Preliminary. Please do not distribute. The Choice of Going Public and Going Private: Evidence from UK Alon Brava, Omer Bravb, Wei Jiangc a Duke University, Durham, NC 27708, USA b c Lehman Brothers, New York Columbia University, New York, NY 10027 Abstract Using a database of virtually all incorporated firms in the UK, public and private, we study the transition of firms from a quoted to unquoted status and vice versa. We find that firms are more likely to be quoted when they face large investment opportunities. Firms are more likely to be quoted on a stock exchange when they are already engaged in high levels of capital investment, when their industry market to book valuations are high and when their growth rates are high. After going public firms’ investment intensity increases. Keywords: Initial Public Offering, Going Private 1. Introduction The decision to list on or delist from a stock exchange is one of the most important events in a company’s life cycle and has generated a wide array of theoretical contributions in the corporate finance literature. While many theories have been proposed to explain why some firms transit from one status to the other and others do not, there is little empirical evidence in the area. This state of affairs is not surprising, however. As argued by Ritter and Welch (2002), formal theories of IPO activity are difficult to test since we usually only observe the set of firms that actually go public and not those private firms that could have gone public but did not. Moreover, lack of empirical evidence affects not only our ability to test theories of IPO activity but also the transition from public to private status (as we do not observe what happens with the firms after going private), and more generally the tradeoff between being and not being listed on a stock exchange. Using a new database containing information on virtually all firms in the U.K., public and private, we are able to provide an extensive set of tests of models that make predictions regarding the tradeoff between being listed on a stock exchange versus remaining private. Our paper builds on earlier work by Pagano, Panetta and Zingales (1998) who focus on the going public decision of a sample of Italian firms. Pagano et al find that larger companies and companies in industries with high market to book ratios are more likely to go public, and that companies going public seem to have reduced their costs of credit. Interestingly, they find that capital expenditure and growth are only secondary factors that explain IPO activity while high investment and growth do not follow after going public. This paper differs from Pagano et al. in at least two major aspects. First, while the stock market plays an important role in the UK economy (as in the US), it plays a much limited role in Italy. As a result, this study provides direct evidence on the going public/private decisions for economies where the stock market plays a significant role. Furthermore, Aganin and Volpin (2003) argue that: “Recent contributions show that the Italian corporate governance regime exhibits low legal protection for investors and poor legal enforcement (La Porta, et al., 1998), underdeveloped equity markets (La Porta, et al., 1997), pyramidal groups, and very high ownership concentration (Barca, et al., 1995). Arguably, due to these institutional characteristics, private benefits of control are high (Zingales, 1994), and minority shareholders are often expropriated (Bragantini, 1999).” - 1- Similarly, Zingales (1994) provides an example of how the Italian legal system provides exceptionally weak protection of minority rights. These facts raise the concern that it may be hard to extrapolate Pagano et al’s results from the Italian market to more developed financial markets like the U.K. or the U.S. Second, instead of treating the decision to go public as a one shot irreversible decision, we view the decision to be public as a reversible dynamic decision (see Benninga, Helmantel and Sarig (2003)). The approach taken in this paper builds on the idea that the tradeoffs that determine whether are firm will be quoted should apply to private as well as public firms. If the tradeoffs between being public or private are the same regardless of the state of the firm (up to transaction costs which can be captured by controlling for the previous state of the firm), the proper population of interest is all the firms, not only private firms, and the relevant model is one that explains the state (public or private) of the firm rather than the decision to go public. This approach, as clarified below, treats the whole path of each firm as one observation without ignoring the information content in the decision made by the firm once it has gone public. Last, the third benefit from our analysis is purely econometric and stems from the fact that studying a much more active stock market like in the U.K., allow for a large number of transitions between public and private status (and vice versa) and thus increased statistical power for our tests. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In Section II we provide a summary of the theoretical literature regarding the decision to go public and private. Section III describes the data. First we describe the data sources and their qualitative characteristics, and then the sample under study. Section IV discusses the theoretical motivation for the empirical tests. Section V contains the results of the paper. We conclude in Section VI. 2. Literature Review Several reasons have been proposed in the academic literature to explain why owners of firms decide to go public.1 In a survey of new stock market entrants, Roell (1996) documents five reasons, among which three were reported by stock market entrants themselves. The first is 1 Throughout the paper we use the terms public, quoted and listed interchangeably. In all cases we mean a firm whose shares are traded on a stock exchange. Notice, however, that in the UK “Public” refers to the legal status of the firm while “Quoted” companies are those companies listed on a stock exchange. In other words, while private firms in the UK are necessarily unquoted, public firms may be quoted or unquoted. See also section ??? for further distinction between these two terms. - 2- access to new finance. The motives for new finance include prospects of growth by acquisition, funds for organic expansion and refinancing of current borrowings. Yet, this in itself does not justify an IPO since bank loans or private equity placements may equally well finance the need for funds. Leland and Pyle (1977) and Chemmanur and Fulghieri (1999) argue that entrepreneurs gain by going public because diversified investors value firm shares more than underdiversified entrepreneurs. Black and Gilson (1998) argue that the assumption of private benefits of control is a standard feature in venture capital models and, more generally, in models that seek to explain the incentive properties of capital structure and that at least for entrepreneurs, appears to be descriptively accurate. The failure rate for startup companies is high enough so that without a large private value for control, many potential entrepreneurs would decide not to leave a secure job to start a new company. By going public, the entrepreneur can raise money from many small investors without loosing control. Moreover, Black and Gilson (1998) argue that in the case of venture capital back companies, the IPO exit of the venture capitalists gives the entrepreneur the opportunity to regain control over the firm. With the same spirit of taking into account the private benefits of control, Pagano and Roell (1998) argue that by going public the initial owner can raise money while achieving the optimal ownership structure from her point of view. This optimal structure is not too concentrated in that it maximizes firm value net of monitoring costs, because she takes into account her own future private benefits. Such sufficiently dispersed ownership structure is in general less costly when the firm is public (depending on the fixed costs of going public versus the variable costs associated with each additional shareholder when the firm remains private). A second reason for going public is enhanced company image and publicity (see Stoughton, Wong, and Zechner (2001)). Public listing provides not only an initial certification by financial market professionals but also a longer term price signal to suppliers, workforce and customers. A robust equity price in the aftermarket reassures suppliers that they can safely grant trade credit, to workers that they can expect a fairly stable job, and to customers that the product will be supported after their purchase. As argued by Stoughton et al (2001) there is a critical importance that consumers react to the information contained in the stock price and do not base their purchase decision only on whether the firm went public. This fact insures that indeed a separating equilibrium exists, and the high quality firms go public. - 3- The third reason for listing is to motivate management and employees. This is a natural response to the company’s signal of growth, but more importantly, share participation schemes help to retain and motivate senior management and employees. Presumably this cannot be achieved with private equity, because employees do not wish to be at the mercy of the controlling group when they leave the company and want to cash out their stake. Alternatively, as suggested by Holmstrom and Tirole (1993), a well informed stock price is of value in itself as an input into managerial performance-linked compensation, thus reducing agency costs. Fourth, issuing the firm’s shares on a stock exchange is a means for the initial owners to cash out. Obviously, as noted in Roell (1996), this reason is not emphasized in IPO prospectuses. Nonetheless, Roell documents a few studies that report that a significant share of the money raised from the public went to the original owners. Divestment by the initial owners does not necessarily have to happen at the IPO, but rather tends to continue in the years following the IPO. For example, Brennan and Franks (1997) find that in less than seven years after the IPO, almost two thirds of the offerings company’s shares have been sold to outside shareholders. More specifically they argue that “The pattern of ownership post-IPO is consistent with the view that going public is a vehicle for the disposal of shares by non-directors”. Regarding venture capital backed firms, Black and Gilson (1998) emphasize the importance of exit by the venture capital fund from its investments. Clearly, cashing in cannot be a reason by itself to go public, as the initial owners can sell the firm privately. Black and Gilson (1998) argue that exit (or cashing in) of the venture capital through an IPO rather than through a private sale is optimal as it is a method to return the private benefits of control to the entrepreneur. Zingales (1995) argues that there are two possible sources of a buyer’s higher valuation which the incumbent should seek to capture: the increase in cash flow and the increase in private benefits of control. In addition, the market for cash flow rights is populated by a large number of small investors and so is fully competitive, while the market for controlling blocks, which is restricted to a few large investors who derive private benefits from controlling a company, is not fully competitive. If the potential buyer is expected to increase the future value of cash flow rights, Zingales argues that while the incumbent will not be able to extract the buyer’s full reservation value through direct bargaining, by selling first the cash flow right to dispersed shareholders, the incumbent is able to fetch the cash flow right’s full value under the buyer. Therefore, Zingales concludes that by selling the company by first going public the initial owners facilitate the acquisition of their company for a higher value than they would get from an outright sale. - 4- The fifth possible reason for going public is when initial owners identify mispricing in the capital market. For example, in documenting the long run underperformance of IPOs, Ritter (1991) argues that the patterns of the data are consistent with an IPO market in which investors are periodically overoptimistic about earnings potential of young growth companies and firms take advantage of these “windows of opportunity”. Similarly, Lerner (1994) shows that venture capital backed companies go public when equity valuations are high and employ private financings when values are lower. There are at least two additional reasons for firms to go public. First, as suggested by Amihud and Mendelson (1988), going public make the firm’s shares more liquid and so more valuable to its owners. Second, Benveniste and Spindt (1989) and Maug (2000), among others, argue that IPOs allow entrepreneurs to use share prices to infer investor valuations of their firm. This information can be used in post-IPO investment decisions. While the theories discussed focus on going public decision, there are several benefits to remaining a private firm. First, the registration and underwriting costs of an IPO. For example, Ritter (1987) reports that on average these costs amount to 14% of the funds raised. Second, the advantage of staying private which allows the company to avoid ongoing administrative costs associated with being public (e.g. filing requirements, audited financial statements, etc.). Third, the well documented underpricing at the time of an IPO serves as another cost of going public. For example, Loughran, Ritter and Rydqvist (1994) report an average initial return of 15.3% in the U.S. Fourth, as suggested by Yosha (1995), among others, the increased disclosure of inside information required from public firms serves as an additional cost. Such disclosure might reduce the competitive advantages of the company. Finally, going public naturally creates a separation between ownership and control. This separation may lead to agency problems (Jensen and Meckling (1976)). For example, Jensen (1986) argues that many of the benefits in going private and leveraged buyout transactions seem to be due to the control function of debt. Jensen argues that desirable leverage buyout candidates are frequently firms or division of larger firms that have stable business histories and substantial free cash flow – situation where agency costs of free cash flow are likely to be high. Opler and Titman (1993) argue that several organizational aspects of leveraged buy outs (“LBOs”) may allow firms to realize the gains while avoiding many of the associated costs of financial distress. These features include (1) an institutionalized debt workout process that may lower bankruptcy costs, (2) strip financing where debt and equity - 5- are owned by the same investors which decreases conflict between different classes of security holders , and (3) LBO sponsorship by specialist firms with reputational incentives to look out for debtholder interests. 3. Data 1.0. Sources The data for this paper comes from several sources. We obtain balance sheet, income statement and cash flow statement information from the Financial Analysis Made Easy (FAME) database. Information on IPOs (going public) and public takeovers (going private) deals is taken from the SDC Platinum (“SDC”) database, and is complemented with Zephyr for the period 1997 to 2003. Data for calculating industry market to book valuations is taken from the Worldscope database. Finally, to compute industry R&D medians (classified by U.S. SIC codes) we extract R&D values from Compustat for US public firms. Since the use of FAME is quite novel, we provide some information on it below. FAME is a database provided by Bureau van Dijk (“BvD”). BvD is one of Europe's leading electronic publishers of business information.2 Under current company legislation in the U.K. companies have a specific period of time from their year end date in which they must file their accounts (Balance sheet, Profit & Loss and Cash Flow statements) at Companies House. Companies House is an executive agency of U.K. Department of Trade and Industry. The main functions of Companies House are to incorporate and dissolve limited companies, examine and store company information delivered under the Companies Act and related legislation, and make this information available to the public.3 The time period in which the company must file its accounts at Companies House depends on the type of the company. A Public Limited Company has up to 7 months and a Private Limited Company has up to 10 months from its year end date to file its accounts.4 Once accounts are filed at Companies House they are processed and checked, put onto microfiche, and made available to the public. Companies House aims for a turnaround 2 For more information about BvD: http://www.bvdep.com/. For more information about Companies House: http://www.companieshouse.gov.uk/about/functionsHistory.shtml. 4 It is worthwhile to note here that “public” in the UK context refers to the legal status of the firm. Although being a public firm is one necessary condition for being listed on the London Stock Exchange (LSE), being public does not mean necessarily that the firm’s shares are traded on the stock exchange (for further details about requirements to be listed on the LSE see section 2.0). In fact, most public firms in the UK are not quoted. For further details about the definition and requirements from public firms in the UK see the Companies House website at: http://www.companieshouse.gov.uk/about/gbhtml/gbf1.shtml#two. 3 - 6- time of 7-14 days. Jordans, a U.K. leading provider of legal information,5 collects data from Companies House daily and transfers it from microfiche to their database with a turnaround time of 3-5 days. Finally, BvD collects data from Jordans on a weekly basis and creates the appropriate search indexes to link with the search software. Once these indexes are tested, a DVD-ROM is created and sent to a manufacturer for duplication and then issued to clients. The DVD version used in this paper is the November 2003 release 173.0.6 There are two main categories of variables in FAME - static and annual. When a variable is annual (mainly accounting data) the values of a given variable are reported for each accounting year end. While FAME includes data for active and dead firms, it keeps data for no more than 10 years for each firm. Hence, companies that have existed long enough and their last year of reported data is before 2002 (mainly firms which have ceased to exist), may have accounting data which dates back prior to 1993. Similarly, the accounting data of active companies dates back at most to 1993 if they have their accounts filed in FAME only up to 2002 and back to 1994 if they have their 2003 accounts already filed in FAME or, obviously, later if they were incorporated after 1993. To avoid any selection bias we use in the analysis below only sample years for which FAME includes all those firms which were registered at the time in Companies House. Therefore the period of analysis in this paper is 1993-2003.7 When a FAME variable is static (or a header variable) this means that only the last year’s reported value exists in the database. Unfortunately, some informative variables, such as the company type (private, public unquoted, public quoted etc.), are static even though they may change from time to time. This fact implies that the history of the firm related to its quoted status needs to be extracted from other sources. We gather information from two sources to extract this information. The first is SDC Platinum, a Thomson Financial database. SDC contains information on multiple deal types including M&A activity, IPOs, going private and joint ventures. Data for the U.K. is available in SDC for the whole sample period from 1993 to 2003. We identify firms that listed on the London Stock Exchange (“LSE”) by extracting all the IPO 5 For more information about Jordans and links to other Jordans websites: http://www.jordans.co.uk/. We thank Mitch Gouss from the New York branch of Bureau van Dijk for providing us with the FAME DVDROM 7 Since part of the active firms have already accounts for 2003 and some only to 2002, the period that truly contains data on all firms in the UK is 1994-2002. However, in order to avoid the loss of data we define our sample period to be 1993-2003. 6 - 7- deals, and firms that delisted by extracting all going private deals. In addition, since SDC does not cover all IPO and going private deals, we complement it with Zephyr. Zephyr, like FAME, is a database provided by BvD. Just like SDC, Zephyr contains information on multiple deal types including M&A activity, IPOs, public to private and joint ventures. There is no minimum deal value for inclusion and senior researchers at Zephus verify all deals before adding them to Zephyr. Data for the U.K. in Zephyr begins in 1997. For the period 1997 to 2003 Zephyr gives a more complete coverage of the IPO and going private deals. Indeed, the two sources do not overlap for the 1997-2003 period, but rather complement each other. 2.0. Sample Since our goal is to study the determinants of the decision to list on or delist from the LSE, we restrict attention to quoted and unquoted firms that satisfy the listing requirements for the LSE. The main requirement that effectively restricts a firm from listing on the LSE is related to the firm’s market value.8,9 A company that lists its shares on the LSE must have a total market capitalization of no less than £700,000.10 The problem with this requirement is that the market capitalization is unobservable for unquoted firms. Therefore, in the analysis below we consider firms to satisfy the market capitalization requirement if according to the Companies House definition they are “medium” or “large”.11 Since financial firms such as banks and insurance companies are intrinsically different in the nature of their operations and accounting information, we exclude any firm that is classified as financial according to its primary U.S. SIC code, primary US SIC code first digit is 6, from FAME and the deals databases (SDC and Zephyr). Since the definition of a firm’s status (public or private) and its transition status is crucial to the analysis in this paper, it is worthwhile to clarify how this classification is done. Consider 8 Here we mean a requirement that cannot be overcome by management exerting some effort or cost. For a detailed description of the listing requirements to the LSE see chapter 3, “conditions for listing”, in the UKLA source book. This can be accessed at: http://www.fsa.gov.uk/pubs/ukla/chapt03-3.pdf. For a brief overview see, “A practical Guide to Listing” from the LSE website, which can be accessed at: http://www.londonstockexchange.com/livecmsattach/1222.pdf 10 This market cap requirement was taken from the 2002 sourcebook. I tried to contact both the LSE and the UKLA to get older versions and see whether this requirement was intact during all my sample period. Both authorities said they do not keep archives of the sourcebooks, and the only information I was able to get from somebody who works in the UKLA for a long time is that “this requirement is there for quite a while”. Therefore, in this paper, I assume that this market cap requirement was valid throughout the sample period (1993-2003). 11 I use also alternative selection procedure, described in detail in section 1.0, which provides very similar results. 9 - 8- first the definition of a private to public transition. In reality, firm’s shares may become publicly listed directly through an IPO, but it may also indirectly go public through a merger or acquisition deal with an already publicly listed company. Since it is plausible that many of the M&A deals are motivated by other economic considerations which are unrelated to the public / private tradeoff - such as operating synergies, market monopoly considerations or tax advantages - we define as a private to public transition only IPOs. Similarly, a firm may be delisted because it went private directly or after being acquired by another unlisted firm. For similar reasons, we include only going private deals (and exclude M&A deals) in the definition of public to private transition.12 Hence, firms that appear in the deals databases at least once are defined as public after an IPO and private before the IPO and vice versa for a public to private transitions. The status of firms that are not involved in any transition (appear in neither SDC nor Zephyr) is defined according to their “Company type” value in FAME. Another issue arises in identifying when a company can be considered as publicly traded. Besides the Official List (OL) and the Alternative Investment Market (AIM) on the London Stock Exchange, by far the most important one, U.K. companies may list in at least another important domestic exchange, the London OFEX, as well as internationally. In the results presented below we include all available deals – firms that went public on any exchange are treated as quoted after the IPO.13 Similarly, for non-deal firms, we classify as ‘quoted’ firms whose company type is defined in FAME as equal to “Public Quoted”, “Public AIM” and “Public OFEX”.14 12 In Zephyr a Public to Private deal is defined as one involving a public takeover which is financed by a venture capital (this includes the various types of the commonly accepted going private deals: MBI, MBO, IBO and LBO). In SDC, public to private deals are defined according to the “going private flag”. 13 Among the IPOs there were also 264 with missing stock exchange name. 14 “OFEX is a market for dealing in unquoted and unlisted securities. It is a market regulated by the FSA (Financial Services Authority) but it is not a Regulated Investment Exchange nor is it a member of the Stock Exchange. Companies on OFEX tend to be smaller than those that apply for membership to AIM, typically seeking to raise capital in the region of £250,000 to £500,000. It also suits those companies not seeking to raise capital but who want to create a dealing facility for their shareholders without having the burden and expense of meeting the main exchange regulations. The requirements of joining OFEX are less onerous than those of applying to the Official List or AIM.” (Source: http://www.grant-thornton.co.uk/pages/services-raising_finance_and_flotations-ofex.html). The firms listed in OFEX and internationally represent a minority of the listings in my sample (85 and 9 IPOs respectively, less than 10% of all the IPOs) and therefore should not have a significant effect on the results presented in this version of the paper, one may be concerned that due to their different characteristic, these firms should not be treated as publicly listed firms. Furthermore, the listing requirements we apply throughout, apply only on the LSE. Therefore, as discussed in section Error! Reference source not found., for robustness check we plan to check the results considering only listings on the LSE. - 9- 3.0. Summary Statistics It is important to note first, that all the figures in the tables are after dropping top and bottom 1 percent of extreme values for each variable. Since apriori it is plausible to assume that the distributions for quoted, unquoted, go private and go public firms are different, I drop (mark as missing) extreme values separately for each of these 4 groups. Table 1 contains summary statistics on the sample of interest – All quoted firms (as all of these firms can elect to go private), and only private firms that are medium or large according to the Companies House definition, which as discussed earlier serves as a proxy for the market requirement for listing on the LSE. Notice that panel A is biased upwards relatively to panel B since panel A includes only large and medium private firms as defined by the Companies House while panel B includes all listed firms, regardless of their book size. For example, the minimum total assets are 1401 and 49, respectively. To make sure that our results are not affected by the fact that the analysis is tilted to low multiple industries, we repeat the analysis with market capitalization approximated with industry multiples. Each panel includes all firm-year observations that belong to the panel classification. Note that any single firm could belong at different periods to a different panel. At the top of each panel is the number of firms that belonged to the panel at least for one accounting period. As one may expect quoted firms are on average larger in any dimension (Total assets, turnover, profit, CAPEX, Cash), however, some of the unquoted firms are very large and are comparable to the large quoted firms. -10- Table 2 presents the sample summary statistics. It provides information on the subset of firms that were involved in a transition from public to private or vice versa. Since the sample period is 1993-2003, and since the analyses below require data on the firm before the deal took place, the information collected on the deals is for the period 1994-2003.15 Panel A provides summary statistics of the IPO deals immediately before and after the IPO. Since some 40% of the IPO deals did not have a record in the FAME database before the IPO as the firm was incorporated just before as a holding group, we collect the data for these firms manually from their IPO prospectuses. A few distinct features of the data that will be further explored in Section V can be already seen. Not only do IPO firms grow larger, as might be expected due to the raising of new capital, their capital expenditure increases and their leverage decreases significantly. More importantly, comparing the summary statistics of the IPO firms with those of the universe of the unquoted firms that satisfy the listing requirement (panel B of table 1), firms that choose to go public have a higher level of capital expenditures (before and after the IPO) and a much higher growth rate. Panel B provides some summary statistics of the going private deals immediately before and after the deal. First notice that the growth rate and level of capital expenditures decrease after going private. In addition also profitability decreases. Comparing firms that go private to the universe of quoted firms (panel B of table 1), the average quoted firms that choose to go private is smaller but the median is larger. 4. Factors related to the quoted/unquoted Status of the firm In examining the public versus private tradeoff, we focus on certain firm and industry level characteristics that are observable and apriori may influence the relative attractiveness of one status over the other (Brau, Francis and Kohers (2003)). We discuss the possible impact of these factors in the following subsections. It is important to point out that some of the theories presented in the literature review section do not have empirical testable implications. More importantly, since firms are not homogenous, and different firms may be motivated to go public 15 The numbers of deals are comparable to those presented in other papers. For example, for the period from1998 to 2000, Weir and Laing (2000) find 116 public to private transactions including financial firms, and 95 transactions excluding financial firms and firms with missing data. In our sample there are 118 public to private transactions of non financial firms for the same period. Khurshed et al (2004) report 415 initial public offerings of U.K. operating companies for the period 1995 to 1999 on the LSE market only. Our sample for the same period consists of 488 IPOs, of which 14 were on OFEX, 6 on international exchanges and 153 with a missing stock exchange name. -11- or private for a combination of different reasons with different weights, an estimated coefficient that is not consistent with the predictions of a theory cannot provide enough evidence to reject the theory. In other words, the purpose of the analysis in this paper is not to distinguish among or reject any of the theories as possible explanations to the going private and public activity, but rather, loosely speaking, to see “on average” which of the theories play a major role in explaining the public to private and private to public transitions. 1.0. Previous Status of the firm The transition between being quoted and unquoted on a stock exchange is not costless. As noted in the introduction the registration and underwriting costs of an IPO are substantial. There are also substantial frictions in going private that are highlighted in Meisner (2002) and Johnson and Weidhaas (2001). Most going-private deals are done by large equity funds that specialize in leveraged buyouts. Most of these investors generally look at going-private deals as a costly and time consuming since “they still have to find a buyer for it or take it public again so they can see a return on their investment, and that's a real pain.” A second factor is the sheer legal complexity involved. “Neal Suggs, a securities lawyer with Orrick Herrington & Sutcliffe LLP in Seattle, argued that going-private deals are much more complicated than initial public offerings.” A third factor that might constrain going private transaction is that at times in which debt markets tighten, financing such deals necessarily becomes costlier. Fourth, going private transactions take a long time to complete. It is difficult for buy-out firms to commit to a process that may take six months to complete, if it is completed at all. Therefore, “everything else equal”, the probability of a quoted (unquoted) firm to be quoted (unquoted) in the following period should be larger than that of an unquoted (quoted) company. In addition the previous status may proxy for unobserved time invariant effect (such as firm desire to have a specific type of corporate governance and therefore choose to stay private every period). This would have the same effect as the frictions discussed above. 2.0. Size Several theories predict that the propensity to go public should be higher for larger firms. On the cost side of going public, a larger firm may be less exposed to the adverse selection costs due to informational asymmetries between the issuer and the less informed investors at the time of the IPO. The adverse selection cost may be a more serious obstacle to the listing of small -12- companies (controlling for age) which have little track record and low visibility than larger companies. In addition, while many of the ongoing administrative expenses of publicly listed companies are fixed (Pagano et al (1998) and Ritter (1987)) some of the benefits are positively related to the size of the company. First, if larger companies are involved in larger investment projects, then being quoted would play a more important role for such companies in overcoming borrowing constraints and gaining access to an alternative source of finance. An obvious objection to this argument is that holding constant the level of a company’s capital expenditure, the size effect should be eliminated. However, this objection is invalid if at least some of these firms start their actual investments only after raising the capital in the public markets. Second, as suggested by Amihud and Mendelson (1988), going public make the firm’s shares more liquid and therefore more valuable to its owners. Since the liquidity of a company’s shares is increasing in its trading volume, this advantage is more relevant to larger firms. We use two measures of firm size in the analysis: total assets and turnover. 3.0. Age The age of the firm may be related to the propensity of private firms to go public in two different ways. On the one hand if the adverse selection cost in the IPO is more serious to the listing of young companies, we would expect that older firms will be more likely to go public. On the other hand, Pagano et al (1998) argue that practitioners talk about entrepreneurs’ “cultural resistance” to take their companies public and we expect that old and unquoted firms are more likely to be subject to this cultural effect. Since the cultural effect is unobservable and therefore cannot be controlled for in the regression analysis, if this cultural effect is indeed playing a role, we expect that the probability of unquoted firms to go public in the following period decreases with the age of the firm. 4.0. Capital Expenditure Raising capital to finance positive NPV projects is the most cited reason for listing the shares of a firm on a stock exchange, and is a common assumption maintained by many theoretical models in the academic literature. If this is indeed the reason for firms to go public, and if firms start raising capital in other forms and engage in large scale investments before they go public, we would expect to see that the higher the CAPEX (capital expenditure over property -13- plant and equipment) the higher the probability a firm will be quoted the following period. In addition, we expect that after going public the CAPEX will increase or at least not decrease. Note that the measure investment is imperfect. Firms with projects that are human capital intensive will not show these expenditures in the CAPEX cash flow item but rather under R&D item in the Profit and Loss (“P&L”) account and as a sub item of the cash flow from operating activity in the cash flow statement. Unfortunately, the P&L accounts in FAME are not detailed enough and the R&D item is not available. Therefore, while CAPEX is a reasonable proxy for investment intensity in asset intensive industries, for human intensive industries, such as some parts of the high tech industry, CAPEX may underestimate investment intensity. We try to proxy for R&D expenses with the difference between gross and operating expenses, but as will be discussed later this is probably not a good proxy. 5.0. Growth If the growth rate of the firm is a proxy for its future investment opportunities then, just like CAPEX, we expect that firms with high growth rate will tend to go public, and quoted firms with low growth rates will go private. We measure growth rate as the rate of growth in sales. 6.0. Industry Multiples Industry multiples may be positively correlated with the probability of a firm to be quoted for two reasons. The first is related to the theory that motivates the use of growth and CAPEX. If investors are rational we would expect to see high valuations, and therefore high multiples, in industries with large future growth opportunities. If these growth opportunities require large investments, high industry multiples will be associated with a higher probability of going public. As mentioned in the introduction, Ritter (1991) argues that the empirical evidence is consistent with an IPO market in which investors are periodically overoptimistic about earnings potential of young growth companies and firms take advantage of these “windows of opportunity”. Similarly, Lerner (1994) shows that venture capital back companies go public when equity valuations are high and employ private financings when values are lower. If this is the case, private firms may choose to go public when they observe multiples that are unjustifiably high for publicly listed companies in their industry. Similarly, if private equity firms and management teams can take a firm private cheaply, we would expect that firms will go private when the industry multiples are low. In other words, regardless of the current firm status, -14- the higher are the industry multiples, the higher is the probability the firm will be quoted the following period. We measure the industry multiples as the median market to book value of equity of all publicly listed companies on the LSE in the same industry. 7.0. Leverage Leverage plays a role in the going public decision for two different reasons. First, if firms go public because they face positive NPV projects and therefore engage in high levels of investment financed initially by debt, we would expect that leverage will be positively correlated with the probability of unquoted firms to go public. In addition, these firms might use the capital raised in the IPO not only to further finance their projects but also to rebalance their capital structure, hence, leverage is expected to decrease after going public. Second, debt serves as a control mechanism to alleviate the agency costs of free cash flow (Jensen (1986)). If this theory plays a major role in explaining the public/private status of firms then the probability of quoted firms to go private should be negatively related to their leverage. 8.0. Cash and Equivalents Following the motivation of the agency theory in Jensen and Meckling (1976), and more in particular, Jensen (1986), when firms have high levels of free cash flow with low level of investment opportunities, management’s incentives may not align with those of its owners when these two are separate – which is the case for publicly listed firms. In such a scenario payouts to shareholders may be much lower than optimal. Management may be inclined to invest the free cash in projects at below the cost of capital or waste it on organization inefficiencies. If this theory plays a major role in explaining the transition of firms from public to private status we would expect to see that higher level of cash and equivalents is associated with a larger probability of the firm to be unlisted the following period. In addition we should expect to see a decrease in the cash levels after going private. 9.0. Return on Assets If high ROA is due to some proprietary knowledge, higher ROA firms have less incentive to go public. In addition, Pagano et al (1998) suggest that ROA may affect the probability of firms to be quoted in two more ways. On the one hand, Pagano et al argue that a more profitable -15- company would not be highly dependent on external equity, suggesting a negative impact of profitability on the probability of an IPO. On the other hand, a company experiencing a temporary surge in profits may list, hoping that investors will mistakenly perceive its high profitability as permanent and will over value its shares (Ritter (1991)). In this case, we expect profitability to be positively associated with the probability of going public. Additional predictions are related to the ex post effect of a transition on profitability. Firms with surplus may go public to increase firm’s performance by increasing employee moral, tying management compensation to performance (Holmstrom and Tirole (1993)), and use market information to make better informed investment decisions (Maug (2000)). If this is the case, ROA should increase after going public. On the other hand if firms go private because of agency problems (Jensen and Meckling (1976)), then after going private and restructuring the firm, ROA should increase. 5. Results The predictions outlined in the previous section are of two types: predictions on the variables that should affect the likelihood of a transition ex ante and predictions on the likely consequences of a transition, ex post. Therefore, to provide as much insight about the public/private tradeoff, in the first subsection we perform the ex ante analysis, and in the second, the ex post analysis. Before presenting the results it is worthwhile to clarify the time notation (the ‘t’ subscript) which is used throughout this section. For flow variables (e.g. CAPEX, turnover) the subscript t denotes a variable measured over the period from accounting statement at time t-1 to accounting statement at time t. For non-flow variables (e.g. Total assets, cash) t is simply the point at which the variable is measured. The status variable, Quotedt+1, which is the dependent variable in all the ex ante regressions, is equal to 1 if the company is quoted on a stock exchange at the accounting statement date t+1, and 0 otherwise. All the independent variables in the regressions are measured at time t. Finally, the time periods, in general, represent 12 months as the accounts are annual. However, in some cases firms may change their accounting year cycle so the time that elapses between two accounting statements may be more or less than 12 months. In such cases we first annualize all the flow variables. -16- 1.0. The determinants of public to private and private to public transitions We model the ex ante predictions using a Probit setup and report the results in table 3. The regression includes any firm-year observation of a public firm and of a private firm that under the Companies House classification is considered to be medium or large. In addition, to the lagged dependent variable (Quotedt), all of the explanatory variables are once interacted with the Quoted dummy variable and once with the unquoted dummy variable. Our main result is easy to summarize: firms with large current investment (CAPEX), large future investments (proxied by the industry market to book) and large growth rates are those who are more likely to go (or remain) public. This pattern is very strong for private firms (all of these three variables are significant at the 1% level), and while weaker, applies also to quoted firms. For quoted firms, the CAPEX is significant at the 5% level, and the growth is only weakly significant. As mentioned in the previous section, a significant coefficient on the market to book ratio may also be due to the “windows of opportunity” hypothesis. Pagano et al (1998) propose a nice way to discriminate between these two hypotheses (that is, to see if one or both of the theories plays a role in explaining the pattern of the data) by relying on ex post evidence: if newly listed companies invest at an abnormal rate and earn large profits, then the relationship between market to book and the status of the firm is likely to be driven by expectations of future growth opportunities; otherwise, it is likely to reflect the desire to exploit a window of opportunity. As we show in the next subsection, IPO firms continue to invest at an abnormal rate and the profitability of the subset of firms with high deficit weakly increases. This evidence implies that firms go public to raise capital and overcome borrowing constraints but it does not help us to discriminate against the windows of opportunity story which might play a role in conjunction with the financing investment motive. To further identify whether the windows of opportunity theory is present in the data, Pagano et al (1998) suggest an additional test based on ex ante evidence: if raising funds for future investments is the main reason to go public, the likelihood of carve outs should not be correlated with the parent firm’s market to book ratio, since in that case the parent company already has access to the stock market. Unfortunately, reviewing over a 100 randomly selected IPO prospectuses we could not identify any carve outs in our sample. Notice however that in the ex post analysis below the profitability as measured by EBIT (ROA) is not -17- affected (slightly decreases) after going public. For the subset of firms with low deficit it even decreases. While this is consistent with the windows of opportunity story and not with the access to capital market in face of positive NPV project motive, the profitability as measured by ROA may not be affected or even decrease after going public for other reasons to be discussed below. Profitability can serve at best only as an indirect test of the market timing hypothesis. The next most statistically and economically significant result is that the transitions from one status to another are extremely costly. The lagged dependent variable has t-statistics of at least 15. The lagged status of the firm has such a high predictive ability for the future status of the firm that the pseudo R square of the regressions is approximately 90% (without the lagged dependent variable the pseudo R squares fall to the range of 13%). The extremely strong effect of the lagged dependent variable implies that firms’ status in many cases may not be optimal but rather influenced by historical reasons. A private firm may find it optimal to stay private, while an otherwise identical firm from any operational aspect may find it optimal to stay public just because it is already public. Stated differently; in a world without frictions discussed in previous section, maximizing shareholders value would induce a much higher transition rate from one status to the other. Another possible interpretation is that the lagged status is capturing some latent time invariant variable as discussed in the previous section. The results for cash and leverage do not lend support to the agency costs of free cash flow theory in Jensen (1986). Leverage does not seem to be a factor driving the probability of being listed. As for cash, firms with more cash are more likely to be quoted the following period. The source of the positive effect of cash in table 3 on the probability of being quoted is not clear. The return on assets is insignificant throughout. This result does not provide evidence to support the predictions in Pagano et al (1998), nor does it support the idea that ROA is a proxy for proprietary knowledge of private firms that constrains them from going public. The regression results indicate that the factors that determine the probability of being listed when the firm is already listed are similar as when it is not yet listed (private). This result is consistent with the approach taken in Benninga et al (2003). However, there are two exceptions – the effect of age and size. Firm age is highly statistically negative in all regressions -18- for the private firms only. This result provides evidence against the role of the adverse selection hypothesis in explaining why firms go (or do not go) public. As discussed in the previous section, this result is consistent with the notion of a “cultural resistance” of many entrepreneurs to take their companies public. Since this cultural resistance is not relevant to firms that are already public, we do not see a similar effect of age for firms already listed. Similar to the effect of firm age we find that the effect of size depends on the present status of the firm. While larger private firms are more likely to go public, larger public firms are more likely to go private. The fact that log size works in the opposite direction for private and public firms is consistent with Meisner (2002) who argues that “…anything below $25 million is a waste of time to the Warburgs of the world…” (Warburg is a large equity funds that specialize in leveraged buyouts). The high frictions and fixed costs involved in the transition from one status to the other overcome the benefits of a transition for small firms. As noted earlier the fact that we do not observe market valuations of private firms creates a potential bias in the way we select private firms in the ex ante analysis – after all, only those firm that satisfied the LSE listing requirements could have entertained the option to go public. Hence, in addition to the selecting private firms according to their size, as defined by the Companies House, we employ an additional, multiples-based valuation approach as in Berger and Ofek (1995). We construct proxies for the valuation of private firms in the sample and then use them to decide whether any given firm, at any given month, satisfies the market capitalization requirement.16 Specifically, using the Worldscope database, we first compute the market to book equity ratio for every listed firm on the LSE, in every month.17 Next, for every month in the sample we classify firms according to their two digit primary U.S. SIC code. For each monthindustry we compute a market to book multiple as the median multiple across the firms in each industry classification.18 Finally, the estimated value of each firm in every month is the book equity value of the firm multiplied by the market to book multiple of the industry it belongs to 16 For a thorough study valuing IPOs using multiples see Kim and Ritter (1999). Note that while the market values used to compute these multiples are indeed monthly, the book values used are from the annual accounting statements. 18 For a significant number of two digit SIC codes the number of firms used to calculate market to book multiples are small. In order to ensure that these multiples are not affected by temporary shocks to the valuation of some of the quoted companies, we compute the industry multiple in each month as a trailing average of the past six months. 17 -19- (again defined according to its two digit primary US SIC code). The results applying this selection procedure provide results that are qualitatively the same as to those presented in table 3. Table 4 presents the Probit regression results for the decision to go public with the distinction between high and low R&D industries. Using data on R&D for public firms in the U.S. from Compustat (item Data46) we classify different industries (classified according to US SIC codes) to high and low intensity R&D industries. As discussed in the previous section, the idea here is that if the difference between gross and operating profit plus depreciation is a good proxy for R&D expenses, we would expect that in high intensity R&D industries this proxy will be an important determinant for the same reason that the CAPEX is, and in low R&D industries this proxy will have no (or lower) effect. As can be seen from in table 4 in both cases this proxy is significant. As we will see in the next section, the ex post behavior of these two types of industries is also very similar (that is, this proxy increases after going public). It therefore seems that this variable is not a good proxy of R&D expenses, and the fact that it is significant is simply because firms that go public are engaged in higher total SG&A expenses, which also increase after going public. 2.0. The consequences of going private and public transitions In comparison to the ex ante analysis in the previous sub-section, studying the ex-post effect of going private and going public transitions is more challenging. One natural approach, in the spirit of the ex post regressions in Pagano et al (1998), is to perform reduced form regressions where the dependent variable is the variable that theory suggest to be affected by the transition, and the independent variable is a dummy equal to 1 if the firm transitioned and 0 otherwise. The problem with these regressions is that the dependent variable is affected by many factors that cannot be controlled for. Indeed, when we try to perform such regressions in various forms, the R squared of these regressions is negligible. Trying to perform richer reduced form regressions does not help much to increase the explanatory power of these regressions. Moreover, the estimated coefficients (and specifically, the coefficient of interest on the transition dummy) are extremely sensitive to the specific reduced form models. The problem with these richer reduced form models is not only that they still do not capture all the factors that may affect the accounting outcomes of the firm, but that such regressions suffer from a severe endogeneity -20- problem. For example, leverage is determined simultaneously with all the other outcomes of the firm. A variant of this approach, taken in Pagano et al (1998), is to control for other aspects of the firm with a fixed effects regression model. First note that these regressions did not increase the explanatory power of the regressions to any meaningful level. More importantly these regressions suffer from two serious problems. First a fixed effect dummy does not control for time varying attributes of the firm. Second, a fixed effect estimator (or a difference effect estimator for that matter) is consistent only when the independent variables are strictly exogenous. If the decision to go public is affected by past outcomes of the dependent variable this condition is clearly not satisfied. For example, If the level of CAPEX at time t affects the decision to be public at time t+1, a fixed effects regression of CAPEX at time t+1 on a transition dummy in period t will provide inconsistent estimates as the IPO dummy is not exogenous to both future and past outcomes of the CAPEX. Furthermore, adding a lagged dependent variable as an explanatory variable (which apriori seems to be an important control) produces inconsistent estimates for the same reason, because the lagged dependent variable cannot be by definition strictly exogenous. Since we do not attempt to predict or explain the behavior of the various accounting variables of the firm, a task which is beyond the scope of this paper, but rather to see only the behavior of several characteristics of the firm before and after a transition, the approach taken in this subsection is to perform a simple univariate analysis. In table 5 (table 6)we compare the means in the period just before the transition with the means 1, 2 and 3 periods after for several interesting variables of firms that went public (private). The results of the ex-post analysis are consistent with the ex ante analysis from the previous sub-section. First, for IPOs, in panel A (all IPOs) we can see that while firms use part of the raised capital to rebalance their leverage, not only do they continue to have higher level of investment (CAPEX) compared to their non IPO peers, but also they raise their investment level. Second, cash levels increase which is a simple result of the infusion of cash from the going public transaction. Third, absolute profitability (EBIT) is not affected, while ROA, if anything, declines. From panels B and C it can be seen that this is driven mainly by IPO firms that have a cash surplus and do not go public to raise capital but rather to cash in. This means that while there is no fundamental change in the operations of the firm – hence their levels of profits remain -21- unchanged, because of the cash infusion of the going public transaction, the assets base increase which decreases in the medium and short run profitability in ROA terms. Looking more carefully at the behavior of cash constrained (high deficit) and cash surplus firms in panel B and C, we can see that there is little evidence to support the idea that the going public decision is motivated by the reasons suggested in Holmstrom and Tirole (1993) and Maug (2000) – the profitability of firms that have cash surpluses (low deficit) does not increase, and, if anything, it actually decreases. For this subset of firms that probably did not go public to access the capital markets (as they have no shortage of capital) these models suggest that the decision to go public was made to increase moral and productivity of employees and to improve investment decision of management using the information embedded in the stock price of the company. Taken together with the fact that larger firms go public, which supports the notion that going public is more valuable due to liquidity reasons suggested in Amihud and Mendelson (1988), the potential control motivations in Black and Gilson (1998) and Pagano and Roell (1998)19, and diversification value of going public as in Leland and Pyle (1977), the results in these two panels provide strong evidence that many IPOs (specifically -- low deficit firms) are motivated by the desire of the incumbent (whether the entrepreneur or venture capital) to cash out in an optimal (value maximizing) way. Comparing high and low R&D industries in panels D and E the only conclusion that can be drawn is that our proxy for R&D expense is probably not good, as we can see this proxy behaves very similarly (increases) in both subsets. As for going private firms, their investment level does not decrease significantly. This result does not provide evidence that going private deals are motivated by the agency problems of Jensen and Meckling (1977) to prevent the management from investing in projects at below the cost of capital. While the cash level decreases, the leverage does not seem to be affected on average by the going private deals (if anything it decreases). This casts doubt as to how the agency costs of free cash flow of Jensen (1986) are important in explaining the decision of taking firms private. While the profitability, measured by EBIT and ROA decreases, this is a one period decrease which probably is caused by the temporary costs involved in the transition. 19 Unfortunately we do not have annual data at this stage on the insider ownership to test these theories. -22- 6. Summary of results In this paper we employ a novel dataset containing all .... our goal is to test.... The main conclusion of this paper is that contrary to the results of Pagano et al (1998) for the Italian market, the main reason firms choose to be public is to raise capital in the public markets in the face of positive NPV projects. The results are also consistent with the windows of opportunity (or market timing) story of Ritter (1991) but more direct tests of this theory is not available with the data used in this study. Second, the results related to the profitability variables (EBIT and ROA) do not lend support to the motives of going public in the models of Tirole (1993) and Maug (2000). While the related evidence here is indirect, the fact that profitability after going IPO does not increase (if anything it decreases) in the whole sample of IPOs and, in particular, in the subset of IPOs that are cash unconstrained, casts doubt as to whether these theories are important in explaining transitions from one status to the other. Third, the results related to the behavior of profitability after going IPO, and the effect of size on the decision to become listed, suggest that going public is simply the optimal way for the incumbents (whether by the entrepreneur or the venture capitalist) to cash out. This result is also consistent with the liquidity value motive of being public as suggested in Amihud and Mendelson (1988). Unfortunately, more direct tests of the cashing out and control stories were not executed in this paper due to lack of relevant information about insider ownership. Fourth, we do not find that the agency stories in Jensen and Meckling (1976) and Jensen (1986) can explain the transition of public firms back to an unlisted status. Leverage does not increase after going private, and investment intensity does not decrease as well. Fifth, we do not find that adverse selection costs are a major factor in the decision to go public. Sixth, not surprisingly, the current status of the firm is a major factor in the determination of the status of the firm in the following period. This variable is in fact the most statistically significant factor. This result provides evidence in support of the idea that the decision to go public or private is affected very much by the fixed costs that are involved in such a transition. Finally, the data supports the approach taken in Benninga, Helmantel and Sarig (2003). While -23- quantitavely the effect of the variables on the decision to list or delist are different for private and public firms, with the exception of the age and size they are qualitatively roughly the same. The economic tradeoffs of listing a firm on the stock exchange are very similar regardless of the present status of the firm. The qualitative difference in the result for age suggests that the “cultural resistance” applies (not surprisingly) only to private firms. The qualitative difference in the results for size is probably due to the high frictions involved in the transition from one status to the other. -24- References Aganin Alexander and Paolo Volpin, 2003, “The History of Corporate Ownership in Italy”, Working Paper Amihud Yakov and Haim Mendelson, 1988, “Liquidity and Asset Prices: Financial Management Implications”, Financial Management, Vol. 17, Iss. 1, 5-15 Benninga Simon, Mark Helmantel and Oded Sarig, 2003, “The Timing of Initial Public Offerings”, Journal of Financial Economics, Forthcoming Benveniste Lawrence M. and Paul A. Spindt, 1989, “How Investment Bankers Determine the Offer Price and Allocation of New Issues”, Journal of Financial Economics 24, 343-361 Berger Philip G. and Eli Ofek, 1995, “Diversification’s effect on firm value”, Journal of Financial Economics 37, 39-65 Black Bernard S. and Ronald J. Gilson, 1998, “Venture capital and the structure of capital markets: bank versus stock markets”, Journal of Financial Economics 47, 243-277 Brau James C., Bill Francis and Ninon Kohers, 2003, “The Choice of IPO versus Takeover: Empirical Evidence”, Journal of Business, Vol. 76, No. 4 Brennan Michael J. and Julian R. Franks, 1997, “Underpricing, ownership and control in initial public offerings of equity securities in the UK”, Journal of Financial Economics 45, 391-413 Chemmanur Thomas J. and Paolo Fulghieri, 1999, “A Theory of the Going-Public Decision”, The Review of Financial Studies, Vol. 12, No. 2, 249-279 Holmstrom Bengt and Jean Tirole, 1993, “Market Liquidity and Performance Monitoring”, Journal of Political Economy, vol. 101, no. 4, 678-709 Jensen Michael C., 1986, “Agency Costs of Free Cash Flow, Corporate Finance, and Takeovers”, The American Economic Review, Vol. 76, No. 2, 323-329 Jensen Michael C. and William H. Meckling, 1976, “Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure”, Journal of Financial Economics, Volume 3, Issue 4, 305-360 Johnson III Joseph L. and Andrew J. Weidhaas, November 13 2001, “The Going-Private Transaction”, New York Law Journal Khurshed Arif, Stefano Paleari and Silvio Vismara, 2004, “The Operating Performance of Initial Public Offerings: The UK Experience”, Unpublished working paper Kim, Moonchul and Jay R. Ritter, 1999, “Valuing IPOs”, Journal of Financial Economics 53, 409-437 -25- Leland Hayne E. and David H. Pyle, 1977, “Informational Asymmetries, Financial Structure, and Financial Intermediation”, The Journal of Finance, Vol. 32, No. 2, 371-387 Lerner Joshua, 1994, “Venture capitalists and the decision to go public”, Journal of Financial Economics 35, 293-316 Loughran Tim, Jay R. Ritter and Kristian Rydqvist, 1994, “Initial Public Offerings: International insights”, Pacific-Basin Finance Journal 2, 165-199 Lowry Michelle, 2003, “Why Does IPO Volume Fluctuate so much?” Journal of Financial Economics 67, 3-40 Maug Ernst, 2001, “Ownership Structure and the Life-Cycle of the Firm: A Theory of the Decision to Go Public”, European Finance Review 5, 167-200 Meisner Jeff, March 15 2002, “Once on Wall Street, going private is not easy”, Business Journal Mizen Paul and Cihan Yalcin, 2002, “Corporate Finance when Monetary Policy Tightens: How Do Banks and Non-Banks Affect Access to Credit?”, Working Paper, University of Nottingham Opler Tim and Sheridan Titman, 1993, “The Determinants of Leveraged Buyout Activity: Free Cash Flow vs. Financial Distress Costs”, The Journal of Finance, Vol. 48, No. 5 Pagano Marco, Fabio Panetta and Luigi Zingales, 1998, “Why Do Companies Go Public? An Empirical Analysis”, The Journal of Finance, Vol. 53, No. 1, 27-64 Pagano Marco and Ailsa Roell, 1998, “The Choice of Stock Ownership Structure: Agency Costs, Monitoring, and the Decision to Go Public”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics 113, 187-225 Ritter Jay R., 1987, “The Costs of Going Public”, Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 19, Issue 2, 269281 Ritter Jay R., 1991, “The Long-Run Performance of Initial Public Offerings”, The Journal of Finance, Vol. 46, No. 1, 3-27 Ritter Jay R. and Ivo Welch, 2002, “A Review of IPO Activity, Pricing, and Allocations”, The Journal of Finance, Vol. LVII, No. 4, 1795-1827 Roell Ailsa, 1996, “The decision to go public: An overview”, European Economic Review 40, 1071-1081 Stoughton Neal M., Kit Pong Wong and Josef Zechner, 2001, “IPOs and Product Quality”, The Journal of Business, Vol. 74, No.3, 375-408 Weir Charlie and David Laing, 2000, “Going Private Transactions and Corporate Governance in the UK”, The Aberdeen Business School, Unpublished working paper -26- Wooldridge Jeffrey M., 2002, “Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data”, The MIT Press Cambridge Yalcin Cihan, Spiros Bougheas and Paul Mizen, 2002, “Corporate Credit and Monetary Policy: The Impact of Firm-Specific Characteristics on Financial Structure”, Working Paper, University of Nottingham Yosha Oved, 1995, “Information disclosure costs and the choice of financing source”, Journal of Financial Intermediation 4, 3-20 Zingales Luigi, 1994, “The Value of the Voting Right: A Study of the Milan Stock Exchange Experience”, The Review of Financial studies, Vol. 7, No.1, 125-148 Zingales Luigi, 1995, “Insider Ownership and the Decision to Go Public”, Review of Economic Studies 62, 425-448 -27- Table 1 Entire Sample Summary statistics Both panels are after dropping the top and bottom 1 percentile for all variables. Medium and large firms are defined according to the Companies House definition. Growtht=Turnovert/Turnovert-1. ROAt=EBITt/((TotAssetst+TotAssetst-1)/2). Currency variables are in thousands of GBP. Age is in years. On the top of each panel is the number of firms that belonged to panel's group at least one period in the sample Total Assets Turnover Profit CAPEX Age Leverage Growth ROA Cash Total Assets Turnover Profit CAPEX Age Leverage Growth ROA Cash Panel A: Medium and Large Non Quoted (90302) # Obs mean median sd min 447614 10684 3812 28534 1401 284564 25421 10594 48497 2801 365302 566 182 2160 -40600 165307 544 111 2435 -17858 482309 24.066 17.208 21.524 0.003 464264 0.61 0.65 0.29 0.00 245653 1.14 1.07 0.42 0.03 336047 0.08 0.07 0.14 -1.43 381575 743 202 2145 0 Panel B: Quoted (2021 firms) # Obs mean median sd min 11914 317160 36277 1007877 49 11175 334809 44296 953501 16 11701 13047 1126 52848 -123300 8927 18530 1584 64367 -19834 12140 29.502 14.560 31.597 0.003 11923 0.52 0.51 0.30 0.00 9976 1.31 1.10 1.23 0.10 10527 0.00 0.08 0.28 -2.54 11078 18671 2569 50790 0 -28- max 6451000 4443000 423000 321000 146.348 3.69 34.33 1.32 490000 max 13500000 10600000 615000 788727 130.137 4.00 25.47 0.54 611000 Table 2 Deals Summary Statistics Both panels are after dropping the top and bottom 1 percentile for all variables. Panel A (B) are summary of ALL IPO (Going Private) deals Growtht=Turnovert/Turnovert-1. ROAt=EBITt/((TotAssetst+TotAssetst-1)/2). proxy R&D =Grossprofit-operating profit. Currency variables are in thousands of GBP. Age is in years. Panel A: IPO sample (Total 1113, 1111 matched with FAME) # Obs mean median sd min Before IPO Total Assets 891 54202 4371 250111 0 Turnover 783 58697 5887 231536 0 Profit 828 1188 126 9813 -40600 CAPEX 620 4460 325 18462 -1105 Age 567 8.866 4.118 15.162 0.003 Leverage 866 0.78 0.70 0.57 0.00 Growth 536 1.91 1.28 2.77 0.04 ROA 367 0.04 0.11 0.38 -2.36 proxy R&D 672 5973 2075 13646 -396 After IPO Total Assets 827 73839 13202 281005 92 Turnover 776 70417 8538 267745 17 Profit 816 709 197 11988 -115600 CAPEX 649 6179 680 22798 -3610 Age 567 9.853 5.118 15.166 0.512 Leverage 833 0.45 0.41 0.35 0.00 Growth 677 1.94 1.26 2.48 0.10 ROA 798 -0.09 0.07 0.44 -2.41 proxy R&D 667 12237 3109 37564 0 Panel B: Going Private Sample (Total 271, 270 matched with FAME) # Obs mean median sd min Before Going Private Total Assets 239 117144 42052 198472 933 Turnover 233 157398 58283 312212 559 Profit 237 2690 860 13481 -59800 CAPEX 193 8636 2076 19777 -8800 Age 195 35.068 23.926 30.967 0.915 Leverage 238 0.52 0.52 0.21 0.07 Growth 219 1.18 1.05 0.66 0.45 ROA 221 0.05 0.08 0.17 -0.74 Cash 221 8192 2600 18647 2 After Going Private Total Assets 199 110378 32605 259996 674 Turnover 146 143531 37913 385749 77 Profit 190 1584 -73 18823 -28543 CAPEX 89 4747 1265 8889 -4964 Age 195 36.091 24.929 30.984 1.718 Leverage 199 0.53 0.48 0.39 0.00 Growth 138 0.98 0.98 0.89 0.01 ROA 190 -0.02 0.01 0.25 -1.43 Cash 167 7993 1730 19563 0 -29- max 3288039 2553000 164000 226000 105.978 3.59 30.78 1.12 161550 4101000 2971827 136000 296074 106.981 3.79 23.80 0.54 518400 max 1230300 2574200 96800 143300 123.337 1.14 6.04 0.45 189800 2966100 3364200 164100 42879 124.337 2.95 10.23 0.74 169100 Table 3 Determinants of the decision to be listed The effect of the variables listed at time t on the probability to be listed on a stock exchange at t+1. The estimates are from a probit model. The sample is restricted to all listed firms and unlisted firms that their book value of total assets is bigger than 1400 thousands GBP. Growtht=Turnovert/Turnovert-1. ROAt=EBITt/((TotAssetst+TotAssetst-1)/2). Leverage=1-Equity/TotAssets. MTB is the median market to book value of equity of listed firms on the LSE in the same industry. The regression also includes a constant term (not reported). Unquoted=1-Quoted. Currency variables are in mil of GBP. In brackets are z statistics. z statistics are hetroskedasticity and autocorrelation (within each firm) robust. Age, Turnover and Total Assets are in logs. Quoted Unquoted*log(Age) Quoted*log(Age) Unquoted*CAPEX Quoted*CAPEX Unquoted*Growth Quoted*Growth Unquoted*MTB Quoted*MTB Unquoted*ROA Quoted*ROA Unquoted*Leverage Quoted*Leverage Unquoted*Cash Quoted*Cash Unquoted*log(TotAsset) Quoted*log(TotAsset) All Accts. 4.4281 [16.64]*** -0.3062 [9.88]*** 0.0068 [0.23] 0.0145 [2.70]*** 0.0026 [2.25]** 0.161 [4.53]*** 0.1576 [1.59] 0.0938 [4.09]*** 0.2 [4.03]*** 0.2241 [0.70] -0.0773 [0.47] -0.0274 [0.20] -0.0059 [0.04] 0.0174 [3.67]*** 0.0057 [2.06]** 0.1826 [6.90]*** -0.0778 [2.98]*** Cons. Accts. 4.2903 [15.22]*** -0.2683 [8.02]*** -0.0058 [0.19] 0.0146 [2.63]*** 0.0023 [2.12]** 0.1444 [4.04]*** 0.1503 [1.48] 0.0772 [2.70]*** 0.1981 [3.88]*** -0.0069 [0.02] -0.0639 [0.39] 0.1624 [1.12] -0.0284 [0.19] 0.0171 [3.61]*** 0.0054 [1.99]** 0.128 [3.94]*** -0.0638 [2.32]** Unquoted*log(Turnover) Quoted*log(Turnover) Observations Pseudo R2 92969 0.9128 38105 0.8994 *** significant at the 1% level, ** at the 5% level, * at the 10% level -30- All Accts. 4.0852 [15.67]*** -0.3182 [10.05]*** 0.0205 [0.69] 0.0216 [3.34]*** 0.0029 [2.26]** 0.1622 [4.41]*** 0.1466 [1.44] 0.0838 [3.65]*** 0.1987 [3.97]*** 0.1199 [0.40] 0.0624 [0.38] -0.059 [0.43] 0.1881 [1.10] 0.0232 [4.24]*** 0.0063 [2.21]** Cons. Accts. 3.9881 [14.70]*** -0.2682 [7.92]*** 0.0066 [0.22] 0.0194 [3.14]*** 0.0026 [2.13]** 0.143 [3.95]*** 0.1415 [1.37] 0.0689 [2.40]** 0.1958 [3.82]*** 0.002 [0.01] 0.0581 [0.35] 0.1813 [1.24] 0.1375 [0.80] 0.022 [4.24]*** 0.006 [2.14]** 0.0532 [1.88]* -0.1017 [4.23]*** 93165 0.9116 0.0063 [0.21] -0.087 [3.45]*** 38270 0.8987 Table 4 Determinants of the decision to be listed - sub samples The effect of the variables listed at time t on the probability to go public at t+1 for sub samples of the data. The estimates are from a probit model. The sample is restricted to all unlisted firms that their book value of total assets is bigger than 1400 thousands GBP. Only consolidated accounts are used. Growtht=Turnovert/Turnovert-1. ROAt=EBITt/((TotAssetst+TotAssetst-1)/2). Leverage=1-Equity/TotAssets. MTB is the median market to book value of equity of listed firms on the LSE in the same industry. The regression also includes a constant term (not reported). Unquoted=1-Quoted. proxyRDabs=(GrossProfit-OperProfit+Depreciation). proxyRDratio=ProxyRDabs/turnover. Currency variables are in mil of GBP. In brackets are z statistics. z statistics are hetroskedasticity and autocorrelation (within each firm) robust. Age, Turnover and Total Assets are in logs. proxyRDabs Low R&D industries 0.0028 [0.51] High R&D industries 0.0093 [1.74]* proxyRDratio log(Age) CAPEX Growth MTB ROA Leverage Cash log(TotAsset) Observations Pseudo R2 -0.3101 [5.22]*** 0.0227 [1.24] 0.1546 [3.67]*** -0.0002 [0.00] 0.0714 [0.11] 0.1769 [0.82] 0.0414 [4.31]*** 0.0693 [1.17] 12504 0.18 -0.2167 [4.66]*** 0.0207 [2.01]** 0.1076 [3.43]*** 0.1481 [4.49]*** -0.0265 [0.05] 0.1649 [0.60] 0.0131 [1.66]* 0.0932 [1.64] 12274 0.1375 Low R&D industries High R&D industries 0.0312 [3.00]*** -0.2959 [4.94]*** 0.0234 [1.32] 0.1562 [3.63]*** 0.0082 [0.08] 0.3461 [0.51] 0.2286 [1.06] 0.0394 [4.04]*** 0.09 [1.52] 12466 0.192 0.0753 [2.49]** -0.2121 [4.62]*** 0.0168 [1.69]* 0.1069 [3.44]*** 0.1496 [4.55]*** 0.0504 [0.10] 0.223 [0.85] 0.0141 [2.02]** 0.1434 [2.91]*** 12269 0.1366 *** significant at the 1% level, ** at the 5% level, * at the 10% level -31- Table 5 The effect of Going Public t+1 is the period immediately after going public. Currency variables are in thousands of GBP. Mtest is the t-stat of the paired test of the hypothesis that var1 - var2 has a mean of zero. N is the number of observations that var1>var2. Rtest is the z-stat of the hypothesis that var1-var2 has a median of zero using the Wilcoxon matched-pairs signed-ranks test. proxyRDabs=(GrossProfit-Operating Profitdepreciation). proxyRDratio=proxyRDabs/turnover. Italic is significant at 10%; Bold is significant at 5%; Bold and underlined is significant at 1%. Panel A - All IPOs Var1 CAPEXt+1 CAPEXt+2 CAPEXt+3 Var2 CAPEXt CAPEXt CAPEXt mean Var1 6173.24 5195.23 5769.15 mean Var2 3990.30 3665.43 3485.66 Mean test 3.40 3.56 3.46 N(var1>var2) 353 322 252 Rank test 9.24 8.79 8.05 #Obs 506 464 358 Leveraget+1 Leveraget 0.45 0.78 -16.81 153 -18.22 802 Leveraget+2 Leveraget 0.53 0.78 -11.74 181 -13.99 722 Leveraget+3 Leveraget 0.52 0.78 -11.35 166 -12.30 609 Casht+1 Casht 6556.28 2874.09 7.70 557 15.88 700 Casht+2 Casht 5926.77 2690.80 5.81 480 13.66 627 Casht+3 Casht 6880.44 3008.10 5.02 390 11.45 510 ROAt+1 ROAt -0.15 -0.11 -0.26 170 -1.41 340 ROAt+2 ROAt -0.02 -0.20 1.20 132 -2.46 301 ROAt+3 ROAt -0.01 0.05 -1.24 98 -4.75 262 EBITt+1 EBITt 3604.13 3378.89 0.59 378 -0.24 762 EBITt+2 EBITt 2356.59 2878.58 -1.11 342 -0.29 691 EBITt+3 EBITt 2604.66 3267.55 -1.15 272 -0.51 576 Panel B – Low Deficit IPOs Var1 CAPEXt+1 CAPEXt+2 Var2 CAPEXt CAPEXt mean Var1 mean Var2 Mean test N(var1>var2) Rank test #Obs 2607.59 1693.03 3.13 110 5.74 152 3789.48 1738.35 2.04 94 6.70 128 CAPEXt+3 Leveraget+1 Leveraget+2 Leveraget+3 Casht+1 Casht+2 Casht+3 ROAt+1 ROAt+2 ROAt+3 EBITt+1 EBITt+2 EBITt+3 CAPEXt Leveraget Leveraget Leveraget Casht Casht Casht ROAt ROAt ROAt EBITt EBITt EBITt 3694.90 0.50 0.53 0.49 5692.84 4394.35 4474.47 0.00 -0.02 -0.04 2104.31 1103.15 1084.51 1056.97 0.68 0.69 0.68 1994.13 1878.21 1972.07 0.08 0.20 0.27 2311.21 2306.72 2180.34 3.46 -7.54 -5.10 -5.49 3.49 5.31 3.65 -0.68 -3.07 -5.75 -0.32 -1.27 -1.04 78 36 30 30 111 102 80 61 40 24 91 77 53 6.16 -7.34 -5.71 -6.17 7.46 6.83 5.43 -2.11 -4.23 -6.53 1.80 1.19 -1.06 97 159 135 118 143 125 107 132 114 99 160 137 116 -32- Table 5 continued Panel C - High Deficit IPOs Var1 CAPEXt+1 CAPEXt+2 CAPEXt+3 Leveraget+1 Leveraget+2 Leveraget+3 Casht+1 Casht+2 Casht+3 ROAt+1 ROAt+2 ROAt+3 EBITt+1 EBITt+2 EBITt+3 Var2 CAPEXt CAPEXt CAPEXt Leveraget Leveraget Leveraget Casht Casht Casht ROAt ROAt ROAt EBITt EBITt EBITt mean Var1 8223.62 6743.37 8023.51 0.45 0.51 0.51 7987.54 8428.76 8187.45 -0.52 -0.04 -0.01 4920.76 3793.43 4019.40 mean Var2 5190.58 3871.90 4687.77 0.77 0.75 0.73 3685.14 2630.13 3087.02 -0.37 -0.34 -0.23 4421.73 3612.41 4399.03 Mean test 3.06 3.47 3.03 -8.25 -6.79 -5.72 4.25 3.45 3.26 -0.64 2.37 1.90 0.85 0.13 -0.23 N(var1>var2) 102 87 69 26 31 26 114 93 81 66 54 41 89 83 64 Rank test 4.62 4.38 4.42 -8.57 -7.36 -6.09 6.59 5.73 5.11 0.62 0.92 0.21 1.27 2.10 1.53 #Obs 156 134 99 160 141 115 153 134 106 116 99 84 161 142 115 N(var1>var2) 194 196 153 130 112 96 Rank test 9.31 11.13 10.05 1.88 2.03 1.83 #Obs 240 219 176 230 203 163 N(var1>var2) 243 245 198 138 139 124 Rank test 10.13 11.90 11.19 1.52 1.96 1.90 #Obs 299 280 226 276 253 213 Panel D - Low R&D industries Var1 Var2 proxyRDabst+1 proxyRDabst proxyRDabst+2 proxyRDabst proxyRDabst+3 proxyRDabst proxyRDratiot+1 proxyRDratiot proxyRDratiot+2 proxyRDratiot proxyRDratiot+3 proxyRDratiot Var1 Var2 proxyRDabst+1 proxyRDabst proxyRDabst+2 proxyRDabst proxyRDabst+3 proxyRDabst proxyRDratiot+1 proxyRDratiot proxyRDratiot+2 proxyRDratiot proxyRDratiot+3 proxyRDratiot mean Var1 7863.72 11151.17 14232.26 1.37 1.15 0.75 mean Var2 6019.55 5920.32 6098.80 2.07 7.99 0.75 Mean test 3.96 6.14 6.71 -1.38 -1.00 0.00 Panel E - High R&D industries mean Var1 7159.67 11556.46 13618.06 1.38 1.57 1.70 mean Var2 5136.22 5149.96 4920.71 6.15 6.55 0.93 -33- Mean test 5.04 4.04 4.48 -1.29 -1.23 1.07 Table 6 The effect of Going Private t+1 is the period immediately after going public. Currency variables are in thousands of GBP. Mtest is the t-stat of the paired test of the hypothesis that var1 - var2 has a mean of zero. N is the number of observations that var1>var2. Rtest is the z-stat of the hypothesis that var1var2 has a median of zero using the Wilcoxon matched-pairs signed-ranks test. Italic is significant at 10%; Bold is significant at 5%; Bold and underlined is significant at 1%. Var1 CAPEXt+1 CAPEXt+2 CAPEXt+3 Var2 CAPEXt CAPEXt CAPEXt mean Var1 5362.66 4776.23 6366.00 mean Var2 6778.74 6400.55 7105.71 Mean test -1.55 -1.25 -0.20 N(var1>var2) 28 17 15 Rank test -1.76 -1.22 0.77 #Obs 74 40 24 Leveraget+1 Leveraget+2 Leveraget+3 Casht+1 Casht+2 Casht+3 ROAt+1 ROAt+2 ROAt+3 EBITt+1 EBITt+2 EBITt+3 Leveraget Leveraget Leveraget Casht Casht Casht ROAt ROAt ROAt EBITt EBITt EBITt 0.53 0.49 0.50 7329.61 5389.55 4357.89 -0.05 0.07 0.13 4038.10 5947.90 9315.62 0.53 0.53 0.55 9224.02 10369.91 9178.74 0.06 0.05 0.09 7783.09 7157.32 7179.21 -0.20 -1.57 -1.27 -1.71 -2.58 -2.36 -1.97 0.76 0.92 -3.13 -0.71 0.51 89 70 53 70 43 27 54 69 45 64 72 54 -1.71 -2.55 -1.70 -1.61 -3.29 -3.03 -6.08 -0.98 -1.40 -4.94 -0.57 -0.80 195 165 119 156 116 76 177 146 103 188 155 112 -34-
© Copyright 2024