Natural Resources as Capital: Theory and Policy1 Larry Karp May 2015, copyright 1 This manuscript bene…tted from comments by Yang Xie, Huayong Zhi, Zhen Sun, Sangeeta Bansal, and Karolina Ryszka. It also bene…tted from the test-runs provided by the 2013 and 2014 classes in EEP 102. ii Contents 1 Resource economics in the Anthropocene 1 2 Preliminaries 2.1 Arbitrage . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 2.2 Comparative statics . . . . . . . . . . 2.3 Elasticities . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 2.4 Competition and monopoly . . . . . 2.5 Discounting . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 2.6 Welfare . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 2.7 Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 2.8 Terms, study questions, and exercises . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 13 15 18 21 23 29 33 36 37 3 Nonrenewable resources 3.1 The competitive equilibrium . . . . . 3.2 Monopoly . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3.3 Comparative statics . . . . . . . . . . 3.4 Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3.5 Terms, study questions, and exercises . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 43 44 48 53 56 57 4 Additional tools 4.1 A more general cost function . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4.2 The perturbation method . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4.2.1 It is optimal to use all of the resource . . . . . . . 4.2.2 It is optimal to leave some of the resource behind 4.2.3 Solving for the equilibrium . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4.3 Rent . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4.3.1 Examples . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4.4 Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 61 62 65 66 69 70 71 73 75 iii iv CONTENTS 4.5 Terms, study questions, and exercises . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 77 5 The 5.1 5.2 5.3 5.4 5.5 5.6 5.7 5.8 Hotelling model The Euler equation (Hotelling rule) . . Rent and Hotelling . . . . . . . . . . . Lagrange multipliers and shadow prices Resources and asset prices . . . . . . . The order of extraction of deposits . . Monopoly . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Terms, study questions, and exercises . 6 Empirics and Hotelling 6.1 Hotelling and prices . . . . . . . . . . 6.2 Non-constant costs . . . . . . . . . . 6.3 Extending the model . . . . . . . . . 6.4 Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6.5 Terms, study questions and exercises 7 Completing the solution 7.1 The change in price . . . . . . . . . . 7.2 The transversality condition . . . . . 7.3 The algorithm . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7.4 Leaving some resource in the ground 7.5 Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7.6 Terms, study questions, and exercises . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8 Backstop technology 8.1 The backstop model . . . . . . . . . . . . 8.2 Constant extraction costs . . . . . . . . . 8.3 More general cost functions . . . . . . . . 8.3.1 Costs depend on extraction but not 8.3.2 Stock-dependent costs . . . . . . . 8.4 Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8.5 Terms, study questions and exercises . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . stock . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 81 82 85 88 89 91 93 94 95 . . . . . . . . . . 99 101 102 103 110 111 . . . . . . 115 . 117 . 118 . 119 . 121 . 122 . 123 . . . . . . . 125 . 126 . 128 . 131 . 131 . 133 . 135 . 135 . . . . . . . . CONTENTS v 9 The 9.1 9.2 9.3 9.4 “Green Paradox” The approach . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Cumulative extraction . . . . . . . . . . Extraction pro…le . . . . . . . . . . . . . Why does the extraction pro…le matter? 9.4.1 Catastrophic changes . . . . . . . 9.4.2 Rapid changes . . . . . . . . . . . 9.4.3 Convex damages . . . . . . . . . 9.5 Assessment of the Paradox . . . . . . . . 9.5.1 Other investment decisions . . . . 9.5.2 The importance of rent . . . . . . 9.5.3 The importance of elasticities . . 9.5.4 Strategic behavior . . . . . . . . . 9.6 Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9.7 Terms, study questions, and exercises . . 10 Policy in a second best world 10.1 Second best policies and targeting . . 10.2 Monopoly + pollution . . . . . . . . 10.3 Collective action and lobbying . . . . 10.4 Policy complements and substitutes . 10.5 Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10.6 Terms, study questions and exercises, . . . . . . 11 Taxes: an introduction 11.1 Types of taxes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 11.2 Tax incidence and tax equivalence . . . 11.3 An application to environmental policy 11.4 Tax equivalence . . . . . . . . . . . . . 11.5 Approximating tax incidence . . . . . . 11.6 The leaky bucket: deadweight cost . . 11.7 Taxes and cap & trade . . . . . . . . . 11.8 Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 11.9 Terms, study questions and exercises . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 139 . 142 . 143 . 144 . 146 . 147 . 150 . 151 . 152 . 153 . 155 . 156 . 156 . 158 . 158 . . . . . . 161 . 163 . 165 . 167 . 171 . 177 . 179 . . . . . . . . . 183 . 184 . 185 . 187 . 188 . 191 . 192 . 198 . 204 . 206 12 Taxes: nonrenewable resources 211 12.1 Resource taxes in the real world . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 212 12.2 The logic of resource taxes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 215 vi CONTENTS 12.3 An example . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 12.3.1 Calculating the price trajectory . . . . 12.3.2 The price trajectories . . . . . . . . . . 12.3.3 Tax incidence . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 12.3.4 Welfare changes . . . . . . . . . . . . . 12.3.5 Consumer welfare in a dynamic setting 12.4 Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 12.5 Terms, study questions, and exercises . . . . . 13 Property rights and regulation 13.1 Overview of property rights . . . . . 13.2 The Coase Theorem . . . . . . . . . 13.3 Regulation of …sheries . . . . . . . . 13.3.1 Over-capitalization . . . . . . 13.3.2 Property rights and regulation 13.4 Subsidies to …sheries . . . . . . . . . 13.5 Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 13.6 Terms, study questions and exercises . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 219 220 222 223 224 226 227 229 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 233 234 238 239 242 245 249 251 252 14 Renewable resources: tools 14.1 Growth dynamics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14.2 Harvest and steady states . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14.3 Stability . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14.3.1 Discrete time versus continuous time models 14.3.2 Stability in continuous time . . . . . . . . . 14.3.3 Stability in the …shing model . . . . . . . . 14.4 Maximum sustainable yield . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14.5 Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14.6 Terms, study questions, and exercises . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 257 . 258 . 260 . 261 . 262 . 263 . 264 . 266 . 268 . 269 15 The 15.1 15.2 15.3 15.4 15.5 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . open access …shery Stock-independent costs . . . . . . . Stock-dependent costs . . . . . . . . Policy applications . . . . . . . . . . Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Terms, study questions, and exercises . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 271 272 274 278 284 285 CONTENTS vii 16 The sole-owner …shery 16.1 The Euler equation for the sole owner . . . . . . . . 16.1.1 Intuition for the Euler equation . . . . . . . 16.1.2 Rent . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 16.2 Policy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 16.2.1 Optimal policy under a single market failure 16.2.2 Optimal policy under two market failures . . 16.2.3 The rent falls as the stock increases . . . . . 16.2.4 Empirical challenges . . . . . . . . . . . . . 16.3 The steady state . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 16.3.1 Harvest costs independent of stock . . . . . 16.3.2 Harvest costs depend on the stock . . . . . . 16.3.3 Empirical evidence . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 16.4 Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 16.5 Terms, study questions, and exercises . . . . . . . . 17 Dynamic analysis 17.1 The continuous time limit . . . . . . . . . . . 17.2 Harvest rules for stock-independent costs . . . 17.2.1 Tax policy implications of Tables 1 and 17.2.2 Con…rming Table 2 . . . . . . . . . . . 17.3 Harvest rules for stock dependent costs . . . . 17.3.1 Tax policy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 17.3.2 The phase portrait . . . . . . . . . . . 17.4 Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 17.5 Terms, study questions, and exercises . . . . . 18 Sustainability (Under construction) 18.1 Concepts of sustainability . . . . . . . . 18.2 The Hartwick rule . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18.3 Discounting and intergenerational equity 18.4 Economics and climate policy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 2 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 289 . 290 . 292 . 294 . 295 . 296 . 298 . 299 . 299 . 301 . 302 . 305 . 308 . 310 . 311 . . . . . . . . . 315 . 317 . 317 . 319 . 321 . 323 . 324 . 327 . 331 . 332 . . . . 335 . 335 . 335 . 335 . 335 A Math Review 337 B Comparative statics 345 C More complicated perturbations 347 viii CONTENTS D The full solution in the backstop model 351 E Geometry of the Theory of the Second Best 355 F Algebra of taxes F.1 Algebraic veri…cation of tax equivalence . . . . . F.2 The open economy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . F.3 Approximating tax incidence . . . . . . . . . . . F.4 Approximating deadweight loss and tax revenue G Continuous versus discrete time G.1 The continuous time limit . . . . G.2 Stability in discrete time . . . . . G.2.1 Explanation of Table 1 . . G.2.2 Applying the stability test G.3 Exercises . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 361 . 361 . 362 . 364 . 366 . . . . . 369 . 369 . 371 . 372 . 374 . 378 H Bioeconomic equilibrium 381 I 385 The Euler equation for the sole owner …shery J Dynamics of the sole owner …shery 389 J.1 Derivation of equation 17.2 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 389 J.2 The di¤erential equation for harvest . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 390 J.3 Finding the full solution . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 392 Afterword 395 Preface Please send suggestions for how this manuscript can be improved (e.g. changes in emphasis or the addition or deletion of topics), and let me know about mistakes and typos: [email protected]. For the online version of this book, click here. The book is designed for upper division undergraduates. Together with the appendices, it is also suitable for a masters level course. Prerequisites include an intermediate micro-economics course and a grounding in calculus. The presentation uses derivatives, and in a few cases partial and total derivatives. Appendix A reviews the required mathematical tools. The text covers standard resource economics topics, including the Hotelling model for nonrenewable resources, and renewable resource models such as …sheries. The distinction between natural resource and environmental economics has blurred and become less useful over the decades. This book re‡ects that evolution by including some topics that also …t in an environmental economics text. For example, the problem of climate change involves resource stocks, and therefore falls under the rubric of natural resources. Environmental externalities drive the problem, so the topic also …ts in an environmental economics text. It is not productive to pigeonhole such problems into either resource economics or environmental economics. Two important ideas run through this book. First, resources are a type of natural capital; their management is an investment problem, requiring forward-looking behavior, and thus requiring dynamics. Second, our interest in natural resources stems largely from the prevalence of market failures, notably imperfect property rights, in resource markets. The book emphasizes skills and intuition needed to think sensibly about dynamic models, and about regulation in the presence of market failures. ix x PREFACE Standard topics Chapters 3 –5 and 8 cover nonrenewable resources. Chapters 3 and 4 study the two-period model, …rst in the simplest setting and then including stock-dependent costs. Chapter 4 explains the role of resource scarcity and stock-dependent extraction costs in determining resource rent. This chapter shows how to obtain the optimality condition using the “perturbation method”; Chapter 5 adapts that method to the T period setting to obtain the Euler equation, known in this context as the Hotelling condition. All of the dynamic analysis uses the perturbation method, the discrete time calculus of variations. This approach enables students to perform constrained optimization almost without being aware of it, and is simpler and more intuitive than the method of Lagrange. We use the two-period optimality condition to write the T -period optimality condition merely by replacing time subscripts. Chapter 5 also discusses the idea of the shadow value of a resource stock. Chapter 8 presents the backstop model. Backstops are economically important; this material gives students practice in working with the Hotelling model and prepares them for a subsequent policy-focused chapter. Chapters 13 – 17 study renewable resources. We emphasize …sheries because these provide a concrete setting, and they illustrate most of the issues found in other renewable resources. Chapter 13 de…nes and provides historical perspective on di¤erent types of property rights, and then de…nes and illustrates the Coase Theorem. The rest of the chapter uses real world examples and a one-period analytic model to describe the di¢ culties and the unintended consequences arising from …shery regulation. It discusses attempts to establish property rights in …sheries, as an alternative or a complement to regulation. Chapter 14 introduces the concepts needed to study renewable resources, including the growth function, steady states, (local) stability, and maximum sustainable yield. Chapter 15 discusses the open access …shery, showing how taxes a¤ect the equilibrium outcome when harvest costs are stock independent and in the more realistic case where costs depend on the stock size. This chapter also shows why the e¤ect of regulation may be sensitive to the initial stock size at the time regulation is introduced. Chapter 16 discusses the sole owner …shery, deriving the Euler equation and illustrating the e¤ect of policy under one or more market failure. This chapter examines the steady state. Chapter 17 provides more advanced material needed to analyze the sole owner …shery outside the steady states, building up to the phase portrait. PREFACE xi Chapter 18 explains concepts of sustainability and then discusses the Hartwick rule. The chapter de…nes the social discount rate, explains its relation to the discount rate used in all previous chapters, and discusses its role in intertermporal cost bene…t analysis. An overview of economists’ approach to the problem of climate policy ties together these issues. Closing the circle, readers are reminded that the climate is a type of natural capital for which there are weak or non-existent property rights; the market will not e¢ ciently solve the investment problem for this capital stock. These ten chapters (3 –5, 8, 13 –18) cover the nuts and bolts of resource economics, and could stand alone as a mini-course. Less standard topics Chapter 2 reviews topics in micro-economics needed to study resource economics. These topics include the concept of arbitrage, the use of elasticities, the relation between competitive and monopoly equilibria, and the use of discounting. Chapter 6 explains what it means to empirically test the Hotelling model, and summarizes research results. A numerical example in Chapter 7 shows how to use the transversality condition and the Euler equation to obtain the equilibrium extraction and price trajectory for a nonrenewable resource. Although not essential for subsequent chapters, this material gives students practice in assembling different pieces of information needed to solve a model that, a few weeks earlier, would have been entirely mysterious to them; it also gives them practice in using an algorithm. Chapters 9 –12 introduce policy problems. Chapter 9 uses the Hotelling model to examine the “Green Paradox”, an important topic in climate policy. In addition to its intrinsic interest, this material gives students practice in using the Hotelling model, and more generally illustrates the use of models to study policy questions. The material promotes critical thinking by discussing limitations of the green paradox model. Chapter 10 provides the foundation for policy analysis when market failures are important. It explains and illustrates the Theory of the Second Best and the Principle of Targeting, and discusses the importance of political lobbying and the distinction between policy complements and substitutes. In order to present this material simply, examples in the chapter use static environmental problems, instead of stock-dependent natural resource problems. Chapter 13 uses the concepts developed here, again in a one-period setting. Chapter 15 then develops these concepts in a dynamic setting. xii PREFACE Taxes and other market-based instruments are becoming increasingly important regulatory tools. Chapter 11 introduces the principles of taxation in a static framework. The material includes the de…nition of di¤erent types of taxes, the meaning and circumstances of tax equivalence, and the meaning and measurement of tax incidence and deadweight loss. These basic ideas provide a conceptual framework for estimating the fraction of permits in a cap and trade scheme that need to be grandfathered in order to compensate …rms for the cost of regulation. Chapter 11 is essential for understanding taxes in the dynamic natural resource setting, the topic of Chapter 12. That chapter provides an overview of actual taxation (and subsidy) or fossil fuels, and then explains how to synthesize the Hotelling model with the information on taxes studied in the static setting. A numerical example illustrates this synthesis. The opportunity cost of including nonstandard topics is that other important issues, such as forestry, water, and habitat protection, are not covered. The objective of this book is to give students a strong foundation in resource economics, enabling them to acquire and assess information about natural resource topics not covered in the book. Chapter 1 Resource economics in the Anthropocene Mounting evidence shows that we are using resources unsustainably, destroying habitat, increasing the rate of species extinction, damaging supplies of water and other essentials, and creating climate-related risks. The power of human ingenuity, operating through markets, also provides examples where we have delayed or overcome impending resource scarcity. This book o¤ers a framework for analyzing resource use, providing tools that can contribute to improved stewardship. Natural resources are a type of capital: natural, as opposed to man-made capital. Resource use potentially changes the stock of this capital, and is a type of investment decision. Change is thus a key feature of natural resources, requiring a dynamic perspective. Natural resources, like other types of capital, provide services that a¤ect human well-being. In some cases, as with burning oil or eating …sh, we consume those services by consuming a part of the resource. In other cases, we consume natural resource services indirectly. Wetlands provide …ltration services, reducing the cost of clean water. Transforming wetlands into farms or cities changes the ‡ow of these services. Other resource stocks, such as bees and bats, critical to agricultural production, provide indirect but essential services. Diminishing those stocks, by reducing habitat or otherwise changing the ecosystem, alters future pollination services. These examples are anthropocentric, attributing value to natural resources only because they provide services to humans. Species or wilderness areas may have intrinsic value apart from any e¤ect, however indirect, they have 1 2 CHAPTER 1. RESOURCE ECONOMICS IN THE ANTHROPOCENE on human welfare. Regardless of whether one begins with a purely anthropocentric view or a more spiritual/philosophical perspective, resource value depends on the remaining stocks: oil, …sh, wetlands, pollinators, wilderness etc. These stocks a¤ect the current and future ‡ows of services. The anthropocentric view, putting humans at the center of the narrative, can lead to more e¤ective remedies. The protection of forests or …sheries is more likely achieved if the people surrounding these resources have a stake in their protection. Ecotourism in nature preserves can give local residents an incentive to respect the preserve; using the dung of elephants and rhinos to create paper products for sale abroad gives people an incentive to protect the animals when they stray from the preserves. Ignoring the human aspect of resource problems leads to ine¢ cient policy. In common usage, “capital” refers to man-made productive inputs, such as machinery, or the monetary value of those inputs. A broader de…nition treats capital as anything that yields a ‡ow of services. For example, education augments our stock of human capital, because it makes us more productive, or otherwise enhances our lives in the future. Natural resources fall under this broader de…nition of capital. A …rm’s decision about purchasing additional machinery, or an individual’s decision about acquiring more education, are investment decisions, and thus “forward looking”; they depend on beliefs about their future consequences. The decisions are “dynamic”rather than “static”because their temporal aspect is central to the decision-making process. Natural capital, like machinery, obeys laws of physics: trees age, machines rust. The fact that the two types of capital inhabit the same physical universe connects resource economics to the broader …eld of economics. However, natural and man-made capital di¤er in the severity of the market failures that a¤ect them. An “externality”, a type of market failure, arises when a person does not take into account all of the consequences of their action. Unregulated pollution or excessive use of a resource stock are leading examples of externalities. Externalities and other market failures are central to the study of resource economics, whereas they are usually peripheral in a general micro economics course. Changes in resource stocks occur either intentionally, via the exercise of property rights, or accidently, arising from externalities. A mine owner understands that extracting a unit of ore today means that this material is not available to extract and sell in the future; in this case, the change in the stock of ore is intentional. Where property rights to resources do not exist, indi- 3 vidual decisions in modern societies are often made without regard to their e¤ect on resource stocks. Farmers choose levels of pesticide and fertilizer in order to increase their pro…ts. Some of these inputs enter waterways, where they damage the publicly owned ecosystem, as has occurred in the Everglades and in the Gulf of Mexico. Individual farms have negligible e¤ect on the aggregate outcomes, and individual farmers have no (sel…sh) interest in those outcomes, so it is rational for them to ignore these consequences. In these cases, society chooses how the publicly owned resources are used. Often the choice, made by default, is to do little to protect the resource. Rapid changes in resource stocks, and the expected change of future stocks, make resource economics an especially important …eld of study. The 2005 Millennium Ecosystem Assessment reports that the recent speed and extent of human-induced change in ecosystems is greater than the world has previously seen. Some of these changes, such as those associated with the expansion of agricultural production, contribute to current human wellbeing. However, many of the changes degrade resources, eroding natural capital and threatening future well-being. The last half-century saw a …fth of the world’s coral reefs lost, and another …fth degraded; a third of mangrove forests have been lost; water use from rivers and lakes has doubled; nitrogen ‡ows entering ecosystems have doubled, and phosphorus ‡ows have tripled. Human actions have increased the rate of species extinction as much as 1000-fold, relative to rates found in the geological record. Estimates of mammal, bird and amphibian species threatened with extinction range from 10 –30%. Tropical forests and many …sheries are in decline. The Millennium Assessment evaluates 24 di¤erent types of ecosystem services and concludes that 60% of these are degraded or threatened with degradation. The loss in natural capital may lead to abrupt changes, as has occurred with sudden ‡ips in water quality (eutrophication) and the rapid emergence of new diseases. Moreover, these damages tend to disproportionately harm the poor and most vulnerable. Barring major policy changes or technological developments, ecosystems will likely face increasing pressure. Standard measures of wealth, including Gross National Product, ignore these changes in natural capital. Attempts to account for natural capital, show that 45% of the 136 countries studied by the World Bank are depleting their wealth even as income measures increase. These countries are living o¤ natural capital. Climate change may pose the single greatest danger to future well-being. Climate change is likely to exacerbate the types of problems already seen, 4 CHAPTER 1. RESOURCE ECONOMICS IN THE ANTHROPOCENE such as loss of species, the spread of diseases, and increased water shortages. It may also lead to new problems, including rising sea levels, increased frequency of severe weather events, and decreased agricultural productivity. The costs of these changes will depend on uncertain relations between stocks of greenhouse gasses and changes in temperature, ocean acidity, and the sealevel, and on the uncertain relation between these variables and economic and ecological consequences (e.g. decreased agricultural productivity and species loss). The future stocks of greenhouse gasses depend on future emissions, which depend on uncertain changes in policy and technology. In recognition of man’s ability to fundamentally alter the earth’s ecosystem, many scientists refer to the current geological period as the Epoch of the Anthropocene (“New Human Epoch”). Proposals for this Epoch’s starting date range from the early industrial age to the middle of the 20th century. The view that current resource use will create large costs to future generations leads to resource pessimism. Thomas Malthus, an early resource pessimist, claimed that if unchecked by war, disease, or starvation, human population tends to rise faster than food production. He concluded that population eventually outstrips food supplies, until starvation, war, or disease brings them back into balance. This description was quite accurate for most of human history, but events since Malthus wrote in 1800 have contradicted both parts of his argument. Many countries have seen a demographic shift associated with higher income, leading to stabilization or decreases, not increases, in population. In poor societies, children are a form of investment for old age. In rich societies, children do not provide the primary support for their aged parents, and the cost of raising children is high. These factors encourage smaller family sizes with rising income. Technological innovations have increased agricultural productivity and reduced the cost of transporting and storing food. Population and food security have both increased. Most recent famines were caused not by the absolute lack of food, but by its unequal distribution, exacerbated by political dysfunction. Resource pessimism spurred the development of resource economics. In 1931 Harold Hotelling produced one of the cornerstones of the …eld, responding to the pessimists of his time. He wrote Contemplation of the world’s disappearing supplies of ... exhaustible assets has led to demands for regulation of their exploitation. The feeling that these products are now too cheap 5 for the good of future generations, that they are being sel…shly exploited at too rapid a rate, and that in consequence of their excessive cheapness they are being produced and consumed wastefully has given rise to the conservation movement. Hotelling studied the use of natural resources in an idealized market with perfect property rights, where a rational owner takes the …nite resource supply into account. In this setting, prices signal scarcity, in‡uencing decisions about extraction, exploration, and the development of alternate energy sources and new technologies. More generally, prices can induce fundamental changes in human behavior, such as family size. Hotelling’s contribution faded as resource pessimism diminished. The 1960’s saw a resurgence in resource pessimism, exempli…ed by Paul Ehrlich’s The Population Bomb. Ehrlich, a biologist, observing rapid increases in the use of natural resources in the 1960s, and accustomed to working with mechanistic models of insect populations, predicted imminent and catastrophic resource scarcity. Julian Simon, an economist, thought that the market would take care of scarcity, as higher prices encouraged exploration, discovery, production and conservation. Simon proposed, and Ehrlich accepted, a bet that over a decade the in‡ation-adjusted price of a basket of …ve minerals would fall. This period of time seemed long enough to test Ehrlich’s forecast of imminent scarcity. Simon won the bet, but Ehrlich never accepted that he was fundamentally wrong, arguing that he had merely underestimated the rapacity of man’s resource extraction. He believed that his prediction of scarcity was wrong only in the timing. The Ehrlich-Simon bet involved prices of metals for which there are well established property rights. These metal prices have been volatile over the past century, and in one respect Ehrlich was simply unlucky. Had he picked a di¤erent decade in the 20th century, he would have had a better than even chance of winning the bet. The price of this basket of metals fell dramatically during the economic upheaval following World War I, and in most subsequent decades rose gradually. The volatility of metal prices has been largely due to macro economic cycles (recessions or booms) or political events (wars or boycotts) unrelated to scarcity. The theory developed in subsequent chapters explains why, putting aside these reasons for price volatility, modest but not spectacular price increases might be expected. The basis for this theory is that resource owners can “arbitrage over time”, advancing or postponing their sales in order to take advantage of expected price changes. This 6 CHAPTER 1. RESOURCE ECONOMICS IN THE ANTHROPOCENE arbitrage tends to lead to modest expected price increases. Making the wager depend on these metal prices was, in some respects, an odd choice for both the resource optimist (Simon) and pessimist (Ehrlich). It is an odd choice for Simon, the economist, because economic theory predicts modest price increases, not decreases. It is (at least with the bene…t of hindsight) an odd choice for Ehrlich, the ecologist, because it involves the category of resources for which market forces are most likely to “work well”: those having strong property rights. Five years later, Ehrlich proposed a di¤erent bet, one involving changes in, among other measures, CO2 concentrations, temperature, tropical forest area, and rice and wheat stocks per person, rather than commodity prices. Simon rejected Ehrlich’s o¤er, and countered with a wager involving direct measures of human well-being, including life expectancy, leisure time, and purchasing power. Ehrlich declined that o¤er. Some of the components of these di¤ering proposals re‡ect di¤erent views about the relation between mankind and natural resources. The resource pessimist begins with the premise that human welfare is inextricably linked to resource stocks; their degradation (e.g. as measured by increased pollution or lower …sh stocks) must eventually lower human welfare. For example, society may be well o¤ during the period it uses …sh or forest resources intensively, degrading their stocks. If resource use is unsustainable, resource extraction must eventually fall, and with it, human well-being. This overuse is more likely for resources where property rights are weak. The resource optimist, in contrast, starts from the premise that society will be able to …nd new resource stocks (new sources of fossil fuels) or alternatives to those resources (solar power instead of fossil fuels). Both camps present plausible scenarios that support their position. The resource pessimism of the 1960’s led to renewed interest in resource economics during the 1970s and 1980s. The dominant strand of this literature extends Hotelling’s earlier work, using the paradigm of rational agents operating with secure property rights. However, there has also been increased recognition of market failures, especially externalities associated with missing markets and weak property rights. Modern resource economics provides a powerful lens through which to study natural resources precisely because it takes market failures seriously. The discipline provides a counterweight to pessimists’tendency to understate society’s ability to respond to market signals, while also providing a remedy to the excessively optimistic belief that markets, by themselves, will solve resource problems. 7 Agriculture and …sheries illustrate the power of markets and the problems arising from market imperfections. In both cases, markets have unleashed productivity gains leading to abundance. But these gains occur in the presence of market failures, giving rise to problems that threaten (in the case of agriculture) or actually (in the case of …sheries) o¤set the initial gains. Neither markets nor natural forces will automatically solve these problems without regulation. Box 1.1 The impossibility of extinction (?). In the mid 1800s, driftnet herring …shermen ask for regulation to restrict the use of “longlines”, which they claimed damaged …sh stocks and reduced catches. Many scientists, believing that the self-correcting power of nature would take care of any temporary problems, resisted those requests. The in‡uential scienti…c philosopher Thomas Henry Huxley, a member of British …shing commissions charged with investigating the complaints, explained in 1883 why the requests were unscienti…c, and merely designed to impede technological progress: “Any tendency to over-…shing will meet with its natural check in the diminution of the supply,... this check will always come into operation long before anything like permanent exhaustion has occurred.” Others disagreed. Maine’s …shery commissioner Edwin Gould stated in 1892 “Its the same old story. The bu¤alo is gone; the whale is disappearing; the seal …shery is threatened with destruction. Fish need protection.” Market-mediated increases in agricultural productivity since the 1960s made it possible to feed twice the population with slightly more than a 10% increase in farmed land, reducing or eliminating the threat of starvation for hundreds of millions of people. Those changes were associated with increased pesticide and fertilizer use that threaten waterways, increased and likely unsustainable use of water, and increased loss of habitat. Human ingenuity, operating through markets, helped to alleviate the problem of insu¢ cient food. But they achieved this progress in a world with imperfect and missing markets, giving rise to signi…cant externalities. Increased demand for …sh has resulted in increased harvest and reduced …sh stocks, leading to relative scarcity and higher prices. Responding to these market signals, …shers developed and adopted new technologies, hugely increasing their ability to catch …sh. These gains have often been short-lived, as the increased harvest 8 CHAPTER 1. RESOURCE ECONOMICS IN THE ANTHROPOCENE degrades …sh stocks, ultimately lowering harvest. Markets have been essential in “disproving”the resource-pessimists thus far. Markets are powerful in part because they are self-organizing. They require a legal and institutional framework that creates respect for private property and con…dence in contracts; they often require regulation, but not detailed governmental management. However, the bene…cial changes assisted by markets, occurring in the context of market imperfections, may in the longer run validate the resource-pessimists. Where market imperfections are severe, markets are unlikely to solve, and may exacerbate resource and environmental problems. There are genuine technological and demographic obstacles to solving resource problems. However, the main obstacles are probably political. Remedies to improve resource problems usually create winners and losers, with the losers often in a better position to defend their interests. For example, e¤ective climate policy will decrease fossil fuel owners’wealth; these groups have substantial political in‡uence in many countries. Clearer thinking will not dispel these objective obstacles to reform. However, clearer thinking and more precise language can provide a basis for negotiations between people with di¤erent values and perspectives. People might disagree on a conservation measure, but it is counter-productive to base the disagreement on one’s identi…cation as an economist or an environmentalist. Economists understand the importance of market failures; environmentalists understand tradeo¤s and markets’ potential in helping to correct a problem e¢ ciently. Too often debate becomes a re‡exive exchange of slogans. Resource economics can help to solve problems by providing a common language and an analytic framework, creating the possibility of moving beyond ideology. Resource economics also helps in understanding that institutional reform, such as the creation of property rights, is often an e¤ective remedy to problems. Some people distrust property rights because they (correctly) see these as the basis for markets, and they (incorrectly) think that markets are responsible for the resource problem. Resource economics teaches that many problems are due not to markets, but to market failures. Disagreements about resource-based problems tend to be easier to resolve where the problems are local or national rather than global, and where changes occur quickly (but not irreversibly), rather than unfolding slowly. The local or national context makes the horse-trading needed to compensate losers easier. The rapid speed of change makes the problem more obvious, 9 and makes the potential bene…ts of remedying the problem, and the costs of failing to do so, more pressing for the people who need to engage in this horse-trading. The most serious contemporary resource-based problems are global and unfold over long periods of time, relative to individuals’lifetime, and certainly relative to the political cycle. A prominent international treaty, the Montreal Protocol, succeeded in halting and reversing the global problem of ozone depletion. The rapid increase in the ozone hole over the southern hemisphere made the problem hard to ignore, and the availability of low-cost alternatives to ozone-depleting substances made it fairly cheap to …x. International negotiations on other global problems, prominently climate change, have been notably unsuccessful. It is di¢ cult to summon the political will to make the international transfers needed to compensate nations that would be, or think they would be, better o¤ without an agreement. The most serious e¤ects of climate change likely impact future generations, who have no direct representation in current negotiations. An overview of the book Two points made above set the stage for the rest of this book. (i) Markets have the potential to ease environmental and resource constraints, contributing hugely to the increase in human welfare. (ii) Many problems arise from market failures, such as externalities associated with pollution; those market failures may diminish or even reverse the bene…cial e¤ects arising from markets that function well. A corollary to these claims is that regulation that harnesses the power of market forces, or the establishment of property rights, may make it easier to solve resource problems. Nevertheless, those regulations and institutional changes require political intervention; they do not arise spontaneously from market forces. This book develops and uses a theoretical apparatus that can contribute to coherent analysis of these issues. Theory makes it possible to intelligently evaluate the facts of speci…c cases, in pursuit of better policy prescriptions. The pedagogic challenge arises from the fact that resources are a type of capital, requiring a dynamic setting in which agents are forward looking. In a static setting, …rms’and regulators’decisions depend on current prices and (for example) pollution. In the dynamic resource setting, a …rm’s decision on how much of the resource to extract and sell in a period depend on the price in that period, and the …rm’s beliefs about future prices. A regulator’s 10CHAPTER 1. RESOURCE ECONOMICS IN THE ANTHROPOCENE (optimal) policy depends on beliefs about future actions, and these depend on future prices. This di¤erence between the static and dynamic setting is central in our presentation of resource economics. The …rst half of the book provides the foundation for studying nonrenewable resources, such as coal or oil. This foundation requires a review of some aspects of microeconomic theory, and the development of methods needed to study dynamic markets. We apply these methods to the resource problem, emphasizing perfectly competitive markets with no externalities or other distortions. This material identi…es incentives that are important in determining resource use, and helps the reader understand the potential for markets, when they work well. The second half of the book applies these tools, emphasizing situations where market failures create a rationale for policy intervention. We consider both the possibility that policies ameliorate the market failure, and the possibility that policy is harmful due to unintended consequences. We also move from nonrenewable to renewable resources, making it possible to show how di¤erent systems of property rights and policies alter resource levels at di¤erent time scales. Terms and concepts Epoch of the Anthropocene, renewable versus nonrenewable resource, eutrophication, market failure, externality, resource pessimist/optimist Sources The United Nations’ (2005) Millennium Ecosytem Assessment reports an international group of scholars’assessment of recent environmental changes, their consequences on human well-being, and likely scenarios for future changes. Alix-Garcia et al (2009) discuss the payment of environmental services in agriculture. Elizabeth Kolbert The Sixth Extinction: an Unnatural History documents species extinction. Duncan Foley (2006) Adam’s Fallacy discusses Thomas Malthus and other important economists. Scott Barrett Environment and Statescraft (2003) discusses the di¢ culty of creating e¤ective global environmental agreements. Gregory Clark A Farewell to Alms provides a long run historical perspective on Mathus’ideas. 11 Paul Sabin, “The Bet” examines the tension between resource optimists and pessimists, in particular between Ehrlich and Simon. The World Bank’s (2014) Little Green Data Book provides statistics on green national accounting. Robert Solow (1974) provides the quote from Hotelling (1931). Partha Dasgupta (2001) Human Well-Being and the Natural Environment and develops the concept of natural resources as a type of capital. Edward Barbier Capitalizing on Nature: Ecosystems as Natural Assets extends this concept to ecosytems, or ecological capital, e.g. wetlands, forests, and watersheds. The quote from Huxley in Box 1.1 is from Kurlansky (1998), and the quote from Gould in from Bolster (2015). 12CHAPTER 1. RESOURCE ECONOMICS IN THE ANTHROPOCENE Chapter 2 Preliminaries Objectives To prepare students to study resource economics. Information and skills Understand the meaning of arbitrage. Understand the distinction between exogenous and endogenous variables; analyze the e¤ect of an exogenous change on an endogenous outcome (comparative statics). Know the de…nition and purpose of elasticities, and be able to calculate them. Understand the relation between a competitive and a monopoly outcome. Know the de…nition and purpose of a discount rate and a discount factor; use them to calculate present values and to compare pro…t or cost streams. Know the basics of welfare economics, in particular the fact that in the absence of market failures, a competitive equilibrium is e¢ cient. This chapter reviews and supplements the micro-economic foundation needed for natural resource economics. In the familiar static setting, a 13 14 CHAPTER 2. PRELIMINARIES competitive equilibrium occurs when many price-taking …rms choose output to maximize their pro…ts. A competitive equilibrium in the resource setting involves a time-path of output, not merely output at a single point in time. Resource-owning …rms begin with an initial stock of the natural resource, and decide how much to supply in (typically) many periods, not just in a single period. For a non-renewable resource such as coal or oil, the cumulative extraction over the …rm’s planning horizon cannot exceed the …rm’s initial stock level. For renewable resources such as …sh, where a natural growth rate can o¤set harvest, the …rm faces a more complex constraint. For both types of resources, the …rm solves a constrained optimization problem. We use the solution to that problem to analyze the competitive equilibrium. In each period, the …rm obtains revenue and incurs costs. A dollar today is not the same as a dollar ten years from now; they are apples and oranges. A sensible description of the …rm’s optimization problem requires that revenue and costs in di¤erent periods are commensurable. Discounting achieves this objective. The necessary conditions for optimality to the …rm’s problem involve techniques developed in subsequent chapters. We interpret these optimality conditions as “intertemporal arbitrage conditions”. Before introducing the idea of intertemporal arbitrage, it helps to discuss the meaning and the implication of plain vanilla “spatial”arbitrage. “Arbitrage”is the practice of taking advantage of di¤erences, often price di¤erences, in di¤erent markets. Moving a commodity from one place to another is the most familiar form or arbitrage. This spatial arbitrage, and “intertemporal arbitrage”, selling a commodity in one period instead of another, can be studied using similar methods. Intertemporal arbitrage is the basis for understanding equilibria in resource markets, and spatial arbitrage provides the foundation for understanding intertemporal arbitrage. Models serve a variety of purposes, one of which is to understand how changes in a piece of data, or an assumption, a¤ect an equilibrium outcome. The piece of data or assumption can often be characterized by assigning a value to a parameter in the model. These “exogenous”parameters are determined “outside the model”. The model helps us discover or understand an “endogenous outcome”, determined “inside the model” For example, the cost of shipping goods from one location to another a¤ects the quantity shipped. We may want to know how changes in shipping costs alter the equilibrium amount shipped. In this example, the shipping cost is an exogenous parameter, and the amount shipped is an endogenous outcome. The question “How 2.1. ARBITRAGE 15 does a change in the shipping costs alter the equilibrium amount shipped?” is a comparative statics question. This chapter provides the foundation for answering these kinds of questions. Economics involves the relation between di¤erent things, such as price and quantity. “Elasticities”provide a “unit free”measure of these types of relations; “unit free”means, for example, that the relation does not depend on whether we measure prices in dollars per pound or Euros per kilo. We emphasize competitive equilibria. However, many important resource markets, including markets for petroleum, diamonds, and aluminium (produced using bauxite, a natural resource) are not, or have not always been, competitive. We therefore supplement the study of competitive markets by considering the case of monopoly. Few, if any resource markets are literally monopolistic, unless one adopts an extremely narrow de…nition of the commodity (e.g. diamonds from a particular region, instead of diamonds in general). The monopoly model is useful as a limiting case, against which to compare perfect competition. Many actual resource markets lie somewhere on the continuum between these two. We use the elasticity of demand to relate the equilibrium conditions under perfect competition and monopoly. Two welfare theorems explain the relation between a competitive equilibrium and the outcome of a social planner who maximizes social welfare. This relation is essential for understanding the circumstances under which a competitive equilibrium is e¢ cient. It also provides the basis for a discussion of market failures. 2.1 Arbitrage Objectives and skills Understand arbitrage and graphically represent and analyze the “noarbitrage”condition. Much of the intuition for later results rests on the idea of “arbitrage over time”. This idea is closely related to the more familiar idea of arbitrage over space, reviewed here. Suppose that there is a …xed stock of tea in China, 10 units. The inverse demand for tea in China is pChina = 20 q China , where q China is the quantity consumed in China. A demand function gives quantity as a function of price, and the inverse demand function gives price 16 CHAPTER 2. PRELIMINARIES price 20 China demand 15 US demand 10 5 0 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 tea Figure 2.1: Solid line shows demand for tea in China. Dashed line shows demand for tea in US. Dotted line shows price received by Chinese exporter with 20% ttransportation costs. as a function of quantity. The inverse demand for tea in the U.S. is pU.S. = 18 q U.S. . Figure 2.1 shows the inverse demand in China (solid line) and in the U.S. (dashed line). Moving left to right on the horizontal axis represents an increase in consumption in China, and a corresponding decrease in the U.S., because total supply is …xed at 10 by assumption. The U.S. demand function is therefore read “right to left”; for example, the point 3 on the tea axis means that China consumes 3 units and the U.S. consumes 7 units. Except where noted otherwise, we assume that the equilibrium is “interior”, meaning (here) that some tea is sold in both countries; at a “boundary” equilibrium, all of the tea is sold in a single country. If there is no cost of transportation, and if sales are positive in both countries, then price in a competitive equilibrium must be equal in the two countries. This equality represents a “no-arbitrage”condition. “Arbitrage” refers to the practice of taking advantage of price di¤erences (possibly in di¤erent locations), to make bene…cial trades. There are no arbitrage opportunities when no further pro…table trades are possible. If the price in China was lower than the U.S. price, an agent with zero transportation costs could make money by buying a unit of the good in China and selling it in the U.S.. If the price in the U.S. was lower, an agent would ship tea from the U.S. to China. There are no remaining opportunities for arbitrage if and only if the price is the same in the two locations. In the competitive equilibrium, using the demand functions above, China consumes 6 units, the U.S. consumes 4 units, and the equilibrium price, 14, is the same in both countries. 2.1. ARBITRAGE 17 It is easy to become confused about causation in a competitive equilibrium. The competitive exporter in our tea example does not move tea from one location to another in order to cause the prices in the two locations to be the same. This competitive exporter takes prices as given. Prices in the two locations are the same because of the exporter’s ability to move goods from one location to another. If the price in China was lower than the U.S. price, the exporter would purchase tea in China to export to the U.S.. Her purchases increase the demand in China, causing price to rise there. Selling the tea in the U.S. increases the supply there, causing the U.S. price to fall. A single exporter may move too few goods to a¤ect prices, but if all exporters have the same incentives, their collective actions a¤ect prices. The outcome is the same regardless of whether there are many small exporters, each of which is an insigni…cant part of the market, or whether there is a single exporter who takes price as given. Transportation costs are important in the real world. These costs can be expressed on a per unit basis (some number of dollars per unit) or on an ad valorem basis (some percent of the value). In the latter case, costs are sometimes called “iceberg costs”; it is as if a certain fraction of the value melts in moving the good from one place to another. The transport costs include the physical cost of transportation, and ancillary costs such as the cost of setting up distribution networks, acquiring information about prices in di¤erent locations, and insurance. We represent these iceberg costs using b (for “berg”). Expressed as a percent (rather than a fraction), the transportation costs are b 100%. If b = 0:3, then an exporter faces transportation costs of 30% of the purchase cost. If the price of a unit is pChina in China, the cost of selling the unit in the U.S. is (1 + b) pChina : an exporter buys the good for pChina and spends bpChina in order to transport the good, for a total cost of (1 + b) pChina . In a competitive equilibrium with positive sales in both countries, (1 + b) pChina = pU.S. , or pChina = 1 pU.S. : (1 + b) (2.1) Equation 2.1 is the no-arbitrage condition in the presence of iceberg transportation costs, b 0. If b > 0, then equation 2.1 implies that the U.S. price exceeds the China price in a competitive equilibrium. The dotted line in Figure 2.1 shows the U.S. demand, adjusted for 30% transport costs (b = 0:3). A point on this dotted line gives the amount that an exporter receives, at a given level of U.S. consumption, after the exporter 18 CHAPTER 2. PRELIMINARIES pays transportation costs. The equilibrium sales occurs at the intersection of the solid line and this dotted line. At this quantity, the price in China equals the price, net of transportation costs, that an exporter receives for U.S. sales. For our example, this equilibrium occurs where China consumes 7.83 units, at price 12.17; the U.S. consumes the remaining 2.17 units. The U.S. transportation-inclusive price, a point on the U.S. demand function (the dashed line), is 1:3 12:17 = 15:83. Net of transportation costs, the exporter receives 12:17, a point on the dotted line. In the examples above, “the law of one price” holds: the price, adjusted for transport costs , is the same in both locations. This “law” describes a tendency. Arbitrage requires that people have information about prices in di¤erent locations. If information about price di¤erences is imperfect, then arbitrage would still create a tendency for prices to move together, but we would not expect them to be exactly equal. The potential to pro…t from price di¤erences gives people an incentive to acquire information. It is not necessary that the individual selling tea in China know the price in the U.S.. There may be a chain of people in a range of markets between the China and the U.S.. Each of these knows the price in neighboring markets, so they know whether it is pro…table to move tea east or west. Markets “aggregate” information; the middlemen move the commodity from where the price is low to where it is high. The actions of these middlemen reveal information about price di¤erences, making it unnecessary for the seller in China to incur the cost to learn about the price in the U.S., thus lowering a component of transportation costs. The middlemen also require payment for their e¤ort, thus increasing transport costs. Modern technology leads to the cheaper ‡ow of information, reducing transportation costs, making it more likely that the forces of arbitrage cause prices to move together. Apps make it possible to instantly compare prices in di¤erent stores. Farmers in developing countries use cell phones to learn about price di¤erences in di¤erent markets. 2.2 Comparative statics Objectives and skills Understand the distinction between endogenous and exogenous variables; understand the meaning of a comparative statics question. 2.2. COMPARATIVE STATICS 19 Be able to use an equilibrium condition to conduct comparative statics analysis. This section uses an example to illustrate the meaning of a comparative statics experiment (or question), and to show how that question can be answered. Using the tea example from Section 2.1, consider the comparative statics question “How do transportation costs a¤ect the equilibrium prices and quantities in the two markets?” This question is simple enough to answer without the use of a model: higher transportation costs decrease exports from China to the U.S., increasing supply and decreasing the equilibrium price in China, and having the opposite e¤ect in the U.S. Figure 2.1 illustrates the graphical approach to answering this question. Mathematics helps for questions that are too complicated to answer using informal reasoning or graphs. The …rst step in addressing a comparative statics question is to be clear about which variable(s) is (are) exogenous (= given, or determined outside the model), and which are endogenous (= determined by the model). In this example, the transportation parameter, b, is exogenous, and the prices and quantities in the two markets are endogenous. The second step is to identify the equilibrium condition that determines the endogenous variables. In this case, the no-arbitrage condition 2.1 is the equilibrium condition. Substituting the demand functions for the two countries, pchina = 20 q China and pU.S. = 18 q U.S. and using the constraint that q U.S. = 10 q China , we can write this equilibrium condition as 1 18 10 q China 20 q China = | {z } 1 + b | {z } : China China L q = R q ;b : (2.2) Once we know q China it is straightforward to …nd q U.S. and the two prices, so we consider only the comparative statics of q China with respect to b. Using the explicit solution Equation 2.2 gives q China as an implicit function of b. Because of its linearity, this equation can be easily solved to yield the explicit equation. 20b + 12 q China = : b+2 20 CHAPTER 2. PRELIMINARIES Using the quotient rule, we obtain the derivative: 28 dq China = >0 db (b + 2)2 (2.3) As already noted, an increase in transport costs increases equilibrium sales in China. Using the implicit relation In cases where the equilibrium condition is too complicated to solve explicitly, we can still obtain information merely by using the equilibrium condition, which gives the endogenous variable as an implicit function of the exogenous parameters. The second line of equation 2.2 shows that the left side is denoted as L q China and the right side as R q China ; b . An exogenous change in b alters the right side without having a direct e¤ect on the left side. In order for the equality L q China = R q China ; b to continue to hold after the change in b, there must be a compensating change in q China . The change in R, denoted dR, must equal the change in L, denoted dL. These changes are called the “di¤erentials” of R and L. Equilibrium requires dL q China = dR q China ; b : (2.4) Using the de…nition of a di¤erential and the rules of partial derivatives (Appendix A), equation 2.4 yields the comparative statics expression (Appendix B) q China + 8 dq China = 2 > 0: (2.5) db b + 3b + 2 Comparing the two methods Equations 2.3 and 2.5 both show how q China responds to a change in transport costs, b. The right side of equation 2.5 involves the unknown value q China , whereas the right side of equation 2.3 involves only numbers and the exogenous parameter b. In this respect, the comparative statics expression 2.3 is more informative than equation 2.5. The approach using di¤erentials is useful when it is di¢ cult to solve the equilibrium condition to obtain the explicit expression for the endogenous variable. Equation 2.5 tells us only that an increase in b increases sales in China. Often we use models to obtain “qualitative”rather than “quantitative”information, e.g. we care more about the direction than the magnitude of the change. 2.3. ELASTICITIES 2.3 21 Elasticities Objectives and skills Calculate elasticities and understand that they are “unit free”. Economists frequently use elasticities instead of slopes (derivatives) to express the relation between two variables, e.g. between price and quantity demanded. The slope of the demand function tells us the number of units of change in quantity demanded for a one unit change in price. The elasticity of demand with respect to price tells us the percent change in quantity demanded for a one percent change in price. Unless the meaning is clear from the context, we have to specify the elasticity of something (here, quantity demanded) with respect to something else (here, price). In general, the value of an elasticity depends on the price at which it is evaluated. denotes the rate The symbol dQ denotes the change in Q. The ratio dQ Q 100 is the of change; multiplying by 100 converts a rate to a percent, so dQ Q percent change in Q. The percent change in Q for each one percent change in P is the ratio dQ dQ 100 dQ P Q Q : = dp = dP dP Q 100 P p The …rst equality follows from cancelling the 100’s, and the second follows from rearranging the ratio of the ratios1 . The demand function Q = D (P ) gives the relation between quantity demanded and price, Q and P . The elasticity of Q with respect to P , denoted , is de…ned as = dQ P = dP Q D0 (P ) P : D (P ) We follow the convention of including the negative sign in the de…nition, making the elasticity a positive value. If we want to evaluate this elasticity at a particular price, say Po , we express it as (Po ) = a D0 (Po ) Po : D (Po ) This rearrangement uses the rule cb = ab dc = ac db . For our problem, a corresponds to d dQ and c corresponds to dP . We can manipulate these variables in the same way that we manipulate a; b; c; d. 1 22 CHAPTER 2. PRELIMINARIES Suppose that we measure quantity in pounds and prices in dollars per pound, and the demand function is Q=3 5P: The inverse demand function corresponding to this demand function is 3 Q : P = 5 The slope of the inverse demand function is 15 . The elasticity of demand with respect to price, evaluated at P = 0:5 is 0:5 dQ P =5 = 5: dp Q 3 5(0:5) Box 2.1 Elasticities are unit free. For the example above, suppose that we want to express the price in pesos rather than dollars, and 1 suppose that there are 10 pesos per dollar; one peso is 10 dollars. Using upper case P to denote the number of dollars, and lower case p . The demand p to denote the number of pesos, p = 10P , so P = 10 function is 1 Q = 3 5P = 3 5 p: 10 The …rst equality gives demand as a function of dollars, and the second gives demand as a function of pesos. The inverse demand, expressed in pesos instead of dollars, is p= 3 Q 1 2 =6 2Q: The change in units from dollars per pound to pesos per pound changes the slope of the inverse demand function from 15 to 2 and changes the vertical (price) intercept from 35 to 6. The elasticity of demand with respect to price, evaluated at a price of 0.5 dollars, or 5 pesos, is 5 dQ p 1 = =5 dp Q 2 3 12 5 Changing the units –in this case from dollars per pound to pesos per pound – changes the appearance of the demand function, but does not change the elasticity. 2.4. COMPETITION AND MONOPOLY 23 Economists frequently use elasticities instead of slopes, or derivatives, because the elasticity, unlike the slope, is “unit free”.2 For example, the elasticity does not change if we change units from pounds to kilos, or measure prices in pesos rather than dollars (Box 2.1). In contrast, the derivative does change if we change these units. 2.4 Competition and monopoly Objectives and skills Be able to write the objectives and the equilibrium conditions for a competitive industry and a monopoly. Understand the similarities and the di¤erences between these two market structures and the corresponding equilibrium conditions. Understand the meaning of “marginal revenue”, and be able to write it using the elasticity of demand. We consider both perfect competition and monopoly. The competitive …rm takes the market price as given, and the monopoly understands that the price responds to sales. In order for the equilibrium prices in the two settings to be comparable, we assume that the inverse demand function, p (Q), and the industry cost function, c (Q), are the same in the two types of markets; Q is aggregate sales. The industry and …rm cost functions What does it mean to say that an industry, consisting of many …rms, has a particular cost function? The simplest way to think of this is to imagine that the industry consists of a large number, n, of factories. Under monopoly, a single …rm owns all factories; under the competitive structure, each …rm own a single factory. Suppose that the cost of producing q in a single factory is c~ (q). All …rms in the competitive industry are identical, making it is reasonable to assume that 2 Units are important. Columbus underestimated the diameter of the world partly as a consequence of confusion over units. The common belief that Napoleon was quite short (the “little man complex”) resulted from confusing English with French units; in fact, he was slightly taller than the average man of his era. The 1999 Mars Climate Orbiter was lost due to miscommunication about units between Lockheed Martin and NASA. 24 CHAPTER 2. PRELIMINARIES they all produce the same quantity, n1 ’th of industry quantity, so nq = Q. If each factory produces q = Qn , then the cost in each …rm is c~ (q) = c~ Qn . The total industry cost is then n~ c Qn . We can de…ne the industry cost as c (Q) = n~ c Q n : Taking the derivative of both sides of this equation, with respect to Q, using the chain rule, gives c0 (Q) d~ c dQ d~ c1 d~ c dc =n Q n =n = dQ dq n dq d n dn c~0 (q) (2.6) Equation 2.6 states that the marginal cost of the industry (the expression on the left) equals the marginal cost of the …rm (or factory), the last expression. This relation holds for any number of …rms, n, provided that q = Qn . This formulation enables us to compare the competitive and the monopoly market structures. In making this comparison, it is essential that we recognize that the cost of producing an arbitrary amount does not change with the market structure. A change in the market structure alters the equilibrium amount produced, but not the technology and therefore not the relation between costs and output. We …nd the competitive and the monopoly equilibria by solving maximization problems. Both types of …rms want to maximize pro…ts, and they both have the same cost structure and face the same demand function. They di¤er because competitive …rms take price as exogenous, whereas the monopoly understands that price is endogenous. The competitive equilibrium A representative …rm chooses its output to maximize pro…ts, taking price as given. This …rm’s optimization problem is: max pq c~ (q) : q The …rst order condition sets the derivative of the objective (pro…ts), with respect to the choice variable, q, equal to 0: d (pq c~ (q)) dq =p set c~0 (q) = 0 ) p = c~0 (q) : 2.4. COMPETITION AND MONOPOLY 25 Using the relation in equation 2.6, we can replace c~0 (q) with c0 (Q); recognizing that the price depends on aggregate sales, we can replace p with the inverse demand function p (Q). With these two substitutions, we rewrite the optimality condition for the representative …rm as price = industry marginal cost: p (Q) = c0 (Q) : (2.7) The monopoly equilibrium The monopoly recognizes that the price, p (Q), depends on its sales. Its pro…ts, revenue minus costs, equal p (Q) Q c (Q). The monopoly’s optimization problem is max p (Q) Q Q c (Q) : The …rst order condition for the monopoly is3 1 (Q) Marginal revenue = Marginal cost: p (Q) 1 Box 2.: Derivation of equation 2.8. pro…t maximization is d(p(Q)Q c(Q)) dQ = c0 (Q) . (2.8) The …rst order condition for = p0 (Q) Q + p set c0 (Q) = 0 ) p0 (Q) Q + p = c0 (Q) ; which states that marginal revenue, p0 (Q) Q+p, equals marginal cost, c0 (Q). We can write marginal revenue (denoted M R (Q)) using the elasticity of demand, : M R (Q) d[p(Q)Q] dQ p 1+ 3 1 dq p dp Q = p0 (Q) Q + p = p 1 + = p (Q) 1 1 (Q) dp Q dQ p : Recognizing that the equilibrium price and quantity lie on the demand function, we have p = p (Q), so we can write the elasticity of demand as (p (Q)), or (with some abuse of notation) as (Q). 26 CHAPTER 2. PRELIMINARIES Comparing the two equilibria The equilibrium conditions for the competitive industry and the monopoly are Competition: p (Q) = c0 (Q) Monopoly p (Q) 1 1 (Q) = c0 (Q) : Both of these equations involve the inverse demand function, p (Q), and the industry marginal cost function, c0 (Q). The competitive equilibrium condition sets price equal to the industry marginal cost, and the monopoly condition sets marginal revenue equal to industry marginal cost. Once we have the necessary condition for a competitive equilibrium, we can obtain the necessary condition for a monopoly equilibrium merely by replacing p with p 1 1 .4 The more elastic is the demand function that the monopoly faces (the larger is ), the less opportunity the monopoly has to exercise market power: it understands that any e¤ort to raise the market price requires a large reduction in sales, and a corresponding fall in revenue. As the market demand becomes in…nitely elastic, i.e. as ! 1 (“ goes to in…nity”), the monopoly looses all market power, and behaves like a competitive …rm. The monopoly never produces where < 1; at such a point, marginal revenue is negative. An example of calculating and comparing the equilibria In general, the demand elasticity, , is a function of sales. The “constant elasticity 1 of demand function”, where p (Q) = AQ , is the exception. Here, the elasticity of demand is a parameter, not a function. With this demand function and the cost function c (Q) = 2b Q2 , we can solve the competitive equilibrium condition (price = marginal cost) AQ 4 1 A = bQ ) = Q b set +1 )Q= A b 1+ )p=A A b 1 1+ : Early in the study of arithmetic we learn that the order in which operations are performed matters: (3 + 4) 7 = 49 6= 3 + (4 7) = 31. The order of operations also matters in carrying out economic calculations. For the monopoly, we …rst replace “price” with the inverse demand function, and then we take the derivative of pro…t with respect to sales. For the competitive …rm, we …rst take the derivative of pro…t with respect to sales, taking price as given, and then substitute the inverse demand function into the …rst order condition to obtain an equation in quantity. The order of these two steps is critical. 2.4. COMPETITION AND MONOPOLY 27 price ratio 1.8 1.7 1.6 1.5 1.4 1.3 1.2 1.1 1.0 1 2 3 4 5 elasticity Figure 2.2: Ratio of monopoly to competitive price For the monopoly problem, assume that > 1 (so marginal revenue is positive). Solving the monopoly equilibrium condition (marginal revenue = marginal cost) gives p (Q) 1 1 (Q) )Q= = AQ A(1 b 1 ) 1 1 1 set = bQ ) 1+ )p=A A(1 b A(1 1 ) b 1 ) =Q +1 1 1+ : Figure 2.2 graphs the ratio of the monopoly to the competitive equilibrium price. For low elasticity of demand ( close to 1) monopoly power is substantial, and the monopoly price is much larger than the competitive price. For large elasticity of demand, the monopoly has little market power, and the monopoly and competitive prices are similar. Optimization and equilibrium In most economic contexts, an equilibrium occurs where all agents simultaneously solve their optimization problems: no one wants to move unilaterally away from an equilibrium. At a competitive equilibrium consumers are maximizing utility, resulting in quantity demanded being on the demand function, and producers are maximizing pro…ts, resulting in quantity supplied being on the supply function. Markets clear, so supply equals demand. Models help to clarify complex situations, but do not literally describe behavior. If people behave completely randomly, then optimization-based eco- 28 CHAPTER 2. PRELIMINARIES nomic models are useless. If people attempt to pursue their self-interest, and behave with a modicum of rationality, these models are informative. Apart from Dr. Spock, everyone behaves irrationally in some contexts. However, managers of …rms who are consistently irrational are not likely to survive long in the market place. Shoppers may not buy food that is good for them, but they buy the food that they want, and in that respect they act in their self interest. Equilibrium is also an abstraction. Competitive …rms’optimal production level depends on the price that they expect to receive. Their expectations may be incorrect. If they have already committed a certain quantity to the market, but the price is lower than they expected (perhaps because demand is lower than they expected), the price-quantity point is below the supply curve. Markets are unlikely to be exactly in equilibrium, but people respond to their mistakes, and those responses likely move a market towards equilibrium. If …rms …nd that the price has systematically been lower than their marginal cost, they have an incentive to decrease quantity. The reduction in quantity leads to a higher price, moving the outcome toward equilibrium. Optimality and no-arbitrage conditions The …rst order condition to an optimization problem is a particular type of no-arbitrage condition. To illustrate this relation, consider the price-taking tea seller who has 10 units of tea in China and faces iceberg transport costs b in moving the tea to the U.S. Using the constraint q U.S. = 10 q China , this seller obtains pro…ts = pChina q China + pU.S 10 q China bpChina 10 q China : The …rst order condition (at an interior equilibrium) is d = pChina dq China set pU.S + bpChina = 0: Rearranging the last equation gives the no arbitrage condition 2.1, repeated here: 1 pChina = pU.S. : (1 + b) Optimality conditions can be interpreted as no-arbitrage conditions, although the exact interpretation varies with the context. 2.5. DISCOUNTING 2.5 29 Discounting Objectives and skills Understand the rationale for and the implementation of discounting. Be able to use discount factors to calculate the present value of a “stream”(= sequence) of future costs or payments. Understand the relation between the magnitude of a discount rate and the length of a period over which discounting occurs. A box of tea in China and a box of tea in the U.S. are not the same commodity if it is costly to move the box from one location to the other. Similarly, a dollar ten years from now is not the same as a dollar today, because there is an opportunity cost, the foregone investment opportunity, of receiving the dollar later rather than earlier. Most of the resource problems studied in this book involve decisions of when to extract a resource, e.g. when to take a unit of oil out of the ground, or when to harvest a unit of …sh. Deciding when to extract requires comparing the …rm’s value of extracting at di¤erent points in time. This comparison involves discounting. Pick a period of arbitrary length, say one year. Suppose that the most pro…table riskless investment available pays a return of r after one year. We call r the discount rate. If a person at period 0 invests z dollars for one year in an asset that returns the rate r, then at the end of the year the person has z (1 + r). The person with this investment opportunity is indi¤erent between receiving $1 at the beginning of the next year and $z in the current 1 . We de…ne period, if and only if z (1 + r) = 1, i.e. if and only if z = 1+r 1 = 1+r as the discount factor. This person is indi¤erent between receiving (for example) $43.60 at the beginning of next period, or $43.60 at the beginning of the current period. Multiplying an amount received one year in the future by , produces the “present value” of the future receipt. Today, the “present value”of $43.60 at the beginning of next year equals $43.60 . A person is indi¤erent between receiving one dollar at the end of two years and $z today if and only if (1 + r) (1 + r) z = 1, i.e. if and only if z = 2 . Thus, 2 is the present value today of a dollar in two years. Similarly, n is the present value today of a dollar n years from now. 30 CHAPTER 2. PRELIMINARIES Suppose that a …rm obtains pro…ts t during periods t = 0; 1; 2:::T . The present discounted stream of pro…ts equals T X t t: t=0 In the special case where t = , a constant, we can simplify this sum using the formula for a geometric series: 1 X t = t=0 1 (2.9) : This formula implies T X t=0 t = 1 X t=0 t T +1 1 X t=0 t = T +1 1 1 : (2.10) Relation between the discount rate and the length of a period The numerical value of the discount rate, and thus of the discount factor, depends on the length of a period of time. For example, suppose that a period lasts for ten years, and an asset held for one ten-year period pays a return of r~. Thus, one dollar invested in this asset for three periods (30 years) returns (1 + r~)3 . We say that this return is “compounded” every decade. We can convert this decadal return to an annual return by choosing the annual discount rate, r to satisfy (1 + r)10 = (1 + r~). Taking logs of both sides and r) . If r~ = 0:8, then r = 0:061; this asset simplifying gives ln (1 + r) = ln(1+~ 10 pays an 80% return over a decade, or a 6.1% return compounded annually. (We multiply by 100 to translate a rate into a percentage.) Given the decadal and annual discount rates, the corresponding decadal 1 1 and annual discount factors are ~ = 1+~ and = 1+r . We could have found r the relation between the two discount factors …rst, and used this result to compute the annual discount rate. The present value of one dollar in one decade is ~. With annual compounding, the present value of one dollar after 1 10 years is 10 . Setting 10 = ~ and taking logs gives ln = 10 ln ~. Example: the levelized cost of electricity Electricity can be produced using coal, natural gas, nuclear power or renewable resources. Each of these power sources has di¤erent production methods, e.g. di¤erent types 2.5. DISCOUNTING 31 of coal powered or nuclear powered plants, and di¤erent types of renewable resources, including wind, solar, and hydro. Di¤erent methods of electricity generation require di¤erent cost streams and produce di¤erent amounts of power. Nuclear-powered plants are expensive to build and require decommissioning, but have low fuel costs. Fossil fuel plants have relatively low investment and decommissioning costs, but high fuel costs. The “levelized cost” of electricity (LCOE) provides a basis for comparison across di¤erent power sources. Calculating the levelized cost of a power source requires estimates of the year-t capital cost, Ct , variable cost, Vt (including fuel and maintenance), the amount of energy produced, Et , and the lifetime (including construction and decommissioning time) of the project, n + 1 years. The formula for LCOE is Pn t (C + Vt ) Pn tt : (2.11) LCOE = t=0 Et t=0 Although the LCOE provides a straightforward means of comparing costs of di¤erent sources, it usually leaves out potentially important considerations. For example, a new power source such as wind or solar may require signi…cant network upgrades in order to bring the power to market. Fossil fuels have health and climate-related externalities. Nuclear power creates the risk of rare but catastrophic events. Incorporating these and other considerations requires additional data. Table 2.1 shows estimates for the U.S. for several power sources. Conventional Coal 96 Wind IGCC 116 Wind o¤shore 66 Advanced Nuclear 96 Solar PV2 Hydro Natural Gas CCC 80 204 130 85 Table 2.1 Estimated LCOE (2012$/MWh) for plants entering service in 2019. *Integrated Coal-Gasi…cation Combined Cycle. ** Conventional Combined Cycle (U.S. Energy Information Administration, 2014) The example in Table 2.2 shows that comparison of LCOEs can be sensitive to the discount rate. Type A generation method is expensive to construct but cheap to run and lasts a long time. Type B is cheap to build, expensive to run, and has a shorter lifetime. They both produce the same amount of energy per year (one unit). 32 CHAPTER 2. PRELIMINARIES ratio 1.3 1.2 1.1 1.0 0.9 0.8 0 1 2 3 4 Figure 2.3: Ratio of LCOE capital cost (billion $) Type A Type B annual operating cost 0.05 0.12 2 0.3 5 r (%) Type A : Type B lifetime 45 years 30 years construction time 5 years 2 years Table 2.2: Data for two di¤erent types of power plants A LCOE = 2+ P50 t=5 P50 t=5 t (0:05) t1 B and LCOE = 0:3 + P32 t (0:12) t=2 P32 t 1 t=2 Figure 2.3 shows the ratio of the two levelized costs as a function of the discount rate. The levelized costs are equal (the ratio is 1) for r = 2:7%; Type A is 10% cheaper at r = 2% and 17% more expensive at r = 4%. When “money is cheap” (the interest rate is low), it is economical to use the method that has large up-front costs but lower costs overall (Type A). However, when the interest rate is high, it is economical to use Type B, which has lower initial costs but higher undiscounted total costs. Example: the social cost of carbon The “social cost of carbon”(SCC) is de…ned as the present discounted stream of damages due to a unit of carbon emissions. It plays an important role in climate economics, in particular in estimates of the optimal carbon tax. The SCC depends on: the relation between a unit of emissions today and future carbon stocks; the relation between carbon stocks and temperature changes; the relation between temperature changes and economic damages; and the discount rate. Higher 2.6. WELFARE 33 discount rates (lower discount factors) place less weight on future damages, and therefore lead to a lower SCC. The Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) provides estimates of the SCC for di¤erent years and under di¤erent discount rates. It estimates, for the year 2015, a SCC of $12 per metric ton of CO2 if the discount rate is 5%, and a SCC of $61 if the discount rate is 2.5%. The estimates of SCC involve complex models, but a simple model illustrates the basic idea, and in particular the role of discounting. For this model, suppose that one metric ton of CO2 creates d dollars of economic damage, via temperature changes, and that carbon decays at a constant rate .5 With these assumptions, one unit of emissions today increases the carbon stock t periods from now by (1 )t and creates d (1 )t dollars of damage in period t. The present discounted value of the stream of damages due to this unit of emissions equals SCC = 1 X d (1 )t t t=0 The last equality uses from formula 2.9. (the larger is ), the larger is the SCC. 2.6 = 1 d (1 ) : The smaller is the discount rate Welfare Objectives and skills Understand the meaning of “Pareto e¢ cient”. Be familiar with the two Fundamental Welfare Theorems, and know the conditions under which a competitive outcome is e¢ cient. Resource economics studies the allocation of a natural resource over time. Under certain conditions, the allocation under competitive markets is Pareto e¢ cient, meaning that there does not exist another allocation of the resource that makes at least one agent better o¤, without making any agent worse o¤. “Pareto e¢ cient” has a technical meaning; it does not express a value 5 Carbon does not literally decay. CO2 is emitted to the atmosphere, and over time some of it moves to di¤erent oceanic and terrestrial “reservoirs”. The model of constant decay is one of the simplest ways to approximate carbon leaving the atmosphere. 34 CHAPTER 2. PRELIMINARIES judgement. “E¢ cient” does not mean “good”. The simplest example of Pareto e¢ ciency involves two people who both like to consume a product that has …xed supply, one unit. These two people, Jiangfeng and Mary, get utility only from their own consumption. A feasible allocation gives Jiangfeng z 0 and Mary w 0 units of the good, with z + w 1. An e¢ cient allocation makes sure that all of the good is consumed; any outcome with z + w = 1 is e¢ cient. Giving all of the good to Jiangfeng or all of it to Mary are both e¢ cient, although neither allocation seems particularly ethical. In this sense, e¢ ciency is a rather weak criterion. For example, we might prefer the equal but ine¢ cient allocation, z = w = 0:4999 to the e¢ cient but ethically questionable allocation w = 1, z = 0. The …rst part of this book emphasizes the competitive equilibrium without market failures, occasionally discussing the monopoly equilibrium. Firms own natural resource stocks and choose how much to extract and sell in each period. In order to make statements about the social welfare arising from the …rms’allocation, we have to specify a “welfare criterion”, i.e. we have to say exactly how one measures welfare. Once we have this criterion, we can imagine a social planner who maximizes it, choosing how much to extract and sell in each period. We can then compare the outcome under competition or monopoly with the outcome under this social planner. We work exclusively with partial equilibrium models: those that involve a single market, e.g. the market for a particular resource. We take as given all “outside” considerations that might in‡uence this market. For example, if the resource is petroleum, the partial equilibrium model seeks to explain petroleum prices and quantities, over time, taking as given: levels of income (which a¤ect demand for petroleum); prices of factors used to produce petroleum (labor, machinery); prices of substitutes (natural gas) and complements (cars); and technology (drilling techniques). With a partial equilibrium model, consumer and producer surplus are reasonable measures of consumer and producer welfare, and their sum is a reasonable measure of social welfare in a period. We take the social welfare function to be the discounted sum (over time) of welfare in each period. This criterion, known as “discounted utilitarianism”, is used in most resource models. Our …ctitious social planner is a discounted utilitarian. If markets are competitive, and certain conditions hold, then a competitive equilibrium is Pareto e¢ cient, using the criterion of discounted social surplus: the competitive equilibrium maximizes the present discounted sum of consumer + producer surplus. In this case, there is no role for government 2.6. WELFARE 35 intervention if we care only about e¢ ciency, not about equity. No taxes or lump sum transfers are needed in order to insure that the competitive equilibrium leads to the same prices and quantities as under the planner. The equivalence between the outcomes under competition and under the social planner requires that markets are “complete” and that there are no unpriced externalities. Markets are complete if there is a market for every type of transaction that people would like to make. For example, if someone would like to buy insurance and someone else is willing to sell insurance, then “complete markets”requires that there is actually an insurance market that makes their exchange possible. An “unpriced externality” is a consequence of the market transaction not fully re‡ected in the price of the good. For example, the price of fossil fuels does not include the environmental damage arising from extracting and using the fuels. In the real world, markets are not complete and externalities are significant, weakening the practical importance of the theoretical possibility that the competitive equilibrium is Pareto e¢ cient. Nevertheless, it is worth understanding this possibility: it is central to modern economics, and provides a good place to begin (but not to end) the analysis of resource markets. The result is known as First Fundamental Welfare Theorem: Suppose that markets are complete, there are no unpriced externalities, and agents are price-takers. Then any competitive equilibrium is Pareto e¢ cient. A second theorem provides conditions under which a particular Pareto ef…cient outcome can result from a competitive equilibrium. We say that a set of transfers and taxes “supports”a particular “outcome X”in a competitive equilibrium if, in the presence of those transfers and taxes, the competitive equilibrium is identical to (e.g. has the same prices and quantities) as “outcome X”. The second theorem is Second Fundamental Welfare theorem: Provided that a technical requirement (“convexity”6 ) is satis…ed, any Pareto e¢ cient 6 For example, constant and decreasing returns to scale technologies are “convex”. A technology with increasing returns to scale is not convex. Constant returns to scale means that doubling inputs doubles output. Decreasing returns to scale means that doubling inputs less than doubles output. Increasing returns to scale means that doubling inputs more than doubles output. 36 CHAPTER 2. PRELIMINARIES equilibrium can be supported as a competitive equilibrium using taxes and lump sum transfers. These two theorems provide the basis for attributing welfare properties to a competitive equilibrium. The …rst theorem provides conditions under which the competitive equilibrium is e¢ cient. With complete, competitive markets where there are no externalities, the First Fundamental Welfare Theorem assures us that the competitive equilibrium is e¢ cient. The second theorem tell us (under “convexity”) that we can obtain any other e¢ cient outcome, as a competitive equilibrium, by using appropriate taxes and transfers. 2.7 Summary An example of arbitrage over space illustrates the meaning of arbitrage. Many of the main ideas in this book are based on arbitrage over time: instead of selling the commodity in one country rather than another, the …rm sells it at one point in time rather than another. Understanding spatial arbitrage makes it easy to understand intertemporal arbitrage. Economic models help to determine how a change in an exogenous parameter changes an endogenous variable. This kind of question is known as a comparative statics question. Casual reasoning or graphical methods su¢ ce to answer very simple comparative statics questions. In more complicated cases, we use mathematics, beginning with an equilibrium condition (e.g., supply equals demand). One approach uses this condition to …nd an explicit expression for the endogenous variable, as a function of the exogenous variables. An alternative uses the di¤erential of the equilibrium condition. We de…ned elasticities, and illustrated the de…nition using the elasticity of demand with respect to price. It is important to be able to calculate an elasticity, and to understand why it is unit free. In order to compare perfect competition and monopoly, we want to “hold everything else constant”, apart from the market structure. In this context, we require that the demand and cost functions (not their levels) are the same for both market structures. We can think of the industry consisting of many factories. In the competitive environment, each …rm owns one of these factories, and in the monopoly, a single …rm owns all factories. Both the monopoly and the representative …rm want to maximize pro…ts. For the price-taking competitive …rms, the equilibrium condition is “price 2.8. TERMS, STUDY QUESTIONS, AND EXERCISES 37 equals marginal cost”. The monopoly understands that its sales a¤ect the price; the monopoly marginal revenue equals p (1 1= ), where is the elasticity of demand. Provided that is …nite, the monopoly sells less than the competitive industry. As demand becomes more elastic, the monopoly has less market power. We use the discount factor to compare money (e.g. pro…ts) received in di¤erent periods. The discount factor is = 1= (1 + r), where r is the discount rate, equal to the highest riskless return available to the agent. The discount factor converts future values into present values. The magnitude of r, and thus of , depend on the length of a period. We can transform the magnitudes of ; r corresponding to a particular length of period, e.g. 10 years, into the magnitudes that correspond to some other length of period, e.g. one year. An outcome, such as the allocation of a product across individuals, geographical regions, or time, is said to be Pareto e¢ cient if there is no reallocation that makes some agent better o¤ without making any agent worse o¤. The two fundamental welfare theorems describe the relation between a competitive equilibrium and the outcome under a social planner. The …rst of these theorems provides conditions under which a competitive equilibrium is Pareto e¢ cient. The second provides conditions under which any Pareto e¢ cient equilibrium can be supported as a competitive equilibrium by means of taxes or income transfers. 2.8 Terms, study questions, and exercises Terms and concepts Demand function, inverse demand function, arbitrage, no-arbitrage condition, interior equilibrium, boundary equilibrium, iceberg transportation costs, endogenous and exogenous variable, law of one price, implicit function, explicit function, comparative statics, di¤erential, …rst order condition, marginal revenue, order of operations, discount function, discount factor, opportunity cost, compounded, capital cost, operating cost, decommissioning cost, levelized cost, partial equilibrium, externality, complete markets, e¢ cient, Pareto e¢ cient, consumer and producer surplus, feasible, discounted utilitarianism. 38 CHAPTER 2. PRELIMINARIES Study questions 1. You should be able to use the type of …gure in Section 2.1 to illustrate the e¤ect of a change on demand in one country, or a change in available supply, or in transportation costs, on the equilibrium allocation of sales across country. 2. Given inverse demand functions in the two countries, available supply, and the transport costs, you should be able to write down the equilibrium condition. Taking the di¤erential of this condition, you should be able to write a comparative statics expression showing the e¤ect of a change in an exogenous variable on an endogenous variable. You should be clear about the distinction between exogenous and endogenous variables. 3. You should know what an elasticity it, how to calculate it, and what it means to say that the elasticity is unit free. 4. Given an industry cost function and an inverse demand, you should be able to write down the equilibrium conditions that determine sales under competition and under monopoly. 5. You should know the relation between a discount rate and a discount factor, and understand what they are used for. There is no need to memorize the formula for the sum of a geometric series, but if given this formula, you should be able to use it to calculate (or show how to calculate) the present discounted stream of payo¤s. For example, you should be able to work through an example like the …rst one in the text that compares the cost of two methods of electricity generation. 6. You should understand the meaning and be able to describe the two Fundamental Welfare theorems. Exercises 1. When quantities are measured in pounds and prices in dollars, the demand function is Q = 3 5P . (a) What is the elasticity of demand, evaluated at P = 1? (b) Express the same relation between demand and price, using di¤erent units, q and p: q are in units of kilos, and p in pesos. There are 3 pesos per dollar. (c) What numerical value of p 2.8. TERMS, STUDY QUESTIONS, AND EXERCISES 39 corresponds to P = 1? (d) Using the new units, q and p, express the elasticity of demand with respect to price, evaluated at the value of p you obtained from part c. (d) What is the point of this exercise? 2. How does an increase in transportation costs a¤ect the location of the dotted line in Figure 2.1, and how does this change alter the equilibrium price and the allocation of tea between the two countries? 3. How does an increase in the available supply (e.g. from 10 units to 12 units of tea) change the appearance of Figure 2.1, and how does this change in supply alter the equilibrium quantities and prices in the two countries? 4. Calculate (Q) for the demand function Q = a hp and then for the demand function Q = ap h , where h is a positive number. Graph the two elasticities as a function of Q. 5. Suppose that a monopoly owns the ten units of tea in China. There is no transportation costs (b = 0). Using the inverse demand functions in Section 2.1, …nd monopoly sales two markets. 6. Consider the monopoly in the previous question. Suppose that iceberg transportation costs are b. Using the equilibrium condition for the monopoly, …nd the comparative statics of the monopoly’s sales in China, with respect to b. (Use the method that does not rely on …nding an explicit solution to …rst period sales as a function of b.) 7. Suppose that the industry has the cost function c (Q) = 2Q + 32 Q2 . This industry consists of n …rms, each with cost function c (q). Find c (q). Hint: “Guess”that the single …rm’s cost function is of the form c Qn , to c~ (q) = aq + 2b q 2 . Then use the requirement that c (Q) = n~ write ! 2 3 2 Q b Q 2Q + Q = n a + : 2 n 2 n This relation must hold for all Q (not just a particular Q), so we can “equate coe¢ cients”of Q and Q2 to …nd the values of a and b. 8. A plant that supplies 1 unit of electricity per year, costs $1 billion to build, lasts 25 years, and has an annual operating cost of $0.2 billion; it 40 CHAPTER 2. PRELIMINARIES costs $0.1 billion to decommission the plant at the end of its lifetime (25 years). (Assume that the construction costs and the operating costs are paid at the beginning of the period, and that the decommissioning cost is paid at the end of the life of the plant.) The annual discount rate is r. Write the formula for the present value of the cost of providing 1 unit of electricity for 100 years, including the decommissioning costs. 9. A monopoly faces the demand function q = p 1:2 and has production costs c (q) = 2b q 2 . Find the comparative statics of equilibrium price, with respect to the cost parameter, b. 10. A person plans to save $1 for 20 years. They can invest at an annual rate of 10% (r = 0:1). This investment opportunity “compounds annually” (meaning that they receive interest payments at the end of each year). A second investment opportunity pays a return of r~ 100%, compounded every decade. (After one decade, the investment of one dollar yields 1 + r~.) For what value of r~ is the person indi¤erent between these two investments? (Assume that there is no chance that the person wants to cash in the investment before the 20 year period.) Explain the rationale behind your calculation. 11. (*) This exercise illustrates the First Fundamental welfare theorem. Inverse demand equals p (q) and total cost is 12 cq 2 . (a) Write the condition for equilibrium in a competitive market. (b) For a linear demand function, draw the graphs whose intersection determines the competitive equilibrium. Using this graph, identify consumer and producer surplus. (c) Explain in words why consumer surplus equals Z q p (w) dw p (q) q: 0 (d) Write the expression for producer surplus, equal to revenue minus costs. (e) De…ne social surplus, S (q), as the sum of consumer and producer surplus. Write the expression for social surplus. Using Leibniz’s rule (see math appendix) write the …rst order condition for maximizing social surplus, by choice of q. (f) Compare this …rst order condition with the equilibrium condition under competition. Explain why this comparison implies that the competitive equilibrium and the solution to the social planner’s problem (maximizing social surplus) 2.8. TERMS, STUDY QUESTIONS, AND EXERCISES 41 are identical. What does this have to do with the First Fundamental Welfare Theorem? Sources The U.S. Energy Information Administration (2014) presents and explains estimates of the Levelized Cost of Electricity. The Interagency Working Group (2013) presents estimates of the Social Cost of Carbon. Amartya Sen On Ethics and Economics (1987) New York, Blackwell provides a background on welfare economics. Aker (2010) provides evidence of the relation between cell phones and agricultural markets. Glaeser and Kohlhase (2004) provide estimates of transport costs, and discuss their role in international trade. Prominent estimates of market power in resource markets include: Hnyilicza and Pindyck (1976), Stollery (1985), Pindyck (1987), Ellis and Halvorsen (2001), Cerda (2007). 42 CHAPTER 2. PRELIMINARIES Chapter 3 Nonrenewable resources Objectives Ability to analyze equilibria under competition and monopoly for the two-period model of nonrenewable resources. Information and skills Translate the techniques and intuition from the “trade in tea” model to the nonrenewable resource setting. Understand the relation between transport costs in the trade model and the discount factor in the resource setting. Derive and interpret an equilibrium condition and analyze it using graphical methods, for both competition and monopoly. Do comparative statics with respect to extraction costs and the discount factor. A two-period model provides much of the intuition needed to understand equilibrium in a nonrenewable resources market. We use graphical methods to analyze the equilibrium under competition or monopoly when …rms are unable to save any resource beyond the second period. We emphasize the case where the initial stock is small enough, relative to demand, that …rms want to exhaust the resource during this time. Arbitrage provides the basis for the intuition in resource models, but here we speak of arbitrage over time, instead of over space. After discussing the 43 44 CHAPTER 3. NONRENEWABLE RESOURCES competitive and the monopoly models, we explain how to answer comparative statics questions of the following sort: How does a change in a demand or a cost parameter a¤ect the equilibrium level of …rst-period sales? A sales trajectory is the sequence of sales, and a price trajectory is the associated sequence of prices. In the two-period setting, each of these sequences contains only two elements. 3.1 The competitive equilibrium Objectives and skills Write the objective and the constraints for a competitive …rm. Obtain and interpret the “no-intertemporal” arbitrage (equilibrium) condition under competition, and analyze it graphically. Understand the e¤ect of constant average extraction costs on the equilibrium sales and price trajectories. Chapter 2.1 considered the allocation of a …xed quantity of tea over two countries, in the presence of iceberg transportation costs. Here, a …xed stock of the resource replaces tea, two periods replace the two countries, and the discount factor replaces the iceberg transportation costs. We require a bit of notation. The …rst period is denoted t = 0, and the second period, t = 1. A price-taking …rm has discount factor , faces prices p0 and p1 in periods 0 and 1, must pay extraction cost c for each unit extracted, and has a …xed stock of the resource, x units. In this model, marginal extraction costs = average extraction costs = c, a constant. The trade example did not include production costs. Except for this di¤erence, the trade and the resource models are exactly the same; we merely call things by di¤erent names. Not surprisingly, the intuition for the equilibrium in the two models is also the same. Let y be sales in period 0. Assuming that all of the resource is sold, x y equals period-1 sales. At an interior equilibrium, extraction is positive in both periods: x > y > 0. The …rm wants to maximize the sum of present value pro…ts in the two periods: competitive (y; p0 ; p1 ) = (p0 c) y + (p1 c) (x y) : (3.1) 3.1. THE COMPETITIVE EQUILIBRIUM 45 Multiplying period-1 pro…ts by the discount factor, , gives the present value of period-1 pro…ts. The derivative of (y; p0 ; p1 ) with respect to y is d competitive dy = (p0 c) y (p1 c) : The …rm prefers to sell all of its stock in period 0 ( d c o m p e titive dy d > 0) if c o m p e titive (p0 c) > (p1 c). It prefers to sell all of its stock in period 1 ( < dy 0) if (p0 c) < (p1 c). In order for the …rm to sell a positive quantity in both periods, as we assume, it must be indi¤erent about when to sell the stock. This indi¤erence requires that the present value of period t = 1 price minus marginal cost equals the value of price minus marginal cost in period t = 0: d competitive = 0 if and only if (p0 c) = (p1 c) : (3.2) dy The second equation is a “no-intertemporal arbitrage” condition; it holds in an interior competitive equilibrium. The equation states that the …rm cannot increase its pro…ts by moving sales from one period to another. The competitive resource owner, just like the competitive exporter in the trade example, takes prices as given. These prices adjust in response to the amount of supply brought to market. Actions of an individual resource owner, just like the actions of an individual exporter, have negligible a¤ect on the price. However, all resource owners (in our model) have the same costs and discount factor, so they have the same incentives. Therefore, we can proceed as if there is a “representative …rm” that takes price as given, and owns all of the stock in the industry. The price responds to changes in this representative …rm’s supply. Figure 3.1 shows the market when extraction costs are c = 0 and the inverse demand in both periods is p = 20 y. Sales in period 0 equal y. Assuming that the initial stock is x = 10, period-1 sales equal 10 y. The solid line shows the demand function in period 0: as y increases, the equilibrium price falls. The dashed line shows the demand function in period 1: as y increases, period 1 sales, 10 y, fall, so the price in that period rises. 1 , equals If the discount rate is 0 (r = 0) then the discount factor, = 1+r 1. In this scenario, …rms allocate the stock evenly between the two periods, and the price in each period equals 15. With zero discount rate, the …rm is indi¤erent between selling in periods 0 or 1 if and only if the prices in the two periods are equal. 46 CHAPTER 3. NONRENEWABLE RESOURCES $ 20 first period demand second period demand 15 10 5 0 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 Figure 3.1: Demand in period 0 (solid). Present value of period 1 price (dotted). 7 8 9 10 11 12 y Demand in period 1 (dashed). The dotted line shows the present value (in period 0) of the period-1 price 1 = 0:77. The equilibrium occurs if the discount rate is r = 0:3, so = 1:3 where the present value of price is the same in both periods, i.e. where the solid and the dotted lines intersect. With our demand function and discount factor, equilibrium sales in period 0 equal 6: 96 and the price is 13: 04. Period-1 sales equal 3:04 and the price is 16: 96. The equilibrium period-1 price is a point on the dashed curve, above the intersection of the solid and the dotted curve. Discounting the future makes future revenue less valuable from the standpoint of the …rm in period 0. The …rm therefore has an incentive to sell more in period 0. As the …rm reallocates sales in this manner, the period-0 price falls, and the period-1 price rises. Equilibrium is restored when the present value of prices in the two periods are equal. The price-taking representative …rm does not shift sales from the future to the present (i.e. from period 1 to period 0) with the intention of causing price to change. If, following an increase of r from 0 to 0.3, the …rm did not reallocate sales, then the present value of a unit of sales in period 0 remains 1 = at p0 = 15 and the present value of a unit of sales in period 1 is 15 1:3 11: 5 < 15. In this case, the …rm has an opportunity for intertemporal arbitrage. Prices adjust as the …rm moves sales from period 1 to period 0, until, at equilibrium, there are no further opportunities for intertemporal arbitrage Figure 3.2 illustrates the model with constant average (= marginal) costs c = 4 (instead of c = 0 as above). The solid and dashed lines show price minus cost, instead of price, in the two periods. With zero discount rate, 3.1. THE COMPETITIVE EQUILIBRIUM 47 $ 20 15 10 5 0 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 y Figure 3.2: Demand - cost in period 0 (solid). Demand - cost in period 1 (dashed). Present value of period 1 price - cost (dotted). sales are again allocated evenly between the two periods, and the price in both periods is again p = 15, so price - costs = 11. In the absence of discounting, the cost increase reduces the …rm’s pro…ts, but has no e¤ect on consumers. The dotted line in Figure 3.2 shows the present value of period-1 price minus extraction costs, for a discount factor = 0:77. In this case, the equilibrium occurs where the present value of price minus extraction costs are equal in the two periods, at the intersection of the solid and the dotted lines. Here, period-0 sales equal 6: 43 and the period-0 price is 13: 57. With discounting, higher extraction costs cause the …rm to move production from period 0 to the period 1. This reallocation causes period-0 price to rise and period-1 price to fall. With discounting, the higher extraction costs lowers consumer surplus in period 0, and increases consumer surplus in period 1. =1 = 0:77 c = 0 p0 = 15 p0 = 13:04 c = 4 p0 = 15 p0 = 13:57 Table 3.1: Period-0 price for di¤erent discount factors and cost Table 1 summarizes the e¤ects of discounting and extraction costs on period-0 price. A higher extraction cost (raising costs from c = 0 to c = 4) has no e¤ect on period-0 price in the absence of discounting, but leads to a reallocation of sales “from the present to the future” (i.e. from period 0 to period 1) under discounting. From the perspective of the …rm in period 48 CHAPTER 3. NONRENEWABLE RESOURCES 0, a one unit increase in costs increases the average and marginal extraction cost today by one unit, and increases the present value of cost in the next period costs by only . Other things equal, higher extraction costs make it less attractive to extract the resource. However, discounting diminishes the period-1 cost-driven disincentive to sell, relative to the period-0 disincentive. Therefore, in the presence of discounting, …rms respond to a higher cost by reducing period-0 sales and increasing period-1 sales. 3.2 Monopoly Objectives and skills Write down the objective and constraints of a monopoly resource owner. Obtain and understand the equilibrium condition for the monopoly. Use graphical methods to illustrate the relation between exogenous parameters and the monopoly equilibrium. Compare the monopoly and the competitive outcomes (e.g. period 0 sales and price in the two cases). Understand the statement “the monopoly is the conservationist’s friend”. The monopoly, like the competitive …rm, wants to maximize the present discounted value of pro…ts, given by expression 3.1. However, the monopoly recognizes that its sales a¤ect the price, whereas the competitive …rm takes price as given. The monopoly understands that period 0 price is the function p (y) and period 1 price is the function p (x y). The present discounted stream of monopoly pro…ts equals monopoly (y) = (p (y) c) y + (p (x y0 ) c) (x y) : (3.3) We can …nd the equilibrium condition for the monopoly by using the …rst order condition to the problem of maximizing monopoly (y). A simpler approach, discussed in Chapter 2.4, …nds this equilibrium condition by adapting the equilibrium condition for the competitive industry, replacing price with marginal revenue. Marginal revenue, M R, is M R (Q) = p (Q) 1 1 (Q) , with (Q) dQ p ; dp Q 3.2. MONOPOLY $ 49 18 16 14 12 10 8 6 4 2 0 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 y Figure 3.3: Solid curves show …rst and second period demand minus marginal cost as a function of …rst period sales. Dashed curves show marginal revenue minus marginal cost curves corresponding to these demand curves. = 1. where is the price elasticity of demand. Again denoting period-0 sales by y (instead of Q) and period-1 sales by x y, we have the equilibrium condition for the monopoly M R (y) c = [M R (x y) c] : (3.4) Figure 3.3 shows the period-0 and period-1 demand functions, p0 = 20 y and p1 = 20 (10 y), minus marginal cost, c = 4, (the two solid lines) as a function of period-0 sales, y. The dashed lines beneath those two demand functions show the marginal pro…t (marginal revenue minus marginal cost) corresponding to those two demand functions. In the absence of discounting ( = 1) optimality for the monopoly requires that marginal pro…t in the two periods are equal. Absent discounting, the monopoly sells the same amount in both periods, so y = 5, exactly as in the competitive equilibrium with no discounting. In this market, moving from a competitive market to a monopoly has no e¤ect on the outcome. This result is due to the fact that the stock of resource is …xed, together with the assumption that the world lasts only two periods, and the assumption that the discount rate is 0 ( = 1). In this setting, neither the monopoly nor the competitive …rm has any incentive to save the resource beyond period 1. Below we show that if r > 0 (so < 1) the monopoly 50 CHAPTER 3. NONRENEWABLE RESOURCES sells less in period 0 than competitive …rms; the monopoly saves more of the resource for the future, period 1, and in that sense is the “conservationist’s friend”. First, however, we consider the simpler case where = 1 in a bit more detail. Digression: Comparing competition and monopoly in the static setting To emphasize that there is nothing peculiar about the possibility that the monopoly and competitive …rm might choose the same level of sales, consider an even simpler, one-period model. In this model, the …rm (either a monopoly or a representative competitive …rm) can produce up to 10 units at constant costs 4. Production beyond that level is not feasible; equivalently, the marginal cost of production becomes in…nite at y = 10. In the …rst scenario, the inverse demand function is p = 30 y, and in the second scenario it is p = 15 y. Figures 3.4 and 3.5 show the demand functions in these two cases (the solid lines), and the corresponding marginal revenue curves (the dashed lines). In both cases the marginal production cost is 4 for y < 10 and in…nite for y > 10. In the high-demand scenario (Figure 3.4), the constraint y 10 is binding for both the monopoly and the competitive …rm, so both …rms produce y = 10. In this case, the price is also the same under the competitive …rm or the monopoly. In the low-demand scenario (Figure 3.5), the constraint is binding for the competitive …rm, which produces y = 10. Here, the marginal revenue curve (which lies below the demand curve) equals marginal cost at y = 5:5. The monopoly produces less than competitive …rms, and receives a higher price. There is nothing special about the possibility that a monopoly and a competitive …rm might produce at the same level. The outcome depends on the relation between the point at which the cost function becomes vertical (y = 10 in this example) and the demand and marginal revenue functions. The monopoly is the conservationists’friend We return to the twoperiod resource model. Under our assumption that both the monopoly and competitive industry extract the same cumulative quantity over two periods, the two market structures lead to the same allocation of the resource if there is no discounting and if extraction costs are either 0 or constant (as in our example): both sell half the aggregate quantity in each period. With discounting (or with non-constant average extraction costs, studied in 3.2. MONOPOLY 51 $ 30 20 10 0 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 y Figure 3.4: The solid line shows the demand function p = 30 y; and the dashed line is the marginal revenue function corresponding to this demand function. Marginal costs are constant at 4 for y < 10 and in…nite for y > 10: $ 20 15 10 5 0 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 y Figure 3.5: The solid line shows the demand function p = 15 y; and the dashed line is the marginal revenue function corresponding to this demand function. Marginal costs are constant at 4 for y < 10 and in…nite for y > 10: 52 CHAPTER 3. NONRENEWABLE RESOURCES $ 20 15 10 5 0 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 y Figure 3.6: The solid curves show the present value (with = 0:5) demand functions in the two periods, minus c = 4, and the dashed lines show the present value marginal revenue curves, minus c = 4. First period sales in the competitive equilibrium = 7.33; …rst period sales under the monopoly = 5.33. “The monopoly is the conservationist’s friend.” Chapter 4), the allocations in the two equilibria are, in general, di¤erent. For “most” demand and cost functions, including those used in this book, the monopoly sells less in period 0, compared to the competitive industry. The monopoly saves more of the resource for the future, compared to the competitive industry: “the monopoly is the conservationists’friend”. This result is not completely general: for some combinations of demand and cost functions (not included in this book) period-0 monopoly sales are greater than period-0 competitive sales. For = 0:5, Figure 3.6 shows the present value of price minus marginal revenue minus cost, illustrating that (in this setting) the monopoly is the conservationist’s friend. The intersection of the solid lines (present value of price minus marginal costs) identi…es the period-0 sales under competition, y = 7:33. The intersection of the dashed lines (present value of marginal revenue minus marginal costs) identi…es the period-0 sales under the monopoly, y = 5:33. A decrease in the discount factor from = 1 to = 0:5 increases period-0 sales under both market structures, but the increase is greater in the competitive market. (Compare Figures 3.3 and 3.6.) A decrease in shifts down and ‡attens both of the period-1 curves in Figure 3.6, but the marginal revenue curve is steeper than the inverse demand function, causing the point of intersection on the marginal revenue curves to move further to the left.. 3.3. COMPARATIVE STATICS 3.3 53 Comparative statics Objectives and skills Reinforce the distinction between exogenous and endogenous variables, and the distinction between an explicit and implicit relation between variables. Use calculus, and both the explicit and the implicit relations, to answer a comparative statics question. This section provides more practice in working through the comparative statics of a model. Following the procedure outlined in Chapter 2.2, we …rst …nd an explicit expression for the endogenous variable of interest (period-0 sales) as a function of model parameters, and take derivatives to …nd comparative static expressions. The alternative approach proceeds by totally di¤erentiating the equilibrium condition with respect to the endogenous and the exogenous variables of interest, and rearranging the resulting di¤erential in order to obtain an expression for the derivative of the endogenous variable with respect to the exogenous variable. We can sometimes, but not always, determine the sign of the comparative static expressions. In cases where we cannot determine the sign, we have to be careful in how we describe our ignorance. If we say that we cannot determine the sign, we mean just that. If, however, we say that the sign of the expression is “ambiguous” we mean that for some parameter values the sign is positive, and for others it is negative. These two statements mean di¤erent things. In one of our examples, we can determine the sign of the comparative static expression when we use the explicit solution, but not when we use the alternative based on the di¤erential of the equilibrium condition. Because the two approaches to …nding the comparative statics are both correct, their answers must be mutually consistent. However, one approach gives more information than the other. The endogenous variables in this model are the prices and quantities in the two periods. The exogenous variables are c and . A slightly richer model replaces the numerical values in the demand function with symbols, replacing p = 20 y with p = a by, and replaces the initial stock, 10, with a symbol, x. For that model, the equilibrium condition in the competitive 54 CHAPTER 3. NONRENEWABLE RESOURCES model is (a by c) = (a b (x y) (3.5) c) : Comparative statics via the explicit relation Because of its linearity, we can solve this equation to obtain an explicit expression for …rst period sales, as a function of the model parameters: y= 1 (a b+b c + (c a + bx)) : We can answer comparative statics questions by di¤erentiating this expression with respect to model parameters. For example, dy 1 = dc b+b 0 and dy 1 1 = 2 (a db b +1 c) 0: (3.6) The “choke price”, de…ned as the price at which demand falls to 0, is a in this model. In order for …rms to extract the resource, it must be the case that a > c. Therefore, the two comparative statics inequalities are “strict” (< instead of =) for < 1. We already showed graphically that when < 1 an increase in extraction costs shifts extraction from the …rst to the second period. A larger value of b makes the inverse demand function steeper, i.e. it reduces demand at any price. The second comparative statics expression shows that this decrease in demand also reduces …rst period sales. Comparative statics via the implicit relation For even slightly more complex models, it would not be possible to obtain explicit comparative statics expressions. Chapter 2.2 illustrates how to …nd comparative static expressions using only the equilibrium condition, not an explicit solution to the model. Following the procedure outlined there, we denote the left side of the equilibrium condition, equation 3.5, as L (y; ) = (a by c) and the right side as R (y; ) = (a b (x y) c). The “ ” notation is shorthand for all of the exogenous variables, the parameters of the model: a; b; c; x; . With this notation, we rewrite the equilibrium condition, equation 3.5 as L (y; ) = R (y; ) : Equilibrium requires that a change in an exogenous parameter, such as the demand slope b, be o¤set by a change in the endogenous variable, period 0 supply, y: dL = dR. Evaluating this equality implies the comparative 3.3. COMPARATIVE STATICS 55 statics expression (Box 3.1) x + (1 + ) y : b (1 + ) dy = db (3.7) The denominator of the right side of this equation is negative, but without additional information we cannot determine whether the numerator is positive or negative. The most that we can say, using only the information in equation 3.7, is that dy < 0 if and only if x + (1 + ) y > 0, i.e. if and db only if y > 1+ x. Box 3.1: Derivation of equation 3.7. We totally di¤erentiate the equilibrium condition, equation 3.5, with respect to y and b, to write dL = @L @R @R @L dy + db = dy + db = dR: @y @b @y @b Rearrange the di¤erentials on the two sides of the equality to write @L @y @R @y dy = @R @b @L @b dy = db ) db @R @b @L @y @L @b : @R @y @R = @b (x y) : To evaluate this expression we use @L = @y b; @R @L = b, = @y @b y; Putting these results together, we have dy = db @R @b @L @y @L @b @R @y = (x y) b ( y) b Simplifying the right side of this equation produces equation 3.7. Comparing the two approaches to comparative statics It is instructive to compare the derivatives dy in equations 3.6 and 3.7. Both of them db are correct, but the former contains more information; it tells us that dy < 0, db whereas equation 3.7 gives us only a condition ( y > 1+ x) under which dy < 0. The fact that the two approaches yield di¤erent amounts of infordb mation is not surprising, because the …rst approach begins with more informa- 56 CHAPTER 3. NONRENEWABLE RESOURCES tion: it uses the explicit expression for y as a function of model parameters. In contrast, the second approach uses only the equilibrium condition. More information is preferred to less, so in this sense the …rst approach is better than the second. But bear in mind that the …rst approach is not always available to us, because many models are too complicated to yield explicit solutions for the endogenous variables. 3.4 Summary Equilibrium in a nonrenewable resource market has many of the characteristics of the equilibrium in the previous trade example. The no-arbitrage condition in the trade model requires that transportation costs account for any price di¤erence between the two locations. In the two-period nonrenewable resource setting, …rms can reallocate sales from one period to another. Intertemporal reallocation in the resource setting corresponds to transportation across space in the trade setting. An intertemporal no-arbitrage condition requires that the present value of the marginal return from selling a good is the same in both periods. The discount factor, used to convert a future receipt into its present value equivalent, plays a role analogous to transportation costs in the trade model. We obtained the equilibrium condition for a monopoly by taking the equilibrium condition for a competitive …rm, and replacing price with marginal revenue, where marginal revenue = p (1 1= ), and is the price elasticity of demand. With constant marginal extraction costs and no discounting (r = 0, so = 1), in our example both types of …rms sell the same amount, half of the available stock, in period 0. Under discounting, ( < 1), the monopoly sells less in the …rst period than the competitive …rm. Here, the monopoly is the conservationist’s friend. Using graphical methods, we showed that for < 1, increasing extraction costs leads to a fall in period-0 sales under both competition or monopoly. Increasing costs decreases the sales incentive both periods; but because of discounting, the incentive for period-1 sales (= extraction) falls by less than does the incentive for period-0 sales. An example illustrated two calculus-based ways to conduct comparative statics: by taking derivatives of an explicit solution, or by using the di¤erential of the equilibrium condition. Both approaches are correct, but the comparative statics expressions that they produce have di¤erent appearances, 3.5. TERMS, STUDY QUESTIONS, AND EXERCISES 57 and possibly contain di¤erent amounts of information. For many models of interest, it is not possible to obtain explicit expressions for the endogenous variables; in those cases, we can use the method based on the di¤erential. 3.5 Terms, study questions, and exercises Terms and concepts Extraction costs, intertemporal arbitrage, trajectory, “monopoly is the conservationist’s friend”, choke price. Study questions For these questions, use the linear inverse demand function, p = 10 y. 1. In the two-period setting, with discount factor < 1, use a …gure to describe the e¤ect of an increase in extraction costs, from C = 0 to C = 2, on the equilibrium price and sales trajectory. Provide the economic explanation for this change. 2. In a two period setting with linear demand and constant average extraction costs C use two …gures to illustrate the equilibrium sales trajectory under competition and under monopoly for the two cases where (a) the discount factor is = 1 and (b) the discount factor is less than 1. Explain the e¤ect of discounting. 3. Answer questions 1 and 2 algebraically, using the equilibrium conditions under competition and monopoly. Exercises 1. Find the …rst order condition to the problem of maximizing monopoly (y) and show that this …rst order condition is identical to equation 3.4. 2. We assumed that the initial stock of the resource is exhausted in two periods, i.e., cumulative extraction equals the initial stock. Continue to assume that the resource has no value after period 1; perhaps the world ends, or perhaps the demand for this resource disappears. (a) Using the demand function p = 20 y and constant extraction costs c = 5, …nd the critical level of the initial stock, xc (a number) such that a competitive equilibrium exhausts the resource if and only if the 58 CHAPTER 3. NONRENEWABLE RESOURCES initial stock, x, satis…es x xc . (b) If x xc , what is true of price in the two periods? (c) Does the critical value depend on ? Does it depend on c? Explain. (d) Now suppose that instead of ending after two period, the model last for three periods. Does this change in assumption alter your answer to part (a)? Explain. (Note: you do not need to …nd the critical value corresponding to the three-period model to answer this question. A bit of economic reasoning is su¢ cient.) 3. Suppose that c = 0 and demand is constant elasticity, p (y) = Ay . (a) Write the equilibrium conditions for the competitive …rm and the monopoly in this case. (b) In order for the monopoly equilibrium condition to be sensible, what restriction must be imposed on ? Provide the economic explanation for this restriction. (c) Compare the level of …rst period sales under competition and under monopoly. 4. The …rst approach to comparative statics (based on the explicit solution < 0 for y as a function of model parameters) demonstrates that dy db (for < 1), and the second approach (based on the di¤erential of the equilibrium condition) demonstrates that dy < 0 if and only if db y > 1+ x. Based on these two (correct) results, what must be true about the relation between y and x for the two results to be mutually consistent? 5. Consider the two-period model with inverse demand p = a bq, constant average extraction cost c, initial stock x, and discount factor . Period 0 extraction is y, the endogenous variable. Suppose that in the competitive equilibrium extraction is positive in both periods, and all of the resource is used. Using the equilibrium condition for the competitive …rm and the “general approach” to comparative statics (i.e., not relying on …nding an explicit solution to the equilibrium value), . …nd dy dc 6. In the text we assumed that extraction is positive in both periods. Using the demand and cost assumptions in the example in Chapter 3.1, …nd the critical discount factor, denoted , such that second period sales in the competitive equilibrium are 0 if < . Provide the economic intuition. 7. Consider the inverse demand function p = y , where 0 < < 1. Marginal extraction costs are constant, at c, and the initial stock is x. (a) 3.5. TERMS, STUDY QUESTIONS, AND EXERCISES 59 What is the interpretation of ? (b) Write the equilibrium conditions for the competitive industry and for the monopoly. (c) Find the comparative statics expression for ddy in the monopoly market. resources. 60 CHAPTER 3. NONRENEWABLE RESOURCES Chapter 4 Additional tools Objectives Work with a general (stock-dependent) cost function; use the “perturbation method” to obtain equilibrium conditions; and express these conditions using “rent”. Information and skills Understand the rationale for using a stock-dependent extraction cost function, and be able to work with a particular cost function. Write down a …rm’s objective function and constraints. Derive and interpret the optimality condition to this problem, for the two cases where the resource constraint is binding or is not binding. Understand the logic of the perturbation method, and apply it in the two-period setting. Understand the meaning of “rent” in the resource setting, and use it to express the optimality (equilibrium) condition. Understand the relation between rent in period 0 and in period 1. We build on the previous chapter, introducing: (i) a more general cost function, (ii) the “perturbation method”, and (iii) the concept of rent. The constant-average-cost model in Chapter 3 provides intuition, but obscures 61 62 CHAPTER 4. ADDITIONAL TOOLS important features of many resource settings. A more general cost function captures these features. By dealing with this generalization at the outset, we can present the subsequent material in a uni…ed and concise manner, without repeating the discussion for each important special case. The “perturbation method” provides a quick way to obtain the equilibrium condition in resource models. The idea behind this method, if not the term, will be familiar to many readers. Imagine the …rm beginning with a “candidate” for an optimal plan, e.g. selling 53% in period 0 and 47% in period 1. The …rm can test whether this candidate is optimal by “perturbing”it, moving a small (in…nitesimal) amount of sales from one period to the other. If this perturbation increases the …rm’s present discounted value of pro…ts, the original candidate was not optimal. It the perturbation decreases the …rm’s pro…ts, then using the “opposite” perturbation, e.g. moving sales from period 0 to period 1, instead of from period 1 to period 0, would increase pro…ts. Thus, if the perturbation either increases or decreases pro…ts, the candidate is not optimal. In order for the candidate to be optimal, an in…nitesimal perturbation must have “zero …rst order e¤ect” on the payo¤. This statement means that the derivative of the payo¤, with respect to the perturbation, evaluated at a zero perturbation, is zero. We also discuss the concept of rent in a resource setting. Although “rent” is a common word, it has a particular meaning in economics, and a still more particular meaning in resource economics. It provides a convenient way to express the equilibrium conditions. This chapter considers the competitive equilibrium. We obtain the equilibrium condition for the monopoly using the competitive equilibrium condition, merely replacing “price”with “marginal revenue”. 4.1 A more general cost function Objectives and skills Understand the reasons for allowing average extraction costs to depend on the stock and the extraction level. Understand the relation between parameter values and the characteristics of cost for an example. The distinction between stock and ‡ow variables is central to resource economics. A stock variable is measured in units of quantity, e.g. billions of 4.1. A MORE GENERAL COST FUNCTION 63 barrels of oil, or tons of coal, or number of …sh, gigatons of carbon. The units of measurement do not depend on units of time. The number of tons of coal might, of course, change over time, but the statement that we have x tons of coal today does not depend on whether we measure time in months or years. In contrast, the units of measurement of ‡ow variables do depend on units of time. For example, the statement “This well produces 1000 barrels of oil”is meaningless unless we know whether it produces this number of barrels per hour, day, or week. The variable xt denotes the stock of a resource, with the subscript identifying time, or the period number. The variable yt is a ‡ow variable, denoting extraction during a period. Thus, if a period lasts for one year, and are quantity units are tons, then xt is in units of tons and and yt is in units of tons per year. The constant average cost function used in Chapter 3 has two restrictive assumptions: (i) Marginal extraction costs do not depend on the size of the remaining resource stock, and (ii) Marginal extraction costs do not depend on the rate of extraction. In reality, marginal (and average) extraction costs typically increase as the size of the remaining stock falls. This relation likely holds at both the level of the individual mine or well, and at the economy-wide level. For example, at the individual level, shallow and relatively inexpensive wells are adequate to extract oil or water when the stock of oil in a …eld or water in an aquifer is high. As the stocks diminish, it becomes necessary to dig deeper and more expensive wells to continue extraction. At the economy-wide level, di¤erent deposits have di¤erent extraction costs. Because it is (generally) e¢ cient to extract from the cheaper deposits …rst, extraction costs increase as the size of the remaining economy-wide stock falls. People began mining coal from seams that lay close to the ground; early oil deposits could be scooped up with little e¤ort. As society exhausted these cheap deposits, it became economical to remove mountaintops to obtain coal and to exploit deep-water deposits to extract oil. In these cases, extraction costs rose as the remaining economy-wide supply of the resource declined. The assumption that the rate of extraction does not a¤ect average and marginal cost implies, for example, that total extraction costs double in a period if we double the amount extracted. In many circumstances, average and marginal costs increase with the rate of extraction. It is important not to confuse stock-dependent extraction costs with increasing average and marginal costs. The former causes average or marginal costs to rise over time, as the stock falls; the latter causes higher extraction 64 CHAPTER 4. ADDITIONAL TOOLS within a period to increase these costs. Average and marginal extraction costs might increase as the stock falls, or as extraction increases, or for both reasons. These two types of cost-related considerations are distinct. To accommodate both of these features, we need a cost function of the form c (x; y), with the following characteristics h i c(x;y) @ y @ 2 c (x; y) @c (x; y) 0, 0, 0: @x @y @y 2 The …rst inequality states that a higher stock either lowers costs or (in the case of equality) leaves them unchanged. The second states that higher extraction either increases average costs or leaves them unchanged. The third states that higher extraction either increases marginal costs or leaves them unchanged. A parametric example helps to make this cost function more concrete: y 1+ ; Parametric example: c (x; y) = C ( + x) (4.1) where C; ; ; and are non-negative parameters. Table 1 shows the relation between parameter values and marginal costs. parameter values C=0 C > 0; >0 and > 0 C > 0; = 0 and = 0 C > 0; = 0; and > 0 C > 0; > 0; and = 0 cost function 0 C (x + ) y 1+ marginal cost 0 C (1 + )(x + ) Cy C Cy 1+ C (1 + ) y C (x + ) y C (x + ) y marginal extraction costs are: zero increasing in extraction, decreasing in stock independent of both extraction and stock increasing in extraction, independent of stock independent of extraction, decreasing in the stock Table 4.1: Relation between parameter values and marginal extraction costs If the stock is zero, it is not possible to extract anything: extraction costs are in…nite if the stock is zero. For = = 0, c (x; y) = Cy for x > 0 and c (x; y) = 1 if y > 0 and x = 0. We adopt the common usage, referring the cost function Cy as stock-independent; in fact, this cost function is stockindependent only for x > 0. 4.2. THE PERTURBATION METHOD 4.2 65 The perturbation method Objectives and skills Write down the …rm’s objectives and constraints, based on a statement of the problem. Write down and interpret the …rst order condition (= optimality condition) for this problem, both in the case where the resource constraint is binding and where it is not binding (= “slack”). Implement two ways of obtaining the optimality condition: (i) eliminating the constraint by substitution, and (ii) using the perturbation method. Given demand and cost functions and all parameters of the model, solve for the equilibrium. This section uses two approaches to derive the necessary condition for optimality (the “equilibrium condition”) in the two-period competitive market. The …rst approach begins by (i) substituting in the constraint, (ii) then taking the derivative of the present discounted value of pro…ts, with respect to period-0 sales, and (iii) …nally, replacing the price in each period (which the …rm takes as exogenous) with the inverse demand function. The resulting …rst order condition is the equilibrium condition for this market. The second approach uses the perturbation method. The perturbation method has no advantages, relative to the more familiar …rst approach, in this simple setting. However, the perturbation method is useful for models with many periods, so we introduce it in the two-peiod setting. The initial stock of the resource, at the beginning of period 0, is x0 . A candidate consists of feasible extraction levels in the two periods, y0 and y1 . These must satisfy the resource constraint and the non-negativity constraints: 0 y0 x0 , 0 y1 x1 = x0 y0 and x1 y1 0: Extraction cannot be negative, and cannot exceed available stock; the available stock in period 1 equals the initial stock minus the amount that was extracted in period 0. The …nal inequality states that the ending stock, 66 CHAPTER 4. ADDITIONAL TOOLS after period-1 extraction, must be non-negative. If extraction is positive in both periods, and all of the resource is used, the constraints imply y0 . y1 = x1 = x0 (4.2) Even in this two-period setting, there are some circumstances where it is not optimal to use all of the resource; in that case, we have y1 < x1 instead of y1 = x1 . We consider these two cases separately. We present the equilibrium for competitive …rms. As discussed in Chapters 2 and 3, we can obtain the equilibrium condition for the monopoly, merely by replacing price in each period with marginal revenue in that period. 4.2.1 It is optimal to use all of the resource In this section, we assume that in equilibrium y1 = x1 , i.e. the resource constraint is binding. The present discounted value of total pro…t for the price-taking …rm is p0 y 0 c (x0 ; y0 ) + [p1 y1 (4.3) c (x1 ; y1 )] : Eliminating the constraint by substitution Probably the most natural way to obtain the equilibrium condition for this model is to substitute the constraints 4.2 into the objective, to write the present discounted value of pro…ts as (y0 ) = p0 y0 c (x0 ; y0 ) + [p1 (x0 y0 ) c (x0 The …rst order condition to the problem of maximizing y0 ; x0 y0 )] : (y0 ) is d (y0 ) set = 0: dy0 This …rst order condition implies (Box 4.1 ): 2 @c (x0 ; y0 ) @c (x1 ; y1 ) p0 = 4 p1 @y0 @y1 3 @c (x1 ; y1 ) 5 @x | {z 1 } (4.4) 4.2. THE PERTURBATION METHOD 67 The optimal decision balances the gain from additional extraction in period 0 (the left side of equation 4.4) with the loss from lower extraction and lower stock in period 1 (the right side of the equation). The left side is the familiar “price minus marginal cost”, the increase in period-0 pro…ts from extracting one more unit in that period. The right side is the present value of two terms, the underlined and the “under-bracketed” terms. The underlined term equals price minus marginal cost in period 1, the loss arising from having one less unit to sell. The under-bracketed term is the cost increase due to a reduction in the stock at the beginning of period 1, resulting from the higher period-0 extraction. 1 ;y1 ) = 0; in this special If costs are independent of the stock, then @c(x @x1 case, the under-bracketed term vanishes and equation 4.4 then states that the present value of marginal pro…t is equal in periods 0 and 1. Box 4.1 Derivation of equation 4.4 The …rst order condition for the competitive …rm’s maximization problem is h i d (y0 ) @c(x0 ;y0 ) = p + 0 dy0 @y0 h 1 p1 dy dy0 @c(x1 ;y1 ) dx1 @x1 dy0 @c(x1 ;y1 ) dy1 @y1 dy0 i set = 0: The second square brackets on the right side uses the chain rule. For 1 ;y1 ) picks up example, period-1 costs depend on the period-1 stock; @c(x @x1 this dependence. From the …rst constraint in equation 4.2, the period1 = 1. Similarly, 1 stock depends on period-0 extraction, via dx dy0 dy1 = 1. dy0 We can use these two equalities to write the …rst order condition as d (y0 ) = p0 dy0 @c (x0 ; y0 ) + @y0 p1 + @c (x1 ; y1 ) @c (x1 ; y1 ) set + = 0: @x1 @y1 Rearranging this condition gives equation 4.4. The alternative: perturbation method The approach used above to derive equation 4.4 is straightforward in the twoperiod setting, but becomes cumbersome in the many-period problem. With that problem in mind, we consider the method of perturbation. We begin with a candidate, y0 and y1 , and the associated period-1 stock, x1 = x0 y0 . 68 CHAPTER 4. ADDITIONAL TOOLS The assumption that it is optimal to consume all of the resource, means that any candidate worth considering sets y1 = x1 ; the ending stock is 0. Expression 4.3 shows the payo¤ associated with this candidate. Suppose that we “perturb”this candidate by changing period-0 extraction by a small (positive or negative) amount, ", the “perturbation parameter”. Because, (by assumption) it is optimal to consume all of the resource, a change in period-0 extraction of " requires an o¤setting change in period-1 extraction of ". For example, a perturbation with " < 0 means that we extract a bit less in period 0 and a bit more in period 1. The “gain” from this perturbation equals g ("; y0 ; x1 ; y1 ) = p0 (y0 + ") c (x0 ; y0 + ") (4.5) + [p1 (y1 ") c (x1 "; y1 ")] : For " = 0, g ("; y0 ; x1 ; y1 ) equals the payo¤ under the candidate, shown in expression 4.3 If the candidate is optimal, then a perturbation causes zero …rst order change to the payo¤. This statement means that at an optimum, it must be the case that dg ("; y0 ; x1 ; y1 ) = 0: d" j"=0 (4.6) Evaluating this derivative (Box 4.2 )produces the same …rst order condition that we obtained above, equation 4.4. The perturbation method is a di¤erent route to the same goal. 4.2. THE PERTURBATION METHOD 69 Box 4.2 Evaluating derivative in equation 4.6. Here we are interested in the e¤ect on the payo¤ of changing ", given the candidate y0 ; x1 ; y1 . The period-1 cost function, c (x1 "; y1 "), involves " in two places, so we need to take the total derivative to evaluate the e¤ect of " on this function. To evaluate this derivative, we use the fact that d (x1 ") d (y1 ") = = d" d" 1: Using the chain rule and these equalities, the total derivative of period1 costs, with respect to ", evaluated at " = 0 is: dc (x1 "; y1 d" ") = j"=0 @c (x1 ; y1 ) @c (x1 ; y1 ) + @x1 @y1 : Using this result, we have dg(";y0 ;x1 ;y1 ) d" j"=0 p0 @c(x0 ;y0 ) @y0 h p1 = @c(x1 ;y1 ) @x1 + @c(x1 ;y1 ) @y1 i : Setting this derivative equal to 0 and rearranging, yields the …rst order condition 4.4. 4.2.2 It is optimal to leave some of the resource behind Depending on the relation between demand and costs, it might not pay to extract all of the resource. Here we consider the situation where, in equilibrium, y1 < x1 : it is optimal to not exhaust the resource. In this case, the resource constraint is “slack”instead of “binding”. If exhausting the resource in period 1 would cause the …rm’s marginal pro…t to become negative, then the …rm chooses not exhaust the resource. The …rm’s period-1 pro…ts equal p1 y1 c (x1 ; y1 ), so its marginal pro…t, price minus marginal cost, is @c (x1 ; y1 ) p1 : @y1 The …rm wants to continue extracting as long as marginal pro…t is positive, but it never extracts to the level that causes marginal pro…t to be negative. If the …rm does not want to exhaust the stock (set y1 = x1 ) then it must 70 CHAPTER 4. ADDITIONAL TOOLS be because doing so would drive marginal pro…ts negative, i.e. it must be the case that @c (x1 ; y1 ) p1 < 0, @y1 jy1 =x1 If this inequality holds, then the …rm extracts up to the point where period-1 marginal pro…t is 0: @c (x1 ; y1 ) = 0. (4.7) p1 @y1 If this equality holds, then an argument similar to that which produces equation 4.4 yields the optimality condition. p0 @c (x0 ; y0 ) = @y0 @c (x1 ; y1 ) : @x1 (4.8) Note that substituting equation 4.7 into equation 4.4 produces equation 4.8. Thus, the situation where the resource constraint is slack is a special case of the situation where the constraint is binding. 4.2.3 Solving for the equilibrium Thus far, we have written the …rm’s equilibrium condition in terms of the prices in the two periods. Firms take these prices as exogenous, but they are determined by equilibrium behavior. (Prices are “endogenous to the model” – not to the …rm.) Given speci…c demand and cost functions, we have enough information to actually solve for the equilibrium. For example, suppose that demand is linear, p = a by, and cost is given by equation 4.1. We can replace p0 and p1 in equation 4.4 with a by0 and a by1 , so equation 4.4 now involves the three unknowns, y0 , y1 , and x1 . We have to consider two cases. If the resource is exhausted, then the …rst order condition, equation 4.4, and the two constraints y1 = x0 y0 = x1 comprise three equations in the three unknowns. We can (in principle) solve these three equations to …nd a candidate. We then have to check to see whether the solution is actually a competitive equilibrium. If price minus marginal costs is greater than or equal to 0 in both periods, then we have the correct solution. However, if price minus marginal cost is negative in either period, the solution to the three equations is not actually an equilibrium. Instead, it must be optimal not to exhaust the resource, y1 < x1 . 4.3. RENT 71 If we have found that it is optimal to not exhaust the resource, then we use equations 4.7 and 4.8, together with the de…nition x1 = x0 y0 to 1 ;y1 ) …nd the three unknowns, y0 , y1 , and x1 . By assumption, @c(x 0, @x1 so any solution to equation 4.8 implies that period-0 price minus marginal cost is non-negative (typically, positive). Thus, we obtain the competitive equilibrium when the resource is not exhausted. 4.3 Rent Objectives and skills Know the meaning of rent and write the optimality condition using rent. Understand the relation between rent in the two periods. Understand that period-0 rent depends on whether the resource is exhausted, and on whether extraction costs depend on the stock. In economics, “rent”is the payment to a factor of production that exceeds the amount necessary to make that factor available. The classic example is rent to unimproved land, used in production. Because the land is in limited supply, it receives a payment. The payment is not needed in order to create the land –it already exists, regardless of the payment. However, the limited supply means that other potential users are willing to bid for the land; the highest value use determines the rent in a competitive market. In the resource setting, the limited initial stock, x0 , gives rise to resource rent. Very little productive land is “unimproved”. Usually, a previous investment increased the land’s productivity by, for example, removing trees and rocks. Once these improvements have been made, they are sunk. Nevertheless, they receive a payment for the same reason that the unimproved land does: their limited supply. The payment occurs after the sunk investment, and the improvements continue to exist regardless of whether the payment is actually made. Because the actual payments are not necessary for the continued existence of the improvements, they resemble rent. However, the improvements were made with the anticipation of the payments, so the payments are not precisely rent. For this reason, payments resulting from a sunk investment are known as “quasi-rent”. 72 CHAPTER 4. ADDITIONAL TOOLS Most natural resource stocks become available only after signi…cant investments in exploration and development. Thus, the payments in excess of extraction costs, arising from the sale of resources, are the sum of rents and quasi-rents. For the most part (until Chapter 12) we ignore this distinction, and refer the resource rent merely as “rent”. In competitive markets (resource) rent is de…ned as the di¤erence between price and marginal extraction costs. Denoting rent in period t as Rt , we have R0 = p0 @c (x0 ; y0 ) and R1 = p1 @y0 @c (x1 ; y1 ) : @y1 We can use this de…nition to write the optimality conditions in the two cases where the resource is exhausted or is not exhausted, using a single equation. If the resource is exhausted, then R1 0; except for knife-edge cases, the inequality is strict. If the resource is not exhausted, then R1 = 0; see equation 4.7 and the de…nition of R1 . We can write the equilibrium conditions 4.4 and 4.8 as @c (x1 ; y1 ) : (4.9) R0 = R1 @x1 Equation 4.9 states that period-0 rent equals the present value of the sum of two terms: period-1 rent, plus the cost reduction due to having higher period-1 stock. Either of the terms on the right side could be zero or positive (but never negative). These two terms capture the two reasons that period-0 rent is (typically) positive: 1. We will run out of the resource. Extracting one more unit today means that we have one less unit to extract in the future. That extra unit of potential future extraction is valuable if and only if R1 > 0. If, instead, R1 = 0, then we will not run out of the resource, thus eliminating one of the reasons that period-0 rent is positive. 2. Extraction of an extra unit today makes future extraction more expensive. For example, we will have to start extracting from a more 1 ;y1 ) = 0 (extraction expensive mine in the future. If, however @c(x @x1 cost does not depend on stock) this reason for positive period-0 rent also vanishes. Under monopoly, we de…ne rent as marginal revenue (instead of price) minus marginal cost. With this modi…cation, equation 4.9 gives the monopoly equilibrium condition. 4.3. RENT 4.3.1 73 Examples To examine the two components of rent, we specialize our parametric cost function, equation 4.1, setting = 0 to obtain C ( + x) y. For given x, this function has constant average and marginal extraction costs C ( + x) . An increase in stock changes costs by @C ( + x) @x y = this relation holds with equality if C ( + x) 1 y 0; = 0 and with inequality if > 0. Stock-independent costs We begin with the simplest case, = 0, where extraction costs do not depend on the stock. Here, equation 4.9 simpli…es to R0 = R1 : the present value of rent is the same in both periods. If it is optimal to consume all of the resource then R1 > 0. If it is optimal to not exhaust the resource, then we have seen that R1 = 0; using R0 = R1 we conclude that in this case, period-0 rent is also zero. Figure 4.1 illustrates these two possibilities, using C = 4, = 0:77 and x0 = 10. (Review the discussion of Figure 3.1 if the meaning of Figure 4.1 is unclear.) The solid lines in this …gure show price minus marginal cost with high demand (p = 20 y) and the dashed lines show price minus marginal cost with low demand (p = 7 y). The high-demand (solid) lines intersect at y0 = 6:4, where rent (R0 = p0 4) is positive, at 9.6. Period-0 extraction is 6.4 and period-1 extraction is 3.6. The resource is exhausted in the competitive equilibrium. The low-demand (dashed) lines intersect below the y (horizontal) axis. This point of intersection corresponds to p0 4 < 0. A competitive …rm does not lose money on sales, so extraction would stop where 7 y 4 = 0, i.e. at y = 3. In this equilibrium, rent is 0 in both periods. The condition R0 = R1 still holds, because 0 = 0. This example illustrates the fact: 1 ;y1 ) = 0 (as it is in our example with = 0), then the If @c(x @x1 only source of rent is the fact that cumulative supply is limited. Rent is positive in this case if and only if the resource constraint is binding, i.e. if competitive …rms extract all of the …xed supply over the life of the program (here, two periods). 74 CHAPTER 4. ADDITIONAL TOOLS $ 18 16 14 12 10 8 6 4 2 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 -2 12 y Figure 4.1: With demand p = 20 y (solid lines), the resource is exhausted. With demand p = 7 y, the resource is not exhausted. Stock-dependent costs We now consider the case where > 0, so extraction costs depend on the stock. In this situation, the second term on the right side of equation 4.9 is positive, so …rst period rent is also positive. We use this example to illustrate the possibility that: With stock-dependent extraction costs: (i) period-0 rent is positive even if the resource constraint is not binding, and (ii) period-0 sales might be either greater or less than period-1 sales. In order to illustrate claim (i), we choose parameter values so that the resource constraint is not binding; therefore, period-1 rent is zero. For this example, C = 7, = 0, = 0:77, x0 = 10; = 0:1 and the inverse demand is p = 10 y. Here, the cost function is Cx y. If y0 is extracted in period 0, then period-1 costs are C (10 y0 ) y1 . The assumption that period-1 rent is 0 implies R1 = 10 y1 7 (10 y0 ) = 0 ) y1 = 10 7 (10 y0 ) : (4.10) Using this relation and the optimality condition, some calculation (Box 4.3) shows that period-0 extraction is y0 = 4:12, period-1 extraction is y1 = 4:14, and aggregate extraction equals 8: 26 < 10. It is optimal to leave 10 8:26 = 1: 74 units of resource in the ground. 4.4. SUMMARY 75 Box 4.3 Finding extraction levels. Using R1 = 0 and equations 4.9 and 4.10, we obtain the equilibrium condition R0 = 10 y0 7 (10) 0 + C (10 = y0 ) 0 + C (10 1 10 7 (10 y0 ) 1 y1 = y0 ) The de…nition of rent gives the …rst equality. The second equality is the equilibrium condition: period-0 rent equals the present value of period-1 rent (here equal to 0), plus the added cost due @c(x1 ;y1 ) to the diminished second period stock, (here equal to @x1 1 y1 ). The third equality uses equation 4.10. It C (10 y0 ) can be con…rmed (numerically) that the solution to this equation is y0 = 4:12, where rent is R0 = 0:318. The stock available at the beginning of period 1 is 10 4:12 = 5: 88, so the average (= marginal) extraction cost in the second period is 7 (10 y0 ) = 7 (5: 88) = 5:86. With these extraction costs, period-1 rent is R1 = 10 y1 5:86. It is optimal to extract up to the point where period-1 rent is 0, which implies y1 = 4:14. Aggregate extraction is 4:12 + 4:14 = The statements “rent is zero in period 1” and “the resource is not exhausted”are equivalent: one statement is true if and only if the other statement is also true. With stock-dependent extraction costs, period-0 rent is positive even if period-1 rent is zero, simply because higher period-0 extraction increases period-1 costs. The …rm extracts less in period 0 than the level that equates price and marginal costs, in order to reduce next-period costs. In this example (but not in general), period-1 extraction is greater than period-0 extraction, so the equilibrium period-1 price is lower than the equilibrium period-0 price. 4.4 Summary Extraction costs may depend on the remaining resource stock, and the marginal extraction costs might increase with the level of extraction (the “extraction rate”). We introduced a parametric cost function that has these features. We used both the method of substitution and the perturbation method to obtain the necessary condition for optimality in a two-period nonrenewable resource problem. 76 CHAPTER 4. ADDITIONAL TOOLS If demand is low relative to extraction costs, it might be optimal not to exhaust the resource. We therefore have to consider the possibility that the resource is exhausted, and also the possibility that some resource remains after period t = 1 (the second and last period). If the resource is exhausted, then the resource constraint means that extraction of an additional unit at t = 0 requires an o¤setting reduction in extraction at t = 1. If the resource constraint is slack, it is not necessary to make this o¤setting change at t = 1. In the resource setting with competitive …rms, rent is de…ned as price minus marginal cost. Under monopoly, rent is de…ned as marginal revenue minus marginal cost. Recognizing this di¤erence in the de…nition of rent under a competitive …rm and under a monopoly, we can express the optimality condition for both markets in the same manner: Rent in period 0 equals the present value of the rent in period 1 plus the cost increase due to a marginal reduction in period-1 stock. In mathematical notation, this condition is R0 = R1 @c (x1 ; y1 ) @x1 : The …rm never extracts where rent is negative; rent is either strictly positive or it is zero. We can use this fact, together with the optimality condition, to solve for the equilibrium, given speci…c functional forms and parameter values for costs and demand. To do this, we …rst solve the problem under the assumption that the resource is exhausted in two periods. That assumption implies y1 = x1 = x0 y0 . These two equations, plus the optimality condition, comprise three equations in the three unknowns, y0 , x1 , and y1 . If, at the solution to these three equations, rent is nonnegative in both periods, we have the solution. If rent in either period is negative, then this proposed solution is incorrect, and it must be the case that y1 < x1 , i.e. the resource is not exhausted. In that case, period-1 rent is 0, and we have R0 = @c (x1 ; y1 ) @x1 and R1 = 0: These two equations, together with the de…nition x1 = x0 equations that we solve to obtain the three unknowns. y0 , give the three 4.5. TERMS, STUDY QUESTIONS, AND EXERCISES 77 When costs depend on the resource stock, we saw by example that there are di¤erent possibilities for the trajectory of extraction and price. In the “usual” case, or at least the one that we emphasize, extraction falls and price rises over time (from period 0 to period 1). But it is also possible that period-1 sales are higher (and the price lower) than in period 0. 4.5 Terms, study questions, and exercises Terms and concepts Binding constraint, slack constraint, stock-dependent and stock-independent costs, perturbation, rent, quasi-rent. Study questions 1. Given an inverse demand function p(y), an extraction cost function c (x; y), a discount factor , and an initial stock x0 : (i) Write down the competitive …rm’s objective (= payo¤) and constraints for the twoperiod problem. (ii) What assumption does this …rm make regarding price in the two periods? (iii) Write down and interpret the optimality condition (= …rst order condition) for the …rm. (Explain what the various terms in the equation mean.) (iv) Write down the de…nition of rent, and then restate the optimality condition in terms of rent in the two periods. 2. (i) In this two-period problem, what does it mean to say that the resource constraint is not binding? (ii) If the resource constraint is not binding, what is the value of period-1 rent? (iii) If the resource constraint is not binding, what is the value of period-0 rent? (iv) What does your answer to part (iii) tell you about the components of period0 rent? (In answering parts iii and iv of this question you need to discuss the two situations where extraction costs are independent of, or depend on, the stock.) 3. Using the objective (= payo¤) for the …rm in question 1, and the assumption that the resource constraint is binding, describe how you can derive the optimality condition, …rst by eliminating the constraint, and second by the perturbation method. It is not necessary to take derivatives or do any calculation; just describe the steps. 78 CHAPTER 4. ADDITIONAL TOOLS 2 cost functions cost 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0.0 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 y 1 1:pdf Figure 4.2: Graphs of two cost functions, as functions of extraction, y, for …xed stock, x. 4. Using the information provided in Chapter 2.4 and the competitive optimality condition, equation 4.4, write down and interpret the monopoly’s optimality condition. Exercises 1. This chapter considers only the competitive equilibrium. (a) For a general inverse demand function, and the parametric cost function, write down the monopoly’s optimization problem in the two-period setting. (b) Under the assumption that the monopoly exhausts the resource, write down the equilibrium condition for the monopoly. (Hint: Review Chapter 2.4, especially the last subsection. (c) Say in words (“interpret”) this equilibrium condition. 2. Figure 4.2 graphs two cost functions of the form C ( + x) y 1+ , with C > 0 and > 0. (a) What can you conclude from these graphs about the parameter in these two functions? (b) What can you conclude about ? Explain the basis for your answers. 3. (a) For the parametric cost function c (x; y) = C ( + x) mine the four partial derivatives: @c (x; y) @c (x; y) @c (x; y) @c (x; y) , , , . @C @ @ @ y +1 , deter- 4.5. TERMS, STUDY QUESTIONS, AND EXERCISES 79 (You may want to consult Appendix A to review a particular rule of derivatives.) (b) Say in words what each of these partial derivatives mean. (This is a one-liner.) 4. Replace the general cost function used in the …rst order condition equation 4.4 with the parametric example given in equation 4.1. Next, rewrite the equation, specializing by setting = 0. Explain in words the meaning of this equation. 5. Section 4.2.2 claims that the …rm never extracts to a level at which marginal pro…t is negative. Explain, in a way that a non-economist will understand, why this claim is true. 6. In our two-period setting, the gain function when it is optimal to consume all of the resource is g ("; y0 ; x1 ; y1 ) = p0 (y0 + ") c (x0 ; y0 + ")+ [p1 (y1 ") c (x1 "; y1 and the gain function when it is optimal not to consume all of the resource (so that the resource constraint x1 0 is not binding) is g ("; y0 ; x1 ; y1 ) = p0 (y0 + ") c (x0 ; y0 + ") + [p1 y1 c (x1 "; y1 )] : Identify the di¤erence between these two functions, and provide the economic explanation for this di¤erence. 7. (a) With stock-dependent resource costs, explain why period-0 rent is positive even if it is not optimal to exhaust the resource (so that the constraint x1 0 is not binding). (b) Explain why period-1 rent must be zero in this circumstance. (c) In this circumstance, what happens to rent over time (i.e. from period 0 to period 1)? This question has a two-word answer. 8. Under the assumption that the monopoly exhausts the resource in this two-period setting, write down the equilibrium condition for the monopoly that faces inverse demand p = 20 y. 9. (Rent and quasi-rent for agricultural land.) Suppose that there is a …xed stock of unimproved land, L = 10. The value of marginal product of this land per year is 20 q, where q is the amount of land that is rented. (a) What is the equilibrium annual rental rate for land? (b) ")] ; 80 CHAPTER 4. ADDITIONAL TOOLS How much would someone with an annual discount rate of r be willing to pay for this land? Recall equation 2.9. (The price of land is the amount that someone pays to buy the land; the rent is the amount they pay to use it for a period of time, e.g. one year.) (c) Suppose that if the land is improved, its value of marginal product increases by 2, to 22 q. What is the equilibrium annual rental rate if all land is improved? (d) What is the equilibrium price of improved land? (e) Suppose that the cost of this improvement is a one-time expense of 10. Assuming that the improvement (like the land) lasts forever, what is the critical value of r at which the landowner is indi¤erent between leaving (all of) the land in its unimproved state, and improving it? 10. (*) Use the inverse demand function p = 20 y and the cost function Cx y, to write the equilibrium condition for a competitive market in the two-period setting. (i) By using the di¤erential of this equilib0 . rium condition, write down the comparative statics expression for dy d (You have to identify the endogenous and the exogenous variable of interest in this exercise, in order to know the relevant di¤erential.) (ii) 0 . (ii) State in words the Then specialize this expression to …nd dy d j =0 meaning of these expressions, and provide the economic intuition for them. Sources Livernois and Uhler (1987) study the role of extraction costs in nonrenewable resource models. Chermak and Patrick (1995), Ellis and Halvorsen (2002), and Stollery (1983) provide empirical estimates of extraction costs. Chapter 5 The Hotelling model Objectives Interpret and use the optimality condition for the T -period problem. Information and skills Understand the relation between the two-period and the T -period problems, and between their optimality conditions. Write down the objective, the constraints, and the Euler equation for the competitive …rm in the T -period problem. Understand the relation between rent in any two periods, and the role of extraction costs in determining the rent. Explain the relation between price in two adjacent periods. Understand the meaning of the “shadow value”of a resource. Understand the meaning of a Lagrange multiplier in a constrained optimization problem. Understand the relation between the Euler equation and an “asset pricing equation”. Show that …rms exhaust cheaper deposits before beginning to extract from more expensive deposits. 81 82 CHAPTER 5. THE HOTELLING MODEL The intuition developed in the two-period setting survives when the resource can be used an arbitrary number of periods, T 1. The perturbation method produces the optimality condition, known as the Euler equation in general settings, and the Hotelling rule in the resource setting. The de…nition of rent provides a succinct means of expressing this rule, which has a close parallel to an asset pricing equation used in investment models. Rent can be interpreted as the “shadow value”of the resource, the amount that a competitive resource owner would pay for one more unit of the resource in the ground. It can also be interpreted as the opportunity cost of extracting the resource. We use the Hotelling rule to show that it is optimal to exhaust mines with relatively low extraction costs, before beginning to extract from more expensive mines. Most of our examples involve physical exhaustion of the resource; in these cases, extraction continues until there is zero resource stock left. However, if extraction costs increase as the resource stock falls, it may be uneconomical to extract all possible stocks. In that case, the stock is economically but not physically exhausted. Most natural resources have increasing costs, and future physical exhaustion is more likely the exception than the rule. At some point, coal will become more expensive than other energy sources, particularly when one factors in the externality cost associated with climate change; coal deposits are unlikely ever to be exhausted. Keeping the atmospheric temperature change below 2o , considered by some to be the maximum safe threshold, will require leaving over 50% of known fossil fuel stocks below the ground. For most fossil fuel resources, economic exhaustion will occur before physical exhaustion. 5.1 The Euler equation (Hotelling rule) Objectives and skills Write the competitive …rm’s objective and constraints. Write and interpret the necessary condition (the Euler equation) to this problem. Understand how the perturbation method produces this condition. We discuss the necessary condition for a …xed length of the program, T +1, leaving the determination of T to Chapter 7. The competitive …rm wants 5.1. THE EULER EQUATION (HOTELLING RULE) 83 to maximize the present discounted sum of pro…ts, subject to the resource constraint. The …rm’s optimization problem is: max xt+1 = xt PT t t=0 (pt yt c (xt ; yt )) subject to (5.1) yt , with x0 given, xt 0 and yt 0 for all t. The …rst order (necessary) condition for this problem is known as the Euler equation; in the nonrenewable resource setting, it is also called the Hotelling rule. The equation is pt 2 @c (xt ; yt ) = 4pt+1 @yt @c (xt+1 ; y+1 ) @yt+1 3 @c (xt+1 ; yt+1 ) 5 : @xt+1 | {z } (5.2) Compare equations 4.4 (for the two-period problem, where T = 1) and 5.2 (for general T ), shows that the two are identical, except for the time subscripts. Equation 5.2 must hold for t = 0; 1; 2:::T 1, i.e. for all pairs of adjacent periods when extraction is positive. Equations 4.4 and 5.2 have the same interpretation. If the …rm sells one more unit in period t and makes an o¤setting reduction of one unit in period t + 1, it receives a marginal gain in period t and incurs a marginal loss in period t + 1. The marginal gain in period t (the left side of equation 5.2) equals the increased pro…t, price minus marginal cost, due to the one unit increase in sales. The marginal loss in period t + 1 is the sum of the two terms on the right side of equation 5.2. The underlined term equals the reduced pro…t due to reduced sales, price minus marginal cost in period t + 1; the under-bracketed term equals increased cost due to the lower stock in period t + 1. Derivation of equation 5.2 By de…nition, T is the last period during which extraction is positive, so extraction at T + 1 is zero. In the class of problems we consider, extraction is also positive at earlier times: yt > 0 for all t < T . This fact means that we can make small changes (perturbations) in any of the yt ’s, and o¤setting changes in other yt ’s, without violating the non-negativity constraints on 84 CHAPTER 5. THE HOTELLING MODEL extraction, or on the stocks. A perturbation is “admissible” if it does not violate these constraints. Recall that a “candidate” is a series of extraction and stock levels that satisfy the non-negativity constraints. At the optimum, any admissible perturbation of the candidate yields zero …rst order change in the payo¤. In the two-period setting, only “one-step”perturbations, where we make a small change in period-0 extraction and an o¤setting change in period-1 extraction, are possible. In a multiperiod setting, in contrast, in…nitely many types of perturbations are possible. For example, we can reduce extraction by " in period t, make no change in period t + 1, and increase extraction by "=3 in each of the subsequent three periods. To test the optimality of a particular candidate, we have to be sure that no admissible perturbation, however complicated, creates a …rst order change in the payo¤. With in…nitely many possible perturbations, that sounds like a di¢ cult job. However, the task turns out to be simple, because any admissible perturbation, no matter how complicated, can be broken down to a series of “one-step” perturbations (Appendix C). Therefore, we can check whether a candidate is optimal by considering only the one-step perturbations a¤ecting pairs of adjacent periods during which extraction is positive. Let t be any period less than T , so that extraction is positive in periods t and t + 1. Because we are considering one-step perturbations that a¤ect only these two periods, we only have to check that the perturbation has zero …rst order e¤ect on the combined payo¤s during these two periods. The combined payo¤ in these two periods, under the perturbation is g ("; yt ; xt ; yt+1 ) = t [(pt (yt + ") c (xt ; yt + ")) (5.3) + (pt+1 (yt+1 ") c (xt+1 "; yt+1 "))]: This gain function and the gain function from the two-period problem, equation 4.5, are the same, except for the time subscripts (and the fact that t multiplies the right side of equation 5.3). In the two-period setting, we noted that an optimal candidate has to satisfy the …rst order condition 4.6. The necessary condition in the T -period setting is exactly the same, except for the time subscripts: dg ("; yt ; xt+1 ; yt+1 ) = 0: d" j"=0 5.2. RENT AND HOTELLING 85 Evaluating this derivative (repeating the steps that lead to equation 4.4) produces the Euler equation 5.2. 5.2 Rent and Hotelling Skills and objectives Rewrite the Euler equation using the de…nition of rent. Explain the relation between rent in period t and in any other period (not merely the next period). Understand how and why this relation depends on whether extraction cost depends on the stock. Explain the relation between rent (and price) in adjacent periods for the case where average extraction cost is constant, C. Using the de…nition of rent when …rms are competitive, Rt = pt @c (xt ; yt ) ; @yt (5.4) we can write the Euler equation (Hotelling rule) more compactly, as Rt = Rt+1 @c (xt+1 ; yt+1 ) : @xt+1 (5.5) Constant marginal costs If marginal costs are constant (i.e. if c (x; y) = Cy), the Hotelling rule simpli…es to Rt = Rt+1 or pt C = (pt+1 C) : (5.6) The …rst equation states that the present value of rent is the same in any two adjacent periods. A stronger result states that the present value of rent is the same in any two periods where extraction is positive: Rt = j Rt+j : (5.7) The Hotelling rule states that the …rm cannot increase its payo¤ by moving a unit of extraction between adjacent periods, t and t + 1; this is a 86 CHAPTER 5. THE HOTELLING MODEL “no-intertemporal arbitrage condition”. Equation 5.7 is more general: it states that the …rm cannot increase its payo¤ by moving extraction between any two periods where extraction is positive (not merely between any two adjacent periods). The intuition for this relation is that a …rm can sell the marginal unit in period t, invest the marginal pro…t (Rt ) for j periods and obtain the return (1 + r)j Rt ; alternatively, the …rm can delay extraction of this marginal unit until period t + j, at which time it earns Rt+j . If there are no opportunities for intertemporal arbitrage, the …rm must be indi¤erent between these two options, i.e. (1 + r)j Rt = Rt+j ) Rt = 1 Rt+j = (1 + r)j j Rt+j : (5.8) With constant marginal = average extraction cost, rent has a particularly simple interpretation. The value of the mine equals the initial rent times the initial stock: Value of mine = T X t=0 t (pt C) yt = T X t Rt yt = R0 t=0 T X yt = R0 x0 : (5.9) t=0 The …rst equality is a de…nition: the value of the mine equals the present discounted stream of pro…ts from extraction. The second equality uses the de…nition of rent, equation 5.4. The third equality uses equation 5.7 to replace t Rt with P R0 . The fourth equality uses the stock constraint: aggregate extraction ( Tt=0 yt ) equals the initial stock (x0 ). We can determine the rate of change of price or rent by (i) multiplying both sides of the two equations 5.6 by 1 + r, (ii) using = (1 + r) 1 , and (iii) rearranging, to obtain pt+1 pt Rt+1 Rt = r or =r Rt pt rC : pt (5.10) The …rst of these two equations says that rent rises at the rate of interest. , i.e. price rises The second says that price rises the rate of interest minus rC pt at less than the rate of interest if C > 0. For C = 0, the second equation simpli…es to pt+1 pt = r; (5.11) pt which states that in a competitive equilibrium where extraction is costless, price rises at the rate of interest: the competitive …rm is indi¤erent between 5.2. RENT AND HOTELLING 87 selling in any two periods if and only if the present value of the price is the same in the two periods. For C > 0, equilibrium price rises more slowly than the interest rate. In Chapter 3, we noted that constant extraction costs cause the …rm to delay extraction, causing the initial price to be higher, and the later price to be lower than would have been the case for C = 0. Thus, C > 0 reduces p1p0p0 in the two-period setting. Equation 5.11 shows that in the T -period setting, a positive C lowers the rate of change of price at every point in time. Box 5.1 The trade analogy. Chapter 2 uses a two-country trade example. Suppose instead that there are n + 1 countries in a row, labelled 0; 1; 2; ::n, with iceberg costs b between any two countries. In order to move tea from one country to another, it is necessary to move it through the intermediate countries. Initially all of the tea is in Country 0. If tea is sold in two adjacent countries, i and i + 1, then 1 pi+1 (review equation 2.1). If tea spatial arbitrage requires pi = 1+b is sold in countries i and i + j, with j 1, spatial arbitrage requires 1 j i+j pi = 1+b p . This equation is the spatial analog of equation 5.8. Stock dependent extraction costs If costs depend on the resource stock t ;yt ) > 0) the “no intertemporal arbitrage” condition implies that the ( @c(x @xt rent in period t equals the sum of two terms: (i) the present discounted value of rent in a future period t + j (the underlined term on the right side of equation 5.12) and (ii) the present discounted stream of cost savings due to the extra unit of stock in the ground, from the current period, t, until period t + j (the under-bracketed term in this equation): Rt = j Rt+j | j X i=1 i @c (xt+i ; yt+i ) {z @xt+i } : (5.12) If the …rm reduces extraction by one unit in period t and increases extraction by one unit in period t + j, it looses Rt in the current period and gains Rt+j in period t + j. The time-t present value of the additional pro…t at t + j is j Rt+j . The under-bracketed term equals the time-t present value of the cost savings arising from the higher stock between periods t + 1 to t + j. Equation 5.12 shows that current rent depends on rent and extraction costs in future periods. Rent is a “forward-looking variable”, because it depends on prices and costs in the future. 88 CHAPTER 5. THE HOTELLING MODEL Rent can be interpreted as the opportunity cost of extracting the resource: the loss from extracting the marginal unit now rather than at some other time. Current extraction reduces future pro…ts, creating an opportunity cost. t ;yt ) . By rearranging the The standard marginal extraction cost is simply @c(x @yt de…nition of rent, we have pt = @c (xt ; yt ) + Rt : @yt This equation states that in a competitive equilibrium, price equals “full” marginal extraction cost, where “full”means that it includes both the standard marginal cost and the opportunity cost (= rent). 5.3 Lagrange multipliers and shadow prices Objectives and skills Understand the meaning of the “shadow value”of a resource. Know that the perturbation method used above yields the same optimality condition as the Method of Lagrange. Recognize that the Lagrange multiplier can be interpreted as the shadow value of the resource. There does not exist a market that enables a resource owner to buy an additional unit of stock in the ground (“in situ”). If there were such a market, how much would the resource owner be willing to pay for this additional unit? The answer is known as the “shadow price” of the resource; the modi…er “shadow” is a way of recognizing that this market is hypothetical. The shadow price at time t equals the equilibrium rent at that time, Rt . The equality between rent and the shadow value of the resource holds in general, but it is particularly obvious in the case of constant marginal extraction costs. Here, equation 5.9 shows that the value of the mine is R0 x0 . The increase in this value, due to the increase in the stock, x0 , is the rent, R0 . The mine owner would be willing to pay R0 for one more unit of the resource at time 0. We used the perturbation method to obtain the equilibrium condition in the competitive resource market. The method of Lagrange provides 5.4. RESOURCES AND ASSET PRICES 89 an alternative derivation. The …rm’s problem contains the T constraints xt+1 = xt yt for t = 0; 1:::T 1. To each of these constraints we assign a variable knows as the Lagrange multiplier. Having one more unit of the stock “relaxes” the constraint, i.e. makes it less severe. The Lagrange multiplier associated with a particular constraint equals the amount by which a “relaxation”in that constraint would increase the present discounted stream of pro…ts. In the resource setting, the Lagrange multiplier associated with the constraint in a particular period equals the amount that the resource owner would pay for a marginal increase in the stock of the resource in that period: the Lagrange multiplier equals the shadow price of the resource, which equals the rent. If someone o¤ered to sell the competitive owner a unit of the stock in situ at time t, the owner would be willing to pay exactly Rt (= the rent = the shadow value = the Lagrange multiplier) for that unit. This claim is not self-evident, because it might seem that an owner who receives one more unit of the resource would not simply extract that unit in the current period, and thus earn Rt . Instead, the owner could extract some of the extra unit in the current period, and some of it later. With that reasoning, it appears that the amount the owner would pay for the marginal unit might di¤er from Rt . This conjecture is false because of the no-intertemporal-arbitrage condition: the owner has no desire to reallocate extraction over time. An owner who acquires one extra unit is indi¤erent between extracting it now, and earning Rt , or extracting it later. In either case, the present value of the owner’s additional pro…t is Rt . The owner would therefore pay Rt for a marginal unit of the resource in situ. 5.4 Resources and asset prices Objectives and skills Understand the relation between the basic asset pricing equation and the Hotelling rule. Competitive equilibria eliminate opportunities for intertemporal arbitrage, both for natural resources and for other types of assets such as shares in companies. To illustrate that intertemporal arbitrage is important in many disparate contexts, we discuss the relation between the Hotelling rule and an asset pricing equation from …nancial economics. 90 CHAPTER 5. THE HOTELLING MODEL By multiplying both sides of equation 5.5 by the result, we can write the Hotelling rule as rRt = Rt+1 Rt 1 = 1 + r and rearranging @c (xt+1 ; yt+1 ) : @xt+1 (5.13) Now consider the equilibrium price of an asset such as shares in a company. There is no risk in our model, and a person can borrow a dollar for one year at the interest rate r. In this perfect information world, people know that next period, t + 1, the price of the asset will be Pt+1 , and they know that there will be a dividend on the stock of Dt+1 . What is the equilibrium price of this asset today, in period t? If the price of the stock at the beginning of period t is Pt , a person who can borrow at annual rate r can borrow Pt at the beginning of the period and buy a unit of the stock. They must repay (1 + r) Pt at the beginning of the next period. If they collect the dividend paid at the beginning of period t + 1, and sell the stock, they collect Pt+1 + Dt+1 . Because the person has not used their own money to carry out this transaction (and thus incurred no opportunity cost), they must make 0 pro…ts, which implies Pt+1 + Dt+1 revenue Rearranging this equality gives: rPt = Pt+1 (1 + r) Pt = 0: | {z } costs Pt + Dt+1 : (5.14) Equation 5.14 is a no-arbitrage condition: it means that a person cannot make money merely by making riskless purchases and sales. The left side is the yearly cost of borrowing enough money to buy one unit of the stock. The right side is the sum of capital gains (the change in the price) and the dividend. If, contrary to equation 5.14, we had rPt < (Pt+1 Pt ) + Dt+1 , then people can make money by borrowing at the riskless rate, buying the asset and then selling it after a year. Here, the asset is too cheap: there is excess demand for it. If rPt > (Pt+1 Pt ) + Dt+1 , then the asset is too expensive, and no one wants to hold it: there is excess supply. Equilibrium therefore requires that equation 5.14 hold. ;xt+1 ) To compare equations 5.13 and 5.14, recall that @c(yt+1 0, because @x a higher stock decreases or leaves unchanged extraction costs; this term corresponds to the dividend, Dt in equation 5.14. It equals the bene…t that 5.5. THE ORDER OF EXTRACTION OF DEPOSITS 91 the resource owner obtains (here, from lower costs) due to holding the asset. The asset price, P , corresponds to R, the resource rent. In the asset price equation, if the dividend is 0, then the price of the stock must rise at the rate of interest in equilibrium: the capital gain due to the change in the asset price must equal the opportunity cost of holding the stock, rPt . A positive dividend makes investors willing to hold the stock at lower capital gains. The same reasoning explains why, in the resource setting, stock dependent extraction costs cause the equilibrium rent to increase at less than the rate of interest. The stock-dependent extraction costs play the same role in the resource setting as the dividend does in the asset price equation. 5.5 The order of extraction of deposits Objectives and skills Use the Euler equation to demonstrate that it is optimal to exhaust a cheaper deposit before beginning to use a more expensive deposit. We have assumed that there is a single deposit, for which extraction costs can be de…ned using a function, c (x; y). We can think of this model as an approximation of a more realistic situation where there are many di¤erent deposits, having di¤erent extraction costs. In a competitive equilibrium, the cheaper deposits are exhausted before beginning to extract from more expensive deposits. Suppose, for example, that there are three di¤erent deposits, with stock size xa = 3, xb = 7, and xd = 2, having associated constant average (= marginal) extraction costs C a = 4, C b = 5:5, C d = 7. Figure 5.1 shows the average cost function for this example, as a function of remaining stock. The graph is a step function, because the extraction costs are constant while a particular deposit is being mined. Costs jump up once that deposit is exhausted, and it becomes necessary to begin mining a more expensive deposit. If instead of there being only three mines, with signi…cantly di¤erent costs, there were many mines, with only small cost di¤erences between the most similar mines, then the …gure would approach a smooth curve, showing costs decreasing in remaining stock. In order to show that, in a competitive equilibrium, cheaper deposits are exhausted before …rms begin to extract from more expensive deposits, it 92 CHAPTER 5. THE HOTELLING MODEL $7 6 5 4 3 2 1 0 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 x Figure 5.1: Extraction costs as a function of remaining stock, when there are three deposits, with individual stocks 3, 7 and 2, and corresponding constant marginal extraction costs, 4, 5.5., and 7 is su¢ cient to consider the case where there are two mines, with constant extraction costs C a < C b . For the sake of exposition, we assume that one competitive …rm owns the low-cost mine and another …rm owns the high-cost mine. The Euler equation must hold for both …rms. In particular, for any two adjacent periods, t and t + 1, during which a …rm is extracting, equation 5.10 must hold, with C replaced by C a or C b (depending on which …rm is extracting). There might be a single period when extraction from both deposits occurs. For example, during the last period when the low cost …rm extracts, its remaining stock may be insu¢ cient to satisfy demand at the equilibrium price. In this case, there is a single period when both …rms extract a positive amount. Extraction of high-cost deposits begins only after or during the last period when extraction from the low-cost deposit occurs. To verify this claim, consider any two adjacent periods, t and t+1, during which the low-cost …rm is extracting. We need to show that the high-cost …rm does not want to extract in t, the …rst of these two periods. If the high-cost …rm did want to extract in period t, then the claim would not be true, because in that case extraction of high-cost deposits occurs in a period prior to the period when the low-cost deposits are exhausted. Given that the low-cost …rm extracts in both t and t + 1, equation 5.10 implies (pt C a ) = (pt+1 C a) : (5.15) 5.6. MONOPOLY 93 Some manipulations (Box 5.2) produce Cb < pt pt+1 Cb . (5.16) This inequality implies that the high-cost …rm strictly prefers to extract nothing in period t. If this …rm were to extract a unit in period t, it would earn pt C b . It could earn strictly higher present value pro…ts by holding on to this unit and then selling it in period t + 1. Therefore, it is not optimal for the high-cost …rm to sell anything in period t. Box 5.2 Derivation of inequality 5.16. Adding C a of equation 5.15 produces C b = (pt+1 pt C a) + C a C b to both sides C b: Add and subtract C b to the right side of this equation and then simplify the result to obtain Cb = pt Because 1 = r 1+r pt+1 C b + (1 > 0 and C a (1 ) Ca Cb : (5.17) C b < 0, we have ) Ca C b < 0: This inequality and equality 5.17 establish inequality 5.16. 5.6 Monopoly Objectives and skills Use previous results to write down and interpret the optimality condition for the monopoly. We obtain the optimality condition under monopoly by using equation 5.2 and replacing price with marginal revenue, M Rt = pt (1 1= (pt )), where (pt ) is the elasticity of demand evaluated at price pt . The Euler equation for the monopoly is pt 1 h pt+1 1 1 (pt+1 ) 1 (pt ) @c(xt ;yt ) @yt @c(xt+1 ;y+1 ) @yt+1 = @c(xt+1 ;yt+1 ) @xt+1 i (5.18) : 94 CHAPTER 5. THE HOTELLING MODEL For the special case where extraction is costless and the elasticity of demand 1 is constant (inverse demand is p = y , and is a constant), equation 5.18 simpli…es to equation 5.11. In this special case, the monopoly and the competitive industry have the same price and sales path. More generally, the monopoly and competitive outcomes di¤er. If extraction is costless but demand becomes more elastic with higher prices (as occurs for the linear demand function and many others) then monopoly price rises more slowly than the rate of interest. In this situation, the initial monopoly price exceeds the initial competitive price, so monopoly sales are initially lower than competitive sales. Here again, “the monopoly is the conservationist’s friend”. De…ning rent for the monopoly as marginal revenue minus marginal cost (instead of price minus marginal cost, as under competition), we can write the monopoly’s optimality condition as in equation 5.5. The interpretation of this equation is the same as under competition, provided that we keep in mind that the de…nition of rent under monopoly di¤ers from the de…nition under competition. 5.7 Summary The perturbation method is as easy to use for the T -period problem as for the two-period problem. It leads to a necessary condition for optimality (equivalently, an equilibrium condition) that expresses current price and costs as a function of next-period price and costs. This equation is known as the Euler equation; in the resource setting, it is also known as the Hotelling rule. We can express this equilibrium condition in terms of rent. The equilibrium market price and the rent in a period depend on future prices (or rent) and costs. Rent is a forward-looking variable. The Hotelling rule states that rent in an arbitrary period equals the present value of rent in the next period, plus the cost increase due to a marginal reduction in stock. For the special case where extraction costs are independent of the stock, the Hotelling rule states that the present value of rent is equal in any two periods where extraction is positive. If extraction costs are zero, the Hotelling rule states that price rises at the rate of interest. For positive constant average extraction costs, price rises more slowly than the rate of interest. The Hotelling rule has a close analog in investment theory, where the asset pricing equation states that the opportunity cost of buying an asset 5.8. TERMS, STUDY QUESTIONS, AND EXERCISES 95 must equal the capital gains plus the dividend from owning the asset. By re-labelling the resource rent as the asset price, and the cost increase due to a lower stock as the dividend, the Hotelling rule becomes identical to this asset pricing equation. We also discussed the following two points: Rent in a period equals the amount that the resource owner would pay in that period for an extra unit of resource in the ground. Rent equals the shadow price for this hypothetical transaction, which equals the Lagrange multiplier associated with the resource constraint in this period. It is optimal to exhaust cheaper deposits before beginning to use more expensive deposits. We con…rmed this result for the case of mines with di¤erent constant extraction costs. 5.8 Terms, study questions, and exercises Terms and concepts Euler equation, Hotelling rule, asset price, capital gains, dividend, Lagrange multiplier, shadow value, in situ. Study questions 1. (a) For a general inverse demand function p (y) and the parametric cost function in equation 4.1, write down the competitive …rm’s objective and constraints. (b) Write down and interpret the Euler equation for this problem. (c) Without actually performing calculations, describe the steps of the perturbation method used to obtain this necessary condition. 2. (a) What is the de…nition of “rent”in the renewable resource problem for the competitive …rm? (b) Use this de…nition to rewrite the Euler equation for the problem described in question #1. (c) Write down the relation between rent in period t and in period t + j (j 1), and interpret this equation. In particular explain the di¤erence between the case where extraction costs depend on the stock and where extraction cost does not depend on the stock. 96 CHAPTER 5. THE HOTELLING MODEL Exercises 1. Write the Euler equation for a monopoly facing the demand function p = 20 7y with the cost function c (x; y) and discount factor . 2. Con…rm, using a proof by induction, that if extraction costs do not depend on stocks, the present value of rent is the same in any two periods where extraction is positive. (The Euler equation only applies if extraction is positive.) This proof requires that you demonstrate that for any integer j = 0; 1; 2; 3; 4::: Rt = j Rt+j is true. In case this is your …rst inductive proof, here is how to proceed. Step 1. First, show that the claim is true for j = 0. (This is a one-liner.) Step 2. Now consider the hypothesis that the present value of rent is the same in periods t and t + j, for some integer j (as distinct from for all integers). That is, your hypothesis is that Rt = j Rt+j for some integer j. Using the Euler equation, show that if this hypothesis is true, then Rt = j+1 Rt+j for that particular integer j These two steps complete the inductive proof. The idea is that Step 1 shows that the claim (Rt = j Rt+j ) is true for j = 0. Step 2 shows that if the claim is true for j = 0 (which we know is true), then it is also true for j = 1. Invoking step 2 again, it follows if the claim is true for j = 1 (as indeed it is) then it is also true for j = 2..... and so on. 3. Fill in the missing algebraic steps that lead from equation 5.5 to 5.10 when extraction costs are constant. 4. Begin with the Hotelling rule, equation 5.5. condition implies Rt+1 = Rt+2 (a) Explain why this @c (xt+2 ; yt+2 ) @xt+2 (This is a one-liner.) (b) Use this fact to write Rt as a function of Rt+2 and @c(x;y) in periods t + 1 and t + 2. (c) Repeat this step to write Rt @x as a function of Rt+3 and @c(x;y) in periods t + 1, t + 2, and t + 3. (d) @x Generalize your formula to write Rt as a function of Rt+j and @c(x;y) in @x periods t + 1, t + 2, ....to t + j for integers j 1. (To avoid having to t ;yt ) carry around a lot of unnecessary notation, de…ne ht = @c(x . With @xt this de…nition, write Rt as a function of Rt+j and ht in periods t + 1, t + 2, ....to t + j (e) Provide an economic explanation for this formula. 5.8. TERMS, STUDY QUESTIONS, AND EXERCISES 97 5. Suppose that extraction costs are constant, c (x; y) = Cy. (a) How does an increase in C change the equilibrium rate of change of price in a competitive equilibrium? [This is a one-liner if you examine the text carefully.] (b) How does an increase in C a¤ect the initial equilibrium price, p0 , in a competitive equilibrium. [This question calls for intelligent speculation, not algebra.] Sources Hotelling (1931) is the classic paper in the economics of nonrenewable resources. Solow (1974) and Gaudet (2007) provide time-lapse views of the role of the Hotelling model in resource economics. Dasgupta and Heal (1979), Fisher (1981) and Conrad (2010) are three excellent graduate texts covering the nonrenewable resource model. Berck and Helfand (xx), Hartwick and Olewiler (1986), and Tietenberg (2006), provide undergraduate-level treatment of this material. 98 CHAPTER 5. THE HOTELLING MODEL Chapter 6 Empirics and Hotelling Objectives Understand what it means to test the Hotelling model, and the practical di¢ culties of performing such a test. Information and skills Summarize the chief implications of the Hotelling model. Have an overview of historical price patterns for several natural resources. Understand some of the ways that people test the Hotelling model, why data limitations complicate the e¤ort. A theory, like a map, involves a trade-o¤ between realism and tractability. A map of the world that consists of a circle is too abstract to be of any use. A map of the world containing all of the details of the world is equally useless.1 As with maps, economic models should be judged on how useful they are in helping us to understand the world, not how faithfully and completely they describe it. The Hotelling model, the basis of the economics of nonrenewable resources, rests on a fact and an assumption. The fact is that resource stocks 1 Jorge Luis Borges’ (very) short story “On Exactitude in Science" tells the tale of an empire in which cartography becomes so precise that the empire creates a map of its territory on a 1–1 scale. Later generations decided that this achievement was useless as a map, although beggars use scraps of it to cover themselves. 99 100 CHAPTER 6. EMPIRICS AND HOTELLING are …nite, so extraction costs must eventually rise. The assumption is that forward looking resource owners attempt to maximize the present discounted stream of pro…ts. If average cost is constant, the model predicts that price minus this constant rises at the rate of interest. Price data contradict this version of the Hotelling theory. Data limitations make it di¢ cult to test more sophisticated versions of the theory, which describe the evolution of rent (= price minus marginal cost). We can observe price, but it is hard to estimate marginal cost, and therefore di¢ cult to assess whether rent actually evolves in the manner the theory predicts. We are therefore unable to empirically validate the foundation for the …eld of nonrenewable resource economics. Why does it matter whether the theory is empirically (approximately) “true”? Concern about long run sustainability is an important motivation for studying resource economics. Resource-pessimists worry that we will run out of essential resources. Resource-optimists think that prices respond to and impending shortages, causing markets to create alternatives. This optimism rests on the belief that market outcomes are determined by rational pro…t maximizing competitive agents, i.e. that the Hotelling model describes resource markets. If the theory is correct, then the First Fundamental Theorem of Welfare Economics (Chapter 2.6) implies that the competitive equilibrium is e¢ cient. In this case, the fact that nonrenewable natural resources are …nite does not, in itself, create a basis for government intervention. There may, of course, be distinct motivations for intervention, e.g. concerns about equity or market failures, just as arise in many other markets. If, however, nonrenewable resource markets are broadly inconsistent with even sophisticated versions of the Hotelling model, then outcomes in these markets are not e¢ cient, and there is no basis for ascribing any particular welfare properties to them. In particular, the theory provides no basis for resource-optimism. In addition, resource economists use the Hotelling model to think through the consequences of policy changes. For example, it is widely accepted that extracting and using fossil fuels contribute to climate change, a type of market failure. Taxing these fuels or subsidizing alternatives alters market outcomes, potentially changing the market failure. We cannot conduct actual policy experiments, similar to the types of experiments that laboratory scientists perform. We do not have one group of economies that serve as 6.1. HOTELLING AND PRICES 101 the “control group”and another that serve as the “treated group”.2 Therefore, economists use mathematical models, an alternative to bona…de (and infeasible) experiments to assess the likely e¤ect of policy. For applications involving fossil fuels, the Hotelling model is key. By comparing a model outcome in the absence of a policy, and second outcome under a particular policy, we have at least some basis for evaluating that policy. Chapter 9 illustrates this procedure. If the underlying model is fundamentally wrong, then this kind of experiment is not informative. Therefore, the validity of the Hotelling theory is important for practical, not just for academic reasons. Given the uncertain empirical foundation of the Hotelling model, why do resource economists rely so heavily on it? One answer is that we do not have a better alternative.3 Also, the pro…t maximizing assumption of the Hotelling model seems at least as true for natural resources as for other types of capital. If there were a more valuable use of the asset, markets should be able to identify it at least as well as a planner could. It would be absurd to take literally the deterministic Hotelling model, in which agents perfectly forecast future prices. But it is unlikely that resource owners –or owners of other types of capital –ignore the future in deciding how to use their asset. Investors make mistakes, but investors who systematically make mistakes are eventually culled from the herd. 6.1 Hotelling and prices Objectives and skills Have an overview of the time trajectories of prices for major resources. The simplest version of the Hotelling model, with zero extraction costs, implies that price rises at the rate of interest. With constant average extraction cost, C > 0, prices rise more slowly than the rate of interest. 2 To test the e¢ cacy of a new drug, researchers compare the outcome of people who receive the drug (the treated group) with those who receive a placebo (the control group). If we could conduct experiments with economies, the economies subject to the policy of interest would be in the treated group, and those without the policy would be in the control group. Of course this kind of experimentation is not feasible. 3 Alternatives matter. How can you tell if someone is an economist? Ask them how their husband/wife/partner is. An economist will answer “Compared to what?” 102 CHAPTER 6. EMPIRICS AND HOTELLING 250 200 150 100 50 0 00 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 ALUMINUM ALUMINUM_T 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 1880 1900 1920 1940 1960 1980 COPPER COPPER_T 1880 1900 1920 1940 1960 1980 COAL COAL_T 100 25 200 180 160 140 120 100 80 60 80 20 60 15 40 10 20 5 1880 1880 1900 1920 1940 1960 1980 LEAD LEAD_T 1900 1920 1940 1960 IRON IRON_T 200 160 120 80 40 14 12 10 8 6 4 2 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 NICKEL NICKEL_T 90 16 14 12 10 8 6 4 2 0 0 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 GAS GAS_T 1200 1000 800 600 400 200 1880 1900 1920 1940 1960 1980 PETROLEUM PETROLEUM_T 0 1880 1900 1920 1940 1960 1980 SILVER SILVER_T Figure 6.1: Real commodity prices. (Lee, List, and Strazicich, 2005) Figure 6.1 shows the pro…les of real prices (nominal prices adjusted for in‡ation) for nine commodities. The dotted lines show the time trends …tted to this price data. The points of discontinuity in the dotted lines capture abrupt changes in the price trajectory. For most of these commodities there are long periods during which the price falls, and at least one abrupt change the price trajectory. We need only price data to test the Hotelling model under the assumption of constant costs. In light of Figure 6.1, it is not surprising that most research …nds that this version of the Hotelling model is not consistent with observed prices. We therefore consider versions of the model with non-constant costs, and then we consider more fundamental changes to the model or the testing procedure. 6.2 Non-constant costs Objectives and skills Understand why it is di¢ cult to test the Hotelling model with nonconstant marginal extraction costs. 6.3. EXTENDING THE MODEL 103 Lack of data makes it di¢ cult to test the Hotelling model with nonconstant costs. The case where costs depend on extraction level, but not on remaining stocks, illustrates the problem. Here, the Hotelling rule is pt dc (yt ) = dy pt+1 dc (yt+1 ) dy : (6.1) The problem is that we do not observe marginal costs. If we assume that costs equal a + h2 y y, then marginal cost equals a + hy. Given data on prices and sales, we can substitute a + hy for marginal costs into equation 6.1 and estimate the parameters ; a; h. If, for example, the estimate of is implausible, either unreasonably small or large, the researcher concludes that the model does not …t the data. This procedure involves a joint hypothesis: the hypothesis that the no-arbitrage condition, equation 6.1, is a reasonable description of behavior, and the hypothesis that the cost function a + h2 y y is a reasonable description of the actual cost function. If the statistical tests reject our joint hypothesis, we do not know whether the rejection was due to the failure of one or both parts of the hypothesis. If we had good data on costs (in addition to prices and quantities), then we could estimate a ‡exible functional form (e.g. a higher order polynomial) for the cost function, and have a reasonable level of con…dence in the resulting estimate of marginal cost. In that case, we would be closer to testing the single hypothesis that we actually are interested in, the one involving behavior. We rarely have good cost data. Low quality cost data limits many …elds of empirical economics, not just resource economics. A common procedure in other …elds uses a …rm’s optimality condition, together with information about factor prices, to estimate marginal costs. Here, however, the empirical objective is to determine whether the optimality condition, the Hotelling rule, describes …rms’behavior. It is not possible to both assume that the Hotelling rule holds and also to test whether it holds. 6.3 Extending the model Objectives and skills Recognize that extensions of the model lead to a better …t with data, but increased di¢ culty of empirical testing. 104 CHAPTER 6. EMPIRICS AND HOTELLING Understand the use of proxies in estimation. The theory presented in Chapter 5 omits many features of the real world, including: (i) the discovery of new stocks of the resource; (ii) unanticipated changes in demand due, for example, to changing macro-economic conditions or the discovery of alternatives to the resource; (iii) changes in extraction costs due to changes in technology or regulation, (iv) and general uncertainty. The literature on resource economics includes all of these features. We consider the empirical implications of some of these extensions. Stock changes We took the level of the resource stock in the initial period as …xed, and assumed that the stock falls over time, with extraction. In reality, …rms invest in …nding and developing new resource stocks, with uncertain success. The level of risk and …rms’attitude toward risk in‡uence their decisions about extracting known reserves and about investing in the search to …nd undiscovered reserves. The theory presented above ignores the discovery and development of new reserves, and all risk. Some extensions of the Hotelling model recognize that the exploration decision is endogenous. A simpler model takes the exploration decision as given, and treats the timing and the magnitude of new reserves as random variables. Rational …rms would factor this randomness into their extraction decisions. Resource owners understand that large new discoveries create competition for previously existing deposits, lowering the value of those deposits. The new discovery therefore causes the rent on existing deposits to fall; recall that rent equals the “shadow price” of the stock, de…ned as the amount that a …rm would be willing to pay for a marginal unit of the stock. Rent equals price minus marginal cost. Because the discovery has no direct e¤ect on extraction costs of previously existing deposits, the fall in rent implies a fall in price. Thus, in a model with random discoveries, price rises between discoveries, but falls at the time of a large new discovery. In this scenario, the price path is saw-toothed, rising for a time and then falling at the times of new discoveries. 6.3. EXTENDING THE MODEL 105 Box 6.1 Royal Dutch Shell and the Kulluck. Royal Dutch Shell’s experience with Arctic drilling illustrates the complexity of oil exploration. In 2005 Shell announced that it had previously overstated its proven reserves by more than 20%, resulting in an overnight drop of 10% in the value of company. (“Proven reserves”are stocks that are highly likely to exist.) In an e¤ort to increase proven reserves, Shell ramped up its Arctic exploration, buying drilling leases and drilling equipment, including a large rig named the Kulluck. In 2012 it received permission to begin exploration and towed the Kulluck into position. By the end of the year and a $6 billion investment, the Kulluck was destroyed in a storm, without having succeeded in drilling a well. Shell paused its exploration e¤orts in 2013 was set to continue them in 2014. In August 2014 oil was $100/barrel, but it had fallen to $55/barrel by the end of the year. “Unconventional” sources of oil, such as in the Arctic, require a price of about $70/barrel to be economical. Changes in demand Unanticipated changes in demand that are expected to persist for a substantial period of time can also change the price path. For example, the Great Recession beginning in 2008 saw a reduction in aggregate demand, including a reduction in demand for many resources. Unexpectedly strong growth in China from 1990 – 2010 increased demand for natural resources. The discovery of alternatives, e.g. the 18th century replacement of petroleum for whale oil, may also change the demand for a resource. If a change in the economic environment causes …rms to expect that future demand will be weaker than they had previously believed, then they revise downward their estimate of the value of their resource stock. This downward revision in rent requires a reduction in price, just as occurs following discovery of a large new deposit. Thus, over a period when …rms are revising downward their projections of future demand, and thus revising downward their belief about the current value of a marginal unit of the stock, the equilibrium price rises more slowly than the theory predicts, and might even be falling. The deterministic (perfect information, no surprises) model ignores unanticipated changes in demand, although those random events are an important feature of the real world and could explain observed price falls. 106 CHAPTER 6. EMPIRICS AND HOTELLING Cost changes The simple Hotelling model ignores changes in costs, apart from those associated with changes in stock or extraction rates. In fact, the extraction cost function might shift up or down over time. Downward shifts are associated with price rises that are lower than the standard model predicts, or even negative. Upward shifts lead to faster price rises than the model predicts. Technological advances over the last 20 years made horizontal drilling both practical and relatively inexpensive, making it cheaper to extract from current deposits, and possible to develop resource deposits that were previously inaccessible. Other changes, such as stricter environmental or labor rules, increase extraction costs. For example, in projecting extraction costs for new reserves, Royal Dutch Shell in 2014 included a (still nonexistent) carbon tax of $40/Mt C02 , or approximately $17/barrel (using the estimate 0.43 metric tons CO2 /barrel). A higher tax corresponds to a higher cost. Consider a model in which average costs are constant with respect to both extraction rates and stock levels, but falling over time; we replace the constant C with a ; (6.2) C (t) = C0 + 1 + ft where C0 , a, and f are positive. The Euler equation is pt C0 + a 1 + ft = pt+1 C0 + a 1 + f (t + 1) : (6.3) Figure 6.2 shows the graphs of price (solid), rent (dashed), and marginal cost (dotted) under the cost function in equation 6.2.4 Falling costs put downward pressure on the equilibrium price, just as with a standard good. Discounting the future puts upward pressure on the price, just as in the nonrenewable resource model with constant costs, C. Initially, the cost e¤ect is more powerful, so the equilibrium price falls. However, the cost decreases diminish over time, because costs never fall below C0 . Eventually, the e¤ect of discounting becomes more powerful, and the equilibrium price rises, just as in the model with constant C. Rent (price minus marginal 4 This …gure corresponds to the continuous time version of the discrete time Euler equation 6.3. We use the discrete time model in order to derive equations and provide intuition. The graphs of equilibrium outcomes of the discrete time model are step functions. The continuous time analogs are easier to graph, and because they are smooth, also easier to interpret. Figure 6.2 uses a = 30, Co = 10, f = 0:5, and the discount rate r = 0:03. 6.3. EXTENDING THE MODEL $ 107 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 time Figure 6.2: Equilibrium price (solid), rent (dashed) and marginal cost (dotted). cost) rises at the constant rate, r, and marginal costs steadily decline to C0 . Adding frequent small shocks and occasional large discoveries causes the graph in Figure 6.2 to become saw-toothed and bumpy, making it more closely resemble the graphs of actual time series shown in Figure 6.1. General uncertainty A rich literature studies the role of uncertainty about new discoveries, changes in demand and extraction costs, and other features of nonrenewable resource markets. Uncertainty alters the expected time path of rents, and thus of prices, even during periods when a large shock does not occur. Uncertainty complicates the already formidable data problem of testing the deterministic Hotelling model, so researchers use proxies, de…ned as variables that can be observed and which are closely related to the unobserved variable of interest: resource rent. For example, in forestry the “stumpage price”is the price paid to a landowner for the right to harvest timber. Oldgrowth timber is a nonrenewable resource, and the stumpage price of this timber is a good proxy for rent. Researchers using this proxy …nd moderate support for the Hotelling model. The stock price of a mining company is a proxy for the rent associated with the resource that the company mines. Both the observable stock price and the unobservable resource rent are forward-looking variables that re‡ect the expected value of the stream of future pro…ts from owning one more unit 108 CHAPTER 6. EMPIRICS AND HOTELLING of an asset. For rent, the asset consists of the resource. For the company stock, the asset is a composite of the resource, the mining equipment that the company owns, and many other factors, including intangibles such as reputation. These two assets are not exactly the same, so the company stock price is not a perfect measure of the resource rent. However, because the resource is a large part of the company assets, the two are closely related. The 2005 fall in Shell’s stock price following the downward revision in its proven reserves illustrates this relation. (Box 6.1) Chapter 5.4 summarizes a model of the equilibrium change in a company’s stock price under certainty. Under uncertainty, the equilibrium expected change in the stock price depends on the correlation between the price of the company and the price of a diversi…ed portfolio of stocks (a “market portfolio”). If the two are negatively correlated, then the company tends to do well when the market does poorly. In this case, owning stock in the company provides a hedge against market risk. A hedge provides an o¤set to the risk associated with a particular activity, here the investment in the market. Owning stock in this company is valuable partly because it reduces an investor’s risk. This reduction in risk is a bene…t of owning the stock, and in that respect, is analogous to the dividend discussed in Chapter 5.4. This “pseudo-dividend”, much like the real dividend, lowers the expected capital gains needed to make investors willing to hold the mining asset. (Box 6.2) Researchers …nd that the stock price of companies owning copper mines is negatively correlated with the return on a market portfolio. The theory sketched in the previous paragraph implies that this negative correlation lowers the equilibrium rate of increase of the mining company’s stock price. If the observed stock price is a good proxy for the unobserved rent, then evidence that one variable is consistent with theory provides some evidence that the other is as well. Using data on copper mining companies, this research “fails to reject”the Hotelling model.5 In general, the market return might have positive, negative, or zero correlation with resource prices. Therefore, in a Hotelling setting, uncertainty might either increase or decrease the expected change in prices. Resource 5 If a statistical test …nds that a hypothesis is consistent with observations, we say that the test “fails to reject” the hypothesis. We do not say that the test “accepts” the hypothesis, because there are usually many other hypotheses that are also consistent with the observed outcome. It does not make sense to accept all of these mutually exclusive hypotheses. 6.3. EXTENDING THE MODEL 109 prices respond to both supply and demand shocks. A positive demand shock (e.g. unexpectedly high consumer demand) and a negative supply shock (e.g. a disruption in supply due to war or political turmoil) both increase the resource price. These two types of shocks may be associated with di¤erent e¤ects on the market return; the supply shock is likely associated with a low return on the market portfolio, and the demand shock with a high return. In this case, resource prices tend to be positively correlated with the market return if the demand shocks overwhelm the supply shocks, negatively correlated in the opposite case, and uncorrelated if the two types of shocks are approximately equally important. Empirical evidence …nds that oil prices are uncorrelated with the market return, even though oil prices are negatively correlated with future economic growth. Large increases in oil prices preceded most of the post-World War II economic downturns. Box 6.2 The Capital Asset Pricing Model. Consider a world in which people can buy a risk-free asset (e.g. government bonds) that pays a return rf . They can also invest in the stock market that has a risky return, the random variable r~m with expectation E r~m = rm . An investor’s opportunity cost of investing in the stock market is rf (the riskless rate), so their expected reward (the “market premium”) from investing in the stock market is rm rf . The investor can also buy a company that owns and mines a nonrenewable resource, e.g. copper, that has a risky return of r~c and an expected return rc . The “beta” of the mining asset is de…ned as = covariance (~ rm ; r~c ) : variance (~ rm ) Under a number of assumptions, including that all investors are rational and risk averse and have the same information and no borrowing or lending constraints, the Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) shows that the equilibrium expected return to the copper asset must be rc = rf + (rm rf ). This equation states that if the copper asset is negatively correlated with the market (the beta is negative), then investors are willing to purchase the copper asset at an expected return lower than the expected market return. They accept this expected loss because the copper asset provides a hedge against market uncertainty. 110 6.4 CHAPTER 6. EMPIRICS AND HOTELLING Summary Observed prices are not consistent with the deterministic Hotelling model under constant average costs. Adding real-world features, including nonconstant marginal extraction costs, exploration, random shocks to stock, demand or cost, or systematic time-varying changes to costs, can generate simulated price paths that resemble observed price paths. Lack of data makes it di¢ cult to directly test models that incorporate these kinds of realistic features. Because we cannot observe rents, they have to be estimated using estimates of marginal costs. Any empirical test of the Hotelling model using such constructed data thus involves the test of joint hypotheses. One part of the hypothesis concerns the Hotelling model, and the other part involves the estimates of marginal costs. A few studies use proxies, such as stumpage fees for timber or the stock price of companies that mine resources, to indirectly test the Hotelling model. Those indirect tests provide modest support for the Hotelling model. Occam’s razor describes a preference for the simpler of any two models that do equally well in explaining observations. Arguably, a model based on a succession of static equilibria with exogenously changing supply and demand functions is simpler than the resource model based on dynamic optimization. Consider a model of a standard good (not a nonrenewable resource), for which costs initially fall faster than demand increases; subsequently, demand rises faster than costs fall. In addition, the supply and demand functions are both subject to random shocks. That model would also produce a bumpy U-shaped trajectory of prices, simply by equating supply and demand in each period. Thus, we could explain observed price patterns for nonrenewable resources using a model that has nothing to do with nonrenewable resources. However, the static model assumes that …rms simply ignore the future. The deterministic Hotelling model, in which resource owners can exactly predict future prices, is not intended to be taken literally, but provides a starting point for studying forward-looking behavior. The …nite supply and stockdependent extraction costs are the distinguishing features of nonrenewable resources, and are the source of rent. For some resources (perhaps coal), rent arising from scarcity is not important, and rent arising from stock-related extraction costs may or may not be important. For other commodities, such as oil, rent is substantial. Low cost oil can be extracted for less than $20 a barrel. When the price is multiples of that, as it has been for long stretches of time, the di¤erence can be attributed to rent (and sometimes to the exercise 6.5. TERMS, STUDY QUESTIONS AND EXERCISES 111 of market power). The theory of nonrenewable resources studied here applies only to commodities where rent is a major component of market price. Many factors apart from the …nite supply and stock-dependent costs (their distinguishing features) are important in determining equilibria in nonrenewable markets. Non-resource-based commodities share most of those factors, including changes that alter costs or change demand. Often those other factors dominate the distinguishing features of nonrenewable resources, leading to outcomes that are not consistent with the Hotelling theory. What is the point in developing a theory that focuses on the “distinguishing features” of the nonrenewable resources, when for long periods of time other factors are more important in determining market outcomes? The answer is that we want to strike a balance between a “theory of everything” and a description of the particular. A theory of everything includes all of the aspects of the world likely to be important in (at least) a large class of markets, including technological changes, unexpected demand shifts, risk. A theory that includes all of these features would be too complicated to produce insights, or to use for policy analysis. In contrast, a description of the particular would choose a particular nonrenewable resource, or even a particular resource during a particular period of history or a particular geographic area, and study that market in detail. That kind of description would provide limited insight about other resources. 6.5 Terms, study questions and exercises Terms and concepts Real versus nominal prices, joint hypothesis, control group, treated group, maintained hypothesis, proven reserves, proxies, hedge, market portfolio, market return, CAPM, stumpage, Occam’s razor Study questions 1. (a) Describe the simplest version of the Hotelling model’s predictions about change in prices over time. (b) Describe important features of price series for actual nonrenewable resources, and contrast these to the predictions of the simplest Hotelling model. (c) What does it mean to empirically “test” the Hotelling model? Discuss some of the 112 CHAPTER 6. EMPIRICS AND HOTELLING di¢ culties in conducting such a test. (Your answer should develop the idea that there are many versions of the Hotelling model, not just the simplest one. Your answer should also discuss the fact that a test of the Hotelling model is almost certainly a test of a “joint hypothesis”, and explain why this matters.) Exercises 1. (a) Beginning with the equilibrium condition (or de…nition), p (y) @c (x; y) = R; @y what is the relation between a change in R and a change in y? Justify your answer and provide the economic explanation. (b) Based on your answer to part (a), what is the relation between a change in R and a change in p? 2. Derive the Euler equation 6.3. 3. Suppose that average extraction cost is constant, C, and the period t inverse demand function is pt = a a0 + a1 t yt ; where a0 ; a1 ; and a are positive known parameters. (This type of model is called “non-stationary” because there is an exogenous timedependent change –here, a change in the demand function.) (a) State in words what this demand function states in symbols. (b) Consider a competitive …rm facing this demand function. Refer to Chapter 5 to write the Euler equation for this model (no derivation needed). (c) Explain what this equilibrium condition implies about the rate of change in prices. Provide an economic explanation. (d) This problem and the previous one show that nonstationary costs and nonstationary demand have di¤erent e¤ects on the appearance of the Euler equation. Identify this di¤erence, and provide an economic explanation for it. (e) The text discusses the e¤ect, on the evolution of rent, of unanticipated changes in demand. Parts (b) and (c) of this question ask you to consider the e¤ect of anticipated changes in demand. Summarize in a 6.5. TERMS, STUDY QUESTIONS AND EXERCISES 113 sentence of two the di¤erence in the e¤ect, on the evolution of rent, of unanticipated versus anticipated changes in demand. (f) Provide an economic explanation for this di¤erence. 4. Using the parametric example in equation 4.1, discuss the equilibrium price e¤ect of unanticipated cost reductions. To answer this question, you have to consider the various ways in which costs might fall; review your answer to Exercise 2 in Chapter 4. 5. Suppose that the return from investing in the market is a random variable r~m with expectation E r~m = rm and variance 2m ; the return from investing in a copper mining company is a random variable r~c and an expected return rc and variance 2c . The correlation coe¢ cient between the two assets is < 0. A person buys one unit of stock in the market and a units in the copper company. The return on this portfolio is the random variable rm + arc . (a) What is the mean and variance of the return on this portfolio? (b) What is the value of a that drives the variance on the portfolio to zero? [Hint: look up the formula for the mean and variance of the weighted sum of random variables, and the formula that shows the relation between the correlation coe¢ cient and the covariance of two random variables.) Sources This chapter relies heavily on the surveys by Livernois (2009) and Slade and Thille (2009). Kronenberg (2008) and Krautkraemer (1998) also provide useful surveys. Heal and Barrow (1980), Berck and Roberts (1996), Pindyck (1999), and Lee, List and Strazicich (2006) test the Hotelling model using price data. Miller and Upton (1985) for oil and gas, Slade and Thille (1997) for copper, and Livernois, Thille, and Zhang (2006) for old-growth timber use proxies to test the Hotelling model. Halvorsen and Smith (1991) estimate the interest rate under the hypothesis that the Hotelling condition holds. Pindyck (1980) pioneered the large literature on uncertainty and nonrenewable resources. Farzin (1995) discusses the impact of technological change on resource scarcity. 114 CHAPTER 6. EMPIRICS AND HOTELLING Hamilton (2011) studies the relation between oil prices and economic activity. Kilian (2009) discusses the distinction between oil demand and supply shocks. Fama and French (2004) explain the Capital Asset Pricing Model and discuss its empirical signi…cance. Reuters (2014) reports Shell’s assumption of carbon tax in projecting future extraction costs. Funk (2014) describes Shell’s experience with the Kulluck. Chapter 7 Completing the solution Objectives Derive the optimality condition for the last period during which extraction is positive, and use this condition to determine the complete solution to the resource extraction problem. Information and skills Use the logic of intertemporal arbitrage to determine the transversality condition that holds during the last period of extraction. Use this condition, together with the Euler equation and the resource stock constraint, to determine the number of periods (T + 1) during which extraction is positive. Use T , the Euler equation, and the stock constraint, to determine the level of extraction and the price in each period (the “full solution”). Obtain the transversality condition for the case where the resource is economically but not physically exhausted. The analysis in Chapter 5, using only the Euler equation, sheds light on some of the qualitative properties of a nonrenewable resource market. The reader still does not have enough information to …nd the level of extraction and the corresponding price in each period. Up to this point, we took T , the …nal date of extraction, as given, without explaining how that value is 115 116 CHAPTER 7. COMPLETING THE SOLUTION determined, or how to use it to compute the equilibrium price and extraction trajectories. Leaving things at this stage is unsatisfactory for two reasons. First, the model remains a black box. Readers cannot fully understand the equilibrium without knowing the missing information. Working through an example in detail removes some of the mysteries. Second, there are occasions when we actually do want to be able to calculate the full equilibrium. We know that the competitive equilibrium maximizes the present discounted value of the sum of producer and consumer welfare. If we want to know how a resource should be consumed to maximize this payo¤, we have to …nd the “complete solution”to the problem. This chapter …lls in the missing pieces. We derive and discuss most of the new results using a numerical example. In the static setting, competitive …rms base their sales decision in a period on the price in only that period. In that setting we can calculate the equilibrium in a period using only the single period demand and the cost function, together with the …rst order condition (Section 2.4). In the resource setting, in contrast, the equilibrium price and quantity in a particular period depend on the equilibrium prices in all subsequent periods. In making their current sales decision, a …rm compares the bene…t of selling the marginal unit in that period or delaying extraction and selling it in a subsequent period. That comparison requires that …rms know not only the current market price, but also know (or form beliefs about) subsequent prices. In the resource setting (but not in the static setting), agents are forward looking. The Euler equation shows the equilibrium relation between prices in adjacent periods. In order to use this equation to determine the trajectory of prices, we need an “anchor”, the price in a particular period. The transversality condition provides that anchor. Box 7.1 Crossing the ravine Crossing a ravine provides a metaphor to the nonrenewable resource problem. Mathematics corresponds to the rope bridge across this ravine. The price and quantity in each period correspond to the rungs of the bridge, and the Euler equation corresponds to the rope that connects one rung to the next, thereby indirectly connecting the …rst and the last rung. The initial condition, the beginning stock, anchors this bridge on one side of the ravine, and the transversality condition is the anchor on the other side. Without all of these parts, the rope bridge is useless. 7.1. THE CHANGE IN PRICE 7.1 117 The change in price Objectives and skills Use the Euler equation to …nd a relation between price in an arbitrary period, and price in period T . We use an example with constant average extraction costs, C, and discount factor . The constraints and optimality condition are: constraints: xt+1 = xt yt , xt Euler equation: pt 0, x0 given 0, yt C = [pt+1 (7.1) C] The full solution to the …rm’s optimization problem is a sequence of extraction levels, y0 ; y1 ; y2 :::yT and corresponding prices. We need the value of T to obtain this sequence. Recall our convention that the initial period is period 0: the number of periods during which extraction is positive is T + 1, not T . The Euler equation implies the following relation between the price in period T and T n (n periods from the date of …nal extraction): pT n = n (pT (7.2) C) + C: Box 7.1 Derivation of equation 7.2 We can write the Euler equation for di¤erent periods: pT pT 1 C = (pT 3 C = (pT 2 C) pT C) :::::::::pT C = (pT 2 n C) 1 C = (pT C) : n+1 Substituting the …rst of this sequence of equations into the right side of the second equation, and adding C to both sides, gives pT 2 = ( (pT C) + C C) + C = pT Substituting this expression for pT and adding C to both sides, gives pT 3 = ( ( (pT 2 2 = 2 (pT C) + C into the third of the sequence, C))) + C = 3 (pT C) + C Repeating this process n times, produces equation 7.2. 118 7.2 CHAPTER 7. COMPLETING THE SOLUTION The transversality condition Objectives and skills Provide the logic and interpretation of the transversality condition. With constant average extraction costs, it is optimal to eventually extract all of the resource, so xT +1 = 0. This equality implies that yT = xT : in the last period during which extraction is positive, all of the remaining resource is extracted. Thus, we need only consider candidates for which yT = xT and yT +1 = 0. Hereafter, we also assume that demand is linear: p = a by, with a > C. For times t < T , where extraction is positive at both time t and at t + 1, it is possible to make a small increase or decrease in time t extraction, and make an o¤setting change in the subsequent period (t + 1). In contrast, at time T , current extraction is positive and extraction in the next period is 0: yT > 0 = yT +1 . It is possible to make a small decrease in yT and an o¤setting increase in yT +1 , but (because negative extraction and a negative stock are infeasible) it is not possible to make a small increase in yT and an o¤setting decrease in yT +1 . Therefore, in order to test the candidate at time T , we need to consider only perturbations that decrease yT . Consequently, the optimality condition at time T , known as the transversality condition is [pT C] [a C] : (7.3) Inequality 7.3 has a straightforward interpretation. Under the candidate trajectory, period T is the last date at which extraction is positive. Therefore, under this candidate, the price in period T + 1 is a b0 = a. A feasible perturbation reduces period T extraction, moving the marginal unit to period T + 1. The cost to the …rm of this perturbation is the marginal loss in pro…t at time T , the left side of inequality 7.3. The present value of the increased T + 1 pro…ts is [a C]. Inequality 7.3 states that the loss exceeds the gain. The …rm does not want to delay extracting the …nal unit: it prefers to extract the …nal unit at time T . Because extraction is positive at T , (yT > 0), we know that pT < a. Combining this inequality and the transversality condition gives a > pT [a C] + C: (7.4) 7.3. THE ALGORITHM 7.3 119 The algorithm Objectives and skills Be able to put together the pieces (the constraints, the Euler equation, and the transversality condition) to …nd the equilibrium price and extraction level in all periods. We obtain T by using information at the end of the problem to obtain information in earlier periods, i.e. by “working backwards”. We then “work forwards” to complete the solution. Equations 7.1, 7.2, and 7.4 enable us to …nd the complete solution. The algorithm consists of the following six steps: Step 1: Combine equations 7.2 and 7.4 to …nd inequalities that the equilibrium price must satisfy: n (a C) + C > pT n n = (pT n C) + C ([ [a C] + C] C) + C or more simply n (a C) + C > pT n+1 n (a (7.5) C) + C Step 2 Use inequality 7.5 and the inverse demand function p = a to obtain bounds on extraction in period T n: n (a C) + C > a a+ n (a C)+C b byT < yT n+1 n a+ (a n+1 (a n C) + C ) C)+C by (7.6) b Step 3 For n = 0; 1; 2:::; sum each of the three parts of the inequality 7.6 from periods T n to T to …nd bounds on cumulative extraction over these periods: n X i=0 a+ i (a C) + C b < n X i=0 yT i n X i=0 a+ i+1 (a b C) + C (7.7) 120 CHAPTER 7. COMPLETING THE SOLUTION Step 4 Compare the initial level of the stock, x0 , with the left and the right sides of equation 7.7, for di¤erent values of n, to identify the value of T. An example illustrates this procedure. Let a = 10, b = 1, C = 2, and = 0:9. Table 7.1 contains values of the Left and the Right sides of equation 7.7 for n = 0; 1; 2 and a …nal column showing the relation between the initial stock and the equilibrium value of T . For example, the row corresponding to n = 2 states that cumulative extraction during the …nal three periods of the program is greater than 2.32 and less than or equal to 4.488. If 2:32 < x0 4:488, then T = 2. If x0 > 4:488, we need more rows of the table to determine the equilibrium value of T . If x0 2:32 then we know that T = 0 or T = 1. n Left side Right side The value of T 0 0 0.8 T = 0 if 0 < x0 0:8 1 0.8 2.32 T = 1 if 0:8 < x0 2:32 2 2.32 4.488 T = 2 if 2:32 < x0 4:488 Table 7.1: Left and Right sides of equation 7.7, and the relation between x0 and T . Step 5 We use the optimal value of T , the Euler Equation, and the initial stock level, to obtain an equation for the unknown period-T level of extraction, yT . We solve that equation to …nd yT . For our linear example, pT = a byT and pT n = a byT n . Substituting these relations into equation 7.2 gives a byT yT n n = = Summing from 0 to n we have n n X X a yT i = i=0 i=0 n (a a ( n (a ( i (a byT byT b byT b C) + C ) C)+C) : C) + C) set = x0 (7.8) To continue the numerical example above, suppose that x0 = 2:34. For this value, we know from Table 7.1 that T = 2 (= n). For this value of n, equation 7.8 simpli…es to n X set yT i = 2: 71yT + 2: 32 = 2:34 ) yT = 0:0074: i=0 7.4. LEAVING SOME RESOURCE IN THE GROUND 121 Step 6 Using yT and the inverse demand function, we obtain pT . This information and equation 7.2 gives us the prices and the quantities in earlier periods, pt and yt . For the example above, we have yT = 0:0074 so pT = 9: 992 6, rounded to 9:993. Table 6.2 uses equation 7.2 to obtain the price and extraction in each period: the complete solution to the model. t T T 1 T 2 Table 7.2: Price and 7.4 pt yt 9:993 0:0074 9:19 0:807 8:47 1:53 extraction in periods before T Leaving some resource in the ground Objectives and skills Derive and interpret the Transversality condition when extraction costs depend on the stock. With stock-independent extraction costs, it is optimal to physically exhaust the resource. With stock-dependent costs, extraction might become so expensive that it is uneconomical to physically exhaust the resource. In this situation, the resource is “economically” (rather than physically) exhausted. Specializing the parametric cost function in equation 4.1 by setting = = 0, and > 0, costs are c (x; y) = Cx y, and marginal cost equals Cx . Marginal costs become large as x approaches 0. For the inverse demand function p = 20 y, the choke prices is p = 20. As long as price is greater than marginal extraction cost, it is optimal to continue extracting. When extraction stops, at T + 1, price equals the choke price, 20. Because it is optimal not to extract in period T + 1 (by de…nition of T ), we know that 1 1 C C . Therefore, as long as xt > 20 , it is optimal to 20 Cx , or x 20 continue extraction. Economic exhaustion occurs as soon as the stock reaches the critical level 1 C . As the stock approaches this level, marginal costs approach the price, 20 so rent approaches 0. An additional unit of the resource in the ground is so expensive to extract, that it is worth almost nothing (rent is close to 0) when 122 CHAPTER 7. COMPLETING THE SOLUTION x is slightly above this critical level; at x less than or equal to the critical level, the rent is 0 and the resource is economically exhausted. 7.5 Summary In static models, a competitive …rm’s equilibrium sales depends only on the price in that period and on the …rm’s cost function. In the resource setting, in contrast, a …rm’s equilibrium sales depends on the current price, and on the …rm’s beliefs about all future prices. These links arise because the …rm has to compare the bene…t of extracting a marginal unit today and extracting that unit in the future. In order to make that comparison, the …rm has to form beliefs about future prices. There is no uncertainty in the models that we use, so …rms correctly anticipate future prices. The fact that …rms in the resource setting are forward looking complicates the problem of solving for the equilibrium. We have to understand how the di¤erent periods …t together. The Euler equation links price and sales in the current period with price and sales in the next periods; the latter are linked to the price and sales in the subsequent period. In this way, the price and sales in a particular period are linked to the prices and sales in all subsequent periods. In the T period model, the number of periods during which the …rm extracts the resource, T + 1, is endogenous. Using an example, we showed how to piece together the necessary conditions for optimality to …nd the complete solution. The necessary conditions consist of (i) the Euler equation, (ii) a transversality condition, and (iii) the resource constraint. The transversality condition to the problem states that at an optimum, the resource owner prefers to extract the …nal unit in period T instead of holding on to it until period T + 1. If extraction costs depend on the resource stock, it might be optimal to leave some of the resource in the ground. In that case, both the price and the marginal extraction costs rise toward the choke price, and rent approaches 0 as the stock approaches the level below which extraction is not economical. 7.6. TERMS, STUDY QUESTIONS, AND EXERCISES 7.6 123 Terms, study questions, and exercises Terms and concepts Transversality condition, algorithm, economic exhaustion. Study questions 1. Suppose that marginal extraction costs are constant, C, inverse demand is p = 20 y, the discount factor is , and the initial stock is x0 . Your job is to explain to a computer programer how to write an algorithm that …nds the competitive equilibrium for this model. You need to describe the algorithm clearly enough so that this person can code it. (Do not do any calculations: that is the computer’s job.) Exercises 1. Use an inductive proof to establish equation 7.2. We begin the inductive chain by showing that the equation is true for the smallest possible value of n, here, n = 0. This demonstration requires only noting that for n = 0, pT = 0 (pT C) + C = pT , which is obviously true. Then show that if the equation holds for arbitrary n (our “hypothesis”) it must also hold for “the next n”, n + 1. To accomplish this, use the Euler equation and the “hypothesis”. 2. Using the methods and the example from Chapter 7.3 …nd the inequalities on the initial stock for which it is optimal to exhaust the resource in 4 periods (T = 3). 3. Consider the linear example in this chapter, with all of the same parameter values: p = 10 y, C = 2, = 0:9, x0 = 2:34. Suppose that the mine owner is a monopoly instead of a competitive …rm. Find the complete solution for the monopoly. (Mimic the steps used for the competitive …rm, making the one change arising from the di¤erence between competition and monopoly.) 124 CHAPTER 7. COMPLETING THE SOLUTION Chapter 8 Backstop technology Objectives Apply the methods and insights developed above to examine the e¤ect of a backstop technology on equilibrium extraction of a nonrenewable resource. Information and skills Know the meaning of and the empirical importance of backstop technologies. Explain why the existence of the backstop a¤ects equilibrium extraction even before the backstop is used. Use the transversality condition to determine the e¤ect of a backstop technology on equilibrium resource extraction. Understand how extraction costs a¤ects the simultaneous use of the resource and the backstop. Understand how cumulative extraction depends on extraction costs. A “backstop”technology provides an alternative to the nonrenewable resource. Solar and wind power, and other methods of generating electricity, are backstop technologies for fossil fuels. We assume that the backstop is a perfect substitute for the resource, can be produced at a constant average cost, b, and can be supplied without limit. In contrast, the natural resource 125 126 CHAPTER 8. BACKSTOP TECHNOLOGY has a …nite potential supply, given by the stock level. We want to know how this backstop a¤ects resource use. As in the previous models, a representative …rm owns the resource. The backstop is available to the economy at large; any …rm –not just resource owners –can use it. The potential to use the backstop a¤ects the equilibrium price and resource extraction paths, even during periods when the backstop is not actually used. The equilibrium level of production and price in a period depend on future prices. The backstop has a direct e¤ect on future prices in periods when the backstop is used. Thus, the backstop has an indirect, but still important, e¤ect on price and resource extraction even in periods when the backstop is not actually used. This insight is true generally. Anything that changes future resource prices –or, in an uncertain world, people’s beliefs about these future prices – changes current extraction decisions. In the static model, competitive supply in a period depends on the price in that period. In the nonrenewable resource setting, however, current supply depends on current and future prices. 8.1 The backstop model Objectives and skills Understand the components of the simplest model of a backstop technology. As above, we use yt to denote resource use in period t. We need two new pieces of notation. Denote zt as the amount of the alternative produced using the backstop technology in period t, and wt = yt + zt as supply of the resource plus the backstop good. In some settings, e.g. with fossil fuels and renewable power, it is natural to think of the good as energy. Fossil fuels and renewable power are physically di¤erent, but we can convert both to common units of energy. The assumption that the resource (e.g. oil) and the alternative produced using the backstop technology (e.g., solar power) are perfect substitutes means that the price in any period depends only on the sum of the resource and the backstop good brought to market, wt . In any period where both the resource and the backstop good are produced and consumed, the price of the two goods must be equal. If they were imperfect substitutes, we would have to consider the di¤erent prices for the two products. 8.1. THE BACKSTOP MODEL 127 If society is using the backstop, then price = marginal cost. Therefore, z > 0 ) p = b: (8.1) The inverse demand function, p (w), equals the price consumers pay for the quantity w. Chapters 5 and 7 provide the tools needed to analyze the model of a backstop technology. Chapter 5 derives the Euler equation, the condition that relates prices and costs in any two adjacent period when extraction is positive. Chapter 7 shows how to use the transversality condition to …nd the …nal date of extraction, and then to use that information to …nd the complete description of the competitive equilibrium. Here we use the constant marginal cost model, c (x; y) = Cy, to show how the presence of a backstop a¤ects equilibrium resource extraction. We then consider matters under more general extraction costs. This model of the backstop technology misses important features of realworld markets. Just as coal is not a perfect substitute for oil, a low-carbon alternative such as solar power is not a perfect substitute for a fossil fuel. Solar power creates an “intermittency” problem: the power goes o¤ when the sun goes down. Oil and coal do not su¤er from this problem. Many machines that can run on fossil fuels have not been adapted to run on solar or wind power. However, solar-generated electricity is the same as oil-generated electricity. Our model uses a constant marginal cost for the backstop, but actual costs might either rise of fall with production levels or with cumulative production. These costs rise if there are decreasing returns to scale. For example, producing solar power uses land. The most economical locations are likely to be used …rst, making subsequent solar farms more expensive. Economies of scale or learning-by-doing might o¤set those cost increases. The unit cost of producing solar power in large scale solar farms might be lower than the unit costs of producing this power on houses and buildings, resulting in economies of scale. The history of new technologies shows that learning-by-doing tends to make costs fall over time, with experience. The cost of solar power is estimated to have fallen by a factor of 50 between 1976 and 2010. Our model overlooks these features in order to illuminate some of the signi…cant features arising from the interaction of backstop and nonrenewable resource markets. 128 8.2 CHAPTER 8. BACKSTOP TECHNOLOGY Constant extraction costs Objectives and skills Identify and interpret the transversality condition in the backstop model with constant average extraction costs. Explain how and why the presence of the backstop changes the equilibrium price and extraction trajectories. The simplest case involves constant average extraction costs, c (x; y) = Cy, where C < b. If C b, the resource is worthless. We also assume that b is less than the choke price; otherwise, the backstop is worthless. The price-taking mine-owner wants to maximize 1 X t [pt yt Cyt ] ; t=0 and the price-taking producer of the backstop wants to maximize 1 X t [pt zt bzt ] : t=0 Both of these representative …rms take price as given, so they act as if their individual decisions have no e¤ect on the other …rm. Therefore, we can combine these two representative …rms into a single, larger representative …rm that chooses both resource extraction and sale of the backstop. This …rm wants to maximize the discounted sum of pro…ts from both the resource and the backstop: 1 X t [pt (yt + zt ) Cyt bzt ] : (8.2) t=0 Apart from one minor di¤erence, and di¤erent notation, this problem is the same as the problem discussed in Chapter 5.5, where we had mines with di¤erent extraction costs. In that chapter, we denoted the extraction costs as C a and C b . Here we denote them as C and b. The minor di¤erence is that here, the “expensive mine” is actually a backstop that, by assumption can be supplied in unlimited quantities at constant costs, b. In Chapter 5.5, both the cheaper and the more expensive mines have …nite stocks. 8.2. CONSTANT EXTRACTION COSTS 129 Chapter 5.5 shows that it is never optimal to begin to extract from the more expensive mine while there remains available stock in the cheaper mine. Either the cheaper mine is exhausted before extraction begins from the more expensive mine, or there is a single period during which extraction occurs from both mines. In that case, in previous periods the cheaper mine satis…es the entire market, and in later periods, when the cheaper mine has been exhausted, the more expensive mine supplies the entire market. The same result occurs here, if we replace “the more expensive mine” with “the backstop technology”. The trajectory consists of periods during which the resource is used, followed by in…nitely many periods when only the backstop is used; there may be a single “transitional” period during which both the resource and the backstop are used. The transversality condition and the Euler equation make it possible to …nd the equilibrium. We begin with the transversality condition. As above, T is the last date during which extraction of the natural resource is positive. If, in period T , the remaining resource stock is not su¢ cient to supply the entire market, then the backstop is also used in that period; in this case, the price in period T is b. If, in period T , the remaining resource stock leads to a price below b, then the resource supplies the entire market, and the backstop is not used until the next period, T + 1. We have to consider both of these possibilities. The transversality condition, i.e. the …rm’s optimality condition in period T is pT C [b C] : (8.3) Compare this equation with 7.3. Here we use the fact that in period T + 1, when the backstop is being used, the price equals the backstop cost, b (not the choke price). The logic used to derive equation 8.3 is the same as the logic behind equation 7.3. Appendix D provides a numerical example that uses the Euler equation and the transversality condition, and the algorithm described in Chapter 7.3, to …nd the equilibrium price and extraction trajectories. A graphical example Figure 8.1 shows the graph of price and quantity for a nonrenewable resource with demand function D = 10p 2 and the parameters b = 5, C = 2, = 0:95 and the initial stock x0 = 301. As with Figure 6.2, Figure 8.1 shows the graphs for the continuous time analog of the discrete time model. While the resource is being used (up to time = 150), extraction is falling and the price is rising. With = 0:95, it is sensible to 130 CHAPTER 8. BACKSTOP TECHNOLOGY 5 price 4 3 2 quantity 1 0 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 110 120 130 140 150 160 170 time Figure 8.1: Resource price and quantity with a backstop think of the unit of time as approximately a year, i.e., the discount rate is about 5%. The vertical axis represents both price and quantity, explaining the absence of a label on that axis. Price and quantity have di¤erent units, so the comparison of the levels of the two graphs (e.g. the crossing point) has no interest. The …gure illustrates the role of the backstop. The initial stock of the resource is so high that it takes 150 years to exhaust it. The rent, at the initial time, is p0 C = 150 (b C) 0 (because (0:95)150 is a small number). The initial price is imperceptibly greater than C = 2. Over time, as the exhaustion date approaches, the rent, and thus also the price, rises; quantity falls. At the time of exhaustion, the price has reached the backstop b = 5. Resource sales falls from a level su¢ cient to satisfy the market at a price approximately equal to b, to zero. Immediately after this date of exhaustion, the backstop supplies the entire market, and price remains constant at b = 5. Thus, total supply and the price change continuously over time; the resource supply changes continuously until the date of exhaustion, at which point the supply falls abruptly from a positive level to 0. At that point in time, the backstop provides the entire market, at price p = b. 8.3. MORE GENERAL COST FUNCTIONS 131 Box 8.1 Continuous versus discrete time The continuous and the discrete time models are qualitatively similar, except for the transitional period when the backstop is …rst used. In the discrete time setting, both the resource and the backstop may supply the market during this transitional period. As we move toward a continuous time model, the length of each period, including the transitional period, becomes smaller. In the continuous time limit, the resource and the backstop are never used simultaneously. Because Figure 8.1 shows the continuous time setting, the extraction rate falls from a positive level an instant before the transitional time T , to zero. 8.3 More general cost functions Objectives and skills Understand how the backstop changes the price and extraction trajectory when average extraction costs depend on either the level of extraction or on the resource stock. The constant average (= marginal) cost function in the previous section is adequate for explaining the basic features of the backstop model, but it has two empirically false implications. First, the model implies that, with the exception of a single transitional period, the resource and the backstop are never used in same period. When marginal costs increase with extraction rates, the resource and the backstop might be used simultaneously in many periods. Second, the constant-cost model implies that the resource is physically exhausted before the backstop starts being used. When costs increase as the stock of resource falls, it may not be economical to physically exhaust the resource. In the interest of clarity, we consider these two features separately. 8.3.1 Costs depend on extraction but not stock Here we assume that marginal costs depend on the rate of extraction, but not the stock: c = c (y), with c0 (y) > 0 and c00 (y) > 0; for example, c (y) = Cy 1+ . Using the same argument that led to equation 8.2, we obtain the objective of the representative mine owner with extraction costs c (y) and 132 CHAPTER 8. BACKSTOP TECHNOLOGY access to the backstop: 1 X t [pt (yt + zt ) c (yt ) bzt ] : t=0 In this setting, there may be many periods during which both the resource and the backstop are used (y > 0 and z > 0). Thus, it is no longer true, in general, that society uses the backstop only when the resource is about to be, or has been, exhausted. Once …rms begin to use the backstop, they do not stop using it. In the model here, where extraction costs are convex (marginal extraction costs increase with the extraction level) there can be either one or two distinct phases of resource extraction. In early periods, provided that the initial stock is su¢ ciently large, it is optimal to extract only the resource. During this phase, the Euler equation holds: pt c0 (yt ) = (pt+1 c0 (yt )) : (8.4) Along this part of the trajectory, price rises to maintain equality of the present value of rent (price - marginal cost) across periods. Whenever production of the backstop is positive (z > 0) the condition that price equals marginal cost implies pt = b. Firms do not stop using the backstop, once they have begun using it. Therefore, if zt > 0, then pt = pt+1 = pt+2 = :::: = b. Putting these equalities together with the Euler equation 8.4, it follows that if the …rm uses both the resource and the backstop in adjacent periods, then b c0 (yt ) = [b c0 (yt+1 )] : (8.5) At some time, say T1 , it becomes optimal to begin using the backstop, while continuing to extract the resource. During this phase, the price remains constant at p = b, the cost of the backstop, but extraction falls (so c0 falls) in order to main equality of the present value of rent across periods. At a later time, T2 T1 the resource is exhausted; thereafter, the sole source of supply is the backstop. The trajectory might consist of these two stages of resource extraction, or it might be optimal to begin using both the resource and the backstop, and then move to using only the backstop. Equation 8.5 is a no-arbitrage condition. Because the backstop is being used in both periods t and t+1, the price in both periods equals b. If the …rm 8.3. MORE GENERAL COST FUNCTIONS 133 extracts one more unit of the resource in period t, it incurs the additional cost c0 (yt ). However, because the price remains at b, the perturbation does not alter total (resource + backstop) sales or revenue: a unit increase in extraction requires a one unit reduction of backstop production. The net cost reduction due to extracting an additional unit of the resource in t and reducing backstop production by one unit is therefore b c0 (yt ). The …rm must eventually reduce resource extraction, because the stock is …nite. On an e¢ cient trajectory, there are no remaining arbitrage opportunities: the …rm is indi¤erent about the timing of the o¤setting reduction in future extraction, required by the original perturbation. If the …rm reduces next period extraction by one unit, it reduces next period cost by c0 (yt+1 ), but incurs the additional cost due to the one unit increase in backstop production. The net increase in future cost is therefore b c0 (yt+1 ), and the present value of that additional cost equals the right side of equation 8.5. Along an optimal extraction path, the …rm has no desire to reallocate the resource use: there are no opportunities for intertemporal arbitrage. 8.3.2 Stock-dependent costs We now consider the case where the …rm’s extraction cost is c (x; y) = C ( + x) y, i.e. average extraction cost depends on the resource stock, but not on the rate of extraction: costs are lower when the resource stock is higher. We assume that b < C ( + 0) , which implies that it is not optimal to physically exhaust the resource. This assumption implies that there is a positive level of x that solves C ( + xmin ) = b; the solution is 1 > 0. It is never optimal to extract when the stock is xmin = Cb below this level, because at such levels it is cheaper to produce the good using the backstop. If the initial stock of the resource is x0 , then the “economically viable”stock, i.e. the amount that will eventually be extracted, is approximately x0 xmin .1 In this model, the resource is not physically exhausted, but for low stocks 1 Why “approximately”instead of “exactly”? We assumed that extraction costs depend on the stock at the beginning of the period. Thus, for example, if the stock is slightly above xmin , it might be optimal to extract to a level slightly below xmin . However, if the current stock is below xmin , further extraction is uneconomical. This complication does not arise in a continous time model, where the economically viable stock is exactly x0 xmin : Provided that the length of each period is reasonably small, say a year or so, the discrete time model and the continuous time model are similar. 134 CHAPTER 8. BACKSTOP TECHNOLOGY $ 7 6 extraction cost 5 4 3 backstop cost = 2 2 1 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 22 24 26 28 30 32 34 36 38 40 stock Figure 8.2: A lower backstop cost, b, increases the minimum economically viable stock. it is not economically viable to extract more. Coal is one of the many examples of such a resource. Even apart from issues related to climate change, we will not use all of the coal on the planet, simply because at some point extraction costs exceed the cost of an alternative. Figure 8.2 shows a graph of stock-dependent average costs, the solid curve, and a backstop cost of 2 at the dashed line. In this example, extraction does not occur if the stock is below xmin 13. The cost of extracting stocks below this level exceeds the production cost using the backstop. It is always optimal to drive the resource at least to the critical level xmin . A trajectory that ceases extraction when the stock is above this critical level “leaves money on the table” (valuable resource in the ground). If the backstop cost falls from b = 2 to b = 1, the dashed line shifts to the dotted line, leading to an increase in the intersection, xmin , and a decrease in the economically viable stock, x0 xmin . As with constant average extraction cost, there is an initial phase during which the backstop is not used, and an in…nitely long phase during which only the backstop is used. There is at most a single period when both the resource and the backstop are used. In the model with constant average costs equal to C, a constant (Section 8.2) we assumed at the outset that C < b. The corresponding assumption in the model with stock-dependent costs C ( + x) , is that at the initial stock, x0 , C ( + x0 ) < b. If this assumption does not hold, the resource is again worthless, because there is an alternative with equal or lower costs. 8.4. SUMMARY 8.4 135 Summary The presence of the backstop substitute for the resource a¤ects the entire trajectory of the resource price, even during periods when the backstop is not being used. This dependence re‡ects the fact that a …rm’s resource extraction decision is an investment problem. Extraction in a period depends on the relation between price in that period and in all subsequent periods. The backstop model drives home an important point: when the commodity is a resource, the supply of the resource brought to market in a period depends on the entire trajectory of current and (anticipated) future prices. In contrast, in the familiar static model, it is often reasonable to model the supply as a function the current price. Where average extraction cost is independent of the extraction level, we have the extreme result that there is at most a single transitional period during which both the resource and the backstop are used. In all other periods, only one energy source is used. If the marginal extraction cost increases with extraction, society might use both sources of energy simultaneously over many periods. Variations of this model include the possibility that: the resource and the backstop are imperfect substitutes; the marginal backstop production costs rises with output (decreasing returns to scale) or falls with output (increasing returns to scale); and that the cost falls with cumulative output (learning by doing). In these cases, the backstop and the resource might also be used simultaneously for many periods. 8.5 Terms, study questions and exercises Terms and concepts Backstop technology, economically viable stock, proof by contradiction, inductive proof. Study questions 1. Explain why the presence of the backstop technology a¤ects the competitive equilibrium even in periods before the backstop is actually used. 136 CHAPTER 8. BACKSTOP TECHNOLOGY 2. Di¤erent assumptions about extraction costs have di¤erent implications concerning the simultaneous use of the natural resource and the backstop. (a) Suppose that average (and marginal) extraction costs are constant. Describe the extraction pro…le of the resource, in relation to the production pro…le of the backstop. In particular, under what if any conditions are the two used in the same period? (b) Suppose that extraction costs are increasing in the rate of extraction. Describe the extraction pro…le of the resource, in relation to the production pro…le of the backstop. In particular, under what if any conditions are the two used in the same period? (c) Explain the source of the di¤erence in parts (a) and (b). Exercises 1. Use a proof by contradiction to establish equation 8.1. [Hint: To use this type of proof, write the hypothesis that states the “opposite” of what we want to prove, and derive a contradiction. Here, the hypothesis is “in some period when z > 0, p 6= b.” This hypothesis is the “opposite”of equation 8.1, the statement that we want to verify. Then show that the hypothesis must be false, by considering individually the two possibilities,“z > 0 and p < b” and then “z > 0 and p > b”. The proof must explain why neither of these two statements can be true in a competitive equilibrium. Consequently, equation 8.1 must be true.] 2. In the constant cost model, explain why the resource is worthless if C b. What is the resource rent in this case? 3. (a) In Chapter 8.3.1, why do we assume that c0 (0) < b? (b) Explain why the assumption c0 (0) < b implies that it is optimal to exhaust the resource. 4. Chapter 8.3.1 claims that once …rms begin using the backstop, they do not stop using it. Verify this claim, using a proof by contradiction. See the hint for problem 1 above. Sources Timilsina et al. (2011) review the evolution and the current status of solar power. 8.5. TERMS, STUDY QUESTIONS AND EXERCISES 137 Heal (1974) is an early paper on natural resources and a backstop. Dasgupta and Heal (1974) study the case where the backstop becomes available at an uncertain time. Tsur and Zemel (2003) consider R&D investment that lowers the cost of the backstop. 138 CHAPTER 8. BACKSTOP TECHNOLOGY Chapter 9 The “Green Paradox” Objectives Use the nonrenewable resource model to analyze the e¤ect of a lower backstop price on extraction trajectories and cumulative extraction of fossil fuels, and to consider possible climate-related consequences. Information and skills Understand how a lower backstop price a¤ects cumulative extraction and/or the extraction pro…le. Explain why both of these changes might have climate-related consequences. Be familiar with the terms “industrial policy” and “green industrial policy”. Be able to synthesize this information to describe the “Green Paradox”. The “Green Paradox”is an unconvential choice for a textbook on resource economics. We include the material for three reasons. First, the topic is intrinsically important. Second, it provides an example of a situation where well-intentioned policies can back…re, a possibility that arises in many other contexts. Chapter 10 provides a more general perspective on this issue; the current chapter sets the stage for the general discussion by considering a speci…c example in detail. Third, the material shows how the Hotelling model can be used to illuminate a policy question. The policy conclusions 139 140 CHAPTER 9. THE “GREEN PARADOX” are straightforward once readers understand the Hotelling model, but without that background the conclusions might be hard to understand or seem counterintuitive. Economists build formal models, like the Hotelling model, in order to better understand real world concerns. This chapter illustrates that process. Burning fossil fuels increases atmospheric stocks of greenhouse gasses. Evidence from climate science shows that these higher stocks will e¤ect the world’s climate, possibly leading to serious environmental and economic consequences. This risk has spurred interest in the development of “green” alternative energy sources, such as solar and wind power, which emit little or no carbon. Much of the political discussion concerns the use of public policy to reduce the cost of providing these alternatives. We consider a particular policy, a subsidy that encourages …rms to undertake research that decreases the cost, b, of a green backstop energy source. A cheaper backstop provides economic bene…ts during periods when it is used. The cheaper backstop also reduces the fossil fuel price trajectory prior to the backstop being used, bene…tting energy consumers. However, if fossil fuel consumption was already socially excessive, the lower price of fossil fuels can lower aggregate welfare. The possibility that an apparently bene…cial change (the lower-cost backstop) harms society is known as the Green Paradox. Other forms of this paradox build on the same general idea. The key feature in all of these cases is that resource owners anticipate a change that directly e¤ects the market in the future. Possible changes include future carbon taxes or the future availability of substitutes to fossil fuels. Those future changes reduce future consumption of fossil fuels, bene…tting the climate. But they induce changes in current behavior that might harm the climate. When these kinds of o¤setting changes occur, their net e¤ect on the climate may be ambiguous. In an economy without market failures (and given the convexity condition discussed in Chapter 2.6), cheaper energy increases social welfare. Although the lower backstop cost bene…ts society in this perfect world, the Fundamental Welfare Theorems imply that there is no need to subsidize green alternatives here. We do not consider providing public subsidies to competitive computer manufacturers, even though their innovations bene…t consumers. In this perfect world, the market rewards the innovators by exactly the amount needed to induce them to undertake the socially optimal level of innovation. 141 However, we are interested in public policy because market failures are prevalent. A monopoly might want to produce either too much or too little innovation, relative to the socially optimal level. Competitive …rms might face research spillovers, a positive externality where one …rm’s innovation bene…ts other …rms. The innovator does not take those bene…ts into consideration and therefore undertakes too little research. These kinds of market failures are potentially important, but our focus is the pollution externality associated with fossil fuels. Greenhouse gasses such as carbon dioxide are a classic example of a public bad. In the absence of “win-win opportunities” (Box 9.1) it is expensive for a country to reduce emissions. Those reductions lower atmospheric stocks of greenhouse gasses, reducing climate-related damages and creating global bene…ts. The individual country making the sacri…ce to reduce emissions obtains only a small share of these global bene…ts. Due to this market failure, countries have inadequate incentive to reduce emissions. There is scope for public policy at the global level. Does a seemingly bene…cial policy, such as a subsidy that lowers the cost of the backstop, actually help to correct this externality, or does it make things worse? The Green Paradox provides examples where a policy of this sort makes matters worse. The subsidy has two types of e¤ects on the externality. First, the subsidy tends to reduce cumulative extraction of fossil fuels over the life of the resource, improving the climate problem. Second, the subsidy alters the extraction path, increasing extraction early on and decreasing extraction later. This “tilting”of the extraction path can worsen the climate problem. Either of these e¤ects might dominate, so we cannot presume that the lower backstop price bene…ts the climate. 142 CHAPTER 9. THE “GREEN PARADOX” Box 9.1 Win-win opportunities With “win-win” opportunities, the unilateral reduction of CO2 emissions can bene…t a country. Reducing C02 tends to also reduce local pollutants such as SO2 and Total Suspended Particles (TSP), generating local health bene…ts. These kinds of “co-bene…ts” have been documented for China, and the Obama administration used these bene…ts as an additional justi…cation for environmental rules announced in the summer of 2014. If the co-bene…ts are large relative to the cost of C02 reductions, the country can gain from the reductions even without taking into account the global bene…t of lower atmospheric carbon stocks: a “win-win”. Using sequestered carbon to improve soil creates or reduce oil extraction costs create other win-win possibilities. 9.1 The approach Objectives and skills Recognize that the Green Paradox does not rely on fact that investment is costly. Rather than speak generally of improvements in green technology, it is useful to have a speci…c model. The simplest of these describes the green technology using the production costs, b, which we again take as a constant, as in Chapter 8. With this model, an improvement in technology corresponds to a reduction in b, to b0 < b. Improving technology of any hue usually involves costs. Suppose that society must invest I (b0 ; b) > 0 (“I” for “investment costs”) to reduce the backstop cost from b to b0 . The factors of production, e.g. scientists and lab space used to improve the technology, are costly. Proponents of green subsidies argue that the social bene…ts, arising from reduced climate-related damages, justify these investment costs. To focus on the Green Paradox, we ignore the investment costs. That is, we ask, “Even if I (b0 ; b) = 0, does society want the lower backstop costs?” This question is similar to the comparative static questions that we introduced in Chapter 2.2, except that here we ask how changing the parameter b alters the entire pro…le of extraction (not merely extraction at a single point in time) and thereby alters climate-related damages. 9.2. CUMULATIVE EXTRACTION 143 A large literature discusses the merits of “Industrial Policy”, governmental attempts to promote speci…c industries. All of the arguments for and against this type of government intervention also apply to green industrial policy. The Green Paradox applies uniquely to green industrial policy, raising the possibility that society might not want the better technology even if it were free. 9.2 Cumulative extraction Objectives and skills Recognize that with stock-dependent costs, lowering the backstop lowers cumulative extraction, making the Green Paradox less likely. Chapter 8 considers one case where extraction costs increase as the remaining stock of the resource falls (costs equal C ( + x) y) and two cases where extraction costs are independent of the remaining stock (costs equal Cy, and costs equal Cy 1+ ). In the …rst case, we noted that zero extraction is optimal for stocks less than or equal to xmin , the solution to C ( + xmin ) = b. In this case, cumulative extraction, over the life of the resource, is x0 xmin . A reduction in the backstop price, e.g. from b to a lower level b0 , increases the critical stock level below which it is not worth extracting the resource. Figure 8.2 illustrates a case where reduction in the cost of the backstop from b = 2 to b = 1 shifts the dashed line to the dotted line. This downward shift increases the critical stock below which it does not pay to extract, from about 13 to 21, thus reducing cumulative extraction by 8 units. By choice of units, we can set one unit of extraction equal to one unit of emissions, so the reduction of cumulative extraction implies an equal reduction of cumulative emissions. One short ton of subbituminous coal contains about 3700 pounds of C02 . We can de…ne a “unit of coal” to equal a short ton and a “unit of C02 ”to equal 3700 pounds, so that one unit of coal equals one unit of C02 . With stock-dependent extraction costs, a lower backstop cost reduces cumulative emissions over the life of the resource. Insofar as climate-related damages arise because of cumulative emissions, the lower backstop cost reduces climate-related damages. Stock-dependent extraction costs therefore militate against the Green Paradox. If extraction costs are independent 144 CHAPTER 9. THE “GREEN PARADOX” extraction low backstop 1.0 0.8 0.6 high backstop 0.4 0.2 0.0 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 110 time Figure 9.1: Extraction pro…les under high and low backstop costs of the stock, the reduction in backstop costs has no e¤ect on cumulative extraction and thus no e¤ect on cumulative emissions. 9.3 Extraction pro…le Objectives and skills Understand the e¤ect of a reduction in backstop cost on the extraction pro…le. Climate damage may depend on the shape of the extraction trajectory (the pro…le), not just cumulative extraction. In order to make this point as simply as possible, we consider the case where average extraction costs are constant at C < b0 < b; here, cumulative extraction is the same for both backstop costs. The assumption of constant average costs thus allows us to isolate the e¤ect of the backstop cost on the extraction pro…le. A more descriptive model, with stock dependent costs, would show how a lower backstop cost changes both cumulative extraction and the extraction pro…le. The intuition from such a model merely combines, without increasing, the intuition that we obtain by considering separately the e¤ects of cumulative extraction and the extraction pro…le. A reduction in the backstop cost reduces future resource prices, thereby reducing the rent in earlier periods. This reduction in rent corresponds to a 9.3. EXTRACTION PROFILE 145 decrease in the …rm’s opportunity cost of selling the resource. A reduction in the opportunity cost, like the reduction in any kind of (marginal) cost, leads to an increase in equilibrium sales. Therefore, a reduction in the backstop costs leads to higher sales during the time that these are positive. Because the resource stock is …nite, it is not possible to increase sales at every point in time. Therefore, the extraction paths (showing extraction as a function of time) under a low and under a high backstop cost, must cross at some point in time. Figure 9.1 shows extraction pro…les corresponding to a high and a low backstop costs. The important features of the …gure are: (i) early in the program (t < 41 for this example) extraction is higher under the low backstop cost, and (ii) exhaustion occurs earlier under the low backstop costs. At T 0 = 41, the resource is exhausted under the low backstop cost; exhaustion occurs at T = 100 under the high backstop cost. The extraction paths cross at T 0 , but not before. The lower backstop cost “tilts the extraction trajectory toward the present” (small t). Provided that the reduction in backstop costs is not large enough to make the resource stock worthless, the timing of the cost reduction may be unimportant in a deterministic setting. In the example above, it does not matter whether the cost reduction occurs right away, at t = 0, or if it is anticipated to occur at t = 40. In either of those cases, the low-cost backstop is not used until t = 41. Box 9.2 Description of Figure 9.1. The extraction pro…les in Figure 9.1 are generated using a continuous time model with constant average extraction costs, C = 5, = 0:95 (a discount rate of about 5%), demand D = 10p 1:3 , and an initial stock of x0 = 46. The high backstop cost, b = 100, leads to the solid curve of extraction, and the low backstop cost, b0 = 6, leads to the dashed extraction trajectory. Because b0 > C, in both cases it is optimal to exhaust the resource; rent is positive. The curves are smooth, except for the points of discontinuity, because of the continuous time setting; in the discrete time setting, where the time index is integer-valued, the graphs would be step functions rather than smooth curves. (See the discussion of Figure 8.1.) 146 CHAPTER 9. THE “GREEN PARADOX” Box 9.3 The logic behind Figure 9.1. The Euler equation does not depend on the backstop price. In the continuous time setting, the price at the last instant of extraction, time T , equals the backstop price. The graphs of the price trajectories, under the two backstop prices, cannot cross: if they were to intersect at any point, they would have to coincide at every point when extraction is positive, simply because both paths satisfy the same Euler equation. However, if the two price trajectories coincide, then it is not possible for both to result in exhaustion of the resource, because the two price trajectories terminate at di¤erent prices, equal to the backstop cost in the two cases. Consequently, the two price trajectories never cross. Therefore, one path must lie strictly below the other, during times when extraction is positive under both. Because the price path corresponding to low backstop cost ends at a lower price, it must be lower during the entire time that extraction is positive. Therefore, extraction must be higher while it is positive, and exhaustion occurs sooner, under the low-cost backstop, as Figure 9.1 shows. 9.4 Why does the extraction pro…le matter? Objectives and skills Understand three reasons why the change in extraction pro…le, associated with the reduction in backstop cost, might increase climate-related damages. Scienti…c evidence points strongly to the conclusion that higher atmospheric stocks of greenhouse gasses contribute to climate change. Climate change may create substantial social costs, including more serious epidemics, rising sea level, and increased frequency and severity of storms and droughts. Climate change may also lead to rapid and large-scale extinction of species, with unpredictable ecological, and ultimately social, consequences; temperature and precipitation changes might decrease agricultural productivity, worsening food insecurity; these changes may also induce massive human migration, worsening social con‡ict. Higher cumulative extraction –thus higher atmospheric stocks of greenhouse gasses –worsens the climate problem. We 9.4. WHY DOES THE EXTRACTION PROFILE MATTER? 147 have seen that a subsidy that reduces backstop costs cannot increase cumulative emissions. There can be no Green Paradox through that channel, leaving only the possibility that tilting the extraction pro…le toward the present worsens climate change. There are many reasons why such a tilt is likely to make things worse. We consider three of these reasons: the tilt might make it more likely that we cross a threshold that triggers a catastrophe, such as rapid melting of the Antarctic ice sheet; the tilt might speed the rate of climate change, and society is worse o¤ when change occurs more quickly; the tilt creates a higher maximum stock level, and costs may be nonlinear in the stock. Figures 9.2 – 9.4 are based on the same assumptions used to generate Figure 9.1. That …gure shows two extraction pro…les that lead to the same cumulative extraction, but the dashed pro…le, corresponding to the low backstop cost, is tilted toward the present: extraction is initially higher with the lower backstop cost, but is eventually lower. 9.4.1 Catastrophic changes Figure 9.2 illustrates the possibility of crossing a threshold that triggers a catastrophe. The two extraction pro…les in Figure 9.1 have di¤erent e¤ects on the stock of carbon. The distinction between stock and ‡ow variables is critical. In the setting here, emissions is a ‡ow variable. It is measured in (for example) tons of carbon per year. The stock variable in this setting is the amount of carbon in the atmosphere. It is measured in (for example) tons of carbon. The ‡ow variable is measured in units of quantity per unit of time, whereas the stock variable is measured in units of quantity. A t = 0, the beginning of the program, the level of the stock is given. Historical emissions, prior to t = 0, determine this initial condition. Some of the carbon entering the atmosphere migrates to other reservoirs, including the ocean and biomass. Although not literally correct, climate economists often describe this migration as a decay of the stock, and for purpose of exposition use a constant decay rate. The emissions generated by fossil fuel use increases the stock of atmospheric carbon and decay reduces the stock. Early in the program, when emissions are high, the stock increases. Later in the program, when emissions are low, the natural decay rate of the stock dominates, and the stock falls. Because the initial stock level is historically determined, it is the same for both extraction paths. However, after the initial period, the stock trajectory 148 CHAPTER 9. THE “GREEN PARADOX” stock 40 low backstop high backstop 30 20 10 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 time Figure 9.2: The stock trajectories corresponding to the two extraction trajectories. Solid curve corresponds to high-cost backstop and dashed curve corresponds to low-cost backstop. depends on the extraction (= emissions) trajectory. Because extraction is initially higher under the low-cost backstop, the stock grows more quickly in that scenario, relative to the high cost backstop scenario. Figure 9.2 shows the stock trajectories corresponding to the two extraction pro…les in Figure 9.1. For approximately the …rst 70 years, the (dashed) stock trajectory under the extraction path corresponding to the low backstop cost lies above the (solid) trajectory corresponding to the high backstop cost. Figure 9.2 also shows the ‡at dotted line at a stock of 38. If, for example, a stock above 38 triggers a catastrophe, then that catastrophe occurs in about 40 years under the low-backstop-cost trajectory, but never occurs under the high-backstop-cost trajectory. If the catastrophe is su¢ ciently severe, then the future economic bene…ts arising from eventual availability of the low-cost backstop do not compensate society for the fact that this low-cost backstop “causes” the catastrophe. The lower cost backstop does not literally cause the catastrophe: the accumulation of stocks does that. But the lower cost backstop changes the competitive equilibrium extraction trajectory, thereby changing the stock trajectory, thereby triggering the catastrophe. The model of the “carbon cycle” Figure 9.2 is drawn using the assumption that the stock of carbon decays at a constant rate: the time derivative of the stock, S(t), for this …gure is dS (t) = y (t) dt S (t) ; (9.1) 9.4. WHY DOES THE EXTRACTION PROFILE MATTER? 149 where y (t) is emissions (= extraction) at time t and > 0 is the constant decay rate. For this model, the stock rises ( dS(t) > 0) when y (t) > S (t) dt and the stock falls when this inequality is reversed. This climate model is simple to work with, and therefore often used in policy models where the goal is to obtain insight, instead of making quantitative policy recommendations, e.g. levels of the optimal carbon tax. The process that governs changes in atmospheric carbon (or more generally, greenhouse gas) stocks is much more complicated. In particular, a constant decay rate does not accurately describe the e¤ect of emissions on the stock. In addition, GHG stocks likely cause damages indirectly, via the e¤ect of the stocks on temperature or precipitation, instead of directly. The inertia in the climate system causes global average temperature and other climate variables to respond to changed GHG stocks with a delay. Therefore, the climateimpact of current emissions might increase over decades, before eventually diminishing.1 In addition to this delay, climate scientists have identi…ed a number of positive feedback e¤ects that might cause stocks to increase even if anthropogenic emissions were close to zero. For example, higher temperatures caused by higher stocks of greenhouse gasses might melt permafrost, releasing additional greenhouse gasses. Our model of catastrophes provides a simple way to think about this possibility. There may be a threshold level of atmospheric stocks that triggers such an event. However, the actual dynamics are much more complicated. Figure 9.2 illustrates a possibility, but it does not establish that a particular outcome is likely. The …gure does not show the unit of measurement of the stock variable, partly to defuse the danger that readers give it undue weight. Its key feature is that the maximum stock level under the low-cost backstop (the dashed trajectory) is above the maximum stock level under the high-cost backstop (the solid trajectory). Provided that the probability of catastrophe increases with the maximum stock level, this model (together with parameter assumptions) implies that the lower backstop cost increases the probability of catastrophe. This result is due to the fact that the initial emissions pro…le is higher under the low-cost backstop. 1 Prominent climate-economics models, e.g. DICE, due to Nordhaus (2008), use climate components in which the major e¤ect on temperature occurs …ve or six decades after the release of emissions. Recent evidence by Ricke and Caldeira (2014) suggests that the major e¤ect occurs within the decade of emissions release. 150 CHAPTER 9. THE “GREEN PARADOX” damages 45 40 35 low backstop 30 high backstop 25 20 0 10 20 30 40 time Figure 9.3: Damages are related to the stock and the speed of change in the stock. Solid curve corresponds to high-cost backstop and dashed curve corresponds to low-cost backstop. Box 9.4 The half life of the stock The half life of the stock equals the amount of time it takes half of a given stock to decay. With constant decay rate , e t of a unit that is emitted at time 0 remains at time t. Setting e t = 0:5 and solving for t, produces the half life of the stock, ln 0:5 . If the half life is between 100 and 200 years, and if we pick the unit of time to equal one year, then 0:0035 < < 0:007. 9.4.2 Rapid changes Even in the absence of catastrophic events, tilting the extraction trajectory toward the present may harm society. If change occurs su¢ ciently slowly, society may be able to adapt to it with moderate costs. Over the very long run, society replaces most infrastructure. Climate-related change alters the speed at which this replacement must occur. If we know, for example, that rising sea levels will make some highways and bridges obsolete in 150 years, then we can divert investment away from maintaining these highways and bridges, and toward building more resilient substitutes. If we have to replace this infrastructure within the next 50 years, then we may be forced to write o¤ much of the current infrastructure that would, absent rising sea levels, still be useful for decades. As a simple way of modeling this dependence of climate-related costs on the speed of change, denote the stock at time t as S (t) and the speed . Suppose that total of change in the stock, the time derivative, as dS(t) dt 9.4. WHY DOES THE EXTRACTION PROFILE MATTER? 151 damages depend linearly on the stock, and are convex increasing in the speed of change: 2 dS (t) Damages = S (t) + 10 . dt With this formulation, marginal damages increase with the speed of change of the stock. From Figure 9.2, it is evident that the stock initially increases more rapidly in the dashed trajectory: its slope – the time derivative – is greater. During the early part of the program, the stock levels are similar, because the stock levels are exactly the same at the initial time, and the stock levels change continuously with time. Therefore, early in the program, damages must be higher in the trajectory corresponding to the low cost backstop. Figure 9.3 shows the graphs of damages in two cases, as a function of time. Damages corresponding to the low-cost backstop are higher early in the program, and only slightly lower late in the trajectory (not shown); the present discounted value (not shown) of damages are also much higher under the low-cost backstop. 9.4.3 Convex damages In the previous example, where the ‡ow of damage is linear in the stock of atmospheric carbon, doubling S (t) S (0) doubles damage. Damages may be convex in the stock. For example, the …rst 10% increase in these stocks may cause negligible additional damage; the second 10% increase may cause only small additional damages; but the fourth or …fth 10% increase may cause substantially higher damages. Convex damages mean that marginal damages are higher, the higher is the stock. This convexity might arise from the relation between atmospheric stocks and temperature change (e.g. due to feedbacks) or from the relation between temperature change and damages. To illustrate the e¤ect of this kind of nonconvexity, suppose that damages equal S (t) + 12 S (t)2 . Figure 9.4 shows the graphs of damages, over time, under the high-cost backstop (solid) and the low-cost backstop (dashed). At the beginning of the program, damages in the two scenarios are exactly the same, because in this model damages depend only on the level of the stock; the initial stock, given by historical emissions, is the same under the low- or high-cost backstop. However, as Figure 9.2 shows, the stock becomes much higher in the low-cost backstop scenario. This increase makes damages much 152 CHAPTER 9. THE “GREEN PARADOX” damages 900 800 low backstop 700 600 high backstop 500 400 300 200 100 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 time Figure 9.4: Damages are convex (quadratic) in the stock. Solid curve corresponds to high-cost backstop and dashed curve corresponds to low-cost backstop. larger, early in the program, in the low-cost backstop scenario. 9.5 Assessment of the Paradox Objectives and skills Understand some of the nuances of the Green Paradox. We explained the Green Paradox in the context of industrial policies (“green subsidies”) that lower backstop costs. The same logic applies to phased-in carbon taxes, i.e. taxes that begin low and rise over time. Both of these policies lower future producer prices of fossil fuels, and therefore tend to lower current prices, increasing current extraction. Green subsidies and future carbon taxes are politically more palatable than policies that discourage current fossil fuel use. Because of their greater political appeal, and the resulting higher likelihood that they will be implemented, it is worth asking whether such policies have unintended consequences. Firms’ current sales decisions, and thus the equilibrium price of a nonrenewable resource in the current period, depends on …rms’expectations of future prices. A lower expected future producer price decreases the scarcity rent, making it less attractive to store the resource rather than sell (and consume) it today. Thus, lower expected future prices increase the availability 9.5. ASSESSMENT OF THE PARADOX 153 of supply in the current period, lowering the current equilibrium price and increasing current consumption. The Green Paradox exempli…es the constructive role that theory can play in informing policy, and also illustrates how easy it is to hijack theory to promote a particular agenda. Theory works best when it is simple enough to communicate easily. That simpli…cation almost always requires focusing on a small set of issues to the exclusion of others. Once the theory has been understood in the simple setting, it is important to recognize its limitations. 9.5.1 Other investment decisions The Green Paradox is usually studied in the Hotelling setting where fossil fuel extraction is the only investment decision explicitly modeled. That treatment ignores other investment decisions, including those related to the development of substitutes for fossil fuels or adaptations to anticipated policy, and those related to the discovery and development of new stocks of fossil fuels. When we recognize that businesses solve a host of investment problems, of which resource extraction is only one, the Paradox appears in a di¤erent light. Instead of providing a strong basis for rejecting green industrial policy, it reminds us that green industrial policy might have unintended consequences. Green alternatives and current adaptation The immediate elimination of carbon emissions would be prohibitively expensive, but there is considerable uncertainty about the cost of moderate emissions reductions. Resolving that uncertainty requires research and development in green alternatives, which likely requires a combination of current R&D subsidies and future carbon taxes. Current subsidies reduce current investment costs, and the anticipation of future carbon taxes increase the expectation of the future pro…tability of current investment. Current carbon taxes increase the current pro…tability of low-carbon alternatives, but not their future pro…tability. Investment incentives depend on the anticipation of future pro…tability, because the fruits of current investment are available only in the future. The Green Paradox focuses on the current response of resource owners to future changes in the market. However, resource users also have an incentive to adapt early to future changes. Consequently, anticipated future 154 CHAPTER 9. THE “GREEN PARADOX” policy a¤ects both current supply and demand. For example, the U.S. Acid Rain program was phased in over a decade, so coal producers and consumers were aware of future sulfur emissions constraints. This noti…cation reduced the rent on high-sulfur coal, inducing owners to increase sales prior to the restrictions coming in to force; this is the supply e¤ect examined by the Green Paradox. Power plants, the major consumers, recognized that the policy would make future emissions expensive. Businesses replace capital as it wears out; their replacement decisions depend on their expectation of future market conditions. The future implementation of the sulfur emissions policy gave power plants an incentive to replace aging capital stock with cleaner technology. Thus, the announcement of the future constraints increased current supply of dirty coal, but reduced near-term demand for that coal, leading to statistically insigni…cant e¤ect on equilibrium consumption. New sources of fossil fuels The discovery and development of new deposits, such as tar sands deposits in Canada and oil o¤ the coast of Brazil, usually involves substantial investment costs, including the costs of infrastructure needed to bring the oil to market. A fundamental rule of economic logic is to ignore sunk costs. The decision whether to develop the new deposits depends on the magnitude of the investment costs relative to potential pro…ts. A green policy that lowers future resource prices, lowering future pro…ts, can change the investment calculation. However, once …rms have incurred the investment costs, the subsequent extraction pro…le does not depend on the now-sunk costs. The Keystone pipeline would bring oil from the Canadian tar sands to U.S. re…neries, and thence to world markets. Extracting and re…ning these deposits creates higher carbon emissions per unit of energy produced, compared to other petroleum deposits. Climate-change activists devoted substantial e¤ort to in‡uence U.S. policymakers to reject permits for this pipeline. Some of this opposition was due to concern about local environmental a¤ects arising from possible leaks in the pipeline. Some of the opposition was for symbolic reasons, to show that the danger of climate change is great enough to justify derailing a project of national importance to Canada. Delaying tactics can sometimes achieve a strategic goal. In 2012, with high oil prices, the pipeline looked like a solid business proposition. After a 40% decrease in oil prices, the economic viability of the project is less certain. A further decline in oil prices might change the oil companies’calculation, 9.5. ASSESSMENT OF THE PARADOX 155 even if they obtain permission to build. Green industrial policy can increase uncertainty about the value of major new exploration and development efforts, delaying and possibly stopping these e¤orts. However, oil prices have historically been volatile (Figure 6.1) even before green industrial policy. Oil producers are accustomed to this volatility; the uncertainty about future green industrial policy (regulatory risk) is just one additional source of risk. As noted in Chapter 6.3, Shell already (in 2014) builds in a carbon tax to the cost of production, in anticipation that this tax will eventually arise. Divestment from fossil fuel companies Climate change activists encourage universities, pension funds and other investment funds to divest from fossil fuel companies on the grounds of social responsibility. These activists draw parallels with the divestment from South Africa during the apartheid regime. By 2015, several universities (including Stanford) and cities (including Seattle, San Francisco and Portland) had begun to divest from coal companies. Other funds have divested from coal on business grounds. In 2014 Norway’s Government Pension Fund Global (GPFG), the worlds largest sovereign fund, divested from 114 companies, including 32 coal companies and several oil sands producers. GPFG stated that these companies where exposed to unacceptable levels of regulatory risk or other changes that would reduce future demand. To date, these divestments are too small to a¤ect fossil fuel companies’ cost of capital or their investment decisions. However, if green industrial policy is large enough to a¤ect current extraction decisions via the change in resource rent, then it is also large enough to alter incentives to invest in the discovery and development of new reserves, and to a¤ect the share price of fossil fuel companies. 9.5.2 The importance of rent The Paradox is relevant only for resources that have a substantial component of rent in their price. As noted in Chapter 6, rent is a signi…cant component of the price of oil, but a much smaller component of the price of coal. Resource-based commodities that have only a small component of rent are similar to standard commodities. The Green Paradox has only slight relevance for such commodities, but so does the theory of nonrenewable resources. 156 CHAPTER 9. THE “GREEN PARADOX” The Green Paradox concerns policies that directly a¤ect markets in the future, and only indirectly a¤ect current markets. Some green policies have direct e¤ects on current markets. For example, renewable fuel portfolio standards impose a minimum requirement on the fraction of energy produced using green technologies. Current subsidies to solar or wind energy increase the demand for green energy sources today, not merely in the future. These sources are substitutes for fossil fuels, so the portfolio standards and the subsidies decrease the current consumption of fossil fuels. These policies do not lead to a Green Paradox. 9.5.3 The importance of elasticities The signi…cance of the Green Paradox depends on the price elasticities of supply and demand for fossil fuels. At least in the short run, demand is quite inelastic. With a low elasticity of demand, a lower current price transfers income from fossil fuel owners to fuel consumers, and having modest e¤ects on current consumption. The Green Paradox is based on the assumption that a downward revision of beliefs about future energy prices would lead to a signi…cant increase in current supply. Technical constraints may limit the supply response, at least in the short run. Many resource …rms operate at or near capacity, and therefore have limited ability to quickly increase their supply. It may also be costly for them to shut down operations, lowering their ‡exibility to reduce supply. These considerations tend to reduce short run supply elasticities, reducing the signi…cance of the Green Paradox. 9.5.4 Strategic behavior The Paradox depends on the behavior of oil exporters, in particular OPEC, the oil cartel. OPEC is less powerful than a monopoly, because it faces a competitive fringe, but it is more sophisticated than the textbook monopoly because it understands that the demand function is not exogenous. The demand function in any period is predetermined by past events. Some past investments in infrastructure (e.g. highways) increase the current demand for fossil fuels, and other investments (e.g. development of the ethanol industry) decrease that demand. Because these investments have already occurred, the demand function (not the quantity demanded) at a point in time is predetermined. 9.5. ASSESSMENT OF THE PARADOX 157 OPEC observed that its oil embargo of the early 1970s changed behavior in importing countries, leading to increased conservation and the development of alternative supplies. OPEC wants to increase its rents, but it understands that the best way of doing that is not to extract every cent of consumer surplus available in the near term. OPEC’s long-term strategy includes maintaining a reliable and reasonably priced source of petroleum, to discourage changes in behavior or the development of alternative sources that would reduce its future demand. Green policies that reduce future demand can have ambiguous e¤ects on current OPEC strategic behavior. One possibility is that the presence of these policies makes OPEC redouble its e¤orts to create a reliable and reasonably priced source of oil, in order to counteract the e¤ect of the policies. The green policies encourage the development of green technologies, and OPEC may decide to try to o¤set that encouragement. How might OPEC go about achieving this goal? OPEC might think that the developers of the green technologies base their beliefs about future energy prices chie‡y on current energy prices. With this view, OPEC could o¤set the subsidies to green technologies, discouraging their development, by reducing current price. In that case, OPEC’s strategic response causes an even larger reduction in current prices, and thus a larger increase in current consumption than the standard Green Paradox suggests. Alternatively, OPEC might think that the developers of green technologies understand that future energy prices will depend on future stocks. With that view, OPEC could save more of its resource stock, in order to make credible its commitment to relatively low future prices. This commitment to low future prices requires a reduction in current extraction, thus working against the Green Paradox. A third possibility is that OPEC decides that e¤orts to discourage green substitutes for fossil fuel are doomed, thus diminishing its incentive to maintain stable and reasonable prices. If those e¤orts contributed to relatively low fossil fuel prices, then the reduction in those e¤orts increases current fossil fuel prices, working against the Green Paradox. That is, OPEC might decide that it is rational to exercise market power to the full extent possible, without concerning itself with the e¤ect that high current prices have on the future demand function. 158 9.6 CHAPTER 9. THE “GREEN PARADOX” Summary The Green Paradox illustrates the possibility that well-intentioned policies can back…re. The paradox potentially applies to policies that directly a¤ect future energy markets, e.g. carbon taxes that begin in the future, or subsidyinduced reductions in the costs of backstop technologies that will be used in the future. These policies directly a¤ect future demand for fossil fuels. Because of the dynamic linkages in resource markets, those future prices a¤ect resource owners’current supply decisions. Any policy that reduces future demand, makes it less attractive for resource owners to hold on to their stock. This kind of policy therefore tilts the extraction trajectory toward the present, increasing current extraction and reducing extraction in some future periods. If extraction costs depend on the remaining resource stock, these policies also reduce cumulative extraction. Lower cumulative extraction, and the associated reduction in cumulative carbon emissions, bene…t the climate. Tilting the extraction pro…le toward the present is likely to harm the climate. The higher earlier extraction likely increases the peak stock of atmospheric carbon, increasing the probability of a “catastrophe”. The tilted extraction pro…le also increases the speed of change of atmospheric stock. Society may be worse o¤, the more rapid this change occurs. Finally, if marginal damages are increasing in the level of the stock, the tilted extraction pro…le is likely to increase damages. The net e¤ect of policies that lower future demand for fossil fuels therefore depends on the balance between the e¤ects of lower cumulative extraction and of higher earlier extraction. The Green Paradox is valuable as a caution to policymakers, but practical considerations may limit its importance. The Green Paradox emphasizes the resource owners’incentives. Consideration of investment in resource exploration and development, and taking into account the externalities associated with investment in green alternatives, can overturn the paradoxical result. 9.7 Terms, study questions, and exercises Terms and concepts Research spillovers, business as usual, green industrial policy, green paradox, win-win opportunities, climate threshold, catastrophic change, stock and ‡ow 9.7. TERMS, STUDY QUESTIONS, AND EXERCISES 159 variables, decay rate, half-life of a stock, convex damages, predetermined versus exogenous. Study questions 1. (a) State the meaning of the Green Paradox in the context considered in this chapter (where green industrial policy reduces the cost of a low fossil renewable alternative to fossil fuels). (b) Discuss some of the reasons that the paradox might occur in the case where fossil fuel marginal extraction costs are constant. Your answer should include both a description of how, and an explanation of why, the industrial policy changes the extraction pro…le. It should also include a discussion of how and why this change in extraction pro…le might change climaterelated damage. (c) Suppose now that extraction costs increase as the remaining resource stock falls. How and why does this di¤erent assumption about extraction costs a¤ect the likelihood that the green paradox occurs? 2. Explain why the consideration of investment decisions other than the resource extraction decision might make the Green Paradox less likely. Exercises 1. Following the sketch in Box 9.3, provide a detailed argument showing that the extraction trajectory under the low-cost backstop lies above the trajectory under the high-cost backstop during the time that both are positive. Explain why this fact implies that exhaustion occurs earlier under the low-cost backstop. Sources The DICE model due to Nordhaus (2008) is probably the most widely used model that “integrates”the economy and a climate cycle Ricke and Caldeira (2014) provide evidence showing that major e¤ect of emissions occurs within the …rst decade of emissions release. Sinn (2008) (elaborated in Sinn 2012) is an early study of the Green Paradox. Hoel (2008 and 2012) studies the role of extraction costs and demand characteristics. 160 CHAPTER 9. THE “GREEN PARADOX” Gerlagh (2011) distinguishes between a “weak”and “strong”paradox. van der Ploeg and Withagen (2012) provide an in-depth analysis of the paradox. van der Werf and Di Maria (2012) survey the literature. Pittel, van der Ploeg and Withagen’s (2014) edited volume brings together recent contributions. Winter (2014) studies the Green Paradox in the presence of climate feedbacks. Ellerman and Montero (1998) examine the e¤ect of future emissions constraints on earlier sulfur emissions. Di Maria et al. (2013) discuss the Green Paradox in the context of the U.S. Acid Rain Program. Alberini et al. (2011) provide estimates of the elasticity of demand for electricity. Vennemo et al. (2006) estimate the health bene…ts to China of reducing CO2 emissions. Lal (2004) discusses a win-win possibility involving carbon sequestration and soil enhancement. Karp and Stevenson (2012) discuss green industrial policy. Chapter 10 Policy in a second best world Objectives Understand the basics of designing policy to correct market failures, and understand why well-intentioned policies can back…re when there are multiple market failures. Information and skills Explain and apply the Theory of the Second Best and the Principle of Targeting. Calculate and illustrate graphically the Pigouvian tax, for competitive markets. Describe a “collective action problem”. Understand the relation between the optimal tax under a monopoly and a competitive industry. Understand why two policies might be either complements or substitutes. The study of economics usually emphasizes perfectly competitive markets where there are no distortions, where the equilibrium is e¢ cient (Chapter 2.6). E¢ ciency means that no one can be made better o¤ without making someone else worse o¤; the e¢ cient equilibrium might not be ethically 161 162 CHAPTER 10. POLICY IN A SECOND BEST WORLD appealing. Market imperfections such as monopoly or externalities, if discussed at all, are usually relegated to a second tier of importance. A negative externality is an unpriced harm, or cost, borne by some part of society other than the …rm or individual that creates the harm. A positive externality is an unpriced bene…t. The emphasis on competitive markets is logical because we can make general statements about these, but not about markets with imperfections. To paraphrase Tolstoy: Perfect markets are all alike; every imperfect market is imperfect in its own way. Theory aims to uncover general truths, not to describe particular cases. In addition, the study of perfect markets yields valuable and counter-intuitive insights. For example, the theory of comparative advantage explains why trade can make all participants better o¤, even if they have very di¤erent levels of development. The Hotelling model explains why scarcity per se is not a rationale for government intervention. Finally, for many markets, the perfectly competitive paradigm is reasonably accurate. However, the emphasis on perfectly competitive markets sometimes seems like an elaborate justi…cation of Dr. Pangloss’claim that “Everything is for the best in this best of all possible worlds”. In fact, market failures are important, especially in natural resource settings. Economics can help us understand how market failures a¤ect outcomes, and how policy can remedy those failures. A “second best world”is a world in which there are two or more market failures. For example, there may be research spillovers, causing …rms to have inadequate incentive to undertake R&D, and at the same time a zero price on pollution, causing …rms to pollute excessively. There are obviously more than two market failures in our world: we inhabit a second best world. Much economic theory (and the …rst part of this book) ignores market failures altogether. Economic analysis of market failures (e.g. research spillovers), often uses models in which the particular failure of interest is the only one that exists. This procedure provides focus, but it can be misleading if two or more market failures interact in important ways. A collection of results having certain features in common, known as the “theory of the second best” (TOSB), sheds light on policy in the presence of multiple market failures. A “…rst best” policy corrects a distortion or achieves an objective (e.g. raising government revenue) in the most e¢ cient manner possible. We say that a policy is “second best” whenever it is not …rst best. Typically it is di¢ cult to rank all of the possible policies; we 10.1. SECOND BEST POLICIES AND TARGETING 163 might not even know which to include. Therefore, we may be unable to say whether a particular policy is 4’th or 17’th best, but able to say that it is not …rst best. We merely say that it is second best. The TOSB warns us against applying, in a second best world, the intuition obtained from the theory of perfect markets. A policy intervention that seems likely to improve welfare might make matters worse. In less extreme circumstances, a policy intervention might improve matters, but in the process might create unnecessary collateral damage. We also discuss an idea closely related to the TOSB: the Principle of Targeting. This principle provides commonsensical but still valuable advice about policy. The insights developed in this chapter are relevant to a broad range of both resource and non-resource markets. We discuss these insights in a fairly general but simple context, in order to make them clear and to emphasize their broad applicability. This material is important for the subsequent study of market failures and policy intervention in natural resource markets. Chapter 9 contains our …rst sustained discussion of market failures, related to climate change. Many other resource markets have similar market failures. Imperfect or non-existent property rights to …sh stocks or groundwater create externalities analogous to those associated with climate change. Those failures lead to overharvesting of …sh or excessive pumping of groundwater, much as the lack of property rights to the atmosphere leads to excessive emissions of greenhouse gasses. 10.1 Second best policies and targeting Objectives and skills Have an intuitive understanding of the Theory of the Second Best and the Principle of Targeting. Di¤erent types of policies might alleviate a particular social, economic, or environmental problem. The choice of policy depends on political and social considerations. In democracies, and under most other types of governance, no single social planner makes the policy decision based on his or her view of what is best. Even though this social planner is a …ction, there is value in trying to determine the policy that would be chosen by a planner who wants to maximize social welfare. That information provides a benchmark against which we can compare policies that are actually used. 164 CHAPTER 10. POLICY IN A SECOND BEST WORLD As noted in Chapter 2.6, the idea of social welfare is itself problematic. In our partial equilibrium setting without market failures and without taxes, we take social welfare to be the present discounted stream of the sum of producer and consumer surplus. A competitive equilibrium maximizes this measure of welfare; it leads to the same outcome as the …ctitious social planner. Here we are interested in market failures, so we need a broader de…nition of welfare. If, for example, the market failure arises from an unpriced externality such as pollution, we have to include the social cost of pollution and the …scal cost or bene…t of policies that attempt to remedy it. Subsidizing …rms to encourage reductions in pollution requires generating tax revenue, in order to …nance the subsidy, and therefore involves a …scal cost. A pollution tax, in contrast, generates tax revenue, making it possible to reduce taxes elsewhere in the economy, and therefore involves a …scal bene…t. These costs or bene…ts are components of social welfare, along with producer and consumer surplus and the costs or bene…ts arising from the externality. The …rst best policy maximizes social welfare; second best policies might increase social welfare, but they do so imperfectly, creating collateral damage or unnecessary costs. Examples: Trade restrictions and industrial policy Some activists promote trade restrictions as ways of achieving environmental or resource objectives. Trade may increase environmentally destructive production, as occurred with shrimp harvesting that kills turtles. In the 1990s the U.S. imposed a trade restriction to decrease, or at least redirect, U.S. shrimp imports, hoping to decrease turtle mortality. This and other trade restrictions might have environmental bene…ts, but trade restrictions are seldom the optimal type of policy to achieve these goals. Turtle mortality was a consequence but not the goal of shrimp harvesting. The policy objective was to decrease turtle mortality, not to decrease trade. An e¢ cient policy “targets”the environmental/resource objective. The U.S. trade restriction led to an international dispute that was resolved by the World Trade Organization (WTO). Although the WTO accepted that the U.S. had the right to use policies for the purpose of protecting international resources such as turtles, it also found that the U.S. policy contravened WTO law because it restricted trade unnecessarily. The dispute was resolved when the U.S. dropped its trade restriction but required exporting countries to use nets with “turtle excluding devices”that protected the turtles. 10.2. MONOPOLY + POLLUTION 165 The Green Paradox provides another example of a policy that may be poorly targeted to an objective. The policy goal is to reduce carbon emissions. Low cost and low carbon alternatives to fossil fuels might help to achieve that goal, but green industrial policy that promotes these alternatives potentially change the extraction pro…le in a way that harms the climate system. The net e¤ect of the green industrial policy might be positive. However, …rst best policies, such as emissions taxes or cap and trade, directly target the environmental objective of reducing carbon emissions. The Principle of Targeting These examples illustrate the Principle of Targeting (POT). This principle makes an intuitive recommendation. When faced with a market failure (i.e., a “distortion” such as an unpriced externality), it is best to use a policy that “targets” that distortion as closely as possible. In some respects, this principle (like much of economics!) is a tautology. It might be interpreted as enjoining the policy maker to use the best policy – hardly advice that anyone needs. However, the principle actually contains some subtle wisdom. Many policies in‡ict collateral damage in correcting a distortion, or cause people to reduce a distortion (e.g. lower pollution) ine¢ ciently. The POT reminds us to be aware of this collateral damage or ine¢ ciency, and to try to avoid it. In most cases, the application of the POT is straightforward. It is necessary to clearly identify the objective or the problem, and to distinguish features that cause the problem from those that are associated with it. In the trade example, the problem is not trade, but that turtles are killed in catching shrimp. In the Green Paradox example, the problem is carbon emissions, not an excessively high backstop cost. The POT tells us that the e¢ cient policy alters …shers’harvesting techniques in the …rst case, and reduces carbon emissions in the second. It is worth being able to identify the e¢ cient policy, even if social or political considerations prevent its adoption. 10.2 Monopoly + pollution Objectives and skills Use graphical methods to compare output under a social planner, a competitive …rm, and a monopoly, in the presence of an externality. Show how a tax alters output under competition and monopoly. 166 CHAPTER 10. POLICY IN A SECOND BEST WORLD p 20 18 16 14 12 10 8 B D 6 4 C 2 A 0 1 -2 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 q -4 Figure 10.1: A: the competitive equilibrium with no pollution tax. B: the competitive equilibrium with the optimal (Pigouvian) tax t = 6. C: the monopoly equilibrium with no pollution tax. D: the monopoly equilibrium with the non-optimal tax t = 6 Illustrate the possibility that a tax that induces competitive …rms to produce at the socially optimal level might lower welfare under a monopoly. A basic idea of the TOSB is a that an ill-advised policy, designed to alleviate some problem, might make another problem worse. The net e¤ect of the policy might be either harmful or bene…cial. One of the most famous, and easily illustrated, example of this possibility arises in a monopoly setting where production creates a negative externality, pollution. Figure 10.1 shows the inverse demand function p = 20 3q, the solid line, and the corresponding marginal revenue curve, M R = 20 6q, the dashed line. Average and marginal costs are constant at 2. Each unit of production (or consumption) creates $6 of environmental damages. In this example, pollution is proportional to output, and social costs are proportional to pollution. The private cost of production here is 2 and the social cost of production, which includes environmental damages, is 2 + 6 = 8. Reserving t for the time index, we use to represent a unit tax. When a policy, such as a tax, can be either positive or negative, we sometimes refer to it as a “tax/subsidy”. More commonly, we call it a tax, recognizing that a negative tax is a subsidy. An untaxed competitive industry sets price equal to marginal cost and produces at point A. The monopoly sets marginal revenue equal to marginal cost, and produces at point C. The optimal tax for the competitive industry, 10.3. COLLECTIVE ACTION AND LOBBYING 167 also known as the Pigouvian tax, is = 6. The socially optimal level of production and the price occur at point B. The tax = 6 “supports” (or “induces”) the socially optimal outcome: when competitive …rms face this tax, they produce at the socially optimal level. In general, the optimal tax causes …rms to face the social cost of production; it causes …rms to “internalize”the cost of pollution. If the monopoly where charged the same tax, = 6, it’s tax-inclusive cost of production also equals the social cost. The monopoly facing = 6 produces at point D. Absent the tax, the monopoly produces too little, relative to the socially optimal level: point C lies to the left of point B. The tax causes the monopoly to reduce output even more, lowering social welfare: the tax that is optimal in a competitive setting ( = 6) lowers social welfare if imposed on the monopoly. This example illustrates the basic point of the TOSB: a policy that improves matters in one circumstance might make things worse in another circumstance. In the competitive setting, there is a single distortion, arising from pollution. In the monopoly setting, there are two distortions, one arising from pollution and the second arising from the exercise of market power. A tax that …xes the …rst distortion makes the second one worse. For our example, the net e¤ect of the policy that is optimal under competition, lowers welfare under monopoly. For this example, the optimal policy under a monopoly is a subsidy (a negative tax). A caveat Our example uses two assumptions: (i) a …xed relation between output and pollution, and (ii) a …xed relation between pollution and social marginal cost. Assumption (i), which means that the only way to reduce pollution is to reduce output, is not realistic; usually it is possible to reduce pollution without reducing output, by using a more costly production method. Despite its lack of plausibility, we adopt this assumption here and later in the text because it makes it simple to deliver the basic message. Assumption (ii) also makes the message simple to deliver, but it can easily be dropped. 10.3 Collective action and lobbying Objective and skills Use a payo¤ matrix to identify a noncooperative Nash equilibrium. 168 CHAPTER 10. POLICY IN A SECOND BEST WORLD Illustrate the collective action problem that arises with lobbying. Understanding the collective action problem helps in making sense of political outcomes. A collective action is a costly action taken by a group, for the bene…t of the group. The “problem”is that people prefer other members of their group to incur the costs, while they share the bene…ts. In some cases, society imposes a solution to this problem by forcing group members to contribute, provided that a su¢ ciently large fraction of the group have voted in favor of the action. For example, the U.S. Agricultural Marketing Agreement Act of 1937 authorizes “marketing orders”for some commodities. Producers are obliged to participate in these marketing orders, which can require minimal quality levels or limited production (in order to maintain high prices). About half the U.S. states require workers to pay union dues to a legally recognized union, on the ground that all workers bene…t from union representation of their workplace. “Right to work”laws remove that requirement, making union membership, and thus union dues, voluntary. Real world policies emerge from a political process, not as the dictate of a benevolent social planner. Political lobbying or naked corruption a¤ects these outcomes. The Sunlight Foundation estimates that in the U.S. between 2007 –2012, 200 companies spent $5.8 billion in lobbying and campaign contributions, and received $4.4 trillion in federal support or contracts: $760 for each dollar contributed. Changes in U.S. law, notably Citizens United, make it easier to use money to in‡uence outcomes. In 2014, Transparency International (www.transparency.org) ranked the U.S. as the 17th least corrupt out of 175 countries. Not all lobbying is corruption, but lobbying uses money and connections to in‡uence outcomes. An example illustrates lobbying and the collective action problem. Society at large may bene…t from reduced pollution, but this reduction imposes costs on some groups. Here we take the extreme case where a group of …rms incur all of the costs and consumers obtain all of the bene…ts of a particular emissions policy. Both groups can lobby to in‡uence the probability that this policy is implemented, but lobbying is expensive. Both consumers and …rms face a “collective action problem” in deciding whether to lobby; the collective action is the lobbying e¤ort. Suppose that the particular emissions policy increases consumer welfare by 100 units and reduces …rm welfare by 50 units, yielding a net bene…t to society of 50 units. Absent lobbying e¤ort, the probability that the policy is implemented equals 0.5, so the expected bene…t to society (the probability 10.3. COLLECTIVE ACTION AND LOBBYING 169 that the bene…t occurs times the level of the bene…t if it does occur) is 25. If only one group spends 10 units on lobbying, that group has its preferred outcome with certainty. If both groups spend 10 units on lobbying, their e¤orts cancel each other, leaving unchanged the probability that the policy is implemented, but wasting 20 units of welfare. Table 1 shows the payo¤ matrix if each group is represented by a single agent who can enforce the decision whether to lobby. consumersn …rms …rms lobby …rms do not lobby consumers lobby (40; 35) (90; 50) consumers do not lobby (0; 10) (50; 25) Table 101: Payo¤ matrix for the lobbying game. First element in an ordered pair shows consumers’expected payo¤, second element shows …rms’expected payo¤. The …rst element of each ordered pair shows consumers’expected payo¤ for a combination of actions, and the second element shows producers’payo¤. For example, if both groups lobby, consumers’expected payo¤ is 0:5 (100) 10 = 40, and …rms’ expected payo¤ is 0:5 (50) 10 = 35. This game is an example of the Prisoners’ Dilemma. Both groups are better o¤ if they forswear lobbying, but if one group decides not to lobby, the other group wants to lobby. The only (Nash) equilibrium in this game is for both groups to lobby. This payo¤ matrix assumes that each group has solved the collective action problem: each acts as a uni…ed agent, i.e. it has delegated authority to a single agent who decides, on the group’s behalf, whether to lobby. This assumption is unrealistic; there may be millions of consumers and only a few …rms. The bene…ts of lobbying are more dispersed for consumers, and each consumer faces a great deal of uncertainty about whether other consumers will contribute to the lobbying e¤ort. Producer groups are legal for the purpose of representing the industry’s interests to legislators, and they can help to coordinate the individual …rm’s lobbying contributions. In this setting, …rms are more likely than consumers to solve their collective action problem. For this example, society’s expected payo¤ is 25 if neither group solves the collective action problem, so that neither lobbies. It is 5 if both groups solve the collective action problem, so that both lobby. Society’s payo¤ is -10 if only …rms solve the collective action problem. A group’s ability to 170 CHAPTER 10. POLICY IN A SECOND BEST WORLD solve its collective action problem may or may not bene…t society. In this example, society’s payo¤ is highest if only consumers solve their collective action problem, and it is lowest if only producers solve their collection action problem –the opposite of what would be likely to occur in this situation. Renewable Fuel Standard In 2005 the U.S. introduced a Renewable Fuel Standard (RFS), requiring annual minimum consumption levels of di¤erent types biofuels; 2007 legislation increased these levels. The Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) implements the policy by estimating gasoline demand in the next year and dividing annual targets for the di¤erent biofuels by the estimated gasoline consumption, to obtain a ratio i for biofuel i. Gasoline producers are required to use i gallons of biofuel i for each gallon of gasoline they produce. These producers therefore face a blending constraint that increases their cost of production, because the biofuels are more expensive than gasoline. Proponents of this policy justify it chie‡y using an “infant industry” argument. The idea is that biofuels will eventually be important both as low carbon alternatives to fossil fuels, and as alternatives to foreign sources of petroleum. Because the current state of technology and infrastructure would not enable this industry to survive under market conditions, government policy is needed to protect this “infant”until it grows into a mature industry. Infant industry arguments go back at least to the early 1800s, when they were used to justify trade restrictions. Many opponents of the RFS begin as skeptics of the infant industry argument in general, because of experiences where infants fail to mature. In addition, the applicability of the infant industry argument is questionable in this case, because the RFS has chie‡y promoted the production of corn-based ethanol, for which the technology was already mature.1 The RFS emphasis on corn-based ethanol has two major disadvantages, in addition to having low potential to encourage new technology. First, it leads to a small, and by some estimates non-existent reduction in carbon emissions. Second, it diverts a major food crop from food to fuel, likely increasing food prices and possibly worsening food insecurity in some parts 1 After 2015, ethanol produced using cellulosic material, including the inedible part of corn and special crops such as switchgrass, is scheduled to become more important in the RFS. Cellulosic biofuels rely on an immature technology, where government support can potentially lead to large improvements. However, the RFS’s support for corn-based ethanol does nothing to promote the development of cellulosic biofuels. 10.4. POLICY COMPLEMENTS AND SUBSTITUTES 171 of the world. The policy has also encouraged farmers to cultivate marginal land that would otherwise likely have been left fallow under a conservation program. Recent evidence estimates that carbon reductions achieved using the RFS are about three times as costly as the reduction that could have been achieved under an e¢ cient policy such as an emissions tax or cap and trade. An important consequence of the RFS was to provide large transfers from the general public (in the form of higher fuel prices) to corn growers, likely with little environmental or technological bene…t. The RFS was estimated to increase U.S. fuel costs by $10 billion per year. Why did the U.S. government implement an ine¢ cient policy instead of an e¢ cient policy? Holland et al. (2015) estimate the transfers resulting from the RFS at the congressional district level, and simulate the transfers that would have resulted from the cap and trade proposal under the Waxman-Markey bill in 2009. A provision in Waxman-Markey required that fuels eligible for the RFS produce greater carbon reduction than currently achieved by corn-based ethanol. Thus, Waxman-Markey would have reduced the transfers that corn producers receive under the RFS. Not surprisingly, representatives tend to vote their constituents’ interest. Those from districts that bene…t under the RFS were more likely to oppose Waxman-Markey, and those from districts that would have bene…ted under Waxman-Markey were more likely to vote in favor of it. Representatives from districts bene…tting from RFS, which would have been harmed by Waxman-Markey, also received greater campaign contributions from groups opposing the bill. Although the cap and trade policy is more e¢ cient than the RFS, the gains from the latter are concentrated in a small number of districts, whereas the bene…ts of the former were more widely dispersed (as in the numerical example above). It was therefore easier to generate e¤ective lobbying opposing Waxman-Markey than to generate lobbying in its support. 10.4 Policy complements and substitutes Objectives and skills Understand why a tax and a subsidy have the same e¤ect on a polluter’s incentives. 172 CHAPTER 10. POLICY IN A SECOND BEST WORLD Understand the political and the economic disadvantages of a subsidy, compared to a tax. Understand the arguments for and against subsidizing R&D in “green technologies”. Determine the socially optimal pollution tax when marginal costs increase with the level of pollution. Determine whether two policies are complements or substitutes. The previous section illustrates the possibility that a socially bene…cial policy might be blocked in a political equilibrium, and provides an example where this actually occurred. Policies typically have di¤erent e¤ects on di¤erent groups of producers and consumers. The success of these groups in the political competition to implement or block a policy may have little relation to the social merits of a policy. E¢ cient policies might be politically infeasible. In this case, other feasible policies might seem like reasonable alternatives, even if they are less e¤ective or more costly. We continue to assume that the social goal is to reduce excessive pollution. The numerical example in Section 10.3 illustrates why a pollution tax might not be a political equilibrium. What are the alternative policies? Subsidizing pollution reduction The most obvious alternative is to subsidize …rms if they reduce pollution instead of taxing them if they create pollution. A …rm has the same incentive to reduce pollution if it is taxed $1 for each unit of pollution, or given a subsidy of $1 for each unit that it reduces pollution (“abates”) relative to some baseline. (“Abatement”is de…ned as the reduction of pollution.) With the tax, a unit of pollution creates a direct cost to …rms; with the subsidy, a unit of pollution creates an opportunity cost to …rms. These two types of costs have the same e¤ect on the …rm’s incentives, so (in principle) the two policies achieve the same level of pollution. There are both political and economic impediments to using the subsidy instead of the tax. The political impediment is that the subsidy imposes a cost on taxpayers; it involves a transfer from general tax revenue to a speci…c group of …rms. Even if the reduced pollution is worth this cost, politicians 10.4. POLICY COMPLEMENTS AND SUBSTITUTES 173 may have a hard time explaining to voters why they should tax themselves to pay …rms not to do something that is socially harmful. The economic impediment is that raising revenue by means of taxes typically creates additional costs, above the direct distributional e¤ect of taking income away from a group. These additional costs are called deadweight costs, a subject discussed in Chapter 11. The deadweight costs may be 20 - 30% of the revenue raised. The distinction between a transfer and a deadweight cost is important. If the government takes $1 from Mary to give to Jiangfeng, this is merely a transfer; it might make Mary unhappy, but it makes Jiangfeng happy, and is not a cost to the economy. However, if the government has to take $1.25 from Mary in order to give $1 to Jiangfeng, there is a $0.25 cost to the economy. This situation is sometimes described by saying that the government makes transfers using a leaky bucket. Due to our assumption of a …xed relation between pollution and output, the only way to reduce one is to reduce the other. Therefore, there is no deadweight cost in taxing the polluting sector. However, taxing other sectors in order to …nance a subsidy for the polluting sector typically does create a deadweight cost. As an illustration, suppose that the deadweight cost associated with general taxes (outside the polluting industry) is 25% of revenue raised by a tax. In that case, …nancing a $1 subsidy to this polluting industry requires rasing $1 of tax revenue elsewhere, creating a deadweight cost of $0.25. If, instead, the polluting industry is taxed $1, and that tax revenue transferred to general funds, then other taxes can be reduced by $1.00, saving society the deadweight cost $0.25. Here, replacing a $1 pollution tax with a $1 abatement subsidy increases social costs by $0.50. This example illustrates why taxing pollution is likely more e¢ cient than subsidizing abatement. Subsidizing R&D in “green technologies” If pollution taxes are politically infeasible because of the collective action problem, and subsidies to reduce pollution are both politically and economically problematic, it is natural to seek alternatives. Green industrial policy, such as a subsidy to develop and implement low-carbon alternatives to fossil fuels, is often proposed as an alternative to a carbon tax or a cap and trade policy. The American Enterprise Institute and the Brookings Institute, a conservative and a liberal think tank, respectively, both endorsed research and development (R&D) subsidies for green technology as an alternative 174 CHAPTER 10. POLICY IN A SECOND BEST WORLD to carbon taxes. These green policies subsidize …rms for doing something socially useful (developing new technologies) instead of for refraining from doing something socially harmful (polluting), and therefore encounter less political resistance than a pollution subsidy. These green policies still involve subsidies, and give rise to deadweight costs, as discussed above. They also invite the criticism that the government does a poor job of picking winners.2 Countering these objections, proponents of green industrial policy argue that the subsidies address market failures other than excessive pollution, such as cross-…rm research spillovers (a positive externality) that leads to insu¢ cient investment in green R&D. Regardless of the merits of these opposing arguments, it is reasonable to ask whether green policies are really an alternative to, i.e. a substitute for emissions taxes, or if instead they should be regarded as a complement to emissions taxes. The terms complements and substitutes are familiar from demand analysis. Beer and pretzels are probably complements, because eating pretzels increases our marginal utility of beer. A big screen TV and a sports car are perhaps substitutes, because our marginal utility of driving the hot car may be lower if we have the option of watching the fantastic TV screen. Two policies are said to be substitutes if the implementation of one makes the other less valuable to society; they are complements if the implementation of one makes the other more valuable. Chapter 9 shows that green industrial policies might aggravate the pollution problem. Here we develop the closely related idea, that instead of being a substitute for a carbon tax, green industrial policy might make the carbon tax more rather than less vital to society. In this case, the policies are said to be complements. Competitive resource …rms’equilibrium condition is pt @c (xt ; yt ) @c (xt ; yt ) = Rt ; or pt = + Rt ; @y @y (10.1) where, as in previous chapters, @c(x@yt ;yt ) is extraction costs and Rt is the …rms’period-t rent. Recall that Rt is an opportunity cost, the amount lost by extracting a unit of resource in period t instead of at some other time. Thus, @c(x@yt ;yt ) + Rt is the “combined” marginal extraction cost, including both the standard marginal cost and the opportunity cost. Chapter 5.2 2 For example, subsidies to Solyndra, a manufacturer of components to solar panels, cost U.S. taxpayers $500 million. Solyndra went bankrupt in 2011. 10.4. POLICY COMPLEMENTS AND SUBSTITUTES 175 shows that Rt equals the …rms’present discounted value of future rents, plus any cost reduction due to a higher stock. Chapter 9 explains why green industrial policy is likely to reduce future rents, thus reducing the …rms’ current (period-t) rent, Rt . Increasing marginal costs of pollution As with the example in Chapter 10.2, we assume that one unit of production (here, extraction) creates one unit of pollution: the only way to reduce pollution is to make a corresponding reduction in output. In the previous example, we took the marginal damage resulting from pollution to be a constant. Here we consider the case where the marginal damage increases with the level of extraction. If extraction (= emissions) is y, then in this example, damages equal y 2 , so marginal damages equal 2y. Where marginal damage are constant, the Pigouvian tax equals that constant. Here, however, where marginal damages depend on the level of extraction, the Pigouvian tax also depends on the level of extraction. In this case we …nd the Pigouvian tax by: 1. Identifying the socially optimal level of extraction, the level that equates price to social marginal costs (= marginal extraction costs, plus the opportunity cost, Rt , plus marginal damage, 2yt .) 2. Once we have found socially optimal level of output, denoted yt , we set the Pigouvian tax equal to the marginal external cost, 2yt for this example. The e¤ect of rent on the Pigouvian tax Figure 10.2 illustrates the case where the …rm has constant marginal extraction costs, @c(x@yt ;yt ) = C.3 Suppose that at a point in time the private combined marginal cost is C + Rt = 10, shown by the solid ‡at line in the …gure. For our example, the social marginal cost equals the private marginal 3 This …gure relies on two assumptions: green industrial policies reduce rent, and marginal damages are increasing in emissions. The …rst assumption is plausible, but in the context of climate change, the second is not. Climate damages are associated with the pollution stock, not with emissions in a single period. This example is useful for illustrating the di¤erence between policy complements and substitutes, but it is not “realistic”for the climate application. 176 CHAPTER 10. POLICY IN A SECOND BEST WORLD cost plus the (external) environmental marginal damage, 10 + 2y. If rent falls by …ve units (e.g. due to the introduction of a green industrial policy that reduces the cost of a backstop), from Rt to Rt0 = Rt 5, the private combined marginal cost, and also the social marginal cost, falls by 5 units. The upwardly sloping solid curve in Figure 10.2 is the graph of 2y+C +Rt , the social marginal cost, equal to marginal damage plus the private cost (the cost of extraction, C, plus the opportunity cost, R). A …ve-unit reduction in rent causes this combined social marginal cost to shift from the positively sloped solid line to the dashed line. This reduction in social cost increases the socially optimal level of production from the intersection shown at point A, to the intersection shown at point B. The reduction in rent decreases the combined social cost of extraction, thereby increasing the socially optimal level of extraction. Because marginal damages increase with the level of extraction, the optimal level of marginal damages increase with the fall in resource rent. As a consequence, the optimal tax also increases with the reduction in rent. This result might seem counter-intuitive, but it holds quite generally: where marginal damages increase with the level of extraction (or in other contexts, with the level of production), a decrease in …rms’ marginal cost leads to an increase in the optimal tax. When …rms’marginal cost falls, they tend to produce more, and the higher production leads to higher marginal damages and a higher optimal tax. The Pigouvian tax induces the …rm to face the social (instead of the private) cost of production, thereby giving …rms the correct incentive to produce at the socially optimal level. If the …rm faces a constant tax and has private costs (inclusive of opportunity cost, its rent) equal to 10, its private cost equals social costs if and only if the tax equals the vertical distance from point A to 10. The Pigouvian tax thus equals this distance, which we denote A . If the …rm’s rent falls so that its rent-inclusive private cost now equals 5, the Pigouvian tax equals the vertical distance from point B to the ‡at dashed line; we denote this tax as B . It is apparent from the …gure, and easy to demonstrate using either geometry or algebra, that B > A . The decrease in rent increases the optimal tax. In this case, an emissions tax and a green industrial policy that reduces rent are complements, not substitutes. 10.5. SUMMARY p 177 25 20 A 15 B 10 5 0 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 q Figure 10.2: External marginal costs = 2q. Solid positively sloped curve shows social marginal costs when private marginal cost C +Rt = 10. Socially optimal production occurs at A. If private marginal costs fall to C + Rt0 = 5, socially optimal production occurs at B. When private costs fall, the optimal tax increases. Relation between this example and the TOSB This tax example illustrates the general possibility that policies that appear to be either unrelated or substitutes might be, on closer examination, complements. The TOSB is based on a related idea: connections that are not apparent may nevertheless be important. The tax example shows that green industrial policy, instead of making carbon taxes less important, might instead make them more important. The TOSB warns that in the presence of two or more distortions, or market failures, correcting only one of those distortions might exacerbate the other distortion to such an extent that welfare falls. Of course, if it is possible to correct all of the distortions, doing so increases welfare. 10.5 Summary This chapter introduces the notion of a second-best policy or an outcome: one that is not optimal, or “…rst best”. The Principle of Targeting recognizes the importance of carefully matching policies and objectives. A Pigouvian tax causes competitive …rms to internalize what would otherwise be an ex- 178 CHAPTER 10. POLICY IN A SECOND BEST WORLD ternality for the …rm. For example, a Pigouvian tax causes …rms to take into account the social cost of pollution when making its production decisions. Two policies are said to be substitutes if the implementation of one policy makes the other policy less important, or decreases the optimal level of the other policy; they are complements if the implementation of one policy makes the other more important, or increases the optimal level of the other policy. The theory of the second best (TOSB) and the Principle of Targeting (POT) are deceptively simple ideas, with important economic implications. The TOSB reminds us that in economies, “the hip bone is connected to the shoulder bone”, although perhaps not directly. Simply because markets connect apparently unconnected outcomes, a policy that reduces one market failure may, in the presence of a second market failure, actually lower welfare. We illustrated this result using an example of a monopoly who produces pollution, and showed that moving from the zero emissions tax to the Pigouvian tax might either increase or decrease social welfare. This possibility is not surprising: a policy that is optimal in one setting (perfect competition) might be harmful in another (monopoly). The POT reminds us to beware of collateral damage in setting policy, and to attempt to select policies that do not in‡ict such damage. There is sometimes the risk of examples that are intended to illuminate a theoretical issue being interpreted as policy prescription. This chapter uses a particular component of green industrial policy –subsidizing the development of low cost alternatives to fossil fuels –as a means of illustrating the TOSB and of explaining the di¤erence between policies that are complements or substitutes. Our example does not put green industrial policy in a favorable light. However, the example was not designed to provide a balanced view of green industrial policy. The TOSB can also be used to construct arguments in support of green industrial policy. For example, the development of some green technologies may provide positive spillovers that encourage still better technologies, making it economically attractive to phase out fossil fuel use early enough to avert serious climate damage. Economic theory can help identify the right questions to ask about a policy. Except in rather extreme cases, theory cannot provide de…nitive judgment of policy. Where it does appear to provide a de…nitive judgement, the reader should question whether theory has been inappropriately applied. 10.6. TERMS, STUDY QUESTIONS AND EXERCISES, 10.6 179 Terms, study questions and exercises, Terms and concepts Theory of the second best, Principle of Targeting, Pigouvian tax, a tax “supports” or “induces” an outcome, internalize an externality, collective action problem, payo¤ matrix, Nash equilibrium, Prisoners Dilemma, Renewable Fuels Standard, deadweight loss, abatement, increasing marginal pollution costs, policy complements and substitutes. Study questions 1. Use a graphical example (and a static model) to show that the Pigouvian tax that corrects a production-related externality (e.g. pollution) in a competitive setting might lower social welfare if applied to a monopoly. 2. (a) Consider a static model. Suppose that inverse demand is 10 q, …rms are competitive with constant average = marginal costs C, and pollution-related damages (arising from output) are q + 12 q 2 , with > 0 What is marginal damage? (b) What is the socially optimal level of production and consumer price, and what is the Pigouvian tax? (c) How does the Pigouvian tax change with ? (d) Provide the economic explanation of this relation. 3. (a) Continue with the model in question #2. Suppose that there is a policy that reduces C, e.g. by making production more e¢ cient. How does this reduction in C alter the Pigouvian tax that you identi…ed in question #2b? (b) Are the two policies (the pollution tax and the policy that reduces C) complements are substitutes? (c) How would the answer to part (b) have changed if = 0? Explain. 4. You are in a conversation with someone who correctly states that, in a particular market, international trade increases production in poorer countries with weaker environmental standards, thereby increasing a global pollutant (i.e. a pollutant that causes worldwide damage, not just damage in the location where production occurs). The person claims that a trade ban is a good remedy for this problem. Regardless of your actual views, use concepts from this chapter to argue against this person’s proposal. 180 CHAPTER 10. POLICY IN A SECOND BEST WORLD 5. Ignoring the possibility of the Green Paradox, what are the principle arguments (actually used in the policy debate) for an against a subsidy that makes it cheaper to reduce pollution? Exercises 1. Suppose that consumers of the product bear the cost of pollution. The model then contains three types of agents: the …rm, consumers, and taxpayers. Taxpayers bene…t from tax revenue and they do not like having to pay the cost of subsidies. Inverse demand is p = 20 3q, private average = marginal cost is 2, and environmental damage per unit of output is 6. A monopoly chooses the level of sales. Using a …gure like Figure 10.1 identify graphically (by shading in appropriate areas) the change in welfare of the three types of agent when a regulator imposes a unit tax of = 6. 2. For this example, identify (graphically) the socially optimal tax/subsidy under the monopoly. That is, identify the tax/subsidy that induces the monopoly to produce at the socially optimal level. 3. Change the example in Exercise 1 to p = 20 0:4q. (Replace the slope 3 by 0:4) Other parameter values are unchanged. (a) Does this change make demand more or less elastic? (b) Find the optimal pollution tax for the competitive …rm. (c) Find the optimal pollution tax under the monopoly. (d) Provide an economic explanation for the relation between the optimal tax and the slope of the inverse demand function, under both a competitive …rm and a monopoly. 4. Suppose that (private) constant marginal costs is c, each unit of pollution creates d dollars of social cost (external to the …rm), and the demand function is demand = Q (p). (a) What is the optimal pollution tax for the competitive industry? (b) Use the formula for marginal revenue (a function of price and elasticity of demand) to …nd the equation for the optimal tax (or subsidy) under a monopoly. (c) Now suppose that Q = p with > 1. Use your formula from part (b) to …nd the optimal tax/subsidy under the monopoly. (d) Provide an economic explanation for the relation between the optimal tax/subsidy under the monopoly and . 10.6. TERMS, STUDY QUESTIONS AND EXERCISES, 181 5. Suppose that demand is p = 20 q, and marginal environmental damages equal 2 + q, where the parameter 0. Suppose that green industrial policy causes private costs, de…ned as @c(x@yt ;yt ) + Rt , to fall from 10 to 5. (a) Discuss the economic interpretation of the parameter . In particular, explain the di¤erence in the model with = 0 and with > 0. (b) Find the socially optimal level of production when private costs equal 10. Find the optimal (Pigouvian) tax in this case. (Both of these are functions of .) (c) Now …nd the optimal production level and the Pigouvian tax when private marginal costs fall to 5. (d) Write the di¤erence in the Pigouvian tax, in these two settings, as a function of . (e) Describe and explain the e¤ect of on the change in the Pigouvian tax arising from the change in private costs. 6. Inverse demand is p = 20 3q, private average = marginal cost is 2, and environmental damage per unit of output is 6. There is a 10% deadweight cost of raising public funds. This cost is symmetric in the following sense: the social value of raising $1 of tax revenue is $1.10, and the social cost of raising $1 in revenue to pay for a subsidy (or anything else) is also $1.10. Explain the qualitative e¤ect, on the optimal policies under competition and monopoly, of the social cost of raising public funds. Sources Lipsey and Lancaster (1956) is the classic article on TOSB. Okum (1975) is credited with the “leaky bucket”metaphor. Fowlie (2009) and Holland (2012) provide recent applications of the TOSB related to environmental regultion. Tritch (2015) discusses the statistics on U.S. lobbying provided by the Sunlight Foundation. Auerbach and Hines (2002) survey the literature on taxation and e¢ ciency. Prakash and Potoski (2007) provide examples of collective action in environmental contexts. Winter (2014) shows that carbon taxes and green industrial policy are likely to be policy complements. Leonhardt 2010 describes the political popularity of green industrial policy. 182 CHAPTER 10. POLICY IN A SECOND BEST WORLD Holland et al. (2015) study the political economy connections between the RFS and the Waxman - Markey bill. Bryce (2015) provides the estimated cost to motorists ($10 billion/year) of the RFS. Chapter 11 Taxes: an introduction Objectives Understand how taxes a¤ect equilibrium outcomes and welfare in a static setting. Information and skills Know the de…nitions of unit and ad valorem taxes. Be able to use graphs and mathematics to determine the e¤ect of taxes on equilibrium prices. Understand the de…nition of tax incidence and be able to explain why a tax on consumers or on producers are “equivalent”in a closed economy. Understand why this equivalence does not hold in an open economy. Be able to illustrate graphically the relation between tax incidence and supply and demand elasticities. Be able to use graphs to identify tax-induced changes in consumer and producer surplus, and to identify the deadweight cost of a tax. Understand the meaning of a “cap and trade”policy, and know the relation between the equilibrium price of permits, and a tax that induces the same level of pollution as the cap. 183 184 CHAPTER 11. TAXES: AN INTRODUCTION Before examining the e¤ect of taxes in the resource setting, readers should understand their e¤ect in the simpler static setting, the topic of this chapter. By changing prices, taxes change consumer and producer behavior. Tobacco taxes discourages smoking, and carbon taxes would reduce carbon emissions. The static model of a competitive economy has a downward sloping demand curve and an upward sloping marginal cost (= supply) curve. The intersection of these two curves determines the equilibrium price and quantity. Provided that neither the demand nor the supply curve is ‡at, producers and consumers both obtain surplus in this equilibrium. A tax, levied on either …rms or consumers, changes the equilibrium price and quantity, changing consumers’ and producers’ levels of surplus. The revenue raised from a tax makes it possible to reduce other taxes while funding the same level of government expenditures. There are three types of agents in our model: consumer welfare depends on consumer surplus; producer welfare depends on producer surplus; and taxpayer welfare depends on tax revenue. Many people belong to two or even all three of these groups. The sum of consumer surplus, producer surplus, and tax revenue is our measure of social welfare. Understanding the e¤ect of taxes in the familiar static model of a competitive …rm is worthwhile for its own sake, and also necessary for understanding the e¤ect of taxes applied to natural resources, studied in Chapter 12. We emphasize competitive markets, dealing only in passing with monopolistic markets. We also emphasize the case where the economy is closed: there is no international trade in the taxed commodity. This assumption means that domestic supply equals domestic demand.1 11.1 Types of taxes Objectives and skills Introduce and de…ne a unit tax, an ad valorem tax, and a pro…ts tax. 1 Appendix F contains technical material related to this chapter, including: algebraic veri…cation of tax equivalence in the closed economy; an example showing that tax equivalence does not hold in an open economy; details on the approximation of tax incidence, deadweight loss, and tax revenue, and details related to the material on cap and trade. 11.2. TAX INCIDENCE AND TAX EQUIVALENCE 185 A unit tax, denoted , is measured in units of currency, such as dollars or Euros. If producers receive $p per unit sold, and the government imposes a tax of = $6 per unit, consumers pay p + 6 per unit. The unit tax is $6. An ad valorem tax, denoted , is measured as a rate. If producers receive $p per unit sold, and the government imposes an ad valorem tax of = 0:2, consumers pay (1 + 0:2) p. The ad valorem tax is a fraction; we multiply by 100 to express the tax as a percent. There is a simple relation between the unit and the ad valorem tax. If producers receive the price p and one group of consumers pays a unit tax and another group of consumers pays an ad valorem tax , the two groups pay the same price if p + = (1 + ) p. Thus, two taxes yield the same consumer price if and only if = p. We can work with whichever type of tax we want, and easily translate one type of tax into another. For the monopoly, the relation between a unit and an ad valorem tax is slightly more complicated. Exercises ask students to investigate taxes under a monopoly. A pro…ts tax takes a percent of pro…ts. Exercises ask students to investigate the e¤ect of a pro…ts tax. 11.2 Tax incidence and tax equivalence Objectives and skills Understand the meaning of tax incidence and tax equivalence. Ability to explain intuitively why producer and consumer taxes are equivalent in a closed economy. We assume that people are “rational”, in the sense that their willingness to buy a commodity depends on the price they pays, not the precise manner in which the price is calculated. For example, an informed consumer is just as likely to buy a commodity priced at $1.10 “out the door”as a commodity marked at $1.00 that requires payment of a 10% sales tax at the cash register. In both cases, the …nal price equals $1.10. A …eld known as behavioral economics shows that people sometimes react di¤erently to these two settings, and in that sense are not rational. It might seem that it should matter whether a tax is levied on consumers or producers (on which group has the “statutory obligation” of paying the tax). However, in a closed economy, the equilibrium price and quantity, 186 CHAPTER 11. TAXES: AN INTRODUCTION and thus the consumer and producer surplus and the tax revenue, are the same regardless of whether the tax is levied on consumers or producers. The consumer and producer taxes are “equivalent”. Both producers and consumers “e¤ectively”end up paying part of the tax. What does it mean to say that one agent, e.g. producers, “e¤ectively” pays part of the tax that is levied on the other agent, e.g. consumers? Suppose that in the absence of a tax, the equilibrium price is $12 and the supply and demand is 100 units. Suppose that a tax of $2 per unit is imposed on consumers. Does the imposition of this tax mean that the price consumers pay rises to $12+$2=$14? In general, the answer is “no”. The tax does increase the price that consumers pay, but (in general) this higher price decreases the amount that they demand. In order for producers to want to decrease the amount that they supply, the price that producers receive must fall. The increase in consumer price, as a percent (or fraction) of the tax is called the consumer incidence of the tax, and the decrease in producer price, as a percent (or fraction) of the tax is the producer incidence. Suppose that the $2 tax causes the tax-inclusive price that consumers face to rise from $12 to an equilibrium of $13.50. This higher price reduces their demand. In order for supply to fall by enough to maintain supply equal to demand, the price that producers receive must have fallen. In this example, it must have fallen to $11.50, because the tax drives a $2 wedge between the consumer (tax-inclusive) price and the producer price. The di¤erence in the tax-inclusive price paid by consumers and the price received by producers is $13.50-$11.50=$2, the amount of the unit tax. Consumers “e¤ectively”pay the share 1:5 13:5 12 = = 0:75; tax 2 or 75% of the tax, and producers “e¤ectively”pay the remaining 25% of the tax. In this example, the tax incidence on consumers is 75% and the tax incidence on producers is 25%. In general, the tax incidence depends on the elasticities of supply and demand, a relation we discuss below. However, the tax incidence and the equilibrium quantity and price do not depend on whether the tax is directly levied on consumers or producers. This equivalence between the producer and consumer taxes arises simply because, in a closed economy (no international trade) supply equals demand. 11.3. AN APPLICATION TO ENVIRONMENTAL POLICY 11.3 187 An application to environmental policy Objectives and skills Introduce the “Polluter Pays Principle”. Understand the relation between this Principle and the tax equivalence result. The equivalence of producer and consumer taxes is potentially important to environmental policy; it implies that it may not matter whether an externality is corrected using a tax on production or on consumption. That equivalence appears to undercut the Polluter Pays Principle, which is based on the idea that it is important which agent –the polluter or the pollutee – directly pays for the damage caused by pollution. If we think of consumers as being a proxy for the agent that su¤ers from the pollution, the principle seems to imply that it would matter whether the tax is levied on consumption or production. However, the equivalence between these two taxes implies that it is immaterial whether a consumer or producer tax is used. In this (limited) sense, the Polluter Pays Principle sets up a meaningless distinction. In order to make the point that the Polluter Pays Principle is sometimes irrelevant, consider the case where each unit of production creates $2 worth of environmental damage. This damage is external to the …rm, meaning that the …rm does not take the damage into consideration in making its production decisions. We also assume that the environmental damage is an inevitable consequence of production. No abatement technology is available, so production and pollution are equivalent: society cannot have one without the other. (See the Caveat at the end of Chapter 10.2.) The optimal policy causes …rms to internalize this environmental cost, just as they internalize costs of production associated with hiring capital and labor. One means of achieving this internalization is to charge producers a $2 per unit tax on output. However, in view of the equivalence of a producer and consumer tax, we achieve the same goal by charging consumers a $2 per unit tax on consumption. The incidence of the two taxes is the same and they have the same e¤ects on welfare, i.e. on the level of environmental damage, tax revenue, and consumer and producer surplus. It does not matter whether the polluter (producers) or the “pollutee” (consumers, as proxies for society) faces the statutory obligation to pay the tax. 188 CHAPTER 11. TAXES: AN INTRODUCTION It also does not matter which agent is responsible for the environmental damage. In some cases (e.g. driving), a major source of environmental damage arises from consumption of the good (cars) rather than production. Suppose that production causes no pollution, but that each unit of consumption causes $2 worth of environmental damage and, as in the previous example, there are no opportunities for abatement. In this case, targeting pollution and targeting consumption are equivalent. The optimal policy charges consumers a consumption tax equal to the marginal cost of pollution. In view of the equivalence between producer and consumer taxes for non-traded goods, we obtain the same outcome by imposing the statutory tax obligation on producers. 11.4 Tax equivalence Objectives and skills Use graphs to show how a tax causes a “shift”in demand or supply. Use graphs to determine tax incidence and the e¤ect of a tax on price and output. Use graphs to show the equivalence of consumer and producer taxes. This section shows that for “rational” agents (as de…ned above), consumer and producer taxes are equivalent for non-traded goods. Figure 11.1 shows a supply and demand curve (the heavy line) in the absence of taxes. Consumers and producers face the same price; the equilibrium price is p . Once we introduce a tax, the consumer and producer prices are di¤erent, so we can no longer use the same axis to measure both prices. We have to be clear about what the vertical axis now measures. Suppose that we introduce a consumer unit tax of . We continue to let the vertical axis be the price that producers receive and we continue to denote the producer price by p. Therefore, the tax does not alter the location of the supply curve. The tax causes the consumer price to be p + . The original demand function under the tax, the heavy downward sloping line, shows the relation between quantity demanded and the price that consumers pay. However, under the tax, we decided to use the vertical axis to represent the price that producers receive. Since the price that consumers pay and the price that 11.4. TAX EQUIVALENCE 189 Figure 11.1: Upward sloping line: supply function. Heavy downward sloping line: demand function with no tax. Light downward sloping line: demand function with tax. The tax equals the distance k bd k, labelled f: producers receive are not the same when a tax is imposed, we cannot use the original demand function (the heavy line) to read o¤ the quantity demanded for an arbitrary producer price. The di¢ culty is that supply is a function of p and demand is a function of p + , and we cannot let one axis represent both of these values. This di¢ culty is easily resolved. Box 11.1 A tax shifts the demand function. Pick an arbitrary point, e.g. b, on the original demand function in Figure 11.1. Suppose that point b corresponds to q = 10 and p = $6. If consumers have to pay a tax $ , then they would be willing to buy 10 units if the producer price is $(6 ); in that case, consumers’tax-inclusive price is $6. Here, where we graph consumer demand as a function of producer price, the point q = 10, p = 6 is a point on “new” (dashed) demand function, under the tax. This point is units below the point on the “original” (solid) demand function.. This procedure is the same for any point on the original demand curve. Thus, the consumer tax shifts the original demand down by units. We want to have the supply and demand curves on the same graph, in order to be able to determine the equilibrium by …nding the intersection between these two graphs. What does the demand function look like, when we hold the tax …xed and consider the quantity demanded to be a function 190 CHAPTER 11. TAXES: AN INTRODUCTION of the producer price, p? The answer is that the tax shifts down the demand curve by the magnitude , resulting in the light dashed demand function shown in Figure 11.1. This “new” demand function contains exactly the same information as the original demand function; it merely shows demand as a function of the producer price rather than the consumer price, recognizing that the consumer price is p + . The unit tax shifts the demand function down by units: the vertical distance between the original demand function and the demand function under the tax, is . The intersection of the original supply function and the new demand function occurs at the price p1 ; this is the equilibrium producer price in the presence of the tax. The equilibrium quantity is obtained by reading o¤ the quantity associated with this price, q1 . The equilibrium consumer price is p1 + . Note that p1 < p < p1 + : The tax incidence for producers in this example is p p1 100 and the tax incidence for consumers is p1 + p 100. We see that both tax incidences lie between 0 and 100%, and they sum to 100%: p p1 100 + p1 + p 100 = 100: Figure 11.2 shows the e¤ect of a unit tax when producers face the statutory tax obligation. In this graph we let the vertical axis represent the price that consumers pay. The price that producers receive is the consumer price minus the tax. Using the same reasoning that was used to explain Figure 11.1, we see that the producer tax shifts the supply curve (as a function of the consumer rather than the producer price) up by the amount . For example, if producers are willing to supply 10 units when they receive a price of $6, once they have to pay the tax they would need to receive 6 + to persuade them to supply 10 units. In the absence of the tax, the equilibrium price is p as before. When producers pay the tax, the equilibrium price that consumers pay increases to p2 = p1 + , but producers’after-tax revenue on each unit sold is p2 = p1 . If we were to superimpose Figure 11.2 onto Figure 11.1, the resulting …gure would show that the equilibrium quantity and the tax-inclusive consumer and producer prices are the same, regardless of whether producers or consumers face the statutory obligation. Tax equivalence does not hold in an open economy (one with international trade). 11.5. APPROXIMATING TAX INCIDENCE p 191 tax P1+t P* p1 Q Figure 11.2: Heavy upward sloping line: supply function. Light upward sloping line: supply function under tax. Downward sloping line: demand function. 11.5 Approximating tax incidence Objectives and skills Introduce the idea of a an approximation of tax incidence. Show the e¤ect of supply and demand elasticities on tax incidence. Calculating the exact tax incidence requires that we …nd the equilibrium price in the absence of the tax, and the equilibrium consumer (or producer price) under the tax, and compare the two. However, we can use supply and demand elasticities to approximate the tax incidence for small taxes. We use the de…nitions of elasticities elasticity of supply elasticity of demand = = dS(p) p dp S dD(p) p ; dpc D (11.1) where it is understood that the elasticities are evaluated at the equilibrium price in the absence of a tax. Using these de…nitions and the condition that supply equals demand, we obtain an expression for the change in equilibrium price due to a change in the tax, starting from a zero tax: dp = d + : (11.2) Equation 11.2 is an example of the type of comparative static expression introduced in Chapter 1. 192 CHAPTER 11. TAXES: AN INTRODUCTION Using equation 11.2 and the elasticity de…nitions, we obtain the approximations for the producer and consumer tax incidence (see Appendix F): producers’approx. tax incidence: + 100 consumers’approx. tax incidence: + 100: (11.3) These approximations are valid only in the neighborhood of a 0 tax: the formulae are “close to being accurate”if the tax is small (close to 0). By their de…nition, the two tax incidences must sum to 100%. Therefore, if we know the tax incidence for one agent, we subtract that number from 100% to …nd the tax incidence for the other agent. Smaller values of mean that demand is less elastic, which translates into a steeper inverse demand function. As demand becomes less elastic, the consumer incidence of the tax increases. If demand is completely inelastic ( = 0) then the inverse demand function is vertical. In that case, the consumer incidence of the tax is 100%. Similarly, a lower elasticity of supply corresponds to a steeper supply function and a larger producer incidence of the tax. To understand the relation between elasticities and tax incidence, the student should draw a supply and demand curve, pick a tax, and identify the tax incidences. Then change one of these curves by rotating it around the no-tax equilibrium. A steeper curve corresponds to a reduction in elasticity, and a ‡atter curve corresponds to an increase in elasticity. From this …gure, it is easy to see how a more elastic supply or demand (i.e. a ‡atter supply or demand) alters the tax incidence. 11.6 The leaky bucket: deadweight cost Objectives and skills Identify graphically the deadweight cost of a tax. Approximate the deadweight cost using elasticities of supply and demand. Understand why a greater elasticity of supply or demand increases the deadweight cost of a tax. Approximate the tax revenue using supply and demand elasticities. 11.6. THE LEAKY BUCKET: DEADWEIGHT COST 193 Use the approximations of deadweight cost and of tax revenue to obtain an approximation of the deadweight cost per unit of tax revenue. Understand the di¤erence between partial and general equilibrium analysis. Understand the di¤erence between short and long run elasticities, and the resulting “time-consistency”problem. As long as the elasticities of supply and demand are both positive and …nite, both consumers and producers bear some of the incidence of the tax. The tax causes consumers’ after-tax price to rise, and producers’ after-tax price to fall. Thus, the tax reduces both consumer and producer surplus. In Figure 11.1, the area of the trapezoid abcp measures the loss in consumer surplus due to the tax, and the area of the trapezoid p cde is the loss in producer surplus. Tax revenue equals the area of rectangle abde. Social welfare is the sum of producer and consumer surplus and tax revenues. The reduction in social welfare, due to moving from a zero tax to a positive tax, equals the reduction consumer surplus, plus the reduction in producer surplus, minus the increase in the tax revenue. In Figure 11.1, this net loss equals the area of the triangle bce. This triangle is society’s deadweight cost of the tax. In the case of linear supply and demand functions, the deadweight loss is literally a triangle (known as the “Harberger triangle”), and its area can be easily measured. However, we use the linear functions only for ease of viewing. For general supply and demand functions, we can use the elasticities to obtain an approximation of the deadweight loss, denoted DW L: DW L q 1 2 + p 2 : (11.4) The approximation uses estimates of the supply and demand elasticities, observation of quantity and price, and the magnitude of the tax. The formula also illustrates an important and general result in economics. The deadweight loss is approximately proportional to the square of the tax. Consequently, the derivative of the (approximation of) deadweight loss is proportional to the tax. In particular, this derivative, evaluated at a zero tax, is 0: a zero tax minimizes the deadweight loss. 194 CHAPTER 11. TAXES: AN INTRODUCTION DWL 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 tax Figure 11.3: The graph of the approximation of deadweight loss. In discussing the fundamental welfare theorems in Chapter 2.6, we noted that a competitive equilibrium maximizes social welfare, when the assumptions of the theorems hold. Thus, a tax, which moves the outcome away from a competitive equilibrium, must lower social welfare. The deadweight loss increases with the magnitude of the tax, but it increases faster than the tax. Figure 11.3 illustrates this relation. This fact means that it is e¢ cient to use a broad tax basis. For example, suppose that in one scenario the government uses a tax = 2 in each of 10 markets; in each markets sales equal 4, so tax collection equals 10 2 4 = 80. In another scenario it doubles the tax base from 10 to 20 commodities and lowers the tax on each from = 2 to = 1, collecting the same amount of revenue, 20 1 4 = 80. If + pq is the same for all of these commodities, the DWL falls from 10 12 + pq 22 to 20 12 + pq 12 , a decrease of 50%. Extremely small taxes cause essentially no deadweight loss, but as the tax increases, the deadweight loss increases rapidly. Doubling a tax increases the approximate deadweight loss by a factor of 22 = 4. Tripling tax increases the approximate deadweight loss by a factor of 32 = 9. Therefore, eliminating an extremely small tax leads to a negligible increase in social welfare. But reducing a tax that is not extremely small, may lead to a substantial increase in social welfare. Notice also that the deadweight loss is symmetric around 0: a small subsidy creates the same deadweight loss as does a small tax. This analysis suggests two “rules” for optimal tax policy. In order to raise a given (arbitrary) amount of tax revenue: (1) It is better to tax goods that have lower elasticity of supply or demand. (2) It is better to have a broad tax base (i.e. tax many instead of few goods). 11.6. THE LEAKY BUCKET: DEADWEIGHT COST 195 A third rule is so obvious that it does not require analysis: It is better to tax “bads”, such as pollution, rather than “goods”, such as labor or investment. Many taxes ignore some or all of these rules. The deadweight cost is expressed in the same monetary unit as prices, e.g. dollars. An alternative (unit-free) measure shows the deadweight loss per unit of the tax revenue. For example, a ratio .2 (20%) means that the deadweight loss is 20% of tax revenue. Chapter 10.4 discusses this measure in a policy setting. Denote p and q as the zero-tax equilibrium price and quantity. We can divide the approximation of deadweight loss by an approximation of tax revenue, to obtain an estimate of the deadweight cost per unit of tax revenue: DWL tax revenue 1 2 q q + p q + p (11.5) Figure 11.4 graphs the right side of equation 11.5 for two arbitrary values of q and for a particular normalization.2 Figure 11.3 shows that the deadweight loss rises “very slowly” for small taxes (i.e. it rises with the square of the tax). Figure 11.4, in contrast, shows that the deadweight loss per unit of tax revenue rises “quite quickly” with the tax. A small tax leads to very little deadweight loss, but it also leads to very little tax revenue. Increasing the tax increases both the deadweight loss and the tax revenue, but the deadweight cost rises more rapidly than does tax revenue. In the context of environmental economics, we are principally interested in taxes or subsidies as a means of correcting a market failure such as a pollution externality, not as a means of raising tax revenue. Properly implemented, those environmental taxes increase social welfare. Many taxes are designed to raise tax revenue. The tax revenue is (we assume here) socially useful, but raising it creates a deadweight cost. That cost might eliminate a signi…cant fraction of the potential social bene…t of each dollar of tax revenue. The revenue raised by taxing a “bad” such as pollution, makes it possible to reduce other taxes whose purpose is to raise revenue, thereby lowering the deadweight loss associated with those taxes. 2 Because of the arbitrary choicea of q, the …gure has no speci…c empirical content, but it illustrates how “easy” it is to obtain ratios of 0.2 – 0.3, i.e. where the deadweight loss reaches 20% –30% of tax revenue. 196 CHAPTER 11. TAXES: AN INTRODUCTION ratio 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 -4 -3 -2 -1 1 2 3 4 tax -0.1 Figure 11.4: Approximate social cost per unit of tax revenue, using normalization (achieved by a particular choice of units) + pq = 1 and the arbitrary values q = 10 (solid curve) and q = 8 (dashed curve). Product markets and general equilibrium analysis The discussion above considers taxes for produced goods. Taxes are also applied to “factors of production”, such as land, labor and capital. The e¤ects of commodity and factor taxes are similar, both having an incidence and a deadweight cost. For example, a tax applied to labor potentially alters the supply of labor, changing the equilibrium wage, a¤ecting both people who supply labor and those who purchase it, and creating a deadweight loss. The factor-tax incidence and deadweight loss depend on elasticities, just as with a product tax. The partial equilibrium analysis examines a single market. There, tax incidence depends entirely on the relative supply and demand elasticity of the commodity or the factor, and the deadweight loss depends on the product of the supply and demand elasticities. If the elasticity of supply is zero, then producers or factor owners bear the entire incidence, and the deadweight loss is zero. In this case, the tax shifts income from producers or factor owners to taxpayers, but causes no e¢ ciency loss. Unimproved land is the classic example of a factor whose supply is perfectly inelastic. Henry George, a 19th century political economist, proposed a “single tax” on unimproved land; this tax causes no economic loss, and falls entirely on people who do not create wealth. A general equilibrium setting recognizes that markets for di¤erent products or factors are interlinked, and that it is seldom possible to alter one market without altering others. For example, if landowners are also farmers, the land tax lowers their income and wealth. The tax-induced reduction 11.6. THE LEAKY BUCKET: DEADWEIGHT COST 197 in income may cause farmers to work harder, changing the supply of labor, thus changing the level and equilibrium price of the output. The tax-induced reduction in farmers’ wealth might induce them to rebuild their wealth by accumulating more capital. The higher stock of capital increases the marginal productivity labor, increasing the equilibrium wage and lowering the return to capital. The changes in these factor prices causes the incidence to be shifted to their owners. If the revenue from the land tax is given to workers, their higher income might cause them to supply less labor, increasing the equilibrium wage. Even ignoring these complications, there are practical di¢ culties in implementing the single tax, whose rationale depends on the zero elasticity of supply of unimproved land. Virtually all productive land, however, has been improved in some manner, often by previous generations. The indirect (or “general equilibrium”) changes are too complicated to summarize in a simple formula. They are sometimes studied using numerical “computable general equilibrium” (CGE) models. Table 1 reports CGEbased estimates of the deadweight loss of various U.S. taxes. The property tax has the lowest deadweight loss, consistent with the low elasticity of supply of land. The fact that most taxes create a deadweight loss means that there is a social cost to raising government revenue. Prominent estimates are that this social cost is at least 20% of tax revenue. Opponents of expensive government programs sometimes invoke this cost to explain that the actual cost of the program exceeds the budgetary cost. income payroll consumer property capital output tax tax sales tax tax tax tax 50 38 26 18 66 21 Table 11.1 Estimates of percent deadweight loss of U.S. taxes Time consistency Putting aside the general equilibrium complications, the partial equilibrium analysis has a simple and powerful policy message: the deadweight cost associated with taxes is lower, the lower is the elasticity of supply or demand associated with the taxed product or factor. The di¤erence between short and long run elasticities complicates this message. In order to make this point, suppose that the government wants to minimize the deadweight loss, subject to the constraint that it raise a certain amount of tax revenue in each period. The government has two policy instruments, a tax on capital and a tax on labor. Investment takes time; the current stock of capital depends on previous, not on current investment. 198 CHAPTER 11. TAXES: AN INTRODUCTION This fact causes the supply of capital to be quite inelastic in the short run,so current capital taxes create little deadweight loss. This observation implies that most of the revenue in the current period should be raised using a capital tax. However, the future stock of capital depends on current investment, which depends on beliefs about future capital taxes. This fact causes the future stock of capital to be quite elastic, militating against the use of a capital tax in the future. If the policymaker today can make a binding commitment to the time pro…le of taxes, she would like to raise most of current revenue using a capital tax, but promise to use a low future capital tax. The current labor tax can therefore be low, but the future labor tax must be high, in order to raise the required amount of revenue in each period. The time consistency problem is that “once the future arrives, it has become the present”. The policymaker in the future has the same incentives as the policymaker today. She has the temptation to renege on her predecessor’s commitment to use a low capital tax, in order to raise the required amount of revenue with little deadweight cost. This is the time consistency problem: the planner in the future does not want to implement the program that her predecessor would like to see used. If today’s planner cannot bind her successors to carry out the program that she wants them to use, that program is not time-consistent. Investors would not believe that they will in fact face low capital taxes in the future, and this understanding informs their current investment decisions. 11.7 Taxes and cap & trade Objectives and skills Understand the basic ingredients of a cap and trade policy. Be able to explain why the equilibrium price of permits, under cap and trade, depends on the number of permits (the “cap”) but not on whether permits are given or auctioned to …rms. Understand that corresponding to every “cap” in the cap and trade policy, there is a “quota-equivalent emissions tax” that leads to the same level of pollution, and the same distribution of pollution across …rms. 11.7. TAXES AND CAP & TRADE 199 Understand how to use tax incidence to estimate the fraction of permits that have to be “grandfathered”in order for a cap and trade policy not to reduce industry pro…ts. Emissions taxes and cap & trade are market-based environmental policies, in contrast to “command and control”policies that reduce emissions by mandating certain types of technology or production methods. Most economists think that market-based policies reduce emissions more cheaply than command and control policies. By the end of 2014 there were almost 50 carbon markets worldwide, the largest being the The European Union’s Emissions Trading Scheme. Southern California’s trading scheme for NOx , RECLAIM, has operated since 1994. The (never passed) 2009 Waxman-Markey bill envisioned setting up a U.S. market for carbon emissions. Environmental reform requires people to change their behavior, and usually imposes some cost on the economy. Cap and trade can reduce the industry cost by “grandfathering” permits, i.e. giving rather than selling businesses a certain number of emissions permits. Our discussion of taxes emphasizes that regardless of who has the statutory obligation to pay the tax, in general both consumers and producers bear some incidence of the tax. Both consumers and producers also typically bear some of the incidence of any other environmental policy, including cap and trade. The Waxman-Markey proposal gave businesses a declining (over time) share of the permit allowance. When does grandfathering merely cushion businesses from a loss of pro…ts, and when does it amount to a give-away? The answer to this kind of question depends on the speci…cs of the provision, but the logic of the answer is straightforward. To explain this logic, imagine that we were interested in slightly di¤erent question. Suppose we pick a tax, and ask what fraction of the tax revenue …rms would have to be given, in order to make them as well o¤ as they are without the tax. Referring to Figure 11.1, we see that the tax causes the …rms to lose the amount of surplus equal to the areas edf p + dce. If …rms were given tax revenue equal to edf p , plus a bit more to make up for their surplus loss dce, they would p be as well o¤ as without the tax. The area edf p equals the fraction edf edba of the tax revenue. Because the length of the rectangles in the numerator and the denominator of this fraction are equal, the ratio equals the ratio of the heights of the two rectangles. This ratio equals pp1 +tp1 , which equals the producer incidence of the tax. In conclusion, we see that if …rms are given a 200 CHAPTER 11. TAXES: AN INTRODUCTION share of the tax revenue equal to their incidence of the tax, plus a bit more (to make up for the missing triangle dce), then they are as well o¤ as before the tax. To apply this logic to cap and trade, instead of taxes, it is necessary to understand the relation between the two types of policies. We explain how a cap and trade system works, and why the equilibrium level of each …rm’s emissions do not depend on whether …rms are given permits or have to buy them. We then explain the sense in which a cap and trade policy is equivalent to an emissions tax. We use that equivalence, together with the logic above, to approximate the fraction of permits that …rms would have to be given, in order to make them just as well o¤ under cap and trade as they are in the absence of regulation. The basic ingredients of cap and trade. The regulator chooses the cap on emissions, denoted Z. The many competitive …rms are able to buy and sell permits. This buying and selling is the “trade” part of the cap and trade policy. Each of these …rms takes the price of an emissions permit as given. Denote the equilibrium price of permits as pe (Z). This relation recognizes that (as in all markets) the equilibrium price depends on the supply. Here, the supply is a number, Z. Firms might be given some permits (“grandfathered”) or no permits at the beginning of the program. Due to the (assumed) …xed relation between output and emissions, by choice of units we can set one unit of output to equal one unit of emissions. For example, if one unit of output creates 2.5 kilograms of pollution, we can measure pollution in units of 2.5 kilograms. Claim #1: The permit price and emissions are independent of the allocation of permits The equilibrium permit price depends on the aggregate number of permits, Z. However, if …rms are price taking and pro…t maximizing, and if the transactions cost in buying and selling permits is low, then …rms’ pollution levels are independent of the distribution of allowances, e.g. whether …rms are given or sold the permits. To verify this claim, we show that each …rm’s demand for permits is independent of its own allocation. Consider an arbitrary …rm that is given an allowance A (possibly equal to zero). This price-taking faces the output price, p, and the permit price, pe , and wants to maximize pro…ts: pq c (q) + pe (A q) : | {z } 11.7. TAXES AND CAP & TRADE 201 The underlined term equals the …rm’s revenue from selling the good minus its cost of production; the under-bracketed term equals the …rm’s pro…ts from selling (if A > q) or its costs of buying (if A < q) permits. The …rst order condition to the …rm’s problem states that price equals marginal cost. Marginal cost here equals the sum of the “usual” marginal dc ), and the cost of buying an emissions permit, pe . The …rst order cost ( dq condition dc p= + pe ; (11.6) dq does not depend on its permit allocation, A. Firms’ decision about how much to produce, and thus about how many permits to use, does not depend on the allocation of permits. A …rm that buys permits has to pay pe for the additional permit needed to produce an additional unit. A …rm that sells permits incurs an opportunity cost pe in using an additional permit: by using that permit it is no longer able to sell it. Thus, regardless of whether the …rm is a net buyer or seller of permits, it incurs the cost pe of using an additional unit. Recent research (Box 11.2) …nds empirical support for Claim 1. Box 11.2 The empirical validity of Claim 1 If allowances were randomly assigned to …rms, then Claim 1 implies that …rms’allowances are uncorrelated with their emissions. In practice, allowances are not randomly assigned; with grandfathering, …rms that emitted more in the past receive higher allowances. These are the same …rms that are more likely to have high future emissions, thus creating a mechanical (and therefore uninformative) positive correlation between allowances and emissions. California’s RECLAIM emissions trading program randomly assigned …rms to di¤erent permit allocation cycles: …rms in the …rst cycle receive their annual allowance at the beginning, and …rms in the second cycle receive their allowance half-way through the calendar year. Moreover, …rms in the second cycle tended to receive a higher allowance than those in the …rst cycle. Similar …rms randomly assigned to di¤erent groups therefore receive, on average di¤erent allowances. Using this design feature (and “instrumental variables”), statistical tests provide empirical support for Claim 1. Claim #2: There exists a quota-equivalent emissions tax To simplify the exposition, we assume that all …rms have the same cost function, 202 CHAPTER 11. TAXES: AN INTRODUCTION $ 10 9 p(Q) 8 dC/dQ 7 6 5 4 3 2 permit price 1 0 0 1 2 3 4 5 Q= Z Figure 11.5: Solid lines: inverse demand and marginal cost. Dashed curve: the equilibrium permit price, pe , is the vertical di¤erence between inverse demand and marginal cost. so that we can use the representative …rm model. As in Chapter 2.4, we denote the cost function for the representative …rm as c (Q). Using the fact that Q = Z (because one unit of output produces one unit of emissions), equation 11.6 implies p (Q)jQ=Z = dC (Q) + pe (Z) or dQ jQ=Z p (Q) dC (Q) dQ = pe (Z) : jQ=Z (11.7) The second equation shows that the equilibrium permit price equals the di¤erence between the inverse demand function, p (Q), and the marginal cost function, dC(Q) . dQ Figure 11.5 shows linear demand and marginal cost curves, and the equilibrium permit price (dashed line) as the vertical di¤erence between the two. For this example, the equilibrium quantity (= emissions) absent regulation is 3:33. If the regulator chooses Z 3:33, then the regulation is vacuous, and the permit price is zero. But for Z < 3:33, the emissions constraint is binding, and the permit price is positive. Every value of Z below the unregulated “Business as usual”level (3.33) corresponds to a di¤erent equilibrium permit price. If the representative …rm faces a tax , the equilibrium condition (price equals “usual”marginal cost plus the tax) is p (Z) = dC (Q) + : dQ 11.7. TAXES AND CAP & TRADE 203 Comparing this equation to the …rst equation in 11.7 shows that the tax = pe (Z) induces the competitive industry to produce at the same level as under the cap and trade policy with cap Z. Claim #3: There is a simple formula for compensating …rms A cap and trade policy with cap Z determines the amount of emissions. We showed that there is an equivalent tax that leads to the same amount of emissions. Under a cap and trade policy the regulator can reduce the cost to the …rms by giving them (for free) some permits, instead of auctioning all of the permits. What fraction of permits would the regulator have to give …rms, to make them (almost) as well o¤ under regulation as under Business as Usual? This question has a simple answer in our setting. If the regulator auctions all of the permits (gives none to the …rms) then from the standpoint of …rms, it is exactly as if they face the tax = pe (Z). Figure 11.1 shows that the …rms’ loss in surplus, due to a tax (or to being forced to buy all of its emissions permits at the price p^ (Z) = ) is the area p cde = edf p + dce. If …rms are given (instead of being forced to buy) the fraction + of permits, then the value of this gift is + times the potential tax revenue. (Review equation 11.3.) This value equals the area of the rectangle p f de. Firms’ net loss equals their loss in producer surplus minus the value of the gift, the area of the triangle f cd. This triangle is the small correction that is needed to make …rms whole. The fraction + is (typically) much less than 1, so even with the correction, it would be necessary to give …rms only a fraction of the permits, to compensate them for the regulation. Lessons and caveats In considering industry’s request for the free allocation of permits, regulators need to remember a fundamental economic fact. A regulation that increases …rms’ costs typically reduces their incentive to supply the good that they produce, thereby increasing the market price of that good. The higher market price provides an automatic cushion for …rms facing the cost increase caused by stricter regulation. The requirement that …rms reduce emissions, together with the free distribution of all emissions permits, might increase …rms’pro…ts relative to the business as usual level. In that case, it is possible to give …rms fewer permits than they actually use (forcing them to buy the rest), and still fully compensate the …rms for lost pro…ts due to the restriction on emissions. 204 CHAPTER 11. TAXES: AN INTRODUCTION All of this may sound too good to be true, so it is worth repeating two assumptions that underlie the argument. The most important of these is that the economy is closed, i.e. there is no international trade. In a closed economy, supply equals demand. If an open economy imposes cap and trade, the regulation may have little or no e¤ect on the price at which the country can buy or sell the commodity. To the extent that the price does not adjust, the market gives producers no automatic cushion to the cost increase resulting from regulation. In that situation, …rms bear the entire incidence of the regulation; they are worse o¤ even if they are given all of the permits. The second assumption is that pollution is proportional to output, i.e. there is no way to lower pollution except by lowering output. This assumption is not realistic, because …rms typically can choose di¤erent production methods, with di¤erent ratios of emissions to output. The …rst two of the claims above remain true in a model with variable emissions/output ratio: (1) Firms’choice of emissions is independent of the allocation of permits (i.e. whether …rms have to buy or are given permits), and (2) For every quota Z there is an emissions tax that leads to the same level of emissions. The third claim needs to be modi…ed if the emissions/output ratio is not a …xed; the formula for compensating …rms becomes more complex. 11.8 Summary The unit and ad valorem taxes are di¤erent ways of expressing a tax. For each unit tax, there is an ad valorem tax that leads to exactly the same outcome. These taxes change equilibrium price and quantity and they create a deadweight cost to society. In contrast, the constant pro…ts tax merely transfers surplus from producers to taxpayers, having no e¤ect on consumers’ welfare or on aggregate social welfare. The deadweight cost of a tax equals the net loss in social welfare arising from the tax: the reduction in the sum of consumer and producer surplus, minus the tax revenue. The consumer incidence of the tax equals the increase in the price that consumers pay, as a percent of the tax. The producer incidence equals the reduction in the price that producers receive, as a percent of the tax. These two incidences sum to 100%. In a closed economy (no international trade) it does not matter whether the tax is imposed on consumers or producers; the two taxes are equivalent. This fact implies that in some settings, the Polluter Pays Principle is vacuous: regardless of whether the polluter or the 11.8. SUMMARY 205 pollutee directly pays, their actual cost is the same. A simple formula relates approximate consumer and producer incidence to supply and demand elasticities. Another approximation shows the deadweight loss of a tax. We also provided an estimate of the deadweight loss of a tax, per unit of tax revenue. The deadweight loss of a tax rises is approximately proportional to the square of the tax. Therefore, reductions in small taxes typically lead to small decreases in deadweight loss. In contrast, reductions in large taxes result in large decreases in deadweight loss. Small taxes lead to small deadweight loss, and also small tax revenue. Increases in the tax increase both the deadweight loss and the tax revenue (at least up to a certain tax level). However, the deadweight loss rises more rapidly than does tax revenue. The deadweight loss might create a sizeable reduction in the potential social bene…t arising from tax revenue. The two basic “rules” of optimal taxation are that it is better to tax commodities or factors for which the elasticity of supply or demand is small (so that the deadweight loss is small), and it is better to have a broad tax base (so that a given amount of revenue can be raised using small taxes in each sector. In the environmental context, we are primarily interested in taxes as a means of correcting externalities such as pollution. These taxes remedy market failures; they do not create social costs. However, the purpose of many taxes, levied on “goods rather than bads”, is to raise tax revenue for social or political purposes. To the extent that taxes on “bads”can replace taxes on “goods”, the former not only correct market failures, but also reduce the deadweight cost of revenue-raising taxes. We used this machinery to examine a recent policy question: Under a cap and trade system, what fraction of permits would …rms have to be given, in order to leave them as well o¤ under the policy as they were before regulation? We addressed this question using a particular model, in which there is a …xed relation between emissions and output. In that setting, we explained and illustrated the equivalence of an emissions tax and a cap and trade policy. In particular, if a policy sets a cap of Z and allows trade, the equilibrium permit price is p^ (Z). The equivalent emissions tax, = p^ (Z), results in the same level of emissions, Z. If …rms are given the fraction of permits, equal to the tax incidence they face under the tax = p^ (Z), plus a small correction to account for their share of the deadweight cost of taxes, then the cap and trade policy has approximately zero e¤ect on producer surplus. In that case, the cap and trade policy can be used to reduce pollution without 206 CHAPTER 11. TAXES: AN INTRODUCTION harming …rms. Giving away instead of selling pollution permits is a loss to the treasury, hurting taxpayers in general but bene…tting the regulated …rms. The e¤ect of taxes in a general equilibrium setting is more complicated than in the partial equilibrium setting we emphasize. In particular, general equilibrium relations can shift the tax incidence in subtle ways. In a dynamic setting, involving investment, the short run elasticity of supply (or demand) typically di¤er from their long run analogs. This di¤erence complicates the problem of designing tax policy, and can lead to the time inconsistency of optimal policy. 11.9 Terms, study questions and exercises New terms or concepts Unit tax, ad valorem tax, consumer and producer tax incidence, rational buyers, behavioral economics, approximation of tax incidence, closed and open economies, Polluter Pays Principle, tax equivalence, Harberger triangle, deadweight loss (or cost) of taxes, approximation of deadweight loss, approximation of tax revenue, factor prices, general equilibrium e¤ects, computable general equilibrium (CGE) model, time consistency, cap and trade, equivalence of a cap and trade and a tax policy, grandfathering. Study questions 1. (a) What does it mean to say that a producer and a consumer tax are “equivalent” in a closed economy? (Your answer should include a de…nition of the term “incidence”. (b) Use either a graphical or a numerical example to illustrate this equivalence in a closed economy. (c) Using either a numerical or a graphical example, show that this equivalence breaks down in an open economy. 2. (a) Use a graphical example to show how the consumer and producer tax incidences (in a closed economy) depend on the relative steepness of the supply and the demand functions at the equilibrium price. (b) Using this example, explain how the approximation of consumer tax incidence depends on the demand elasticity relative to the supply elasticity (i.e. the ratio of the two elasticities) evaluated at the no-tax 11.9. TERMS, STUDY QUESTIONS AND EXERCISES 207 equilibrium. [Begin by drawing a supply demand function, picking a tax, and identifying the tax incidences. Then rotate one of the curves around the no-tax equilibrium, making it much steeper (= less elastic) or much ‡atter (= more elastic) and show graphically how the incidences change.] 3. Suppose that a regulator imposes a producer tax in a closed economy. (a) Use the concept of producer tax incidence to approximate the fraction of the tax revenue that would have to be turned over to producers to make them almost as well o¤ under the tax + transfer as they were before the tax. (b) Use the concept of consumer tax incidence to approximate the fraction of the tax revenue that would have to be turned over to consumers to make them almost as well o¤ under the tax + transfer as they were before the tax. (c) Is it possible, by means of transferring the tax revenue (associated only with this particular tax), to make both producers and consumers exactly as well o¤ under the tax + transfer as they were before the tax? Explain 4. (a) Describe a cap and trade policy. (Explain how it works.) (b) Explain what it means to auction permits. (c) Explain why …rms’ equilibrium level of pollution does not depend on whether permits are given to the …rm or auctioned. 5. (a) Explain what is meant by the claim that a pollution tax and a cap and trade policy are equivalent. (b) Explain why the claim is true (in the particular setting we used). (c) Suppose that instead of using a cap and trade, a regulator uses a “cap and no trade”policy, in which …rms are allocated pollution permits but not allowed to trade them. Is a pollution tax equivalent to a “cap and no trade policy”? Explain. For example, if you claim that the two policies are still equivalent, without trade, you should justify that conclusion. If you claim that the two policies are di¤erent, with respect to some signi…cant outcome, you should identify and explain the di¤erence. Exercises Assume for all questions that the economy is closed. 1. Consider a monopoly, in a static setting, with constant marginal cost c. If the monopoly receives price p and consumers pay a unit tax 208 CHAPTER 11. TAXES: AN INTRODUCTION , consumers’ tax-inclusive prices is pc = p + ; if instead they pay the ad valorem tax , they pay the tax-inclusive price pc = p (1 + ). The demand function is q = a pc . (a) Write down the monopoly’s maximization problem and …rst order condition in the two scenarios, with a unit and an ad valorem tax. (b) Solve these two …rst order conditions to …nd the equilibrium consumer price in these two cases. (In one case this price is a function of and in the other case it is a function of .) (c) Use part b to …nd the relation between and such that if the taxes satisfy this relation, the consumer price is the same under either tax. 2. (a) Draw a linear demand function and a linear marginal cost function. Use this …gure to identify (graphically) consumer and producer incidence of a unit tax, , in a competitive equilibrium. (b) Reproduce the …gure you drew from part (a), except now make the supply function steeper at the zero-tax competitive equilibrium. Identify the consumer and producer tax incidence and compare these to your answer in part (a). (c) Explain the relation between your answer to part (b) and equation 11.3. (d) Reproduce the …gure that you drew from part (a). A regulator uses a unit tax . Use this new …gure to compare the consumer tax incidence in a competitive equilibrium and under a monopoly. 3. (a) Using the approximation of deadweight loss in equation 11.4, show that deadweight cost increases with either the elasticity of demand or the elasticity of supply. (Hint: take a derivative.) For this question, you are holding the tax and the zero-tax equilibrium quantity and price constant, and considering the e¤ect of making either the demand or the supply function ‡atter (more elastic) at this equilibrium. (b) Provide an economic explanation for the relation you showed in part (a). 4. A pro…t tax is usually expressed in ad valorem terms. If …rms have profits py c (y) and pay a pro…t tax , their after-tax pro…t is (1 ) [py c (y)]. (a) How, if at all, does a pro…ts tax a¤ect the equilibrium price in a competitive equilibrium? (b) What, if anything, does a pro…t tax affect in a competitive equilibrium? (Make a list of the features of the competitive equilibrium that we care about, and ask which if any of those features are altered by the pro…ts tax.) (c) Now answer parts (a) and (b), replacing the competitive …rm with a monopoly. 11.9. TERMS, STUDY QUESTIONS AND EXERCISES 209 5. A monopoly has constant costs, c. Consumers, facing price pc , demand q = a pc units of the good; so the inverse demand is pc = a q. (a) Write down the monopoly pro…ts, as a function of its sales, q, in the two cases where consumers pay the unit tax , and then when the monopoly pays the unit tax . (b) Compare the pro…t function in these two cases. Based on this comparison, does the monopoly equilibrium depend on which agent (consumers or the monopoly) directly pays the tax? Sources Gentry (2007) reviews evidence that labor bears a signi…cant share of the incidence of corporate taxes. Feldstein (1977) discusses the general equilibrium e¤ects of a land tax. Diewert et al. (1998) and Conover (2010) review estimates of tax incidence; Table 11.1 is based on Conover. Judd (1985) discusses the time path of capital taxes, and Karp and Lee (2003) discuss the time-inconsistency of the optimal program. The World Bank (2014) surveys carbon markets across the world. Fowlie, Holland and Mansur (2012) document the success of the RECLAIM market for NOx . Fowlie and Perlo¤ (2013) …nd support for the hypothesis that emissions levels do not depend on permit allocations (Claim 1 and Box 11.2). McAusland (2003 and 2008) compares environmental taxes in open and closed economies. 210 CHAPTER 11. TAXES: AN INTRODUCTION Chapter 12 Taxes: nonrenewable resources Objectives Be able to synthesize the material on nonrenewable resources and on static taxes to understand the role of taxes applied to nonrenewable resources. Information and skills Have an overview of actual fossil fuel taxes. Understand the time consistency problem arising from quasi-rent. Understand how taxes alter a …rm’s extraction incentives. Be able to analyze the equilibrium e¤ects of di¤erent (e.g. constant versus increasing) tax pro…les . Understand how a tax-induced change in the price trajectory maps into a trajectory of consumer and producer tax incidence. Be able to explain why, in the resource setting, consumer tax incidence is negative over some periods. Understand and be able to describe the measures of the present discounted ‡ow of consumer surplus/producer surplus/tax revenue. 211 212 CHAPTER 12. TAXES: NONRENEWABLE RESOURCES With static markets, consumers’ and producers’ decisions depend only on the current price. For natural resources markets, …rms’ current sales decisions depend on their expectations of future prices, and on the relation between those prices and the current price. Some results from static tax analysis carry over to the dynamic setting. For example, in a closed economy the incidence of the tax is the same regardless of whether it is levied on consumers or producers, and for every unit tax, there is an equivalent ad valorem tax. Therefore, there is no loss in generality in assuming that producers rather that consumers have the statutory obligation to pay a unit tax. In other respects, taxes might have qualitatively di¤erent e¤ects in a static setting and in a dynamic setting with natural resources. In a static setting, taxes reduce equilibrium supply. In the resource setting, a tax reallocates supply across periods, but might have no e¤ect on cumulative supply. The tax-induced change in the timing of sales can have important welfare e¤ects. 12.1 Resource taxes in the real world Natural resources, particularly fossil fuels, are an important part of the world economy, so it is not surprising that governments derive substantial revenue from their taxation. Between 2005 – 2010 the (mostly rich) 24 countries in the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) raised about $850 billion per year on petroleum taxes, including goods and services taxes and value added taxes. These taxes served a variety of purposes, including internalization of environmental externalities, road building and maintenance, and general government expenses. For large oil producing countries, government receipts from the hydrocarbon sector was a large fraction of total government revenue (2000 - 2007 data): 72% for Saudi Arabia, 48% from Venezuela, and 22% for Russia. Despite the large contribution of resource taxes to government co¤ers, the important story is that in many rich countries the oil sector receives signi…cant implicit subsidies in the form of tax deductions. Just as a tax on producers is an implicit tax on consumers (Chapter 11), so a producer subsidy is an implicit consumption subsidy. Other countries, principally middle income and developing countries that export fossil fuels, directly subsidize domestic fuel consumption by maintaining a domestic price lower than the world price. For both groups of countries, these policies subsidize fuel con- 12.1. RESOURCE TAXES IN THE REAL WORLD 213 sumption, creating signi…cant distortions. In 2009, leaders of the G20 (a group of wealthy countries) committed to “rationalize and phase out over the medium term ine¢ cient fossil fuel subsidies that encourage wasteful consumption”. A group of international organizations, including the OECD and World Bank, estimated the scope of energy subsidies and made suggestions for their reduction. Their report identi…ed 250 individual mechanisms that support fossil fuel production in the OECD countries, having an aggregate value of USD $ 45 -75 billion per year over 2005 - 2010; 54% of this subsidy went to petroleum, 24% to coal, and 22% to natural gas. In the U.S., tax breaks provide implicit fossil fuel subsidies of about $4 billion per year. The three most important of these are: write-o¤s for intangible drilling costs, a domestic manufacturing tax deduction, and a percentage depletion allowance for oil and gas wells. These tax breaks transfer income from taxpayers to resource owners, without promoting the development of new technologies. A group of 37 emerging and developing countries provide direct domestic fuel consumption subsidies, maintaining domestic prices below international prices. This group accounts for over half of world fossil fuel consumption in 2010. With a domestic price of pd and a world price of pw , the per unit subsidy is pw pd . The nation loses pw pd times the amount of subsidized consumption from selling fuel at the low domestic price instead of the higher world price. Most of the countries maintained a stable domestic price, while the world price ‡uctuated, causing the per unit subsidy to also ‡uctuate. The cost of the subsidies to their domestic treasuries amounted to $409 billion in 2010 and $300 billion in 2009. Oil received 47% of total, and the average subsidy was 23% of the world price. The subsidy rates were highest among oil and gas exporters in Middle East, North Africa and Central Asia. A common justi…cation for fuel subsidies is that they bene…t the poor, providing them with access to energy services. However, only 8% of the $409 billion subsidy in 2010 went to poorest 20% of the population. If the subsidy had been eliminated, and the fuel sold at world price, and each person then given an equal share of the proceeds, the poorest 20% would have received approximately twice as much as they did under the subsidy. This approximation probably overstates the ine¢ ciency of the subsidy as a means of helping the poor. First, if all of this fuel had been diverted from the domestic to the world market, it would have lowered the world price, thus lowering the gain from the sales. Second, given the levels of domestic corruption, it is unlikely that the poor would have received an equal share 214 CHAPTER 12. TAXES: NONRENEWABLE RESOURCES of the increased revenue resulting from removal of the subsidies. Despite these two quali…cations, fuel subsidies – like most commodity subsidies – are an ine¢ cient way to help the poor. There is modest evidence that the magnitude of these subsidies has been decreasing. They fell from about 1.8% of government budgets in 2004 to 1.3% in 2010. Absent reforms, 2011 estimates project that these fossil fuel subsidies would reach $660 billion per year by 2020. The elimination of consumption subsidies was estimated to reduce 2020 fuel demand by 4.1% and CO2 emissions by 4.7%. A 2015 International Monetary Fund (IMF) study updates estimates of the magnitude and economic cost of fossil fuel subsidies, and also includes unpriced externalities. For example if the cost of supplying a unit of the good, inclusive of rent, is 10, and the externality cost is 2, the e¢ cient price is 12. If the externality is not taxed, and in addition a subsidy reduces the cost to consumer by 1, then consumers pay 9. In this example, the total subsidy per unit equals 3. For fossil fuels, the externality cost is larger than the direct subsidy. Local health e¤ects, not climate change, accounts for the bulk of this externality cost. The IMF study estimates that global energy subsidies (including the externality cost) amounted to about $5 trillion, or 6% of world Gross Domestic Product (GDP) in 2013; removal of these subsidies would have raised almost $3 trillion in government revenue, and would have increased global GDP by more than 2%. For comparison, estimates of the increase in welfare due to major trade liberalization are typically only a fraction of a percent of GDP. Fossil fuel subsidies are ine¢ cient for at least four reasons. Most importantly, they subsidize a commodity that should, because of environmental externalities, be taxed. The subsidies also violate both of the two “rules” of optimal taxation discussed in Chapter 11.6. The …rst rule states that, for the purpose of raising government revenue, goods with inelastic supply and/or demand should be the most highly taxed. Fossil fuels likely fall into that category, but in practice they are subsidized. The second rule states that governments should seek to have a broad tax base, so that taxes on each sector can be low. Subsidizing rather than taxing the fossil fuel sector ‡ies in the face of this advice, requiring higher taxes in other sectors to …nance the fossil fuel subsidies. Finally, commodity subsidies are an ine¢ cient means of making transfers to the poor. Political power, not economic logic, explains the tax and subsidy policies used in a wide range of fossil fuel markets, for both importers and exporters countries, and for rich and developing nations. 12.2. THE LOGIC OF RESOURCE TAXES 12.2 215 The logic of resource taxes Just as in the static setting, taxes (and subsidies) drive a wedge between consumer and producer price. Typically, they alter people’s decisions, creating an e¢ ciency cost, the deadweight loss. If either the elasticity of supply or demand are zero, then the tax (or subsidy) does not alter behavior, and it creates zero deadweight loss. The deadweight cost of a tax is low when either of these elasticities is low. This fact is the basis for much of the theory of taxes; it helps to explain the popularity of the 19th century recommendation of a “single tax” on unimproved land, a factor of production with inelastic supply. Taxes applied to natural resources can alter both the timing of extraction and cumulative extraction. To focus on the former, we consider the case where …rms have constant average (and marginal) extraction cost C. We then discuss the relation between taxes and investment. Taxes and the timing of extraction: special cases (First special case) Suppose that …rms have constant average production costs C and the government introduces a positive constant unit tax, . From the standpoint of the …rm, it is as if its costs increased from C to C 0 = C + . We saw in Chapter 3.3 that a higher extraction cost causes …rms to shift production from the current period to future periods. The intuition for this result is that discounting reduces the present value of costs that are incurred in the future. If a …rm moves one unit of extraction from the current period to t periods in the future, its current tax liability falls by $ and the present value of its future tax liability increases by t < . Shifting extraction from the current time to the future lowers the present value of the …rm’s tax liability. Therefore, the constant tax causes the …rm to delay extraction. In a static model, if …rms have constant production costs, then their elasticity of supply, , is in…nite. In this case, using equation 11.3, the ratio = 0: …rms incur of producer tax incidence to consumer tax incidence, none of the incidence of the tax. That result has a simple explanation. With constant production costs, …rms earn zero producer surplus. They cannot possibly earn less than zero surplus, so imposition of the tax leaves their surplus unchanged at zero. Because the tax has no e¤ect on the price that producers receive, consumers’price rises by the magnitude of the tax: consumers bear the entire tax incidence. 216 CHAPTER 12. TAXES: NONRENEWABLE RESOURCES The resource model with constant extraction costs resembles the static model, but there is an important di¤erence. In the resource model, extraction costs are constant up to the point where the resource is exhausted, but beyond that point, extraction costs are in…nite, i.e. the elasticity of supply becomes zero: …rms cannot supply the resource when they have no more of the stock. The …nite supply of the resource creates rent. In the resource model, we do not have a formula for measuring tax incidence as simple as those in equation 11.3. However, from the discussion above, we see that a constant tax decreases supply, increasing the equilibrium price early in the program, and has the opposite e¤ect later in the program. Thus, the consumer incidence of the tax early in the program is positive (just as in the static model), but late in the program it is negative. (Second special case) Now we assume that (i) the tax increases at the discount rate, so that the tax in period t is t = (1 + r)t 0 , where 0 is a positive constant; and (ii) the tax does not become large enough to make the …rm want to cease production while it has remaining resource stock. Let T be the …nal date of extraction under a zero tax. Under the tax, the taxinclusive unit cost for the …rm in period T is C + (1 + r)T 0 . Assumption (ii) states that C + (1 + r)T 0 is less than the choke price. Consider the perturbation that reduces period 0 extraction by one unit, and makes an o¤setting one unit increase in period t extraction. The reduction in current extraction reduces the present value of the …rm’s tax liability by 0 ; the increase in period t extraction increases the present value of the …rm’s tax liability by t t = t (1 + r)t 0 = 0 . In this case, moving a unit of extraction from the current period to a future period has no e¤ect on the present value of the …rm’s tax liability. This tax has no e¤ect on the extraction pro…le or on consumer prices. The consumer incidence is 0; …rms bear the entire tax incidence. The present value of the tax receipts is T X t=0 t (1 + r) t 0 yt = 0 T X yt = 0 x0 t=0 This tax transfers the rent 0 x0 from producers to taxpayers, without creating a distortion. Equation 5.9 shows that under constant extraction costs and zero tax, the value of the …rm is R0 x0 . Therefore, under the tax considered here, the after-tax value of the …rm is (R0 0 ) x0 , where R0 is the pre-tax initial rent. By setting the initial tax, 0 , close to R0 , the government can 12.2. THE LOGIC OF RESOURCE TAXES 217 extract nearly all of the rent from the resource owner. Investment Rent is the return to a factor of production in …xed supply; quasi-rent is the return to a previous, now “sunk”, investment. Chapter 4.3 notes that most natural resource stocks require signi…cant investment in exploration and development. Thus, the di¤erence between the price that a …rm receives and its marginal cost of extracting the resource, is actually the sum of rent and quasi-rent. We referred to this sum as “rent” merely in the interest of simplicity. Now, for the purpose of studying tax policy, the distinction is important. For example, suppose that the initial rent + quasi-rent for a mine with constant extraction costs is R0 = 10 and the initial stock is x0 = 10, so the value of this mine (using equation 5.9) is 100. Suppose, in addition, that each mine costs 5 to develop, and on average a …rm must develop …ve mines to …nd one that is successful. We assume that the development cost 5 includes the cost of capital and that the …rm can test many potential mines at the same time, understanding that on average 20% of them will be successful.1 It is important to account for all of the unsuccessful mines in estimating the development cost of a successful mine. In this example, the expected investment cost for a successful mine is 25. Here, the rent on the mine is 75 and the quasi-rent is 25. Prior to the exploration and development, the government might announce a tax that begins, at the time of initial extraction, at 7:5, and rises at the rate of interest. With this tax, the government captures all of the rent, but leaves …rms with the quasi-rent. In this case, …rms break even, and are willing to undertake the investment. (As a practical matter, it would be important to leave …rms with some rent, in order to induce them to undertake the risk; we ignore that complication, in assuming that …rms are risk neutral.) Once a successful mine is in operation, the government might be tempted to renege on its announcement, and to impose an initial tax of 0 = 10, which increases at the rate of interest. This tax transfers all of the rent + quasi-rent from the …rm to taxpayers. The …rm in this case loses all of its sunk investment costs. This temptation to renege illustrates the potential time-inconsistency of optimal plans. 1 For example, if …rms have to invest I at time 0 to learn, after three years, whether 3 the mine is successful, then I (1 + r) = 5. 218 CHAPTER 12. TAXES: NONRENEWABLE RESOURCES The real-world importance of this time inconsistency varies with the setting. If there are many cycles of investment and extraction, then the government has an incentive to adhere to its promises in order to maintain its reputation. By behaving opportunistically, this government obtains some short run bene…ts, in the form of higher tax revenue, but it discourages future investment: it kills the goose that lays the golden eggs. This time inconsistency is therefore more important for a single large project, e.g. a one-time development of o¤shore oil deposits. (All of these considerations also apply to non-resource related infrastructure projects, e.g. building a harbor or developing a transportation network.) In this case, the government’s temptation to renege may be greater if the major investors are foreigners; domestic investors might be better able to defend their interests in the political process that determines the tax. For large one-o¤ foreign-sourced investment projects, time inconsistency can be a major issue. Without some protection, the foreign investors would be unwilling to undertake the project, or would require a large risk premium for doing so. This reluctance to invest is an example of the “holdup problem”, which occurs whenever an action that is mutually bene…cial (here, investment) leaves one party exposed to the risk of opportunistic actions (here, con…scatory tax) by the other. The OECD and other international organizations attempted, during the 1980s and 1990s, to negotiate a Multilateral Agreement on Investment to resolve this hold-up problem. The hope was that this agreement would encourage international investment, in much the same way that the World Trade Organization promotes international trade. Largely due to resistance from developing countries, this e¤ort was unsuccessful. However, there are currently thousands of Bilateral Investment Treaties (BITs), most of which involve one rich and one developing country; the U.S. is party to over 40 BITs. The parties of these treaties are countries, not private …rms, but many of the treaties have an “investor-to-state”provision. This provision permits a private investor originating in one signatory (usually the rich country) to sue, in an international court, the government of the other signatory (usually the developing country) for violation of the treaty. A primary purpose of the treaties is to protect an investor against overt con…scation of their investment, but many treaties also provide protection against measures that are “tantamount to expropriation”, such as “con…scatory taxes”or even post-investment changes to environmental rules. Business interests regard 12.3. AN EXAMPLE 219 tax 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 0 1 2 Figure 12.1: The tax pro…le for (dashed). 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 = 0:05 (solid), 10 11 12 t = 0:5 (dotted) and = 0:8 the investor-to-state provision of these treaties as essential, because they are not con…dent that their own government would act in their interests. For example, foreign policy considerations might make the U.S. government reluctant to invoke a treaty in protection of a U.S. investor. The investor, in contrast, has no such qualms about exercising the treaty rights. The treaties provide a self-enforcing mechanism, a credible commitment against opportunistic behavior. However, they also limit a country’s ability to exercise what are known as “police powers” (e.g. environmental regulation) and to respond to contingencies not foreseen at the time of investment (e.g. a major recession). Although business groups strongly support these treaties, some NGOs think that they harm developing country interests. 12.3 An example A numerical example illustrates the e¤ect on resource markets of a particular time-varying tax, (t) = b (t + 1) , with b 0 and 1 > 0. At time t = 0, the tax equals is (0) = b. The rate of increase of the tax is d (t) dt (t) = t+1 : The rate of increase begins (when t = 0) at and falls steadily to 0 at t increases. The tax increases over time, approaching 1 as t ! 1, but the tax increases at a decreasing rate; after a while, the tax increases very slowly. The e¤ect of the tax on the incentive to extract is intuitive. If is close to 0, so the tax grows slowly, then the situation is similar to the constant tax 220 CHAPTER 12. TAXES: NONRENEWABLE RESOURCES case. We saw (Chapter 12.2) that in this case the tax creates an incentive to delay extraction, as a means of decreasing the present value of the tax liability. If is large, the tax grows quickly. Here, the …rm has an incentive to accelerate extraction so that more of its sales incur the relatively low current taxes instead of high future taxes, reducing the …rm’s present value tax liability. Figure 12.1 shows the tax pro…le for three values of for b = 1. These tax begin at (0) = 1 and approach in…nity as t becomes large. With = 0:05, the tax is approximately 1.12 after 12 periods and with = 0:8 the tax reaches 7.6 after 12 periods. Larger values of imply a more rapid increase in the tax. Box 12.1 The e¤ect of the tax on the timing of extraction. By extracting one less unit in period 0 and instead extracting that unit in period t, the present value of the tax liability falls by b and int creases by t b (t + 1) , for a net decrease of b b (t + 1) . A bit of computation establishes that d ( t b (t + 1) dt b) > 0 if and only if ln (1 + r) > t+1 : For small r, ln (1 + r) r. Using this approximation, we see that if r > t+1 , the tax creates an incentive to delay extraction. This inequality holds for all t if = 0, the case we already considered in Chapter 12.2. However, if is large, then the inequality does not hold early in the program (when t is small); in that case, the tax creates an incentive for the …rm to extract earlier rather than later. 12.3.1 Calculating the price trajectory For our example, demand is 10 p, the constant average cost is C = 1, the initial stock is x0 = 20, and annual discount rate is 4%. We …nd the equilibrium price trajectory (for a given tax pro…le) and then graph the consumer and producer incidence corresponding to that tax trajectory. Consumers pay the price p (t), so the producer’s after-tax price is p (t) (t). The rent at at time t is p (t) (t) C. The Euler equation requires that the present value of rent is the same at each instant when extraction is positive. In particular, the present value of 12.3. AN EXAMPLE 221 rent at time t equals the present value of rent at the …nal time, T : t (p (t) C (t)) = T (p (T ) C (T )) : (12.1) The resource is (by assumption) exhausted, i.e. cumulative sales equal the initial stock, x0 : T X (10 p (t)) = x0 = 20: (12.2) t=0 The amount extracted at time t equals the amount consumed, which equals 10 p (t). Therefore, the left side of equation 12.2 equals the amount extracted during the program, which equals the initial stock; for our example, it is not optimal to stop extracting while some resource remains in the ground. Chapter 7 shows that it is possible to solve these equations (together with the transversality condition) to …nd the complete solution: the number of periods, T , and the level of sales and the price in each period. As we noted before, it is easier to solve (but more di¢ cult to explain) the continuous time version of this problem. In addition, the smooth graphs in the continuous time setting are easier to interpret than the step functions (or points) that arise in the discrete time model. We therefore present all results in this section using a continuous time model. Box 12. The continuous time model The Euler equation in the continuous time setting implies equation 12.1. To obtain the continuous time version of equation 12.2, we replace the summation with an integral, to write Z T (10 p (t)) dt = 20: (12.3) 0 At any time after T , when the resource has been exhausted, the price equals the level that drives demand to 0, so p (t) = 10 for t > T . If it were the case that p (T ) < 10, there would be an upward jump in the price at time T . That jump would imply that by delaying extraction an in…nitesimal amount of time, the resource owner increases the present discounted value of pro…ts; the jump therefore violates the no-intertemporal-arbitrage condition. Consequently, p (T ) = 10, the choke price, in the continuous time model. 222 CHAPTER 12. TAXES: NONRENEWABLE RESOURCES p 11 10 9 8 7 6 5 4 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 t Figure 12.2: The equilibrium consumer price trajectory under the tax = (t + 1)0:05 (solid); under the tax = (t + 1)0:8 (dashed); and price under zero tax, = 0 (dotted). Demand = 10 p, constant extraction costs c = 1, initial stock x0 = 20, and discount rate r = 0:04. Graphs are shown for continuous time model. 12.3.2 The price trajectories Using p (T ) = 10, we can solve equations 12.1 and 12.3 numerically for the three taxes. For the zero tax, = 0, we obtain the terminal time T = 11:2. For the slowly growing tax, = (t + 1)0:05 , the terminal time is only slightly greater, T = 11:5. The rapidly growing tax, = (t + 1)0:8 , gives producers a strong incentive to extract early, while the tax is still relatively low, leading to a much earlier exhaustion time, T = 7:5. Figure 12.2 shows the equilibrium price trajectories under these three tax pro…les. Each trajectory reaches the choke price at the time of exhaustion. The equilibrium price trajectories under the zero tax (dotted) and under the slowly increasing tax, = (t + 1)0:05 , (solid) are almost indistinguishable. The positive tax encourages …rms to delay extraction, which tends to increase the initial price; but the fact that the tax pro…le is increasing encourages …rms to move extraction forward in time, which tends to reduce the initial price. When the tax rises slowly, these two e¤ects almost cancel each other, but the net e¤ect is to slightly increase the initial consumer price, from 6.72 to 6.86, and to slightly delay the exhaustion date. (Compare the solid and the dotted graphs.) The steeply rising tax trajectory gives …rms a much stronger incentive to extract early, while the tax is still relatively low. The 12.3. AN EXAMPLE incidence 223 120 100 80 producer incidence 60 40 20 consumer incidence 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 t -20 Figure 12.3: Consumer and producer incidence of tax under the slowly increasing tax steeply rising tax therefore leads to a substantially lower initial price and earlier exhaustion. (Compare the dashed and the solid graphs.) 12.3.3 Tax incidence Figure 12.3 graphs the producer and the consumer tax incidences, as a function of time, under the slowly growing tax. As in Chapter 11.2, the consumer incidence is de…ned as the di¤erence in the consumer price with and without the tax, divided by the tax, times 100 (to convert to a percent). The consumer and producer tax incidences sum to 100 by de…nition, so we obtain the producer incidence by subtracting the consumer incidence from 100. The consumer incidence begins at about 15% but over time falls to a negative level. The price paths corresponding to the zero and the slowly growing tax shown in Figure 12.2 (the dotted and solid curves, respectively) cross at about t = 6:5. At later dates, the tax reduces the equilibrium consumer price, so the consumer incidence is negative there. Over this region, the producer incidence is greater than 100%. Figure 12.4 graphs the consumer and producer tax incidence over time under the rapidly growing tax. This tax lowers the equilibrium consumer price for t < 4:5, so over this region, the consumer incidence is negative, and the producer incidence exceeds 100%. At later dates, the tax incidence for both consumers and producers lies between 0 and 100%. These last two …gures show that even in an extremely simple model, the 224 CHAPTER 12. TAXES: NONRENEWABLE RESOURCES incidence 300 200 producer incidence 100 0 1 2 3 4 Consumer incidence 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 t -100 -200 Figure 12.4: Consumer and producer incidence of tax under the rapidly increasing tax trajectories of tax incidence can be quite complicated. The tax causes a reallocation of supply over time, but no change in aggregate supply (equal to the initial stock) over the life of the resource. Thus, there must be some periods during which the tax lowers the equilibrium consumer price. Over those periods, the consumer tax incidence is negative, and the producer tax incidence exceeds 100%. In contrast, in a static competitive model both the consumer and producer tax incidences lie between 0 and 100%. Box 12.3 The pro…ts tax Exercise 2 in Chapter 11 explores the e¤ect of a constant pro…ts tax in a static model. That exercise shows that a constant pro…ts tax, , extracts rent from producers, but has no e¤ect on equilibrium price or quantity. This result also holds for resource markets. The constant pro…ts tax reduces pro…ts in each period proportionally, and does not alter the …rm’s incentives about when to produce. A time varying pro…ts tax, (t), does alter the …rm’s incentives, and therefore a¤ects consumers in addition to …rms. 12.3.4 Welfare changes If the price in period t is p, consumer surplus (CS (t)), producer pro…t (P S (t)), and tax revenue (G (t), for “government”) in that period equal, 12.3. AN EXAMPLE 225 respectively, CS = R 10 p (10 q) dq = 50 P S = (p (t) 10p + 12 p2 1) (10 G = (t) (10 (12.4) p) p) : The equilibrium p changes over time, so the functions CS; P S; G also change over time. In static models, we are accustomed to thinking about a component of social welfare (e.g. consumer or producer surplus or tax revenue) as a single number. In dynamic models, it is important to think of these payo¤s as being trajectories. We de…ne an agent’s welfare as the present discounted value of their stream of single period payo¤s. Welfare for consumers, producers, and taxpayers equal, respectively, Z T Z T Z T t t t G (t) dt: (12.5) P S (t) dt, CS (t) dt, 0 0 0 The sum of these three integrals equals social welfare. Table 1 shows welfare for consumers, producers, and taxpayers, and the sum of these three welfare measures (social welfare) under the zero tax and for both the slowly and the rapidly growing tax. The table also shows the percent change in welfare for consumers, producers, and society as a whole, in moving from the 0 tax to either of the two positive taxes. consumer welfare zero tax 20.2 “slow tax” 19 % change -5.9% “fast tax” 33.1 % change +64% producer welfare 114.4 97.2 -15% 50.1 -56.2% taxpayer welfare 0 18.3 NA 47 NA social welfare 134.6 134.5 -0.07% 130.2 -3.3% DWL tax rev 5. 5 10 3 9. 4 10 2 Table 12.1: Agents’welfare and % change in welfare under the zero tax, the “slow tax” (t) = (t + 1)0:05 , and the “fast tax” (t) = (t + 1)0:8 . “% change”is relative to = 0. Just as in the static model, the slowly growing tax reduces consumer and producer welfare, here by 6% and 15%, respectively. The increase in tax revenue (from 0 to 18.3) almost o¤sets those two reductions, so social 226 CHAPTER 12. TAXES: NONRENEWABLE RESOURCES welfare under this tax falls by less than a tenth of 1%. Social welfare falls by over 3% under the rapidly growing tax. We previously observed this pattern in the static model. In discussing Figure 11.3, we noted that any non-zero tax leads to deadweight loss, and the deadweight loss (or at least its approximation) increases with the square of tax. The deadweight loss is negligible at a small tax, and increases with the magnitude of the tax. The social loss per unit of tax revenue (both expressed as present discounted sums) equals 134:618:3134:5 = 0:0055 for the slowly growing tax, and 134:647130:3 = 0:094 for the rapidly growing tax. To convert to percentage, multiply by 100. For example, the social cost as a percent of tax revenue for the slowly growing tax is 0.55%, i.e., about one half of one percent. For both of these examples, the social loss per unit of tax revenue is negligible. In the static setting, the tax (weakly) increases the equilibrium price that consumers face, and thus lowers consumer welfare. In contrast, in the nonrenewable resource setting, the tax increases price in some periods and lowers prices in other periods. Depending on the magnitude and the timing of the changes, consumer welfare might either increase or decrease. Figure 12.2 shows that the rapidly growing tax leads to a fall in consumer price early in the trajectory, and an increase in the consumer price late in the trajectory. The tax thus increases the ‡ow of consumer surplus early in the trajectory and lowers the ‡ow of consumer surplus late in the trajectory. Because of discounting, the early increases count for more, in terms of present discounted value, than do the later reductions. Thus, the rapidly growing tax increases the present discounted value of the stream of consumer surplus. This tax bene…ts consumers and leads to a large increase in tax revenue (from 0 to 47), but it also causes a large (56%) decrease in producer welfare. The tax decreases aggregate social welfare by 3.3%. 12.3.5 Consumer welfare in a dynamic setting We proceeded as if using the present discounted stream of surplus to measure consumers’and producers’welfare is so obvious as not to require comment. Although this procedure is standard in economics, it has a serious shortcoming when applied to consumers. We mention the problem here, and take it up more carefully in Chapter xx. Suppose that we have in mind a resource that will last 200 years. Clearly, the consumers alive today are not the same people who will be consuming in 100 years or more. What does it mean to say that “consumer welfare” increases under the 12.4. SUMMARY 227 rapidly growing tax? The individuals currently consuming are clearly better o¤, because the tax causes them to face a lower price. However, the consumers late in the period are worse o¤, because the tax causes them to face a higher price, or possibly leads to exhaustion of the resource before they are born. The ethical objection to our welfare measure is that it adds up the utility of people who are alive at di¤erent points in time. Moreover, it does so in a way that privileges those currently living, because the welfare measure discounts the surplus of future generations of consumers. Our measure of social surplus at a point in time also adds up the surplus of possibly di¤erent people, consumers and producers. That aggregation is ethically less questionable, for two reasons. First, consumers and producers may or may not be di¤erent people, whereas individuals living today and in 100 years are certainly di¤erent people. Second, consumers and producers currently living have at least the potential for in‡uencing current government policy that a¤ects their well-being. People living in the future have no direct voice in the current political process. 12.4 Summary The theory of optimal taxation suggests that fossil fuels should be relatively heavily taxed, in order to o¤set the negative externality associated with their consumption, and to take advantage of their relatively low elasticity of supply. In practice, both rich and developing nations, and both importers and exporters subsidize consumption of fossil fuels. Political constraints impede international attempts to move toward more rational resource policies. Although the equilibrium e¤ects of taxes applied to nonrenewable resources is more complicated than in the static model, the methods developed in earlier chapters make the outline of the analysis straightforward. A constant tax on extraction encourages …rms to delay extraction, raising consumer prices early in the program and lowering prices later in the program. A tax that increases at the rate of interest has no e¤ect on the extraction trajectory, because the present value of this tax is constant. A tax that increases rapidly over time increases …rms’ incentive to extract early, before the tax is high. This e¤ect tends to o¤set the incentive of a constant tax to delay extraction. If the tax increases very slowly, then the “delay incentive”is the stronger of the two. However, if the tax increases rapidly, producers respond to the tax by moving the extraction pro…le forward in time. Thus, a rapidly 228 CHAPTER 12. TAXES: NONRENEWABLE RESOURCES increasing tax lowers price early in the program and increases later prices. Taxes (other than the tax with constant present value) lead to a reallocation of supply over time. Therefore, there are some periods when the tax leads to an increase in supply, relative to the no-tax case; for those periods, the consumer incidence of the tax is negative, and the producer incidence of the tax exceeds 100%. These periods of negative consumer tax incidence tend to occur late in the program, if the tax is constant or increases slowly; those periods tend to occur early in the period if the tax increases rapidly. The zero-tax competitive equilibrium maximizes social surplus, so in the setting here a tax of any nature reduces social surplus. In the static competitive setting, both consumers and producers bear some of the incidence of the tax. The tax therefore decreases the welfare of both agents. In the resource setting with stock-independent extraction costs, the tax shifts production from one period to another, without altering cumulative production. In this case, the tax must lower price and therefore increase consumer surplus in some periods. The tax might either increase or decrease the present discounted value of the stream of consumer surplus, as our examples showed. However, the tax reduces the producer price (equal to the price consumers pay minus the unit tax) in every period. Therefore the producer incidence is positive in every period. In addition, the tax lowers producer pro…t (equal to the producer price minus extraction costs, times sales) in every period. Therefore, the tax necessarily lowers the present discounted stream of producer pro…t. We emphasize the relation between taxes and extraction decisions, usually keeping the investment decision in the background. However, investment is important in resource markets, creating “quasi-rents”, the return to a previous investment. Price minus marginal costs, which we usually refer to as “resource rent”is in fact the sum of genuine rent and quasi-rent. The fact that investment is sunk at the time of extraction creates a time consistency or holdup problem for policy makers. This problem is likely most severe in the case of large, one-o¤ foreign investments. Bilateral investment treaties, with an investor-to-state provision, is an attempt at solving this hold-up problem. 12.5. TERMS, STUDY QUESTIONS, AND EXERCISES 12.5 229 Terms, study questions, and exercises Terms and concepts Tax trajectories, hold-up problem, rate of change of a tax (or of anything else), trajectories of producer and consumer tax incidence, intertemporal welfare (the integral, or the sum, of the discounted stream of consumer or producer welfare). Study questions For all these questions, assume that the average = marginal extraction cost is constant with respect to extraction and independent of the stock of the resource. 1. (a) Explain how a constant tax alters the competitive nonrenewable resource owner’s incentives to extract, and thus how the tax a¤ects the equilibrium price trajectory. (b) Now explain how an increasing tax trajectory alters the competitive resource owner’s incentives, and thereby alters the equilibrium price trajectory. (Your answer to both parts should make clear how the taxes a¤ect the relative advantage of extracting at one point instead of another.) (c) Use your answers to parts (a) and (b) to explain why the three tax pro…les shown in Figure 12.1 give rise to the three price pro…les shown in Figure 12.2. 2. Using Figure 12.2, sketch the consumer and producer tax incidence over time, for the slowly growing and the rapidly growing tax. (Figures in the text actually show those graphs. You should see whether you can produce the sketches using only Figure 12.2 and then compare your answers with the …gures in the text. Your sketches will not get the magnitudes correct, but they should correctly show the intervals of time where an incidence is negative, positive and less than 100%, or greater than 100%. If you do it carefully, you can also see where the incidences are increasing or decreasing over time. The point of this question is to see whether you REALLY know what tax incidence means. 3. (a) Explain why, in the static setting, a tax always reduces consumer surplus. (b) Explain why, in the resource setting, the tax must increase consumer surplus at some points in time. (c) Explain why your 230 CHAPTER 12. TAXES: NONRENEWABLE RESOURCES answer to part (b) implies that a tax might either increase of decrease the present discount stream of consumer surplus. (d) Is there any objection to using the present discounted stream of consumer surplus as a measure of consumer welfare? Exercises 1. Suppose that the government uses a pro…ts tax, (t), instead of a unit tax. This pro…ts tax equals (t) = 1 exp ( t) with > 0. (a) Sketch two graphs of this tax, as function of time, on the same …gure, for a small and a large value of . (b) Following the logic in the text for the increasing unit tax, brie‡y explain the e¤ect of an increasing pro…ts tax on the equilibrium extraction pro…le. (You have to think about how the increasing pro…ts tax a¤ects the …rm’s incentive to extract the resource. (c) Compare the equilibrium e¤ect (on the extraction pro…le) of a constant unit tax and a constant pro…ts tax. What explains this di¤erence between the two types of constant taxes? 2. You need functional forms and parameter values to calculate the taxincidence graphs shown in Figures 12.3 and 12.4, but you can infer their general shape by inspection of Figure 12.2, and from the de…nition of “tax incidence”. Explain how to make this inference. 3. The text considers the e¤ect of a tax in a model with stock-independent extraction costs. How might stock dependent extraction costs alter the trajectories of tax incidence. (This question calls for intelligent speculation, not calculation.) 4. Suppose that …rms have constant extraction costs and face a time varying pro…ts tax, (t) = (0:05) t . Under this tax, if extraction in period t is y, a …rm’s after-tax pro…t is (1 (t)) (p (y) y C). (a) On the same …gure, graph (t) (as a function of t) for < 1 and also for > 1. (b) Using intelligent speculation (not calculation), explain how these two pro…ts tax a¤ects the equilibrium price and extraction paths. (Figures will make your explanations clearer.) Provide the economic logic for your answer. 5. Justify the claim that the functions in equation 12.4 do indeed equal consumer and producer welfare and tax revenue. 12.5. TERMS, STUDY QUESTIONS, AND EXERCISES 231 Sources Sinclair (1992) points out the e¤ect of a rising carbon tax on the incentive to extract fossil fuels. Boadway and Keen (2009) survey the theory of resource taxation. Chapter 12.1 is based largely on the IEA, OPEC, OECD and World Bank Joint Report (2011). The IMF paper by Coady et al (2015) provides estimates of the cost (including environmental costs) of resource subsidies. Aldy (2013) discusses the …scal implications of eliminating U.S. fossil fuel subsidies. Daubanes and Andrade de Sa (2014) consider the role of resource taxation when the discovery and development of new deposits is costly. Lund (2009) reviews the literature on resource taxation under uncertainty. Bohn and Deacon (2000) discuss investment risk with natural resources. Aisbett et al. (2010) discuss investment risk and bilateral investment treaties. 232 CHAPTER 12. TAXES: NONRENEWABLE RESOURCES Chapter 13 Property rights and regulation Objectives Understand how the establishment of property rights alters the problem of second-best regulation. Information and skills A basic knowledge of the consequences of and the evolution of property rights. Familiarity with the Coase Theorem, and understanding its relevance to policy in the presence of externalities. An overview of the history of …shery regulation, and understanding why regulation has led to overcapitalization in the sector Understanding how individual quotas establish property rights, and the e¤ects of these quotas. We have emphasized competitive equilibria in nonrenewable resource markets (e.g., oil, coal) with perfect property rights. This chapter sets the stage for a discussion of renewable resources (e.g. …sh, groundwater, forests, the climate), emphasizing the role of imperfect property rights. We begin with a general discussion of property rights and then show that the emergence of an e¢ cient outcome depends on the existence but not on the allocation of property rights (i.e., who possesses the property rights). This result is known as the Coase Theorem. 233 234 CHAPTER 13. PROPERTY RIGHTS AND REGULATION We then discuss the role of property rights and regulation in …sheries. Fisheries provide a natural focus for this discussion, because: they are economically important; they are plagued by imperfect property rights; there is a large body of research devoted to their study; and the insight gained from studying …sheries is applicable to many other resource problems, e.g. water and forests. Due to over…shing, loss of habitat, and climate change, 30% of the world’s …sheries are at risk of population collapse. Fisheries support nations’ well-being through direct employment in …shing, processing, and ancillary services amounting to hundreds of billions of dollars annually. Fish provide nearly 3 billion people with 15 percent of their animal protein needs; including post-catch activities and workers’dependents, marine …sheries support nearly 8% of the world’s population. 13.1 Overview of property rights Objectives and skills Know the characteristics of the three leading types of property rights, and understand that none of them eliminate the need for regulation. A spectrum of social arrangements govern the use of natural resources. The three leading modes are private property, common property, and open access. With private property, an individual or a well-de…ned group of individuals (e.g. a company) owns the asset and determines how it is used. Under common property, use of the asset is limited to a certain group of people, e.g. those living in a town or an area; community members pursuing their individual self-interest, instead of a single agent, decide how to use the asset. Anyone is free to use an open access resource. A farm owned by an individual, family, or corporation, is private property. The owner decides how to use the farm. A …eld on which anyone in the village can graze their cows, but from which those outside the village are excluded, is common property. A …eld that anyone can use is open access. This taxonomy identi…es di¤erent types of ownership structure, but in practice the boundaries between them are often blurred. Labor, health, and environmental laws govern working conditions and pesticide use on privately owned land, limiting the exercise of private property rights. In Britain, common law allows anyone to use paths across privately owned farmland, 13.1. OVERVIEW OF PROPERTY RIGHTS 235 provided that they do not create a nuisance, such as leaving gates open, further limiting private property rights; in Norway, people are allowed to enter uncultivated private property to pick berries. Common property dilutes property rights, but social norms often limit community members’actions. Anyone in the village may be allowed to use the village common, but they might be restricted to grazing one cow, not ten. Even for an asset that is nominally open access, members of a group might exert pressure to restrict outsiders. Local surfers at some California public beaches make it uncomfortable or dangerous for outsiders to surf. As these examples suggest, there is a continuum of types of property rights, not three neat types. De jure property rights describe the legal status of property, and de facto property rights describe the actual property rights. De jure and de facto property rights might coincide or di¤er. In the sur…ng example, the de jure property rights are open access, but to the extent that the local surfers are successful in excluding outsiders, the de facto property rights more closely resemble common property. Property rights to a resource may change over time, often responding to migration and increased trade, and often accompanied by social upheaval. The enclosure movement in the UK, converting village commons to private property, began in the 13th century and was formalized by acts of parliament in the 18th and 19th century. These enclosures increased agricultural productivity and dispossessed a large part of the rural population. In the late 19th and early 20th century Igbo groups in Nigeria converted palm trees from private to common property in response to increased palm oil trade. Trade increased the value of the palm trees, increasing the need to protect them from over-harvesting. In this case (but not in general) monitoring and enforcement costs needed to protect the resource were lower under common property. The 1924 White Act in Alaska, later incorporated into the state’s constitution, abrogated aboriginal community rights to the salmon …shery. The Act also disallowed private ownership, insuring that non-residents would not control the resource. The Act was rationalized by the claim that the resource is owned by the nation, not the communities previously managing it. Open access replaced e¤ective common property management, leading to resource degradation and requiring regulation. 236 CHAPTER 13. PROPERTY RIGHTS AND REGULATION A long-running dispute in the U.S. tests the limits of private property rights. The legal doctrine of “regulatory taking” seeks to de…ne zoning and environmental rules that diminish the value of property as “takings”, requiring compensation under the Fifth Amendment to the U.S. constitution. The doctrine’s objective is to weaken governments’ police powers (e.g. environmental regulation), strengthening the rights of private property owners.1 Periodic legal disputes in coastal states, including California and Texas, test landowners’ability to impede access to beaches, or to insist on public investment (e.g. sea walls) that maintains the value of private property. Private property diminishes or eliminates some externalities that are prevalent under common property or open access. Grazing an additional cow on a …eld creates bene…ts for the cow’s owner. If the cow competes with other animals for fodder, it creates a negative externality for other owners, much in the way that an additional driver contributes to road congestion. The overgrazing also damages the …eld, lowering its long run productivity, thus lowering both short and long run community welfare. This outcome is known as the “tragedy of the commons”. Private owners internalize the congestion created by the additional cow, and are therefore less likely to overgraze the …eld. To the extent that private property avoids the tragedy of the commons, it improves resource management.2 An emerging body of research shows that many societies have successfully managed common property natural resources, avoiding the tragedy of the commons. Common property management requires widespread agreement on the rules of use, and mechanisms for monitoring and enforcement of the rules. Private property also requires adjudication of disputes, and monitoring and enforcement of laws. Stable conditions and homogenous users 1 Supreme Court rulings have largely rea¢ rmed these police powers, undermining the Doctrine of Regulatory Takings. Bilateral Investment Treaties (Chapter 12.2) requiring compensation for regulation that is “tantamount to expropriation” strengthens the Doctrine in the sphere of international, rather than US domestic law. 2 Anyone who has lived in a shared household already knows a great deal about the potential bene…ts and pitfalls of common property. A person who buys or leases their own house has private ownership, within the terms of their lease and the local laws. Private housing is on the private property end of the property rights continuum. A squat resembles the open access resource. No squatter has de jure property rights to the dwelling, although a squatter or a group of squatters might be able to exclude outsiders and enforce rules, much like the surfers on some beaches. A communal household lies between a private house and a squat, and is a type of common property. 13.1. OVERVIEW OF PROPERTY RIGHTS 237 increase the success of common property management. A rapid change that increases the demand for the resource, such as migration or opening to trade, can undermine common property management. Historical events during the last quarter century show that private property does not guarantee e¢ cient management. When the Soviet Union collapsed in 1991, reformers and their western advisors (primarily economists) debated the right pace of privatization of state owned property. Those supporting rapid privatization hoped that it would lead to the e¢ cient use of natural and man-made capital, and feared that a slower pace would only perpetuate the ine¢ ciencies and make it possible to reverse the reforms. Privatization occurred rapidly, but instead of leading it e¢ ciency it created a class of oligarchs and an entrenched system of corruption. Following a political upheaval, local elites might capture resources, replacing common property with private property, thus rendering the traditional monitoring and enforcement mechanisms irrelevant. In a politically unstable environment, the new owners recognize that the next political upheaval might replace them with another group of elites, making their property rights insecure. The combination of current absolute but insecure property rights is particularly likely to lead to overuse of the resource. The current owners can use the resource as they see …t, usually to enrich themselves; the risk of losing control of the resource gives them the incentive to attach little weight to its future uses. In summary, actual property rights tend to exist on a continuum that includes the three main types as special cases. Regulation is particularly necessary under open access, which is especially vulnerable to the tragedy of the commons. Common property management in small communities has (often) avoided this tragedy. As communities integrate into wider markets, the management practices frequently break down, requiring di¤erent kinds of regulation. Private property solves some externality problems but creates others, and also typically requires regulation. For example, converting the village commons to a privately owned farm gives the farmer the incentive to manage the land e¢ ciently (e.g. to avoid erosion), but not to correct o¤-farm externalities (e.g. pollution run-o¤). Arguably, in this example the problem lies not with private ownership of the land, but with the lack of property rights to the waterways that absorb the pollution. With this view, the policy prescription is to create property rights for the waterways. Creating those additional rights may be too expensive or politically or ethically unacceptable, in which case the policy prescription is to regulate the 238 CHAPTER 13. PROPERTY RIGHTS AND REGULATION pollution. 13.2 The Coase Theorem Objectives and skills Be able to state and explain the Coase Theorem. Be able to apply the theorem to speci…c settings. Transactions costs include the costs of reaching and enforcing an agreement. The Coase Theorem states that if transactions costs are negligible, and property rights are well-de…ned, agents can reach the e¢ cient outcome regardless of the distribution (or allocation) of property rights. The basis for this result is that rational agents will not leave money on the table if it is costless for them to pick it up. Under the conditions of the theorem, there is no need for a regulator, because private agents reach an e¢ cient outcome by bargaining. The government’s only role is to insure that agents honor their contracts, and possibly to make transfers in order to promote fairness; e¢ ciency does not require those transfers. In many situations where we observe regulation instead of a bargained outcome, transactions costs are large, making it impractical for agents, bargaining amongst themselves, to achieve an e¢ cient outcome. In other situations, the property rights are not well-de…ned, leaving agents uncertain about the payo¤s of reaching a bargain, making it more di¢ cult to reach an agreement. Most natural resource problems, including those that arise in …sheries, require some form of regulation. To illustrate the Coase Theorem, suppose that the total pro…t of a …shery depends on the number of boats operating there. With one boat, the pro…t is 1, with two boats, the aggregate pro…t is 4, and with three boats, the aggregate pro…t is 3. Initially, three boats, each with a separate owner, operate in the …shery. The surplus obtained from inducing one boat to exit equals 4 3 = 1. In an extreme case, one person has exclusive property rights to the …shery. That person would insist that the other two …shers leave the sector, and the person would buy an additional boat, thus increasing industry pro…t by 1 and reaching the optimal outcome. If all three …shers have some property rights, and if the transactions costs are small, then they can reach an agreement 13.3. REGULATION OF FISHERIES 239 in which one of them sells her right to …sh to the other two and leaves the sector. There are many types of bargains that they might strike, leading to di¤erent splits of the surplus. The Coase Theorem does not identify the particular bargain reached. For example, if the three …shers are equally productive, they can create a lottery that determines who leaves the sector.3 The person who leaves receives a payment of 1 + x, their initial pro…t plus the compensation x for leaving. The two remaining …shers split the higher pro…t, each receiving 2, and share the cost of buying out the departing …sher, for a net bene…t . The expected payo¤ to an agent participating in a fair lottery of 2 1+x 2 = (where the chance of leaving the sector is 1=3) is 31 (1 + x) + 23 2 1+x 2 4 1 , which is greater than their payo¤ under the status quo (1). If x > , the 3 3 person who leaves is a winner, and if the inequality is reversed, this person is a loser; setting x = 13 insures that there are no losers. Other procedures, not involving a lottery (e.g. arm wrestling), could also be used to determine who leaves. The Coase Theorem does not predict how the e¢ cient outcome is obtained (a lottery or arm wrestling) or the compensation (x in the lottery example). It merely says that if transactions costs are small and property rights well de…ned, rational agents will bargain and achieve an e¢ cient outcome. Di¤erences in bargaining power, perhaps due to di¤erences in outside options (a …sher’s best alternative to remaining in the sector) or levels of bargaining skill lead to di¤erent distributions but not di¤erent levels of the bargaining surplus. 13.3 Regulation of …sheries Objectives and skills Know the basics of the recent history of …shery regulation. Understand how, under limited regulation, …shers’ endogenous decisions limit the e¢ cacy of regulation. Understand how assigning property rights can alleviate the regulatory problem. 3 If the …shers are not equally productive, then an e¢ cient procedure must chose the two most productive to remain in the …shery. 240 CHAPTER 13. PROPERTY RIGHTS AND REGULATION Prior to the 20th century, the concept of “freedom of the seas” gave nations sovereignty up to three miles from their coastline. Other nations’ ships were allowed to operate outside that area. In the 20th century, nations began to claim control of larger areas, often to protect their rights to …sh stocks. The United Nations Convention on the Law of the Sea, concluded in 1982, replaced earlier agreements, giving nations an “exclusive economic zone” (EEZ), e.g. to harvest …sh or extract oil, 200 miles beyond their coastline. The U.S. passed the Manguson-Stevens Fishery Conservation and Management Act in 1976 and amended it in 1996 and 2006, to promote optimal use of …sheries within its EEZ. Goals included: conserving …shery resources, enforcing international …shing agreements, developing under-used …sheries, protecting …sh habitat, and limiting “bycatch” (…sh caught unintentionally, while in pursuit of other types of …sh). The law established Regional Fishery Management Councils, charged with developing Fishery Management Plans (FMPs). These FMPs identify over…shed stocks and propose plans to restore and protect the stocks. The law requires management practices to be based on science. For each …shery, a scienti…c panel determines the “acceptable biological catch”, and the managers then set an “annual catch limit” (ACL), not to exceed the acceptable biological catch. The Fishery Management Councils can enforce the ACL by: restricting entry to speci…c boats or operators (limited access); restricting …shing to certain times of the year or certain locations; regulating …shing gear; and requiring on-board observers to insure that boats obey regulations. A 2009 National Marine Fisheries report states that of the 192 stocks being monitored, the percent with excessive harvest fell from 38% to 20% over the decade, and the percent with over-…shed stocks fell from 48% to 22%. Most of the important …sheries are concentrated in countries’ exclusive economic zones and are regulated in some fashion; these are “limited access” …sheries. Despite this regulation, scienti…c di¢ culties and human frailty often leads to over-…shed stocks. For most …sheries, identifying the actual stock is a di¢ cult measurement problem. Random stock changes, due to unforeseen changes in ocean conditions and changes in stocks of predators and prey (that impact the regulated …shery) make it di¢ cult to determine safe stock levels, even if the stocks can be measured; imprecise measures compound the scienti…c problem. Managers may decide to ignore scienti…c evidence if they distrust it or are swayed by lobbying from …shers or processors. “Regulatory capture”, a widespread phenomena, occurs when regulators are “captured” 13.3. REGULATION OF FISHERIES 241 by the groups that they are charged with regulating: human frailty. Box 13.1 The U.S. Northwest Atlantic scallop …shery: a success story. Scallops are caught by dragging dredges along the seabed, trapping scallops of legal size. In 1994 the government closed 3 large banks and scallopers responded by concentrating and subsequently exhausting other areas of the …shery. Fisherman hired University of Massachusetts biologists to conduct a stock survey, …nding that the population in the closed areas had rebounded. The industry began to commit a fraction of its pro…ts, about $12 - $15 million per year, to conduct surveys. Using this data, the National Marine Fishery Services (NMFS) closes over…shed seabeds long enough to allow the population to recover, about 3 - 5 years. This system resembles …eld rotation in agriculture. The success of the program relied on good data, cooperation between …shers and NMFS, leading to trust (because …shers supply the data), and a common interest among …shers to preserve the stock. Even without the scienti…c and political impediments, …shery regulation is inherently di¢ cult. The problem arises from the mismatch between “targets”(or “margins”) and “instruments”(or policies) (Chapter 10). A target (margin) is anything that a regulator would, in an ideal world, like to control. The optimal harvest of a stock involves many considerations, in addition to the annual catch limit. The ecology depends on the annual catch limit, but the economic pro…ts depend on how that limit is harvested, including speci…cs about gear, e.g. types of nets, engine size, and other boat equipment. In principle, the Regional Fishery Management Councils have the authority to regulate most of these features, but regulation of every important business decision is not practical. Most regulation involves fairly simple policies. For example, the Council can enforce the annual catch limit by restricting the length of the season and limiting the number of boats; but the Council is unlikely to be able to control all of the decisions that go in to …shing. The problem is that when the regulator restricts one margin (e.g. by limiting the season length), …shers respond on another margin, (e.g. by changing the gear they use). Regulators cannot control all margins, so regulation is second-best. Fishers respond to regulation, acting in their individual selfinterest. However, they in‡ict externalities on others, leading to a socially ine¢ cient outcome. This ine¢ ciency manifests as over-capitalization: too many boats, or too much gear, chasing too few …sh. Over-capitalization 242 CHAPTER 13. PROPERTY RIGHTS AND REGULATION reduces industry pro…ts, making a given annual catch limit more expensive to harvest. Estimates of over-capacity vary widely, ranging from 30% to over 200%, but there is a consensus that it is severe. 13.3.1 Over-capitalization We illustrate the over-capitalization and the resulting loss in industry profits using a simple model with four targets: annual allowable catch, A; the number of boats, N ; the number of days of the season, D, and the amount of “e¤ort”per boat per day, E. E¤ort is an amalgam of all of the decisions the …sher makes (boat size, crew, gear characteristics). Each unit of e¤ort costs w per day, and E units of e¤ort enable a boat to catch E 0:5 …sh per day. In the …rst best setting, the regulator chooses the value of all four variables. To examine the forces at work in the real world, where regulators are unable to control every margin, we consider a second best setting where the regulator chooses the annual catch and the length of the season, A and D. Fishers choose e¤ort, E, to maximize their pro…ts. We …rst consider the case where N is exogenous and …xed; perhaps it is historically determined. We then allow N to be endogenous. Exogenous N Individual …shers, each with a boat, choose e¤ort in order to maximize pro…t (revenue minus cost). If the price of a unit of …sh is p, the …sher chooses E to maximize pro…ts per day: max pE 0:5 E wE ) p d (pE 0:5 wE) set = 0 ) E = 0:5 dE w 2 : (13.1) Given that the N …shers choose this level of e¤ort, the manager who wants to set annual catch equal to A must choose the number of days of the season, D, so that the number of …shers (N ) times the catch per day per …sher (E 0:5 ) times the number of days equals A: NE 0:5 D=N p 0:5 w 2 0:5 set D =A)D=2 Aw : Np The maximum feasible season length (e.g., due to weather conditions) is , the fraction of the potential season that …shing is S. We denote = D S 13.3. REGULATION OF FISHERIES allowed, and we assume that D S 243 < 1 i.e., = 2Aw < 1: N Sp (13.2) This inequality implies that, given …shers’ individually optimal choice of e¤ort per day, the annual allowance, A, constrains the length of the season. If, instead, inequality 13.2 is reversed ( 1), then …shers can be allowed to …sh during the maximum feasible number of days (S), without exceeding the annual ceiling. In that case, …shers want to catch less than the limit, and regulation is not needed. In this second-best setting, where the regulator chooses the length of the season and …shers choose e¤ort, total industry pro…t equals pro…tsecond best = DN (pE 0:5 Aw N 2N p p 0:5 wp 2 0:5 wE) = w 0:5 wp 2 = Ap 2 In the …rst best setting, the regulator chooses both e¤ort and the number of days in order to reach the ACL, A. It is straightforward to show that costs are minimized by setting D = S, the maximum feasible season, and 2 E = NAS (Problem #2). With these values, total pro…t in the industry is pro…t…rst best = DN (pE 0:5 SN p A NS w A 2 NS wE) = = pA A2 w : NS The percent increase pro…t in moving from the second best to the …rst best regulation is 1 Ap 1 2 pro…t…rst best pro…tsecond best 100 = Ap pro…tsecond best 2 2Aw N Sp 100 = (1 ) 100 > 0; where the last equality follows from the de…nition of , and the inequality follows from inequality 13.2. Fishers act in their self-interest in choosing e¤ort, but they in‡ict a negative externality on the industry: as e¤ort increases, catch per day also increases, requiring that the regulator shorten the season in order to maintain the annual catch limit. This self-interested behavior leads to 12 times the 244 CHAPTER 13. PROPERTY RIGHTS AND REGULATION …rst best level of e¤ort. This over-capitalization decreases industry pro…ts by the percent decrease in the length of the season. For example, if second best regulation leads to a season only 20% as long as the …rst best level, then industry pro…ts are only 20% of the …rst best level. This model illustrates an empirically important phenomenon: the race to catch …sh (and resulting over-capitalization) has lead to shorter seasons and lower industry pro…t in many …sheries. In the early 20th century, the North Paci…c halibut …shery operated throughout the year, leading to excessive harvests. In 1930 the U.S. and Canada agreed to manage the …shery using an annual quota. The management success increased pro…ts, leading to overcapitalization of the …shery. Managers responded by reducing the season length to two months in the 1950s and to less than a week in the 1970s. Endogenous N Above we took the total number of boats, N , as …xed, but in the absence of regulation, N is endogenous; it is another “target”, or “margin”. Higher pro…ts encourage entry, changing the (endogenous) value of N unless regulation restricts entry. For example, suppose that initially the …shery is totally unregulated, leading to depleted stocks, making it expensive to catch …sh. The low stocks and high costs cause pro…ts in the sector to be low, discouraging entry or encouraging …shers in the sector to leave. Now suppose that a restriction on annual catch succeeds in rebuilding the stock, making it cheaper to catch …sh, and thus increasing pro…ts. In the absence of entry restrictions, more boats may enter, creating another type of over-capitalization. Suppose that each boat costs $F /year to own; F is the opportunity cost of the money tied up in owning a boat for a year. Under second best regulation, where the length of the season adjusts in order to maintain the . With N boats, the pro…t catch limit, we saw above that industry pro…t is Ap 2 Ap per boat per year is 2N . Under free entry, boats would enter the industry until the annual opportunity cost of being in the sector equals the pro…t of Ap Ap 4 …shing there, which requires 2N = F , or N = 2F . For smaller values of N additional boats have an incentive to enter the …shery (to obtain positive net pro…ts), and for larger values of N existing boats have an incentive to leave the …shery (to avoid losses). Consider the case where the number of boats is in a second best equilib4 This calculation ignores the fact that the number of boats must be an integer. 13.3. REGULATION OF FISHERIES 245 Ap rium (N = 2F ) and technological advances suddenly enable the regulator to control e¤ort, determining the gear each boat uses. We showed above that this change, at the initial level of N , increases industry pro…t by (1 ) 100%, (1 )2F 100 (1 )100 %= % (using the expresincreasing the pro…t per boat by N Ap sion for the equilibrium level of N ). This increase in pro…t encourages additional boats to enter. Ap The second best equilibrium number of boats (N = 2F ) is already excessive from the standpoint of society, but at least the regulator does not have to discourage more boats from entering: they have no desire to do so. However, successfully reducing one type of over-capitalization by reducing e¤ort per boat creates an incentive for new boats to enter, exacerbating the other source of overcapitalization. Getting one margin right (reducing e¤ort per boat) causes another margin (the number of boats) to move further from the social optimum. This kind of problem is endemic to a second best setting, i.e. to the real world: …xing one problem can make another problem worse. In theory, the regulator can determine the optimal number of boats and the optimal e¤ort per boat, and then either decree that …shers accept these levels, or impose taxes (e.g. a tax per unit of e¤ort and an entry tax) that “induce”these levels. That level of regulation is seldom practical. Box 13.2 The relation between N and e¤ort. In the model here, …shers’equilibrium choice of e¤ort does not depend on the number of boats (equation 13.1). That independence simpli…es the calculations, but it is a consequence of functional assumptions. More generally, equilibrium e¤ort depends on the number of boats. Regulating one aspect of the industry a¤ects other …shing decisions. Economic agents who are constrained in one dimension (e.g. not being able to increase the number of boats) respond by making changes in other dimensions (e.g. increasing the speed of boats). Over-capacity can show up in many ways, e.g. as too many boats, too much gear, or boats that are too big or too fast. The economy is like a water bed: applying pressure in one location creates movement elsewhere. 13.3.2 Property rights and regulation Fishing, like most resource extraction problems, creates an externality. Here, the outcome when individuals pursue their self interest is not e¢ cient. The externality leads to over-…shing and lower stocks. Because individual …shers 246 CHAPTER 13. PROPERTY RIGHTS AND REGULATION do not own the stocks, they have little incentive to manage them for future users. Even if the over-…shing problem can be solved by setting and enforcing an annual catch limit, history shows that other ine¢ ciencies remain, often leading to over-capitalization and low pro…ts. Creating property rights is the obvious alternative to standard regulation (such as limiting the …shing season, restricting the number of boats, and regulating …shing gear). Problems in …sheries arise largely from the lack of property rights, so creating these rights is the most direct remedy; recall the Principle of Targeting from Chapter 10. Individual Quotas (IQs), or Individually Transferable Quotas (ITQs) are the most signi…cant form of property rights in …sheries. These measures set an annual Total Allowable Catch (TAC) for a species and give individuals shares in that quota. An individual with share s is entitled to harvest s times that year’s TAC of that species. Under ITQs, owners can sell or lease (“transfer”) their shares. Property rights-based regulation has been shown to decrease costs, increase revenue, and protect …sh stocks. However, less than 2% of the world’s …sheries currently use property rights based regulation. Reducing industry costs For a given TAC (or ACL), property rights cause …shers to internalize the externalities that lead to overcapitalization. Property rights reduce costs, increasing pro…ts. Using the model above, a …sher with the share s of a TAC A for a …shery with price p obtains the …xed revenue sAp. With …xed revenue, the …sher maximizes pro…ts by choosing e¤ort and days …shed to minimize the cost of catching sA. This …sher’s cost minimization problem is the same as that of the regulator who chooses both e¤ort and season length (Problem #2). Thus, the …sher with property rights chooses the socially optimal amount of e¤ort and days …shed. If the quotas are transferable (ITQs instead of IQs), there are two additional sources of cost savings. First, some of the …shers may be more e¢ cient. For example, the average …sher may catch E 0:5 …sh per day, but half may catch 10% more and half 10% less with the same level of e¤ort. Regulators are unlikely to know …shers’relative e¢ ciency, or be able to act on that information even if they have it. Fishers probably have a better idea of their relative e¢ ciency. Shares in the quota are worth more to the e¢ cient …shers than to the ine¢ cient …shers, so there are opportunities for the former to buy the latter’s’licenses. If that occurs, aggregate costs in the …shery falls by 10% in this example. 13.3. REGULATION OF FISHERIES 247 Second, even if all …shers are equally productive, there may be too many boats in the sector: industry pro…ts would be higher if some boats could be persuaded to leave, as in the example in Chapter 13.2. If transactions costs are su¢ ciently low, and …shers manage to solve the Coasian bargain, some boats sell their quotas and leave the sector. Pro…ts under the smaller ‡eet are higher. The Mid-Atlantic surf clam …shery switched from restricted entry regulation to ITQs in 1990. Prior to the switch, there were 128 vessels in the …shery. Estimates at the time claimed that the optimal number of boats for the industry was 21 –25, and that rationalization of e¤ort could reduce costs by 45%. By 1994, the ‡eet size had fallen to 50 vessels and costs had fallen by 30%. The costs savings due to rationalization of ‡eet size and gear choice likely occur over a period of time; it takes time to change. Increasing revenue For a …xed TAC, IQs and ITQs can increase revenue, in addition to reducing harvest costs. We showed above that partial regulation leads to too much gear and/or too many boats chasing a given number of …sh, requiring regulators to reduce the …shing season, sometimes to a period of a week or less. Over-capitalization increases …shing costs, but it also makes the annual harvest available during a short period of time, instead of being spread out during the season. If the market for fresh …sh is inelastic, a sudden increase in harvest leads to a much lower equilibrium price. There may also be capacity constraints in transporting fresh …sh to market. Fish processors may be able to wield market power if …shers have to unload large catches during short periods of time. For all of these reasons, the ex vessel price that …shers receive may be lower when the annual catch is landed during a short interval. The lowerpriced …sh may then enter the frozen …sh market, where prices are typically lower than for fresh …sh. Moving from regulation to IQs or ITQs eliminates or at least reduces the race to catch …sh, causing harvest to be spread out over the season, and increasing the average price of landings. Before the British Columbia halibut …shery switched to ITQs in 1993, the …shing season lasted about …ve days, and most of the catch went to the frozen …sh market. With the more spread-out and thus steadier supply of …sh caused by the move to ITQs, wholesalers found it pro…table to develop marketing networks for transporting fresh …sh. Prior to the ITQs, the price of fresh …sh fell rapidly if more than 100,000 pounds a week became available, 248 CHAPTER 13. PROPERTY RIGHTS AND REGULATION but with the development of the new marketing networks, the market could absorb 800,000 pounds before prices dropped. A 2003 study estimates the potential gains from introducing ITQs in the Gulf of Mexico reef …sh …shery, accounting for both cost reductions and revenue increases. ITQs had the potential to increase revenue by almost 50% and to reduce costs by 75%. The study also estimates that under ITQs the equilibrium ‡eet size contains 29 – 70 vessels, compared to the actual level of 387 vessels. Protecting …sh stocks Standard regulation and IQs/ITQs both rely on an annual limit (TAC) but they use di¤erent ways of enforcing that limit. The mismatch between targets and instruments under standard regulation, and the resulting ine¢ ciencies lead to high costs, low revenue, and …nancial di¢ culties for …shers. Fishers have an incentive to pressure regulators to increase the annual catch as a short-term …nancial …x. If this pressure overrides the scienti…c advice, it imperils …sh stocks. The creation of property rights potentially eases these stresses. When …shers have property rights to the catch, they have incentives to protect the stock. Property rightsbased regulation changes the political dynamics and likely helps to protect …sh stocks. The di¢ culty of measuring stocks makes it hard to know if a stock is over…shed. A common de…nition calls a …shery “collapsed” in a particular year if the harvest in that year is less than 10% of the maximum previous harvest. By this de…nition, 27% of the …sheries were collapsed in 2003. Fisheries with IQ/ITQs were less likely to be collapsed, but the “selection problem” makes it di¢ cult to tell whether this negative correlation between ITQ status and …shery collapse implies that the property rights-based mechanism really protects species’health. Unobserved characteristics of a …shery that decrease its likelihood of collapse may also increase its likelihood of being “selected into” property rights-based management. This selection problem creates a negative correlation between ITQ status and collapse, without implying a causal relation. Statistical methods based on “matching” can alleviate this measurement problem. The idea is that we would like to compare collapse status between pairs of …sheries that are alike, except for their ITQ status. A 2008 study based on 50 years of data and over 11,000 …sheries, which takes into account the selection problem, …nds evidence of a causal relation, and estimates that ITQs reduce the probability of collapse in a year by about 13.4. SUBSIDIES TO FISHERIES 249 half. It also estimates that had there been a general movement to ITQs in 1970, the percent of …sheries collapsed in 2003 would have been about 9% instead of the observed 27%. Remaining ine¢ ciencies The property rights created by IQs and ITQs can improve the …nancial and ecological health of a …shery, but they leave many problems unsolved. They create particular property rights to a particular species. They may leave important externalities even for that species. For example, increases in production costs during the season due to the intra-seasonal decrease in stock can still create a race to catch …sh, leading to overcapitalization. The IQs and ITQs do not protect other species. They provide no incentive to reduce by-catch, the unintentional harvest of …sh not being targeted. Other regulations, or the creation of additional property rights can reduce by-catch, but these may be costly to implement and may have unintended consequences. A fairly new mechanism, Territorial Use Rights Fisheries (TURFs) attempt to alleviate the cross-species problem by giving groups of …shers (e.g. coops) exclusive rights to an area, instead of to a species. TURFs are less e¤ective if important species move in and out of the territorial area. 13.4 Subsidies to …sheries Policy failure harms natural resources by permitting and sometimes encouraging over-harvest, damaging ecosystems. This loss in natural capital can have serious long run social costs. The short run economic costs of these policies appear as over-capitalized and …nancially stressed …sheries, and stagnant or diminishing supplies of high value catch. The policy targets are to reduce catch in order to allow …sheries to recover, and to encourage rationalization and consolidation of the industry to increase pro…ts. Reducing catch and encouraging …shers to leave the industry are both politically fraught prospects. Subsidizing the industry is politically easier, but ultimately counterproductive. Subsidies disguise the economic costs, enabling …shers to remain in an unpro…table activity, worsening both the problem of over-harvest and over-capitalization. A variety of domestic and international agencies have documented the link between subsidies and over-…shing and over-capitalization. 250 CHAPTER 13. PROPERTY RIGHTS AND REGULATION A 2013 European Parliament study estimates annual global subsidies to the …shing sector of $35 billion (2009 dollars). Over half of those subsidies generate increased capacity; 22% come in the form of fuel subsidies, 20% subsidize …shery management, and 10% subsidize ports and harbors (Table 13.1). Developed countries are responsible for most of the subsidies; 43% originate in Asia, chie‡y Japan and China. Between 1996 –2004, the U.S. …shing industry received over $6.4 billion in subsidies, or $713 million per year. type of subsidy source of subsidy fuel: 22 developed countries: 65 management: 20 Asia: 43 Japan: 20 China: 20 ports and harbors:10 Europe: 25 capacity increasing: 57 North America: 16 Table 13.1 Types and geographical sources of …shing subsidies, as a percent of total. (Sumaila et al. 2013) Subsidies transfer income from one group to another, here from tax payers to …shers. Thus, the dollar value of the subsidy does not provide a measure of the economic cost, or lost welfare. A 2009 study commissioned by the World Bank conservatively estimates the annual global economic cost of …shery subsidies at $50 billion. This estimate includes the costs due to reduced stock size (which reduces harvest and increases the harvest cost) and of overcapitalization. In some cases, the value of harvest is less than the true cost of harvest; in these cases, the industry operates at a loss, and the loss is disguised by government subsidies.5 According to this study, half the current number of vessels could achieve current catch. Subsidies account for approximately 20% of …shing revenue. 5 This situation is reminiscent of many Russian and east European industries after the collapse of the Soviet Union. These industries were not economically viable, and had been kept alive by government subsidies; closing them down increased gross national product. 13.5. SUMMARY 251 Box 13.3 Subsidies in other sectors. Fisheries are not alone in receiving politically motivated but economically unproductive subsidies; Chapter 12.1 discusses fossil fuel subsidies. Agriculture in many developed countries also receives large subsidies, often justi…ed as helping struggling farmers. However, endogenous changes induced by the subsidies often undo whatever short term …nancial help the subsidies provide. Agricultural subsidies are “capitalized”in the price of land: the expectation that the subsidies will continue into the future make people willing to pay more for land, raising its equilibrium price. Current land owners who sell their land, not entering farmers who must buy the land, capture these increased rents. Subsidies, and in particular the belief that they will continue into the future, increase young farmers’ debt (via the increase in land prices), making them more vulnerable to future …nancial di¢ culties and more dependent on the subsidies. 13.5 Summary Private property, common property, and open access are the three leading modes of property rights. Property rights to most resources lie somewhere on the continuum that includes these three modes. De facto property rights sometimes di¤er from de jure rights. Common property can lead to overuse of the resource, a result known as the tragedy of the commons. Many societies developed mechanisms that e¢ ciently manage common property resources; integration into the global market sometimes erodes these mechanisms. If transactions costs are small and property rights well de…ned, agents can (plausibly) reach an e¢ cient outcome through bargaining. The Coase theorem states that in this case, the e¢ ciency of the outcome does not depend on the distribution of bargaining power, or more generally, on the assignment of property rights. This result implies that explicit regulation is less important or even unnecessary, provided that transactions costs are low and property rights are secure. Most economically important …sheries fall within nations’Exclusive Economic Zone, and are regulated. The impracticality of regulating every facet of …shing leaves regulators in a second best setting. Many …sheries set annual quotas, enforced using a variety of policies, notably early season closures. The resulting race amongst …shers to catch …sh leads to over-capitalization, 252 CHAPTER 13. PROPERTY RIGHTS AND REGULATION which results in high costs and, because much of the harvest is landed during a short period of time, low revenue. Property rights-based regulation, primarily ITQs, can lead to consolidation and rationalization of …sheries, lowering costs, increasing revenue, and via a political dynamic, increasing the prospect for …shery health (adequate stocks). However, only a small percent of …sheries operate under ITQs. Subsidies, especially from developed nations, provide short run bene…ts to …sheries, but exacerbate the problems that lead to low pro…ts and over-…shing. 13.6 Terms, study questions and exercises Terms and concepts Open access, common property, de jure, de facto, congestion, tragedy of the commons, Doctrine of Regulatory Taking, transactions costs, Coase Theorem, fair lottery, outside option, Law of the Sea, exclusive economic zone, Manguson-Stevens Fishery Act, by-catch, Regional Fishery Management Councils, Fishery Management Plans, acceptable biological catch, annual catch limit, regulatory capture, overcapitalization, Individual (Transferable) Quotas or I(T)Qs, Territorial Use Rights Fisheries (TURFs). Study questions 1. Recently there have been a spate of disputes on airlines concerning whether a person is entitled to recline their seat. These disputes are essentially about who has the property rights to the several inches of space between a seat and the one in front of it. Some airlines have (either implicit or explicit) rules that assign property rights: a person is entitled to recline her seat, except during meals (and of course during landing and takeo¤). Recently these rules seem to have become vaguer, or less well understood. Discuss the increasing occurrence of these disputes among passengers, in light of the Coase Theorem. Exercises 1. This exercise takes the reader through one of the classic examples of the Coase Theorem. A factory that emits e units of pollution obtains the total bene…t from emissions, 10e 12 e2 . A (very old fashioned) 13.6. TERMS, STUDY QUESTIONS AND EXERCISES 253 downstream laundry dries clothes outside. The pollution makes it more expensive for the laundry to return clean clothes to its customers, and therefore increases the laundry’s costs by 2e2 . (a) Find the socially optimal level of pollution, i.e. the level that maximizes bene…ts minus costs. (b) Find the emissions tax that supports this level of pollution as a competitive equilibrium. (c) Assume that the factory has the right to pollute as much as it wants. The laundry and the factory are able to costlessly bargain to reduce pollution. Who pays and who gets paid in the bargaining outcome? (d) Justify the Coasian conclusion, namely that the outcome of an e¢ cient bargain leads to the socially optimal level of pollution. One can establish this claim using the following proof by contradiction: Suppose, contrary to the claim, that they reach a bargain that entails an amount of pollution di¤erent than the socially optimal level. (To avoid repetition, consider only the case where this amount is greater than the socially optimal level.) Show that at such a level, the laundry’s willingness to pay for a marginal reduction in pollution is strictly more than the …rm would have to receive in order for it to be willing to reduce pollution by a marginal amount. Explain why this conclusion implies that if the agreement by the factory and the laundry leads to more pollution than is socially optimal, then the factory and the laundry have left money on the table. They should resume bargaining and capture some of this waste. 2. This exercise asks the reader to obtain the formula for e¤ort under full regulation, given in Chapter 13.3.1. Under full regulation (where the regulator is able to choose both D and E) the total revenue is …xed at pA, so the regulator’s objective is to minimize costs, subject to the constraints that the limit is caught (N E 0:5 D = A) and that D not exceed the maximum number of days, S, during which (e.g. due to weather conditions) it is feasible to …sh (D S): minE;D (wED) subject to N E 0:5 D = A and D S Proceed as follows: (i) Use the constraint involving A to solve for E. (ii) Substitute this value of E into the minimand (the thing being minimized, here, costs). (iii) Note that the resulting minimand is decreasing in D. Conclude that the value of D that minimizes costs is therefore the maximum feasible value, S. (iv) Using D = S from part 254 CHAPTER 13. PROPERTY RIGHTS AND REGULATION (iii) in the expression you obtained from part (i) to write the optimal level of e¤ort (per boat per day) as a function of the model parameters 3. Using the model in Chapter 13.3.1, and the formulae given there, show that under partial regulation …shers choose 12 times as much e¤ort per day as the regulator chooses under full regulation. 4. As in Chapter 13.3.1, suppose that cost per unit of e¤ort per boat per day is w, the price per unit of …sh is p, the catch per boat per day is E 0:5 , the cost per boat per year is F , and the annual allowable catch is A. The regulator can choose the number of days of the season, D, and can also choose the number of boats, N , via a licensing requirement. Compare the regulator’s optimal choice of N and D in the two cases where (a) …shers choose their individually rational level of e¤ort, and (b) where the regulator can choose E. For part (a) proceed as follows: (i) Recall the fact that …shers choose a particular level of E (a function), and that given that value of E and N , the regulator chooses a particular level of D in order to satisfy the catch constraint. (ii) Substitute these values of D and E in the regulator’s cost minimization problem and minimize with respect to N . For part (b) proceed as follows: (i) Write the cost minimization problem when the regulator chooses N; E; D. Don’t forget the …xed cost. (ii) Use your answer from question 2 to write the optimal level of E, as a function of N and D. (iii) Substitute this expression for E into the minimand. For any level of N note that the minimand is decreasing in D. What does this imply about the optimal level of D? (iv) Use your answer to the previous part to write the minimand as only a function of N . Find the cost minimizing value of N . 5. The answer to question 4b tells you the optimal number of boats under full regulation. The text tells you equilibrium number of boats under full regulation. Assume that …shers are able to solve the Coasian bargain. (a) Using this information, what is the ratio of the ‡eet size under ITQs to the ‡eet size under free entry and partial regulation to ITQs? (b) Using this ratio, can you determine whether the number of boats falls or rises, in moving from the open access partial regulation equilibrium to the …rst best? HINT: You need to use inequality 13.2. (c) What e¤ect do the parameters F and S have on this ratio? Provide an economic explanation for this e¤ect. (d) What is the role, in your 13.6. TERMS, STUDY QUESTIONS AND EXERCISES 255 answer to part a of the assumption that …shers are able to solve the Coasian bargain? (How would your answer have changed if you had not made that assumption?) Sources Dietz, Ostrom and Stern (2003) and Ostrom (1990 and 2007) discuss conditions under which societies successfully manage common property without formal regulation. Hardin (1968) introduced the term “tragedy of the commons”. Gordon (1954) provided the …rst well known analysis of …sheries as common property resources. Ka¢ ne (2009) documents California surfers’ e¤orts to exercise de facto property rights on some beaches. The Millennium Ecosystem Assessment (United Nations, 2005), Sumaila et al. (2011) and Dyck and Sumaila (2010) provide overviews of the state of …sheries. Johnson and Libcap (1982) describe the replacement of common property with open access in the Alaska salmon …shery. Fenske (2012) documents the case of property rights for rubber trees among the Nigerian Igbo. The 2009 National Marine Fisheries Service report to Congress summarizes the change in regulated U.S. …sheries. Wittenberg (2014) provides the information for Box 13.1. Smith (2012) surveys the problems of regulating …sheries when there more “targets”(aka “margins”) than policy variables. Homans and Wilen (1997) show how individually rational e¤ort decisions, and the resulting overcapitalization, lead to reductions in the length of a …shing season. Homans and Wilen (2005) document the e¤ect of ITQs on revenue, and provide the example of the British Columbia halibut …shery. Weniger and Waters (2003) estimate potential revenue gains, cost reductions, and ‡eet consolidation due to using ITQs in the Gulf of Mexico reef …sh …shery. Weninger (1999) provides the information in Chapter 13.3.2 on the MidAtlantic surf clam. Abbott and Wilen (2009 and 2011) examine …shers’response to quotas on bycatch. 256 CHAPTER 13. PROPERTY RIGHTS AND REGULATION Costello, Gaines and Lynham (2008) estimate the e¤ect of ITQs on …shery collapse, reported in Chapter 13.3.2. Deacon, Parker, and Costello (2013) study a situation where …shers had the option of obtaining property rights by joining a coop. The 2012 Symposium “Rights-based Fisheries Management”, edited by Costello and with papers by Aranson, Deacon, and Uchida and Wilen, reviews the literature on rights-based management. Sharp and Sumaila (2009) quantify U.S. …shery subsidies. Sumaila et al. (2013) quantify global …shery subsidies. Aronson, Kelleher and Willman (2009) estimate the economic cost of global …shery subsidies. Chapter 14 Renewable resources: tools Objectives Gain familiarity with the building blocks used to construct models of renewable resources. Skills Understand and be able to work with a growth function. Understand the meaning of a “harvest rule”and understand how harvest rules change the growth equation. Know the meaning of a steady state, and understand the relation between a growth equation and a steady state. Have an intuitive understanding of the relation between a discrete time and continuous time model. Understand the meaning of stability, and be able to test for it in a continuous time model. Understand the meaning of “maximum sustainable yield”and be able to identify it for simple growth functions. A few basic tools make it possible analyze a wide variety of renewable resource models, including stock pollutants, forestry, and …sheries. In subsequent chapters we use these tools to study the open access …shery and the sole owner …shery, and also to study regulation in both of these settings. 257 258 CHAPTER 14. RENEWABLE RESOURCES: TOOLS Renewable resource models involve one or more “stock variables” that (potentially) change over time. In the nonrenewable resource setting, the stock variable equals the amount of the resource remaining in the mine; there, any extraction decreases the stock. In the renewable resource setting, the extraction of the stock might be o¤set by intrinsic growth. In this situation, the stock might either decrease or increase over time. In water economics, we might measure the stock using the level of groundwater or the amount of water in a reservoir. Consuming the water reduces the stock, but a natural recharge (e.g. rain) can increase it. In forestry economics, the stock might be measured using the biomass of forestry, the number of tons of wood. Cutting down trees reduces the stock, but the forest’s natural growth increases it. In climate economics, the stock might be measured using the parts per million (ppm) of atmospheric CO2 . Carbon emissions increase the stock, but some of the stock is absorbed into other carbon reservoirs, e.g. oceans. In all of these case, the stock might increase or decrease over time, depending on the relation between the natural growth/recharge/decay and the consumption decisions. 14.1 Growth dynamics Objectives and skills Understand the meaning of biomass and the growth function. Understand the meaning of the two parameters in the logistic growth function. Be able to graph this function. For the sake of speci…city, we consider …shery economics, where we measure the stock of …sh using biomass, e.g. the number of tons of …sh. Biomass does not capture the population age and size distribution: twenty half-pound …sh and ten one-pound …sh contribute equally to this measure. For some purposes, the age and size distributions are important. Those features are hard to measure and they increase model complexity. For the purpose of understanding the basics renewable resource model, and the …shery model in particular, biomass is a useful measure of the stock. We denote the stock of …sh in period t as xt , so the change in the stock is xt+1 xt . The growth function, F (x), describes the evolution of the …sh 14.1. GROWTH DYNAMICS 259 stock in the absence of harvest. Some …sh die and new …sh are born, so the stock might increase or decrease over time. Growth (absent harvest) depends on the stock: xt+1 xt = F (xt ) : Growth also depends on the possibly random stocks of predators and prey and changes in pollution concentrations and ocean temperature. Even holding those features …xed, there may be intrinsic randomness of the growth of x. These types of considerations lead to a more descriptive but more complicated model, and we ignore them. If a period equals one year, then F (x) equals the annual growth, and F (x) equals the annual growth rate. The percent growth rate is F (x) 100. x x The most common functional form for the growth function is the Shae¤er, or “logistic”model: xt F (xt ) = xt 1 . (14.1) K This model uses two parameters, > 0, and K > 0. The parameter K is the “carrying capacity”; it measures the level of stock that can be sustained, absent harvest. Growth is zero if xt = K or if xt = 0; the stock grows if 0 < xt < K and it falls if xt > K. Congestion decreases the carrying capacity, K. As the stock increases, the …sh compete for prey, and/or they become more vulnerable to predators. This congestion limits the potential growth of the stock. Smaller values of K correspond to greater congestion, and thus lower potential stock sizes. The growth rate of the stock with the logistic growth function is xt 1 F (xt ) xt+1 xt = = xt xt xt xt K = 1 xt : K (14.2) The parameter is the “intrinsic growth rate”. In the absence of congestion (xt = 0 or K = 1), the growth rate equals . A larger value of K implies a higher growth rate (less congestion) for given x. For given and K, the growth rate falls with x, so the growth rate (not growth) reaches the maximum value, , at x = 0. The value = 0:07, for example, means that in the absence of congestion, the stock grows at 7% per year. For x close to 0, congestion is relatively unimportant, and the growth rate is close to 7%. However, as the stock gets larger, congestion becomes more important, until growth ceases as x approaches the carrying capacity, K. Figure ?? shows graphs of the logistic growth function for three di¤erent growth rates, and K = 50. For positive stocks, a larger implies larger growth. 260 CHAPTER 14. RENEWABLE RESOURCES: TOOLS F 0.8 0.6 gamma = 0.07 0.4 gamma = 0.03 0.2 gamnma = 0.01 0.0 10 20 30 40 50 60 x -0.2 -0.4 -0.6 -0.8 Figure 14.1: The logistic growth function for three values of : 14.2 Harvest and steady states Objectives and skills Understand the meaning of a “harvest rule”and be able to graph simple harvest rules. Understand the meaning of “steady state”. Using the logistic growth function and a particular harvest rule, identify the steady states both graphically and algebraically. The introduction of harvest, y > 0, changes the dynamics. A “harvest rule” gives the harvest level as a function of the stock. Two examples illustrate harvest rules: y (x) = min (x; Y ), where Y is a constant, and y (x) = x, with > 0 a constant. For the …rst example, harvest is constant at Y if this level is feasible, i.e. if x Y . If the stock is less than Y , all of it is harvested. For the second example, harvest is a constant fraction of the stock. For example, for = 0:01, annual harvest equals one percent of the …sh stock. It is not possible to take more than the entire stock, so 1. Figure 14.2 shows the growth functions with the zero, constant, and the proportional harvest. With the two non-zero harvest rules, the change in the stock is constant harvest: xt+1 xt = x t 1 harvest proportional to stock: xt+1 xt K min (xt ; Y ) xt = x t 1 xt K xt : (14.3) 14.3. STABILITY 261 growth zero harvest constant harvest 0.2 0.0 10 20 30 40 50 60 x -0.2 -0.4 proportional harvest -0.6 -0.8 Figure 14.2: Growth with zero harvest (heavy solid curve), with harvest proportional to the stock (dashed), and with the stock equal to Y for x Y . Parameter values: K = 50, = 0:03, Y = 0:1 and = 0:01 A steady state is any level of the stock at which growth minus harvest equals 0. A stock beginning at a steady state remains there. We have three examples of harvest rules: zero harvest, and the two rules shown in equation 14.3. We obtain the steady states in these three cases by setting the growth minus harvest equal to 0 and solving for x: y = 0: x K x 1 =0 ) x1 ; 2 f0; 50g y = min (x; 0:1) : x 1 x K min (x; 0:1) = 0 ) x1 2 f0; 3:6; 46:4g y = 0:01x: x 1 x K (14.4) 0:01x = 0 ) x1 2 f0; 33g : The subscript 1 denotes that the stock is a steady state level. Where this meaning is clear from the context, we drop the subscript. These examples use the parameter values K = 50, = 0:03, Y = 0:1, and = 0:01. 14.3 Stability Objectives and skills Be able to explain what it means to say that a steady state is stable or unstable. 262 CHAPTER 14. RENEWABLE RESOURCES: TOOLS Given a …gure showing either (i) the growth function and the harvest rule, or (ii) the growth function minus the harvest rule: be able to identify the steady states and to determine (for the continuous time problem) whether a steady state is stable or unstable. Know that the conditions for stability are slightly more complicated in the discrete time setting, and that the continuous time analog provides a “reasonable approximation”to the discrete time problem only if the length of a period in the latter is small. A steady state is said to be “stable” if the stock trajectory approaches the steady state when the stock begins su¢ ciently close to the steady state. (What happens in Vegas stays in Vegas.) A steady state is “unstable” if the stock trajectory moves away from the steady state when the stock begins close to the steady state. (What happens in Washington DC gets broadcast to the world.) The stability or lack of stability of a steady state provides important information about the dynamics of the …sh stock, and is therefore important in policy questions. For example, suppose that harvest is a constant fraction of the stock, y = x. For the parameter values used to generate the …nal line of equation 14.4, we see that there are two steady states, x = 0 and x = 33:33. It matters whether the …sh stock will die out, i.e. approach x = 0, or approach x = 33:33, which is 66% of the carrying capacity, K. 14.3.1 Discrete time versus continuous time models We have emphasized discrete time models. The discrete time setting makes it possible to derive the necessary condition for optimality (the Euler equation) using only elementary calculus. The intuition is also more straightforward in the discrete time setting. The discrete time setting also makes it easier to describe the dynamics in the renewable resource setting (without optimization), as above. There is a cost to convenience. The cost is that the analysis, as distinct from the description, of the discrete time dynamic system is more complicated than for the continuous time system. The problem arises because in the discrete time setting there is a nonnegligible change in variables (e.g. the stock of …sh) from one period to the next, outside of a steady state. Here, the stock might jump from one interval to another where the behavior is quite di¤erent. This possibility can lead to 14.3. STABILITY 263 chaos even for simple models like the logistic growth function. Chaos refers to the situation where paths (trajectories) are very irregular, i.e. they do not repeat in a …nite amount of time. These paths are very sensitive to the initial condition, and therefore do not lend themselves to resource modeling (at least for our purposes). It is possible to rule out chaotic behavior by restricting parameter values, but that still leaves special cases. For example, a steady state might be stable (meaning that paths starting close to the steady state approach the steady state), but the approach path might be monotonic (steadily increasing or decreasing over time) or it might be cyclical (…rst increasing, then decreasing, then increasing, and so on). These possibilities can be interesting, but they require a digression that is tangential to our study of renewable resources. In addition, in the discrete time setting we cannot determine the stability or instability of a steady state merely by examining a graph; we require calculation. Therefore, for the purpose of considering stability, we consider “the continuous time analog” to the discrete time model. Using the general growth function and harvest rule, F (x) and y(x), we begin by replacing equation 14.3 with the more more general relation xt+1 xt = F (xt ) y (xt ) : (14.5) Instead of studying the stability of steady states of this equation, we study the stability of steady states of the continuous time analog, the ordinary di¤erential equation1 dxt = F (xt ) y (xt ) : (14.6) dt 14.3.2 Stability in continuous time It is simple to determine whether an interior steady state is stable in the continuous time setting. First, we identify the steady state(s) by …nding the solution(s) to the equation F (x) y (x) = 0, exactly as in the discrete time setting. Figure 14.3 shows the graph of an arbitrary function F (x) y (x) 1 Appendix G explains the relation between equations 14.5 and 14.6. These two equat tions have the same steady states: xt+1 xt = 0 if and only if dx dt = 0. Provided that the length of a period in the discrete time setting is su¢ ciently small, the dynamics of the continuous and discrete systems are similar in the neighborhood of a steady state. In this case, it is valid to study the stability of steady states in the discrete time setting using the continuous time model. 264 CHAPTER 14. RENEWABLE RESOURCES: TOOLS F(x)-y(x) 10 8 6 4 2 0 1 2 3 4 5 -2 6 x -4 -6 -8 -10 = F (x) y (x). There are three steady states, Figure 14.3: The graph of dx dt at x = 0:4, x = 1:4 and x = 5:2. The …rst and third are stable, and the middle steady state is unstable (one without a speci…c resource interpretation). This function has three roots, i.e. three steady states, where the graph crosses the x axis. Consider the low steady state, x = 0:4. We see that for a value of x close to but slightly below 0.4, dx = F (x) y (x) > 0, i.e. x is dt becoming larger over time. For a value of x close to but slightly above 0.4, dx = F (x) y (x) < 0, i.e. x is becoming smaller. Therefore, we conclude dt that x = 0:4 is a stable steady state: a trajectory beginning close to, but not equal to x = 0:4 approaches the level x = 0:4. A parallel argument shows that the middle steady state, x = 1:4, is an unstable steady state, and the large steady state, x = 5:2, is a stable steady state. Noticing that the slope of F (x) y (x) is negative at the two stable steady states in Figure 14.3, and the slope is positive at the unstable steady state, we obtain the following rule for checking stability.2 x1 is a stable steady state if and only if d(F (x1 ) y(x1 )) dx x1 is an unstable steady state if and only if 14.3.3 <0 d(F (x1 ) y(x1 )) dx (14.7) > 0: Stability in the …shing model ) y(x1 )) If d(F (x1dx = 0, points on one side of the steady state approach the steady state, and points on the other side move away from the steady state. This is a knife-edge case, and we do not consider it further. 2 14.3. STABILITY 265 y 0.3 0.2 0.1 0.0 10 -0.1 20 30 40 50 x -0.2 -0.3 -0.4 -0.5 Figure 14.4: Solid curve: the graph of the logistic curve, F (x). Dashed curve: the graph of F (x) 0:01x. Dotted curve: the graph of F (x) 0:3: Figure 14.4 shows the graphs of: the logistic growth function F (x) with carrying capacity K = 50 and intrinsic growth rate = 0:03 (solid); F (x) 0:01x (dashed); and F (x) 0:3 (dotted) We can use the rule in equation 14.7 to determine whether the steady states corresponding to the three graphs in Figure 14.4 are stable or unstable. The points of intersection of the graphs in Figure 14.4 and the x axis are steady states. Absent harvest, the solid curve shows that the steady states are x = 0 and x = K = 50. Using the rule in equation 14.7, we see that x = 0 is an unstable steady state and x = K is a stable steady state. The dashed curve shows that under proportional harvest, y = 0:01x, the two steady states are x = 0 and x = 33:33. Again, the low steady state is unstable and the high steady state is stable. The dotted curve, corresponding to constant harvest y = 0:3, has two points of intersection with the x axis: x = 13:8 and x = 36:2. The low steady state is unstable, and the high steady state is stable. Under constant harvest, x = 0 is also a stable steady state, even though the graph of F (x) 0:3 does not intersect the x axis. In the continuous time model, y is a rate. When x > 0, y can take any …nite non-negative value, although perhaps not for long. As soon as the stock hits x = 0, harvest must stop. If stock is small, here lower than 13.8, constant harvest y = 0:3, exceeds natural growth, and the stock falls. The stock heads to extinction, x = 0. Figure 14.4 illustrates an important possibility that we will encounter again. Under zero harvest or harvest proportional to the stock, the stock always approaches the high steady state (x = 50 and x = 33:33 in the two 266 CHAPTER 14. RENEWABLE RESOURCES: TOOLS harvest y=0.3 0.3 F 0.2 y=0.01x 0.1 0.0 10 20 30 40 50 x -0.1 Figure 14.5: The logistic growth function, and two harvest rules: constant harvest, y = 0:3 (dotted) and harvest proportional to stock, y = 0:01x (dotted). examples), provided that the initial stock is positive. In contrast, under constant harvest, beginning with a positive stock, the stock might eventually approach either stable steady state, x = 0 or x = 36:2. The unstable steady state, x = 13:8, is a critical stock level. For initial stocks above this critical level, the stock approaches the high steady state, and for initial stocks below this level, the stock approaches the low steady state, 0. Figure 14.5 shows the logistic growth function and two harvest rules, the constant harvest y = 0:3 and proportional harvest y = 0:01x. Despite their di¤erent appearance, Figures 14.5 and 14.4 can both be used to identify steady states and their stability. Figures 14.5 shows graphs of the growth and the harvest functions in the same …gure, and Figure 14.4 shows their di¤erence. The reader should con…rm that, as we move from left to right in Figure 14.5: (i) If the harvest function cuts the growth function from above, the associated steady state is unstable. (ii) if the harvest function cuts the growth function from below, the associated steady state is stable. 14.4 Maximum sustainable yield Objectives and skills 14.4. MAXIMUM SUSTAINABLE YIELD 267 Know the de…nition of Maximum Sustainable Yield (MSY) and be able to calculate the MSY for the logistic growth function. Understand the economic factors that determine whether optimal steady sate harvest should be above or below MSY. The maximum sustainable yield is the largest harvest that can be sustained in perpetuity. The maximum sustainable yield occurs where the growth function, F (x), reaches its maximum. For logistic growth, the maximum sustainable yield occurs at the stock x = K2 , which for our example equals 25; there, the harvest is y = F (25) = 0:375. Any constant harvest y lower than or equal to the maximum sustainable yield can be sustained in perpetuity. The steady state …sh stock that maximizes sustainable harvest is the solution to the condition dFdx(x) = 0. For the logistic growth function, this condition is d x 1 Kx 1 set = (K 2x) = 0: dx K Solving this equation gives the steady state stock that maximizes the sustainable yield K x= : 2 Substituting this value into the growth function, x 1 Kx , gives the maximum sustainable yield 1 MSY: y = K : 4 An increase in either the intrinsic growth rate, , or the carrying capacity, K increases the maximum sustainable. The socially optimal steady state Chapter 16 examines the socially optimal steady state, but even at this stage we can use economic logic to identify the factors that determine the optimal level. First, we need a criterion for comparing di¤erent outcomes. The most common criterion (discounted utilitarianism) is the present discounted value of the stream of consumer and producer surplus. (For the discussion here we ignore externalities and taxes.) What steady state is optimal under this criterion? By de…nition, steady state output = consumption is highest at the MSY, so consumer surplus 268 CHAPTER 14. RENEWABLE RESOURCES: TOOLS is highest there. Producer surplus, equal to revenue minus costs, depends on the cost of catching …sh. If it is cheaper to catch …sh when there are many …sh (the stock is large), increasing x above K2 reduces costs. With stock dependent harvest costs, the increase in the stock and the consequent decrease in the costs might increase producer surplus. (At this level of generality we do not know whether the change actually increases producer surplus, because the change also alters revenue.) It is easy to construct examples where increasing the stock above K2 increases producer surplus and also increases the sum of producer and consumer surplus. Even in this circumstance, we cannot conclude that it is socially optimal to have a steady state stock above K2 . With a positive discount rate, a future bene…t (e.g. consumer or producer surplus) is less valuable than a current bene…t. Therefore, a positive discount rate encourages society to consume more today, leaving less for the future, and reducing the stock below the MSY. In summary, consideration only of the consumption bene…t suggests that the MSY is the optimal steady harvest. Recognition that harvest costs depend on stock size suggests that the optimal steady state stock might lie above the level of MSY. Taking into account that the future is worth less than the present (due to discounting) suggests that society should aim for a steady state stock below the level of MSY. At this level of generality, there is not much more one can say. We need a model to determine the balance of these competing forces. 14.5 Summary Ignoring age and size distribution, we measure the stock of …sh as biomass, e.g. the number of tons of …sh. The growth equation determines the stock in the subsequent period as a function of the current stock. The logistic growth function depends on two parameters, the intrinsic growth rate and the carrying capacity K. A harvest rule, a function of the stock of …sh, determines the harvest in a period. We emphasized two simple harvest rules. One sets harvest equal to a constant fraction of the stock, and the other sets harvest equal to a constant. At a steady state, the …sh stock remains constant over time. The steady state depends on both the growth function and the harvest rule. There may be multiple steady states. A steady state is stable if and only if stocks that begin su¢ ciently close to the steady state converge to that steady state. If 14.6. TERMS, STUDY QUESTIONS, AND EXERCISES 269 a trajectory beginning at any initial condition close to but not equal to the steady state moves away from that steady state, the steady state is unstable. We introduced the continuous time model, for the purpose of making it easy to determine the stability or instability of a steady state. In order to relate the discrete and the continuos time models, the reader should think of the length of a period in our discrete time setting as being very small. In the continuous time setting, the interior steady states and their stability, are easy to determine. If the growth function is F (x) and the harvest = F (x) y (x). Any solution to F (x) y (x) = 0 function y (x), then dx dt is a steady state. That steady state is stable if the derivative, d(F (x)dx y(x)) , evaluated at the steady state is negative; it is unstable is this derivative is positive. We also need to consider levels of the state at which an inequality constraint binds. In the …shing context, the biomass cannot be negative, so x 0. With (positive) constant harvest, we saw that the steady state x = 0 is stable. The maximum sustainable yield equals the maximum point on the growth function. For the logistic growth model, the maximum sustainable yield occurs where the stock is half of its carrying capacity. 14.6 Terms, study questions, and exercises Terms and concepts Biomass, stock variables, annual growth rate, logistic growth (or logistic model), carrying capacity, intrinsic growth rate, harvest rule, steady state, chaos, stability, monotonic path, cyclical path, Maximum Sustainable Yield. Study questions 1. Given the graph of a growth function xt+1 xt = F (x), you should be able to identify the carrying capacity and the maximum sustainable yield, and say in a few words what each of these mean. 2. For a di¤erential equation dx = G (x), if you are shown a graph of G (x) dt you should be able to identify the steady state(s) and say which, if any of these are stable. You should be able to explain your answer in a couple of sentences. 270 CHAPTER 14. RENEWABLE RESOURCES: TOOLS 3. (a) Given a single …gure that shows both the graph of the growth function F (x) and the harvest function y (x), should be able to identify the steady states and explain (in very few words) which is stable and which is unstable. You should be able to sketch a graph of their = F (x) y (x), and use the rule in equation 14.7 to di¤erence, dx dt con…rm that your answer to part (a) was correct. Exercises 1. Using an argument that parallels the discussion of the low steady state in Figure 14.3, explain why the middle steady state is unstable and why the high steady state is stable. 2. For the logistic growth function, F (x) = x Kx , identify the proportional harvest rule (the value of in the rule y = x) that supports the maximum sustainable yield as a steady state. Is this steady state stable? 3. The “skewed logistic”growth function is F (xt ) = xt 1 xt K , with > 0. For = 1 we have the logistic growth function in equation 14.1. (a) How does the magnitude of a¤ect the growth rate? (b) The maximum sustainable yield occurs at x = K . Derive this formula. +1 (c) Use a software package of your choice to draw this curve for K = 50, = 0:03, and for both = 2 and = 0:5. Sources Cite Shae¤er paper Colin Clark’s book Chapter 15 The open access …shery Objectives Ability to characterize the harvest rule and the evolution of biomass under open access, and to analyze the e¤ect of speci…c policies. Skills Be able to determine the cost function corresponding to a particular production function. Determine the relation between a representative …rm cost function and the open access “harvest rule”. Determine the evolution of biomass under this open access harvest rule. Understand how a tax or some other type of regulation a¤ects the incentive to harvest, at an arbitrary level of the biomass. Determine the e¤ect of the policy on the evolution of biomass, and on the steady state(s). We apply the methods developed in previous chapters to study the open access …shery. We want to determine both the static and the dynamic e¤ects of taxes (or some other type of regulation). The static tax e¤ect equals the e¤ect of the tax at a point in time, for a given biomass. The dynamic tax e¤ect equals the e¤ect of the tax on the evolution of the biomass. 271 272 CHAPTER 15. THE OPEN ACCESS FISHERY The agents studied in the chapters on non-renewable resources were (by assumption) sole owners of the resource. Each of those agents knows that extracting one more unit in the current period means that they have one less unit to extract in some future period. These agents are “forward looking”; they take into account future prices in making current decisions. In contrast, in the open access …shery, no individual has property rights. Moreover, we assume that each individual is such a small part of the total ‡eet that her actions have negligible e¤ect on the aggregate catch. Under these circumstances, it is rational for an agent to ignore the future: there is nothing she can do about it. Here, an individual …sher chooses her current harvest level to maximize her own current pro…ts, without regard for the e¤ect of her decisions on other …shers or on her own future pro…ts. Chapter 13.3 studies a static version of this scenario, where everything happens in the same period. Dynamics are central to the …shery problem, where the externality unfolds over time. Here we study a model in which …shers’aggregate current harvest a¤ects the subsequent stock, thereby a¤ecting future harvest cost: there is a “dynamic”externality. We emphasized in Chapter 13.3 that the …rst best harvest typically involves many types of decisions, and that regulators rarely have as many instruments (policy variables) as there are targets. There we assumed that the regulator could in‡uence harvest by choosing the length of the …shing season. Here we consider a di¤erent policy variable, a tax on catch, known as a landing fee. We show how this tax in‡uences the open access equilibrium. We use two specializations of the parametric cost function from equation 4.1, c (x; y) = C ( + x) y 1+ . The …rst, with constant stock-independent average harvest costs, sets = = = 0, so c (x; y) = Cy. The second specialization sets = = 0 and = 1, so c (x; y) = C xy . 15.1 Stock-independent costs Objectives and skills Given an inverse demand function and constant harvest costs, …nd the open access harvest rule. Sketch the graph corresponding to this harvest rule and the logistic growth function. 15.1. STOCK-INDEPENDENT COSTS 273 Use this graph to identify the steady states and (for the continuous time setting) determine whether each steady state is stable or unstable. The case of stock-independent constant harvest costs, c (x; y) = Cy, provides the simplest illustration of the open access equilibrium. The competitive supply function is in…nitely elastic (‡at) at C for y x, and perfectly inelastic (vertical) at y = x. In the discrete time setting, it is not possible for y to exceed x.1 We assume that …rms can adjust their output instantaneously, so under open access, pro…ts are zero in every period, and price equals average cost. For the inverse demand function p = a by, price = average costs requires y = a b C . If C a, then average cost is greater than or equal to the choke price (a) and harvest is always zero. We therefore assume C < a, where open access harvest is positive whenever the stock is positive. Here, the open access harvest rule is y (x) = min x; a C b (15.1) Chapter 14 examines the dynamics under this kind of harvest rule. Figure 15.1 reviews this material, showing the graph of a logistic growth function and the graphs of two harvest rules, corresponding to a low and a high cost, C (the dashed and dotted lines, respectively). For both of these costs, there are three steady states. The zero steady state and the high steady state (occurring to the right of the maximum sustainable yield) are both stable. The middle steady state is unstable. 1 In the continuous time setting, harvest is a rate and can take any nonnegative value when x > 0 (Chapter 14.3.3). 274 CHAPTER 15. THE OPEN ACCESS FISHERY y 0.3 ((a-1)/b) 0.2 0.1 ((a-3)/b) 0.0 10 20 30 40 50 x Figure 15.1: The solid curve is the graph of the logistic growth function with = 0:03 and K = 50. The dashed line shows the open access harvest rule for C = 1 and the dotten line shows the harvest rule for C = 3. Inverse demand is p = a = by with a = 3:5 and b = 10. Box 15.1 The zero pro…t assumption. The assumption that pro…t is zero in each period is based on the implicit assumption that e¤ort adjusts instantaneously. In fact, adjustment is likely to be sluggish, simply because more rapid adjustment (either increases or decreases in e¤ort) is more expensive. With this kind of adjustment cost, e¤ort becomes a stock variable (an asset). Two types of models study this situation. The simplest uses an ad hoc assumption that the change in e¤ort is an exogenous function of current pro…t. For example, current change in e¤ort is proportional to current pro…t. The second type of model assumes that agents are forward looking with respect to their investment decision. Both settings can lead to cyclical dynamics, where the resource stock rises and falls over time. 15.2 Stock-dependent costs Objectives and skills Given a particular production function, be able to …nd the …rm’s cost function. Given this cost function and an inverse demand function, …nd the open access harvest rule. 15.2. STOCK-DEPENDENT COSTS 275 Be able to sketch the graph of this harvest rule and the logistic growth function. Use this graph to identify the steady states, and to determine which of these are stable and which unstable. Be able to determine how a change in a parameter of the demand function or the cost function alters the graph, thus altering the stock’s dynamics. The case of stock dependent costs is more interesting, but more complicated than the constant cost case. We therefore begin with a road map: 1. We use a production function to obtain a cost function in the open access equilibrium. 2. We use the cost function and the market clearing condition (supply = demand) to obtain the open-access “harvest rule”. 3. We use the open-access harvest rule to examine the dynamics of biomass, and to determine how parameters of the model (e.g. the demand intercept) alters the dynamics. 1. From the production function to the cost function Fishing “effort”, E, can be measured in a variety of ways, including by the number of boats and the number of person-hours per season. We treat e¤ort as an amalgam of all of the inputs in the …shery sector. For example, one unit of e¤ort might equal one boat, 200 hours of labor, and a particular type of net. In a representative agent model, Et is the aggregate e¤ort in the …shery in period t. Greater e¤ort increases harvest. Fish are easier to catch when the stock is large, so for a given amount of e¤ort, a larger stock increases harvest. The …shery production function shows how e¤ort, E, and the stock, x, determine harvest, y. The simplest production function assumes that the level of harvest per unit of e¤ort is proportional to the size of the stock, Ey = qx, or y = qEx: (15.2) The parameter q > 0 is the “catchability coe¢ cient”. A larger q means that for a given stock size, …shers need less e¤ort to obtain a given level of harvest. 276 CHAPTER 15. THE OPEN ACCESS FISHERY The cost per unit of e¤ort is the constant, w. If one “unit of e¤ort” equals one boat and 200 hours of labor and a particular net, then w equals the cost of renting the boat, paying the crew, and buying or renting the net. We use the production function to derive the cost function, which shows how costs depend on harvest, the stock and parameters of the model. We can rewrite equation 15.2 as y = E; qx which shows how e¤ort depends on the level of harvest and the stock; E units of e¤ort cost wE. Therefore, the cost of harvesting y, given the stock x, and given parameters w and q, is harvest cost: c (x; y) = wE = where C w . q C w y = y; qx x (15.3) Harvest costs fall as the stock of …sh rises. 2. From the cost function to the open access harvest rule Individual …shers in our model are price takers and they ignore the e¤ect of their harvest on the subsequent stock. If each individual …sher is a small part of the industry, as is consistent with the price-taking assumption, then it is rational for them to act as if their own current harvest decision has negligible e¤ect on the next-period stock, and thus on their next-period harvest cost. With these assumptions, and the cost function in equation 15.3, the equilibrium condition for harvest is that price equals average cost. For this model, where average = marginal harvest costs, each …sher obtains zero pro…t (= producer surplus) in each period (Box 15.1). If price is less than marginal = average cost, then supply equals 0. If supply is positive, then the zero-pro…t condition requires that price equals average cost. This condition determines the inverse supply function psupply (y) = C : x (15.4) Setting inverse demand, p (y), equal to the inverse supply function in equation 15.4, gives the equilibrium condition (demand = supply, when supply is positive) C p (y) = : x 15.2. STOCK-DEPENDENT COSTS 277 With linear inverse demand p (y) = a be solved to yield the harvest function by, this equilibrium condition can y (x) = 1 b a Cx for a Cx 0 for a Cx < 0: 0 (15.5) The second line of this equation takes into account the fact that supply = demand = 0 if the average harvest cost, Cx , exceeds the choke price, a. Most …sheries are regulated. Some regulations, e.g. gear restrictions, increase harvest costs. In the model here, these types of regulations imply an increase in the parameter C. Equation 15.5 shows that a larger C reduces the equilibrium open access harvest rule. Taxes, or landing fees, drive a wedge between consumer and producer prices, also altering the harvest rule. 3. Using the harvest rule to examine dynamics of the biomass Figure 15.2 shows the graph of the logistic growth function and the open access harvesting rule in equation 15.5 for both “low demand”, p = 3:5 10y and “high demand”, p = 4:2 10y, the dashed and dotted curves, respectively. The …gure also shows the three interior steady states (where x > 0), points A; B; D, under low demand. In the high demand scenario, the only interior steady state occurs at a low stock level, close to but slightly lower than point A. Extinction, x = 0, is a steady state in both cases. Consider the low demand scenario, shown by the dashed curve. Moving from left to right, we see that the dashed curve cuts the growth function from below at points A and D, and it cuts the growth function from above at point B. Thus, points A and D are stable steady states, and point B is an unstable steady state. (Refer to the …nal paragraph in Section 14.3.3 if this claim is not clear.) The point x = 0 is an unstable equilibrium. For su¢ ciently small but positive stock, a Cx < 0. Here, the stock is so low, and the harvest costs so high, that the equilibrium harvest is 0. Because growth is positive for small positive x, the …sh stock is growing in this region. Therefore, if the initial stock is positive and below point B, the stock in the open access …shery converges to point A. If the initial stock is above point B, the stock converges to point D. In the high demand scenario (the dotted curve), there are two steady states. The stable steady state is slightly below point A; x = 0 is an unstable steady state. Thus, in the high demand scenario, for any positive initial stock, the stock under open access converges to a level slightly below 278 CHAPTER 15. THE OPEN ACCESS FISHERY growth 0.4 D B 0.3 0.2 0.1 A 0.0 10 20 30 40 50 stock -0.1 Figure 15.2: The solid curve shows the logistic growth function with = 0:03 and K = 50. The dashed curve shows the open access harvest rule, with a = 3:5, b = 10 and C = 5 and the three steady states, A, B, and D. The dotted curve shows the open access harvest rule with a = 4:20, b = 10 and C = 5. point A.2 15.3 Policy applications Objectives and skills Using the …gure obtained from the previous section, describe and explain the e¤ect of a constant tax on the evolution of the biomass and on the steady states. Illustrate and explain the role of the initial condition (the stock at the time the tax is imposed) on the e¤ect of the tax. Policy a¤ects the equilibrium outcome by altering the equilibrium harvest rule. Even this simple model is rich enough to address several types of policy questions. We noted that policies that restrict the type of gear …shers can use, increase C. From equations 15.1 and 15.5 we see that a larger C shifts 2 Appendix H provides a di¤erent way to visulaize the equilibrum, using the concept of a “bioeconomic equilibrium”. 15.3. POLICY APPLICATIONS 279 down the harvest rule. Here we consider the e¤ect of taxes when average harvest costs depend on the stock. The fact that there are (potentially) multiple steady states in this model means that the e¤ect of policy might be sensitive not just to the level of policy (e.g., the magnitude of the tax), but also to the level of the stock at the time the policy is imposed. A policy imposed when the stock is low might have a completely di¤erent e¤ect on the outcome, than would the same policy imposed when the stock is high. We explore this dependence under taxes. The e¤ect of the tax on the harvest rule Suppose that producers face the unit tax . Chapter 11 shows that (in a closed economy) a tax has the same e¤ect regardless of whether consumers or producers have statutory responsibility for paying it. That chapter also explains that the tax incidence depends on relative supply and demand elasticities. In the model here, with constant average = marginal costs in a period (i.e. for a given level of biomass), supply is in…nitely elastic. Therefore, consumers bear the entire incidence of the tax at a point in time (i.e. for a given level of biomass).3 Denote the price …shers receive as p, so consumers’ price is p + . The inverse supply curve remains unchanged at psupply (y) = Cx . With linear inverse demand, consumers facing the price p + demand the quantity y that solves p + = a by. The market clearing condition, supply equals demand, requires p + = a by = Cx + . Solving the second equation for harvest gives the harvest rule 1 C C 0 a for a b x x y (x) = (15.6) C 0 for a < 0: x The second line of equation 15.6 recognizes that if the average cost plus the C < 0), then sales tax, + Cx , is greater than the choke price (so that a x are zero. This equation shows that the harvest rule depends on the di¤erence between the choke price and the tax, a . A one unit decrease in a or a one unit increase in have the same e¤ect on a . An increase in the tax, , has the same e¤ect on harvest as does a decrease in the demand intercept, a. We use this fact and Figure 15.2 to study the e¤ect of a change in the unit tax, . 3 Fishers are already receiving zero pro…t in equilibrium. A tax could not reduce their pro…t to a negative number: …shers would leave the sector rather than experience negative pro…ts. 280 CHAPTER 15. THE OPEN ACCESS FISHERY growth 0.4 B' D' D B 0.3 0.2 0.1 A 0.0 10 20 30 40 50 stock -0.1 Figure 15.3: The logistic growth function (the solid graph) and three equilibrium harvest rules: the harvest rule under high demand, p = 4:2 10y for no tax (the highest graph); the harvest rule under a unit tax = 0:35 (the middle graph); and the harvest rule under a unit tax = 0:7 (the lowest graph). Figure 15.2 shows how a change in the demand intercept alters the harvest rule, thus altering the equilibrium steady states and the dynamics of the …sh stock. For the policy application, we hold the demand intercept …xed at a = 4:2 (the high demand scenario) and we consider the e¤ect of changing the tax, . We use the fact that a decrease in a or an increase in have the same e¤ect on the harvest rule. Figure 15.3 reproduces Figure 15.2, adding (merely for emphasis) a harvest rule laying between the original two harvest rules. Holding a …xed at 4:2, Figure 15.3 illustrates the e¤ect of increasing the tax from = 0, …rst to = 0:35 (so a = 3:85), and then to = 0:7 (so a = 3:5). The role of the initial condition The steady states B 0 and D0 correspond to the harvest rule for = 0:35. The low steady states for the three harvest rules are slightly di¤erent, but they all occur so close to point A, where xA = 1:7, as to be indistinguishable at the level of resolution contained in the …gure. However, the intermediate and the high steady states are appreciably di¤erent under the two positive taxes; these steady states do not exist if = 0. The numerical values of the stock corresponding to the low, 15.3. POLICY APPLICATIONS 281 intermediate and high steady states are xA = 1:7, xB = 15:4, xB 0 = 20, xD0 = 28:6, and xD = 33:2: We do not distinguish between xA and xA0 because these are so close that their di¤erence is not interesting. The stock at the time the tax policy is imposed is the “initial condition”. Figure 15.3 illustrates that the initial stock, – not just the policy level – can have a signi…cant e¤ect on the stock dynamics, and particularly on the steady state to which the stock converges. If the initial stock is less than 15.4, neither tax has an appreciable e¤ect on the steady state. The stock converges to a point close to xA = 1:7, regardless of whether = 0 or = 0:35 or = 0:7. If the initial stock is between 15:4 and 20, the tax = 0:35 has a negligible e¤ect on the steady state to which the stock converges: close to xA = 1:7. In this same circumstance, the tax = 0:7 causes the stock to converge to 33.2. If the initial stock lies above x = 20, then the stock converges to x = 28:6 for = 0:35 and to x = 32:2 for = 0:7. In this example, if the initial stock is “moderately small” (15:4 < x0 < 20), then = 0:35 has a negligible e¤ect on the steady state, whereas the tax = 0:7 has a qualitative e¤ect, leading to a large increase in the steady state. If the initial stock is “moderately large”, (x0 > 20) then both taxes lead to a qualitatively di¤erent steady state, compared to = 0. The high steady states under = 0:7 (xD = 33:2) and under = 0:35 (xD0 = 28:6) are appreciably di¤erent. The zero tax leads to a very low steady state stock, regardless of the initial condition. Steady state welfare e¤ects of the tax Provided that the initial condition is greater than x = 20, the low tax leads to a lower steady state, but a higher steady state harvest, compared to the high tax: point D0 is higher (larger y) than point D in Figure 15.3. Therefore, the steady state ‡ow of consumer surplus (at the high stable steady state) is higher under the low tax. This claim follows from the fact that consumption = harvest is higher at xD0 than at xD ; consequently, consumers must pay a lower price at xD0 . In the high steady state under the high tax, xD = 33:2, so harvest = consumption is the solution to y = xD 1 xD K = 0:335. 282 CHAPTER 15. THE OPEN ACCESS FISHERY Consumers are willing to purchase this amount if they face the tax-inclusive price 4:2 10 0:335 = 0:853. At this price, consumer surplus (our measure of consumer welfare) is4 Z 4:2 0:853 4:2 z 10 dz = 0:56 and tax revenue is y = 0:7 (0:853) = 0:234. Pro…ts are zero at every point, so social welfare equals the sum of consumer surplus plus tax revenue, 0.794. Table 1 collects these numbers at the high stable steady states under the two taxes. It shows that steady state consumer surplus is higher, tax revenue is lower, and their sum, social welfare, is higher under the smaller tax. consumer social tax revenue surplus welfare 0:7 33.2 0.335 0.853 0.56 0.234 0.794 0:35 28.6 0.367 0.528 0.67 0.129 0.803 Table 15.1: High stable steady state stock, harvest, price, consumer surplus, tax revenue, and social surplus for two taxes. K = 50; = 0:03; C = 5, inverse demand = p = 4:2 10y tax ( ) stock harvest price Policy implications This analysis shows that the e¤ect of the tax on the steady state payo¤ depends on the initial condition (= the value of the stock at the time the tax is …rst imposed). For example, if the initial stock is x0 > xD0 = 20, the smaller tax drives the stock to a steady state with a higher payo¤, compared to the larger tax. However, if the initial stock is 15:4 < x0 < 20, the low tax drives the stock to a low steady state (close to 1.7) with a very low payo¤, whereas the high tax drives the stock to the high state, 33.2, with the relatively high payo¤. If the regulator actually knows the initial value of the stock, along with all of the other parameters of the problem, then she can solve the mathematical problem to determine the optimal (constant) tax. In the real world, the regulator does not know these things, and data limitations make their estimation di¢ cult. It is possible to estimate the demand function, using data on price and quantity. It is di¢ cult to get good data on costs or stocks; 4 Recall that consumer surplus equals the area “to the left” of the demand curve, between the market price, here 0.853, and the choke price, here 4.2. The integral equals this area. 15.3. POLICY APPLICATIONS 283 consequently, at best we can hope for ball-park estimates of the parameters of the cost function and the growth equation, C; ; K. In addition, we have at best a rough idea of the current biomass, the initial condition to the optimization problem. Therefore, it would be risky to recommend a tax using an optimization problem based on the …ction that we actually know these parameters. However, the analysis above reveals the nature of the trade-o¤. Given the amount of uncertainty in going from the real world to the mathematical model, the regulator might want to build in a margin of safety by choosing a tax that exceeds the optimal level for this toy model. The larger tax provides protection against the possibility that we overestimated the initial biomass. Our estimate of the initial biomass might be above the critical level where the trajectory takes us to a high steady state; but if the actual initial stock is below that critical level, the consequences of the tax are very di¤erent than we expected. Because we do not actually know the precise initial stock, we may want to include a margin of safety in choosing the tax. Non-constant taxes Thus far we have considered only a constant tax. We know from elementary principles that a constant tax is not …rst best, even if we knew all of the parameters of the problem. The constant tax is a single number. It can therefore be used to target (i.e., to select) a single variable. We have used the steady state stock, and corresponding payo¤, as the target of interest. However, it makes sense for the regulator to care about the payo¤ along the trajectory en route to the steady state, and thus to care about the trajectory –not just its endpoint (the steady state). Thus (ignoring the uncertainty discussed above), a richer description of the regulatory problem includes taxes in each period, or for each possible level of the biomass. Even if a tax has only a negligible e¤ect on the steady state to which the stock converges, the tax may nevertheless have a signi…cant e¤ect on welfare, by slowing the decline of the …shery. For example, if x0 is slightly lower than 15:4, the tax = 0:35 causes a 9% reduction in the initial harvest, and the tax = 0:7 causes an 18% reduction in the initial harvest; both of these changes are relative to harvest under = 0. Even though this di¤erence is not large enough to keep the stock from converging to approximately the same low level, the higher tax slows the …shery’s decline. The welfare trajectories under the high and the low taxes lead to approximately the same low level, 284 CHAPTER 15. THE OPEN ACCESS FISHERY but the welfare begins at a higher level and falls more slowly under the larger tax. Therefore, for an initial condition below 15:4, the present discounted stream of that welfare is likely higher under the larger tax. 15.4 Summary “E¤ort” is an amalgam of inputs (boats, labor) in the …shing sector. The production function gives harvest as a function of e¤ort and the …sh stock. We used the production function to obtain the industry cost function. In an open access equilibrium, where pro…ts are zero, the condition that average cost equals price gives the industry supply function. Equating supply and demand and solving for harvest gives the open access harvest rule: harvest depends on the model parameters, and when costs depend on the stock, the harvest rule also depends on the stock. With linear demand and where harvest per unit of e¤ort is proportional to the stock, we obtain a closed form expression for the open access harvest rule. We used the growth function and the harvest rule to identify and classify steady states. Our use of the continuous time model here makes it possible to rely on graphs (e.g. Figure 15.2) not only to identify steady states, but also to determine whether they are stable. If we had stuck with the discrete time setting, the same …gure would identify the steady states, but checking for stability would have required a numerical calculation. To determine stability of a steady state in the continuous time setting, we need only determine whether, as we move from left to right, the harvest rule cuts the growth function from above (at an unstable steady state) or from below (at a stable steady state). Depending on parameter values, there might be a single interior (= positive) steady state or three interior steady states. In the former case, the unique interior steady state is stable. In the latter case, the low and the high interior steady states are stable, and the middle steady state is unstable. The stock x = 0 is an unstable steady state in our models. A unit tax on harvest shifts down the open access harvest rule, reducing harvest for any level of the stock. A su¢ ciently high unit tax moves the …shery from the situation where there is a single interior steady state to the situation where there are there interior steady states. In this situation, the tax creates a stable steady state with a high level of the stock. The e¤ect of a tax depends on both the magnitude of the tax and on the level of the stock 15.5. TERMS, STUDY QUESTIONS, AND EXERCISES 285 at the time the tax is …rst imposed (the initial condition). We also used this example to determine the steady state level of welfare (= consumer surplus plus tax revenue) under di¤erent taxes. 15.5 Terms, study questions, and exercises Terms and concepts Myopic, catchability coe¢ cient, initial condition, steady state supply function. Study questions 1. (a) For the case of constant average harvest cost, Cy, linear inverse demand, p = a by, and logistic growth, obtain the open access harvest rule, and sketch it on the same …gure as the growth function. Illustrate how a change in C alters the steady state and the dynamics of the …sh stock. (b) Illustrate and explain the e¤ect of a constant unit tax, , on the steady states. (c) Use a graph and short discussion to illustrate the fact that the e¤ect of a given tax depends both on its magnitude and on the stock level at the time the tax is imposed. 2. Begin with the production function showing output (harvest) y = qEx, where E is e¤ort and x is biomass. Explain the meaning of E (perhaps by using an example) and the meaning of the parameter q. What is the name given to this parameter? 3. Suppose that a unit of e¤ort costs w. Derive the cost function for the example in the previous question. Explain your derivation. (It is not enough to merely memorize this cost function.) 4. Using the cost function in the previous question and the inverse demand curve p = a by, derive the open access harvest rule. Be able to explain each step. (Memorization is not su¢ cient.) 5. Write down the logistic growth function. On the same …gure, sketch graphs of this growth function and the harvest rule obtained in the previous question. 286 CHAPTER 15. THE OPEN ACCESS FISHERY 6. Using the …gure from the previous question, show the e¤ect of an increase in the demand slope, b, or intercept, a, on harvest rule, and on any steady state(s). Discuss the e¤ect of this change (in a parameter of the demand function) on the evolution of the stock. A complete answer must explain how the parameter change can qualitatively alter the evolution of the stock, depending on the initial condition. 7. Show how a constant tax a¤ects the open access harvest rule. 8. By means of a graph, show how an increase in the tax can alter the steady state(s). 9. Explain why the e¤ect of the tax depends on both the magnitude of the tax and on the initial condition of the biomass, at the time the tax is …rst implemented. Exercises 1. This exercise illustrates the fact that imposing restrictions typically increases production costs. Suppose that e¤ort depends on the size of the boat, B, and the amount of labor, L in the following manner: E = B 0:5 L0:5 . The cost of the boat, bB is proportional to its size, with a “price per unit size b”. The wage is w, so the labor bill is wL. Thus, the cost of providing one unit of e¤ort is C, with c = min (bB + wL) subject to B L1 B;L = 1: (a) Find the optimal labor/boat size ratio, BL and the cost of providing one unit of e¤ort„c, as a function of prices b and w (b) Suppose that regulation doubles the required labor/boat size ratio to 2 BL . Denote as c~, the cost of providing a unit of e¤ort under this regulation, a function of b and w. Compare c~ and c. 2. (a) Show how a constant tax a¤ects the steady state under open access where costs do not depend on the stock, c (x; y) = Cy. (b) Show how this tax alters the dynamics of the …sh stock. Your answer to part (b) needs to describe how the e¤ect of the tax on the evolution of the stock depends on the initial condition. 15.5. TERMS, STUDY QUESTIONS, AND EXERCISES 287 3. Using Figure 15.2, show how a larger value of C alters the two harvest rules (corresponding to low demand and high demand). Using this information, describe the e¤ect of a larger C on the steady state(s) in the low and high demand scenarios. 4. Using equation 15.5, provide the economic explanation for the statement that y (x) = 0 for a Cx < 0: 5. Suppose that inverse demand is p = a a0:21 y, with a > 1. (a) Show that for this demand function, the elasticity of demand, evaluated at p = 1, is = a 1 1 . A larger value of a implies less elastic demand. (b) Using Figure ??, show how the set of steady states changes as demand becomes more elastic (a decreases toward 1). Provide an economic explanation for your observation. 6. (*) Suppose that the production function for harvest is y = (qEx) with 0 < < 1. The cost of a unit of e¤ort is c, a constant. (a) Write the cost function (expressing cost of harvest as a function of harvest and the stock). Sketch the cost function as a function of harvest (for a given stock). (b) There is free entry, so that at each point in time, pro…ts equal 0. Use this equilibrium condition, and the linear inverse demand function, p = a by, to write an equation that gives harvest as an implicit function of the stock. (c) Although it is not possible to solve this equation to obtain harvest as an explicit function of the stock, it is simple to solve it to obtain the stock as an explicit function of the harvest. Using this approach, graph the relation between the harvest and the stock. It helps to pick a particular value of , e.g. = 0:5. On the same graph, sketch the graph of the harvest rule when = 1 (shown in Figure 15.2). (d) Transfer these two graphs onto a …gure that also shows the growth function F , and use the result to describe the qualitative e¤ect on the dynamics, of a decrease in (here, from 1 to 0.5). Provide an economic explanation. Hint, part a. Mimic the procedure used to …nd the cost function in the text. Rewrite the production function to …nd the level of e¤ort needed to produce a given harvest, y, at a particular stock, x. How much does this level of e¤ort cost? The answer is the cost function. Sources Berck and Perlo¤ for forward-looking e¤ort adjustment; earlier papers for ad hoc adjustment rules. 288 CHAPTER 15. THE OPEN ACCESS FISHERY Chapter 16 The sole-owner …shery Objectives Ability to derive and interpret the necessary condition for an equilibrium under a price-taking sole owner …shery; use this equilibrium condition to obtain and discuss the steady state(s) and to study taxes under open access. Skills Adapt the skills developed from the nonrenewable to the renewable resource setting. Be able to write the sole owner’s objective function and to apply the perturbation method. Understand how growth in the renewable resource setting enters the no-intertemporal-arbitrage condition. Understand the de…nition of rent and be able to use it to rewrite and re-interpret the Euler equation. Be able to use the optimality condition to describe optimal policy in the presence of market failures. Be able to use the optimality condition to identify the steady state for the optimally controlled …shery. 289 290 CHAPTER 16. THE SOLE-OWNER FISHERY This chapter studies the equilibrium under the price-taking sole-owner …shery, extending earlier results on nonrenewable resources. Absent other market failures, the outcome under the sole owner is e¢ cient. That owner maximizes the present discounted sum of the sequence of producer + consumer surplus. There are few if any important sole owner …sheries. However, the sole owner outcome provides a baseline against which we can compare an open access or common property outcome. That comparison provides insight about …shery management when property rights are imperfect. Fisheries are intrinsically important, and the tools developed for their study are useful in many renewable resource settings For example, excessive greenhouse gas emissions occur because of the absence of property rights for the atmosphere. For both the open access …shery and the climate, property rights are weak or nonexistent. In both cases, a comparison of the outcome without property rights, and the outcome under a social planner (or sole owner), provides information on optimal regulation. The sole owner …shery (typically) obtains resource rents, which may depend on the resource stock. The sole owner understands that current harvest a¤ects future stocks, thus a¤ecting future rent. Fishers in the open-access setting ignore the e¤ect of their harvest on future stock. Because of this difference, the former leads to socially optimal harvest, and (except for special cases) the latter leads to excessive harvest. We state the sole owner’s optimization problem and then derive the optimality condition, the Euler equation. The de…nition of rent leads to a more concise statement of Euler equation. We consider a situation where the …shery provides ecological services, e.g. as a food source for other valuable species, and the sole owner does not internalize the value of those services. Property rights for the particular species corrects some, but perhaps not all market failures. The sole owner equilibrium conditions determine the steady states, which we compare to the open access steady states. 16.1 The Euler equation for the sole owner Objectives and skills: State the sole owner’s optimization problem. Write and interpret the Euler equation. 16.1. THE EULER EQUATION FOR THE SOLE OWNER 291 Express the Euler equation using rent, and interpret. We consider two specializations of the parametric cost function. In the …rst, average harvest costs are constant in harvest and independent of the stock, c (x; y) = Cy. In the second, average harvest costs are constant in the harvest and decreasing in the stock c (x; y) = Cx y, so @c(x;y) = xC2 y < 0. @x The owner of the resource takes the sequence of prices, p0 , p1 , p2 ::: as given; these prices are “endogenous to the model”, via the inverse demand function, pt = p (yt ), but the resource owner takes the prices as exogenous. The owner’s present discounted stream of pro…ts is 1 X t (pt yt c (xt ; yt )) . t=0 For the constant average cost speci…cation, the owner chooses the sequence of harvests, y0 ; y1 ; y2 ::: to solve P t (pt C) yt max 1 t=0 (16.1) subject to xt+1 = xt + F (xt ) yt : For the stock dependent average cost speci…cation, the owner’s objective and constraints are P t pt xCt yt max 1 t=0 (16.2) subject to xt+1 = xt + F (xt ) yt : In general, the resource owner obtains positive rent, which depends on the level of the stock. The owner therefore takes into account how current harvest a¤ects future stock, and future rent. In addition, with stock dependent costs, the owner understands that a change in current harvest alters future harvest costs, via the change in the stock. For the sole owner facing constant harvest costs, C, the Euler equation is pt C= (pt+1 C) 1 + dF (xt+1 ) dxt+1 : (16.3) The Euler equation for stock dependent case is (Appendix I) pt C = xt pt+1 C xt+1 1+ dF (xt+1 ) dxt+1 + C yt+1 : x2t+1 (16.4) 292 16.1.1 CHAPTER 16. THE SOLE-OWNER FISHERY Intuition for the Euler equation We emphasize the case of stock dependent harvest costs, equation 16.4. With one important di¤erence, this necessary condition is identical to the Euler equation 5.2 for the nonrenewable resource.1 The di¤erence is that the right side of equation 16.4 involves pt+1 C xt+1 1+ dF (xt+1 ) dxt+1 ; whereas the corresponding term with nonrenewable resources (from equation 5.2) is C pt+1 (1 + 0) : xt+1 t+1 ) = 0, i.e. unless the stock has These two expressions di¤er unless dFdx(xt+1 no e¤ect on growth. Stock dependent growth is central in the renewable resource setting in general, and to the …shery problem in particular. A trajectory consists of a sequence of harvest and stock levels. Along an optimal trajectory, a small change in harvest in some period, and an o¤setting change in some other period, must lead to a zero …rst order change in the payo¤: a perturbation does not improve the outcome. We obtain the Euler equation by considering a particular perturbation: one that changes harvest by a small amount in one period, and then makes an o¤setting change to harvest in the next period, so that the subsequent stock remains on the candidate trajectory. The left side of equation 16.4 equals the marginal bene…t of increasing harvest in period t, and the right side equals the marginal cost of the o¤setting change needed in the subsequent period, to return the trajectory to the candidate path. The di¤erence between the Euler equation in the nonrenewable resource and the renewable resource settings, arising because of growth. Growth a¤ects the change needed in period t + 1 to o¤set the change in period t. A “savings example” for intuition To provide intuition, we consider a savings problem unrelated to resources. An investor earns a per period return of r: investing a dollar at the beginning of a period produces 1 + r 1 Compare equations 5.2 and 16.4, and use the fact that for our cost function here, t ;yt ) c (xt ; yt ) = xCt yt , so @c(x = xCt . @yt 16.1. THE EULER EQUATION FOR THE SOLE OWNER 293 dollars at the end of the period. This investor has a “candidate savings plan”, a trajectory of savings (a ‡ow variable) and wealth (a stock variable) for a certain number of periods. The savings decision corresponds to harvest in the …shery setting, and wealth corresponds to biomass. Suppose that the investor considers perturbing this candidate in period t by saving one dollar less than the candidate prescribes. In order to put her plan back on the candidate trajectory by period t + 2, she has to invest an additional 1 + r dollars in period t + 1, over and above the amount that her original (“pre-perturbation”) plan calls for. The extra $1 makes up for the dollar that she took out in period t, and the extra $r makes up for the interest that she lost by taking out that dollar. In the nonrenewable resource setting, extracting an extra unit (above the level speci…ed by the candidate) at t required a one unit reduction in extraction at t + 1, in order to return the trajectory to the candidate. In the savings example, where the stock (wealth, instead of the resource) grows on its own, o¤setting the change at time t requires “something extra” at time t + 1. The same type of consideration applies in the …shery setting. The savings example is simpler than the …shery problem because in the savings problem growth in wealth (Wt ) is a linear function of wealth (with slope equal to 1 + r): Absent savings, wealth in the next period is Wt+1 = (1 + r) Wt . In the …shery problem, growth in biomass is not a linear function of biomass. Using this intuition Harvesting an extra unit in period t generates pt additional units of revenue, and xCt additional units of cost, for a net increase in pro…ts of pt xCt , the left side of equation 16.4. This perturbation reduces next period pro…ts because it necessitates lower harvest, and because the harvest that does occur is more expensive, due to the lower stock caused by t+1 ) the perturbation. Each unit of stock contributes dFdx(xt+1 units of growth. To o¤set the direct e¤ect of the unit of increased harvest in period t, the owner must reduce harvest in period t + 1 by one unit; in addition, the owner must t+1 ) reduce harvest in period t + 1 by dFdx(xt+1 to make up for the reduced growth in period t + 1. The term the savings example. dF (xt+1 ) dxt+1 corresponds to the interest payment in C Each unit of reduced harvest in period t+1 reduces pro…ts by pt+1 xt+1 . Therefore, the reduction in period-t + 1 pro…ts, caused by the reduced t + 1 294 CHAPTER 16. THE SOLE-OWNER FISHERY harvest, is pt+1 C xt+1 1+ dF (xt+1 ) dxt+1 ; which equals the …rst term in square brackets in equation 16.4. The higher harvest in period t also reduces period t + 1 pro…ts via a cost C yt+1 . e¤ect. Harvest costs under the candidate, in period t + 1, equal xt+1 The lower t + 1 stock, caused by the period-t perturbation, leads to increased harvest cost of C @ xt+1 yt+1 C = 2 yt+1 ; @xt+1 xt+1 which equals the second term in square brackets in equation 16.4. The present value cost, at time t, of the additional marginal harvest at time t equals the right side of equation 16.4. 16.1.2 Rent We write the Euler equations, for the two types of harvest costs, using rent, providing a more concise expression of the Euler equation. As in the nonrenewable resource setting, we de…ne rent as the di¤erence between price and marginal cost. For our example (but not in general), marginal cost equals average cost, so rent equals pro…t per unit of harvest. For the case of stock independent average costs this de…nition is Rt = pt C Using this de…nition, the Euler equation 16.3 in terms of rent is Rt = Rt+1 1 + dF (xt+1 ) dxt+1 : (16.5) For the case of stock dependent harvest costs, the de…nition of rent is Rt = pt C : xt (16.6) Substituting this expression in the Euler equation 16.4 gives Rt = Rt+1 1 + dF (xt+1 ) dxt+1 + C yt+1 : x2t+1 (16.7) 16.2. POLICY 295 The sole owner never sells where price is below average costs, so rent is never negative, and in general (but not always) is positive. The open access …shery eliminates pro…ts, driving rent to zero. Chapter 13.3.2 notes that Individual Transferable Quotas (ITQs) create property rights, making an open access or common property …shery more like a sole owner …shery. The equilibrium annual lease price of an ITQ equals that amount of pro…t a …sher can expect to obtain for the volume of harvest covered by the quota licence. The lease price thus provides an estimate of the rent associated with that volume of …sh. Most lease prices range from 50% to 80% of the ex vessel …sh price (the price …shers receive). Rent accounts for a substantial fraction of the value of …sheries with strong property rights. 16.2 Policy Objectives and skills: Understand why the optimal stock-dependent tax under open access equals the rent for the agent who harvests at the …rst best level. In the absence of externalities, the First Fundamental Welfare Theorem implies that the price-taking sole owner harvests e¢ ciently, so there is no role for policy. However, the sole owner outcome provides information on the tax that induces open access …shers to harvest e¢ ciently. Market failures can occur even under the sole owner. For example, the biomass creates ecological services if the …sh being harvested are important to some other …sh stock, or to the marine ecology more generally. If the …shery owner does not receive compensation for these services, then they are “external”to her decision problem. The owner’s failure to internalize these bene…ts results in excessive harvest that drives the stock to too low a level, resulting in under-provision of the ecological services. Here there is a role for regulation even under the sole owner, and under open access, there are two market failures. Weak property rights and the ecological externality both cause excessive harvest. A particular unit tax induces the open access …shery to harvest at the socially optimal level. This tax equals the rent in the optimally managed …shery. Absent externalities, the sole owner harvests at the optimal level, so the tax equals the rent under this …shery. If there is an externality, then the optimal tax equals the rent under the sole owner who is induced to 296 CHAPTER 16. THE SOLE-OWNER FISHERY take the externalities into account. In both cases, the optimal tax induces open access …shers to “internalize the externalities” associated with their harvest decisions, in much the same way as the Pigouvian tax from Chapter 11 induces …rms to internalize the cost of their pollution. 16.2.1 Optimal policy under a single market failure Here we assume that there are no externalities under the sole owner, so that owner harvests e¢ ciently. Under open access, there is a single market failure, arising from the absence of property rights to the …sh stock. Our goal is to …nd a stock-dependent unit tax, a function (x), that induces open-access …shers to harvest e¢ ciently. If open access …shers face the tax (x), they harvest up to the point where their tax-inclusive pro…ts equal zero. The equilibrium condition for these …shers sets price minus average harvest costs minus the unit tax equal to zero: p (yt ) C xt (xt ) = 0: (16.8) The period t price depends on harvest in that period, although individual …shers take the price as given. Comparing equations 16.6 and 16.8, we see that for all values of the stock, xt , the levels of the price, and thus the level of the harvest, are the same under the sole owner and under the open access with-tax, if and only if the tax is set equal to the sole owner’s rent: (xt ) = Rt : (16.9) Figure 16.1 illustrates the stock-dependent tax. The …gure shows the graphs of p (y) Cx for x = 10 (dashed) and x = 1 (solid). The untaxed open access harvest occurs at p (y) Cx = 0. Harvest is y = 2 when x = 1 (where the stock is low and harvest costs are relatively high) and y = 4:7 when x = 10 (where the stock is high and harvest costs are relatively low). Under the sole owner, rent is positive at both stock levels, but the rent falls with the stock (see below). The example in the …gure uses the assumptions R (1) = 1:5 and R (10) = 1, illustrating that the rent is lower when the stock is higher. The dotted curves show the graphs of p (y) Cx R (x) for the two values of x, illustrating that the sole owner harvests less than under open access. For this example, the e¢ ciency-inducing tax is = 1:5 at x = 1, and the tax is = 1 at x = 10: lower stocks require higher taxes. 16.2. POLICY 297 $ 8 6 4 2 0 1 -2 2 3 4 5 harvest -4 -6 Figure 16.1: p (y) Cx for x = 10 (dashed) and x = 1 (solid). Dotted lines show the graph of p (y) Cx R (x) for these two stock levels. In this example, R (10) = 1 < 1:5 = R (1) : Implementing the tax Equation 16.9 de…nes the optimal tax under open access. The di¢ culty of implementing this tax is that in the real world we do not have two …sheries that are identical, except that one operates under open access the other under the sole owner. The policy problem arises under open access, where we do not observe the sole owner’s rent. We therefore have to estimate what the rent would be under the sole owner. We have the de…nition of the sole owner’s rent: price minus marginal cost. However, rent in a period depends on price, which depends on harvest, which in general depends on the stock. (A …shery owner with a large stock is likely to harvest at a di¤erent level than an owner with a small stock.) Denote the sole owner’s harvest rule as y = Y (x). Given the parameters of the growth function, inverse demand function, and cost function, and the discount factor, numerical methods enable us to approximate the sole owner’s harvest rule. Given the approximation of this harvest rule, we can approximate the sole owner’s rent as R (x) = p (Y (x)) C (= price minus marginal cost). x Approximating the harvest rule, Y (x), requires the application of numerical methods that are beyond the scope of this book. However, the most di¢ cult part of the problem is …nding reliable estimates of the parameters of the cost and growth function, and estimates of the stock of the …sh. 298 CHAPTER 16. THE SOLE-OWNER FISHERY 16.2.2 Optimal policy under two market failures Suppose now that the stock of …sh provides an ecological service, with the non-market value V (xt ). This value is external to …shers: they ignore it in choosing harvest. There is a market failure even under the sole owner. Therefore, under open access there are two market failures: the lack of property rights and the externality due to ecological services. To …nd the optimal tax for the open access …shery, we need to …nd the sole owner’s rent in the case where she does receive the value of the ecological services. For example, if the sole owner were given a payment V (xt ) in each period, then her goals are perfectly aligned with those of the social planner. The objective and constraints of the sole owner who receives this payment is i P1 t h C y + V (x ) p t t t t=0 xt (16.10) subject to xt+1 = xt + F (xt ) yt : Comparing the maximand in the …rst line of equations 16.2 and 16.10, we see that they are identical, apart from the addition of the lump-sum subsidy V (xt ) in the latter. We can repeat the steps used to obtain the Euler equation 16.4, to obtain the Euler equation for the slightly more complicated case here, and then rewrite that equation using the de…nition of rent to obtain Rt = Rt+1 1 + dF (xt+1 ) dxt+1 + dV (xt+1 ) C yt+1 + : 2 xt+1 dxt+1 (16.11) The left sides of equations 16.7 and 16.11, showing the marginal bene…t of harvesting one more unit in period t, are the same. The right sides, showing the marginal next-period cost of this perturbation, di¤er only by the presence t+1 ) of the term dVdx(xt+1 , the change in the lump-sum subsidy due to the reduced stock. Again, given a particular inverse demand function, p (y) ; and function V (x), and parameters of the cost function, one can numerically approxi~ (x) instead of R (x) to mate the rent function; we denote this function as R recognize that the presence of the function V (x) alters the solution to the problem. Using the same reasoning as in Chapter 16.2.1, the optimal tax ~ (x). for the open access …shery is (x) = R In summary, the optimal tax for the open access …shery equals the rent (a function of the stock of …sh) in the scenario with no market failures. If 16.2. POLICY 299 the only market failure under open access is the lack of property rights, we “merely”have to …nd the rent function, R (x), under the sole owner. If there is an additional market failure, e.g. arising from ecological services that are external to the resource owner, then we have to …nd the rent function that would arise if the sole owner were induced to internalize the externality. 16.2.3 The rent falls as the stock increases We can interpret the rent on the resource as a shadow value: the amount that the resource owner would pay for a marginal increase in the stock (Chapter 5.3). Larger stocks decrease the sole owner’s rent for three reasons:2 (i) A higher stock decreases harvest cost, but it does so at a decreasing rate. A unit increase in the stock decreases harvest cost; a second unit increase in the stock leads to an additional, but smaller decrease in the harvest cost. (ii) Discounting reduces the value of future harvests. An additional unit of the stock is harvested further in the future, the greater is the current stock. Thus, the marginal value of an added unit of the stock is smaller, the larger is the stock, because the additional unit will be used in the more distant future. (iii) Even though the sole owner takes prices as exogenous, they are endogenous unless the industry faces a perfectly elastic demand function. When the demand function is downward sloping, the additional harvest arising from the higher stock receives a lower market price. The marginal value of the additional stock therefore falls as the stock increases. In summary, the optimal tax for the open access …shery equals the shadow price of the stock in the absence of market failures. This shadow price falls with the stock, so the optimal tax also falls with the stock, as Figure 16.1 illustrates. 16.2.4 Empirical challenges Managers are unable to observe the growth function or the cost function, or the biological stock on which they depend. Without estimates of these functions and the stock, the management tools described above cannot be 2 Like most categorical statements in economics, the assertion that rent falls as the stock increases, relies on “reasonable”(or at least commonly made) assumptions. The model here assumes a concave (e.g. logistic) growth function. If the growth function has regions of convexity, where a small increase in the stock leads to a rapid increase in growth, the rent might increase over some ranges of the stock. 300 CHAPTER 16. THE SOLE-OWNER FISHERY directly used (although they might nevertheless provide insight). Here we discuss two approaches to estimating these ingredients. The …rst approach relies on catch and e¤ort data and simple models; the second approach uses much more data and more complicated models. To explain the …rst approach, consider the case where (as is true in some …sheries) we have “panel data”of e¤ort and catch for many boats for many years. The e¤ort data consists of characteristics of the boats and expenditures; here, “e¤ort” is not a single number. In a particular year, all of the boats confront (approximately) the same level of the stock. Using this fact and the panel data, we can estimate parameters relating harvest to the effort characteristics, and also estimate a “stock index”.3 This index involves both the physical stock and economic parameters; we cannot separate these, so we have a stock index, instead of an estimate of the actual stock. This entanglement does not matter for the purpose of estimating the parameters of the growth function. The second approach is more complicated and requires more data, but permits the estimation of more complex models involving di¤erent species and di¤erent age or size categories within a species. Scientists collect samples by dragging nets across …shing areas. By counting rings in the bones (e.g. in the ear canal or the jaw), they estimate the age of individuals in the sample in much the same way that counting rings of tree identi…es the tree’s age. Estimation relies on a dynamic model and a measurement model. The dynamic model consists of a system of equations that describe the evolution of the stock(s) and age classes. Taking as given the equations’ functional form, the goal is to estimate the parameters of the functions. In the simplest case, with a single stock variable, scientists might assume the logistic growth function, and then estimate the two parameters of that function, the natural growth rate and the carrying capacity. Actual applications tend to be much more complicated. The measurement model relates the underlying but unobservable variables of interest (e.g. stock size for di¤erent ages) to the measured variables (e.g. age estimates of the sample). Estimation of the unknown parameters and unknown stocks uses an iterative procedure. Beginning with a guess of the unknown values, we can calculate what the measurements would have been, had the guess been cor3 An “index” is a measurement related to the object of interest (here, the stock), not the object itself. For example, the economy-wide price level is a theoretical construction, not an observable price. We use the consumer price index to measure this price level, and then to measure in‡ation. 16.3. THE STEADY STATE 301 rect. Of course, the guess is not correct, so the calculated values di¤er from the observed measurements. We then change our guess (using sophisticated numerical methods) of the unknown values, in an e¤ort to make the calculated values closer to the observed measurements. We stop the iteration when we decide that it is not possible to get a closer …t between the calculated values and the observed measures. The …nal stage of the iteration yields estimates of the parameters and stock variables. 16.3 The steady state Objectives and skills: Ability to obtain and to analyze the steady state under the sole owner. Ability to compare steady states under the sole owner and under open access. Comparison of the sole owner and the open access steady states tells us something about the relation between property rights and equilibrium outcomes. For the examples in Chapter 15, we obtained the harvest rule under open access by solving the zero-pro…t condition, price = average cost. There, we could determine which of the steady states is stable, and also determine the relation between the initial condition and the steady state to which the stock converges. Matters are more complicated in the sole owner setting. Here, we only have an optimality condition (the Euler equation), not an explicit harvest rule. In this section, we only identify the sole owner steady states, and compare these to the open access steady states. The next chapter compares the harvest rules in the two cases. Without these harvest rules (or at least some information about them), we do not know whether a particular steady state is stable. At a steady state, the harvest, the stock, and the rent are unchanging over time. We drop the time subscripts to denote the fact that these variables are constant in the steady state. The equation of motion of the stock is xt+1 xt = F (xt ) yt . In the steady state, the left side of this equation is zero; dropping the time subscripts, we write this equation, evaluated at the steady state, as 0 = F (x) y. We write the de…nition of the steady state . rent as R = p(y) @c(x;y) @y 302 CHAPTER 16. THE SOLE-OWNER FISHERY We obtain a third equation by evaluating the Euler equation at a steady state. This equation, unlike the previous two, depends on the cost function. We then have three equations in three unknowns, the steady state stock, harvest, and rent. We can solve these three equations to determine the steady state values. We …rst consider the case of constant average extraction costs, and then the case of stock dependent average extraction costs. 16.3.1 Harvest costs independent of stock We begin by evaluating equation 16.5 at a steady state (mechanically, dropping the time subscripts), to obtain R= R 1+ dF (x) dx : 1 Using = 1+r , we multiply both sides of the equation by 1 + r and cancel terms, to write dF (x) 0=R r : (16.12) dx Equation 16.12 implies that at a steady state either R = 0 or r= dF (x) : dx (16.13) Equation 16.13 states at an interior steady state with R > 0, the sole owner is indi¤erent between two investment opportunities, because they both earn the same return. The owner can marginally increase current harvest, and invest the additional pro…t in an asset that earns the annual return r, or she can keep the extra unit of stock in the …shery, where it contributes to growth, thus contributing to future harvests and future pro…ts. At an interior optimum, the owner is indi¤erent between these two investment opportunities. The solution to equation 16.13 depends only on the discount rate and the growth rate of the stock, not on demand or cost. However, the rent depends on demand (via price) and costs. We can solve equation 16.13 to …nd the steady state “candidate”and then check to determine whether R 0; if this inequality holds, then we have identi…ed an interior steady state. However, if R < 0, the solution to equation 16.13 has no signi…cance. 16.3. THE STEADY STATE y 303 0.6 0.5 e d 0.4 C=0.4 c b C=1.25 0.3 f 0.2 a C=3 0.1 0.0 0 10 20 30 40 50 x x Figure 16.2: For F = 0:04x 1 50 and r = 0:02 one candidate for a steady state under the sole owner is point d, where x = 12:5 and y = :375. For inverse demand = 5 10y, open access steady states (where rent and growth are both zero) are points e and c for C = 0:4, points b and d for C = 1:25, and points f and a for C = 3. These points are also steady states under the sole owner. We illustrate this procedure using the logistic growth function, F (x) = . Substituting this expression into the x 1 Kx , where dFdx(x) = 1 2x K right side of equation 16.13, and solving for x, we obtain the candidate steady state stock K r K (16.14) 1 < : x1 = 2 2 Recall that K2 is the stock level that maximizes growth, i.e. leads to Maximum Sustainable Yield (MSY). Equation 16.14 notes that the candidate steady state is less than K2 , so harvest is less than MSY. The equality also shows that the candidate steady state decreases in r : a higher discount rate (greater impatience) lowers the candidate, and faster growth increases the candidate. Two conditions must hold in order for the solution to equation 16.13 to be an interior steady state: (i)The solution must be positive: x1 > 0; and (ii)R (y1 ) 0: (16.15) First, we determine whether x1 > 0. If < r, the value of x1 given by equation 16.14 is negative, an obvious impossibility. Thus, for < r, there is no interior steady state with positive rent. (There might still be interior 304 CHAPTER 16. THE SOLE-OWNER FISHERY steady states with zero rent.) If > r, then x1 > 0: the candidate passes the …rst of the two tests in equation 16.15. For > r we next check whether rent is non-negative at x1 . At this steady state, harvest is y1 = F (x1 ), and the formula for rent is p (y1 ) C. If p (y1 ) C 0, then our candidate x1 passes the second of the two tests in equation 16.15, and is a steady state for the sole owner. If p (y1 ) C < 0, then x1 has no signi…cance. x and r = 0:02. Pursuing the logistic example, let F (x) = 0:04x 1 50 Because = 0:04 > r for this example, x1 , given by equation 16.13, is positive: x1 = 12:5 and y1 = :375. Figure 16.2 identi…es this solution as the tangency, point d, between the graph of the growth function and the line with slope r = 0:02. For this example, x1 > 0, i.e. the candidate passes the …rst test. To check whether it passes the second test, we use the inverse demand function p (y) = 5 10y. Given the choke price 5, the …sh has value if and only if C < 5, as we hereafter assume. Rent, evaluated at the candidate steady state, point d, is R = 5 10(:375) C. The second test, R 0, requires C 1:25. Figure 16.2 shows three horizontal lines, values of harvest where R = 5 10y C = 0 (y = 510C ), for three values of C. These horizontal lines show the harvest rule under open access. From Chapter 15.1 we know that under open access (provided that C is less than the choke price, here 5), there are three steady states: 0, an intermediate steady state (e; f; d for the three values of C) and a high steady state (c; b; a for the three cases). In addition, we know that under open access the high steady state and x = 0 are stable steady states, and the intermediate steady state is unstable. Now consider the steady states under the sole owner. The open access high steady states, (c; b; a) also satisfy the sole owner steady state conditions. At these points: (i) y = F (x), so the stock is unchanging, (ii) R = 0, so the steady state Euler equation 16.12 is satis…ed, and (iii) the de…nition of rent is also satis…ed. Exactly the same reasoning holds at the open access intermediate steady states, and at x = 0. Thus, for this problem, all of the steady states under open access are also steady states under the sole owner. If C 1:25, then the two tests in equation 16.15 are satis…ed, so point d is also a steady state under the sole owner. If C > 1:25, d is not a steady state under the sole owner. Under open access, d is not a steady state except in the knife-edge case C = 1:25. In summary, every point that is a steady state under open access is also a steady state under the sole owner. At all of these points, rent (or harvest) 16.3. THE STEADY STATE 305 is zero. For su¢ ciently low costs (C < 1:25 in our example) there is an additional steady state under the sole owner, that does not exist under open access. At that steady state, the sole owner has positive rent. The next chapter turns to the question of determining which of the sole owner steady states is stable. 16.3.2 Harvest costs depend on the stock Now we turn to the case where harvest costs depend on the stock. The main insights from this material are: For low harvest costs (small C) the sole owner steady state (with positive rent) is lower than the stock that maximizes steady state yield; for large harvest costs, the steady state is above the stock corresponding to maximum steady state yield. Higher harvest costs might either increase or decrease the owner’s steady state rent, and the steady state consumer surplus. We use equation 16.7 to write the steady state condition for rent (merely by dropping the time subscripts): R= R 1+ We simplify this equation using cancelling terms, to write r = dF (x) dx 1 , 1+r dF (x) dx + C y : x2 multiplying both sides by 1 + r and R= C y: x2 We collect the steady state conditions in F (x) y = 0, r dF (x) dx R C y = 0, and R = p (y) x2 C x (16.16) The …rst two equations repeat the steady state conditions for the stock and the rent, and the third equation repeats the de…nition of rent. System 16.16 comprises three equations in three unknowns, x; y; and R. All three equations must hold if x > 0, i.e. at an interior solution. Figure 306 CHAPTER 16. THE SOLE-OWNER FISHERY y 0.5 0 0.4 20 0.3 100 0.2 200 0.1 300 0.0 0 10 20 30 40 50 x Figure 16.3: Graphs of F and the steady state condition for rent, the upward sloping curves. Each of those curves correspond to a value of C, shown next to the curve. The sole owner steady state (with positive pro…ts) occurs at the intersection of the curves. An increase in C increases the point of intersection. 16.3 shows the graph of the growth function and the graphs of the steady state Euler equation (the upward sloping curves) corresponding to di¤erent x and r = values of C. (The …gure uses p = 10 y, F = 0:04x 1 50 0:02.) At all points on the growth function, harvest equals growth: the …rst equation in system 16.16 is satis…ed. At all points on an upward sloping curve (corresponding to a particular value of C), the second two equations in the system are are satis…ed. Thus, satisfaction of all three equations occurs (only) at a point of intersection. That intersection is the sole owner steady state (with positive pro…ts).4 The …gure shows that an increase in C causes the graph of the steady state Euler equation to shift to the right, increasing the point of intersection: larger values of the cost parameter lead to larger steady states under the sole owner. At a given level of the stock, a larger C means that costs are higher, discouraging harvest. As the harvest falls (for a given level of stock), the steady state stock rises. 4 Figure 16.3 and Table 16.1 show only the sole owner steady state with positive rent. For small values of C there is a second (stable) steady state where rent is zero, just as in the constant cost model. For large initial stocks, the stock is not a scarce resource, and the trajectory converges to a high steady state with zero rent. 16.3. THE STEADY STATE 307 Figure 16.3 shows that the sole owner steady state might lie either to the left or the right of the MSY stock level. Recall that harvest under the sole owner (absent other market failures) is e¢ cient. This example demonstrates that it might be socially optimal to maintain a stock either above or below the MSY stock level. Discounting gives the sole owner (and the social planner) an incentive to harvest earlier rather than later. This incentive decreases the steady state stock. When harvest costs are sensitive to the level of the stock, the sole owner (and the social planner) has an incentive to build up the stock, in order to decrease future harvest costs. This incentive increases the steady state stock. When costs are insensitive to the stock (e.g. C = 0 or C = 20) the second incentive is small or vanishes, leaving only the discounting incentive. Thus, for small C the steady state is below the stock corresponding to MSY. When costs are sensitive to the stock, as with C = 300, the second incentive dominates the …rst, leading to a stock above the MSY. At the steady state, harvest equals growth. Moving from left to right along the growth function, we see that steady state harvest increases when the stock is below the MSY level (x = 25), and harvest decreases when the stock is above that level. Because the stock increases in C, and harvest is nonmonotonic in the stock, there is a nonmontonic relation between C and the steady state harvest. Table 16.1 shows sole owner (superscript “so”) steady state values of the stock, harvest, and rent, under three values of the cost parameter, C. The last two columns of the table show the open access (superscript “oa”) steady state stock and harvest for those values of C. so so oa C xso y1 R1 xoa y1 1 1 0 12:5 0:38 9: 6 0 0 50 18:6 0:47 1:7 5:1 0:18 300 38:2 0:36 1:8 31:47 0:47 Table 16.1 Steady state stock, harvest, and rent for the sole owner, and stock and harvest under open access. Price falls and consumer welfare increases as harvests increase, so an increase in C might make consumers either better or worse o¤ in the steady state. In the static competitive setting, in contrast, higher costs shift the equilibrium supply function in and up, leading to a higher equilibrium price and lower consumer surplus. Why do higher costs have di¤erent e¤ects in the (steady state) …shery, compared to the static market? The answer 308 CHAPTER 16. THE SOLE-OWNER FISHERY rests on two facts already discussed. First, in the …shery context, a higher C reduces the incentive to harvest, leading to a higher steady state stock . Second, the steady state harvest is nonmonotonic in the stock. Steady state rent is also non-monotonic in the cost parameter. At a very high cost (C = 300) harvest is quite low and the price correspondingly high, tending to increase rent. Marginal costs, Cx , are also high, tending to reduce the rent. The net e¤ect of a larger C could be to increase or decrease rent, as Table 16.1 illustrates. 16.3.3 Empirical evidence The sole owner (and thus the socially optimal) steady state can be below or above the MSY stock level. The ordering depends on extraction costs, the growth function, and the discount rate. The ordering is therefore a di¢ cult empirical question, because it depends on functions that we can measure imprecisely, at best. A 2007 study of four …sheries, including slow-growing long-lived orange roughy, …nds that the socially optimal stock level exceeds the MSY stock level. Therefore, the steady state harvest is below the MSY. The fact that the study includes a slow-growing …sh is important. Chapter 16.3.1 notes that a low growth rate reduces the optimal steady state stock, and possibly leads to extinction. Because other considerations (e.g. strongly stock-dependent harvest costs) cause the steady state to increase, the optimal steady state depends on a balance of con‡icting forces. A 2013 study for a di¤erent …sh stock, North Paci…c albacore, concludes that the optimal steady state lies to the left of the level corresponding to MSY. This study emphasizes the role of cost-reducing technology improvements. As Figure 16.3 illustrates, lower harvest costs (smaller C) reduce the sole owner steady state. There are important di¤erences across …sheries, regarding both growth functions and harvest costs. As noted in Chapter 16.2.4, there are also di¤erent ways to estimate the parameters of these functions. Models also di¤er in important features, e.g. whether they treat technology as …xed. In view of these di¤erences, it is not surprising that studies disagree on the ordering of optimal stock and MSY stock. Most actual management practices try to keep the stock at the level of MSY. There is a plausible and a dubious argument in favor of this practice. The plausible argument is that, lacking a strong a priori basis for thinking 16.3. THE STEADY STATE y 309 0.5 20 100 0.4 0 0.3 0.2 200 300 0.1 0.0 0 10 20 30 40 50 x Figure 16.4: Graphs of F and the steady state condition for rent, the upward sloping curves. Same parameter values as in Figure 16.3 except that here r = 0: that the stock should be to the right or the left of this level, and in view of the measurement di¢ culties, the MSY level is “neutral”. The dubious argument, based on intergenerational ethics, is that a positive discount rate is unfair to future generation, because it gives them less weight in the social welfare function. Even it one accepts this view of ethics, it does not imply, in general, that the ethically optimal steady state occurs at MSY. The MSY maximizes consumer surplus, but when harvest cost depends on the stock it does not maximize social welfare, the sum of consumer and producer surplus. With stock dependent costs, low discount rates require a higher steady state stock in order to take advantage of cost reductions. Because these stocks occur to the right of the MSY level, they correspond to lower harvests and lower consumer surplus, but higher producer surplus, and a higher social surplus. Figure 16.4 illustrates this claim, reproducing the graphs in Figure 16.3, but replacing r = 0:02 (a 2% per annum discount rate) with r = 0. For stock-independent costs (C = 0), the optimal steady state (for r = 0) occurs at the MSY. However, if harvest costs depend on the stock, the optimal steady state stock always lies to right of the MSY. For any value of C (including C = 0), a decrease in the discount rate causes the upward sloping curves in the …gures to shift to the right, leading to a higher steady state stock. 310 16.4 CHAPTER 16. THE SOLE-OWNER FISHERY Summary We derived and interpreted the Euler equation for the price-taking sole-owner …shery, emphasizing the di¤erence between the renewable and nonrenewable resources. We have to consider growth with a renewable resource, but not with a nonrenewable resource. The sole owner internalizes the e¤ect of her current harvest decisions on future stocks. Absent externalities, the First Fundamental Welfare Theorem implies that the outcome under the sole owner is e¢ cient. In that case, there is no e¢ ciency rationale for regulation. Moving from open access to the sole owner solves the only market failure. If it is not possible or politically desirable to privatize an open access …shery (thus moving to the sole-owner scenario), the open access …shery can be induced to harvest e¢ ciently by charging a tax per unit of harvest. The optimal tax equals the rent under the sole owner. We also considered the case where the stock of …sh provides ecological services that are external to the sole owner. A subsidy or a tax can induce the sole owner to internalize that externality, in which case the sole owner again harvests e¢ ciently. A tax equal to the sole owner’s rent, when that owner harvests e¢ ciently, induces the open access …shery to harvest e¢ ciently. Because this e¢ ciency-inducing tax varies with the stock of …sh, a constant tax is not …rst best. For the nonrenewable resource, extraction eventually ceases as the resource is exhausted. For the renewable resource, the sole owner might drive the stock to an interior (i.e. positive) steady state, where harvest and the stock remain constant forever; or the owner might drive the …shery to extinction. A model with constant (stock-independent) average harvest costs illustrates these possibilities. Here, if the intrinsic growth rate is less than the rate of interest ( < r), there is no interior steady state with positive rent: either the owner drives the stock to extinction, or she maintains the stock at a positive level with zero rent. If the intrinsic growth rate exceeds the rate of interest ( > r), there is a candidate interior steady state at which the actual growth rate equals the rate of interest. This candidate is a steady state for the sole owner if and only if rent is greater than or equal to zero there. In this case, the owner does not drive the stock to extinction. There is typically another interior steady state at which rent is zero. Stock dependent harvest costs give the sole owner an incentive to restrict harvest in order to let the stock grow, thus reducing future harvest costs. Thus, stock dependence tends to increase the sole owner steady state, while discounting tends to decrease it. The sole owner steady state might lie 16.5. TERMS, STUDY QUESTIONS, AND EXERCISES 311 above or below the MSY stock level. Lower discount rates increase the sole owner steady state. In the limiting case with zero discounting, the sole owner steady state equals the MSY level when harvest costs do not depend on stocks; with stock dependent harvest costs, that steady state is above the MSY stock level. 16.5 Terms, study questions, and exercises Terms and concepts stock-dependent e¢ ciency-inducing tax, ecological services Study questions 1. Given a growth function F (x), a cost function c (x; y) and discount factor write down the sole owner’s objective function and constraints. Without doing calculations, describe the steps needed to obtain the Euler equation in this model. 2. If you are given the Euler equation for a particular model (with or without stock dependent harvest costs) you should be prepared to provide an economic interpretation of this equation. 3. (a) Consider the case where marginal harvest costs equal average harvest costs. Identify the stock-dependent tax that induces the open access industry to harvest at the same rate as the untaxed sole owner. (Compare the equilibrium conditions under the sole owner (price –marginal costs = rent) and under open access (price - average costs = 0). (b) Suppose instead that harvest costs are convex in harvest (so that marginal costs exceed average costs). In order to induce the open access …shery to harvest at the same level as the untaxed sole owner, would you have to increase or decrease the tax you identi…ed in part (a)? Explain. 4. For the model with constant (stock independent) average harvest costs, C, and logistic growth F (x) = x 1 Kx , the Euler equation evaluated at the steady state is 0 = R r dFdx(x) . (a) What is the de…nition of steady state rent? (b) Under what conditions is there an 312 CHAPTER 16. THE SOLE-OWNER FISHERY interior steady state with positive rent? Explain. (c) If the conditions in part (b) are not satis…ed, are there other interior steady states? If so, describe these. 5. Consider the following two claims “(i) An open access …shery leads to excessive harvest. (ii) It is never socially optimal to exhaust the stock.” Discuss these two claims in light of the model described in Question 4. State whether you agree or disagree with these claims and justify your answer. Exercises 1. (a) Derive the Euler equation for the sole owner price-taking …shery when average costs are constant, independent of the stock. (b) Provide an intuitive explanation for this equation. (Students can answer this question by mimicking the derivation and the explanation in the text, making changes to re‡ect the di¤erent cost function here.) 2. Write down and interpret the Euler equation for the monopoly owner of a renewable resource facing inverse demand p (y) and constant average harvest costs, Cy. (Hint: use the same methods that we applied to the nonrenewable resource problem.) 3. Provide the economic intuition for the Euler equation 16.11. This equation corresponds to the scenario where the stock provides ecological services V (xt ), and the sole owner receives a subsidy equal to V (xt ); that subsidy internalizes the externality. You need to understand the intuition for the simpler case (where V is absent) and then explain why the presence of payment for the ecological services changes the optimality condition. 4. Show that, provided that F (x) is concave, an interior steady state in the case where costs do not depend on the stock, always lies below the maximum sustainable yield. 5. Consider the model with constant harvest costs C and logistic growth F (x) = x 1 Kx . Suppose that < r. Are there circumstances where the sole owner drives the stock to a positive steady state? Explain and justify your answer. (Hint: Is there any reason to suppose that rent is positive in this model?) 16.5. TERMS, STUDY QUESTIONS, AND EXERCISES 313 6. Using equation 16.14 for the case of stock-independent harvest costs with logistic growth, verify that if > r, then a larger value of K or or a smaller value of r, all increase the interior steady state. Provide an economic (not mathematical) explanation for these results. You need to explain how changes in these parameters changes the owner’s incentive to conserve the …sh. Think about how an increase in r changes the current valuation of future rents. Think about how increases in K or alter the value of a larger …sh stock. Sources Homans and Wilen (2005) provide the estimate of the annual lease prices for …shing quotas, as a percent of ex vessel price of catch. Fenechel and Abbott (2014) show how estimates of stock dynamics and the production function can be used to estimate the gain from better management of …sh stocks. Zhang and Smith (2011) describe and implement, for Gulf Coast reef …sh, the …rst estimation approach discussed in Chapter 16.2.4. http://www.nmfs.noaa.gov/stories/2012/05/05_23_12stock_assessment_101_part1.html explains the second estimation approach in Chapter 16.2.4. The International Scienti…c Committee for Tuna (2011) illustrates the second estimation approach, for the case of tuna stocks. Grafton et al. (2007) provide evidence that the socially optimal stock exceeds the MSY stock. Squires and Vestergaard (2013) provide evidence that increases in technical e¢ ciency cause socially optimal steady state stocks to be below the MSY stock. 314 CHAPTER 16. THE SOLE-OWNER FISHERY Chapter 17 Dynamic analysis Objectives Use the necessary conditions for optimality under the sole owner to characterize the equilibrium harvest rule, and the evolution of the …sh stock over time. Skills Use intuition and economic reasoning to analyze the case of constant average harvest costs. Use phase portrait analysis to analyze dynamics under stock dependent harvest cost. Use the comparison of harvest rules under the sole owner and under open access to characterize the e¢ ciency-inducing tax rule for open access. This chapter moves beyond steady state analysis to study the evolution of the …sh stock and harvest under the sole owner. We assume throughout the chapter that the …shery provides no non-market (e.g. ecosystem) services, so there are no market failures under the price taking sole owner. The sole owner and the social planner make the same decisions. We compare the optimally controlled stock with the stock trajectory under open access in order to characterize the optimal tax (a landing fee)under open access. The market failure under open access arises from the lack of property rights. As Chapter 13.3.2 emphasizes, the …rst best remedy in this situation 315 316 CHAPTER 17. DYNAMIC ANALYSIS (usually) involves institutional changes, e.g. the establishment of property rights, not regulation, e.g. a landing fee or a restriction on gear. It is important to keep this point in mind. However, only a small fraction of …sheries are currently managed using property rights-based regulation. It is worth understanding how other types of regulation, such as taxes, can bring the open access …sher closer to the optimally managed sole owner. We emphasize graphical analysis, using a parametric model. This analysis is qualitative, i.e. it provides information about the direction of change and the relation between initial conditions and the ultimate steady state. In one section we use numerical methods to illustrate the complete solution. As Chapter 14.3.1 notes, the dynamics of a discrete time system is complicated because the stock can “jump” across steady states. Without resorting to numerical methods that are beyond the scope of this book, the alternative is to consider the continuous time limit of the discrete state model. That is, we proceed under the assumption that the length of each period is so small that we can replace the (discrete time) di¤erence equations with (continuous time) di¤erential equations. We use the continuous time system for analysis. We consider two scenarios. In the …rst, average harvest costs are constant, equal to C. In the second, average extraction costs, Cx , depend on the stock. The …rst scenario makes it possible to obtain results using economic reasoning, without introducing additional mathematical tools. This approach is useful for intuition, but it disguises many subtleties, and it does not suggest a method for analyzing more general problems. In addition, the assumption of constant harvest costs is questionable for many resource settings, including most …sheries. The case of stock-dependent costs Cx is simple enough to explain most of the subtleties without a great deal of technical detail, although it does require additional mathematical tools. Those methods are useful for a wide variety of dynamic problems. For both of these scenarios, it is important to keep in mind that the solution to the sole owner’s problem is a “harvest rule”, giving optimal harvest as a function of the stock; typically, we represent a harvest rule by showing its graph. Chapter 14 uses exogenous harvest rules, ones that are not based on theory, and do not emerge from a model. Chapter 15 derives the endogenous harvest rule under open access, by …nding the harvest, a function of the …sh stock, that drives rent to zero. We obtained those rules merely by solving an equation (rent = 0). We denote the endogenous harvest rule for the sole owner’s optimization problem as y(x) (harvest as a function of the stock). In general, we cannot …nd a closed form expression for this function. 17.1. THE CONTINUOUS TIME LIMIT 317 We rely primarily on qualitative, and occasionally on numerical analysis. 17.1 The continuous time limit Objectives and skills Provide an intuitive understanding of the continuous time analog of the discrete time Euler equation. We need one intermediate result: the continuous time version of the discrete time Euler equation. In deriving that equation, we did not specify whether the length of a period is one year or one second. Here we assume that the length of period in the discrete time setting is su¢ ciently small that the continuous time limit provides a reasonable approximation. As in Chapter 14.3, the continuous limit of the discrete time equation of = F (x) y. The missing piece is the continuous motion for the stock is dx dt time analog for the Euler equation. We use equation 16.5 for the case of constant average harvest cost and equation 16.7 for the case of stock dependent cost. The continuous time limit under constant average harvest costs (Appendix J) is dRt = Rt r dt dF (xt ) dxt : (17.1) and the continuous time limit under stock dependent harvest costs is dRt = Rt r dt 17.2 dF (xt ) dxt C yt : x2t (17.2) Harvest rules for stock-independent costs Objectives and skills Characterize the harvest rule for the sole owner with constant harvest costs. Compare this rule with the harvest rule under open access. Use this comparison to characterize the optimal tax under open access. 318 CHAPTER 17. DYNAMIC ANALYSIS y 0.6 0.5 e d 0.4 C=0.4 c b C=1.25 0.3 f 0.2 a C=3 0.1 0.0 0 10 20 30 40 50 x Figure 17.1: Open access and sole owner steady states for F = 0:04x 1 r = 0:02, and p = 5 10y. x 50 , This section uses the example introduced in Chapter 16.3.1, with growth x function F (x) = 0:04x 1 50 , inverse demand p (y) = 5 10y, discount rate r = 0:02, and constant average costs C, the only free parameter in this model. By varying C, we can determine the relation between harvest costs and the sole-owner equilibrium. The Euler equation 17.1 must hold at every point along the sole-owner’s harvest path. We reproduce Figure 16.2, here shown as Figure 17.1. First consider the open-access equilibrium. The horizontal dashed lines in Figure 17.1 are the open-access harvest rules corresponding to three values of C. These (constant) values of y satisfy the zero-pro…t open access condition, 5 10y = C, or y = 510C . Using the analysis in Chapter 15, the points a, b and c are stable interior steady states, and f , d and e are unstable steady states, for the three values of C. The origin, x = 0 is a stable steady state in all three cases. For example, at C = 0:4, the open-access stock approaches point c if the initial stock is greater than the horizontal coordinate of point e; if the initial stock lies below this level, the open-access stock approaches x = 0. The entries in Table 1 show the open access steady state, x1 , corresponding to di¤erent values of C and di¤erent initial conditions, x0 . In writing x1 = a, for example, we mean that x1 equals the horizontal coordinate of point a. 17.2. HARVEST RULES FOR STOCK-INDEPENDENT COSTS 319 x0 above unstable x0 below unstable steady state (e, d or f ) steady state (e, d or f ) C = 0:4 x1 = c x1 = 0 C = 1:25 x1 = b x1 = 0 C=3 x1 = a x1 = 0 Table 1: Open-access steady state, x1 , for di¤erent initial conditions, x0 Now consider the sole-owner equilibrium. As noted above, here we cannot explicitly determine the harvest rule for all values of x. However, we know one important fact about this rule: the sole owner never extracts so much that rent becomes negative. In symbols, y > 0 ) R 0. Based on this information, and some reasoning discussed below, we can identify the steady state that the stock approaches in the sole owner …shery, as a function of the value of C and of the initial conditions x0 . Table 2 summarizes this information, and Section 17.2.2 explains how we obtain it. First, we consider the policy implications of Tables 1 and 2.1 x0 above middle steady state (e, d or f ) C = 0:4 x1 = c C = 1:25 x1 = b C=3 x1 = a Table 2: Sole owner steady state, x1 , for 17.2.1 x0 below middle steady state (e, d or f ) x1 = d x1 = d x1 = f di¤erent initial conditions, x0 : Tax policy implications of Tables 1 and 2 The information in Tables 1 and 2 has direct and simple policy implications. For both open access and the sole owner, the high steady state (a, b, or c, depending on the value of the cost parameter, C) is stable. For su¢ ciently high initial stocks, the stock approaches the same steady state level under both property rights regimes. In contrast, x = 0 is a stable steady state under open access, but not under the sole owner. For su¢ ciently low initial stocks, the open access …shery eventually drives the stock to extinction. Regardless of how small the initial stock is, provided that it is positive, the 1 For C = 1:25 and C = 3, the middle steady states (d and f , respectively) are “semistable”: initial conditions to the left of these points the trajectory converges to the point, and for initial conditions to the right, the trajectory moves away from the point. 320 CHAPTER 17. DYNAMIC ANALYSIS stock recovers to a positive level in the sole owner …shery. This di¤erence is key to understanding the role of tax policy under open access. We say that the initial stock is “large” if it exceeds the middle steady state, points e, d or f (depending on the value of C); thus, the precise meaning of “large” depends on C. For all three values of C, if the initial stock is large, the equilibrium is the same under open access and under the sole owner. In these cases, the stock is large enough that the sole owner’s rent, along the equilibrium trajectory, is 0, exactly as under open access. Here, the resource is not scarce. There is no reason to tax harvest under open access, when the initial stock is large, because open access does not create a market failure in this circumstance. For C = 0:4 or C = 1:25 (and more generally, whenever C 1:25) and x0 “small”(i.e. below the middle steady state), open access drives the stock to extinction. Under the sole owner, the stock approaches (the horizontal coordinate of) point d, i.e. it remains positive. Thus, when harvest is inexpensive (C is small) and the stock is small, it is important to tax harvest (or otherwise the open access …shery) in order to preserve the resource stock. The …rst best tax policy, for small stocks, varies with the level of the stock. We previously noted (Chapter 16.2) that in a resource setting, the optimal tax is typically stock-dependent. We would require numerical methods to compute the optimal tax as a function of the level of the stock, at stocks below the unstable steady state. Optimality might be too much to ask for, but the analysis suggests some second-best alternatives. One alternative (for C 1:25) is to simply close down the open access …shery until the stock recovers to (the horizontal coordinate of) point d, and then maintain a constant tax that supports openaccess harvest at point d. A less extreme alternative uses a high tax to permit recovery of low stocks, reducing the tax as the stock increases. The analysis is a bit di¤erent when C exceeds the critical level 1:25, but is less than 5. (If C 5, the choke price, neither the open access nor the sole owner …shery harvest anything.) Consider the case where C = 3. Here, for initial stocks above the unstable steady state (point f ) the stock approaches a under both open access and under the sole owner. Just as is the case for the lower values of C, the sole owner and the open access …shery harvest at the same rate, and both have zero rent, provided that the initial stock is su¢ ciently high. For stocks below point f , the open access …shery drives the stock to extinction. The sole owner …shery, in contrast, drives the stock to point f (not to point d, where rent would be negative). 17.2. HARVEST RULES FOR STOCK-INDEPENDENT COSTS 321 In summary, for this example, it is important to regulate an open access …shery, e.g. by means of a tax, when the stock is low. There may be no need to regulate the open access …shery if the stock is su¢ ciently high. Taxes can achieve distinct, but related objectives: to alter the steady state to which the open access stock converges, and to alter the speed at which the open access stock declines. In general, at low levels of the stock, the optimal tax for the open access …shery depends on the stock. It might not be practical to use the optimal tax, but second best taxes can insure that the stock approaches the …rst best steady state, even if the approach trajectory does not occur at the optimal speed. 17.2.2 Con…rming Table 2 We provide details for the case C = 0:4, leaving the other two cases as exercises. Our goal is to show that the sole owner’s harvest rule implies the claims in the second row of Table 2. Recall that the harvest rule gives harvest as a function of the stock of …sh. We can describe this rule using a graph, showing harvest as function of the stock. We begin by stating seven facts about the graph of the sole owner’s harvest rule. 1. The graph of the rule lies on or below the dashed line labelled C = 0:4 in Figure 17.1. At any point above that line, rent is negative, i.e. harvest results in negative pro…ts. The sole owner never harvests so much that rent becomes negative. 2. The sole owner’s harvest rule intersects x = 0 = y, where price equals the choke price. If the stock is 0, the harvest must also be 0: you cannot get blood out of a turnip. 3. The harvest rule is continuous. A discontinuous rule would lead to jumps in the price trajectory (as a function of time), violating the “nointertemporal-arbitrage”condition (the Euler equation). 4. Point d is the unique interior steady state with positive rent. Chapter 16.3.1 establishes this claim. 5. At points to the left of d, r < dFdx(x) and at points to the right of d the inequality is reversed. This claim follows from inspection of Figure 17.1. 322 CHAPTER 17. DYNAMIC ANALYSIS 6. Where x is positive and close to 0, the sole owner’s rent is positive. This claim follows from Fact 3: for small x, price is close to the choke price, a, and rent is close to a 0:4 > 0. t 7. For 0 < x < d, dR < 0. This claim uses Facts 1 and 6 to con…rm dt dF (x) that Rt > 0 and r < 0; these two inequalities and equation 17.1 dx dRt establish that dt < 0. We use these facts to characterize the sole owner’s harvest rule over three intervals of the stock: x > e, x < d, and d < x < e. x > e: Here, the sole owner’s harvest rule is identical to the rule under open-access: the graph of that rule equals the highest dashed horizontal line in Figure 17.1 to the right of point e. At this constant level of harvest, the stock approaches point c. Along that trajectory, R = 0, so the Euler equation 17.1 is always satis…ed. For this problem, the necessary conditions for optimality are also su¢ cient, so for x greater than the horizontal coordinate of point e, we have found the sole owner’s harvest rule. x < d: The sole owner’s harvest rule lies below the graph of the growth function for stocks to the left of point d. In order to con…rm this claim, we note that there are only three possibilities for the graph of the harvest rule over this interval: (i) it might intersect the growth function to the left of d; (ii) it might lie strictly above the growth function to the left of d; or (iii) it might lie strictly below the growth function to the left of d. We can exclude possibility (i) because a point of intersection between the harvest rule and the growth function is a steady state at which rent is positive, contradicting Fact 4. Thus, we are left with possibilities (ii) and (iii). We can exclude possibility (ii), because in this scenario, harvest exceeds growth and the stock is falling to 0 over time. As the stock approaches 0, Fact 3 implies that harvest approaches 0, so during this part of the trajectory, harvest is falling and rent (R = a by C) is rising. However, that conclusion contradicts Fact 7, which states that rent is falling. Therefore, we are left with possibility (iii): for stocks to the left of point d, the harvest rule lies below the growth function and the stock is increasing. 17.3. HARVEST RULES FOR STOCK DEPENDENT COSTS 323 d < x < e. By Fact 4, there are no points of intersection between the harvest rule and the growth function over this interval. We can exclude the possibility that the harvest rule lies below the growth function over this interval using an argument that parallels the argument in the previous paragraph. Therefore, over this interval of x, the harvest rule lies above the growth function. Summary Points d and e are steady states, so they are on the sole owner’s harvest rule. We showed above that this rule is below the growth function for x < d and above the growth function for d < x < e. Therefore, we conclude that for 0 < x < e, point d is a stable steady state. We also showed that for x > e, point c is a stable steady state. Thus, we con…rm the claims in the second row of Table 2. 17.3 Harvest rules for stock dependent costs Objectives and skills Ability to interpret a …gure showing graphs of the open access and the sole owner harvest rules. Ability to use this …gure to calculate the e¢ ciency-inducing tax for the sole owner. Introduction to the phase portrait and its ingredients, the isoclines and isosectors. We carry out all of the analysis using the following parametric example c (x; y) = F (x) = x 1 p=a x K C y x with C = 5 with K = 50 and = 0:04 (17.3) by; a = 3:5 and b = 10; and r = 0:03: We begin by summarizing the policy implications based on this example. Subsequent material develops the methods used to obtain those results. There, we explain the meaning and the use of the “phase portrait”, the important new tool in this chapter. We then explain what a “full solution” means in a model of this sort. 324 17.3.1 CHAPTER 17. DYNAMIC ANALYSIS Tax policy Here we explain how to interpret Figure 17.2, and the policy implications that it contains. For the model in equation 17.3, there is a unique steady state under the sole owner, x1 = 39:35, y1 = 0:335. We discuss only the behavior of the …shery for x below the steady state. Figure 17.2 shows the growth function, the heavy solid line, for x 39:35. The dotted line shows the harvest rule under the sole owner for x below the steady state. Most of the work involved with this analysis lies in identifying this harvest rule, i.e. in constructing the dotted graph. For the time being, we put those di¢ culties aside and discuss the meaning of this graph. In this example, where harvest costs depend on the stock of …sh, the owner wants a high stock in order to have low harvest costs. (We do not use the thin solid curve in the discussion here, although it plays an important role in the derivation below.) The dashed line shows the harvest rule under open access, obtained (as always) by setting rent = 0 and solving for harvest as a function of the stock. There are three steady states under open access, the points of intersection between the dashed and the heavy solid curve. The middle point is unstable, and the higher and the lower points of intersection are stable. The low steady state, approximately x = 2, and the high steady state, slightly less than 39:35 (the sole owner steady state), are both stable. The intermediate steady state, approximately equal to x = 8, is unstable. The harvest rule under the sole owner (the dotted curve) lies everywhere below the harvest rule under open access (the dashed curve). The sole owner always harvests less than the open access …shery. For stock levels above approximately x = 20, the open access and the sole owner harvest rules are nearly the same. For this range of stocks, the stock is su¢ ciently large that the sole owner and open access …shery harvest at nearly (but not exactly) the same level. Here, it is not important to regulate the open access …shery. For stocks above the open access unstable steady state (x = 8), harvest under open access is low enough to allow the …sh stock to reach almost the optimal steady state, x = 39:35. For 8 x < 20 there is a slight, but appreciable di¤erence in the two harvest rules. For this range of stocks, there is a minor role for regulation. Regulation allows the …sh stock to recover more quickly, and produces positive rent. However, regulation has no signi…cant long term e¤ect, because the steady states under open access and under the sole owner are almost the same. 17.3. HARVEST RULES FOR STOCK DEPENDENT COSTS y 325 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0.0 0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 x Figure 17.2: A part of the phase portrait, for stocks below the steady state level. The higher solid curve is the x isocline (the growth function) and the lower solid curve is the y isocline. The dashed curve is the set of points where rent = 0. Rent is positive below this curve. The dotted line, sandwiched between the “rent = 0” curve and the y isocline is the optimal trajectory, giving the optimal harvest as a function of the stock. For stocks below the open access unstable steady state, regulation is important under open access. Over this range, the stock declines to x = 2, whereas under the sole owner, the stock eventually recovers to 39.35. Given the two harvest rules, it is a simple matter to determine the optimal tax, for any level of the stock. An example illustrates the procedure. Suppose that x = 7 (an arbitrary choice, merely for illustration). Reading from the harvest rules, we see that the open access harvest is approximately y = 0:29 and the sole owner harvest is approximately y = 0:2, yielding the equilibrium open access price 3:5 10 (0:29) = 0:6 and the equilibrium sole owner price 3:5 10 (0:2) = 1: 5. The tax jx=7 = 1:5 0:6 = 0:9 induces the open access to reduce harvest y = 0:2; at that level, the market price minus the tax equals the average harvest cost, and industry rent is zero. The tax = 0:9 thus supports the e¢ cient level of harvest at x = 7. Because the vertical distance between the two harvest functions changes with the level of the stock, the optimal tax also changes with the stock. The optimal tax is negligible for large stocks, but the tax is large at small stocks. For our example, the optimal tax comprises 60% of the equilibrium consumer price at x = 7. Recalling Chapter 16.2.1, the optimal tax under open access equals 326 CHAPTER 17. DYNAMIC ANALYSIS the rent under the sole owner. Thus, for this example, rent under the sole owner comprises about 60% of the market price when x = 7. The comparison of Figures 17.1 and 17.2 illustrates the e¤ect of stock dependent harvest costs. In both of these models, there are three steady states under open access. The intermediate steady state is unstable, and the other two are stable. The low steady state is zero under constant costs, but positive under our example of stock-dependent harvest cost. With stockdependent harvest costs, the open access …shery drives the stock to a low but positive level, where harvest is expensive, price is high, and consumer surplus low. With stock independent harvest costs, there are either three or four steady states under the sole owner, one of which is x = 0.2 In our stock-dependent harvest cost example, there is a single positive stable steady state, x = 39:35. This steady state exceeds the MSY stock, x = 25. The sole owner (and the social planner) wants to drive the stock above the level that maximizes steady state yield, because doing so reduces harvest costs. The tax implications of the two models are quite similar. In both, it is unimportant to tax the open access …shery at high stock levels. At high stock levels the optimal tax is zero under constant harvest costs, and the optimal tax is close to zero in our example of stock-dependent harvest costs. For high stocks, the optimal tax for the open access …shery reduces harvest and speeds recovery of the stock to a high level, but the tax has negligible long run e¤ect. At low stocks, the tax is important in both models; it avoids physical extinction in one case, and economic irrelevance in the other. 2 For constant cost C = 0:4 there are four sole owner steady states, at x = 0, d, e and c; the steady states 0 and e are unstable, and d and c are stable. For C = 3, there are three steady states, at x = 0, f and a. The steady state 0 is unstable, and a is stable; point f is “semi-stable”: trajectories beginning at positive stocks below this level approach f , but trajectories beginning above it move away, approaching a. 17.3. HARVEST RULES FOR STOCK DEPENDENT COSTS 327 Box 17.1 Back to Huxley and Gould Box 1.1 contains quotes from two 19th century …gures, one explaining why regulation is not needed, and the other explaining why it is needed. The above analysis illustrates the circumstances where one or the other is correct. If stocks are above the unstable open access steady state, the open access outcome is at least approximately socially optimal. Stock dependent costs reinforce this tendency, by inducing …shers to reduce harvest as the stock falls. These forces provide a kind of automatic protection, as Huxley suggested, and there is no need for regulation. However, at low stocks, neither the market (which limits demand) nor technology (which limits supply by increasing costs) is adequate to protect the stock: regulation is needed, as Gould stated. 17.3.2 The phase portrait Equations 14.6 and 17.2 give the di¤erential equations for the stock and for the rent under the sole owner. We can use these two equations, together C , to obtain a third di¤erential with the de…nition of rent, R = p (y) x dy equation, for the harvest, dt . It helps to give this di¤erential equation a name, so we denote it as dy = H (x; y). (Appendix J.2 explains how we dt …nd this function H.) The solution to these three di¤erential equations (in x; R; y) gives the optimal paths of the stock, rent, and harvest. Apart from the simplest problems, we cannot solve these equations analytically. Our …rst goal is to learn as much as possible about the solution without actually solving the equations: we seek qualitative information about the solution. The phase portrait is the key to achieving this. The phase portrait contains two “isoclines”. An isocline is a curve along which the time derivative of a variable is 0. Consider the logistic growth y. Setting this derivative equal to 0 gives = x 1 Kx function, dx dt y = x 1 Kx ; the graph of this function is the x isocline (the curve where dx = 0). Thus, the x isocline is simply the growth function; we are given dt that function as part of the statement of the problem, so no work is required to obtain the x isocline. We can also obtain the y isocline, the curve where dy = H (x; y) = 0. Figure 17.3 shows the graphs of the two isoclines for our dt example. The intersection of these isoclines identi…es the steady state, the point where dx = 0 = dy . For our example, the steady state is x = 39:35, dt dt y = 0:335. In order to understand a phase portrait, the reader has to keep in mind 328 CHAPTER 17. DYNAMIC ANALYSIS y 0.8 0.7 A 0.6 stock constant 0.5 B 0.4 0.3 E 0.2 harvest constant 0.1 D 0.0 0 10 20 30 40 50 x Figure 17.3: The solid curve: the x isocline (where dx = 0; dashed curve: dt dy the y isocline (where dt = 0). The two isoclines divide the plane into four regions, A; B; C and D, known as isosectors. that, outside the steady state, the stock and the harvest are changing over time. Imagine that there is a third axis, labelled time, t, perpendicular to the page, coming directly toward the reader. A point on the page represents a particular value of x and y at t = 0. A point above the page represents a particular value of x and y and a time t > 0. Suppose that we start at t = 0, with some initial condition, x0 = x (0), and we pick some initial harvest, y0 . Starting from this point, there is a path, a curve in three dimensional space, call it (xt ; yt ; t) along which the = F (x) y and dy = H (x; y) are satis…ed. Now di¤erential equations dx dt dt imagine shining a light from your eyes to the page. The curve (xt ; yt ; t), casts a shadow onto the page. We refer to this shadow as a trajectory. The phase portrait provides information about such a trajectory (i.e., the “shadow”); we use that information to infer facts about the behavior of the stock and the harvest over time. To this end, we use the four “isosectors” de…ned by the two isoclines. Figure 17.3 identi…es these four regions as A; B; D; and E. 17.3. HARVEST RULES FOR STOCK DEPENDENT COSTS Isosector motion of x motion of y A decreasing (west) increasing (north) B increasing (east) increasing (north) D increasing (east) decreasing (south) 329 E decreasing (west) decreasing (south) overall motion north-west north-east south-east south-west of trajectory Table 3. Direction of change of x and y and overall direction of motion of trajectory in the four iso-sectors Consider isosectors B and D, the region below the x isocline (the graph of y = F (x)). For any point in either of those two isosectors, y < F (x). = F (x) y > 0, i.e. x is increasing over Consequently at such a point, dx dt time. For shorthand, we say that the trajectory is moving east (x is getting larger). Similarly, above the x isocline, in isosectors A and E, y > F (x), so dx = F (x) y < 0. In these two isosectors, x is getting smaller, so we say dt that the trajectory is moving west. The second row of Table 3 summarizes this information. We can identify the direction of movement in the north-south direction = H (x; y) by using information about the di¤erential equation for y, dy dt (details in Appendix J.2). Below the y isocline (in isosectors D and E) dy = H (x; y) < 0, i.e. y is decreasing, so the trajectory is moving south. dt = H (x; y) > 0, i.e. y is Above the y isocline (in isosectors A and B) dy dt increasing, so the trajectory is moving north. The third row of Table 3 summarizes this information. The fourth row puts together the previous information, to obtain the overall direction of motion of a trajectory in each isosector. This qualitative information tells us that an optimal trajectory that approaches the steady state x1 from a smaller value of x (to the west of x1 ), must lie in isosector B. Similarly, a trajectory that approaches the steady state from a larger value of x (to the east of x1 ) lies in isosector E. To explain and con…rm these statements, we consider the case where the optimal trajectory approaches the steady state from below (i.e. from the west); the situation where the optimal trajectory approaches from above is similar. A trajectory that approaches the steady state from below cannot lie in isosector E, because that isosector contains no stock levels less than the steady state. Therefore, the trajectory must lie in isosectors A; B, or D. The path cannot lie in isosector A, because trajectories there involve westward 330 CHAPTER 17. DYNAMIC ANALYSIS movements, i.e. reductions in the stock. Therefore, the trajectory must lie in either isosector B or D. It cannot lie in D, because from any point in D, it would be necessary for y to increase in order to reach the steady state; but trajectories in D move south, i.e. y falls there. Consequently, trajectories that approach the steady state from below (with stocks lower than the steady state level) do so in isosector E. For this problem, regardless of the initial (positive) stock level, the optimally controlled …shery approaches the steady state. We can use this fact to establish that for any initial stock below the steady state, the optimal trajectory lies entirely in isosector B; and for any initial stock above the steady state, the optimal trajectory lies entirely in isosector E. For example, suppose that we begin with a stock below the steady state level. If, contrary to our claim, the trajectory beginning with this stock lay in either isosector A or D it would move away from the steady state. Figure 17.4 repeats the previous …gure, adding the dotted curve, the set of points where rent is zero. Rent is positive below the dotted curve, where harvest is lower and price is consequently higher than on the curve. We know from above that if the stock begins below the steady state, it approaches the steady state in isosector B, so the trajectory must be above the dashed curve (a boundary to isosector B). We also know that the sole owner never harvests where rent is negative, so the trajectory must be on or below the dotted curve. Therefore, we conclude that if the initial stock is below the steady state, the trajectory must be sandwiched between the dashed and the dotted curves. We obtained this information without actually solving the optimization problem, using only the necessary conditions for optimality and a bit of graphical analysis. This procedure illustrates the power of the phase portrait. Given the resolution of Figure 17.4, it appears that the dotted and the dashed curves are coincident around the steady state. However, if we enlarged the …gure in the neighborhood of the steady state, we would see that the dashed curve lies below the dotted curve, and the steady state lies on the dashed curve. For this example, rent is always positive, but it is close to zero for …sh stocks near the steady state. For di¤erent functional forms or parameter values, rent might be substantial along the optimal trajectory. 17.4. SUMMARY y 331 0.8 0.7 A 0.6 stock constant 0.5 B 0.4 0.3 E 0.2 harvest constant 0.1 D 0.0 0 10 20 30 40 50 x Figure 17.4: The dotted curve shows the combination of harvest and stock at which rent is 0. The full solution Figure 17.2 contains the graph of the sole-owner’s optimal harvest rule (the dotted curve in that …gure). To construct that graph, we need the solution to the pair of di¤erential equations dx = F (x) y and dy = H (x; y) that dt dt includes the point (x1 ; y1 ), the steady state. The steady state is a “boundary condition” for this mathematical problem. As noted above, except for very few functional forms (not including our parametric example), there is no analytic solution to this problem. However, there are numerical routines that are straightforward to implement. The harvest rule shown in Figure 17.2 was obtained using Mupad, a feature of Scienti…cWorkplace. 17.4 Summary Two examples, one with constant harvest costs, and the other with stockdependent harvest costs, show how to analyze the dynamics under the sole owner. We showed how to determine the sole owner steady state(s), and to determine which steady state the sole owner …shery approaches, as a function of the initial condition. With constant harvest costs, this determination requires careful economic reasoning, but no new mathematical tools. With stock-dependent harvest costs, we require new tools. The most important of these is the phase portrait, which has many uses in dynamic problems. Given this information, and using the fact that the open access …shery 332 CHAPTER 17. DYNAMIC ANALYSIS harvests up to the point where rent is zero, we were able to make qualitative statements about the optimal tax for the open access …shery. In particular, we learned that regulating this …shery is important if the stock is low; for su¢ ciently high stocks, regulation of the open access …shery is unimportant. This di¤erence illustrates the general principle that for resource problems, the optimal tax is stock-dependent. In practice, we seldom have enough information to determine the optimal tax. A second best alternative is to close down the open access …shery at low stock, and leave the …shery untaxed at high stocks. A more nuanced policy imposes low or zero taxes at high stocks, and high taxes at low stocks. Examples of this sort are useful for developing intuition. The pedagogic danger of these examples is that they may make the problem of regulation appear too simple. It might appear that all we need is a few parameters estimates and a modest knowledge of mathematics to propose optimal policy measures. That conclusion is too optimistic. The models studied here are good for the big picture, but they are too simple to be directly useful in actual policy environments. There, it may be important to consider multiple species or multiple cohorts of a single species, and di¤erent kinds of uncertainty, including uncertainty about functional forms and parameter values. Nevertheless, simple models provide a good place to begin. 17.5 Terms, study questions, and exercises Terms and concepts Continuous time Euler equation, isocline, phase portrait Study questions 1. Using Figure 17.1, for each of the three values of C, sketch the sole owner’s harvest rule that is consistent with the claims in Table 2. 2. (a) Using your sketch from #1 and C = 3, pick two values of x to the left of point f . At these two points, identify on the graph the di¤erences in harvest under open access and under the sole owner. (b) Explain how you would use this graph to obtain the optimal tax under the sole owner, at these two values of x. (c) What qualitative statement 17.5. TERMS, STUDY QUESTIONS, AND EXERCISES 333 can you make about the magnitude of the optimal taxes for the two values of x? Exercises 1. By adapting the arguments used in Section 17.2.2, con…rm the claims in the last two rows of Table 2. x , inverse demand is p (y) = 5 10y, 2. Suppose that F (x) = 0:04x 1 50 the discount rate is r = 0:02, and harvest costs are constant at C = 0:4. Suppose also that the initial condition, x0 , is below the horizontal coordinate of point e in Figure 17.1. (a) What tax (a number) supports an open access steady state at point d? (b) If the policymaker uses this constant tax, does it drive the stock to point d for all initial conditions below e? (c) For initial conditions below e (i.e., for values of x0 below the horizontal coordinate of point e) does the optimal tax rise or fall with higher x? 3. * For the parametric example in the Exercise 2, suppose that C = 1:25. (a) Con…rm that for initial conditions below the unstable steady state (f ), the sole owner drives the stock to x = 0. (b) Con…rm that along the path to extinction, rent is positive as long as the stock is positive. (c) Using your answer to part (b), sketch the harvest rule under the sole owner. (Your drawing will not be accurate, but you should be able to identify the points on the graph of the harvest rule, y(x), corresponding to x = f and x = 0. (d) Using this sketch, how does the …rst-best (stock-dependent) tax under open access vary with the stock, x? 4. For the model in equation 17.3, use Figure 17.2 to estimate the optimal tax for the open access …shery, at x = 5. Explain your steps. 334 CHAPTER 17. DYNAMIC ANALYSIS Chapter 18 Sustainability (Under construction) 18.1 Concepts of sustainability 18.2 The Hartwick rule 18.3 Discounting and intergenerational equity 18.4 Economics and climate policy 335 336 CHAPTER 18. SUSTAINABILITY (UNDER CONSTRUCTION) Appendices are currently under revision Appendix A Math Review (Revised August 25, 2014) This appendix reviews some concepts and results from basic calculus. It can be used as a reference during the course, and also gives readers an idea of the level of mathematics required for the course. The text assumes that readers have seen much this material before. (x0 ) , is the 1 The derivative of a function, f (x) at a point x0 , written dfdx tangent (“slope”) of a function, evaluated at a particular point, here x0 . If f (x) = a + bx, where a; b are independent of x (and therefore constants for df = b; a constant. our purposes here), then dx More generally, however, the value of the derivative depends on x. Figure A.1 shows the graph of f (x) = 2 + 3x 4x2 5x3 , the solid curve, the graph 2 f (x) (x) of g (x) = dfdx , the dashed curve, and the graph of h (x) = dg(x) = d dx 2 . dx This …gure reminds the reader that, in general, (1) a derivative is a function, not a constant; (2) where a function reaches an extreme point (a maximum or a minimum) the derivative of that function equals 0. If the graph of a function has an in‡exion point, i.e. switches from being concave to convex, the second derivative of the function equals 0 at the in‡exion point. Another way to indicate that a function is being evaluated at a particular point, say x = 2, uses subscripts. For example, the subscript “jx = 2”here indicates that we evaluate the derivative of f with respect to x at x = 2: df (x) = 2 + 3 (2) dx jx=2 It is worth repeating that (in general) we called this function g (x). Similarly, 337 4 (2)2 5 (2)3 : df (x) is itself a function of x; above dx d2 f (x) is a function of x; above we dx2 338 APPENDIX A. MATH REVIEW h(x)=dg/dx 10 f(x) -1.4 -1.2 -1.0 g(x) =df/dx -0.8 -0.6 -0.4 -0.2 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 x -10 -20 Figure A.1: The solid curve shows the graph of f (x), the dashed curve df , and the dotted curve shows the graphof shows the graph of g(x) = dx 2 dg d f h (x) = dx = dx2 . call it h (x). Another way to write the derivative uses the “prime sign”, 0 : df (x) = f 0 (x) : dx 2. In the example above we took the derivative of a function involving an exponent. Students should memorize the following rule: if a is a constant (with respect to x), then d (xa ) = axa 1 : dx We write that “a is a constant with respect to x", instead of merely writing “a is a constant” because the formula above is correct even if a is a function of other variables (not x). For the purpose of taking this derivative, it does not matter whether a is a literally a constant or merely a constant with “respect to x”. What matters is that a change in x does not change a. 3. Students should memorize a few of the primary rules for derivatives. Suppose we have two functions of x, a (x) and b (x). (Note: in the previous line we treated a as a constant. Here we treat it as a function. In general, we are careful not to use the same symbol to mean two di¤erent things. Here, we intentionally use the same symbol, a, to mean two di¤erent things, …rst a 339 constant and then a function. We want to encourage readers to pay attention to de…nitions.) We can form other functions using these two functions. If c is the sum of these two functions, then c (x) = a (x) + b (x) and dc da db = + . dx dx dx The derivative of a sum equals the sum of a derivative. For brevity we write, da for example, dx instead of da(x) . dx If c is the product of the two functions, then c (x) = a (x) b (x) and da db dc = b + a. dx dx dx If c is the quotient of two functions, then c (x) = b da a db dc a (x) and = dx 2 dx . b (x) dx b 4. The chain rule enables us to take the derivative of a function of a function. Suppose that y is a function of x and x is a function of z. Then y is a function of z, via the e¤ect of z on x. The chain rule states dy (x (z)) dx (z) dy = : dz dx dz For example, if y = x0:3 and x = 7z, then dy (x (z)) dx (z) dy = = 0:3x0:3 dz dx dz dy(x) dx 1 = 0:3x0:3 1 7 = 0:3 (7z) and 0:7 dx dz = 7, so 7. 5. Some of our functions involve two arguments, instead of one. Throughout the book we use a cost function that depends on the stock of the resource, x, and the amount that is extracted in a period, y. We write this cost function as c (x; y). A partial derivative tells us how the value of the function (here, costs) changes if we change just one of the variables, either x or y. We use the symbol @ instead of d to indicate that we are interested in the partial derivative. We frequently illustrate concepts using the following speci…c cost function Parametric example: c (x; y) = C ( + x) y 1+ ; 340 APPENDIX A. MATH REVIEW where C; ; ; and are non-negative parameters. (Note that lower case c is a function, and upper case C is a parameter; this use of two similar symbols to mean two di¤erent things is intentional. It is important to pay attention to de…nitions.) The partial derivatives of this function with respect to x and y are are 1 1+ @C(x+ ) y 1+ = C (x + ) y ; @x @C(x+ ) y 1+ = (1 + ) C (x + ) y . @y Because we use this formulation throughout the text, the reader should be sure to understand it at this point. For example, in taking the partial of c with respect to x, we recognize that Cy 1+ does not depend on x. Thus, in writing the partial of c with respect to x we treat Cy 1+ as a constant. Although not literally a constant, this term is constant with respect to x. In English: this term does not depend on x; therefore, changes in x do not a¤ect this term. To drive this point home, we can write c (x; y) = “Constant with respect to x” ( + x) and then use the rule in item #2 above to write the partial derivative of c with respect to x as = “Constant with respect to x” d( +x) dx = “Constant with respect to x” ( ) ( + x) 1 1+ = C ( + x) y @c(x;y) @x 1 The two partial derivatives of c with respect to x and y are themselves functions of x and y. Thus, we can di¤erentiate either of these functions, with respect to either x or y, to obtain a higher order partial derivative. For example, @ 2 C(x+ ) @y 2 @ y 1+ @C(x+ ) @y y 1+ @ [(1+ )C(x+ ) @y 1 = = @y = (1 + ) C (x + ) y and @ 2 C(x+ ) y 1+ @y@x @ @C(x+ ) @y = (1 + ) ( y 1+ = ) C (x + ) @x y ] ; @ [(1+ )C(x+ ) @x 1 y ] = y . 6. A function may depend on two variables, and each of those variables might depend on a third variable. The total derivative tells us how much the 341 function changes for a change in this third argument. For example, suppose that costs depend on x and y, as above, and x and y both depend on ". We show this dependence by writing x (") and y ("). With this notation, we write costs as c (x (") ; y (")). The total derivative of c with respect to " is dc (x (") ; y (")) @c dx @c dy = + : d" @x d" @y d" (A.1) In writing this equation, we merely apply the chain rule twice: the …rst term accounts for the fact that a change in " alters c via the change in x, and the second term accounts for the fact that a change in " alters c via the change in y. The total change in c due a change in " is the sum of these two terms. This expression might seem complicated, but most of the applications in this book are extremely simple. We will be interested in the case where x = x1 " and y = y1 ", where x1 and y1 are treated as constants for the purpose here. For these two functions, we have dx = d" 1 and dy = d" (A.2) 1: Substituting equation A.2 into equation A.1 gives the total derivative dc (x (") ; y (")) = d" @c (x1 "; y1 @x ") @c (x1 "; y1 @y ") : We often want to evaluate this derivative at " = 0. In this case, we write dc (x (") ; y (")) = d" j"=0 @c (x1 ; y1 ) @x @c (x1 ; y1 ) : @y Remember that the subscript “j" = 0”on the left side of this equation means that we evaluate the derivative of c with respect to " where " = 0. 7. A function might depend on several arguments. Suppose that a function L depends on x; y; z: L = L (x; y; z). The di¤erential of L, denoted dL is @L @L @L dL = dx + dy + dz. @x @y @z The change in L (denoted dL) equals the change in L due to the change in x, @L times the change in x, dx, plus the change in L due to the change in @x @L y, @y , times the change in in y, dy, plus the change in L due to the change in z, @L , times the change in z, dz. @z 342 APPENDIX A. MATH REVIEW E 8 6 4 2 0 0.1 0.2 0.3 p -2 Figure A.2: The solid graph shows the excess demand for = 3; here the equilibrium price is p = 0:17. The dashed graph shows excess demand for = 5. Here the equilibrium price is p = 0:15. We use di¤erentials to perform some comparative statics exercises. An “equilibrium condition”is (usually) an equation; this equation might be the …rst order condition to an optimization problem, or it might be a statement that says “supply equals demand”. The equilibrium condition determines an “endogenous variable” (e.g., the optimal level of sales or the price that equates supply and demand) as a function of model parameters. A comparative statics exercise asks how the endogenous variable changes as one or more parameters of the model change. For example, suppose that the demand is QD = p 0:6 and supply is QS = 2 + p + p0:5 , with > 0. De…ne excess demand, E (p; ), as demand minus supply. The equilibrium price equates supply and demand, i.e. it sets excess demand equal to 0: E (p; ) = p 0:6 2 + p + p0:5 = 0: For this example, we have one endogenous variable, p, and one parameter, . We cannot solve the equilibrium price as a function of . Figure A.2 shows the graphs of excess demand for = 3 (solid) and for = 5 (dashed). The higher value of (associated with a larger supply at every price) leads to a lower equilibrium price. The di¤erential of E is dE = @E @E dp + d . @p @ 343 As we change , the equilibrium price also changes. The equilibrium price causes excess demand to equal 0. Therefore, equilibrium requires that dE = 0: @E @E dE = dp + d = 0. (A.3) @p @ This equation states that an exogenous change in , d , induces an endogenous change in the price, dp, in order to maintain excess demand at 0. The partial derivatives of E are @E @p = 0:6p 1:6 @E @ 0:5p = 0:5 <0 (A.4) p < 0: Notice the inequalities in the two lines of equation A.4. The …rst inequality says that an increase in p, at …xed , decreases excess demand. The second inequality says that an increase in , at …xed p, decreases excess demand. The endogenous price must adjust to a change in in order to keep excess demand at 0, in order to satisfy our equilibrium condition. Inspection of these two partial derivatives tells us that if increases (thereby lowering E), there must be an o¤setting decrease in p, in order to maintain excess demand at 0. Here we can …gure out how p must change in response to a change in simply by thinking a bit about the implication of the signs of the partial derivatives. Many problems are too complicated for that kind of casual reasoning to be useful. Therefore, we proceed systematically, using equations A.3 and A.4: 0= @E dp @p + @E d @ = ( 0:6p ( 0:6p 1:6 1:6 0:5p 0:5p 0:5 0:5 ) dp + ( p) d ) ) dp = pd : The …rst equality repeats equation A.3; the second uses the information in equation A.4. Rearranging this equation gives the implication in the second line. We solve this equation, dividing both sides by d and also dividing both sides by ( 0:6p 1:6 0:5p 0:5 ) to write dp = d ( 0:6p p 1:6 0:5p 0:5 ) : This equation is our comparative static expression. The numerator of the ratio on the right side is positive and the denominator is negative, so ddp < 0. 344 APPENDIX A. MATH REVIEW Appendix B Comparative statics Derivation of equation 2.5 Using the de…nition of the di¤erential and the fact that the right side of the equilibrium condition (R) depends on both b and q China , and the left side (L) depends only on q China , we have dL = dR = @L(q C h in a ) dq China @q C h in a @R(q C h in a ;b) dq China @q C h in a + @R(q C h in a ;b) db: @b Substituting these expressions into the de…nitions of the di¤erentials, and using the equilibrium requirement dL = dR gives @L q China @R q China ; b @R q China ; b China China dq = dq + db: @q China @q China @b Collecting terms gives ! @L q China @R q China ; b @R q China ; b China dq = db: @q China @q China @b Rearranging this equation gives dq China = db @R(q C h in a ;b) @b @L(q C h in a ) @R(q C h in a ;b) @q C h in a @q C h in a Using rules of di¤erentiation, we have @L(q C h in a ) @R(q C h in a ;b) = 1 < 0, = C h in a @q @q C h in a and @R(q C h in a ;b) @b = 1 (1+b)2 18 345 10 > 0: 1 1+b >0 q China < 0: 346 APPENDIX B. COMPARATIVE STATICS Substituting the expressions for the partial derivatives into the previous equation and simplifying yields equation 2.5. Appendix C More complicated perturbations For example, suppose that T = 9, and consider the e¤ect of a particular perturbation that leaves the candidate trajectory unchanged in period 0 and from periods 5 to 9. Suppose that this perturbation increases (relative to the candidate) extraction by 0.2 units in period 1, by 1 unit in period 2, makes no change to extraction in period 3, and then reduces period-4 extraction by 1.2 units. The cumulative change in extraction is 0:2 + 1 1:2 = 0, so the period-5 stock under this perturbation is unchanged.1 Figure C.1 shows the graph of an arbitrary sequence of extraction levels, the solid step function, a particular candidate. The dashed lines show the extraction levels under the perturbation, described above, to this candidate. The solid and dashed lines are coincident except in periods 1, 2, and 4, when the perturbation is non-zero. Figure C.2 shows the graph of the stock under the candidate shown in Figure C.1 (the solid lines) and under the perturbation (the dashed lines). Notice that the increased extraction in periods 1 and 2, under the perturbation, lead to lower stocks in periods 2, 3 and 4, even though the extraction in period 4 is the same under the candidate and under the extraction. This somewhat complicated perturbation can be broken down into three 1 The changes in this perturbation are non-in…nitesimal, whereas in deriving the optimality condition we consider only in…nitesimal changes. The procedure described here can be made rigorous by multiplying each of the non-in…nitesimal changes by ", and letting " become arbitrarily small but positive. With this modi…cation, each of the changes is in…nitesimal, and the ratios of changes are as in the example. 347 348 APPENDIX C. MORE COMPLICATED PERTURBATIONS y 4 3 2 1 0 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 t Figure C.1: Solid lines show a candidate, consisting of levels of extraction from periods 0 through 8. The dashes lines show the perturbations relative to this candidate. The perturbation changes extraction only in periods 1, 2 and 4. The perturbation is 0 during periods when the solid and dashed lines are coincident. x 18 16 14 12 10 8 6 4 2 0 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 t Figure C.2: The solid lines show the stock level under the candidate, beginning with stock 17.5. The dashed lines show the stock under the perturbation illustrated in Figure C.1 349 one-step perturbations: Perturbation 1: increase extraction by 0.2 units in period 1 and make an o¤setting reduction of 0.2 units in period 2. Perturbation 2: increase extraction by 1.2 unit in period 2 and make an o¤setting reduction of 1.2 units in period 3. Perturbation 3: increase extraction by 1.2 units in period 3 and make an o¤setting reduction of 1.2 units in period 4. An exercise asks the reader to con…rm that the trajectories under the original perturbation and under the sequence of three one-step perturbations are exactly the same in periods 1, 2, 3 and 4. Thus, the e¤ects on the payo¤ of the original perturbation and of the three one-step perturbations are also the same. If our candidate is optimal, then any one of these one-step perturbations must have zero …rst order e¤ect on the payo¤. Therefore, the e¤ect of all of the changes combined, i.e. the e¤ect of the original three-step perturbation also has a zero …rst order e¤ect. This example illustrates the fact that in order to check for the optimality of the candidate, it is not necessary to consider these complicated multi-step perturbations. It is enough to check that there are no one-step perturbations that yield a …rst order change in the payo¤. 350 APPENDIX C. MORE COMPLICATED PERTURBATIONS Appendix D The full solution in the backstop model An example shows how to use equation ?? to …nd the full solution, using methods that follow Chapter 7. Let C = 2, b = 5, = 0:9, D (p) = 10 p. For these values, (b C) + C = 0:9 (5 2) + 2 = 4: 7. The …rst column of Table 1 shows calendar time working backwards, from T to T 4. Corresponding to each of these times, we use equation ?? to …nd the bounds on price in that period. With these bounds, we …nd the range of possible extraction levels during that period. For example, for t = T 3, the left side of equation ?? is 3 1 b + 3 1 3 C (1 ) = 4: 187 and the right side of this equation is (1 )C +b 3 = 3:9683. These numbers appear in the price column corresponding to t = T 3. The numbers in the extraction column use the demand function and the prices in the adjacent column, and the fact that yT > 0 (by the de…nition of T ). The second column in Table 2, “cumulative extraction”, uses the information in the “extraction” column of the previous table to determine the range of cumulative extraction, in the current and subsequent periods, and denotes this value as x0 . For example, at t = T 1 there are two periods remaining, periods T and T 1. The most that could possibly be extracted in these two periods is 5:3 + 5:57 = 10: 87 and the least that could be consumed is 5:3 + 0 = 5: 3. (Because periods T extraction is strictly positive, not 0, the cumulative extraction over T 1 and T must be strictly greater than 0, not greater than or equal to 0.) We obtain the entries in the other rows using the same logic. If, for example, the initial stock of the resource 351 352APPENDIX D. THE FULL SOLUTION IN THE BACKSTOP MODEL satis…es 16:683 < x0 22:7174, then it takes four periods (T = 3) to exhaust the resource. If the initial stock exceeds 28:94323, we would add additional rows to the tables until reaching the number of periods needed to exhaust the initial stock. time (t = T n) price extraction t=T 5 pT 4:7 0 < y 5:3 t=T 1 4:7 pT 1 4: 43 5:3 y 5:57 t=T 2 4: 43 pT 2 4: 187 5:57 y 5:813 t=T 3 4: 187 pT 3 3: 968 3 5:813 y 6: 031 7 t=T 4 3: 968 3 pT 4 3: 771 47 6: 031 7 y 6: 228 53 Table 8.1 Inequalities on price, extraction, and cumulative extraction during the remaining life of the resource, for di¤erent values of t. Using Table 2, we can obtain the complete solution to the problem once we know the initial stock. If x0 = 15 then Table 2 implies that the resource is exhausted in three periods (T = 2). Choosing y0 as our unknown variable, and using the inverse demand function, we have p0 C = 10 y0 2. time (t = T n) “cumulative extraction” t=T 0 < x0 5:3 t=T 1 5:3 < x0 10:87 t=T 2 10:87 < x0 < 16:683 t=T 3 16:683 < x0 22:7174 t=T 4 22:7174 < x0 28: 943 23 Table 8.2 Inequalities on price, extraction, and cumulative extraction during the remaining life of the resource, for di¤erent values of t. Using the Euler equation we have 10 y0 2 = 0:9 (10 y1 2) ) y1 = 8 8 y0 : 0:9 Using the Euler equation again and then substitution, we have y2 = 8 8 y1 =8 0:9 8 8 80:9y0 : 0:9 353 Adding extraction in the three periods and setting the sum equal to the initial stock, gives y0 + 8 8 y0 0:9 + 8 8 (8 8 y0 0:9 0:9 ) = 15 ) y0 = 5:31 ) y1 = 5:01 ) y2 = 4:48: The natural resource supplies the entire market during periods 0 and 1; during these periods, supply exceeds 5 and the price is below 5, so it is uneconomical to use the backstop. In period 2 the resource supplies 4.48 units and the backstop produces 5 4:48 = 0:52 units; the price equals b = 5. 354APPENDIX D. THE FULL SOLUTION IN THE BACKSTOP MODEL Appendix E Geometry of the Theory of the Second Best The TOSB merits a more general discussion, because of its importance in helping us think clearly about the second best world that we inhabit. We begin by explaining the meaning of level sets and the convexity of a set. We then use this terminology to discuss the TOSB. Figure ?? shows an example of a topological map. These kinds of maps contain curves that identify the coordinates that have the same altitude. They provide information that helps hikers not to get lost. The terrain is relatively steep in a region where topological curves are close to each other, and the terrain is relatively ‡at where curves are far from each other. For this example, the origin (0; 0) is the peak of the mountain. Curves that are closer to the origin have higher altitudes. For example, every point on the dashed curve is higher than any point on the solid curve. Each of these curves is a “level set”, which means that all points on a particular curve have the same altitude. We will call the set of points that are at the same altitude or higher than an arbitrary point as the “higher than”set corresponding to that point. For example, every point on or inside the solid curve is in the “higher than” set corresponding to point a, a point on the solid curve. A set is said to be convex if the following is true: a chord drawn between any two points in that set lies in the set. The “higher than” sets in this …gure are not convex. For example, points a and b both lie in the “higher than” set corresponding to point a, but the chord between points a and b does not lie in this set. Figure E.2 shows two indi¤erence curves for beer and pornography. Points 355 356APPENDIX E. GEOMETRY OF THE THEORY OF THE SECOND BEST N a b E W S Figure E.1: A topological map. Curves closer to the center correspond to points in space that have higher altitude: the altitude is higher at every point on the dashed curve than the solid curve. The “higher than” sets are not convex: a chord that connects two points on a level set, such as points a and b does not lie in the “higher than”sets corresponding to one or both of those sets. on the dashed curve are preferred to points below that curve. The “preferred” set corresponding to any point consists of all combinations of beer and pornography that yield the same or higher level of utility than that point. In this …gure, the preferred sets are convex. For example, every point on the chord between any two points on a level set, such as points a and b, give the same or higher level of utility than either of those two points. In Figure ??, the axes represent distances east or north of the top of the mountain. In Figure E.2, the axes represent amounts of two commodities. In Figures ?? and E.4, the axes represent the magnitude of two distortions. The term “distortion” has both its common meaning, and a slightly more technical meaning in the setting here. A distortion is anything that keeps a market outcome from being e¢ cient, including market failures such as imperfect competition and externalities. A rather mechanical interpretation of “distortion”is helpful in some contexts. We can think of an e¢ cient outcome as consisting of the solution to …rst order conditions to a social planner’s problem. If the outcome consists of n di¤erent variables, we typically require n of these …rst order conditions in order to determine the e¢ cient outcome. For example, suppose (unlike in 357 a c pornography Figure E.2: Points on the dashed indi¤erence curve are preferred to points on the solid indi¤erence curve. The “preferred”sets are convex. our pollution + monopoly example) it is possible to determine both output, y, and emissions, e, independently, and that social welfare, W (q; e) depends on these two variables. We hold all other variables in the economy …xed. The …rst order conditions to the social planner’s problem are @W (q ; e ) @W (q ; e ) = 0 and = 0. @q @e Suppose that a market outcome (q m ; em ) 6= (q ; e ) is not e¢ cient, i.e. it does not solve the planner’s problem. In this case, in general it is possible to write @W (q m ; em ) @W (q m ; em ) = d1 and = d2 ; @q @e with either or both d1 , d2 , not equal to 0. The numbers d1 and d2 are the manifestations of the distortions in the economy. If policy changes resulted in d1 = d2 = 0, then the market outcome and the social planner’s solution are identical: (q m ; em ) = (q ; e ). A policy that causes either d1 or d2 to move closer to 0 reduces (in a mechanical sense) a distortion. The question is: When does such a reduction also increase social welfare? Figures ?? and E.4 show the level sets in two scenarios. Here, a point in the plane shows the two distortions, d1 and d2 , and a level set gives the 358APPENDIX E. GEOMETRY OF THE THEORY OF THE SECOND BEST d2 5 4 3 d2 = 2 2A 1 -5 -4 -3 -2 -1 1 2 3 4 -1 5 d1 -2 -3 -4 -5 Figure E.3: Points on level sets closer to the origen have higher welfare. The level sets are convex. d2 5 4 3 A 1 -5 -4 -3 -2 d2 =2 2 -1 a 1 -1 2 3 4 5 d1 -2 -3 -4 -5 Figure E.4: Points on level sets closer to the origen have higher welfare. The preferred sets are convex combinations of these distortions that have the same level of welfare. In both of these …gures, the level sets are convex, and in both of them the origin (where d1 = 0 = d2 ) is the point of highest welfare, the e¢ cient point. The convexity assumption eliminates a slew of possibilities that complicate the exposition. For example, convexity of these sets means that the economy does not have increasing returns to scale. We put aside those kinds of complications, and now discuss the signi…cance of Figures ?? and E.4. Figure ?? is symmetric with respect to the axes, and Figure E.4 is asymmetric with respect to the axes. These two …gures correspond to di¤erent economic stories. The symmetry of Figure ?? means that if we pick any level of d2 , and hold that level …xed, and then ask “Given this …xed level of d2 , what level of d1 is optimal for the economy?”, the answer is always “d1 = 0 is 359 optimal for the economy”. Figure ?? illustrates this fact for d2 = 2. Given that we are not able to alter this value of d2 , the policy problem is to …nd the level of d1 that gives the highest level of welfare. The mathematical problem is to …nd the highest level set (the one closest to the origin) that has d2 = 2. The solution to this problem requires that the level set is tangent to the ‡at line at d2 = 2, as at point A. At this point of tangency, d1 = 0. The reader can verify that if we had …xed d2 at any level, and asked what level of d1 , maximizes welfare„the answer would always be to set d1 = 0. Similarly, if we had …xed d1 at an arbitrary value, and asked what value of d2 maximizes welfare, the answer is d2 = 0. There may be two policies that potentially correct the two distortions. Policy #1 can correct distortion #1, and Policy #2 can correct distortion #2. Continuing our monopoly + pollution example, we can think of Policy #1 as being a pollution tax (or subsidy, if negative) and Policy #2 as being an antitrust policy that forces …rms to price closer to marginal cost than they would like. In this setting, larger values of d2 mean that a …rm exercises more market power, i.e. moves away from producing where price equals marginal cost, towards producing where marginal revenue equals marginal cost. Here, d1 corresponds to the di¤erence between the tax that …rms face and social cost of emissions (6 in our earlier example). For that example, d1 = 0 means that the tax equals the social cost of emissions; d2 > 0 means that the tax is greater than the social cost of emissions, and d2 < 0 means that the tax (possibly a subsidy) is less than the social cost of emissions. If the pollution and the monopoly power occur in di¤erent sectors, then (apart from general equilibrium complications) the two distortions are unrelated, as in Figure ??. In that case, the two policies are neither substitutes nor complements: the …xed level of one distortion does not a¤ect the optimal level of the other policy. In this circumstance, we can study the two policy problems in isolation. We can try to reduce the monopoly distortion without worrying about the magnitude of the pollution externality, and we can try to reduce the pollution distortion without worrying about the degree of market power. The situation in Figure E.4 is substantively di¤erent, and is closer to the monopoly + pollution example that we used above, where the pollution and monopoly power both arise in the same sector. Here, if we are told that d2 is …xed at any value other than 0, then it is optimal to set d1 to a level other than 0. For example, we can think of the restriction d2 = 2 as the statement that there is a given level of market power that we are not able to 360APPENDIX E. GEOMETRY OF THE THEORY OF THE SECOND BEST in‡uence. Given that level, Figure E.4 shows that the tangency occurs at point A, so the optimal level of d1 is negative. This means that the optimal pollution tax, in the presence of market power, is less than the social cost of pollution. Possibly, the optimal tax is a subsidy ( < 0) as in Figure 10.1; the important conclusion is only that the optimal tax is less than the social cost of pollution. (Whether the tax is positive or negative depends on the relative magnitudes of the two distortions.) A bit of experimentation with Figure E.4 shows that if we lower the market power distortion, (shift down the line at d2 = 2 to a lower level) the optimal subsidy falls. If the market power distortion vanishes, then it is optimal to set the tax equal to the social cost of emissions, so that the pollution externality also vanishes (d1 = 0). Figure E.4, together with our de…nition of d1 and d2 imply that (for the monopoly + pollution example) environmental taxes and antitrust policy are complements: stricter enforcement of antitrust policy (lowering d2 ) implies that the optimal pollution tax increases (causing d1 to move toward 0). Of course, the …rst best policy combination eliminates both distortions, putting the economy at the origin of the …gure, the top of the mountain, i.e. the highest level of social welfare. Appendix F Algebra of taxes This appendix collects technical details for the chapter on taxes. F.1 Algebraic veri…cation of tax equivalence Denote the producer price as ps (for supply) and the consumer price as pc (for consumption) and write the “market price”as p. If consumers pay the tax, the prices are ps = p and pc = ps + (producers receive the market price and consumers pay this price plus the tax). If producers pay the tax, ps = p and pc = p (consumers pay the market price and producers receive this price minus the tax). We want to con…rm that tax-inclusive prices are the same regardless of who directly pays the tax. If consumers pay the tax, the supply equal demand condition is S(p) = D(p + ): (F.1) Let p ( ) be the (unique) price that solves this equation; this is the equilibrium producer price (a function of ) when consumers pay the tax: p (0) is the equilibrium price when = 0. Because consumers (directly) pay the tax, the price producers receive (the “supply price”) equals p ( ) and the price consumers pay equals p ( ) + . If, instead, producers directly pay the tax, the equilibrium condition is S(p Substitute p = p + ) = D(p): into this equation to write equation (F:2) as S(p ) = D(p + ): 361 (F.2) 362 APPENDIX F. ALGEBRA OF TAXES The last equation reproduces equation (F:1) evaluated at p = p ( ), the unique solution to that equation. Thus, the two equations (F:1) and (F:2) lead to the same producer and consumer prices. Appendix ?? contains further details. F.2 The open economy For a closed economy, domestic supply equals domestic demand: there is no trade. For an open economy, domestic supply does not equal domestic demand: the di¤erence equals the amount imported or exported. The tax equivalence result above holds in a closed economy, where all sources of supply or demand are subject to the tax. An example shows that when the economy is open, tax equivalence does not hold. With international trade, domestically produced supply does not equal domestic demand. With trade, the optimal policy depends on whether the environmental damage is associated with consumption or production. There, it does matter whether a consumer or producer tax is used. First consider the case where the economy is closed. Suppose that domestic demand is q d = 10 p and domestic supply equals q s = bp. Column 2 of Table 1 shows that the consumer and producer tax incidence does not depend on which agent, consumers or producers, directly pays the tax. The incidences in this column are calculated using the following steps: 1. Calculate the equilibrium price in the absence of tax by setting the untaxed supply equal to the untaxed demand. 2. Calculate the equilibrium consumer price and producer price when one of these agents directly pays the tax, by setting the (taxed) demand equal to the (taxed) supply. 3. Use the tax-inclusive consumer and producer price for the two cases (where one agent or the other directly pays the tax) and the zero-tax price to calculate the incidences. The third column of the table shows that in the open economy, the incidences do depend on which (domestic) agent directly pays the tax. For example, to calculate the incidences in the open economy when consumers directly pay the tax (regardless of the source of supply), we use essentially F.2. THE OPEN ECONOMY 363 the same steps as above. The market clearing condition in the absence of a tax is 10 p = (b + c) p. We solve this to …nd the zero-tax price. If consumers pay the tax, the market clearing condition is 10 (p + ) = bp + cp, where now we understand that p is the price received by both domestic and foreign …rms, and p + t is the consumer tax-inclusive price. We solve this equation to …nd the equilibrium producer and consumer prices. Using the formula for tax incidence, we obtain the expressions in the third row and third column of Table 1. An exercise asks readers to use this procedure to derive the formulae in the table. closed economy open economy q d = 10 p q s = bp q d = 10 p q s = bp and q s;f or = cp market clearing 10 consumers pay tax domestic producers pay tax p = bp consumer incidence b 100% 1+b market clearing 10 p = (b + c) p consumer incidence producer incidence consumer incidence b 100% 1+b producer incidence consumer incidence producer incidence 1 100% 1+b producer incidence 1 100% 1+b b+c 100% 1+b+c 1 100% 1+b+c b 100% 1+b+c 1+c 100% 1+b+c Table 1 consumer and producer tax incidence in closed and open economy In an open economy, domestic supply does not equal to domestic demand. Taxing consumers causes the market demand function to shift in, lowering the price that both producers face and increasing the consumer’s tax-inclusive price. Taxing only domestic supply causes the domestic supply function to shift in, increasing the consumer price, decreasing the domestic tax-inclusive price, and shifting supply from domestic to foreign producers. Under the consumer tax, both the domestic and foreign producers receive the same price. Under the (domestic) producer tax, consumers and foreign producers face the same price, and domestic producers receive a lower after-tax price. This example shows that although in a closed economy producer and consumer taxes are equivalent, the two taxes are not equivalent in an open economy. Hereafter, we return to the closed economy model. Exercise: 364 APPENDIX F. ALGEBRA OF TAXES 1. Derive the tax incidences shown in Table 1. F.3 Approximating tax incidence In the closed economy, it does not matter whether consumers or producers are charged the tax. Suppose that consumers are charged the tax, so that the equilibrium condition is equation F.1. This equation expresses the equilibrium price as an implicit function of the tax: as the tax changes, the equilibrium price p changes. The consumer incidence (expressed as a fraction instead of a percent) equals p (0) p +1= + 1: (F.3) 0 The numerator on the left side equals the change in price that consumers pay. We obtain the …rst equality by simplifying, i.e. using the fact that = 1, and subtracting 0 from the denominator. We subtract 0 in order to emphasize that both the numerator and the denominator are changes: the numerator is the change in price, in moving from a 0 tax to a non-zero tax, and the denominator is the change in the tax, 0. We obtain the second equality by using the “delta notation”: means “change in”. The next step requires a formula for an approximation of p , which we obtain using the fact that the derivative ddp is approximately equal to p . Treating p = p( ) (i.e. price as a function of the tax –and dropping the “*” to simplify notation) we can di¤erentiate both sides of the equilibrium condition F.1 to write dD(p + ) dp dS(p) dp = +1 : dp d dpc d p ( )+ p (0) = p ( ) Divide both sides by the equilibrium quantity, using S = D, and multiply by the equilibrium price p to write dS(p) p dp dD(p + ) p = dp S d dpc D dp +1 : d (F.4) Because we are considering an approximation for small , we evaluate equation F.4 at = 0. Using the de…nitions in equation 11.1, and evaluating equation F.4 at = 0, we rewrite that equation as dp = d dp +1 : d F.3. APPROXIMATING TAX INCIDENCE We can solve this equation for dp d 365 to obtain dp = d + (F.5) : This equation shows the derivative of the equilibrium price with respect to the tax, evaluated at a 0 tax. Notice that ddp < 0: the tax, although paid by consumers, reduces the equilibrium price that producers receive. We use the fact that dp p d and equations F.3 and F.5 to write the expression for the consumer incidence as p dp +1 +1=1 = : d + + The tax incidence for producers equals reduction in producer price : level of (unit) tax Initially the tax is 0, so the level of the tax (once it is imposed) is The producer tax incidence is producer incidence: p + 0= . : This expression involves p rather than p because the de…nition of the producer incidence involves the “price reduction”, not the “price change”. If the price change is, for example, 3, then the reduction is 3. Exercise: 1. Suppose that consumers are charged the tax, as above. Let the demand function be D (p) = p with > 1 and suppose that …rms have constant marginal cost, c. Evaluate the consumer and producer tax incidence under the monopoly, as a function of . Compare with the consumer and producer tax incidence under competition, with the same demand and cost functions. Hint Mimic the derivation above, replacing marginal revenue with price. 366 F.4 APPENDIX F. ALGEBRA OF TAXES Approximating deadweight loss and tax revenue The graphical representation of the deadweight cost of the tax is the area of the triangle in Figure 11.1. We want an approximation for this area that is valid even if the supply and demand functions are not linear. For this purpose, we use the formula for the area of a triangle, 21 base height. The height of the triangle is simply the tax, (see ). Denote the base of this triangle as q, the change in quantity demanded. We have (by multiplying and dividing) q= q p= p q p p qp pq = q p p : (F.6) Equation 11.2 and the de…nition of the supply elasticity imply, respectively, the following two equations p dp = d + qp pq and . Inserting these formulae into equation F.6 gives the approximation q : + p q (F.7) Here we used the fact that = 0 = , because we are taking the approximation in the neighborhood of a zero tax. This result and the formula for the area of a triangle produces equation 11.4. It is worth taking a moment to consider the units in which deadweight loss is measured. Suppose that we measure quantity in kilograms and price in dollars per kilogram. In this case, the tax is also measured in dollars per kilogram. The units of the ratio pq are therefore kilograms dollars kilogram (kilograms)2 = . dollars The units of pq t2 are therefore (kilograms)2 dollars dollars kilograms 2 = dollars. F.4. APPROXIMATING DEADWEIGHT LOSS AND TAX REVENUE367 The elasticities are already “unit free”–that is the reason that we use them. Therefore, deadweight loss is measured in dollars (or whatever monetary unit we begin with). This result makes sense: we want a measure of value in monetary units, not, for example, in units of kilograms. The tax revenue equals (q q), where q is the pretax quantity sold and q is the change in the quantity due to the tax. Using equation F.7, we have q tax revenue: (q q) q : (F.8) + p Dividing the approximation of deadweight loss by this formula and cancelling produces equation 11.5. We can use the approximation of tax revenue and of DWL to illustrate the second “rule”for optimal tax policy: use a large tax base. Suppose that the economy consists of two commodities, and for each of these (by choice of units) + pq = 1 and in the absence of taxes, output (= consumption) is (by assumption) q = 10. The government has to raise $20 of tax revenue. If the government raises this revenue by taxing only one commodity, it needs to solve (10 1 ) = 20 ) 1 (1) (2: 76)2 = 3:82: 2 2:76 ) DW L In contrast, if the government uses a broader tax basis, it solves 2 (10 1 ) = 20 ) 1:27 ) DW L 2 1 (1) (1:27)2 = 1:61: 2 For this example, doubling the tax basis leads to a 57% decrease in the total DWL. 368 APPENDIX F. ALGEBRA OF TAXES Appendix G Continuous versus discrete time G.1 The continuous time limit Consider the growth equation with a harvest rule y(x). Recall that a harvest rule determines the level of harvest as a function of the stock, x. Equation 14.3 shows the discrete time dynamics for two particular harvest rules. Later we encounter other harvest rules, so here we use the general formulation y (x). With this harvest rule, the next-period and current-period stocks are related according to xt+1 xt = F (xt ) y (xt ) = [F (xt ) y (xt )] 1: (G.1) Multiplying F (xt ) y (xt ) by 1, as in the last equality, obviously does not change the quantity. We have to measure time in speci…c units. For example, it is meaningful to say “That was three years ago,”but we would never say “That was three ago.” We choose the unit of time to equal one year; this choice is arbitrary: we could have chosen a unit to equal one second or one century. There is no reason (apart from convenience) to assume that the length of a period equals one unit of time. For some models, where events unfold over long periods of time, it might make sense to choose the length of a period equal to a decade; prominent climate policy models use that time scale. For other models, where events occur quickly, we might want the length of a period to equal one day or even an hour or less; some models involving …nancial transactions use that kind of time scale. 369 370 APPENDIX G. CONTINUOUS VERSUS DISCRETE TIME We use the symbol to represent the length of a period. If a period lasts for a decade, then = 10 (because our unit of time is one year). If 1 a period lasts for a day, then = 364 . In order for our model to show explicitly the length of a period, we can replace the number 1 wherever it appears in equation ?? (including in the subscripts) with ; the equation becomes xt+ xt = [F (xt ; ) y (xt ; )] ) (G.2) xt+ xt = F (xt ; ) y (xt ; ) : By introducing the parameter , we have made a subtle change in the de…nition of F (xt ) and y (xt ); these are now rates, i.e. they give growth and harvest per unit of time (one year). To take into account this change, we 1 replace F (xt ) and y (xt ) with F (xt ; ) and y (xt ; ). If = 364 and if the growth per year is 0:8, and harvest per year is 0:2 , then the amount 0:8 1 ) equals 364 of growth and harvest over one period (one day, for = 364 0:2 and 364 , respectively. (The change over one day is xt+ xt = (0:8 0:2) 1 3 = (0:8 0:2) 364 = 1: 65 10 .) Now that we explicitly recognize that growth and harvest are rates, we no longer need to require that y x. For example, suppose that x = 40 and y = 60. It is not possible to extract 60 units of biomass if the stock of biomass equals only 40. However, it is certainly possible to harvest at 1 an annual rate of 60 for a short period of time. If = 364 and y = 60, 60 then after 10 periods (= 10 days) we have extracted 364 10 = 1: 65 units of biomass. In general, if is su¢ ciently small, then the annual harvest rate y can be arbitrarily large without violating the non-negativity constraint on the stock of …sh. The last line of equation G.2 shows the ratio xt+ xt , equal to the change 1 in stock per change in time. With = 364 , this ratio is the change in the xt+ xt stock per day. As ! 0, the ratio converges to a time derivative. We de…ne F (x) = lim F (x; ) and y (x) = lim y (x; ) : !0 !0 With this de…nition, the continuous time limit of the last line of equation G.2 is dxt = F (xt ) y (xt ) : (G.3) dt Equation G.2 is a di¤erence equation, and equation G.3 is a di¤erential equation. They both describe how x changes over time. Hereafter, when G.2. STABILITY IN DISCRETE TIME 371 studying stability (and for some other purposes that arise in Chapter 16) we “jump to continuous time”. Readers interested in knowing how to think about stability in the discrete time setting should consult Appendix G. It is important to be clear about the relation between equations G.2 and G.3. By construction, they have the same steady states. In other respects, however, they may contain very di¤erent information. For example, suppose that we have two …sh stocks; the …rst grows according to equation G.2 and the second grows according to equation G.3. We start both stocks at the same level, and let each evolve in the manner described by its equation of motion. Would these two stocks evolve in the same way, i.e. would the time-graphs of their trajectories look similar? In general, the answer is “no”. If we want to change the length of a period (e.g. from = 1 1 to = 10;000;000;000 ), while keeping the trajectory qualitatively unchanged, we have to re-calibrate the functions F (xt ) and y (xt ). However, if is su¢ ciently small, then trajectories arising from the continuous and discrete time models are qualitatively similar, at least in the neighborhood of a steady state. G.2 Stability in discrete time A trajectory that moves away from an unstable steady state, or toward a stable steady state, might be changing monotonically (i.e. the path continues to increase or to decrease) or it might cycle (i.e. the path increases, then decreases, then increases, etc.). Table 1 includes these four possibilities; we discuss the entries of the table below. Other kinds of much more complicated behavior, including chaos, can arise in even these simple discrete time models. We select parameter values to exclude that complexity. Roughly, the complexity can arise in a discrete time setting because there the stock can change by an appreciable amount from one period to another. The stock can therefore jump from an interval in which the dynamics “behave in a certain way” to another region where the dynamics “behave in a very di¤erent way”. This type of complexity does not arise in continuous time settings where the stock moves smoothly over time. monotonic trajectory cyclical trajectory 0 0 stable 1 < F (x1 ) y (x1 ) < 0 2 < F 0 (x1 ) y 0 (x1 ) < 0 0 0 unstable F (x1 ) y (x1 ) > 0 F (x1 ) y 0 (x1 ) < 2 1 372 APPENDIX G. CONTINUOUS VERSUS DISCRETE TIME Table 14.1: Types of steady states Given particular functional forms and parameter values, we can test numerically whether a steady state is stable. Consider the example where harvest is a constant fraction of the stock, yt = xt . In this case, we can write the second line of equation 14.3 as xt K xt+1 = xt + xt 1 xt . (G.4) We call x0 , the level of the stock at the initial time, t = 0, the “initial condition”. Given a numerical value of x0 and numerical values of ; , and K, we can solve this equation to …nd x1 . Plugging that value into the equation we …nd x2 . Proceeding in this manner, we can determine whether the successive values of xt approach either the high or the low steady state (33.33 and 0 in the example above). Although this approach is easy enough to implement, it does not provide any insight into the problem. There is simple test for determining the stability and the adjustment paths (monotonic or cyclical) of steady states, without actually computing the trajectory. We apply this method in other settings, so it is worth stating it fairly generally. Let F (x) be a growth function (e.g., logistic) and y (x) be a particular harvest rule (e.g. a constant fraction of the stock). Given these function, any solution to 0 = F (x) y (x) is a steady state. Given a particular steady state (recall that there may be more than one), we can compute the derivatives F 0 (x1 ) and y 0 (x1 ). The entries in Table 1 show the combinations of these derivatives that result in the four types of behavior. G.2.1 Explanation of Table 1 We appeared to pull Table 1 out of the air, but a simple graphical argument explains it. We require one additional piece of notation. For a growth function xt+1 xt = F (xt ) and the harvest rule y (xt ), de…ne the stock in the next period, given xt , as g (xt ) xt+1 = xt + F (xt ) y (xt ) g (xt ) : (G.5) For example, the right side of equation G.4 shows the function g under the logistic growth function and the proportional harvest rule. Figure G.1 provides the basis for understanding Table 1. This …gure appears to be very simple, but it requires a bit of thought to use. The G.2. STABILITY IN DISCRETE TIME 373 Figure G.1: A stable steady state. The curve g (x) = x + F (x) y.takes the current value of the stock, x, into the next period value. The steady state is the intersection of g (x) and the 45o line. horizontal axis shows the value of the stock in the “current”period, denoted x. As above, the stock x changes according to the equation xt+1 = g (xt ) : The heavy line in Figure G.1 is the graph of g and the 45o is the graph of x. We use the 45o line and the graph of g for three purposes: to identify the steady states, to determine whether each of these is stable, and also to trace out the evolution of the stock, given an initial condition. At the intersection of the 45o line and the graph of g (x), x = g (x). Therefore, the intersection of the 45o line and the graph of g identi…es the steady states. Figure G.1 shows a single point of intersection, i.e., a single steady state, merely to keep the …gure simple. In general there could be several steady states, as the …sh examples illustrate. In Figure G.1 it is apparent that the derivative of g at the steady state is positive, and that in addition, the graph of g approaches the steady state from above the 45o line, which has a slope of 1. Therefore, 0 < g 0 (x1 ) < 1 in this …gure. Restating this inequality using the functions F (x) and y (x), the inequality becomes 0 < 1 + F 0 (x) y 0 (x) < 1. Subtracting 1 from all parts of this inequality produces the equivalent relation 1 < F 0 (x) y 0 (x) < 0. The upper left entry of Table 1 states that the corresponding steady state is stable, and that paths beginning in the neighborhood of the steady state approach it 374 APPENDIX G. CONTINUOUS VERSUS DISCRETE TIME monotonically. How can we reach this conclusion based only on the slope of g shown in Figure G.1? The answer requires understanding how to interpret this …gure. The numerical values shown on the horizontal and vertical axis of the …gure make it easy explain this interpretation, but otherwise have no signi…cance. Suppose that the stock in a particular period is x = 2:3, the value of the horizontal coordinate of point a in the …gure. By de…nition of the growth function, the stock in the next period equals g (2:3), which is the vertical coordinate of the point above a, on the curve g. In the …gure, g (2:3) = 2:7. The 45o line enables us to use the above information to carry on to the next period. This line is like a mirror that re‡ects the stock from one period to the next. It “re‡ects” a value on the vertical axis onto the horizontal axis. The reader should draw a horizontal line from the vertical axis, at 2:7. Where this line hits the 45o line (at point b), drop a line straight down to the x axis. This procedure gives us the new “current period” value of the stock, 2:7 on the horizontal axis. Given this value, we can …nd the new “next period”stock, the point on the heavy curve above point b. The …gure shows this value as 3:9. Proceeding in this way, we can trace out the sequence of stocks. Once the reader has performed these steps a few times, it becomes apparent that the procedure can be simpli…ed. We need an initial condition, x = 2:3, in the example above, to get started. With this initial condition, we identify the point a on the 45o curve. We then draw an arrow toward the curve g; where the arrow hits g we draw another arrow to the 45o line. Where that arrow hits the 45o line we draw another arrow to g. The horizontal coordinates of the points on the 45o line, a; b, c... in Figure G.1 are the successive values of x. We can repeat this step inde…nitely, but after a few steps it is apparent that the trajectory converges toward the steady state. We can see that for this …gure, with a stock that begins at 2.3 (or at any other value su¢ ciently close to the steady state), the sequence approaches the steady state monotonically, as Table 1 states. Exercises ask the reader to construct analogous …gures that establish the other three entries in Table 1. G.2.2 Applying the stability test We begin with a graphical example that helps to develop intuition about steady states and stability. We then proceed more formally, using the in- G.2. STABILITY IN DISCRETE TIME 375 formation in Table 1. Figure 14.5 shows the logistic growth function with K = 50 and = 0:03, and two harvest rules: the constant harvest y = 0:3 and the harvest rule that takes 1% of the stock in each period, y = 0:01x. Consider …rst the constant extraction rule, shown by the dotted line. This line intersects the growth function at two stock levels, x = 14 and x = 36. Both of these stock levels are steady states (when y = 0:3) but the …rst is unstable and the second is stable. At a stock slightly below x = 14, the harvest exceeds the natural growth, F , so the stock is falling. Similarly, at a stock slightly above x = 14, the natural growth, F , exceeds harvest, so the stock is increasing. Therefore, at any point close to, but not exactly equal to, the low steady state (x = 14) the stock trajectory moves away from the low steady state. The low steady state therefore appears to be (and in fact is) unstable. By similar reasoning, the high steady state is stable. The upward sloping dashed line is the graph of the harvest rule y = 0:01x. The line y = 0:01x intersects the curve F at two points, x = 0 and x = 33. These are both steady states for this harvest rule. At a stock close to, but slightly greater than x = 0, the natural growth exceeds the harvest, so the stock increases; it moves away from x = 0, so that steady state is unstable. At a point close to but slightly smaller than x = 33, the natural growth exceeds the harvest, so the stock is increasing. At a point close to but slightly larger than x = 33, the harvest exceeds the natural growth rate, so the stock is falling. Thus, for stock levels close to the steady state x = 33, the stock trajectory approaches x = 33. This steady state appears to be (and in fact is) stable. The de…nition of stability of a steady state involves the behavior of the stock trajectory in the neighborhood of (i.e., close to) the steady state. In simple cases, such as represented by …gure 14.5, we can make a stronger statement. For the constant harvest rule, y = 0:3, beginning with any stock level x > 14, the stock approaches the high steady state, x = 36. For initial stock levels x < 14, the harvest always exceeds growth, so the stock is driven to 0, which is also a stable steady state. The dynamics with the proportional harvest rule are even simpler. Beginning with any stock greater than 0, the stock approaches the stable steady state. In discussing Figure 14.5, we did not use information in Table 1. Given the simplicity of this …gure, the reader may wonder why we bothered with that Table at all. The answer is that some of the conclusions that we drew above, concerning Figure 14.5, happen to be correct because of our choice of parameter values, but cannot actually be deduced from the …gure alone. 376 APPENDIX G. CONTINUOUS VERSUS DISCRETE TIME Footnote 1, below, and an exercise provide more insight into the problem with relying exclusively on …gures; this problem arises because the stock can “jump around” in a discrete time setting. Graphs are useful for providing intuition, but to be con…dent of the characteristics of a steady state, we need the formality contained in Table 1. The remainder of this section uses the information in Table 1 to determine the characteristics of steady states. We …rst use Table 1 to …nd a restriction on the growth function that insures that the carrying capacity, K, is a stable steady state in the absence of harvest. If harvest is always zero, y (x) = 0 = . y 0 (x) for all x. The derivative of F (x) = x 1 Kx is F 0 (x) = 1 2x K 2K 0 Evaluating this derivative at x = K gives F (K) = 1 K = . Thus, F 0 (x1 ) y 0 (x1 ) = , for the steady state x1 = K. Substituting this value into Table 1 gives: monotonic trajectory cyclical trajectory stable 1> >0 2> >1 unstable < 0 (XX) >2 Table 14.2: characteristics of the steady state x = K for logistic growth with zero harvest Table 2 states that, for the logistic growth function with zero harvest, the carrying capacity (the steady state x = K) is stable if 2 > > 0. For 1 > > 0, paths beginning in the neighborhood of the steady state approach the steady state monotonically. For 2 > > 1, paths beginning in the neighborhood of the steady state approach the steady state cyclically. A negative growth rate, < 0, is not sensible in this model, so we can ignore that case; hence, the “XX”in that entry. The remaining possibility is > 2, for which paths beginning near the steady state diverge (move away from it) cyclically. Hereafter, we assume that 0 < < 2, so the carrying capacity is a stable steady state.1 1 As increases, the complexity of oscillations increases. Beyond some point ( slightly larger than 2.5) the oscillations become “chaotic”: from almost all initial conditions, they are very irregular (they do not repeat in a …nite interval of time). Moreover, the paths are very sensitive to the initial condition. This situation is the example, alluded to in the text, for why inspection of graphs is insu¢ cient in some cases to determine the characteristics of the steady state. If we graphed the logistic growth function for > 2:5, it would have the same general appearance as the logistic growth function in Figure 14.5. Reasoning as we did in the text, we might conclude that the x = K is stable in this case. But the information contained in Table 2 tells us that it is in fact not stable. The point to remember is that …gures can be deceptive in these discrete time models. G.2. STABILITY IN DISCRETE TIME 377 We can use the same procedure to check for stability of steady states under the proportional harvest rule, y = x, still using the logistic growth function. We begin by …nding the steady states, by setting harvest-inclusive growth equal to zero, F (x) x = 0, and solving for the stock, x. There are two ). The stock must be non-negative, steady states, x = 0 and x = K ( so the second steady state exists if and only if > . The derivative of y(x) . is y 0 (x) = , a constant, and the derivative of F (x) is F 0 (x) = 1 2x K Table 1 shows that the stability test depends on a comparison of these two derivatives. The derivative of F is not a constant, so we need to evaluate it at both of the steady states: F 0 (0) = F0 K ( ) = 1 2K ( K ) =2 : (G.6) We now consider each of two steady states in turn. Using Table 1 and the …rst line of equation G.6 produces Table 3: monotonic trajectory cyclical trajectory stable 1< <0 2< < 1 unstable >0 < 2 Table 14.3: characteristics of the steady state x = 0 for logistic growth with harvest proportional to the stock. Using Table 1, the second line of equation G.6 and the fact that 2 produces Table 4: monotonic trajectory cyclical trajectory stable 1< <0 2< < 1 unstable > 0 (XX) < 2 (XX) Table 14.4: characteristics of the interior steady state x = K ( for logistic growth with harvest proportional to the stock. = ) We place an “XX” by the two entries in the last low row of the table, because the associated parameter values are excluded by assumption. The fact that we are considering the interior steady state in this table implies that this steady state exists, i.e. it is positive. That requires < , ruling out the lower left entry. We previously assumed that < 2 (in order to 378 APPENDIX G. CONTINUOUS VERSUS DISCRETE TIME Figure G.2: An example of an unstable steady state exclude chaotic behavior in the absence of harvest), and because 0, it follows that > 2, thus ruling out the lower right entry in Table 4. Consequently, if the carrying capacity is a stable steady state in the absence of harvest, and if an interior steady state exists under proportional harvest, that steady state must be stable for this model. Using this fact and Table 3, we conclude that if an interior steady state exists, then x = 0 is an unstable steady state. If an interior steady state does not exist (i.e. if > ), then x = 0 is a stable steady state; it is also the only steady state here. G.3 Exercises 1. Figure G.2 di¤ers from Figure G.1 in that the heavy curve (which represents the growth function g (xt )) cuts the 45o line “from below”, > 1. Pick a as we move left to right. In particular, dg(x) dx jsteady state point somewhat close to the steady state (the intersection of the heavy curve and the 45o line). Use the steps described in the discussion of Figure G.1 to trace out the stock dynamics (the evolution of x), over a couple of periods. This trajectory illustrates the lower left entry of Table 1. 2. Draw two other …gures to illustrate the remaining entries of Table 1. Each …gure should have a 45o line and a graph of g that intersects the line. In one …gure, 1 < g 0 (x1 ) < 0 and in the other g 0 (x1 ) < 1. Trace out the dynamics for trajectories that begin near the respective G.3. EXERCISES 379 steady states. 3. Suppose that the harvest rate is a constant, y (for stocks x y); in addition y is such that there exist two interior steady states. The growth function is logistic, F (x) = x 1 Kx . (a) Find an inequality (depending on the parameters of the growth function) that y must satisfy in order for there to be two interior steady states. (Hint: draw a picture.) (b) For a y that satis…es this inequality, determine which, if either steady state is stable. (Hint: Write the analog to equation G.4 with constant harvest: xt y g (xt ) : xt+1 = xt + xt 1 K Write the derivative dg(x) for this expression. Use dg(x) , expressed as a dx dx function of x (not of y) to …nd a condition on x that must be satis…ed in order for a steady state to be stable. If your calculations are accurate, you will discover that for a constant harvest rule, a steady state is stable for x above a critical level, and the steady state is unstable for x below this critical level. You need to …nd this critical level. A graph is a big help here.) 4. Figure G.3 shows a standard growth function with a very odd looking non-monotonic harvest rule, the dashed curve. The key feature of this harvest rule is that its slope is very large in absolute value in the neighborhood of the two larger steady states. (a) Use this information, together with Table 1, to determine which, if any steady states are stable. (b) Use the information in Figure G.3 to construct a …gure that contains the graph of g (x) = x + F (x) g (x) and a 45o line. You do not have the functional form of y (x), so your graph of g cannot be “accurate”. The objective is to that it has characteristics compatible with Figure G.3. For example, your graph should have three points of intersection between g and the 45o line. Pick an initial condition (a points on the x axis) near each of the steady states and use your …gure to trace out the stock trajectory. 5. Figure G.4 shows a growth function, F (x). (a) Sketch the …gure on a piece of paper and identify: (i) the carrying capacity, (ii) the maximum sustainable yield, and (iii) the stock level associated with the maximum sustainable yield. (b) The dashed curve represents a particular harvest 380 APPENDIX G. CONTINUOUS VERSUS DISCRETE TIME Figure G.3: A standard growth function, the solid curve, and an highly nonmonotonic harvest rule, the dashed line. The harvest rule is very steep in the neighborhood of the two largest steady steady states. Figure G.4: See Exercise 5. The solid curve is a growth function and the dashed curve is a harvest rule. rule. Identify each steady state(s) associated with this harvest rule using the letters A; B; :::. For each of these steady states, what (if anything) can you say about its stability? Provide a brief explanation. Appendix H Bioeconomic equilibrium Objectives and skills Understand the meaning of a “bioeconomic equilibrium”. For simple cost and growth functions, be able to write down and graph the “steady state supply function”. Using the steady state supply function and a demand function, identify the steady states. Using the …ction of the “Walrasian auctioneer”, identify which steady states are stable and which are unstable. Here we o¤er a slightly di¤erent perspective on the open access steady state. The zero pro…t condition, and the production function in equation 15.2, imply C w = ; (H.1) 0 = (pqx w) E ) x = pq p where the last equality uses the de…nition wq = C. The production function 15.2 and the steady state condition under logistic growth (harvest equal growth) give x y = qEx = x 1 : (H.2) K Substituting equation H.1 into equation H.2 gives the steady state supply function C C y= 1 : (H.3) p Kp 381 382 APPENDIX H. BIOECONOMIC EQUILIBRIUM price 3 A 2 1 B D 0 0.00 0.05 0.10 0.15 0.20 0.25 0.30 0.35 0.40 harvest Figure H.1: The backward bending steady state supply function (solid) and a linear demand curve. The steady state supply function for harvest gives the harvest level, as a function of the price, that is consistent with a steady state stock of the …sh and zero pro…ts in the …shery. Figure ?? shows the supply function for parameter values K = 50; = 0:03, and C = 5 (as in our previous examples). The notable feature is that this supply function bends backwards. For prices 1 = 0:2, supply increases with price, and is very price-elastic (‡at). At p < Kq higher prices, equilibrium supply decreases with the higher price. At a given stock, the higher price induces greater harvest, but the higher harvest reduces the steady state stock. The net e¤ect in the steady state is that a higher price reduces equilibrium supply over the backward bending part of the curve. The dashed curve in the …gure shows the linear demand curve, p = 3:5 10y. There are three “bioeconomic equilibria”, combinations of output and price where supply equals demand and the stock is in a steady state. The equilibria A and D, corresponding to high price and low harvest, and low price and high harvest, are stable; the intermediate equilibrium is unstable, just as we saw in Section 15.2. An exercise asks the reader to show how the set of steady states changes as demand becomes more elastic. The argument that determines stability or instability is a bit di¤erent in the setting in this section, compared to the above. We introduce a …ctitious “Walrasian auctioneer”. This auctioneer calls out an arbitrary price. If, at that price, supply equals demand, the auctioneer has found an equilibrium. 383 However, if at the price the auctioneer has called out, demand exceeds supply, then the auctioneer raises the price, in an e¤ort to bring supply and demand into equilibrium. Suppose that this auctioneer calls out a price slightly above the p coordinate of point B; at this slightly higher price, demand exceeds supply. In an e¤ort to balance supply and demand, the auctioneer increases the price. The higher price initially elicits greater supply, but that reduces future stock, creating an even larger divergence between steady state supply and demand. The auctioneer continues to raise the price, toward the p coordinate of point A, where at last steady state supply equals demand. Thus, a price that begins slightly above the p coordinate of point B moves away from that point, so this price is unstable. Parallel arguments show that the prices corresponding to points A and D are stable steady states. Section 15.2 uses a graph in the stock-harvest plane, and here we use a graph in the harvest-price plane. Both perspectives have something to o¤er. The backward bending supply function provides a useful contrast between familiar static models and the dynamic …sh model, but it is a bit harder to interpret, and requires introducing the …ction of the Walrasian auctioneer. The graphs using the harvest rule and the growth function follow more directly from the dynamic model, and have a direct physical interpretation. 384 APPENDIX H. BIOECONOMIC EQUILIBRIUM Appendix I The Euler equation for the sole owner …shery Objectives and skills: Apply the perturbation method to obtain the Euler equation. The constraints of the sole owner’s optimization problem are x 0 and y 0. The …rst constraint implies that yt xt : it is not possible to harvest more than the total stock of …sh. We …nd the necessary condition where both the stock and the harvest are strictly positive, i.e. along an interior optimum. As in Chapter 5, we determine the necessary conditions for optimality using the perturbation method. Natural growth, the function F (xt ), complicates the problem, but the logic is the same. We begin with a feasible “candidate trajectory” of harvest, y0 , y1 , y2 :::; and the corresponding stock sequence, x0 , x1 , x2 ... . We obtain the condition that must be satis…ed if no perturbation increases the present discounted value of the payo¤. As before, we achieve this objective by considering a particular one-step perturbation: one that increases harvest in an arbitrary period (t) by ", and makes an o¤setting change in harvest in the next period (t+1) in order to keep unchanged the stock in the subsequent period (t + 2). As explained in Chapter 5, we can build a more complicated perturbation from a series of these one-step perturbations. Thus, for the purpose of obtaining the necessary conditions, it su¢ ces to consider this one-step perturbation. We begin by …nding the o¤setting change needed in period t + 1, in order to keep unchanged (relative to the unperturbed candidate) the stock in period 385 386APPENDIX I. THE EULER EQUATION FOR THE SOLE OWNER FISHERY t + 2. If we increase harvest in period t by ", the stock in period t + 1 is xt+1 = xt + F (xt ) (yt + ") : This relation implies dxt+1 = 1: (I.1) d" The increased harvest in period t reduces the stock in period t + 1 from xt+1 (the level under the candidate trajectory) to xt+1 ". Under the candidate trajectory, we plan to harvest yt+1 in period t + 1. The o¤setting change in yt+1 , required by the fact that we increased yt by ", and by our insistence that xt+2 be unchanged, is ("). The notation (") emphasizes that , the change in yt+1 , depends on, ", the change in yt . Using the growth function, we have xt+2 = (xt+1 ") + F (xt+1 ") (yt+1 + (")) : (I.2) We require that the total change in xt+2 – including the changes in both periods t and t + 1, be zero, i.e., dxt+2 = 0. d" Using this condition, and di¤erentiating both sides of equation I.2 implies dxt+2 d" =0= 1+ dF (xt+1 ) dxt+1 dxt+1 d" d d" = 1+ d d" ) dF (xt+1 ) dxt+1 1 dF (xt+1 ) dxt+1 d d" =0) (I.3) : The …rst line di¤erentiates both sides of equation I.2 with respect to ", using the chain rule. We use equation I.1 to eliminate dxd"t+1 to obtain the equation after the …rst “)”, and rearrange that equation to obtain the second line. The last line of equation I.3 provides the …rst piece of information: the required reduction in yt+1 , given that we increase yt by ", and given that we want to keep xt+2 unchanged. A one unit increase in yt leads to a one unit t+1 ) direct reduction in xt+1 and dFdx(xt+1 units loss in growth; the loss in growth a¤ects xt+2 . Therefore, if we increase yt by " units, we must decrease yt+1 by t+1 ) 1 + dFdx(xt+1 " units, to o¤set both the direct e¤ect on xt+2 and the indirect e¤ect that occurs via the reduced growth. 387 Under the candidate trajectory, periods t and t + 1 current value contribution to the total payo¤ is t times pt C xt yt + pt+1 C xt+1 yt+1 : Under the perturbation, these two periods contribute g (") = pt C xt (yt + ") + pt+1 C xt+1 " t times yt+1 (yt+1 + ) : If the candidate is optimal, then a perturbation must lead to a zero …rst order change in the gain function. Using the product and the quotient rules, we have h i dg(") C C C d y + pt+1 xt+1 d" = = p t xt + d" j"=0 x2t+1 t+1 h i dF (xt+1 ) C C C p t xt + y pt+1 xt+1 1 + dxt+1 =0) x2t+1 t+1 i h C t+1 ) pt xCt = pt+1 xt+1 1 + dFdx(xt+1 + x2C yt+1 t+1 The last line is the Euler Equation 16.4. 388APPENDIX I. THE EULER EQUATION FOR THE SOLE OWNER FISHERY Appendix J Dynamics of the sole owner …shery This appendix derives the continuous time analog of the Euler equation, and then derives the di¤erential equation for harvest. J.1 Derivation of equation 17.2 We could have begun with a continuous time problem, and derived equation 17.2 directly. That approach is mathematically preferable, but it requires methods that we have not discussed. Therefore, we proceed mechanically, taking equation 16.7 as our starting point, and showing how to manipulate it to produce the continuous time analog, equation 17.2. We need to have in mind a unit of time. Because we want the discrete time and the continuous time models to be “close to each other”, the unit of time should be small. As in Chapter 14.3, we begin with the model in which one period equals one unit of time, and then divide that period into smaller subperiods. Mechanically, we do this by replacing the number 1, the length of a period, with . We also need to rewrite the discount factor as 1 Using the growth equation = 1+1 r instead of = 1+r xt+ xt = [F (xt ) we replace F (xt ) and y (xt ) with F (xt ) dF (xt+1 ) and dxt+1 389 y (xt )] ; and y (xt ) . Thus, the terms C yt+1 x2t+1 390 APPENDIX J. DYNAMICS OF THE SOLE OWNER FISHERY in equation 16.7 become, respectively, dF (xt+ ) dxt+ and C x2t+ yt+ : These substitutions mean that instead of having the length of a period be one unit of time (e.g. one minute), we now have the length of a period be units of time. With these substitutions, we rewrite equation 16.7 as Rt = 1 Rt+ 1+ r 1+ dF (xt+ ) dxt+ + C x2t+ yt+ (J.1) : Subtract Rt+ from both sides of equation J.1 and collect terms on the right side to rewrite the result as Rt Rt+ = 1 1+ r 1 Rt+ + 1 Rt+ 1+ r Divide both sides of this equation by (Rt+ Rt ) = 1 1+ r 1 Rt+ + dF (xt+ ) dxt+ (Rt+ !0 Rt ) = 1 Rt+ 1+ r dRt and lim !0 dt C x2t+ yt+ dF (xt+ ) dxt+ 1 1+ r 1 + C x2t+ yt+ ! 0, using = lim !0 1 1 r 1+ r = r to write dRt = dt Multiplying through by J.2 Rt r : to write Now take the limit of both sides of this equation as lim + dF (xt ) dxt + C yt : x2t 1 gives equation 17.2. The di¤erential equation for harvest Chapter 17.3.2 uses the di¤erential equation for the sole owner harvest, dy = dt H (x; y). This appendix explains how we obtain this equation, i.e., how we obtain the function H (x; y). The procedure uses the equations of motion : J.2. THE DIFFERENTIAL EQUATION FOR HARVEST for the stock, the rent, and the de…nition of rent. equations: dx = F (x) y dt dRt dt dF (xt ) dxt = Rt r Rt = p (yt ) 391 We repeat these three C y x2t t (J.2) C xt The …rst equation is merely the constraint of the problem, i.e. it is “data” (given to us). The second equation is the Euler equation, expressed in terms of rent. Both of these equations are the continuous time versions of the discrete time model. The third equation is the de…nition of rent. Because the third equation holds identically with respect to time (i.e., it holds at every instant of time), we can di¤erentiate it with respect to time to write h i C d p (yt ) xt dyt C dxt dRt = = p0 (yt ) + 2 yt dt dt dt xt dt We can use the …rst two lines of equation J.2 to eliminate write Rt r dF (xt ) dxt dyt C C y = p0 (yt ) + 2 yt (F (x) 2 t xt dt xt dRt dt and dxt , dt to y) : We can now use the third line of equation J.2 to eliminate Rt , to write p (yt ) C xt r Solving this equation for p (yt ) dy = dt C xt dyt C C y = p0 (yt ) + 2 yt (F (x) 2 t xt dt xt dF (xt ) dxt r dyt dt y) : gives dF (xt ) dxt C y x2t t p0 (yt ) C y x2t t (F (x) y) = H (xt ; yt ) The middle expression is a function of only x and y, and the model parameters. We de…ne this expression as the function H (xt ; yt ). This function looks complicated, but for the functional forms and the parameter values in our example, it simpli…es to dy 500:0yx + 80:0yx2 = 0:000 02 dt 28:0x2 + 195:0x + 750:0 = H (xt ; yt ) : x 392 APPENDIX J. DYNAMICS OF THE SOLE OWNER FISHERY Chapter 17.3.2 uses this function to construct the y isocline, the set of points = 0. This isocline is given by where dy dt dy =0)y= dt J.3 1 10x (0:08x 0:5) 0:28x2 + 1: 95x + 7: 5 : Finding the full solution In order to …nd the solution to the optimization problem, needed to construct the dotted curve in Figure 17.2, we take the ratio of the di¤erential equation for y and the di¤erential equation for x, to obtain a new di¤erential equation, showing how y changes with changes in x: dy dt dx dt = dy H (xt yt ) = : dx F (x) y The solution to this equation is a function giving the optimal harvest as a function of the stock, the optimal “harvest rule”. Denote this function as y = Y (x). Figure 17.2 shows the graph of Y (x), the dotted curve. Solving the di¤erential equation to obtain the optimal harvest rule, Y (x), requires a “boundary condition”, giving the value of y at some value of x. Our boundary condition is given by the steady state, denoted (x1 ; y1 ). We calculate the steady state by …nding the intersection of the x and the y isoclines. Our boundary condition is y (x1 ) = y1 . Some numerical algorithms encounter a problem in solving the di¤erential dy vanish at the equation, because both the numerator and denominator of dx steady state, making the ratio an indeterminate form. This problem is easily resolved, but involves methods beyond the scope of this book. We can linearize our original non-linear system and use the eigenvector associated with the stable eigenvalue to replace the boundary condition (the steady state) with a point on the “stable” eigenvector. We have to (numerically) solve the resulting initial value problem twice, once beginning with a point slightly below the steady state, and then beginning with a point slightly above the steady state. Figure 17.2 shows the …rst of these two parts of the solution. The dotted curve in Figure 17.2 shows the graph of the optimal harvest level, as a function of the stock, x. Harvest is positive only when the stock is above 3. As the stock increases over time, the harvest rises. The harvest is J.3. FINDING THE FULL SOLUTION 393 nearly constant, once the stock reaches about 20 or 25. The stock continues to grow to its steady state, and the harvest changes very little. 394 APPENDIX J. DYNAMICS OF THE SOLE OWNER FISHERY Afterword The back matter often includes one or more of an index, an afterword, acknowledgements, a bibliography, a colophon, or any other similar item. In the back matter, chapters do not produce a chapter number, but they are entered in the table of contents. If you are not using anything in the back matter, you can delete the back matter TeX …eld and everything that follows it. 395 396 AFTERWORD Bibliography (????):. (????):. (????):. (????):. Abbott, J., and J. Wilen (2009): “Regulating of …sheries bycatch with common-pool output quoatas,”Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 57, 195–204. (2011): “Dissecting the tragedy: a spatial model of behavior in the commons,” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 62, 386–401. Administration, U. E. I. (2014): “Annual Energy Outlook 2014,”Discussion paper, DOE/IEA-0383(2014). Aker, J. (2010): “Information from markets near and far: Mobile phones and agricultural markets in Niger,”American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 2, 46–59. Aldy, J. (2013): “Eliminating Fossil Fuel Subsidies,”The Hamilton Project, Brookings. Alix-Garcia, J., A. de Janvry, E. Sadoulet, and J. Torres (2009): “Payment for eco-system services program,”in Payments for Environmental Services in Agricultural Landscapes, ed. by L. Lipper, T. Sakuyama, R. Stringer, and D. Zilberman, pp. 163 –188. FAO and Springer. 397 398 BIBLIOGRAPHY Aranson, R. (2012): “Property rights in …sheries: how much can Individual Transferable Quotas accomplish?,” Review of Environmental Economics and Policy, 10.1093/reep/res011. Arnason, R., K. Kelleher, and R. Willmann (2009): “The sunken billioms: the economic justi…cation for …sheries reform,”The World Bank, Agriculture and Rural Development. Auerbach, A., and J. Hines (2002): “Taxation and Economic E¢ cienc, vol. 1y,” in Handbook of Public Economics, ed. by A. Auerbach, and M. Feldstein, pp. 1347–1421. North Holland, Amsterdam. Barbier, E. (2011): Capitalizing on Nature: Ecosystems as Natural Assets. Cambridge University Press. Barrett, S. (2003): Environment and Statecraft. Oxford University Press. Berck, P., and M. Roberts (1996): “Natural-resource prices: Will they ever turn up?,” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 31, 65 –78. Boadway, R., and M. Keen (2009): “Theoretical perspectives on resource tax design,”Queens Economics Department Working Paper, No 1206. Bohn, H., and R. Deacon (2000): “Ownership risk, investment, and the use of natural resources,”American Economic Review, 90, 526–49. Bolster, J. (2015): “Where have all the cod gone?,” Opinion Pages, New York Times January 2. Bryce, R. (2015): “The hidden corn ethanol tax – How much does the Renewable Fuel Standard costs motorists?,” Manhattan Institute Issues Brief 32. CD Dii Maria, I. L., and E. van der Werf (2013): “Goiong full Circle: Demand-Side Constraints to the Green Paradox,”CESifo Working per No. 4152. Cerda, R. (2007): “Market power and primary commodity prices: the case of copper,”Applied Economics Letters, 14, 775–778. BIBLIOGRAPHY 399 Chermak, J. M., and R. Partick (1995): “A well-based cost function and the economics of exhaustible resources: The case of natural gas,”Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 28, 174–189. Coady, D., I. Parry, L. Sears, and B. Shang (2011): “How large are global energy subsidies?,”IMF Working Paper WP/15/105. Conover, C. (2010): “Congress should account for the excess burden of taxation,”Cato Institute, Policy Analysis, October 13, 2010. Costello, C. (2012): “Introduction to the symposium on rights-based …sheries management,” Review of Environmental Economics and Policy, 10.1093/reep/res011. Costello, C., S. Gaines, and J. Lynham (2008): “Can catch shares prevent …sheries collapse,”Science, 321, 1678–1681. Dasgupta, P. (2001): Human Well-Being and the Natural Environment. Oxford University Press. Dasgupta, P., and G. Heal (????): Economic Thoery and Exhaustible Resources. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. (1974): “The optimal depletion of exhaustible resources,” The Review of Economic Studies, 41, 3–28. Daubanes, J., and S. A. de Sa (2014): “Taxing the rent of non-renewable resource sectors: a theoretical note,”OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No 1149. Deacon, R. (2012): “Fishery management by harvester coops,” Review of Environmental Economics and Policy, 10.1093/reep/res011. Deacon, R., D. Parker, and C. Costello (2013): “Reforming …sheries: lessons from a self-selected coopeartive,” Journal of Law and Economics, 56, 83–125. Dietz, T., E. Ostrom, and P. C. Stern (2003): “The Struggle to Govern the Commons,”Science, 302(5652), 1907–1912. 400 BIBLIOGRAPHY Diewert, W. E., D. A. Lawrence, and F. Thompson (1998): “The marginal cost of taxation and regulation,”in Handbook of Public Finance, ed. by F. Thomson, and M. T. Green, p. xx. Marcel Decker, New York. Dyck, A., and U. R. Sumaila (2010): “Economic impact of ocean …sh populations in the global …shery,”Journal of Bioeconomics, 12, 227–43. Ellerman, A., and J. Montero (1998): “The declining trend in sulfur dioxide emissions: implications for allowance prices,”Journal of Environmental Economics and Policy, 36, 26–45. Ellis, G., and R. Halvorsen (2002): “Estimation of market power in a nonrenewable resource industry,” The Journal of Political Economy, 110, 883–899. Fama, E., and K. French (2004): “The Capital Asset Pricing Model: Theory and evidence,”Journal of Economic Perspectives, 18, 25–46. Farzin, Y. (1984): “The e¤ect of the discount rate on depeletion of exhaustible resources,”Journal of Political Economy, 92, 841–51. Feldstein, M. (1977): “The surprising incidence of a tax on pure rent: a new answer to an old question,”Journal of Political Economy, 85, 349–360. Fenichel, E. P., and J. K. Abbott (2014): “Natural Capital: From Metaphor to Measurement,”Journal of the Association of Environmental and Resource Economics, 1, 1–27. Fenske, J. (2012): “Imachi Nkwu: trade and the commons,”CSAE Working Paper WPS/2012-19. Fisher, A. (1981): Resource and Environmental Economics. Cambridge University Press. Fowlie, M. (2009): “Incomplete Environmental Regulation, Imperfect Competition, and Emissions Leakage,”American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 1, 72–112. Fowlie, M., S. Holland, and E. Mansur (2012): “What do emissions markets deliver and to whome? Eveidence from Southern California’s NOx trading program,”American Economic Review, 102, 965 –993. BIBLIOGRAPHY 401 Fowlie, M., and J. Perloff (2013): “Distributing pollution rights in Capand-Trade programs: are outcomes independent of allocation?,”Review of Economics and Statistics, 95, 1640–1652. Gentry, W. (2007): “A review of the evidence of the incidence of the Corporate Income Tax,”US Department of Treasury, OTA Paper 101. Gerlgh, R. (2011): “Too much oil,” CESifo Economic Studies, pp. 79 – 102. Glaeser, E., and J. Kohlhase (????): “Cities, regions, and the decline of transport costs,” Papers in Regional Science, 83, 197–228, DOI: 10.1007/s10110-003-0183-x. Gordon, H. S. (1954): “The Economic Theory of a Common-Property Resource: The Fishery,”Journal of Political Economy, 62, 124–142. grafton, R. Q., T. Kompas, and R. Hilborn (????):. Guadet, G. (2007): “Natural resource economics under the Rule of Hotelling,”Presidential address, Canadian Economics Association. Halvorsen, R., and T. Smith (1991): “A test of the theory of exhaustible resources,”Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106, 123–140. Hamilton, J. (2011): “Nonlinearities and the macroeconomic e¤ects of oil prices,”Macroeconomic Dynamics, 15, 364–378. Hardin, G. (1968): “The Tragedy of the Commons,” Science, 162(3859), 1243–1248. Hartwick, J., and N. Olewiler (1986): The Economics of Natural Resource Use. Harper and Row, New York. Heal, G., and M. Barrow (1980): “The relationship between interest rates and metal-price movements,” Review of Economic Studies, 47, 161– 182. Hnyilicza, E., and R. Pindyck (1976): “Pricing policies for a two-part exhaustible resource cartel: the Case of OPEC,” European Economic Review, 8, 139–154. 402 BIBLIOGRAPHY Hoel, M. (2008): “Bush meets Hotelling: the e¤ects of improved renewable energy technology on greenhouse gas emissions,” University of Oslo Working Paper. (2012): “The supply side of CO2 with country heterogeneity,”Scandanavian Journal of Economics, 113, 846–865. Holland, S. (2012): “Emissions taxes versus intensity standards: Secondbest environmental policies with incomplete regulation,”Journal of Environmetnal Economics and Management, 63, 375–87. Holland, S., J. Hughes, C. Knittel, and N. Parker (2015): “Some inconvenient truths about climate change policy: the distributional impacts of tranportation policies,” Review of Economics and Statistics, p. xxx. Homans, F. R., and J. Wilen (1997): “A model of regulated open access resource use,”Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 32, 1–21. (2005): “Markets and rent dissipation in regulated open access …sheries,”Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 49, 381– 404. Hotelling, H. (1931): “The economics of exhaustible resources,” Journal of Political Economy, 39, 137–175. IEA, OPEC, OECD and World Bank (2011): “Joint report by IEA, OPEC, OECD and World Bank on fossil-fuel and other subsidies,” Discussion paper. Interagency Working Group (2013): “Technical update of the Social Cost of Carbon,”Discussion paper. International Scientific Committee for Tuna (2011): “Report of the Albacore Working Group Stock Assessment Workshop,”. Johnson, R., and G. Libcap (1982): “Contracting problems and regulation: the case of the …sheryl,” American Economic Review, 72, 1005 – 1022. BIBLIOGRAPHY 403 Judd, K. (1985): “Redistributive taxation in a simple perfect foresight model,”Journal of Public Economics, 28, 59–83. Kaffine, D. (2003): “Quality and the Commons: the surf gangs of California,”Journal of Law and Economics, 52, 727–743. Karp, L., and I. H. Lee (2003): “Time Consistent Policies,” Journal of Economic Theory, 112(2), 353–364. Karp, L., and M. Stevensonl (2012): “Green Industrial Policy : Trade and Theory,” World Bank Working Paper, https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/handle/10986/12081. Kilian, L. (2009): “Not all oil price shocks are alike: Disentangling demand and supply shocks in the crude oil market,” American Economic Review, 99, 1053–1069. Krautkraemer, J. (1998): “Nonrenewable resource scarcity,” Journal of Economic Literature, 36, 2065–2107. Kronenberg, T. (2008): “Should we worry about failure of the Hotelling Rule?,”Journal of Economic Surveys, 22, 774–793. Kurlansky, M. (1998): Cod: a Biography of the Fish that Changed the World. Penguin Books. Lee, J., J. A. List, and M. Strazicich (2006): “Nonrenewable resource prices: deterministic or stochastic trends?,” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 51, 354–370. Leonhardt, D. (2012): “A Climate proposal beyond cap and trade,”New York Times, October 12. Lin, C., and G. Wagner (2007): “Steady state growth in a Hotelling Model of resource extraction,” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 54, 68–83. Lipsey, R., and K. Lancaster (1956): “The General Theory of Second BestF,”Review of Economic Studies, 24, 11–32. Livernois, J. (2009): “On the emprical signi…cance of the Hotelling rule,” Review of Environmental Economics and Policy, 3, 21–41. 404 BIBLIOGRAPHY Livernois, J., H. Thille, and X. Zhang (2006): “A test of the Hotelling Rule using old-growth timber,”Canadian Journal of Economics, 39, 163– 186. Livernois, J., and R. Uhler (1987): “Extraction costs and the economics of nonrenewable resources,”Journal of Political Economy, 95, 1195–203. Lund, D. (2009): “Rent taxation for nonrenewable resources,” Annual Review of Resource Economics, 1, 10.1146/annurev.resource.050708.144216. McAusland, C. (2003): “Voting for Pollution Policy: The Importance of Income Inequality and Openness to Trade,” Journal of International Economics, 61(2), 425–51. (2008): “Trade, Politics and the Environment: Tailpipe vs.Smokestack,” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 55, 52–71. Miller, M., and C. Upton (1985): “A test of the Hotelling valuation principle,”Journal of Political Economy, 93, 1–25. Newell, R., J. Sanchirico, and S. Kerr (2005): “Fishing quota markets,” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 49, 437– 462. Okum, A. (1975): Equality and E¢ ciency: The Big Tradeo¤. The Brookings Institution. Ostrom, E. (1990): Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action. Cambridge University Press. (2007): “A Diagnostic Approach for Going beyond Panaceas,”Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 104(39), 15181–15187. Pindyck, R. (1978): “The optimal exploration and production of nonrenewable resources,”Journal of Political Economy, 86, 841–861. (1980): “Uncertainty and exhaustible resource markets,”Journal of Political Economy, 86, 841–61. (1987): “On monopoly power in extractive resource markets,”Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 14, 128–142. BIBLIOGRAPHY 405 (1999): “The long-run evolution of energy prices,”Energy Journal, 20, 1–27. Prakash, A., and M. Potoski (2007): “Collective Action through Voluntary Environmental Programs: A Club Theory Perspective,”Policy Studies Journal, 35, 773–792. Reuterst (2014): “Shell says fossil fuel reserves won’t be ’stranded’ by climate regualtion,”May 19. Schaefer, M. (1954): “Some aspects of the dynamics of population important to the management of commercial marine …sheries,” Bulletin of the InterAmerican Tropical Tuna Commission, 1, 26–56. Sen, A. (1987): On Ethics and Economics. Blackwell. Service, N. M. F. (2009): “Status of Fisheries of the United States: A Report to Congress,”. Sharp, R., and U. Sumaila (2009): “Quanti…cation of U.S. marine subsidies,”North American Journal of Fisheries Management, 29, 18 –32. Sinn, H. (2008): “Public Policies against Global Warming: A Supply Side Approach,”International Tax and Public Finance, 15, 360–394. Sinn, H. W. (2012): The Green Paradox. Massachusetts Institute of Technology. Slade, M. (1984): “Tax policy and the supply of exhaustible resources,” Land Economics, 60, 133 –47. Slade, M., and H. Thille (1997): “Hotelling confronts CAPM: a test of the theory of exhaustible resources,”Canadian Journal of Economics, 30, 685 –708. (2009): “Whither Hotelling: Tests of the Theory of Exhaustible Resources,”Annual Review of Resource Economics, 1, 239–259. Smith, M. (2012): “The new …sheries econom: Incentives across many margins,”Annual Review of Resource Economics, 4, 379–402. 406 BIBLIOGRAPHY Solow, R. (1974): “The economics of resources or the resources of economics,”American Economic Review, 64, 1–14. Squires, D., and N. Vestergaard (2013): “Technical change and the commons,”The Review of Economics and Statistics, 95, 1769–1787. Stollery, K. R. (2008): “Mineral depletion with cost as the extraction limit,” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 10, 151– 65. Sumailia, U., W. Cheung, V. Lam, D. Pauly, and S. Herrick (2011): “Climate change impacts on the biophysics and economics of world …sheries,”Nature Climate Change, doi:10.1038/nclimate1301. Sumailia, U., V. Lam, F. Le Manach, W. Wartz, and D. Pauly (2013): “Global Fisheries Subsidies,”Report to European Parliament. Tietenberg, T. (2006): Environmental and Natural resource Economics, 7th ed. Pearson, Boston. Tritch, R. (2015): “President Obama could unmask big political donors,” The New York Times, March 24. Tsur, Y., and A. Zemel (2003): “Optimal transition to backstop substitutes for nonrenewable resources,”Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 27, 551–572. United Nations (2005): Millennium Ecosystem Assessment. United Nations, http://www.maweb.org/en/index.aspx. van der Ploeg, R., and C. Withagen (2012): “Is there really a green paradox?,” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 64, 342–363. van der Werf, E., and C. Di Maria (2012): “Imperfect environmental policy and polluting emissions: the green paradox and beyond,” International Review of Environmental Resource Economicst, 6, 153–194. Vennemo, H., K. Aunan, F. Jingua, P. Hotedahl, H. Tao, and H. Seip (2006): “DOMESTIC ENVIRONMENTAL BENEFITS OF CHI¼´ZS ENERGY-RELATED CDM POTENTIAL,” Climactic Change, NAâA 75, 215–239. BIBLIOGRAPHY 407 Weninger, Q. (1999): “Assessing e¢ ciency gains from individual transferable quota: an application to the Mid-Atlantic surf clam and ocean quahog …shery,”American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 80, 750–764. Weninger, Q., and J. R. Waters (2003): “Economic bene…ts of management reform in the northern Gulf of Mexico reef …sh …shery,” Journal of Environmental Economcis and Managment, 46, 207–230. Wilen, J., J. Cancion, and H. Uchida (2012): “The economics of Territorial Use Rights Fisheries,” Review of Environmental Economics and Policy, 10.1093/reep/res011. Winter, R. (2014): “Innovation and the Dynamic of Global Warming,” Journal of Environmental Economic and Management, 68, 124–140. WorldBank (2014): “State and Trends of Carbon Pricing 2014,” Discussion paper, World Bank Group Climate Change. Zhang, J., and M. D. Smith (2011): “Estmation of a generalized …shery model,”Review of Economics and Statistics, 93, 690–99.
© Copyright 2024