JAMES M. POTERBA MassachusettsInstituteTechnology ANDREW A. SAMWICK Dartmouth College Stock Ownership Patterns, Stock Market Fluctuations, and Consumption the last year has raisedthe total value of corporate stock in the United States by nearly a trillion dollars. While many analystshave tried to explain or interpretthe recent movementsof the stock market, there has been less attentionto the link between rising stock prices and real economic activity. How are the gains from an increasein shareprices distributedacrosshouseholds?Whatfractionof these gains accrues to a small set of wealthy investors?How do rising stock prices affect consumerspending? The standardtextbooktreatmentof aggregateconsumptionholds that consumptiondepends on labor income and financialwealth.' The marginal propensity to consume out of wealth is typically taken to be approximately0.04 per year. In this framework,the wealth effect of a stock marketrally should have an importantstimulativeeffect on consumption.Althoughthis view neglects some potentiallyimportantfactorsthatmight also affect consumptiondirectly(notably,the possibility that stock prices may rise as a result of a decline in real interestrates), THE BULL MARKET of We are gratefulto Rochelle Antoniewicz, JohnCampbell,Joel Dickson, JerryHausman, N. Gregory Mankiw, Thomas Morley, Chris Probyn, James Shapiro, Robert Shiller, AndreiShleifer, David Shulman,ChristopherSims, JustinSmith, MarthaStarrMcCluer, David Wilcox, and participantson the BrookingsPanel and at a seminarat the FederalReserve Boardfor helpful discussions. We also thankAlex David for data on share repurchasesand, especially, ArthurKennickellfor assistance with the 1992 Survey of ConsumerFinances. This researchwas supportedby the National Science Foundation. 1. See, for example, Dornbuschand Fischer(1994). 295 296 BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity, 2:1995 many economic forecastersembracethe textbook view. For example, a recent Wall Street research report explains that "as long as asset prices are rising, the risk of a significantdrop in consumerspendingis small," and notes that the rising numberof stockholdershas "made real economic activity more tied to the performanceof financialassets than ever before."2 This paperdescribes the changingpatternof stock ownershipduring the last three decades, investigates whether changing ownership patterns have, in fact, altered the links between stock values and consumption,and explores the "wealth effect" of stock price fluctuations. At the outset it is importantto recognize that an increase in consumer spendingfollowing a rise in shareprices could be attributableto either of two factors. First, stock prices may rise in anticipationof strong economic activity, including consumer spending. The role of share prices as a leading indicatoris well documented.In this case changes in stock marketvalues are not a source of subsequentchanges in consumption, but merely an indicator that subsequent changes are expected. A second, and not necessarily exclusive, link between stock prices and consumptionis the wealth effect; that is, changes in share values cause changes in consumption by relaxing the resource constraintsthat households face. Over long horizons, theremust be such a wealth effect; we consider whether there is also an importantwealth effect on consumptionat horizons of one to four quarters.It is difficult to distinguishbetween the leading indicatorand causativeviews of the relationshipbetweenshareprices andconsumptionbecausethis requires identifying autonomousmovements in share prices that are not attributable to changing expectations of futuredividends or interestrates. This paperpresents new evidence on the association between share price movements and consumption. It summarizesthe changes in consumptionthathave typically followed substantialchanges in stock market values, and presentsseveral tests directedat disentanglingthe leading indicatorand wealth effect views. If the leading indicatorview is correct, the patternof consumptionchanges following stock price fluctuations should be independentof the distributionof stock ownership and there is no reason to expect differentconsumptionresponses from householdsthat do and do not own corporatestock. This paperpresents 2. Shulman,Usem, and Brown (1995). James M. Poterba and AndrewA. Samwick 297 empiricaltests of both of these propositions. It finds little evidence of an importantwealth effect of share prices on consumption.The strong positive correlationbetweenconsumptiongrowthandlagged stock market returns,therefore, appearsto be primarilydue to the leading indicator featureof stock price movements. We begin by placing the 1995 stock marketincrease in context. We reporton the evolution of price-to-dividendand price-to-earningsratios, Tobin's q, and the ratio of stock marketvalue to GDP duringthe post-World War II period. Some of these measures, notably Tobin's q, suggest that the stock marketof 1995 is at a postwarvaluationhigh. Others, notably the price-to-earningsratio, suggest a less extreme situation. We next investigate the fraction of stock marketcapital gains that accrue directly to individual investors, in contrastto gains that accrue to them indirectly, through financial intermediariessuch as defined benefit pension plans or life insurancecompanies. A range of recent behavioralmodels of consumptionsuggest thatthe marginalpropensity to spend out of different types of assets depends not only on their risk and returncharacteristics,but also on the way in which they are held.3 Households may exhibit lower marginalpropensitiesto spend out of capital gains on assets that are held in retirementplans than on assets that are held directly. Popular discussions sometimes note that the fraction of corporate stock owned by householdshas declined duringthe postwarperiod and is currentlyless than 50 percent.4In fact, the principalpostwar trend has been away from direct individual stock ownership and toward indirect ownership throughvarious financial intermediaries.This paper reanalyzesthe widely cited Flow of Fundsdata of the FederalReserve Boardthat show householdsowning less than50 percentof outstanding shares. Combining individual ownership of equities through mutual funds, definedcontributionpension plans, and other financialintermediaries, it is apparentthat individuals have direct control over nearly two-thirdsof outstandingcorporatestock. To describe the changing incidence of stock ownershipwe examine 3. Thaler(1994) providesa summaryof this literature. 4. See, for example, "IndividualsLose MarketShare," New YorkTimes, July 18, 1995, p. D21, and "Small Investor Continuesto Give Up Controlof Stocks," Wall StreetJournal, May 11, 1992, p. C1. 298 BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity, 2:1995 data from the 1962 Survey of FinancialCharacteristicsof Consumers, and the 1983 and 1992 Surveys of ConsumerFinances. While share ownership patternschanged relatively little between 1962 and 1983, therehas been a substantialincrease in the prevalenceof shareownership duringthe last decade. This growth is the result of rising rates of indirect share ownership. The fraction of stock held by the largest stockholders,those in the top 0.5 percentof the distributionof equity investors, has also declined duringthis period. To develop evidence that can distinguish between the leading indicator and the wealth effect views of how shareprices affect consumption, the paper explores the correlationbetween stock returnsand the compositionof consumerspending. If there is a wealth effect, positive stock returnsshould increase the share of consumptionaccountedfor by luxury goods. We consider aggregatedata on several categories of consumption that are disproportionatelypurchased by high-income households, including "upperluxury" vehicles, andfindlittle evidence that luxury spending rises in the wake of rising stock prices. The paper considers whether changing patternsof stock ownership affect the linkages between consumptionand stock marketfluctuations. The leading indicatorview suggests that ownershippatternsshould not affect this relationship, while the wealth effect at least admitsthe possibility. We explore the effect of changes in stock prices, as well as changesin the dividend-to-priceandearnings-to-priceratios, on various measures of consumption.5We recognize that stock prices and consumptionarejointly determined,and simply try to describethe typical patternof economic activity following substantialstock price movements. Ourresults suggest thatchanges in stock prices have significant predictivepower for futureconsumptionspending. A permanentstock price rise of 17 percent (roughly the same magnitudeas the price increase in the first six months of 1995) forecasts an increase of about 1.1 percent in consumption in mid-1996, relative to what it would otherwisehave been. Increases in consumerspendingon new automobiles and other durableswould be particularlylarge. We find little evidence to suggest thatthe shift fromdirectto indirect ownershipof corporatestock has alteredthe link between stock price 5. Fama(1981), FischerandMerton(1984), andBarro(1990) also estimatereducedform equations measuringthe predictivepower of stock price movementsfor various macroeconomicaggregates. James M. Poterba and AndrewA. Samwick 299 fluctuationsand consumptionspending, and more generally, little evidence of an importantwealth effect on consumption. Since the timeseries variationin the patternof corporatestock ownershipyields tests with low statisticalpower, we also use household survey datafrom the Panel Study of Income Dynamics to comparethe correlationbetween stock marketfluctuationsand growth in consumptionfor stockholders with direct and indirectholdings. We find some evidence that the consumptionof individuals who hold stocks throughthrift plans, such as 401(k)s, 403(b)s, and ESOPs, is more sensitive to stock price movements than the consumptionof those who do not hold any stock; but once again, the available tests have low power. We do not find any evidence that the effect of share prices on consumption depends on the source of stock price movements. This is somewhatsurprising,given the substantialbody of researchin financial economics suggesting that price fluctuationsthat change the value of the dividend-to-priceor earnings-to-priceratios are often reversedover a period of several years. Recent Stock Market Fluctuations in Perspective The stock markethas climbed to record heights in the last year. In the six monthsafterthe Dow Jones IndustrialAverage firstreachedthe historic four thousandlevel on February23, 1995, it climbed another seven hundredpoints. And before the end of 1995, the Dow index had closed at well above five thousand. Between January1 and June 30, 1995, the Standardand Poor's 500-stock index (S&P 500) rose by nearly 17 percent.6Although the news media have depicted the recent bull marketas unprecedented,recent returnsare not extraordinary.In twenty of the sixty-eight years between 1926 and 1993, the real return on stocks of large corporationsexceeded 20 percent. In five of those years the real returnexceeded 40 percent.7 To provide backgroundfor analyzing the aggregateeffects of stock price movements, table 1 presentsseveral summarystatistics. The first column shows the real value of the S&P 500 in units comparableto its 6. We calculate this as ln(539.4/455.2) = 0. 1697, which we approximateas 17 percent. 7. These statistics are based on IbbotsonAssociates (1994). 300 BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity, 2:1995 Table 1. Real Valueof the Stock Market, 1955-95 Unitsas indicated Year Real value of S&P 500" 1955 253.4 ... 1,643.5 1956 1957 1958 1959 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995c 251.9 212.6 277.1 300.7 285.3 358.0 308.5 359.3 402.8 431.8 370.1 420.8 449.0 361.8 338.7 361.2 413.9 307.1 193.5 239.3 269.2 226.2 212.5 210.4 231.5 197.1 213.8 242.9 233.8 283.9 336.8 312.6 343.5 413.8 367.8 421.8 459.6 478.4 455.2 539.4 -0.6 - 15.6 30.3 8.5 -5.1 25.5 - 13.8 16.5 12.1 7.2 - 14.3 13.7 6.7 - 19.4 - 6.4 6.6 14.6 - 25.8 - 37.0 23.7 12.5 - 16.0 -6.0 - 1.0 10.1 - 14.9 8.4 13.6 - 3.7 21.4 18.6 - 7.2 9.9 20.5 -11.1 14.7 9.0 4.1 -4.9 18.5 1,712.1 1,479.9 2,039.2 2,169.8 2,134.7 2,710.7 2,339.0 2,719.3 3,105.6 3,459.7 3,005.0 3,687.8 4,200.4 3,374.7 3,164.8 3,597.0 3,978.3 2,875.5 1,730.4 2,158.4 2,721.8 2,271.9 2,191.9 2,293.7 2,662.2 2,265.5 2,471.2 2,837.1 2,631.3 3,232.3 3,743.8 3,604.9 3,849.9 4,522.7 3,949.7 5,279.8 5,763.2 6,352.0 6,048.8 7,167.8 Percentagechange in real S&P 500 Real valueof corporatestock" Source: Data on the S&P 500 and the CPI-U are from Data Resources Inc. The real value of corporate stock is from the Federal Reserve, Flow of Funds Accounts. a. Real S&P 500 is benchmarked for June 1995. Earlier values are computed using the average S&P index for each December and the CPI-U. b. Billions of 1994 dollars. c. Entries for 1995 relate to June; the real value of corporate stock for this year is the authors' estimate. James M. Poterba and AndrewA. Samwick 301 1994 value. The second column presents the real annual percentage change in the index. This column does not correspondto the returnon the marketbecause it excludes income from dividends. It confirmsthat there have been other years with returnscomparableto those in 1995. The thirdcolumn shows the real value of corporatesharesat the end of each year, in 1994 dollars, as reportedin the Flow of Funds accounts. Real equity values increasedby morethan$ 1.1 trillionin the six months ending June 30, 1995.8 While the increase in shareprices duringthe last year is not unprecedented, some measuresof stock marketvaluationdo suggest that the stock marketis currentlyat a post-World WarII high. Table 2 reports four different valuation measures. The first column shows the ratio of the marketvalue of corporatestock to GDP. On June 30, 1995, this ratio was 1.039, a level that has been exceeded only once since the early 1950s, in 1968. It has more than doubled in just over ten years. The table records one previous move of similar magnitude, when the ratio doubled between the early 1950s and the early 1960s.9 The second column of table 2 shows the year-endprice-to-earnings ratio for the S&P 500; this ratio is also plotted in figure 1. Price-toearningsratiosdo not suggest that stocks are currentlyat historichighs. The recent stock price rise has coincided with rapidly increasingcorporateearnings, so that while the price-to-earningsratio in mid-1995 (16.3) is above its postwaraveragevalue, it is substantiallylower than at the end of 1991 (26.2) or of 1992 (22.8). Since late 1991 shareprices have increased by nearly 30 percent, while earnings have more than doubled. Because earnings fluctuatesubstantiallyfrom year to year, it can be helpful to construct alternativevaluation measuresthat divide share prices by a moving average of real earnings. We do this with a ten-year arithmetic average of real earnings for the S&P 500. The 8. The change in the marketvalue of equity duringany periodreflectsthe change in the value of the shares that were outstandingat the beginning of the periodplus the valueof any new sharesissuedduringthe period.If firmsare issuingsubstantialamounts of new equity, changes in the marketvalue of stock can overstatethe rateof shareprice appreciation.In each quarterof 1994 and in the first two quartersof 1995, however, nonfinancialcorporationswere net repurchasersof shares, so this concern does not apply. 9. A similar patternemerges if we consider the marketvalue of corporateequity plus an estimateof the marketvalue of corporatedebt, which is computedby capitalizing corporateinterestpaymentsby the BAA bond rate, relativeto GDP. 302 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2:1995 Table2. RelativeMeasures of CorporateShare Values, 1947-95 Unitsas indicated Year 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995d Market valueof shareslGDP" ... ... ... ... ... 0.470 0.450 0.628 0.709 0.723 0.625 0.834 0.851 0.832 0.989 0.820 0.908 0.981 1.006 0.838 1.000 1.090 0.868 0.820 0.880 0.899 0.633 0.399 0.481 0.578 0.460 0.421 0.456 0.542 0.459 0.504 0.541 0.478 0.570 0.637 0.593 0.614 0.713 0.631 0.839 0.885 0.955 0.877 1.039 Price-to-earnings ratio' 9.5 6.6 7.2 7.2 9.7 11.1 9.9 13.0 12.6 13.7 11.9 19.1 17.7 17.8 22.4 17.2 18.7 18.6 17.8 14.5 18.1 18.0 15.9 18.0 17.9 18.4 12.0 7.7 11.3 10.8 8.7 7.8 7.3 9.2 8.0 11.1 11.8 10.1 14.5 16.7 14.1 11.7 15.5 15.5 26.2 22.8 21.3 15.0 16.3 Price-to-dividend ratio" 18.0 16.0 14.8 13.8 16.7 18.3 17.2 22.5 24.1 23.6 21.6 30.0 31.5 29.3 35.1 29.4 32.0 32.8 32.8 27.9 32.4 34.1 28.4 28.9 32.3 37.0 27.0 18.4 24.2 25.5 19.6 18.5 18.1 21.1 18.0 20.3 23.2 21.4 25.8 29.6 27.0 27.2 30.0 26.7 32.2 34.5 36.8 34.4 39.2 Tobin'sq 0.437 0.396 0.418 0.475 0.510 0.483 0.452 0.656 0.756 0.742 0.593 0.819 0.830 0.808 0.954 0.832 0.942 1.056 1.080 0.897 1.070 1.111 0.846 0.778 0.828 0.835 0.575 0.319 0.390 0.470 0.371 0.343 0.350 0.413 0.336 0.360 0.417 0.387 0.472 0.556 0.574 0.617 0.761 0.733 1.068 1.264 1.361 1.268 1.467 Source: Market value of stock is from Federal Reserve, Flow of Funds Accounts. Price-to-earnings and price-to-dividend ratios are from Data Resources Inc. Tobin's q is from the Balance Sheetsfor the U.S. Economy'. a. The market value of corporate stock (year-end value) divided by the fourth-quarterGDP for each year. b. The price-to-earnings ratio for the S&P 500, averaged for the last month of each calendar year. c. The price-to-dividend ratio for the S&P 500, averaged for the last month of each calendar year. The price-to-dividend ratio is the market value of equity in nonfinancial corporations divided by the replacement cost of their net assets, net of debt outstanding. d. Tobin's q for June 1995 is estimated by the authors. James M. Poterba and AndrewA. Samwick 303 Figure 1. Price-to-Earningsand Price-to-DividendRatios for the S&P 500, 1947-95 Ratio Price-to-dividend ratio 35 3025- A 20 - 15 Vr~ Price-to-earnings ,r/ I \ ratio 10 V J~V 5 I- I 1950 I 1955 I 1960 I 1965 I 1970 I 1975 1980 I 1985 I 1990 1 1995 Source: Data Resources Inc. resultingP-Eavgratio is 22.3 at the end of June 1995, up from 9.8 in 1980, 11.9 in 1985, and 15.7 in 1990. The June 1995 value is higher than any year-end value in the 1990s, although it is not the highest value recorded in the postwar period; it reached 23.3 at the end of 1965.10 Nevertheless, this valuationindicatorsuggests thatstock prices are high, relative to historical patterns. The rise in corporate earnings is evident in the national income accounts where corporateprofits adjustedfor capital consumptionand inventoryvaluationhave increasedas a shareof GNP from 5.6 percent in 1991 to 7.2 percentin 1994. The rateof returnon tangibleassets has also increased. Table 3 presentsrecentestimatesof a standardmeasure of the pretax rate of returnon the tangible assets of nonfinancialcor10. The values of PIEavgfor the early 1990s are as follows: 1990 = 15.7, 1991 = 18.4, 1992 = 20.3, 1993 = 21.2, and 1994 = 19.9. Table3. Rates of Return to NonfinancialCorporateCapital, 1947-95a Percent Year Unadjusted rate Cycle-adjusted rate 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 11.0 12.4 10.8 12.6 12.8 10.9 10.3 9.6 11.9 10.3 9.4 8.1 10.1 9.3 9.3 10.5 11.3 11.9 13.1 12.9 11.6 11.3 10.0 8.0 8.4 8.6 8.5 6.7 7.0 7.4 7.8 7.8 6.9 5.8 6.0 5.2 6.0 7.4 7.2 6.8 7.5 8.1 7.7 7.6 7.4 7.9 9.1 10.2 10.3 ... 11.4 10.9 12.4 11.5 9.4 8.8 9.6 11.2 9.5 8.6 8.6 9.9 9.1 9.8 10.4 11.2 11.6 12.4 11.9 10.6 10.2 8.8 7.6 8.5 8.6 8.0 6.6 8.5 8.4 8.5 8.0 6.9 6.6 7.0 7.2 8.1 8.3 8.0 7.4 7.8 7.9 7.5 7.5 7.9 8.8 9.7 10.3 10.2 Averages 1950-59 1960-69 1970-79 1980-89 10.6 11.1 7.7 6.8 10.0 10.6 8.0 7.6 Source: National Income and Product Accounts of the United States (NIPA) and Balance Sheels for ihe U.S. Economy. a. The return is computed as the ratio of pretax profits for the nonfinancial corporate sector, with the capital consumption adjustment and inventory valuation adjustment, plus net interest payments by nonfinancial corporations, divided by an estimate of the midyear value of the tangible assets held by these corporations. The value for 1995 is based on two quarters of profits and interest payouts, and an estimate of nonfinancial corporations' tangible assets as of March 31, 1995. James M. Poterba and AndrewA. Samwick 305 porations." In additionto the rate of returnshown in the first column, the table also reportsa business cycle-adjusted rate of return.To construct the adjusted return, we first regress the rate of return on the civilian unemploymentrate (RU), using a first-orderserial correlation correctionwith an autocorrelationcoefficient, p. This yields the following equation(with standarderrorsin parentheses): Return = 0.124 - 0.0052(RUt), (0.010) (0.0013) p = 0.845. (0.085) We then compute fitted values at the sample average unemployment rate of 5.61 percent.'2The adjustedand unadjustedseries are plotted in figure 2. The unadjustedrateof returnrose nearly3 percentagepointsbetween 1991 and 1994, and while the rate of returnin 1994 and 1995 is not as high as it was throughoutthe 1960s, it is higherthanat any point in the last twenty-fiveyears. The change in the cycle-adjustedreturnbetween 1992 and 1994 is less dramaticthan that of the unadjustedseries, but still suggests an increase of 1.5 percentagepoints.'3 In spite of this sharpincrease in earnings, corporatedividends have not risen during the last few years. The third column of table 2, and also figure 1, shows the price-to-dividendratio on the S&P 500. This reaches39.2 at the end of June 1995, the highest year-endvalue during the postwar period. Values of the price-to-dividendratio in excess of 30 have been recordedonly a few times duringthe last forty years: in the late 1950s and early 1960s, in the late 1960s, and in the mid-1990s. Onepotentialexplanationof risingprice-to-dividendratiosis a grow11. This measureof the rate of returnwas analyzedby Nordhaus(1974) and Feldstein and Summers(1977). For a discussionof alternativemeasuresof the rateof return, and of the effective tax rate on corporateearnings, see Feldstein, Dicks-Mireaux,and Poterba(1983). 12. Adding a time trendto this equationdoes not change the coefficienton RU. The time coefficient, -0.00051 (0.00034), provides weak supportfor a seculardecline in the corporateprofitrate. 13. We have also estimatedthe cycle-adjustmentequation,usingthe dummyvariable DUM94&95to allow for a shift in the level of profitsin 1994 and 1995. The resultsare: Return = 0.123 - (0.010) 0.0052(RU) + 0.0073(DUM94&95), p (0.0013) (0.0088) = 0.842. (0.086) If we also include a time trend, the coefficient on the trendis - 0.00067 (0.00031), and the coefficienton DUM94&95rises to 0.0136 (0.0093). 306 BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity, 2:1995 Figure 2. Return to Capital for NonfinancialCorporations, 1948-95 Percent r Unadjusted 13 1950 1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 Source: Authors' calculations using data from National Product and Income Accounts of the United States (NIPA) and Balancn e Sheets for the U.S. Economy. ing reliance on nondividend alternatives for returning cash to shareholders, such as share repurchases and cash purchases of stock in other companies. Repurchases, which historically had been very limited, became an important source of cash payout during the mid-1980s. Their importance declined in the late 1980s and early 1990s, and although it has increased in the last two years, it has not reached the level of the mid-1980s\.14 Table 4 tracks the role of nondividend cash payouts over the last fifteen years and suggests that these payouts cannot explain the recent rise in price-to-dividend ratios. The first column in table 4 shows the ratio of all cash payouts-to-cash dividends for nonfinancial corporations. This ratio, which was very close to one at the beginning of the 1980s, rose above 2 in the mid-1980s. It declined in the early 1990s, and has 14. Bagwell and Shoven (1989) describe the growth of share repurchasesin the 1980s, and the tax incentives for repurchasesratherthancash dividends. James M. Poterba and AndrewA. Samwick 307 Table4. Dividends and Other Cash Payoutsfor NonfinancialCorporations,1980-95 Year 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995d Totalcash payoutslcashdividends" 0.993 1.488 1.204 1.109 2.285 2.334 2.409 2.238 2.712 2.312 1.602 1.169 1.080 1.154 1.462 1.206 Priceldividendb 21.1 18.0 20.3 23.2 21.4 25.8 29.6 27.0 27.2 30.0 26.7 32.2 34.5 36.8 34.4 39.2 Priceltotal cashpayouts" 21.2 12.1 16.8 20.9 9.4 11.0 12.3 12.0 10.0 13.0 16.7 27.5 31.9 31.9 23.5 32.5 Source: Data on dividend payments for nonfinancial corporations are from N IPA, table 1. 16. Data on gross share purchases are from the Federal Reserve Board. The price-to-dividend ratio is from Data Resources Inc. a. Total cash payouts divided by cash dividends is the ratio of dividend payments plus gross share purchases by nonfinancial corporations, including both share repurchases and shares bought in corporate control transactions, to dividend payments by nonfinancial corporations. b. The price-to-dividend ratio for the S&P 500. c. Price divided by total cash payouts equals the price-to-dividend ratio (column two) divided by the ratio of total cash payouts to cash dividends (column one). d. Values for 1995 are estimates based on data for the first two quarters;price divided by dividends and price divided by total cash payouts are as of June 30, 1995. rangedbetween 1 and 1.5 in recentyears. The second andthirdcolumns present the price-to-dividendratio and the price-to-totalcash payout ratio, respectively, for the S&P 500. They show an even more rapid increasein shareprices relativeto total cash payoutsthanin shareprices relativeto dividends over 1988-95, because nondividendcash payouts have declined relative to cash dividends duringthe mid-1990s. The fourth column of table 2, as well as figure 3, shows Tobin's q ratiofor nonfinancialcorporations;thatis, the ratioof the marketvalue of their equity to the replacementcost of their tangible assets, net of outstandingdebt.'5 This ratio, which falls below 0.40 for a numberof 15. This ratio is computed by the Federal Reserve Board and published in the Balance Sheetsfor the U.S. Economy,June 8, 1995, table B 104, p. 37. Tangibleassets include plant, equipment, and residentialstructures,the replacementvalues of which are estimatedby the CommerceDepartmentusing a perpetualinventorymethod with adjustmentfor changingprices of investmentgoods, inventories,and land. The market value of land is estimated by the Federal Reserve Board. The book value of debt is 308 BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity, 2:1995 Figure 3. Stock Market-to-GDP Ratio and Tobin'sq, 1952-95 Marketvalue/GDP q ratio _ 2.50 1.10 A Stockmarket-to-GDP (left axis) 2.25 ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~ 07 \ 1.00 _/ I' / 'I .90. 0.90 0.80 0.70[_ 0.00 - (right axis) I I J I \ I 1.50 I A I I I- 01.25 0.40 - 1.00 0.300.75 0.20 -Tbn (right axis) ~~~~~~0.50 0.10 0.00 F0.25 1950 1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 Source: Authors' calculations using data from Federal Reserve, Flow of Funds Accounts. years between the mid-1970s and the early 1980s, is 1.27 at the end of 1994, and 1.47 at the end of June 1995. 16 The change in q over 199095 is unusual. The only comparablepercentagechange, a decline of more that 50 percent over a two-year period, took place between late 1972 and late 1974, the period of the first oil embargo. Moreover, the recent values are the highest recordedfor q duringthe postwarperiod. There are good reasons for suspecting that "average" q measures, subtractedfrom this estimateof asset replacementcost. This measureof q suffers from several limitations, notably, the failure to compute the marketvalue of debt and the absence of any correction for the present-discountedvalue of future tax shields, as implementedby Summers(1981). These factors are unlikely to result in large changes in the short-runmovementsin q. 16. Revisions to the Flow of Funds that are expected on December 15, 1995 will reducethe estimatedmarketvalue of equity in nonfinancialcorporations,therebyreducing the estimateof q for recentyears. The rise in the value of q in 1994-95, relativeto otherrecentyears, will not be affected. James M. Poterba and AndrewA. Samwick 309 such as those in table 2, are poor measuresof relative value for some types of firms. BronwynHall's extensive studyof the marketvalue and replacementcost of corporateassets in the 1980s makes it possible to illustratethis.'7 At the end of 1987, when the aggregatevalue of q was 0.574, many high-technologyand high-growthstocks exhibitedqs that were many times greaterthan the aggregate, as the following informal table shows: Company Average q, December 1987 Coca-Cola Compaq 2.89 2.65 IBM 1.53 Intel Kodak Motorola 2.79 1.53 1.59 If a rising fraction of firms' high-value assets is intangibles such as patents, specialized workforces with particularhuman capital attributes, or brandloyalty, ratherthan property,plant, and equipment, q will rise on this account. In addition, noise will enter q measurements as an increasing fraction of corporateearnings is generatedoverseas, since the replacementcost of foreign assets is probablymeasuredwith more errorthan that of domestic assets.'8 The market value of equity relative to GDP has increased more slowly thanTobin's q duringthe recent stock marketrise. This implies a decline in the ratio of tangible corporateassets to GDP. At the end of 1994 the replacementcost of tangible assets for the nonfinancialcorporatesector was 0.77 times GDP. This value was morethan20 percent below the value of the ratio at the end of 1989 (1.016), and 40 percent below the value in the early 1980s (1.23 in 1982). From the end of WorldWar II until 1973 this ratio fluctuatedbetween 0.86 and 0.96. It rose between 1974 and 1982, and has been declining since. It is difficultto distill a simple conclusion from table 2. While price17. The q values shown below are drawnfrom the researchand developmentdatabase describedand analyzed in Hall (1993). 18. Hines (1991) documentsthe rising shareof internationalearningsfor U.S. nonfinancialcorporations. 310 Brookings Papers on EconomicActivity, 2:1995 to-earningsratios are not unusually high at present, other measuresof stock price valuation are at, or near, historical highs. To determine whethercurrentstock prices can be justifiedby fundamentalsis beyond the currentproject.19Table 2 does suggest, however, that in assessing the macroeconomicconsequences of stock price movements, it may be importantto distinguishbetween stock price fluctuationsthat are associated with movements in the price-to-earningsor price-to-dividends ratios and those that are not. A numberof recent studies suggest that variationsin the earningsto-price ratio are correlatedwith prospectivestock marketreturns,and one concludes that "shocks to [stock]prices holdingdividendsconstant are almost entirely transitory."20Sharpincreasesin eitherthe price-toearningsor the price-to-dividendsratio, otherthings equal, are associated with lower prospective returns. If households view differently increasesin shareprices thatarenot supportedby increasesin dividends or earningsand those that are, these two types of shareprice movement might have divergenteffects on consumption. Aggregate Trends in the Ownership of Corporate Stock All corporate stock is ultimately owned by individuals. With the exception of sharesheld by foreigners(currentlyabout5 percentof the total), U.S. equities representnet worth of U.S. citizens. Yet if individuals adjusttheirconsumptionmore in responseto fluctuationsin the price of shares that they own directly than in response to shares that they hold throughfinancialintermediariesor in accountsthat are dedicated to retirementsaving, then the way in which stock prices affect real economic activity may depend on stock ownershippatterns.2' 19. One of the authors,having concluded in Frenchand Poterba(1991) that fundamentalfactorscould explain why Tokyo's Nikkei stock indexwas approximately39,000 in 1989 (high real estate values for corporateland made Tobin's q for Japaneseshares nearlyone), is hesitantto ventureagain into analyzingstock marketfundamentals! 20. Cochrane(1994, p. 241). Campbelland Shiller (1988a, 1988b)presentclosely relatedevidence on earnings-to-priceand dividends-to-priceratios and stock returns. 21. Behavioralmodels suggest that the form in which sharesare held, and even the particularrecord-keepingconventionthat is appliedto them, may affect the magnitude of the wealth effect on consumerspending (see, for example, Thaler, 1994). Because James M. Poterba and AndrewA. Samwick 311 Differential transactions costs associated with different types of equity accounts, such as penaltytaxes for early withdrawalsfrom IRAs or 401(k)s, can also induce divergences in the consumptionresponse to capitalgains on stock held differentways. Accumulationin accounts that are "off-limits" may not lead to the same spending response as increases in the value of directly held assets that can be tapped for currentconsumption. Investmentthroughthis type of account has become particularlyimportantin recentyears. In the firsteight monthsof 1995, more than two-thirdsof the cash inflows to leading mutualfund managerswere directed to funds held in retirementplans. Retirement plan assets now representnearly one-thirdof all mutualfund assets.22 For some categories of indirectstock ownership, the link between a currentcapital gain and benefits to the indirect individual holders is complicated. Considerthe example of equity held by a state and local governmentretirementplan, a definedbenefitplan for the retirementof state and local employees. Individuals as taxpayers are the ultimate beneficiariesof gains in the value of this pensionfund's holdings, since higher asset values imply that future tax burdenscan be lowered and will still fund future pension liabilities. Yet individuals may not be awareof the increase in the value of their locality's pension portfolio, andthey may not be confidentenough thattheirfuturetaxes will decline to raise consumptionin responseto such gains.23The perceivedchange in net worth may be quite different for changes in the value of stock owned directly, or stock owned throughmutualfunds that continually provide informationon net asset value. Before considering whether changes in stock ownership patterns have affected the link between share prices and consumerspending, it is helpful to summarizethe postwarhistory of individualstock ownership. The standardclaim that individualinvestorsnow accountfor less thanhalf of equity ownershipin the United States is based on datafrom individualinvestorsreceive quarterlystatementsfrom mutualfunds and otherfinancial intermediaries,they may be more aware of their gains on these investmentsthan on directstock investmentsthat requireinitiativeto evaluate. 22. Ellen E. Schultz, "Tidal Wave of RetirementCash Anchors MutualFunds," WallStreetJournal, September27, 1995, p. C1. 23. There is an inconclusive literatureon the extent to which unfundedstate and local governmentpension liabilities are capitalized into house values (see Epple and Schipper, 1981). 312 BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity, 2:1995 the FederalReserveBoard's Flow of Fundsaccounts.24These datashow "household" ownership of corporatestock declining from nearly 90 percentin the 1950s to less than 50 percentin the mid-1990s. Although widely used, the Flow of Fundsdata do not measurewhat many analysts think they measure. They do not apply to listed equity on stock exchanges but rather,to a broaderconceptof corporateequity, including stock in closely held companies.25Moreover, they do not describeholdings of individualinvestorsbut rather,of a groupof economic actors, the "household sector," which includes nonprofitinstitutions. The entry for household sector holdings in the Flow of Funds table for corporateequity balances also excludes equity held throughmutual funds, defined contributionpension plan accounts, and other financial products, such as variable annuities. These forms of individualequity ownership are allocated to other sectors in the Flow of Funds, and as they have become more importantin the last decade, the potentialfor misinterpretationof the household sector data has grown. The growth of institutionalholdings does not necessarilyimply that shocks to stock marketvalues now have smallereffects on individualnet worththanin previous periods. Table 5 summarizesthe Flow of Fundsdataon the shareof outstanding equity held by variousclasses of investors. The householdsector is shown in the first column.26The column for mutual funds combines ownershipby open-endand closed-end investmentcompanies, andthat for pension funds includes private pension funds as well as state and local government retirement systems. The pension fund column includes both defined contributionplans, in which the plan participants have distinct accounts that change in value along with the price of the underlyingassets, as well as defined benefitplans, which promiseparticular benefit streams to retirees as a function of their age, years of service, and wage history at retirement. 24. See, for example, Blume and Zeldes (1993) and Friedman(1996). 25. The total marketvalue of corporatestock in the Flow of Fundsexceeds that on the NYSE, AMEX, and NASDAQ. The value of closely held sharesat the end of 1994 was approximately$1.2 trillion. 26. The sharpdecline in the shareof equity held by householdsbetween 1968 (81.9 percent) and 1969 (69.1 percent) is due to the creation of a separateFlow of Funds categoryfor bank personaltrusts, which accountedfor 10.5 percentof equity holdings in 1969. Table5. Stock Ownership Shares, UnadjustedFlow of Funds, 1952-94 Percent Year Households" 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 89.7 88.6 89.3 88.6 88.6 87.5 87.6 86.8 85.8 85.7 84.7 84.2 84.1 83.8 83.0 81.7 81.9 69.1 68.0 65.9 64.1 60.4 56.1 56.7 61.8 59.0 56.9 58.7 60.9 59.0 56.1 53.5 51.4 51.3 50.6 49.8 48.8 48.0 48.6 50.8 51.4 49.7 47.7 Pension funds" 1.1 1.5 1.4 2.1 2.3 2.8 3.0 3.5 4.0 4.4 4.8 5.2 5.5 5.9 6.4 6.6 6.8 8.1 9.2 10.5 11.5 12.8 15.2 16.5 14.7 16.3 18.5 18.1 17.4 18.7 21.3 22.9 24.6 24.8 25.4 25.5 26.8 27.2 27.0 26.2 25.8 25.6 25.7 Mutual funds" 3.1 3.5 3.3 3.3 3.5 3.9 4.0 4.3 4.6 4.6 4.8 4.9 4.9 5.0 5.2 5.3 5.3 5.5 5.2 5.5 5.1 5.1 5.4 4.9 4.1 3.9 3.7 3.4 3.1 2.9 3.3 4.1 4.6 5.0 6.1 6.9 6.5 7.0 7.1 7.7 8.7 11.5 13.6 Foreign Insurance companies" 2.2 2.2 2.2 2.2 2.2 2.2 2.1 2.2 2.2 2.2 2.2 2.2 2.1 2.0 1.9 3.1 3.0 3.1 3.2 3.1 3.5 3.8 4.0 4.2 3.7 4.2 4.2 4.1 4.2 4.5 4.7 5.0 5.2 5.3 6.1 6.3 6.5 6.6 6.3 5.6 5.5 5.5 5.4 3.4 3.6 3.3 3.1 2.9 3.0 2.8 2.8 2.9 2.9 3.1 3.0 3.0 2.9 3.0 2.8 2.8 3.1 3.3 3.7 4.3 5.1 5.7 5.2 4.8 5.2 5.5 5.4 5.1 5.5 5.7 5.7 5.7 5.5 5.0 5.2 5.2 5.0 5.0 4.4 4.0 4.0 4.2 Source: Federal Reserve, Flow of Funds Accounts. a. Household category includes ownership by nonprofit institutions. b. Pension funds include private and government plans. c. Mutual funds include closed-end as well as open-end investment companies. Entries are based on the total amount of corporate stock held by mutual funds. d. Insurancecompanies include both property and casualty, and life insurance companies. 314 BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity, 2:1995 To estimate the share of corporatestock that individualshold either directly or,indirectly, we make five adjustmentsto the Flow of Funds household sector data: -We subtractthe equity holdings of nonprofitinstitutions.Experimental data presented in the Flow of Funds accounts show that the equity holdings of nonprofitinstitutionsaveraged 15.7 percent of the household sector's equity holdings duringthe period 1987-92. Therefore we multiply the Flow of Funds household sector equity value by 0.843 in each year between 1952 and 1994 in order to remove these holdings. -We add stock held by bank personaltrusts, since individualsare the beneficiariesof all of these accounts. -We add equity held in defined contributionpension plans. At the end of 1993, private pension plans held $1,075 billion in corporate stock, of which $481 billion was held in defined contributionplans. Since individuals are the owners of these accounts, we attributethis equity to them. The share of privatepension fund equity assets held in definedcontributionplans has increasedfromjust over a quarterat the beginning of the 1980s to nearly a half in the mid-1990s. -We add equity held in variable annuityreserves at life insurance companies.Variableannuities,which have been one of the most rapidly growing insurance products of the last decade, provide a means for individualsto defer taxes on capital income, at the price of insurance loads and some limitationson investmentoptions and withdrawalprovisions. Total assets held in variableannuityaccountshave grownfrom $47.7 billion at the end of 1991 to $176.4 billion at the end of 1994, and nearly three-quartersof variableannuitiesare invested in stock.27 -We add household ownership of open- and closed-end mutual fundsthatinvest in corporatestock. Individualsare the ultimateowners of most mutualfund shares. At the end of 1994, 66.2 percentof mutual fundshareswere allocatedto householdsin the Flow of Funds. Another 13.2 percent were allocated to bank trust departments,which we aggregate with households. Given the growthin mutualfund holdings of corporateequity over time, it is increasinglyimportantto recognize this channel for individualequity ownership.28 27. Gentryt1994) and Poterba(1995b) discuss the growthof variableannuities. 28. Retirementaccountscompriseabouttwo-thirdsof householdmutualfund hold- James M. Poterba and AndrewA. Samwick 315 The magnitudeof each of these correctionsto householdequity ownership is shown for the end of 1994:29 Percent of total corporate stock outstanding Flow of Fundshouseholdsector less nonprofitholdings plus bankpersonaltrusts plus pensionplan assets plus variableannuityaccounts plus mutualfundholdings equalsadjustedindividualholdings 47.7 (7.5) 2.7 7.7 2.0 11.0 63.7 The net effect of these adjustmentsis to raise substantiallythe fraction of corporateequity that is attributedto individuals. Ratherthan suggesting that individuals hold less than half of all corporatestock, the modifiedcalculations suggest that individualinvestors hold two-thirds of outstandingstock, either directly or througha fiduciary. Table 6 shows these adjustmenttermsfor the period 1952-94; figure 4 plots the adjusted and unadjustedtime series for individual stock ownership. The adjustmentschange the trend in stock ownershippatterns. The secular decline in the share of equity owned by individuals that emerges in the first column of table 6 is not supportedby the data on individualdirect and indirectownership.In the expandeddefinition, individualownershipdeclines from 75 percentof the marketin 1970 to just over 60 percentin the late 1980s, but then startsto rebound.It has grown by more than 3 percentagepoints during the last four years of the period. This is largely the result of the diffusion of tax-deferred ings. At the end of 1994, householdownershipof mutualfunds totaled$1,066 billion. Data from the InvestmentCompanyInstituteshow that $361 billion of this was held in IRAs, $161 billion in 401(k) plans, $76 billion in other defined contributionpension plans, and $98 billion in 403(b) plans. 29. One of the changes that is due to be incorporatedin the December1995 revision of the Flow of Funds accounts involves some reallocationof variable annuity assets between the mutualfund and insurancecompany sectors. The currentFlow of Funds procedureincludesvariableannuityequity assets in both the mutualfund and insurance sectors, and consequentlysubtractsthese assets twica from total equity outstandingin computinghouseholdequityholdings. Addingback variableannuityassets, as described in the text, corrects for this. The revision is also expected to decreasethe amountof stock held by corporatepension plans. . . o -:> -k rn m 2 do U t- o o m It It o- . . o)mv o o o o o C \C 00 00 C)1t o o a o o . . . . om o o o o o o o o o o kf \. r- r- r- C) m cro o ooo o \p oo o m o c-i o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o m - t -t ~ . o ~~~~~~~ v a . a, 00 00 00 00 00 00 00 r- r- r- r- 0oW a, ~~~~~~ _o ro oON Cn n oo w) C on r- c- Cl Cl t k - o 0o o oo (ON r- a o to~~~~~L .e = u o < Q %% X ~a., t SC ) (W S) SC) W) WC)oo) oo l oo a, a, ON lON ON N c\o c, -o oC \C \C , a, , a, --Cho , 00 Ct 0- \t - i - wo r - C > N C (ON It C W) m o lCO 0 06 CJo C It 0e (Ni - C C m m C) C) r- C)} -; 00 r N w) o o CI (ON r- (ON r- "-\ \C C \ o c- c- c- k k w oo C \ \6 6 O - c W) W - i -- m oo omNn 00 ?t o OChr 06 00 0 r- o nChChn 0 00 CJo Cl sC: *h mt Ch r00: 06 0- r- r- z C ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~ m (O C kr 00 00 m ON ON o - o w-r w) w) r- n (N \C a) (O . - L1 2101 0u - CJ 00 0C) (O w) \p - Ccoo r rr- r- o rD Ch(OO o, Ch r- w w - ) 't m 00 ci w m w -t w -) w o w - - - - - - - - - - - 0) \ 00 It r- r oo oo, ooo-C r 00 00 00 Ctmm\ oo - 00 , oo - - - - - - - W - - - 318 Brookings Papers on EconomicActivity, 2:1995 Figure 4. Share of Stock Owned by Households, 1952-94 Percent 90 Flow of Funds '__ households 80 Individuals 70 60 50 I 1950 l 1955 1960 I 1965 I 1970 I 1975 I 1980 I 1985 I 1990 I 1995 Source: Authors' calculations using data from Federal Reserve, Flow of Funds Accounts. saving plans, particularlytax-deferred401(k)s and403(b)s, throughthe employed population. These adjustmentsto the Flow of Funds data are necessary for understandingthe potential consumptioneffects of an increase in share values in the "mental accounts" framework. A key concern in this context is the degree to which individuals recognize capital gains on equities as a potentialbasis for higherconsumption.The adjustedmeasures of individualstock ownershipmay also be importantfor gauging the significance of "noise traders" in security markets.30 For other issues concerningstock ownership,however, these corrections may not be relevant, and the standardview that individualsown less than half of corporatestock may be appropriate.Since corporate stock held throughmutualfunds or definedcontributionpension plans is voted by the fiduciaries,not by the individualswho are the beneficial 30. Shleifer and Summers(1990) describe models of financialmarketequilibrium with noise tradersand explore their allocative effects. James M. Poterba and AndrewA. Samwick 319 holdersof these shares, the rise of indirectownershipmay have altered the balance of power within corporations. The factorsthatexplain the evident trendaway fromdirectownership of corporatestock and toward ownershipthroughfinancialintermediaries are not well understood. Tax considerationsactually encourage directownershipof shares. Individualscan more efficiently invoke tax strategiesthat realize capital losses and defer capital gains if they own sharesdirectly, ratherthan througha mutualfund. Tax incentives may explain partof the growthof corporatepensions. By investing through 401(k) plans and defined contributionpension plans, individuals can defer taxes on both capital gains and dividend income. Many households hold equity only in these tax-deferredforms. A countervailing incentive is the opportunityfor greaterdiversificationthat is afforded by mutualfunds, relative to purchasesof securities in individualcompanies. Furtherwork is needed to understandthe other factors in the financialservices marketplacethat have led investorsaway from direct stock holding. Evolving Patterns of Individual Stock Ownership One of the salient features of stock ownership is its concentration among a subset of the population. In light of the higher historical averagereturnon stocks thanon otherinvestmentassets, the substantial numberof households that hold no equity representsa puzzle in the analysis of portfolio behavior.3'Holdings of corporatestock are more concentratedthan most other components of net worth. This may be importantfor understandingthe consumptioneffects of rising share prices, and it is also a key input to standardanalyses of "who gains or loses" from share price fluctuations. Because the changing roles of directand indirectstock ownershipmay be associatedwith shifts in the distributionof stock holdings, we interruptour analysis of aggregate trendsto presentsummaryinformationon the changingcross-sectional patternof equity ownership. We use data from the 1962 Survey of Financial Characteristicsof 31. Haliassos and Bertaut(1995) provide a recent survey of the related literature. They andKing andLeape(1984) presentcarefuleconometrictreatmentsof the incidence of stock ownership. 320 Brookings Papers on EconomicActivity, 2:1995 Consumers, and the 1983 and 1992 Surveys of Consumer Finances (SCF) to summarizeindividual equity ownershipduringthe last three decades.32The Survey of Consumer Finances is a stratifiedrandom sampleof U.S. households, administeredby the FederalReserveBoard. Designed to gather detailed informationon assets, liabilites, and demographiccharacteristics,it has been conductedevery threeyearssince 1983. In recognition of the highly skewed distributionsof many types of financialandreal assets, the survey oversampleshigh-incomehouseholds. Each SCF contains an area-probabilitysample, which is a stratified randomsample of householdschosen fromthe populationat large, and a stratifiedrandomsample of householdsdrawnfrom a set of highincome tax returns. Both samples are surveyed using the same questionnaire. In 1983, 438 of the 4,103 SCF households were from the high-income sample, comparedwith 1,450 of 3,906 in 1992.33 The presentanalysis focuses primarilyon the 1983 and 1992 Surveys of ConsumerFinances because in these two years the specific goal of the SCF was to provide a detailed cross-sectional sample of wealth holdings.34In this respect, the intermediatesurveysare less useful. The 1986 SCF merely reinterviewedthe 1983 sample and was not as complete in its gatheringof stock and pension dataas the previoussurvey.35 In 1989, one of the priorities was to establish a panel with the 1983 survey. The design of the 1983 and 1992 surveys was not encumbered by considerationsof preservinga panel data set.36 Table 7 reports the numberand percentage of households owning stock in 1962, 1983, and 1992. Both for households with any stock holdings and households with stock holdings greaterthan $2,000, successive rows of the table contain progressively more comprehensive 32. A systematic survey of trends in share ownershipin the early postwarperiod may be found in Blume, Crockett, and Friend (1974). Projectorand Weiss (1966) describethe 1962 Survey of FinancialCharacteristicsof Consumers. 33. Kennickelland Starr-McCluer(1994). 34. The 1983 survey instrumentand sample are describedin Avery, Elliehausen, and Kennickell(1988), while the 1992 survey is describedin Kennickell(1995). 35. See Heeringa,Connor, and Woodburn(1994). 36. Curtin,Juster, and Morgan(1989) comparedifferentwealth surveys, and conclude that only the SCF has enough high-income householdsto permittabulationsof detailed asset categories. Avery, Elliehausen,and Canner(1984) and Avery and Elliehausen(1986) tabulatebasic resultsfrom the 1983 SCF. The 1992 dataare summarized in Kennickelland Starr-McCluer(1994). Antoniewicz(1995) describesthe link between SCF data and aggregatedata from the Flow of Fundsaccounts. James M. Poterba and AndrewA. Samwick 321 Table7. Stock Ownership, 1962, 1983, and 1992a Units as indicated Investment form and householdcategory Anystockholdings Publiclytraded Plus mutualfund Plus IRA/Keoghaccount Plus 40l (k) plan Plus all defined contributionplan Stockholdings> $2,000h Publiclytraded Plus mutualfund Plus IRA/Keoghaccounts Plus401(k) plan Plus all defined contributionplan Total Numberof households (millions) As percentageof all households 1962 1983 1992 1962 1983 1992 10.0 11.1 . .. .. . 16.0 16.9 19.7 23.2 17.0 21.1 26.8 31.8 17.2 19.0 .. . .. . 19.1 20.1 23.5 27.7 17.8 22.0 28.0 33.2 ... 27.9 35.7 .. . 33.2 37.4 . . . 11.5 12.3 14.4 16.8 12.4 16.3 21.5 24.8 12.6 14.3 . .. .. . 13.7 14.6 17.1 20.0 12.9 17.0 22.5 25.9 .. . 20.7 28.0 .. . 24.6 29.3 57.9 83.9 95.6 ... ... 7.3 8.3 . .. Source: 1962 Survey of Financial Characteristics of Consumers and the 1983 and 1992 SCFs. a. Some equity holdings may still be omitted from the analysis because the SCF does not provide detailed information on equity held in trusts for which the respondent is a beneficiary, or in variable annuity accounts. For 1983, we have imputed the share of mutual fund holdings that are accounted for by equity mutual funds. The SCF questionnaire for that year did not collect information on the type of mutual fund investors held. We therefore divide reported 1983 mutual fund assets between stock and bond mutual funds on the basis of the relative proportions of these funds in the 1989 SCF. b. 1992 dollars. measuresof stock ownership. The first row focuses on direct holding of shares in publicly tradedcompanies. The second row also includes stock held indirectly throughmutualfunds. The thirdrow adds shares held in IRAs or Keogh accounts. The fourth row adds shares held throughtax-deferredsaving plans, such as 401(k)s. Finally, the fifth row adds equity held in defined contributionpension plans. The upper panel of table 7 shows that the numberof households owning stock increasedbetween 1962 and 1983. Institutionalchanges and data limitations only permit calculations for two definitions of 37. Some equity holdings may still be omitted from the analysis because the SCF does not providedetailed informationon equity held in trustsfor which the respondent is a beneficiary,or in variableannuityaccounts. For 1983, we have imputedthe share of mutualfund holdings that are accountedfor by equity mutualfunds. The SCF questionnairefor that year did not collect informationon the type of mutualfund investors held. We thereforedivide reported 1983 mutual fund assets between stock and bond mutualfunds on the basis of the relativeproportionsof these funds in the 1989 SCF. 322 BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity, 2:1995 ownershipin 1962: directly held stock, and stock held either directly or throughmutualfunds. Neither IRAs, nor 401(k) plans, nor Keoghs existed in 1962, and since the Survey of Financial Characteristicsof Consumersdid not collect informationon detailed pension plan attributes, there is no informationon equity held throughdefined contribution pension plans. The percentageof households with direct stock ownershipdeclined between 1983 and 1992, while the percentagewith indirect holdings increased. By 1992 direct holdersof corporatestock accountedfor less than half of all equity holders. While 37.4 percent of all households owned stock either directly or throughan intermediary,only 17.8 percent of households reporteddirect stock holdings. For all but the most limited measureof stock ownership(direct holdings) the data show an increase in the incidence of stock ownershipbetween 1983 and 1992. The percentageof households that own stock either directlyor through mutualfunds, for example, rises from 20.1 to 22.0 percent. The share of households holding equity under the most expansive definition increased by 4.2 percentagepoints, from 33.2 to 37.4 percent.38 The firstpartof table 7 indicatesthe total numberof householdswith any exposure to stock price fluctuations. For analyzing consumption decisions, however, it may be more appropriateto focus only on those households with substantialexposure, as defined by an absolute level of equity holding.39When the definition of stockholdersis limited to only those individuals with at least $2,000 invested in stocks in 1992, the fractionof householdscategorizedas stock ownersdeclines to 12.9 percent, and the extended measureof ownershipfalls to 29.3 percent. Thus roughly 8 percent of households own some corporatestock, but less than $2,000 worth. Stock price fluctuationsare not likely to have large absolute effects on the net worth of these households, although given the low levels of asset holdings for many households, the proportionateeffects of stock price movementsmay be substantial.40 38. SCF staff reportsome concern that some closely held stock was classified as publicly tradedstock in the 1983 SCF, therebyoverstatingthe numberof households owning tradedstock and understatingthe growth of shareholdingsbetween 1983 and 1992. 39. All monetaryamountsin our analysis of the Survey of ConsumerFinancesare given in 1992 dollars. 40. Poterba, Venti, and Wise (1994) present data on the distributionof financial asset holdings for householdsin which the head is approachingretirementage. James M. Poterba and AndrewA. Samwick 323 One of the reasons for exploring the disaggregatepatternof stock ownershipis to provide some informationon the marginalpropensities to consume out of wealth for stockholders.An importantdimensionfor such analysis is stockholderage. Table 8 presentsinformationon stock ownershipby the age of household head for 1983 and 1992.4' Households in which the head is over the age of sixty-five hold more than40 percentof the publicly tradedstock held by individualsin 1992 (almost 50 percentin 1983). The highest probabilityof owning stock occurs in the years immediatelyprecedingretirement. Table 8 illustratesthe dramaticgrowthof indirectstock holdings. In 1983, for example, 17 percentof households in the 45-54 group hold stock only indirectly.By 1992, this percentagehas grownto 28 percent. The comparablestatistic for the households of those aged from thirtyfive to forty-fourrises from 20 to 24 percent. Comparingthe entries in the middle and right panels of table 8 suggests that the critical growth has taken place in mutualfund and IRA or Keogh holdings. Including indirect holdings has a larger effect on the estimated rate of stock ownershipfor householdswith youngerheads thanfor those with older ones. In 1992 the proportionof householdsin the 35-44 groupthatown shares directly is only 20 percent, comparedwith 44 percentthat own stock directlyor indirectly.The increasein the probabilityof ownership is smaller(18 percentto 27 percent)for householdswith headsover the age of sixty-five. To link the disaggregateinformationon stock ownershipto the discussion of consumptionand stock price fluctuations,the informationin table 8 can be used to compute the age distributionof capital gains on corporatestock. The market value of corporate stock was $6,048.8 billion at the end of 1994, and it increasedby $1,119 billion between December 1994 and June 1995. Since 63.7 percentof outstandingequity was held in forms that we define as providing individual control over these assets, individualsthereforereceived a capital gain of $713 billion. The distributionof this gain by age is as follows: 41. Bosworth, Burtless, and Sabelhaus(1991) and Attanasio(1994) presentinformationon age-specific saving rates. This paperuses the following conventionfor selecting a head of household. When the survey respondentis partof a marriedcouple, the head is the spouse with higher wage, salary, or self-employmentincome. If neither spouse reportslabor income, the head is the older spouse. t~~~~~~~~~r C-) M R t X Y o o t~~~~~;:d m ? C) tf N n- t o - 0-) C) ( -q Y O X o: t> k o _ ? n X n ? O ? _a R <_, ? r- Il-o -_N I- - > It n o C) > C t ) 'I 00 CN E~~~~~~~~~f 2 o r- r- n ~~~~~~~~~N o Il *2 C m - m - o ? ~~CN cn Il tf C) C) mN m C C) 0 o (N C Ill- 0N O t cn ~~~~~n o :t c O> C 0C.- 0 Cu _ C) O hS R > 0 L X S O ON - 0 > X f L Cq > t > k C) -N C1 o. ~~~tf ? 0 N X o t X 2 k> t k~~~~~~~ o1 X~~~~~~~~~~~~1 2- m C) C o 'IC r C :O m tf C - _ (m4 C) L > cl O 4~~~~~~~~~~" )N? 0_) ?f o O ? - , I-oooo O nctln-r-- > 0dB 'IC -4 ~m N r- c N tf oo-> N o o o) 'I oo o Ct N ? ? _aZ 0 01 tf ooot 00 00 C t oo4 _ N?? (, ) m s _ c W) < r- 00 = t: C ,In ( 4 C n~~~~~Ci 0 C cl,_ *;~~~~~~~~~~~~, o~~~~~~C ? 00 o t rCI N - 0? 00 ( 00 00 C 00 ? m Oo ) C) t t 1 1C O r-4 Cj ' j- 0->Z> L o t n o o N00onON n_o 0 C-4 James M. Poterba and AndrewA. Samwick Age of household head < 35 35-45 45-54 54-64 65 + 325 Billions of dollars 37 121 175 161 219 The key conclusion from this calculation is that the majorityof wealth changes from stock marketfluctuationsaccrueto householdswith older heads.42 Some have arguedthat households with younger heads benefit indirectly when share prices rise because they will receive substantialbequests from the currentelderly. This could even stimulatehigher consumption among households that do not hold stock. Ultimately, the young will receive in bequests any assets that are not consumed by elderly. Yet to develop this argumentin more detail, we consider the timing of expected bequests. We use actualmortalitytables to compute the expected percentageof corporatestock that will be bequeathedto younger generationsover various horizons.43The results suggest that bequestsare not a critical factor in the nearterm. We estimatethatover the next five years 5.7 percent of corporatestock will be bequeathed. Over a fifteen-yearhorizon the share is 24.4 percent, and over twentyfive years, 45.3 percent. These calculationsdo not suggest thatyounger generations will soon receive a large fraction of outstandingequity throughthis channel, but it is notablethatthe expectedbequestof equity during the next fifteen years is comparableto the amount of equity currentlyheld by households with heads underthe age of forty-five. The concentrationof stock ownership, as well as its age distribution, can affect the linkage between stock price fluctuationsandconsumption 42. We can translatethis into a consumptionmetricwith the crude assumptionthat households exhibit marginalpropensitiesto consume out of wealth equal to 1I(T age), where T is expected age at the end of life. We set T = 80, assume that all householdsheadsover age sixty-five are age seventy-two,thatall those underage thirtyfive are age thirty, and thatthe householdsin the otherage bracketsare all at the bracket midpoint.This implies a "predicted"consumptionresponseof $45 billion (6.3 percent) to the $713 billion share price increase. 43. For marriedcouple householdsthatown stock, we definea bequestas occurring whenbothmembersof the couple have died. The averagemortalitytablesmayunderstate life expectancyfor stockholders,since age-specific mortalityrates are negatively correlatedwith wealth. 326 BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity, 2:1995 spending. The skewed nature of ownership underpinsthe view that consumption adjustmentsby the small set of substantialstock owners cannot have detectable effects on aggregate consumer spending. Table 9 describesthe concentrationof shareownershipwith information from the 1962 Surveyof FinancialCharacteristics of Consumersand the 1983 and 1992 SCFs. The results confirm well-knowncross-sectional patterns, but suggest new conclusions about trends. In 1983 the 0.5 percentof stock owners with the largestequityportfolios,including both direct and indirectholdings, owned 55.1 percentof total stock. In 1992, this group held only 36.8 percent. The households in this top 0.5 percentgroupin 1992 had at least $800,000 in equities.The next 0.5 percentof stockholdershadequityportfoliosworthbetween$500,000 and $800,000 in 1992, and held 10.3 percentof all equity. The degree of concentrationis even greaterif attentionis limited to directly held, publicly traded stock. Over 66 percent of directly held stock was held by the 0.5 percent of stock owners with the largest holdingsin 1983. This percentagehaddeclinedto 58.6 percentby 1992. Comparisonbetween the entries for "all equity" and "nonpension equity" in table 9 suggests that growing participationin defined contributionpensionplanshas been less importantthangrowinginvestment in mutual funds and the expansion of tax-deferredretirementsaving vehicles, such as IRAs, in reducing the concentrationof equity ownership among the wealthiest owners.44 Table 9 permits comparisonsof inequality in equity holdings, nonequity financialasset holding, and net worth, in 1962, 1983, and 1992. Because some of the variables that we use to construct net worth in 1992 are not available in the 1962 data, and vice versa, we reporttwo variantsof 1983 wealth inequalityfor comparisonwith 1992 and 1962, respectively. We then focus on pairwisecomparisonsacrossyears. The calculations for the 1983 data, on the basis of 1962 definitions, are shown in the last two columns of table 9. The comparison between 1962 and 1983 suggests relatively little change in the concentrationof equity ownership.The shareof publicly tradedstock held by the 0.5 percentof householdswith the largeststock 44. Some assets that are accumulatedin defined contributionpension plans may appearas assets in IRAs, if these pension assets have been "rolled over" in a lumpsum distribution.For informationon the importanceof such rollovers, see Poterba,Venti, andWise (1995). Z ,, . . . : :t . . . (N 00 . . . c )e' rNc cn r- 00 C :-N t o.W : o . . 00ONt~-t.. -t Y o ON oo 00 ~ ~~O ~ ~~ _b 5 - o ~ le I-Cl Q . t b X < X t *S0 .t t i; C o ON _ (Z CN mc C CN C" . ( ) : N-Nr O r u/Nl 00 o C o - ) On 0 o t 0 N 0N ) ~~~~~~~~~~Co _ N .ot 0 t ? O ? N t N 00 > > N o e X O X X O < ? ? oN m ? . . . . . . 00 0 > t 00 C r- O Co C __ o. . . t . - . O 0 ' C)_o _ N O ~ . : o o- o > oo0 m _Z O 00 00 e X tm t) O)CN c N~ . 00 CO - cn tr -) o) C) 0 Nt - Z ZZ - ? tf ) CN - N oo oo - O N~ - O- Cq tf mc Nt cq CN tNC Ol o 00 ONE-ZZZZ C) O O CW 00o - ec o sc r-ONuNr e>N clIC (, C" - ONClr-.- k ~-Cl s2 t O t ~~ >eeo O ' _- _ ) CN N Nt_ >cI ~t Y Cq -N- Ocloooo C" C" cn C" 00o ~ C0ON CCl--- 0N O m r C S cl'm -- C- tf r- NN1~lrt Cloo 00 -: ._~~~~~~~~~~" ,?q cl~ ,0 Cl .. tf ,I- 00 tf S w >~~~~~~~~~~0 ~~~-> C) cn Xc On ~~~~oo ~~~ ~~t ~ Cl ON tCl ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~~~~~~~~~0 00 -b ^ -eNeNm . > ol ? m t o ~ ' C .. . . Q . . Y 328 BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity, 2:1995 portfolios in 1962 was 63.3 percent, comparedwith 66.2 percent in 1983. Total nonpensionequity also became only slightly more unequal between 1962 and 1983. Thus the substantialdecline in the inequality of nonpensionequity between 1983 and 1992 (from 62.3 percentheld by the top 0.5 percentto 43.9 percent)representsa significantdeparture fromthe trendof the previousperiod. The datashow thatbetween 1983 and 1992, the share of equity held by the top 0.5 percentof the stockholding populationdeclined, while that of householdswith stock portfolios in the ninetieth to ninety-ninth percentiles increased substantially. The share of directly held stock accountedfor by householdsin the eightieth throughninetieth percentiles declined slightly, while the fractionof total equity holdings attributedto this group increased. The central message of table 9 is that more than one-third of the gains or losses on corporatestock accrue to the roughly half a million householdswith the largest equity holdings, and another40 percentof the gains accrue to the 4.5 million households with the next largest equity stakes. If the linkage between stock returnsand consumption turnson directlyheld equity, then the concentrationof holdings is even more dramatic:nearly 60 percent of the capital gains on directly held corporatestock accrueto the half a million householdswith the largest portfolios of corporatestock. Table 9 also presentsdistributionsof nonequityfinancialassets, real assets such as owner-occupiedreal estate, and total net worth. These tabulationsuse the data and sample weights that underliethe first published tabulations from the 1992 data set.45The sample weights are subject to revision in the final version of the data set for public use. With the exception of owner-occupiedreal estate, the shareof each of these asset categories held by very wealthy households declines between 1983 and 1992.46 The seventhcolumnin table9 shows the income distributionin 1983 and 1992 as computed from the Survey of ConsumerFinances. It shows a growing share(from 7.6 percentin 1983 to 45. Kennickell and Starr-McCluer(1994). The tabulationsare subject to revision because the final version of the 1992 Survey of ConsumerFinanceswas not available whenthis study was conducted.The dataunderlyingthe reportedtabulationscontainno missing values, but use a preliminarysampleweight to constructthe asset distributions. 46. Ournet worthcalculations,andmost othersdirectedat measuringthe inequality of wealth, exclude the actuarialpresent-discountedvalue of defined benefit pension benefits. Includingthese benefits would probablyreducethe shareof net worthheld by the most wealthy households. James M. Poterba and AndrewA. Samwick 329 9.7 percent in 1992) of family income accruing to households in the top 0.5 percent of the income distribution, and a substantialdecline (from 49.6 percent in 1983 to 43.4 in 1992) in the share of income reportedby the bottom 80 percent of the distribution.47This finding, andthe growing concentrationof housing equity, is importantin showing that the diminishing inequality of equity holding is not simply an artifactof the Survey of ConsumerFinances data set, nor of our computational algorithms. Net worth is distributedmore unequally than income, nonequityfinancialassets are distributedmore unequallythan net worth, and equity holdings are distributedless equally than nonequity financialassets. The findingthatthe fractionof corporatestock and of net worthheld by the top 0.5 percent and top 1 percent of the distributiondeclined between 1983 and 1992 contrasts with recent studies of wealth inequality that suggest that the inequality of financial asset holdings increased duringthe period 1983-89.48 The result is striking, given the rise in share prices during this period and the unequal distributionof share ownership. An increase in the relative value of an asset that is distributedless equally thannet worth shouldincreasethe inequalityof net worth; in principle, it is even possible for the distributionof each component asset to become more equal while the distributionof net worthbecomes less equal, with such asset price changes.49 47. Levy and Murnane(1992) describe and discuss recent changes in the U.S. income distribution. 48. Wolff (1994, 1995) reportsthe changes in wealth inequalitybetween 1983 and 1989. These studies adjustthe SCF datato align the total reportedassets with aggregate totals in the Flow of Fundsaccounts. Because the SCF totals are typically below those of the Flow of Funds, these correctionsinflate the amountof each asset held by each householdthat reportsit. They do not change the set of householdswho have a given asset, nor the inequalitywithin asset categories, althoughthey can affect the measured inequalityof broadercomposite measuresof financialassets or net worth. 49. Consideran economy with two assets, A andB. Householdsin the top 1 percent of the wealthdistributionown SA and SB percentof these assets respectively.The market value of asset A is VA and that of B is V,. Let WA = VA/(VA + V,) and w11= Vi/(VA + V,1).The percent of net worth held by the richest 1 percentof households is SAWA + Assume thatA is distributedless equally thanB, such thatSA > SB. At a different SBWB3. date, the top 1 percentof householdshold SA' and SB' percentof A andB, respectively. Assume SA' < SA and s,1' < s,. It does not follow that net worth is more equally distributed.If WA' > WA,wealth could still be more equal at the second date then the first. In the simple case of s,,' = s,], the inequalityof net worthrises if SA'/SA > SB/SA + (1 - sR/SA)(wA/WA,'). If SB/SA = 0.25, and asset A appreciates50 percent,so that WA! WA' = 0.67, then the inequalityof net worth will rise for any SA'/SA above 0.75. 330 BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity, 2:1995 To assess the contributionof rising share prices to inequality, we estimate the change in the inequality of net worth between 1983 and 1992 that would have resulted only from changes in asset prices.50We adjustthe reported1983 values of corporatestock holdings and closely held businesses by the real appreciationof the Standardand Poor's CompositeSharePrice Index, andthe value of owner-occupiedhousing by the real change in the Commerce Department's price index for constant-qualityhomes. The resulting shares of net worth are as follows: Wealthpercentile Actual 1983 (percent) Predicted 1992 (percent) Actual 1992 (percent) Top 0.5 Next 0.5 Next 4.0 Next 5.0 Next 10.0 Remaining80.0 23.74 7.12 22.86 12.12 13.08 21.08 25.63 7.70 23.11 11.71 12.10 19.75 21.68 6.99 24.37 13.77 14.10 19.20 Thus the actual share of wealth holdings by the most wealthy households in 1992 was substantiallyless than the extrapolationof the 1983 wealth distributionwould have predicted. Ceteris paribus,the relative rise in corporate stock prices would have contributedto increasing inequality. Other changes, however, were more importantthan asset pricechangesin generatingchangesin the distributionof equityholdings andnet worth;in particular,the diffusionof substantialstockholdings to householdsnear, but not at, the top of the wealthdistribution. The difference between these findings and others showing rising inequalityappearsto be due to our reliance on 1992, ratherthan 1989, data. When we apply our methodsto the 1989 SCF data, we find rising wealth inequality between 1983 and 1989. Our estimates suggest that the shareof total net worth held by the 0.5 percentof householdswith the highest net worth increased from 23.7 percentto 26.1 percentbetween 1983 and 1989. This makes the decline from 26.1 percent in 50. Weicher(1995) explores the effect of rising sharepriceson net worthinequality duringthe period 1983-89 and concludes that favorablestock returnsdid not substantially exacerbate inequality at that time, because they were paralleledby rising real estate values. James M. Poterba and AndrewA. Samwick 331 1989 to 21.7 percent in 1992 all the more striking. A critical question is whether the change in wealth inequality recordedby the 1989 and 1992 Surveys of ConsumerFinances is a reliable indicatorof actual changes in the U.S. wealth distribution.5' The asset distributionamong the households with highest net worth in 1983, 1989, and 1992 raises some questions aboutthe datafrom the 1989 SCF. Among the top 0.5 percentof households, for example, the share of net worth held in corporatestocks was 21.2 percentin 1983, 8.0 percentin 1989, and 14.4 percent in 1992. The shareof net worth in closely held businesses was 34.6 percent, 42.1 percent, and 38.4 percent in these years, respectively. At a minimum, the negatively correlatedfluctuationsin the shares of these two assets suggests that there may be some misclassification of closely held equity in some years. It is not clear whetherthis could have any effect on the measured inequalityof net worth, but it could affect the inequalityof component assets, such as corporatestock. The 1989 and 1992 Surveys of ConsumerFinance both show a decline in the share of net worth held by the 80 percent of households with the lowest net worth. This group's share of net worth fell from 21.1 percent in 1983 to 19.2 percent in 1992. The gain in net worth sharefor households between the eightieth and ninetiethpercentilesin the wealth distributionwas approximatelyhalf of the decline for the lowest 80 percent of households. A key conclusion to emerge from table 9 is that there have been nontrivialrecent changes in the distribution of wealth among the households that are high in the net worth distribution. To complete the disaggregateanalysis of stock ownership, we considerthe income and nonequitywealth holdings of householdsthatown stock.52Tables 10 and 11 provide summaryinformationon these dimensions of stock ownership, drawn from the 1983 and 1992 SCFs. They show a strong positive relationship between income, financial assets other than equity, and the probabilityof stock ownership. 51. Even though the SCF is the best available data source on the distributionof wealth, the small numberof high-wealthhouseholdson which the SCF resultsare based still makes these tabulationspotentiallysensitive to outliers. Analysis of the 1983-89 SCF panel might providefurtherinformationon the changingpatternsof asset holdings betweenthese years. 52. Poterba (1995a) presents more detailed informationon the characteristicsof stockholders. - > ~~~~~~~~~oocn > o r- S~~~~~~~~~~0 11 C- C- ooi > rN CN rXON r- -t rl: 00 0,, -q - c 0l t 0 -) c _'~~~~~~~~~ C, S0 > k X N m m m -- W m C- C 7l 0 o- rq w 00 cs E - w r0 _C_) 0o m o C "C"C\CNI_\C 00 e) m 0 oN - ~0qr r-(N c, 1 >N t IN 5 IN .C - -0 W) 'I 00 IC C-_w2ot?N ~c rit- r- t~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~n Vkc;0 Ct - ^':; W m sz oo C)< (,, oc 6 O) V- (71 -- O m r It -- 00 o -~ t E > o. o oO NC 00 o_ v~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~C C4 CX tu S 0 XE-.Z X ?-k ~~~~~~~~ Y X ~ S E -X CA.. _ tn Y 1 C 0 e = g ~6 cl o \1 6 ro N e \m C>V_ o tn m C>C> m _ ? o _N o oooo m u U N > N e e w ^ o ~ ~ ~0Clfl ~ --~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~r: Cl 00 Cl > Q o m ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~C> < :c< 0 o 6\o 06 " "m tt >? o1 ot.i- eI \o o ~~~~~~i~~- ~~~~~~~~ o _X U X >St w .S < I Io m r' r- 06 ';~ot ot NDoNo>0o Hor o W Io > ? i { Io V C,; o, o o8e oo8-i eD0N000o o Z~~~~~C 0 0 0 00 Io= C C -> _66Cf Z -^ o # - X Y z o ~~~~~~) t It (Z) - O It m kr o C( r CN C) rn - ( - Q > 0 0 ow oN en - rt C C,, rvn ) ? 00r. 0 i-r t 0f) C s k Il o t m s~~~~~~~~- Z S X X O Wo C-, > N C n -rNoq40 -ro o X I C -vn? oo mO r -0r 0 \OmO> o > - t - m -o 40 roq 0 X t _ -> o - Xk ON C -- OC cq CN rn 0Vk) Nmt 4 C_)> s ibi>> - t oIr O oo 1 ( - X oo N t kr r V) 6 N rjo ? N 0 kr C ?o m - C)C- 00 OV r- O-r - U _n ri Z ONoo Im C ~ ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~ xk) kr I g~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~C - oo cq s ~~~~~~~ X - - >~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~C {_\ ? s O N o o C)) oo > ooo) q w-r) -t ? \o s~~~~~~~~~~~r 0<) r-, - v 0 >~~~~~~~~~~~~r -Cl00000(5N rn0 rtn C"\ )to> t kO - X C- 0v r- It O - o noo roq O r;o i;o i;o v) > OC O I o ? O r C 334 Brookings Papers on EconomicActivity, 2:1995 Table 10 shows that in 1992, 61 percentof householdswith a family income of more than $250,000 owned stock directly. The probability of direct or indirect stock ownership was 79 percent for this group. Both of these probabilitieswere much higher a decade earlier;in 1983 the probabilityof direct or indirect equity ownershipfor a household with an income of $250,000 (in 1992 dollars) was 92 percent. In 1992 approximately23 percentof corporatestock was owned by households with family incomes of more than $250,000; another23 percent was held by households with incomes between $100,000 and $250,000. Thusconsumptiondecisions by these householdsplay an importantpart in linking stock price fluctuationsto overall consumerspending. However, table 10 also shows the rising equality of share ownership. In 1983, households with family incomes of $100,000 and above (in 1992 dollars) held 75 percent of all directly held equity; that share had declined to 50 percentby 1992. Table 11 presents similar information on the nonequity financial assets of the householdsthatown corporatestock. Publiclytradedstock is the most unequally distributedequity measurethat we consider;43 percent of directly held stock is owned by households with nonequity financialasset holdings above $250,000. The comparisonbetween 1983 and 1992 again reveals a substantialincrease in ownershipof stock at lower wealth levels, consistent with the previous data on the family incomes of stock holders. On the most expansive definition of equity holdings, which includes equity in defined contributionplans as well as sharesheld throughfinancialintermediaries,27 percentof corporate stock is held by households with less than $50,000 in other financial assets, and 34 percentby those with nonequityfinancialassets between $50,000 and $250,000 in 1992. The conclusion thatemerges fromthis analysisof the cross-sectional data is that stock ownership has become more equal over time, but remainshighly concentrated.The propositionthat equity capital gains accrue to only a small set of households is not supportedby the data, since 37.4 percentof householdsowned some corporatestock in 1992. The concentrationof stock holdings nevertheless implies that a small subset of the population (about 5 percent of all households) receives roughly three-quartersof the capital gains and losses associated with stock price movements. James M. Poterba and AndrewA. Samwick 335 Stock Market Fluctuations and Consumption To analyze the relationshipbetween stock marketreturnsand consumption,we test whetherthe stock markethas a causalwealtheffect on consumption,or is simplya leadingindicatorthatforecastsfuturechanges in consumerspending.53We considerthe effect of rising stock priceson consumptionoutlaysin severalsteps. We begin by summarizingthe time series relationshipbetweenstock pricechangesandsubsequentconsumption fluctuations.The difficultyof interpretingthese time-seriesrelationships is illustratedby referenceto the consumptioneffects of the stock marketcrashes of 1987 and 1929. We then study four issues that are motivatedby the foregoingdiscussionof shareownershippatterns.First, we examine whetherstock price fluctuationsaffect the compositionof consumptionspending, in terms of "luxury goods" that are disproportionatelyconsumedby high-incomehouseholdsand all othergoods. Second, we use householdsurvey data to investigatewhetherconsumption by householdsthatown stock is moreclosely correlatedwith changesin shareprices than is consumptionby nonstockholdinghouseholds.Third, we investigatewhetherthe changingpatternof directversusindirectstock ownershipaffects the relationshipbetweenstock marketfluctuationsand movementsin consumptionspending.Specifically,we test whetherstock pricechangesin the early postwaryearshad greaterpredictivepowerfor consumptiongrowth than analogousfluctuationsin more recent years, when individualdirectstock ownershiphas representeda smallershareof total marketcapitalization.Fourth,we explore whetherchangesin share pricesthatare associatedwith changesin dividends(thatis, pricefluctuations with a constant dividend-to-priceratio) have differenteffects on consumptionspendingthanfluctuationsthatarenot supportedby dividend movements. Aggregate Statistics We begin by regressing the growth rate in real per capita consumption (Aln c,) on lagged changes in real share prices, Aln P,_ : 53. This leading indicatorview closely resemblesthe "passive informant"hypothesis that Morck, Shleifer, and Vishny (1990) develop with respectto stock price movements and investment spending. Detailed evidence on the predictivepower of stock returnsas leading indicatorsmay be found in Stock and Watson(1990). 336 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2:1995 Table12. Aggregate ConsumptionSpending and Stock Price Fluctuations! Dependentvariable Constant One quarter lagged change in real stock price Totalconsumption 0.0037 (0.0011) 0.031 (0.008) 0.0036 (0.0011) Consumptionof durables Consumptionof nondurables R2 .. . 0.068 0.064 (0.014) 0.101 ... 0.0017 (0.0057) 0.139 (0.041) .. . 0.058 -0.0011 (0.0057) .. . 0.290 (0.076) 0.091 0.0021 (0.0011) 0.032 (0.008) . ... 0.0023 (0.001 1) Consumptionof services Four quarter sumof lagged changesin stockprice 0.007 (0.006) 0.0055 (0.0008) ... 0.0056 (0.0008) . . 0.065 0.054 (0.015) 0.070 .. . 0.009 0.025 (0.010) 0.015 Source: Authors' regressions based on data from NIPA. a. Each row reports estimates of the coefficient oi, or oas, from an equation of the form Aln c, = ao + a(L)Aln P,_ I + e,. All equations are estimated from 1947:3 to 1995:2, and include seasonal dummy variables. Standard errors are shown in parentheses. (1) Aln c,= oz0 + 0(L) Aln Pt,I + Et. We consider equations with only the most recent lagged stock price change on the right-handside, as well as equationswith a fourth-order lag polynomial, oL(L).We estimateequationsusing seasonally adjusted quarterlydata from the second quarterof 1947 to the second quarterof 1995 1 9 .54 Table 12 presents the results of estimating equation 1 for several broad consumption aggregates. The results in the first row, for total consumptionwith only a single lagged stock return,suggest that stock 54. Fischer and Merton (1984) report some results for consumptiongrowth as a functionof lagged stock returns.Hall (1978) finds that lagged stock marketreturnsare the only variableknownat the beginningof each quarterwith predictivevalue for future consumptionchanges. James M. Poterba and AndrewA. Samwick 337 marketfluctuationsforecast increases in real consumptionoutlays. A 10 percentrise in real stock prices predictsan increasein real per capita consumptionof approximately0.3 percent.55Furtherlagged changes in share prices also have predictive power for consumptiongrowth. The second row of table 12, which also relates to total consumption,shows the sum of the coefficients on the four lagged values of stock price changes. Four quarters after a stock price increase the cumulative change in aggregate consumptionis 0.064, more than twice the firstquartereffect.56 In orderto considerthe predictionsthatstock price fluctuationsmake for various categories of consumption, table 12 also presents results with one lagged value and four lagged values of Aln P,__ for each of the three major subcategoriesof consumption:durables, nondurables, and services. The results in the lower rows of table 12 show that stock price changes predict the largest percentage change in spending for consumer durables. A 10 percent increase in share prices predicts an increase in durableoutlays of 1.4 percent in the first quarter,and 2.9 percentafter four quarters.Rising stock prices predicta proportionate increase in durable outlays that is between four and six times larger than that for nondurables,which, in turn, is several times largerthan the increase in the consumptionof services. To avoid the simultaneity in contemporaneousstock returns and consumption growth, the results in table 12 focus on the change in consumptionbeginning in the quarterafter a change in stock prices. This may result in underestimatingthe total change in consumptionthat is predictedby a stock price change, althoughthe use of quarterlydata should mitigate this problem. We have explored the sensitivity of our findings to the inclusion of contemporaneousstock marketreturns.In an equation like that in the second row of table 12, where the sum of the coefficients on four lagged stock marketreturnsis 0.064 (0.014), the current stock market return has a coefficient of 0.011 (0.007). 55. We test for the possibility that stock price increasesare associatedwith proportionally different changes in subsequentconsumptionthan stock price decreases, but find no evidence of such an effect. 56. In equationsnot reportedhere, we also include four lagged values of the real consumptiongrowth rate in the specification. Only one of these values enters with a statistically significant coefficient, and the predicted long-run effect of stock price growthon consumptionis very similar to that from the equationin the second row of table 12. 338 BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity, 2:1995 The coefficients on the lagged stock market returnsremain virtually unchangedwith the addition of the currentreturnto the specification. The largest contemporaneouscorrelationis between stock returnsand nondurableconsumption;the correlation with outlays on durables is negative. The point estimates in table 12 suggest that the 17 percentincrease in share prices between December 1994 and June 1995 predicts an increasein total consumptionof 1.09 percent,andan increasein durable consumption of 4.9 percent, after four quarters. Since total durable spending in 1994 was $591.5 billion and total consumption was $4,628.4 billion, this correspondsto a $29 billion incrementto 1995 durableoutlays and a $50.4 billion increasein total consumption.Since a 17 percent rise in share prices translatesinto just over $1 trillion of wealth creation, the predictedchange in consumptionspending is approximately0.05 times the change in net worth.57Thus the conclusion thatemerges from these consumptiongrowthequations,which exclude many potential control variables, is very similar to that of traditional aggregateconsumptionfunctionanalysis. The open questionis whether these results reflect the stock market's role as a leading indicator, or whether they are partly due to a wealth effect associated with stock price fluctuations.58 Consumption and the Stock Market in 1987 and 1929 In spite of the long traditionof modeling aggregateconsumptionas a function of labor income and household net worth, there appearsto be some reluctanceto apply this model to the analysis of the consumption effects of large stock market movements.59This is particularly 57. One componentof the link between stock price fluctuationsand consumption involves the "target saving" of defined benefit pension plans. When shareprices rise, corporationsdo not needto contributeas muchto theirpensionplansto coverprospective pension liabilities. This diminishes the flow of contributionsto these plans. In the nationalincome accountsthese contributionsare classifiedas personalsaving. Bernheim and Shoven (1988) discuss this linkage between asset prices and saving in more detail. 58. The ideal test for distinguishingthese views would study the reactionof consumptionto autonomouschanges in stock prices, changes that were not explainedby revisionsto expectationsaboutfuturecash flows or discountrates. Morck,Shleifer, and Vishny (1990) attempta related test in their analysis of how the stock marketaffects investment. 59. Ando and Modigliani(1963) is the seminal paperon the empiricalmodelingof James M. Poterba and AndrewA. Samwick 339 evident in discussions about the economic effects of the stock market crashes in 1987 and 1929. The stock marketcrash of October 1987 provides a valuable opportunity to study the effect of stock price fluctuationson consumption spending, andto review the economic analysisof this effect. As a result of the crash, real share prices declined by nearly 30 percentfrom their peak in August 1987. In evaluatingthe potentialeffect of such a price changeon consumerspending, the reportof the PresidentialTask Force on Market Mechanisms concluded that "it is unlikely that a direct wealth effect along the straightforwardlines usually described stands behind . . . the observed relationship between stock price movements and aggregate-level consumer spending."60 This statementwas based on the fact that most householdsdo not own stock andthatamongthose thatdo, the distributionof ownershipis highly concentrated,as well as on the view thatthose who do own substantialstock have enoughwealth to insulate their consumer spending from short-runshocks.6' Popular accounts noted that the feared collapse in consumptionhad failed to materialize in the months after the crash, and surveys indicated that most consumershad not adjustedtheir spendingpatternsin responseto the crash.62 Two importantfeaturesof the 1987 stock marketcrashwere the short durationof the stock price increase that precededit and the reboundin shareprices in the quarterafterthe crash. The growthpathof both total anddurableconsumption,as well as the patternof stock marketreturns, for the seven quarterscenteredon the October 1987 stock marketcrash is shown below: aggregateconsumptionas a functionof laborincomeandnet worth. Blinderand Deaton (1985) providea recentdiscussion of aggregateconsumptionfunctions. 60. U.S. PresidentialTask Force on MarketMechanisms(1988, p. VII-2). 61. Mankiwand Zeldes (1991) note that householdsthatreportowning stock in the Panel Study of Income Dynamics account for 32 percentof total food consumptionin this database.Because the budgetshareof food is smallerfor high-income,high-wealth households than for lower-income households, the fraction of total consumptionaccountedfor by stockholdersis presumablygreaterthanthis. 62. In a Business Week-Harrispoll, 85 percent of respondentsindicatedthat the crash did not affect their finances. By that time some macroeconomicforecastershad also reviseddownwardtheirview of the "wealth effect" of stockpriceson consumption. (See KarenPennar, "It's Almost As If It Never Happened-Almost," Business Week, April 18, 1988, pp. 56-59.) 340 Quarter 1987:1 1987:2 1987:3 1987:4(crash) 1988:1 1988:2 1988:3 BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity, 2:1995 Log change in stock price 14.8 1.9 4.6 - 29.0 9.1 0.6 - 2.3 Per capita growth Total consumption Durables -0.002 0.010 0.007 -0.003 0.015 0.004 0.005 -0.067 0.032 0.033 -0.034 0.047 0.002 -0.010 The stock price increases in the three quartersbefore the crash were reversedby the crash, but stock prices finished 1987 only 7.7 percent below their value a year earlier. The stock market rally in the first quarterof 1988 left the marketabove its value in January1987. The informaltable above shows that per capitaconsumptiongrowth was slightly negative, and that growth in spending on durables was substantiallynegative, in the quarterof the crash.63Includingindicator variablesfor the fourthquarterof 1987 and the first quarterof 1988 in the regressionequationsfor total consumptionoutlays reportedin table 12 yields coefficient estimates, with standarderrorsin parentheses,of -0.0096 (0.0073) and 0.018 (0.008), respectively. Thus the first quarterof 1988 experiencedmorerapidconsumptiongrowththanwould have been predictedby simple models with four lagged quarterlyvalues of stock returns. We cannot reject the null hypothesis of no unusual effect on totalconsumptionin the fourthquarterof 1987.64 Fordurables, the patternsare slightly different. The effect of the fourth quarterof 1987 is negative, but the coefficient for the firstquarterof 1988 is 0.071 (0.042). Expenditureon durablesdid decline in the quarterof the stock marketcrash, but it was unusually strong during the first quarterof 1988, given the decline in share prices. The data thus suggest that the 63. Dornbuschand Fischer(1994) note thatconsumptiongrew slowly afterthe crash and use this as evidence in supportof a wealth effect on consumption. 64. The models in table 12 relate consumptiongrowthto lagged returns.Since the stock market crash occurred only three weeks into the fourth quarterof 1987, it is plausibleto expect unusuallylow consumptiongrowth in this quarter.While the coefficient estimateon the dummyvariablefor the fourthquarterof 1987 confirmsthis, we are unableto reject the hypothesisthat consumptiongrowthin this quarteris explained by the model that excludes currentreturns. James M. Poterba and AndrewA. Samwick 341 1987 stock marketcrash had a smaller negative effect on consumption growththanthe regressionequationsin table 12 would have predicted.65 The events of 1929 and the early 1930s provide anotheropportunity to study the effect of stock price fluctuationson consumption.The data for this period are less detailed than for 1987, and the strengthof the conclusions that can be drawn is correspondinglylower. Calculations that assume a stable marginal propensity to consume out of wealth suggest that the wealth effect of the 1929 crash on consumerspending should have been small, both because the stock marketaccountedfor a relativelysmall shareof householdnet worth, andbecausethe marginal propensityto consume out of wealth appearsto have been small during the interwarperiod.66Household spending on durablesdeclined more than that on nondurables,which remainedrobustuntil 1932.67 Thus it appearsthat the effect of a stock price decline on consumers, through the wealth effect, was muted. Stock Returns and Spending on Luxury Goods We investigate whether stock price fluctuations affect consumer spending througha wealth effect by examining whetherstock returns forecastchanges in the compositionof consumerspending. We use the ConsumerExpenditureSurvey published by the Bureauof LaborStatistics to identify several groups of goods that are disproportionately consumedby high-incomehouseholdsthat are likely to own stock, and 65. Birinyi and Miller (1987) conclude that the evidence that stock marketfluctuations cause consumptionchanges is weak at best. They find a very weak association betweenthe pricesof New YorkCity condominiumsandchangesin stock marketvalues, despitethe fact that this is a luxuryconsumptionitem that might be demandedby stock owners. This evidence is similar, in spirit, to ourtests for whetherstock marketfluctuations affect the shareof luxuryconsumption,discussed below. 66. A constantmarginalpropensityto consumeout of wealth is a specializedresult thatobtains, for example, when a consumermaximizesa time-separableutility function with per-periodutility given by ln(C). More generally, the marginalpropensityto consume out of wealth dependsupon the availablerateof return. 67. Temin (1976) discusses the effect of the 1929 stock marketcrashon consumption. Romer (1990) draws particularattentionto the role of consumeruncertaintyin depressingconsumptionof householddurables.Wigmore(1985) examinesthe behavior of the earningsand share prices of companies in various sectors of the economy and notes the relatively stable earningsof retailersuntil 1932. Durablesproducers,notably automobilecompanies, experiencedsharpdownturnsin profitsand share prices much soonerafterthe crash. 342 BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity, 2:1995 Table 13. Consumptionof Luxuries and Antiluxuries Unitsas indicated Consumption category Totalconsumption Luxuries New automobiles Education" OtherLodging Entertainmentc Householdservices Anti-Luxuries Renteddwellings Tobaccoproducts Consumptionshare of $70,000 + households" Spendingratio, $70,000 + householdsto $20,000-$30,000 households" Consumption shareby category 0.236 1.85 1.000 0.314 0.308 0.369 0.337 0.296 3.10 3.24 3.69 3.44 2.76 0.023 0.023 0.003 0.004 0.003 0.045 0.099 0.25 0.54 0.037 0.008 Source: The consumption share of the highest-income households and the spending ratio are from the Consumer Expenditure Surveys for 1991-93, as reported in U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics (1994). Consumption share by category is from NIPA for 1994. a. Households are allocated to income groups on the basis of pretax income. b. Education is the NIPA personal consumption category for "education and research." c. Entertainmentis the sum of the NIPA personal consumption categories for admission to "motion picture theaters," "legitimate theaters and opera," and "spectator sports." test whether the share of these goods in aggregateconsumptionrises afterstock prices increase.68Anecdotalevidence suggests a very strong marketfor some luxuryproductsin 1995, possibly relatedto the rise in shareprices.69 Table 13 presentsthe resultsof this analysisof consumptionpatterns. It reportsboththe shareof spendingon particularitems thatis accounted for by householdswith annualbefore-taxincomes of $70,000 andabove (the value at which income in the ConsumerExpenditureSurveyis topcoded) and the ratio of spending by this group to spending by households with before-tax income between $20,000 and 30,000. For example, householdswith incomes of $70,000 andabove accountfor 31.4 percentof spending on new cars, while they account for 23.6 percent of spendingon all goods. Table 14 reportsthe results of estimating consumptionshare equations that are designed to evaluate whetherincreasesin shareprices tilt 68. U.S. Bureauof LaborStatistics (1994). 69. See LauraBird, "Tired of T-Shirtsand No-NameWatches, ShoppersReturnto Tiffany and Chanel," WallStreetJournal, September6, 1995, p. B 1. James M. Poterba and AndrewA. Samwick 343 Table 14. Consumptionof Luxuries and Antiluxuriesand Stock Price Fluctuationsa One quarterlaggedchange in stockprice Four quartersumof lagged changesin stockprice 0.250 (0.103) 0.627 (0.193) Education -0.022 (0.012) -0.041 (0.024) Otherlodging -0.007 (0.041) 0.011 (0.082) Entertainment -0.086 (0.056) -0.128 (0.109) Householdservices -0.000 (0.033) 0.019 (0.065) -0.026 (0.007) -0.051 (0.015) -0.018 (0.024) -0.071 (0.046) Dependentvariable Luxuries New automobiles Antiluxuries Renteddwellings Tobaccoproducts Source: Authors' regressions based on data from NIPA. a. The estimated equation is of the form ln(L,IC,) = ot( + ot lln(L,.1/C,_ I)I + 0t2(AInP,-1) + E,, where L, denotes luxury (or antiluxury) consumption and C, denotes aggregate consumption spending. All equations are estimated from 1959:1 to 1995:2, with the exception of the equation for new automobiles, which is estimated from 1947:2 to 1995:2. All equations include seasonal dummy variables. Standarderrors are shown in parentheses. the composition of consumption toward goods that are consumed by higher-income, stockholding households. The first row considers spendingon new cars. A 10 percentrise in shareprices in the current quarteris predictedto raise spendingon new cars as a fractionof total consumptionby 2.5 percent in the next quarter, and by 6.3 percent after four quarters.70After four quarters, a 20 percent rise in share prices, similarto the rise in the firsthalf of 1995, would raise spending on new cars from 2.3 percentto 2.6 percentof total spending. Whetherthese findings for new car sales reflect the operationof a wealth effect or simply the stock market'sforecastof strongconsumer demandcan be evaluated by considering the relative demandfor differenttypes of automobiles.Ward'sAutomotiveYearbookallocatesnew 70. One difficulty with interpretingthese results is that automobilemanufacturers and the firmsthat supply them with componentscomprisea nontrivialfractionof total stock marketvalue. If investorsforesee an increase in new car sales, stock prices may rise as a result. 344 Brookings Papers on EconomicActivity, 2:1995 Figure 5. Luxury Car Sales, 1980-95 Percentof new cars sold Percentof new cars sold 16 4 A tr 12 104 vu cr | \i, 311l 0 10 Iars Upperluxury (rightaxis) 2 6 I 1980 I 1983 I I 1986 1989 I 1992 l 1995 Source: Authors' calculations based on data from Ferris (1995). See text for classifications. cars to several differentcategories, one of which is termed"luxury."71 This includes most cars with prices above $25,000 in 1994, and many with prices below this level. Of 8.99 million cars sold in 1994, 1.22 million were classified as luxury cars. Further, the "upper luxury" category, which accounted for 0.17 million cars in 1994, consists of only fifteen models, including BMWs in the 5-, 6-, and 7-series, three Jaguars,and Mercedes E- and S-class cars. The households who purchase these vehicles are almost surely in the wealth category where stock ownership is prevalent, and many are likely to have substantial equity portfolios. Figure 5 shows both luxuryand upperluxurycars as a percentageof new car sales for the period 1980-95. To study the effect of share prices on luxury car purchases, we 71. Ferris (1995). James M. Poterba and AndrewA. Samwick 345 estimate a regression equation for the luxury fractionof new car sales in each quarter. If share price changes affect consumer spending througha wealth effect, then stock returnsshould affect positively the fraction of new car sales that are classified as luxury vehicles. We estimate this relationship for the period between the first quarterof 1980 and the second quarterof 1995:2, for which the Ward'sdatawere available. The regressionequation, which includesunreportedseasonal indicatorvariables, is as follows (with standarderrorsin parentheses): ln(luxury,lallcar,) = - 0.283 - 0.084(Aln Pt-,) + 0.821[ln(luxuryt_,/allcart_,)], (0.130) (0.098) R2 (0.064) = 0.763. These resultsdo not supportthe existence of an importantwealtheffect. The unreportedseasonal coefficients suggest that purchasesof luxury cars reach their highest share of all vehicles in the fourth quarterof each year; on average, they account for a 14.5 percentgreatershareof total vehicle sales in the fourthquarterthanin the firstquarter,and 5.4 percentmore in the fourthquarterthan in the thirdquarter. We estimate a similar equationfor the share of upperluxurycars in the mix of automobilessold, with the following results (standarderrors are in parentheses): ln(upp luxtlallcart) - 0.223 + 0.017(zln Pt ) + 0.900[ln(upp luxt/allcart)], = (0.244) (0.046) (0.056) R2 = 0.824. While stock prices are positively correlatedwith the upperluxuryfraction of new vehicle sales, the effect is not statisticallysignificant.These results also provide little supportfor the wealth effect, as opposed to the leading indicator, explanationof the correlationbetween stock returnsand futureconsumptiongrowth. The results for the otherluxuryitems that we considerare consistent with the findings for luxury cars. The regression coefficients on each consumptioncategory are shown in table 14. We cannotreject the null hypothesis that stock price changes do not predict any change in the shareof aggregateconsumptionaccountedfor by education, hotel and motel spending, domestic services, and entertainmentspending. In 346 BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity, 2:1995 most cases the standarderrors on the estimates are large, admitting large positive or negative effects, but the point estimates are not supportive of wealth effects. The two "antiluxuries" consideredat the bottomof table 14 provide more supportfor the propositionthat stock returnsaffect the composition of consumption. Rising share prices are associated with a decline in the share of rental housing in total consumption, and exert a weak negative effect on the share of tobacco spending. Thus, overall, this analysis of luxury goods producestnixed results. Stock Prices and Consumption: Household-Level Evidence Aggregatedataappearto have limitedpowerto resolve whetherstock returnsexert a significantwealth effect on consumption.An alternative source of informationon this issue is household survey data. One of the standardproblemswith basing such analysis on householdsurveys, however, is the absence of data sets that collect informationon both household portfolio holdings and consumption. The Panel Study of Income Dynamics (PSID), which collects informationduringthe first few monthsof each year, is one survey that does containboth types of data, althoughdirect informationon consumptionis limited to outlays on food. In an importantstudy designed to help resolve the "equity premiumpuzzle," GregoryMankiw and StephenZeldes stratifyPSID households into those that own stock and those that do not, and then computethe correlationbetween growthin percapitafood consumption andexcess returnson the stock marketfor the two groups.72The results suggest that this correlationis substantiallyhigher for those who own stock thanfor others. These resultscould be due to differencesbetween stockholdersandnonstockholdersthatareunrelatedto shareownership, per se, but they at least raise the possibility that stock returnsaffect consumptionthroughwealth effects. We revisit the Mankiw-Zeldesanalysis, but introducethree modifications. First, in additionto consideringgrowth in food consumption, we analyze a broadermeasureof total consumption.JonathanSkinner shows that informationon rent payments and house value, as well as spendingfor food at home and away from home, can be used to obtain 72. See Mankiwand Zeldes (1991). James M. Poterba and AndrewA. Samwick 347 a proxy for total householdconsumptionfor PSID households.73While food consumption alone explains only 26 percent of the variation in total consumptionfrom the ConsumerExpenditureSurvey, a consumption proxy including house value and rentalpaymentsexplains 72 percent. Thus it seems possible to substantiallyimprove upon food consumptionas an indicatorof householdconsumption.Second, we exploit informationthat has been released since Mankiw and Zeldes's study, notably, additional years of consumption data. Third, we use PSID informationon participationin pension plans and employerthriftplans to identify households that are likely to have only indirectholdings of corporatestock. While direct ownership of tradedequity and mutual fundscannotbe distinguishedin the PSID, the distinctionbetweenthose with such equity holdings andthose with equity in 401(k) plans, 403(b) plans, or definedcontributionpension plans is relevantfor our analysis of direct versus indirectstock holdings.74 We follow previous work in defining the sample for analysis.75In particular,we exclude PSID families who were partof the 1968 poverty subsample, families that are living with other families (which makes it difficult to distinguish consumptionoutlays), family-yearsin which the identity of the household head or the head's spouse changed, and family-yearsin which any componentof consumptionwas top-coded. Our sample spans the period 1970-92, but because the PSID did not collect informationon food consumption in 1973, 1988, or 1989, it excludes the years 1973, 1974, 1988, 1989, and 1990. We stratify PSID households along three dimensions. The first is whether or not they report ownership of corporate stock or mutual funds. We distinguish between households with different levels of direct equity ownership, defining as "stockholders" those with any corporatestock, those with morethan$ 1,000 in corporatestock, andthose 73. Skinner (1987) develops this broaderconsumptionmeasure and explores its statisticalproperties. 74. The PSID survey asks households whetherthey own "any shares of stock in publicly held corporations, mutual funds, or investment trusts, including stocks in IRAs." 75. We follow the sample selection and datadefinitionrules describedin the appendix to Mankiw and Zeldes (1991) and Zeldes (1989). When we test for differences in the correlationbetween consumptiongrowth and stock returnsfor householdsthathold stock andthose thatdo not, we obtainresultsthatarebroadlysimilarto those of Mankiw andZeldes for the sample periodthat they consider. 348 BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity, 2:1995 with more than $10,000 (in 1984 dollars). The second dimension is whether the head of household or the head's spouse participatesin a thrift plan; and the third is participationin a pension plan.76We then considerthe correlationbetween the year-to-yeargrowthof the Skinner consumptionaggregate and stock marketreturnsfor groups of households with differentcombinationsof directequityholdings, thriftplans, andpension coverage. While the previousanalysisfocused on quarterly time-series data and related changes in consumptionto lagged stock marketreturns, because the PSID data are annual we now focus on contemporaneouschanges in share prices and consumption.77 Table 15 presentsthe resultsof our analysis. The upperpanel reports results for growth in food consumption, while the lower panel is concerned with growth in the Skinnerconsumptionindex.78When we use the Skinnerindex, we find small differences in the correlationbetween growthin consumptionandstock returnsfor stockholdersandnonstockholders. For each classification of stock ownership, however, the correlation is greaterfor those who are classified as stockholdersthan for those who are not. With the Skinner index, only one of these differences, that for stockholders with more than $10,000 in equity, approaches significance underconventional statistical tests. Most of the findingsfor food consumption, in the upperpanel, are also imprecise. It is disturbingthat many of the correlationsbetween the growth rate of the Skinnerconsumptionindex andexcess stock returnsarenegative. This appearsto be due to the nonfood componentsof the index, since 76. The PSID only collects detailed informationon pension plan characteristicsfor workersover the age of forty-five. For youngerworkers,it does not distinguishbetween definedbenefit and defined contributionplans. Thereforewe can only use an indicator variable for "pension plan participant," recognizing that this includes some defined benefitplan participantswith no equity stake along with equity holdersthroughdefined contributionplans. 77. We have estimated the correlationbetween currentconsumptiongrowth and lagged stock returnsfor the PSID householdsand findthatthe resultingcorrelationsare indistinguishablefrom zero. This is due to our choice of sampleperiod;a similarresult emergesfrom annualnationalaccountsdatafor the PSID sampleyears, even thoughour findings in table 12 show that, over a longer period, quarterlynationalaccountsdata suggest a positive correlationbetween changes in stock price and consumptiongrowth. 78. The differences in the correlationsbetween stock returnsand growth in food consumptionfor stockholdersand nonstockholdersparallelthose in MankiwandZeldes (1991). Ourresultsfromthe longerPSID sampleperiodyield less statisticallysignificant differencesin these correlationsthanthose found by Mankiwand Zeldes. James M. Poterba and AndrewA. Samwick 349 Table 15. Correlationof ConsumptionGrowth and Stock Returnsfor Stockholders and NonstockholdersL Correlation Consumptionmeasure and stockownership category Per capitafood consumption Nonstockholders Withoutthriftplan Withthriftplan Withoutpensionplan Withpensionplan Stockholders Withoutthriftplan Withthriftplan Withoutpensionplan Withpensionplan Criterionfor classificationas a "stockholder" Stock value > 0 Stock value > 1,000 Stock value > 10,000 0.120 0.058 0.350 0.059 0.143 0.125 0.190 0.043 0.148 0.089 0.076 0.077 0.049 0.071 0.047 0.214 0.133 0.261 0.134 0.205 0.078 0.063 0.226 0.044 0.080 0.286 0.226 0.314 0.339 0.232 Per capitaSkinnerconsumptionindex Nonstockholders -0.125 Withoutthriftplan - 0.208 Withthriftplan 0.218 Withoutpensionplan - 0.217 Withpensionplan -0.004 Stockholders 0.011 Withoutthriftplan 0.081 Withthriftplan -0.095 Withoutpensionplan 0.055 Withpensionplan -0.012 -0.146 -0.178 -0.010 -0.191 -0.090 0.068 0.042 0.094 0.026 0.092 - 0.126 - 0.182 0.048 -0.202 -0.052 0.219 0.269 0.097 0.226 0.187 Source: Authors' calculations based on data from the PSID. a. Each entry reports the correlation of a measure of consumption growth with return on the stock market for PSID households in each category, as described in the text. The sample period is 1970-92, excluding 1973, 1974, 1988, 1989, and 1990. Stockholders are defined by the criteria at the column heads. The standard error of each calculation may be computed as A/V(1where 16 denotes the degrees of freedom; these standarderrors are approximately0.25 for each pT2)/16, entry. the correlationbetween food consumptiongrowthand excess returnsis positive. The results with respect to indirect stock ownershipare suggestive, but not conclusive. For both food consumptiongrowthand the Skinner index of consumptiongrowth, and for most definitionsof stock ownership, those who have thriftplans exhibit greatercorrelationbetween consumptiongrowthand stock returnsthanthose who do not have thrift plans. Similarly, those with pension plans, some of which are defined contributionplans, also exhibit a higher consumptiongrowth correla- 350 BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity, 2:1995 tion than those without such plans.79These results are consistent with the notion that even indirect stock holding mattersin household consumption planning, but they do not reject the null hypothesis of no effect. Moreover, some of the patternsare difficultto explain. For two of the three definitionsof stock ownership, in the Skinnerindex, those in thrift plans exhibit weaker consumption growth correlationsthan those who are not. The results of this analysis are strongerthan the findings using aggregate data, but they are still not conclusive. Stock returnsare more closely correlatedwith the consumptiongrowthof householdsthatown stock than of those that do not. The PSID data do not, however, have enough power to distinguish between the view that only direct stock ownership matters and the possibility that direct and indirect stock ownershiphave similareffects on consumptiongrowth. The results are consistent with the presence of a wealth effect, but they do not provide definitive supportfor one. There is only weak evidence that the consumptiongrowth of those with larger stock portfolios is more closely correlatedwith stock market fluctuationsthan is the consumptionof those with small portfolios. Share Ownership and the Consumption-Stock Price Nexus The thirdbroadissue that we consider concernsthe effect of changing stock ownership patterns on the link between stock returns and consumption. We study this question by interactingthe lagged stock return variable in equation 1 with two measures of the fraction of corporatestock held by households.80The first measure, which corresponds to direct individual ownership, is the ratio of stock ownership for the Flow of Funds household sector (excluding nonprofitholdings) to the total marketvalue of sharesoutstanding.This time series declines substantiallyduringthe postwarperiod, from 72.3 percentin 1960, to 51.3 percent in 1980, to 40.2 percent in 1994. We amendequation 1 79. These findings emerge for two of the three definitionsof stockholders:those with any equity and those with stock worth more than $10,000. 80. We also test the subsamplecoefficientstabilityof the equationsreportedin table 12, dividing the sample before and after the first quarterof 1970, and before and after the first quarterof 1985. We cannot reject the null hypothesisof constantcoefficients for any of the consumptioncategories;this foreshadowsourweak resultsfor the trending shareownershipvariables. James M. Poterba and AndrewA. Samwick 351 to include lagged stock price changes as well as the lagged price change interactedwith the direct share ownershipmeasure,SHARE1, : (2) Aln c, = oxo+ (xI(AlnP,_ I) + o2(SHAREJ,t)(Aln P,) + E,. Because Aln Pt_ I andSHARE1,_l (Aln P,_ ) are collinearvariables,we also estimate equationsthat only include the interactionterm.8' In addition, we estimate equation 2 with a variable that captures direct as well as indirectshareownership(SHARE2,)in the interaction term. SHARE2,is the percentageof corporatestock owned by individuals directlyor throughbankpersonaltrusts, mutualfunds, anddefined contributionpension plans. The time series for SHARE2,is shown in the last column of table 6. This time series declines more gradually over the postwar period than SHARE]. In 1970 SHARE2was 75 percent, and by 1994 it had fallen to 63.7 percent. The results of estimatingequation2 are shown in table 16. The first row shows an equation relating consumptiongrowth to lagged stock returnswithout any allowance for shareownershipeffects. The second row shows the effect of including the interactiveterm with SHARE],. The coefficient on the lagged stock price change is negative, and that on the interactionterm is positive and roughly twice as large as the coefficient on the stock price change in the first row. The collinearity of these two variablesmakes it impossible to reject the hypothesisthat either oxlor Ot2 in equation 2 is equal to zero, although we reject the hypothesis that these coefficients are jointly zero. The third row presents an equation that includes only the SHAREl,(AlnP, ) variable and shows that the explanatorypower of this variablealone is greater than that of the lagged stock price variablealone.82 The fourth and fifth rows in table 16 show results parallelto those in the second and thirdrows, with SHARE2,insteadof SHARE],in the interactionterms. The findings are similar to those for SHARE],; the interactionterm is the more importantin the specification with both variables and it has a positive effect on consumption, whereas the 81. Includinga trendingvariablesuch as SHARE],_ as a separateregressorin these equationsdoes not affect the resultsbecausethereis little trendin the rateof consumption growth. 82. A nonnestedhypothesis test of the model with SHAREJ,(AlnP,-,) as the dependentvariable, against the model with Aln P,_ , does not permitus to reject either hypothesisin favor of the other. 352 Brookings Papers on EconomicActivity, 2:1995 Table 16. Regressions of Consumption on Stock Prices for Alternative Stock Ownership Share Variablesa Stockownership share variable Constant Laggedchangein real stockprice Ownershipshare x lagged changein real stockprice R2 None . . 0.0047 (0.0005) 0.030 (0.007) 0.0047 (0.0005) - 0.003 (0.031) 0.060 (0.055) 0.098 0.0047 (0.0005) . . . 0.056 (0.012) 0.104 0.0047 (0.0005) -0.064 (0.069) 0.136 (0.099) 0.102 0.0047 (0.0005) . . . 0.045 (0.010) 0.103 . 0.098 Direct individual stock ownership Expanded individual stock ownership Source: Authors' regressions based on consumption data from NIPA. Share prices and ownership are the authors' calculations based on data in Federal Reserve, Flow of Funds Accounts. a. The dependent variable is total consumption. Each row corresponds to an estimate of an equation of the form An c, = oao+ ota(AlnP,_1) + _y2(SHAREI,II)AlnP,_1 + e,. All estimates correspond to the period from 1947:2 to 1995:2, representing 193 quarterlyobservations. The values ofSHAREI and SHARE2, that replaces SHARE] in the foregoing equation, are defined on the basis of data from the Flow of Funds Accounts for the period from 1952:4 to 1994:4; they are extrapolated at either end of the sample. All equations include seasonal dummy variables. Standard errors are shown in parentheses. lagged share price term alone has a negative coefficient. Yet the collinearityproblems remain. On balance, the results do not supportthe view that changing patternsof stock ownershipalter the link between shareprice fluctuationsand consumption."83 The Forecasting Power of Stock Returns, Dividend Movements, and Earnings Movements A final aspect of the linkage between stock returnsand consumption concernswhetherthe source of stock price fluctuationsaffects the predictive power of stock returnsfor future consumptiongrowth. Given 83. One way to develop additionaltests of whetherstock ownershippatternsaffect the wealtheffect of stock prices on consumptionwould be to analyzedatafromdifferent countries. In Japan, for example, the fractionof shares held directly by individualsis substantiallylower than that in the United States. James M. Poterba and AndrewA. Samwick 353 the evidence that fluctuations in the price-to-dividend and price-toearnings ratios predict future stock returns, implying that increases in stock prices that are not associated with rising dividends are more likely to be transitory than similar price changes backed by dividend fluctuations, there might be differences in the predictive effects of different stock market shocks. To explore whether fluctuations in share prices, dividends, earnings, or some combination of these variables have the greatest predictive power for consumption spending, we augment equation 1, for the simple case of ox(L) = ox, with the lagged change in dividend payments for the stocks in the S&P 500, Aln Dt_ l: (3) Aln c, = oxo + xI(AlnP,t) + y(Aln D,t) + E,. If share price fluctuations predict the same change in future consumption regardless of their source, then Yi should equal zero. If stock prices only predict changes in consumption when prices move while the priceto-dividend ratio remains constant, then yl should be positive and o(x should be indistinguishable from zero. Table 17 shows the results of estimating equation 3, with dividend growth rates and also lagged earning growth rates in the specification. The estimates suggest that changes in stock prices predict similar changes in consumption, regardless of their source. The equations that include lagged dividend growth provide no support for the view that dividend fluctuations can predict future consumption growth. We cannot reject the null hypothesis that changes in real dividends have no predictive power for future consumption growth, and the estimated coefficient on real share prices is virtually unaffected by including real dividends in these equations. These results are insensitive to our choice of consumption aggregate. The results with lagged earnings growth are more difficult to interpret. For two of the four broad consumption categories, total consumption and spending on durables, the lagged earnings growth variable enters with a positive coefficient that is statistically significantly different from zero at roughly the 10 percent significance level. Controlling for earnings growth does not reduce the coefficient on the lagged change in real stock prices, but actually raises this coefficient in all specifications. As a further test of these results, not shown here, we have estimated models with four lagged values of real stock price changes and 354 BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity, 2:1995 Table 17.Linkage between ConsumptionSpending, Stock Price Fluctuations, Dividends, and Earningsa Dependent variable Total consumption Consumption of durables Consumption of nondurables Consumption of services Constant Lagged stock price Lagged dividends 0.0045 0.030 0.002 (0.0005) (0.007) (0.021) 0.0044 0.032 (0.0005) (0.007) 0.0070 0.137 (0.0030) (0.041) 0.0063 0.146 (0.0029) (0.041) ... -0.008 . . . 0.032 0.013 (0.021) 0.033 . . . 0.0059 0.008 0.001 (0.006) (0.016) 0.0058 0.008 (0.006) 0.071 0.015 0.081 . . 0.046 0.100 0.062 . . . 0.074 0.010 0.076 . (0.011) (0.0004) (0.0004) . . (0.056) (0.008) (0.008) R2 (0.113) 0.0022 0.0021 . _ (0.010) (0.0006) (0.0006) Lagged earnings . . . . .. 0.005 -0.001 0.001 (0.008) Source: Authors' regressions based on consumption data from NIPA. Stock prices, dividends, and earnings are the authors' calculations based on data in Federal Reserve, Flow of Funds Accounts. a. Each row reports estimates of the coefficients in the equationAin c, = oao+ ota(AlnP,_l) + -yj(Aln D,_,) + El, or this equation with E,_- replacing D,_ 1. All estimated correspond to the period from 1947:3 to 1995:2, representing 192 quarterly observations. Dividends denotes the real value of dividend payments to shares in the S&P 500; earnings denotes the analogous measure of earnings for these firms. Standarderrors are shown in parentheses. four lagged values of real earnings growth. The results do not support the notion that earnings fluctuations are an important determinant of consumption growth. The sum of the coefficients on the four lagged stock return terms is positive and statistically significantly different from zero. The sum of the coefficients on lagged earnings, however, is negative and statistically insignificantly different from zero. Thus the evidence seems to suggest that share price increases have similar effects on consumption, regardless of their source. We follow a separate strategy to identify the effects of shocks to discount rates and to expected cash flows on consumption growth. We estimate a first-order autoregression for the price-to-dividend ratio and define the residuals from this equation as estimates of the shock to discount rate expectations.84 For the period from the second quarter of 84. This procedurefollows the suggestion of Fama and French(1988, p. 20), who James M. Poterba and AndrewA. Samwick 355 1947 to the second quarter of 1995, this autoregression generates an estimated coefficient of 0.961 (0.021) on the lagged value of the dividend-to-price ratio (DIP). We then include the value of [(D/P),_ 0.961(D/P),t2] in regression equations analogous to those in table 12. The results suggest that it is not possible to distinguish the effects of discount rate shocks and cash flow shocks with the available data. For example, the estimated equation for total consumption (with standard errors in parentheses) is Aln c, = 0.004 + 0.013(Aln P,t-) - 0.004[(D/P), (0.001) (0.016) (0.003) R2 = 0.0719. I - 0.961(D/P),t2], The imprecision of the coefficient estimates makes it difficult to argue that shocks to expected returns are more or less important than shocks to cash flow in predicting future consumption growth. Conclusions and Future Directions This paper documents substantial changes in the aggregate and crosssectional patterns of corporate stock ownership during the postwar period. There has been a gradual but significant trend toward greater ownership of equity through mutual funds and thrift plans (for example, 401(k)s, ESOPs, and 403(b)s) and defined contribution pension plans. In each of these cases direct individual ownership has been replaced by indirect ownership through a financial intermediary. The rise of IRAs, thrift plans, and other related institutions has led to an increase in stock ownership during the most recent decade, substantially reversing a decline during the previous two decades. We explore the implications of growing ownership by intermediaries for the effect of stock price fluctuations on consumer spending. We find clear evidence that changes in share prices portend growth in consumer spending, and particularly large growth in outlays on consumer durables. We then try to distinguish between two alternative explanations arguethat "the unexpectedcomponentof DIP can be interpretedas a (noisy) measure of the shock to expected returns." 356 Brookings Papers on EconomicActivity, 2:1995 for this finding. The first is the view that stock returnsare a leading indicator, reflecting news that suggests a prospective increase in consumption before the change actually occurs. The second is the traditional wealth effect of asset market fluctuations, which suggests that higher stock prices should lead to an increase in consumerspending. We investigatethe effect of stock returnson the shareof consumption thatis devoted to luxurygoods, and also use household-leveldatafrom the Panel Study of Income Dynamics to study the correlationbetween consumptiongrowth and stock returnsfor households that own corporate stock and those thatdo not. We do not find any pronouncedeffects of stock price fluctuationson the mix of luxury and nonluxuryconsumptionwithin the following year. This evidence casts doubt on the short-run importance of wealth effects associated with stock price movements.85We do not find any evidence that changing patternsof shareownershiphave alteredthe relationshipbetween stock price fluctuationsand consumption,even thoughsuch effects might be expected in some behavioralmodels of saving and consumption. These findings representa challenge to the traditionalmodel of the aggregateconsumptionfunction that is found in many macroeconomic textbooks.86The logic of budgetconstraintssuggests that stock market rallies that increasehousehold wealth must be reflectedeither in higher consumptionduringthe lifetimes of currentstockholders,or in greater bequests.It is possible thatconsumptionrespondsgraduallyto increases in stock marketwealth, and that our focus on fluctuationsin consumption within a year of stock price movements does not capture these effects. It is also possible that the effect of stock price fluctuationson consumptionoperates throughchannels other than a direct wealth effect, for example by altering "consumerconfidence." Moregenerally, our findingssuggest the need to develop betterdata, andpossibly better models, for the determinationof consumptionspendingby high-wealth households. While our primaryfocus is on testing for wealth effects, we also investigate the links between the predictivepower of changes in stock 85. It is still possible that cash realizationsof past gains affect currentconsumption outlays, as suggested in Poterba(1991). 86. In manyways, they parallelthe findingsof Morck,Shleifer, and Vishny (1990) thatthe stock market'srole in predictinginvestmentmovementsis largelydue to its role as a passive informantof futuredevelopments. James M. Poterba and AndrewA. Samwick 357 prices, dividends, and earnings for future consumption growth. Substantial evidence suggests that changes in share prices that are not associated with changes in dividends are transitory, yet we find find no evidence that consumption evolves differently after increases in share prices associated with dividend increases than after changes associated with discount rate movements. Our analysis focuses on a relatively limited set of household responses to higher stock prices and leaves many issues for further research. We have not considered the possibility that higher share prices lead to changes in labor supply, for example, to earlier retirement by those nearing retirement age. Rising share values that lead to increases in household net worth may also trigger changes in occupation, such as leaving paid employment and striking out as an entrepreneur.87 Furthermore, the influence of consumer confidence on spending decisions is poorly understood. Some of the most important issues that arise from changing stock ownership patterns, and which our tests have not addressed, concern the effect of ownership structure on the performance of asset markets. If the switch from direct individual ownership to indirect stock ownership through a small set of financial intermediaries alters the way in which investors respond to new information or to past stock returns, then it could have significant implications for many aspects of macroeconomic performance, including capital availability and market volatility.88 Many discussions of noise trader models in financial economics implicitly portray individual investors as poorly informed traders who may be affected by fads or other investment trends, and professional money managers as arbitrageurs who trade against this group. Exploring these issues requires information on how institutional investors differ from individual investors along a range of dimensions; much of the core research remains to be done. 87. Holtz-Eakin,Joulfaian,andRosen (1994) presentempiricalevidence suggesting that the decision to become self-employed is sensitive to changes in net worth, in their case, the receipt of a bequest. Samwick (1995) summarizesthe availableevidence on the effects of financialassets on retirementdecisions. 88. Friedman(1996). Comments and Discussion Andrei Shleifer: James Poterba and Andrew Samwick have written a fascinating paper in the growing literature on the (nonexistent) effects of the stock market on real economic activity. Although they produce many nice results, I will focus only on certain points. The paper begins by showing how high U.S. stock prices are in mid1995, relative to traditional measures of fundamentals, such as the book value of assets or dividends. Despite their striking evidence, the authors do not conclude that the stock market is overvalued. I might be less cautious. At the peak of almost every financial bubble, theories have been advanced to explain why assets prices were not, in fact, excessively high. In Japan in the mid-1980s, some people argued that the economy would continue to grow at 8 percent per year forever, thus justifying stock prices that were about to fall by half. In the United States, Irving Fisher argued that the stock prices had "reached a new and higher plateau" shortly before the crash of 1929. Before the demise of Drexel, Burnham, Lambert and the collapse of junk bonds, Michael C. Jensen argued that the corporate organizational form was obsolete, and ready to be replaced by leveraged buyouts financed by debt. In the Florida land bubble of the 1920s, William Jennings Bryan argued that much of American population was going to move to Florida. The list can be expanded to suggest that plausible theories are usually advanced to justify asset prices that seem excessive, based on historical averages, and that typically, these plausible theories prove to be wrong. In what is perhaps the most important contribution of the paper, Poterba and Samwick document persuasively that most American equi358 James M. Poterba and AndrewA. Samwick 359 ties are owned by wealthy old people. This section strongly suggests that understanding the effects of the stock market on real economic activity would require focusing on the habits of these people. Unfortunately, the data used in the paper do not specifically address the behavior of the wealthy elderly. Nor does the paper address the implications of this evidence for economic policies that have the potential to increase both equality and economic growth, such as selectively cutting social security and medicare benefits. The most interesting theoretical question that the paper poses is whether the stock market affects real economic activity. Answering this question is difficult since, to the extent that the stock market is correlated with the net present value of future cash flows to equities, it will forecast future economic activity without really affecting it. Indeed, earlier studies of investment have concluded that the stock market looks more like a passive predictor than a significant determinant of investment.' Poterba and Samwick ingeniously address the closely related question of whether the wealth increases resulting from stock market movements affect consumption. Their strongest test uses the earlier result that the wealthy own a very high fraction of equities, and examines the effect of stock price movements on the consumption of luxuries, such as upper luxury cars. By and large, their evidence shows that stock price movements do not affect the consumption of luxuries disproportionately. This, as well as most of the other evidence presented by Poterba and Samwick, is inconsistent with the importance of the wealth effect and consistent with the earlier findings on investment. In the short run, at least, the stock market is a sideshow for consumption as well as investment. The good news, of course, is that if stock prices fall from their 1995 heights, the economy need not follow. Robert J. Shiller: In much of the discussion of the stock market, dating back many years, there has been a sense that it is meaningful to present the observed relation between stock prices and macroeconomic aggregates such as consumption in very simple terms, that it is possible to discover very simple hypotheses about the relation of the market to the macroeconomy. James Poterba and Andrew Samwick present two such 1. See, for example, Blanchard,Rhee, and Summers(1993) and Morck, Schleifer, and Vishny (1990). 360 BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity, 2:1995 hypothesesand endeavorto find out whetherthere is any basic truthin either of them. According to the wealth effect hypothesis, there is a causal link from the stock market to consumption:when people see stock prices rise, they feel richer and so, consume more. For this reason, an increase in the stock marketwill cause future consumptionto increase. According to the leading indicatorhypothesis, the causality works in reverse: from informationthat consumptionwill increase in the future(therebyimprovingthe business situation)to the stock price increase. Poterbaand Samwick intendto distinguishbetweenthese two hypotheses; they are very imaginative and resourceful and provide a large amountof relevant information. One problem is that these two different hypotheses are not really different.Whenchoosing how muchto consume, people areat the same time choosing how much of theirresourcesto put into savings vehicles, such as the stock market, instead. They make the two decisions at the same time, and the outcome is both the level of consumptionand the level of the stock market. How can it be meaningful to specify the directionof causality? Poterba and Samwick never completely explain the two causality hypotheses, and it is not clear that the extremehypothesesreally make any sense. Could it possibly be meaningful to say that there is, ultimately, no wealth effect from the stock marketon consumption;that is, thatif people were given more stock, they would not consumemore? In particular,would this make sense over long periods of time? Could it possibly be meaningfulto say that, ultimately, the stock markethas no tendencyto function as a leading indicatorof consumption;that is, that if it were announcedthat people would be forced to consume less (for example, through taxes), there would be no effect on the stock market?Apparentlythe authors are not seriously proposing either of these extremehypotheses, but are tryingto determinewhich hypothesis is moreuseful for understandingthe observedcorrelationbetweenyearto-year movements in the stock market. One interpretationof how they are trying to distinguishbetween the two different directions of causality is that they are trying to learn something about lengths of lags. For example, the wealth effect hypothesis could be counted as wrong, as they note in their conclusion, if people take longer than one quarter(the forecastinghorizonin much of this paper)to adjusttheir consumptionto theircurrentwealth. If that James M. Poterba and AndrewA. Samwick 361 is what Poterbaand Samwick are exploring here, it is not really best describedas an issue of causality. Anotherinterpretationis that they are saying that it might be meaningful to suppose that there is a single direction of causality if two different groups of people are making the two decisions, to consume and to invest in stocks. By framingthe issues in this way, Poterbaand Samwick take account of some very importantfacts about the U.S. economy that many theorists wish they did not have to confront in building their models, and the more abstracttheorists almost always ignore: that much of the investing is done by institutionalinvestors, and that a large proportionof the stocks are held by a small, wealthy segment of the population. There might be evidence suggesting something akin to the leading indicatorhypothesis if the tendency towardinstitutionalownershipof stocks had proceeded to such an extent that all stocks were held in pension funds managedby professionals. The "mental compartment" theoryof H. M. ShefrinandRichardThalercould implythatindividuals put their institutionalizedinvestments into a certain mental category thatis off-limits for currentconsumption,even if they actuallyare able to get at them, and thereforeare psychologically committedto leaving theirconsumptiondecisions to the institutionalinvestors.' The ShefrinThaler theory derives from the notion that people find it difficult to limit their consumption;saving is a little like dieting. People find that it is easiest to control themselves if they follow simple rules of thumb (analogousto dieters swearing off sweets altogether). In addition, retiredpeople mightnever consumetheiraccumulatedwealth, but instead bequeathit to the next generation. Then, conceivably, there might not be a wealth effect; consumersmight not react to stock marketvalues. The lack of response in domestic consumptionto the domestic stock marketwould be even clearer if institutionalinvestors diversified all aroundthe world, so that a country's wealth did not correspondto the value of its stock market. If that were the situation today, then there would, indeed, seem to be some merit to the extreme leading indicator hypothesis. When deciding their allocationsbetween stocks and bonds in variouscountriesandotherinvestments,institutionalinvestorsmight react to informationabout future consumptionin the home countryof 1. See Shefrinand Thaler(1988). 362 BrookingsPapers on Economic Activity, 2:1995 the companies, wherethey tend to sell theirproducts,andtherebymake the stock market a leading indicator;but there would be virtually no reverse causality, from the stock marketin a countryto consumption in that country, operatingthroughthe consumersthemselves. As Poterba and Samwick so carefully document, there is only an element of truthto the premisethatcontrolof stock marketinvestments has been turnedover to people otherthanconsumers.Most U.S. stocks are still held by U.S. citizens, not foreigners. Moreover, much of the increasedconcentrationof holdings of stocks is in the form of mutual funds that people are able to cash in and thus, control. It is probable that people do not put mutual fund investments in a very different mental category from direct investmentsin stocks. Theremight also be evidence suggesting some version of the leading indicatorhypothesis if the wealthy subset of the populationthat holds stocks is very differentfrom the generalpopulationwhose consumption dominatesin the consumptionfigures. Thenthe profitsof the companies thatrepresentthe stock marketwould be tied to the futureconsumption of the population at large, and thereforethe marketought to take account of informationabout this. But the future consumptionthat responds to the marketthroughthe wealth effect would be the consumption of wealthy people. Poterbaand Samwick carefully show that the concentrationof stock holdings does, indeed, remain in a few wealthy hands:they conclude that about three-quartersof all stocks are currently held by only 5 percent of the population. Moreover, they provide evidence on the consumptionof the wealthyfromdataon expenditureson luxurygoods. The fact that their regressions fail to find any predictive power of the U.S. stock marketon domestic luxury car sales does seem to suggest that the wealth effect is not a strong one; if there was a rapid stock marketwealth effect anywhere, it would be on luxurycar sales. (However, the coefficient of the stock marketis not significantlynegative, and it is unclearhow large a coefficient should be expected from these rathervaguely defined hypotheses.) Poterba and Samwick carry the evidence for the leading indicator hypothesisfurtherby using Skinner'smethodof derivinga consumption aggregatefor groups of households that hold stocks. But the Skinner proxy seems more than a little questionable.He createshis proxy from the ConsumerExpenditureSurvey, by fitting a cross-sectionalregres- James M. Poterba and AndrewA. Samwick 363 sion of total consumptionon food consumption,house value, andrental payments. The fitted value of this regression can then be generated using the panel data from the PSID. But it does not seem appropriate to use quarterlychanges in such a variable as a proxy for quarterly change in consumption. Short-runchanges in house values and rents are not, themselves, changes in the consumptionof housing services, since the housing stock is fixed in the short run. Skinner argues that this same predictiveequationfits equallywell using cross-sectionaldata from both the 1972-73 and the 1983 ConsumerExpenditureSurveys; but this is an intervalof a decade, not a quarter.In any event there is, in effect, only one out-of-sample observation-1983-to test the stability throughtime of the Skinnerrelation.2 PoterbaandSamwickalso reportsome interestingconsumptionfunction estimates with which they attemptto uncover an interactioneffect between the share of households investing in stocks andthe stock market price. Unfortunately, as they themselves point out, the multicollinearity in these regressions prevents them from drawing any strong conclusions. Overall, Poterbaand Samwick conclude that their evidence is more in accord with the leading indicatorthan the wealth effect hypothesis. While thereis nothingdefinitiveaboutthis statement,they areprobably on the right track;their most convincing evidence is their regressions of luxury good consumption, such as luxury cars, on stock market returns. Interpretingthis denial of the wealth effect hypothesis as an indication that people may respond very sluggishly to changes in the stock market,Poterbaand Samwickmay be rightto say thattheirresults suggest that the rapideffect of the stock marketon consumptionallegedly representedin the consumptionfunctionsof some macroeconomic models might, in fact, be spurious. I suppose that it is plausible that wealthy people do not adjust their consumptionbehavior rapidly to change in the stock market;they may, for example, tend to thinkof the stock marketas mean-revertingand so, not react to it much until a lot of time has gone by. Still, Poterba and Samwick's models of the consumptionfunction are only suggestive, and many other confounding factors could be broughtto bear, possibly changingtheir conclusions. Those who work 2. Skinner(1987). 364 BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity, 2:1995 in the macroeconometricmodel traditionwould include several other variablesbesides the stock marketin theirregressions. For example, in Ray Fair's model the consumptionequations also include disposable income, the mortgage interest rate, the value of the stock of housing (as partof a broaderwealth measure), the stock of consumerdurables (in durables consumption), and age (baby boom) variables, as well as lagged consumption. He finds all of these to be statistically significant in his estimation of U.S. consumptionequations for the period 1954-93, and achieves an R2 of well over 0.99 in explaining the level of consumption.3Fromthis perspective,Poterbaand Samwick'sresults might partly be due to the omission of certain variables in the consumptionmodel, or the failureto take accountof simultaneousequation effects. Thus it would be risky to try to infer much from such simple consumptionrelations. Muchrecentliteratureon consumptionhas suggestedtheoreticalreasons for using some very simple models. The empirical literatureon stock prices and consumption has been heavily influenced by Euler equationmethods, which are based on first-orderconditions for a hypothesized maximizationproblem. These methods do suggest simpler relationsthanthe complicatedconsumptionfunctionsused by the macroeconomicmodel builders. For example, it is not necessaryto include the interestrate in the model of consumptionand stock prices because this variabledoes not appearin the usualEulerequationfor stockprices. But the hypotheses underconsiderationhere do not seem to fit into the appropriatemaximization framework. Poterba and Samwick are not estimating Euler equations, since the stock price change that they include in their regressions is lagged, ratherthan contemporaneous. General Discussion Several participantsdiscussed the theory and evidence behind the idea that changes in stock price cause changes in consumption.Benjamin Friedmannoted that estimates of the traditionalModiglianiwealth effect suggest that for every dollar of change in aggregate wealth, aggregate consumption changes by about 5 cents within a year. To 3. See Fair (1994). James M. Poterba and AndrewA. Samwick 365 gauge how reasonablethat estimate looks when applied to changes in stock prices, he suggested looking at stock ownershipin termsof three distinctgroups. The top 0.5 to 1 percentof stockholdershold very large amountsof stocks and are unlikely to adjusttheir consumptionappreciably over shorttime horizons. The lower 80 percentof the population owns a negligible amountof stocks andso would be unaffectedby stock price changes in the short to medium term. This leaves the remaining 19 percent, who own noticeable amountsof stock, to account for virtually all the change in aggregateconsumptionpredictedby the aggregate wealth effect. Friedmanregardedsuch a concentratedchange in consumptionas implausible. Gregory Mankiw, however, argued that the marginalpropensityto consume of those in the top 20 percent of the populationshould be expected to be high because these people are in older households and so, in a life-cycle framework,would be predicted to consume a large proportionof incrementalwealth. John Shoven pointed out another possible response to stock price changes related to the concentrationof ownershipamong older, highincome, households. These individuals might spend their windfall by bringingforwardtheir retirement,a form of consumptionthat lies outside the consumptionmeasuresin the paper. Shoven suggested looking for real effects of changes in stock prices by examiningthe correlation between stock prices and labor force participationfor this group of consumers. He added that anothereffect of the recent runupin stock prices might be found in the reduced saving of the defined benefits sector of the pension industry. Andrew Samwick agreed with the importance of Shoven's point about retirementbehavior and suggested extending it to examine the effect of the stock marketon new business startupsand entrepreneurialactivity more generally. Robert Hall noted that the life-cycle model of consumptioncould accommodatethe fact that consumptiondid not react to the 1987 stock marketcrash. If the utility function has an elasticity of intertemporal substitutionof zero, people simply consume out of currentincome. Interpretinga stock marketcrashas an increasein the discountratethat is appliedto futureearnings, two effects on consumptionexactly offset each other, so that thereis no consumptionresponse. With the discount rate rising and the stock marketfalling, the productof the two, which can be thoughtof as the underlyingflow of value fromstock ownership, remainsthe same. Thus Hall suggested that the consumptionresponse 366 BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity, 2:1995 to the 1987 stock market crash can be seen as a naturalexperiment providingevidence that, in the life-cycle framework,the elasticity of intertemporalsubstitutionshould be near zero ratherthan one. Membersof the panel suggested alternativeapproachesto looking at the consumptionresponseto stock price changesanddiscussedpossible extensions of the paper. Hall questionedthe paper's focus on the predictive effect of lagged stock price changes on consumptionwhen the life-cycle model suggests that the entire wealth effect is contemporaneous. ChristopherSims agreed, and addedthat the econometricwork in the paper fell in some unclear middle groundbetween testing theories, such as the life-cycle model, and attemptingto find optimal forecasting relations. He suggested testing the simple stochastic life-cycle model, with its contemporaneouseffects of wealth on consumption,to see just how it performs in explaining the data. Because this model relates consumptionto total wealth, it would be necessary to examine whetherother componentsof total wealth are systematicallyrelatedto stock wealth, a possibility that might improve the performanceof the model. As for forecasting, Sims noted that serious forecasters used many variables, some of which might be correlatedwith stock prices, and that the forecasting value of stock prices alone was of limited interest. Allen Berger underlinedthe need for making the measureof wealthmore comprehensiveby noting thatthe large swings in the debtto-equityratios of companiesmay occur at the same time as their stock price is changing. He advocatedcheckingwhetherthe estimationresults are robust to including the value of debt along with equities. Sims observedthat equity costs were an incompletemeasureof a company's cost of capital. He noted that other natural measures of the cost of capital might move in the same way or in an off-setting direction to stock prices. MargaretBlair observedthatthe sharesof outputgoing to labor and capital have not been constantover time, and that some part of the runup in stock prices in recent years can be attributedto an increase in the capital share. This shift away from labor should be expected to hold down the consumptionof the 80 percentof the population that owns little or no stock, creating a negative correlationbetween consumptionand stock prices on this account. Anil Kashyap suggested using consumptionand stock marketdata fromJapanto supplementthe paper'sanalysis based on U. S. data. The spectacularrise and subsequentcollapse of the Japanesemarketshould James M. Poterba and AndrewA. Samwick 367 provide ample variation from which to identify any consumptionresponse to stock price changes. He conjecturedthatevidence fromJapan would support the view that the stock market is a sideshow and has little effect on people's consumptiondecisions. 368 BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity, 2:1995 References Ando, Albert, and FrancoModigliani. 1963. "The 'Life Cycle' Hypothesisof Saving: Aggregate Implications and Tests." American Economic Review 53(1): 55-84. Antoniewicz, Rochelle L. 1995. "A Comparisonof the HouseholdSectorfrom the Flow of Funds Accounts and the Survey of Consumer Finances." Unpublished paper. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (February). Attanasio,Orazio P. 1994. "Personal Saving in the United States." In International Comparisons of Household Saving, edited by James M. Poterba. Chicago:Universityof Chicago Press. Avery, RobertB., and GregoryE. Elliehausen. 1986. "FinancialCharacteristics of High-IncomeFamilies." Federal ReserveBulletin 72(3): 164-77. . 1988. 1983 Survey of Consumer Finances: Technical Manual and Codebook.Washington:Boardof Governorsof the FederalReserveSystem. Avery, Robert B., Gregory E. Elliehausen, and Glenn B. Canner. 1984. "Survey of Consumer Finances, 1983." Federal Reserve Bulletin 70(9): 679-92. Avery, Robert B., GregoryE. Elliehausen, and ArthurB. Kennickell. 1988. "MeasuringWealthwith Survey Data:An Evaluationof the 1983 Surveyof Consumer Finances." Review of Income and Wealth 34(4): 339-69. Bagwell, Laurie Simon, and John B. Shoven. 1989. "Cash Distributionsto Shareholders." Journal of Economic Perspectives 3(3): 129-40. Barro, Robert. 1990. "The Stock Marketand Investment."Review of Financial Studies 3(1): 115-31. Bernheim, B. Douglas, and John B. Shoven. 1988. "Pension Funding and Saving." In Pensions in the U.S. Economy, edited by Zvi Bodie, John B. Shoven, and David A. Wise. Chicago:Universityof Chicago Press. Birinyi, Laszlo, Jr., and Keith Miller. 1987. "The WealthEffect." Salomon BrothersEquity MarketAnalysis. New York: Salomon Brothers(November). Blanchard,Olivier, ChangyongRhee, andLawrenceH. Summers.1993. "The Stock Market, Profit, and Investment." Quarterly Journal of Economics 108(1): 115-36. Blinder, Alan S., and Angus Deaton. 1985. "The Time Series Consumption FunctionRevisited." BPEA, 2:1985, 465-51 1. Blume, MarshallE., JeanCrockett,and IrwinFriend. 1974. "Stockownership in the United States: Characteristicsand Trends." Surveyof CurrentBusiness 54(11): 16-40. Blume, MarshallE., and Stephen P. Zeldes. 1993. "The Structureof Stock- James M. Poterba and AndrewA. Samwick 369 ownership in the U.S." Unpublished paper. University of Pennsylvania, Wharton School of Business (March). Bosworth, Barry, Gary Burtless, and John Sabelhaus. 1991. "The Decline in Saving: Evidence from Household Surveys." BPEA, 1:1991, 183-241. Campbell, John Y., and Robert J. Shiller. 1988a. "The Dividend-Price Ratio and Expectations of Future Dividends and Discount Factors." Review of Financial Studies 1(3): 195-228. . 1988b. "Stock Prices, Earnings, and Expected Dividends." Journal of Finance 43(3): 661-76. Cochrane, John H. 1994. "Permanent and Transitory Components of GNP and Stock Prices." Quarterly Journal of Economics 109(1): 241-65. Curtin, Richard T., F. Thomas Juster, and James N. Morgan. 1989. "Survey Estimates of Wealth: An Assessment of Quality." In The Measurement of Saving, Investment, and Wealth, edited by Richard E. Lipsey and Helen Stone Tice. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Dornbusch, Rudiger, and Stanley Fischer. 1994. Macroeconomics, 6th ed. New York: McGraw-Hill. Epple, Dennis, and Katherine Schipper. 1981. "Municipal Pension Funding: A Theory and Some Evidence." Public Choice 37(1): 141-78. Fair, Ray C. 1994. Testing Macroeconometric Models. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press. Fama, Eugene F. 1981. "Stock Returns, Real Activity, Inflation, and Money." American Economic Review 71(4): 545-65. Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French. 1988. "Dividend Yields and Expected Stock Returns." Journal of Financial Economics 22(1): 3-25. Feldstein, Martin, Louis Dicks-Mireaux, and James Poterba. 1983. "The Effective Tax Rate and the Pretax Rate of Return." Journal of Public Economics 21(2): 129-58. Feldstein, Martin, and Lawrence Summers. 1977. "Is the Rate of Profit Falling?" BPEA, 1 :1977, 211-27. Ferris, Deebe, editor. 1995. Ward's 1995 Automotive Yearbook. Southfield, Mich.: Ward's Communications. Fischer, Stanley, and Robert C. Merton. 1984. "Macroeconomics and Finance: The Role of the Stock Market." Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 21: 57-108. French, Kenneth R., and James M. Poterba. 1991. "Were Japanese Stock Prices Too High?" Journal of Financial Economics 29(2): 337-63. Friedman, Benjamin M. 1996. "Economic Implications of Changing Share Ownership." Journal of Portfolio Management (forthcoming). Gentry, William. 1994. "Annuity Markets and Retirement Saving." In Proceedings of the National Tax Association-Tax Institute of America. Columbus, Ohio: National Tax Association. 370 BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity, 2:1995 Haliassos, Michael, and Carol C. Bertaut. 1995. "Why Do So Few Hold Stocks?" Economic Jouirnal 105(432): 1110-29. Hall, BronwynH. 1993. "IndustrialResearchDuringthe 1980s: Did the Rate of Return Fall?" BPEA, Microeconomics, 2:1993, 289-330. Hall, RobertE. 1978. "Stochastic Implicationsof the Life Cycle-Permanent Income Hypothesis: Theory and Evidence." Journal of Political Economy 86(6): 971-87. Heeringa,Steven G., JudithH. Connor,andR. Louise Woodburn.1994. "The 1989 Surveys of ConsumerFinances Sample Design and WeightingDocumentation."Unpublishedpaper.Universityof Michigan,Institutefor Social Research(April). Hines, James R., Jr. 1991. "Dividends and Profits:Some Unsubtle Foreign Influences." WorkingPaper 3730. Cambridge,Mass.: National Bureauof EconomicResearch(June). Holtz-Eakin,Douglas, David Joulfaian, and HarveyS. Rosen. 1994. "EntrepreneurialDecisions and LiquidityConstraints."RANDJournalof Economics 25(2): 334-47. Ibbotson Associates. 1994. Stocks, Bonds, Bills, and Inflation: 1994 Yearbook. Chicago:IbbotsonAssociates. Kennickell, Arthur B. 1995. Working Codebook for 1992 SCF. Washington: Boardof Governorsof the FederalReserve System. Kennickell,ArthurB., and MarthaStarr-McCluer.1994. "Changesin Family Finances from 1989 to 1992: Evidence from the Survey of ConsumerFinances. " Federal Reserve Bulletin 80(10): 861-82. King, MervynA., and JonathanI. Leape. 1984. "Wealth and PortfolioComposition:Theory and Evidence." WorkingPaper 1468. Cambridge,Mass.: NationalBureauof Economic Research(September). Levy, Frank, and Richard J. Murnane. 1992. "U.S. Earnings Levels and EarningsInequality:A Review of Recent Trends and Proposed Explanations." Journal of Economic Literature 30(3): 1333-81. Mankiw, N. Gregory, and Stephen P. Zeldes. 1991. "The Consumptionof Stockholders and Nonstockholders." Journal of Financial Economics 29(1): 97-112. Morck, Randall, Andrei Shleifer, and RobertW. Vishny. 1990. "The Stock Marketand Investment:Is the Marketa Sideshow?" BPEA, 2:1990, 157202. Nordhaus,William D. 1974. "The Falling Shareof Profits." BPEA, 1:1974, 169-208. Poterba,James M. 1991. "Dividends, CapitalGains, and the CorporateVeil: Evidencefrom Britain, Canada,and the United States." In National Saving and Economic Performance, edited by B. Douglas Bernheimand John B. Shoven. Chicago:Universityof Chicago Press. James M. Poterba and AndrewA. Samwick 371 . 1995a. "CorporateStock Ownershipin the United States." In The Extent of Shareownership Among U.S. Households. New York: New York Stock Exchange(forthcoming). . 1995b. "The Historyof Annuitiesin the UnitedStates." Unpublished paper.MassachusettsInstituteof Technology (October). Poterba,James M., Steven F. Venti, and David A. Wise. 1994. "Targeted RetirementSaving and the Net Worth of Elderly Americans." American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings 84(2): 180-85. . 1995. "Lump-SumDistributionsfrom RetirementSaving Plans: Receipt and Utilization." Working Paper 5298. Cambridge,Mass.: National Bureauof Economic Research(October). Projector, Dorothy S., and GertrudeS. Weiss. 1966. Survey of Financial Characteristics of Consumers. Washington: Board of Governors of the Fed- eral Reserve System. Romer, Christina D. 1990. "The Great Crash and the Onset of the Great Depression." Quarterly Journal of Economics 105(3): 597-624. Samwick, AndrewA. 1995. "The JointEffect of Social Securityand Pensions on the Timing of Retirement:Some New Evidence." Unpublishedpaper. DartmouthCollege (November). Shefrin, HershM., and RichardH. Thaler. 1988. "The BehavioralLife-Cycle Hypothesis." EconomicInquiry26(4): 609-43. Shleifer, Andrei, and LawrenceH. Summers. 1990. "The Noise TraderApproach to Finance." Journal of Economic Perspectives 4(2): 19-33. Shulman,David S., Marc S. Usem, and JeffreyF. Brown. 1995. "The Ghost of Keynes." Salomon Brothers Equity Strategy. New York: Salomon Broth- ers. Skinner,Jonathan.1987. "A SuperiorMeasureof Consumptionfromthe Panel Study of Income Dynamics." EconomicsLetters23(2): 213-16. Stock, James H., and MarkW. Watson. 1990. "Business Cycle Propertiesof Selected U.S. Economic Time Series, 1959-1988." WorkingPaper3376. Cambridge,Mass.: NationalBureauof EconomicResearch(June). Summers, Lawrence H. 1981. "Taxation and CorporateInvestment:A qTheoryApproach."BPEA, 1:1981, 67-127. Thaler,RichardH. 1994. "Psychology and Savings Policies." AmericanEconomic Review, Papers and Proceedings 84(2): 186-92. Temin, Peter. 1976. Did Monetary Forces Cause the Great Depression? New York:Norton. U .S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. 1994. Consumer Expenditures in 1993. Wash- ington:Departmentof Labor. U.S. PresidentialTask Force on Market Mechanisms. 1988. Report of the Presidential Task Force on Market Mechanisms. Washington: Government PrintingOffice. 372 BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity, 2:1995 Weicher, John C. 1995. "Changes in the Distribution of Wealth: Increasing Inequality?" Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review 77(1): 5-23. Wigmore, Barrie A. 1985. The Crash and Its Aftermath: A Histoiy of Securities Markets in the United States, 1929-1993. Westport, Conn.: Greenwood Press. Wolff, Edward N. 1994. "Trends in Household Wealth in the United States, 1962-83 and 1983-89." Review of Income and Wealth 40(2): 143-74. . 1995. Top Heavy: A Study of the Increasing Inequality of Wealth in America. New York: Twentieth Century Fund Press. Zeldes, Stephen P. 1989. "Consumption and Liquidity Constraints: An Empirical Investigation." Journal of Political Economy 97(2): 305-46.
© Copyright 2024