32 CHAPTER 3 TAXATION AND INCOME DISTRIBUTION 3.1 Introduction In Chapter 2 we discussed the theory of government expenditure in term of the provision of public goods. This chapter focuses on how to finance the provision of public goods as a component of government expenditure. Taxes are the main source of government revenue for financing government expenditure. The greater the government expenditure in the economy, the higher the demands on the government raising tax revenue. The implication is that many countries have implemented tax reform to increase tax revenues. Examples include the case of China (Bahl, 1999a), the case of Australia (Jonson, 2006), the case of Japan (Horioka and Sekita, 2007), the case of Russia (Martinez, Rider and Wallace, 2008), (Bawazier and Kadir, Nasution in Abimayu, 2009) in Indonesia and (World Bank Report and Georgia State University, 2009) in Pakistan. Performance of the tax system in Russia after the tax reform changed significant. For example, the share of tax revenue to GDP in the 1990s decreased from 26.4 percent of GDP in 1992 to 19.85 percent of GDP in 1998. After the tax reform, tax revenue’s share of GDP increased to reach 32.68% in 2005. However, it should be noted that not all countries that have conducted tax reform experience an increase revenues. Tax reform efforts are not something easily done by many countries. Countries face various obstacles and challenges when trying to implement tax reform. It should also be noted that tax reform is not done just once but often several times in a country. In regards to Indonesia, the tax system has been undertaken several times. During the period 19942008, tax reform continues in effect to increase self-reliance in development funding. Ten years after the first tax reform, or rather in 1994, the government has sought to improve tax provisions in order to reflect justice, legal certainty (for taxpayers and tax officials), and efficiency. During this period, much of country’s the tax law was established including the Law of Income Tax, the Value Added Tax, and the property tax. In 2003 tax reform was sought back especially in regards to tax administration in the medium and long term. In 2007 and 2008 the Directorate General of Taxes established the provisions of the General Tax Procedures and Income Tax laws as a refinement of the previous regulation. These tax reforms were aimed at reducing inefficiency and increasing state revenues. Changes in tax rates are one form of tax reform that will have a large impact on the economy. Taxes may or may not improve distribution of income. Similarly, taxes may make the economy better or worse off depending on the economic efficiency or inefficiency that they create. That is why, when the government tries to make changes to the tax system, such as the level of tax rates, it is not surprising that debates were had over who bears the burden of taxes and who these taxes should be imposed on? Are taxes imposed on consumers and producers fairly distributed? This question invites us to discuss the question of how taxes affect real income distribution. This chapter describes the theory of 33 taxation and income distribution. Discussion topics include tax incidence and the tax incidence through partial equilibrium and general equilibrium models. 3.2. Defining tax incidence Basically, an analysis of the theory of taxation consists of two parts; tax incidence and excess burden. Tax incidence analyzes which individuals bear the ultimate burden of taxes, that is, who bears the burden after the economy has adjusted to any changes caused by the taxes? Incidence is usually defined as the change in real private incomes and wealth as the result of the adoption or change of a tax. When government imposes taxes on certain commodities, which should bear the tax burden, consumers or producers? A consumer may bear the tax if they buy the commodity and will not bear the tax burden if they do not consume the commodity. The broader definition proposed by Sennoga, Sjoquist and Wallace (2008) that tax incidence is how the prices of factors of production and final goods and services change as a result of a tax. This means that tax affects on real incomes and wealth for both producer and consumers through the changes of the prices of factors production and final goods and services. When the firm charges the higher price level to consumers, consumers are only able to buy commodities in a number of smaller. This means that consumers bear some of the tax burden. At the same time, producers also bear some of the tax burden by accepting a lower price. Thus, if consumers want to avoid the tax burden, they simply reduce the amount of the product they consume or they can stop consuming the product. In a similar manner, firms may respond to higher taxes by selling in smaller quantities. There are two important terms that must be understood in relation to tax incidence analysis: the statutory incidence and economic incidence. Statutory incidence of a tax burden created by an individual or firm who sent a check to the government. Or statutory tax incidence is determined by who pays taxes to the government (Gruber, 2005). For example gasoline producers pay taxes to the government because that's the producer is imposed by tax (according to statutory incidence). In fact, the rules were not always to be valid because market can react to respond the tax. This reaction is called the economic incidence. Incidence tax is the tax burden measured through changes in the resources available to any economic agent as a result of taxation. For example, when a tax is imposed on gasoline producers in a perfectly competition market, producers raise prices to offset the tax burden and income producers will not fall by the amount of tax. The same thing for the consumer, when a tax is imposed on consumers in a perfectly competitive market, consumers will not want to pay taxes as much as commodity taxes. There are three rules regarding tax incidence as described by Gruber (2005); (i) The Statutory burden of a tax does not describe who really bears the tax. This ambiguity creates a market reaction. The reaction changes the resources available and then changes the behavior of economic agents. If the tax is borne by producers (statutory incidence), in fact it is partly borne by the consumers as well because producers can increase the prices to offset commodity taxes. Consumers can reduce the number of items purchased to offset price increases due to taxes. 34 (ii) The size of the market on which the tax is imposed is irrelevant to the distribution of the tax burdens. Tax incidence is identical whether the taxes are levied on producers or consumers. With certain tax rates charged to producers and consumers, consumers will always bear a greater tax and producers bear a number of smaller taxes. This means that the imposition of taxes in perfectly competitive markets is not relevant to the distribution of tax burdens. This occurs because of the market mechanism. (iii) Parties with inelastic supply and demand bear taxes; parties with elastic supply and demand avoid taxes. When a tax is levied on producers and consumers' demand curve is perfectly inelastic, it means that the tax increase is entirely borne by consumers. If the demand curve is perfectly elastic, producers bear the entire burden of taxation. To analyze in more detail the influence of tax incidence on income distribution, the following describes two models related to the incidence of tax: partial equilibrium model and general equilibrium models. 3.3. Partial Equilibrium Model of Tax Incidence In this section, we describe the effects of a commodity tax (unit tax on the commodity) by using a partial equilibrium model. How can producers and consumers respond to the tax? How does the tax affect price and quantity? Unit taxes on commodity imposed by producers A unit tax is a tax levied on commodities with a certain value. For example the government imposes a tax on gasoline that must be paid by the firm. Figure 3.1 shows the equilibrium price and quantity before tax. The vertical axis shows the price of gasoline per liter and the horizontal axis shows the quantity demanded. Dg shows the market demand curve for gasoline, Sg shows the supply curves for gasoline. In a perfectly competitive market, the amount of gasoline bought by consumers and produced by the suppliers is represented by Q *= 10 at equilibrium price level P *= 5 (thousand rupiahs). At this point the producers are willing to produce at 10 because of the firm's marginal cost of producing gasoline. Now, suppose that the government imposes a tax on gasoline of 1500 rupiah per liter. Do producers receive less than 1500 per liters of their production due to taxes? When a tax of 1500 is levied on producers, this is equivalent to an increase in the marginal cost of producing gasoline. Because the firms must pay the original cost and the marginal tax rate of 1500, the firm will increase the price of gasoline. In order to produce the same quantity of gas as before, firms must raise prices by 6500 rupiah. At the equilibrium conditions, where P *= 5000, there is excess demand. The amount requested by the consumer is 10, while the amount of gasoline to be sold by the firms is 8, at point C. At the price of 5000, there is shortage of gas production as much as 2 that is (10 – 8). Following a perfectly competitive market system, consumers compete for the available quantity for the firm. As a result, the consumer price is continuously increasing to arrive at the new equilibrium at the point of A. Now, the price at P3= 6000 is higher than before tax, and the quantity is 9. 35 Figure 3.1 Incidence of Tax Unit Imposed to Producers Pg Per liter (Rp) S’g Consumers Burden =1000 D P2=6500 Sg A P3=6000 E P*=5000 P1=4500 C B Producer burden= 500 Dg 8 9 Q*=10 Qg Figure 3.1 Incidence tax unit imposed to producer The question is how the tax will affect consumers and producers? In the new equilibrium, there are two prices; the price paid by consumers and the price received by producers. The price to be paid by consumers is P* plus tax (5000 plus 1500). Thus, the new equilibrium price is P3 = 6000 where the new supply curve, S’g and consumer's demand curve, Dg intersect. The price received by producer is P1 = 4500. Thus, at P1, the price is lower than the original price of P*. We can conclude that although the tax on gasoline is levied on producers, both consumers and producers become worse off. From the perspective of producers, the pain of the 1500 tax is somewhat offset by the fact that the price received by producers is 1000 more than the initial equilibrium price. Thus, producers have to pay 500 rupiah of the tax, just the portion that is not offset by price increases. From the perspective of consumers, the consumer feels some of the pain of the tax since they pay 1000 per liter, although they do not send checks directly to the government. Consumers actually bear 1000 rupiah more than 500 rupiah borne by producers. The amount borne by consumers is P3 - P*(6000 -5000) = 1000 rupiah. While the amount that should borne by producers is P*- P2 + tax (5000 - 6000 + 1500) = 500 rupiah. In total, the amount of tax received by the government is the rectangular region denoted by P1BAP3. By looking at this simple calculation it can be said that the tax is imposed on the firm but it is the consumer that actually bears the heavier burden. Unit taxes on commodity imposed by Consumers A commodity tax imposed on consumers (according to the Statutory) is basically equivalent to a commodity tax on producers as previously described. The only difference is the shift in the 36 curve. If consumers have to pay taxes, the consumer demand curve shifts while the supply curve does not change. Figure 3.2 shows the incidence of tax gasoline imposed on consumers. At the beginning equilibrium condition, consumers and producers agree on the price of P* = 5000 with a quantity of 10. How will the behavior of consumers and producers change as the government imposes a gasoline tax of Rp 1500 and what part of the tax will be borne by consumers? In response to a tax, the consumer reduces the amount of gasoline purchased. This is seen through a shift in the demand curve from Dg to D’g. Before the tax, consumers are willing to buy gasoline at point E for 10. Now, with the shift to the new demand curve, consumers are willing to buy 10 at a lower price where P2 = 3500 at point D, as long as they have to pay taxes for 1500 units of each purchase of gasoline. At the initial equilibrium price, P*= 5000, there is excess supply; the firm offers a quantity of 9, while consumers are only willing to buy 8. This implies an excess supply of 1. If the producers are willing to sell this surplus, they must reduce the price from P* = 5000 to P1 =4500. At this price, the new equilibrium occurs, where the amount purchased by consumers and sold by the firm is 9. The market price now at P1= 4500 is lower than the initial equilibrium price, P*= 5000. Intuitively, the incidence of tax imposed on consumers has two effects in the market; first, there is a change in the price paid by consumers and the price received by producers, the price falls from 5000 to 4500. Second, consumers must pay the government 1500 for each liter of purchase. At the equilibrium price P1 = 4500, an additional tax of 1500 paid by the consumer so the price paid by consumers is on P3 = 6000, indicated by A, with a quantity of 9. We can also measure how much tax burden should be borne by consumers. This calculation is done by taking the new equilibrium price and subtracting the initial equilibrium price plus tax. So P1-P* + tax (4500 - 500 + 1500) = 1000 rupiah. In this example, consumers bear 1000 rupiah of the 1500 rupiah gasoline tax. On the other hand the tax burden borne by producers is P *- P1 or (5000-4500) = 500 rupiah. The amount of taxes collected by the government is 1500 and is represented by the region P1BAP3. There are two important conclusions that can be drawn from Figure 3.1 and 3.2 namely: (i) Producers and consumers are worse off due to tax however, the consumer tax burden greater than the producers. (ii) Tax does not result in the equitable distribution of income. Figures 3.1 and 3.2 have two important implications: 1. The incidence of a commodity tax is independent of whether it is imposed on consumers or producers. 2. The incidence of a commodity tax depends on the elasticity of the supply and demand curves 37 Figure 3.2 Incidence of Tax Unit Imposed to Consumers Pg per liter (Rp) Sg Consumer burden= 1000 tax A P3=6 E P*=5 C B P1=4.5 Producer Burden= 500 P2=4 D Dg D’g 8 9 Q*=10 Qg Figure 3.2. Incidence Tax Unit Imposed to Consumers The Incidence of a tax of commodity is independent of whether is imposed on consumers or producers Looking back at Figure 3.1 we can compare between the old equilibrium prices and the new equilibrium price after the tax has been implemented. After the tax, producers still produce at a quantity of 10, but the price level, now at P2, is higher. This condition cannot hold as long as consumers have to pay the price level, P* + tax, at P2. Therefore, producers must shift their supply curve, S’g. The new supply curve intersects with the demand curve, so that there is a new equilibrium at point A, with a new quantity of 9. In this case, producers will pay taxes to the government of (P+tax), but partly of it will be borne by consumers, even if consumers do not have to directly pay the government (according to the Statutory incidence). The price received by producers has been lowered. However, because the consumers also bear part of the burden, the price received by the producers is not by lowered by the full amount of the tax. A very similar story occurs when the government levies a tax on consumers. If consumers want to maintain the same amount purchased at pre-tax levels, then they will be willing to buy at the lower price of P1 (Figure 3.2). However, at this price, the producer must accept a lower price and producers do not seem to be willing to accept that price. With the tax, consumers will shift the demand curve down and supply less. This condition occurs at the new equilibrium price level of P1 and a quantity of 9. The Price level paid by consumers is P3 because of the tax and the new price received by producers is P1. The conclusion is that a commodity tax has impact on both consumers and producers; however, consumers will bear a larger burden than the producers. This proves that the tax does not 38 reflect a fair distribution of income. Taxes cause there to be a difference between the price received by the producers and the price paid by consumers. This is often referred to as the tax wedge. Incidence of a tax of Commodity depends on elasticity of supply and demand Analyzing tax incidence through a geometric approach provides an easier understanding of how much the tax burden will be borne by consumers and how much will be borne by producers. The size of the tax burden depends on the elasticity of the demand and supply curves. The previous Figure shows that the tax burden borne by consumers is greater than that borne by the producers. This is due to inelastic demand curve. The more inelastic the demand curve, the greater the burden borne by the consumer, assuming other factors remains constant. Conversely, the more elastic the demand curve, the less tax burden. Similarly, a more elastic supply curve will result in a smaller tax burden on producers. Figure 3.3 Tax Incidences with Perfectly Elastic and Inelastic Supply Curve P Pc P tax tax S Pc=Po S Ps=Po Ps D D D’ Q2 Q1 D’ Q Panel A. Perfectly elastic of supply curve Price paid by consumers Increases by full the amount of the tax Consumers bear the entire burden of the tax Q Panel B. Perfectly inelastic of supply curve Price received by producers falls by full the amount of the tax Producers bear the entire burden of the tax Figure 3.3. Tax incidence with perfectly elastic and inelastic of supply curves: Figure 3.3 Panel A illustrates a tax levied on consumers and a perfectly elastic supply curve. This implies that consumers will bear the entire burden of the tax. This means that the added tax is paid entirely by consumers. Before the tax, consumers can buy Q at the price of Ps = Po. After tax, the consumer demand curve shifts to the left and the quantity purchased drops to Q1. The price paid by consumers is Pc and the price received by producers is Ps. Thus, if the supply curve is perfectly elastic, the consumers bear the entire burden of the tax. In Panel B, the shape of supply curve is perfectly inelastic. When a commodity tax is levied on consumers, the consumer demand curve shifts to the left, D'. The price received by producers is the intersection between S and D'. Note that Ps is exactly the same as the amount of taxes 39 minus Po. So the price received by producers falls by the size of the tax. However, the price paid by the consumers remains at Po. In this case, firms bear the entire burden of tax. Figure 3.3 can also be used to analyze tax incidence when the tax levied on producers. Who will bear the tax burden? In Panel A, for example, a tax is levied on producers and the producer supply curve shifts upward by the amount of tax. The equilibrium is achieved at the intersection of the new supply curve and the initial demand curve (not shown in the figure). The price to be paid by consumers increases by the amount of the tax. Thus, the entire tax burden is borne by consumers. Whereas in Panel B, the price paid by the consumers does not change after tax. This means that the entire tax burden is borne by the firm. This happens because the production does not depend on the price. Figure 3.4 Tax incidences with perfectly elastic and Inelastic demand curves P S’ Tax Borned by producers Pc=Po E1 S Pc tax E P D Ps=Po Tax Borne by consumers S’ D E1 S tax E Ps Q2 Q1 Q Panel A. Perfectly elastic demand curve Price received by producers falls by full the amount of the tax producers bear the entire burden of the tax Q Panel B. Perfectly inelastic of demand curve Price paid by consumers Increases by full the amount of the tax Consumers bear the entire burden of the tax Figure 3.4. Tax incidence with perfectly elastic and inelastic demand curves: Suppose that the shape of the demand curve is perfectly elastic or perfectly inelastic and the government levies a tax on producers (Figure 3.4). Who should bear the tax burden? Is it producers or consumers? The answer depends on the shape of the demand curve. Panel A shows the shape of the demand curve to be perfectly elastic. When there are taxes, the producer’s supply curve shifts up and becomes S' which intersects the demand curve, D. As a result, there is a new equilibrium at point E1. Because the demand curve is perfectly elastic, the consumers do not bear the price increase due to tax. Consumers are not affected at the level of prices, consumer prices remain at Po. Thus, all taxes due to price increases are borne entirely by the firm. The price received by producer decreases by the amount of the tax. Panel B shows 40 the case where the demand curve is perfectly inelastic. When a commodity tax is levied on producers and producers face perfectly inelastic demand, the resulting tax will shift the supply curve upward to S'. There is a new equilibrium at point E1. At point E1, the price paid by consumers will rise by the amount of the tax. Thus, consumers bear the entire tax if the demand curve is perfectly inelastic. Ad Valorem Taxes The above discussion focused on specific taxes or commodity taxes. Now we discuss ad valorem taxes. Specific tax is a tax imposed on a given commodities or output. While the ad valorem tax is a tax imposed as a given percentage of the price. What is the extent of the impact of ad valorem taxes on equilibrium? Are there similarities or differences in the impact of ad valorem taxes and the impact of specific taxes? Suppose the government imposes an ad valorem tax of 20 percent on consumers in the market. Figure 3.5 shows the ad valorem tax incidence. Pretax equilibrium is characterized by P* and Q*. Remember that a demand curve lists the maximum price that consumers are willing to pay for various quantities. So an ad valorem tax vertically lowers the demand curve facing producers by the amount of the tax. Unlike, a unit tax, however, an ad valorem tax is a percentage of the sales price, and therefore the demand curve does not shift down in a parallel manner. For example, at an initial price of 2000 per unit, the after tax price received by producers would be 1600. At an initial price of 200, the after tax price would be 160. This logic plots out D’ as the new demand curve facing firms and, as shown in Figure 3.5, the vertical distance between D and D’ falls as price falls. Point E1 is the after tax equilibrium, at the intersection of the after tax demand curve D' and the supply curve. The price received by producers is P1 and the price paid by consumers is P2. P1P2 reflects the ad valorem tax. The burden imposed on producers is P1P*, and for consumers it is P*P2. Thus, the ad valorem tax and specific tax have the same effect. Level of output sold, tax revenues, price paid by consumer and price received by producers are all the same. 41 Figure 3.5 Incidence Tax Ad Valorem P 2000 S 1600 P2 E P* Before Tax P1 E1 Ad Valorem Tax 200 160 D D’ Q1 Q* Q Figure 3.5. Incidence Tax Ad valorem Tax incidence with Imperfect Competition Taxation effects depend on market structure. The two most extreme market structures are perfect competition and imperfect competition. We consider monopoly as an example of imperfect competition. The imposition of taxes on firms that face the market structure of imperfect competition such as monopolist has a different impact on prices, tax revenues and output. The question is how big of an impact will taxes have on the firms when firms face imperfect competition market as opposed to when they face perfect competition? Figure 3.6 shows the initial equilibrium before the tax. The demand curve faced by a monopolist is D. The marginal revenue curve is MR. The MR curve lies below the demand curve and shows the extra revenue received by the firm from selling an extra unit of output. In this case, the firm chooses the amount of output Q*, where marginal cost and marginal revenue intersect. Recall that a monopolist reaches a maximum profit when MR = MC. Because the monopolist is a price taker, the monopolist sets the price along the consumer demand curve. At a price of Pm, the amount of output sold is Q1, so the total profit of the monopolist is the area of rectangle, PCAPm. 42 Figure 3.6 Equilibrium of a Monopolist before tax P Pm P Economic Profits A MC ATC C D MR Q1 Q* Q Figure 3.6. Equilibrium of a Monopolist before tax Now suppose that government imposes a unit tax on the commodity. What is the impact on the monopolist? The explanation is similar to that of a perfectly competitive market in that the demand curve faced by the monopolist shifts down by the amount of the tax, D1. The downward shift in the consumer demand curve results in a decrease in additional revenue received by the marginal revenue curve shifting downward to MR1. The marginal cost curve and average total cost curve also shift upwards because firms’ costs increase after the tax. These are labeled MC1 and ATC1, respectively (Figure 3.7). Many references such as Gruber (2005), Stiglitz (2000) and Rosen (2008) do not show the shift upwards of the marginal cost curve (MC) and the shift downward of the marginal revenue, (MR). The reason is that the final outcomes are identical. Now, however, the MC and MR shift is associated with the change of the monopolist’s situation. This is to make it easier for the reader to understand. The intersection between MR1 and MC1 is a necessary condition for maximum profit. The price received by the monopolist after tax is Pm1. The total average cost for output Q1 is the distance de. Thus, economic profit for a monopolist is a rectangle area, Pm1def (green color).This is the difference between the price received by the monopolist, Pm1 and the average cost per unit of output sold, de. The conclusion is (1) after tax, output Q1 <Q*, (2) the price paid by consumer goes up from Pm to Pc, (3) the price received by monopolist goes down from Pm to Pm1, (4) Economic Profit for monopolist goes down from PmACf (orange color) to Pm1def (green color). In the case of imperfect competition such as a monopoly, the tax effect depends on the shape of the demand curve. The same thing can be done with ad valorem taxes to the monopolist. 43 Figure 3.7 Incidence Unit Tax on Monopolist P MC1 G Pc A Pm After tax f d e ATC1 Before tax Pm1 C tax MR1 MR Q1 D D1 Q* Q Figure 3.7. Incidence a unit tax on Monopolist 3.4. General Equilibrium Model of tax incidence Tax incidence analysis using a partial equilibrium model, seems not to give a perfect analysis of tax incidence. A partial equilibrium model focuses only on one market. A partial equilibrium model assumed that the output produced is very small firms in comparison with the overall output. Thus, if there is a reduction in output due to the tax, the other firm did not share in the impact the tax. In many cases, firms are interdependent, so that if one of them is disrupted by a government policy such as a unit tax, then other companies would also be disrupted. More generally, when a tax imposed on a “large sector” relative to the economy, looking at only one particular market may not be enough. In this case, general equilibrium analysis takes into account the ways in which various markets are interrelated. Rosen (2008) discusses some of the weaknesses that are found by using partial equilibrium analysis; (i) because it only focuses on one market, it ignores other market feedback. For example consider the reduction in cigarette sales due to a tax. The tax causes farmers to not plant tobacco and they divert to other crops such as cotton. As a result, the cotton supply increases, prices fall and so on, eventually farmers who previously grew cotton share the burden of the cigarette tax. (ii) The partial equilibrium model produces insufficient information when it only focuses on the question of how the producer of a commodity is taxed. 44 To better understand let us illustrate through Figure 3.8 A and B. It is assumed that there are only two output markets in the economy, a market for electric fans and a market for chairs. These two outputs are interdependent. Figure 3.8A shows initial equilibrium by P* and Q*, the intersection of supply, Sf and Df. Now consider how a unit tax on producers of fans affects resource allocation in the market for fans. A unit tax, T causes a parallel shift in the supply curve to Sf + tax. This increases the equilibrium price to P'f and decreases the quantity to Q1. So far this analysis is no difference than before,. In this case, the price paid by the consumer is, P'f and the price received by producers is P1. So, the consumers bear the tax burden, P* P'f and producers bear the burden tax, P1P*. This is similar partial equilibrium model. However, the analysis becomes more complex if the electric fan market is associated with other markets, such as the chair market. If the resource has high mobility, a decline in market supply electric fan causes more resources to be diverts to the output of chairs. Resources previously used to produce the fan are no longer used and they transferred to chair output. Figure 3.8B shows the movement of the supply curve down to S'C. The intersection of the new supply curve and demand curve produces a new equilibrium, P1Q1, previously shown by P*Q*.Chair output increases and the output of electric fan decreases. Figure 3.8A Tax Incidence of General Equilibrium Model P Fan S’f+Tax Sf P’f A E P*f P1 B Df Q1 Q* Qf Figure 3.8.A Tax Incidence with General Equilibrium Model By using a general equilibrium model, the outputs of chairs and electric fans affect input markets and other markets as well. What will happen in others market? For example, the labor market for electric fans and the labor market for the chairs. In addition, the market for other inputs used to produce electric chairs and fans are also affected. 45 A general equilibrium model is relatively easy to understand in a world with two goods in which taxes are imposed only in one market. However, a unit tax may be imposed on both the fan market and also on the chair market at the same time. When the tax is imposed at the same time, it may be expected that resources will not shift as much as in the case in which a tax is imposed on only one market. If we extend the analysis past the two good cases to a case where hundreds or thousands of goods are produced, then the general equilibrium model becomes more complex. If we do not carefully analyze how the tax affects all markets then tax policy may ultimately be inefficient. Many empirical studies estimate the impact of a tax policy on the economy, by using general equilibrium model (see for example; Baldacci, E., Cangiano, M., Mahfouz, S., and Schimmelpfennig, A. 2001; Chakraborty, L.S., 2001; Blomquist, Eklof, and Newey, 2001; Benos, , 2004). They concluded that the taxes effect on income distribution depends on the political and economic conditions of the country. Figure 3.8 B Tax Incidences of General Equilibrium Model for Other Market P Chair Sc S’c E P* P’c A Dc Q* Q1 Qc Figure 3.8.B Tax Incidence with General Equilibrium Model for other Market The imposition of taxes both the consumer and the producer must be done carefully. Taxes policy is not always able to generate economic efficiency so that the income is not distributed properly. Horioka and Sekita (2007) conducted a analysis of personal taxes (defined to include consumption and income taxes), found that the structure of Japan’s current consumption and income taxes was problematic from the viewpoints of both efficiency and equity and propose a reform package that improves both the efficiency and equity of Japan’s personal taxes and, at the same time, achieves fiscal reconstruction. This finding, however, contradicted the finding by Bye and Avitsland (2003) for the case of tax reform in Norwegia. Bye and Avitsland analyzed the welfare effects of imposing a neutral system of housing taxation by using an intertemporal general equilibrium model (CGM) for the Norwegian 46 economy. They found that the tax reform implies a substantial increase in the tax revenue from housing taxation. The imposition of taxes to the producer can affect other economic variables such as labor hours, labor income, tax revenue, income distribution and investment. The tax system generates inefficiency in the labor market through both direct and indirect labor income taxation (Bye and Avitsland, 2003). The US Tax Reform of 1986 increased the intertemporal non-neutrality of the tax system, but this negative contribution to welfare was more than outweighed by the intertemporal efficiency gain of leveling the capital tax rates and reducing the labor income tax (Goulder and Thalmann 1993). Blomquist, Eklof, and Newey (2001) evaluated the tax reform carried out in Sweden between 1980 and 1991. They used a recently developed non-parametric estimation technique to account for the labor supply responses of married prime aged males. They decomposed the tax reform to study how the separate components influence hours of work, tax revenue, and income distribution. They found that the decrease in marginal tax rates stimulated labor supply. The net increase in average desired hours of work was approximately 2%. They also found that the reform was under financed and that inequality increased. The recent study regards to tax incidence conducted by Wahid and Wallace (2008) and Sennoga, Sjoquist, and Wallace (2008). Wahid and Wallace (2008) found that all households bear part of the burden of taxes in Pakistan, the higher income of households bear a larger share of the burden than low-income households. Taxes on capital would generally increase the tax burden on the higher income groups. In addition, they noted that changes in any tax (such as corporate income tax) can have impacts throughout the income distribution. Sennoga, Sjoquist, and Wallace (2008) developed a computable general equilibrium model (CGE) and tested the impact of various assumptions regarding specific issues that reflect the reality of property taxes in transition and developing countries. They pointed that the burden of property taxes imposed on capital and land is borne by the owners of land and capital and is not significantly influenced by the assumptions regarding the mobility of capital. From their analysis it appears that property tax is a vehicle for introducing some progressivity into the revenue structure of developing and transition countries. Capital income tax reductions are often used to stimulate economic activity during business downturns or to promote economic growth. In general, lowering capital income tax rates improves the after– rate of return of investment and facilitates capital accumulation. A higher capital stock, in turn, raises the marginal product of labor and the real wage. Consequently, it is often argued that capital income tax reductions have trickle–down effects because labor also benefits from a higher income. However, in the empirical study, capital income tax reduction did not create the trickle-down effects it depends on how government manages debt to maintain budget solvency (Shu-Chun Susan, 2007). Doing a tax cut for income distribution objectives in principle has two important implications: the financing of the tax changes, and the implications of behavioral responses for economic growth, incomes, and well-being. A tax cut can made some people are better off, especially for high-income households and most of the others are made worse off, especially in the lower three income quintiles (Douglas W.Elmendorf, Jason; Furman, William G; Gale and Benjamin H; Harris (2008). 47
© Copyright 2024