UCSC AMS/ECON 11A Supplemental Notes # 6 Elasticity c 2006 Yonatan Katznelson 1. Relative and percentage rates of change The derivative of a differentiable function y = f (x) describes how the function changes. The value of the derivative at a point, f 0 (x0 ), gives the instantaneous rate of change of the function at that point, which we can understand in more practical terms via the approximation formula ∆y = f (x0 + ∆x) − f (x0 ) ≈ f 0 (x0 ) · ∆x, which is accurate when ∆x is sufficiently small, (see SN5 for more details). This formula describes the change ∆y in terms of the change ∆x, which is very useful in a variety of contexts. In other contexts however, it is sometimes more appropriate to describe the change in y in relative terms. In other words, to compare the change in y to its previous value. Suppose, for example that you learn that a firm’s revenue increased by $2.5 million over the past year. An increase in revenue is generally a good thing, but how good is a $2.5 million increase? The answer depends on the size of the firm, and more specifically, on the amount of last year’s revenue. If in the previous year the firm’s revenue was $2.1 million, then an increase of $2.5 million means that revenue more than doubled, which means that the firm’s business is growing very robustly. On the other hand, if last year’s revenue was $350 million, then $2.5 million is an increase of less than 1%, which is far less impressive. The relative change in the value of a variable or function is simply the ratio of the change in value to the starting value. I.e., the relative change in y = f (x) is given by ∆y f (x0 + ∆x) − f (x0 ) = . y f (x0 ) Likewise, the relative rate of change (rroc) of a function y = f (x) is obtained by dividing the derivative of the function by the function itself, rroc = f 0 (x) 1 dy = · . f (x) y dx (1) Example 1 dy Suppose that y = x2 + 1, then = 2x, and the relative rate of change of y with respect to x dx is 2x 1 dy · = 2 . y dx x +1 When x = 4, the relative rate of change is 2 · 4/(42 + 1) = 8/17 ≈ 0.47, and when x = 10, the relative rate of change is 2 · 10/(102 + 1) = 20/101 ≈ 0.198. ♣ The relative change, and the relative rate of change are often expressed in the percentage terms, in which case they are usually called the percentage change and the percentage rate of change, respectively. Thus, the percentage change in y is given by %∆y = ∆y f (x0 + ∆x) − f (x0 ) · 100% = · 100%, y f (x0 ) 1 and the percentage rate of change (%-roc) of the function y = f (x) is simply the relative rate of change multiplied by 100%, %-roc = rroc · 100% = f 0 (x) 1 dy · 100% = · · 100%. f (x) y dx Example 1 (continued) The percentage rate of change of the function y = x2 + 1 is 1 dy 2x · · 100% = 2 · 100%. y dx x +1 When x = 4, the percentage rate of change of the function is 8 · 100% ≈ 47%, 17 and when x = 10 the percentage rate of change is 20 · 100% ≈ 19.8%. 101 ♣ Since the approximation formula provides an estimate for ∆y, it can also be used to estimate the percentage change, (∆y/y) · 100%. Specifically, if ∆x is sufficiently small, then the approximation formula says that ∆y ≈ f 0 (x0 ) · ∆x, and therefore %∆y = ∆y f 0 (x0 ) · ∆x · 100% ≈ · 100%. y f (x0 ) If we rearrange the factors on the right-hand side we obtain Fact 1 (Approximation formula for percentage rate of change) If y = f (x) is differentiable at the point x = x0 and ∆x is sufficiently small, then 0 f (x0 ) f (x0 + ∆x) − f (x0 ) · 100% ≈ · 100% · ∆x. (2) %∆y = f (x0 ) f (x0 ) In words, if ∆x is sufficiently small, then the percentage change in y is approximately equal to the percentage rate of change of y multiplied by the change in x. Example 1 (conclusion) We have already seen that for y = x2 + 1, the percentage rate of change when x = 10 is 20/101 ≈ 19.8%. Now, suppose that x increases from x0 = 10 to x1 = 10.4, so that ∆x = 0.4. Then, according to equation (2), the percentage change in y will be approximately %∆y ≈ (19.8%) · (0.4) = 7.92%. ♣ 2. Elasticity Economists frequently describe changes in percentage terms, and as described above, the derivative can be used to compute the percentage rate of change of a function. Another measure of change that we commonly see in economics is elasticity. Average elasticity is defined as a ratio of percentage changes. 2 Definition 1 For the function y = f (x), the average elasticity, Ey/x , of the variable y with respect to the variable x is given by the ratio Ey/x = (∆y/y) · 100% %∆y = . %∆x (∆x/x) · 100% (3) Note that elasticity is a units-free measure of change, since the percentage units in the numerator and denominator cancel each other. Example 2 A firm’s short-term production function is given Q = 20L1/4 , where Q is weekly output, measured in $1000’s and L is labor input, measured in 100’s of weekly worker-hours. In preparation for the holiday season, the firm increases labor input from 4000 hours per week to 4300 hours per week, in other words, L increases from L0 = 40 to L1 = 43. Correspondingly, the firm’s output increases from Q0 = 20 · 401/4 ≈ 50.297, to Q1 = 20 · 431/4 ≈ 51.215. In percentage terms, the change in labor input is %∆L = (3/40) · 100% = 7.5%, and the change in output is %∆Q ≈ (0.918/50.297) · 100% ≈ 1.825%. The firm’s average labor elasticity of output is therefore EQ/L = %∆Q 1.825% ≈ ≈ 0.243, %∆L 7.5% ♣ in this case. The instantaneous rate of change, a.k.a. the derivative, was defined by considering the limit of average rates of change over smaller and smaller intervals. In the same way, we define the point elasticity by considering the limit of average elasticity, as the length of interval of change goes to 0. Definition 2 For the function y = f (x), the point elasticity of y with respect to x is denoted η y/x , and is defined by η y/x = lim Ey/x = lim ∆x→0 ∆x→0 %∆y . %∆x (4) The point elasticity is often just called the elasticity. The limit in equation (4) is actually easy to compute, but to do so, we need to express the ratio (%∆y)/(%∆x) in more familiar terms. Namely, we have ∆y ∆y · 100% ∆y x %∆y y y = = = · . ∆x ∆x %∆x ∆x y · 100% x x Now, if we substitute the expression on the right-hand side of the equation above into the definition of point elasticity in equation (4), then we find that %∆y ∆y x ∆y x dy x η y/x = lim = lim · = lim · = · , ∆x→0 %∆x ∆x→0 ∆x y ∆x→0 ∆x y dx y or, simply put, η y/x = dy x · . dx y 3 (5) Comment: Given the function y = f (x), the elasticity η y/x is also a function of the variable x, η y/x = f 0 (x) · x, f (x) and we see that the point elasticity is simply the relative rate of change of y with respect to x, multiplied by x. Example 3 Returning to the production function, Q = 20L1/4 , from Example 2, let’s compute the elasticity of Q with respect to L at the point L0 = 40. First we compute η Q/L , η Q/L = dQ L 1 L 1 20 1 · = 20 · L−3/4 · = · · L−3/4 · L3/4 = , dL Q 4 4 20 4 20L1/4 i.e., the labor elasticity of output is constant in this case! In particular, the (point) elasticity of output with respect to labor input at the point L0 = 40 is equal to 0.25. ♣ Example 4 Household demand for a certain good is given by the function q = 20 ln(0.001y 3 + 1), where q is the number of units of the good consumed per year, and y is the annual disposable household income, measured in $1000’s. The income elasticity of demand is η q/y = dq y 0.003y 2 y 0.003y 3 · = 20 · · = . dy q 0.001y 3 + 1 20 ln(0.001y 3 + 1) (0.001y 3 + 1) ln(0.001y 3 + 1) If a household’s disposable income is $20000, then their income elasticity of demand for this good is 24 η q/y ≈ 1.2136. = 9 · ln 9 y=20 If a household’s disposable income is $30000, then their income elasticity of demand is 81 η q/y = ≈ 0.8681, 28 · ln 28 y=30 and if their income is $40000 then the income elasticity is 192 η q/y = ≈ 0.7076. 65 · ln 65 y=40 Can you show that η q/y is a decreasing function of y, for this demand function? ♣ What do these numbers mean? To understand how the (point) elasticity of y with respect to x may be interpreted, we return to the definition, %∆y . ∆x→0 %∆x η y/x = lim This means that when ∆x is sufficiently small, the ratio on the right is very close to the elasticity, i.e., when ∆x is sufficiently small %∆y ≈ η y/x . %∆x If we multiply both sides of this approximate equality by %∆x, we obtain 4 Fact 2 (The approximation formula for elasticity) If y = f (x) and ∆x is sufficiently small, then (6) %∆y ≈ η y/x · (%∆x) . Example 4 (continued) How will a household’s consumption of the good change, if their annual disposable income increases from $20000 to $21000? The $1000 increase represents a 5% increase, in other words %∆y = 5%, so according to the approximation formula above, %∆q ≈ η q/y · (%∆y) ≈ 1.2136 · 5% ≈ 6.068%. y=20 In other words, consumption will increase by a little more than 6%. If a household’s income increases from $40000 to $42000, again a 5% increase, then according to the approximation formula %∆q ≈ η q/y · (%∆y) ≈ 0.7076 · 5% ≈ 3.538%. y=40 ♣ Example 5 The supply curve1 for the widget market is given by qs = 300(0.5p − 10)4/3 , where qs is the quantity of widgets supplied weekly, and p is the price of a widget. The price-elasticity of supply is 4 p dqs p 2p 1/3 · = 300 · (0.5p − 10) · (0.5) · . η qs /p = = 4/3 dp qs 3 1.5p − 30) 300(0.5p − 10) When p = 30, the price-elasticity of supply is η qs /p = 60/15 = 4, and when p = 60 the elasticity is η qs /p = 120/60 = 2. In general, as the price rises, the price elasticity of supply in this example decreases, but it never goes below η 0 = 1.5. Can you prove the last statement above? You should begin your attempt by phrasing the statement in terms of a limit. ♣ To be continued... 1 This model for supply only makes sense once the price of widgets is high enough so that the supply is positive, i.e., when p > 20. 5
© Copyright 2024