and Trade, New Zealand. 2004. A Joint Study Report On A Free Trade Agreement Between China and New Zealand. November 2004, p. 76. [Online]. Available: www..mfat.govtn/tradeagreements/nzchinafta/pdf/chinanzftastudy.pdf. Sandrey, R. 2006. South African merchandise trade with China. tralac Working Paper WP3/2006, March. 25 Switzerland.Working Papers 2002 US safeguard measures on steel imports: specific implications by Niel Joubert & Rian Geldenhuys. WP 1/2002, April A few reflections on Annex VI to the SADC Trade Protocol by Jan Bohanes WP 2/2002, August Competition policy in a regional context: a SADC perspective on trade investment & competition issues by Trudi Hartzenberg WP 3/2002, November Rules of Origin and Agriculture: some observations by Hilton Zunckel WP 4/2002, November 2003 A new anti-dumping regime for South Africa and SACU by Stuart Clark & Gerhard Erasmus WP 1/2003, May Why build capacity in international trade law? by Gerhard Erasmus WP 2/2003, May The regional integration facilitation forum: a simple answer to a complicated issue? by Henry Mutai WP 3/2003, July The WTO GMO dispute by Maxine Kennett WP 4/2003, July WTO accession by Maxine Kennett WP 5/2003, July On the road to Cancun: a development perspective on EU trade policies by Faizel Ismail WP 6/2003, August GATS: an update on the negotiations and developments of trade in services in SADC by Adeline Tibakweitira WP 7/2003, August An evaluation of the capitals control debate: is there a case for controlling capital flows in the SACU-US free trade agreement? by Calvin Manduna WP 8/2003, August Non-smokers hooked on tobacco by Calvin Manduna WP 9/2003, August Assessing the impact of trade liberalisation: the importance of policy complementarities and policy processes in a SADC context by Trudi Hartzenberg WP 10/2003, October An examination of regional trade agreements: a case study of the EC and the East African community by Jeremy Everard John Streatfeild WP 11/2003, October 26 Reforming the EU sugar regime: will Southern Africa still feature? by Daniel Malzbender WP 12/2003, October 2004 Complexities and inadequacies relating to certain provision of the General Agreement on Trade in Services by Leon Steenkamp WP 1/2004, March Challenges posed by electronic commerce to the operation and implementation of the General Agreement on Trade in Services by Leon Steenkamp WP 2/2004, March Trade liberalisation and regional integration in SADC: policy synergies assessed in an industrial organisation framework by Martine Visser and Trudi Hartzenberg WP 3/2004, March Tanzania and AGOA: opportunities missed? by Eckart Naumann and Linda Mtango WP 4/2004, March Rationale behind agricultural reform negotiations by Hilton Zunkel WP 5/2004, July The impact of US-SACU FTA negotiations on Public Health in Southern Africa by Tenu Avafia WP 6/2004, November Export Performance of the South African Automotive Industry by Mareika Meyn WP 7/2004 December 2005 Textiles and clothing: Reflections on the sector’s integration into the post-quota environment by Eckart Naumann WP 1/2005, March Assessing the Causes of Sub-Saharan Africa's Declining Exports and Addressing Supply-Side Constraints by Calvin Manduna WP 2/2005, May A Few Reflections on Annex VI to the SADC Trade Protocol by Jan Bohanes WP 3/2005, June Tariff liberisation impacts of the EAC Customs Union in perspective by Heinz - Michael Stahl WP4/2005, August Trade facilitation and the WTO: A critical analysis of proposals on trade facilitation and their implications for African countries by Gainmore Zanamwe WP5/2005, September An evaluation of the alternatives and possibilities for countries in sub-Saharan Africa to meet the sanitary standards for entry into the international trade in animals and animal products by Gideon K. Brückner WP 6/2005, October Dispute Settlement under COMESA by Felix Maonera WP7/2005, October 27 The Challenges Facing Least Developed Countries in the GATS Negotiations: A Case Study of Lesotho by Calvin Manduna WP8/2005. November Rules of Origin under EPAs: Key Issues and New Directions by Eckart Naumann WP9/2005, December Lesotho: Potential Export Diversification Study: July 2005 by Ron Sandrey, Adelaide Matlanyane, David Maleleka and Dirk Ernst van Seventer WP10/2005, December African Member States and the Negotiations on Dispute Settlement Reform in the World Trade Organization by Clement Ng’ong’ola WP11/2005, December 2006 Agriculture and the World Trade Organization – 10 Years On by Ron Sandrey WP1/2006, January Trade Liberalisation: What exactly does it mean for South Africa? by Ron Sandrey WP2/2006, March South African merchandise trade with China by Ron Sandrey WP3/2006, March The Multifibre Agreement – WTO Agreement on Textiles and Clothing by Eckart Naumann WP4/2006, April The WTO – ten years on: trade and development by Catherine Grant WP5/2006, May A review of the results of the 6th WTO Hong Kong Ministerial Conference – Considerations for African, Caribbean and Pacific (ACP) Countries by Calvin Manduna WP6/2006, June Trade Liberalisation: What exactly does it mean for Lesotho? by Ron Sandrey , Adelaide Matlanyane and David Maleleka WP7/2006, June Trade Briefs 2002 Cost sharing in international dispute settlement: some reflections in the context of SADC by Jan Bohanes & Gerhard Erasmus. TB 1/2002, July Trade dispute between Zambia & Zimbabwe by Tapiwa C. Gandidze. TB 2/2002, August 2003 Non-tariff barriers: the reward of curtailed freedom by Hilton Zunckel TB 1/2003, February The effects of globalization on negotiating tactics by Gerhard Erasmus & Lee Padayachee TB 2/2003, May 28 The US-SACU FTA : implications for wheat trade by Hilton Zunckel TB 3/2003, June Memberships in multiple regional trading arrangements : legal implications for the conduct of trade negotiations by Henry Mutai TB 4/2003, August 2004 Apparel Trade and Quotas: Developments since AGOA’s inception and challenges ahead by Eckart Naumann TB 1/2004, March Adequately boxing Africa in the debate on domestic support and export subsidies by Hilton E Zunckel TB 2/2004, July Recent changes to the AGOA legislation by Eckart Naumann TB 3/2004, August 2005 Trade after Preferences: a New Adjustment Partnership? by Ron Sandrey TB1/2005, June TRIPs and Public Health: The Unresolved Debate by Tenu Avafia TB2/2005, June Daring to Dispute: Are there shifting trends in African participation in WTO dispute settlement? by Calvin Manduna TB3/2005, June South Africa’s Countervailing Regulations by Gustav Brink TB4/2005, August Trade and competitiveness in African fish exports: Impacts of WTO and EU negotiations and regulation by Stefano Ponte, Jesper Raakjær Nielsen, & Liam Campling TB5/2005, September Geographical Indications: Implications for Africa by Catherine Grant TB6/November 2006 Southern Africa and the European Union: the TDCA and SADC EPA by Catherine Grant TB1/2006, May Safeguarding South Africa’s clothing, textile and footwear industries by Gustav Brink TB2/2006, May Agricultural Safeguards in South Africa by Gustav Brink TB3/2006, May The WTO Trade Policy Review Mechanism: application and benefit to SACU by Paul Kruger TB4/2006, June 29
© Copyright 2024