Oil Economics - NAI Carolantic

Volume 15 Issue 1
This is an excerpt from the Spring 2015 issue of The Linneman Letter.
Oil Economics
By Dr. Peter Linneman, PhD
Chief Economist, NAI Global
Principal, Linneman Associates
The big questions on everyone’s mind are, “What do low oil prices
mean?” and “Will they remain low?” The volatility of crude prices has
increased since 1994. From 1964-1993, the standard deviation of
real crude prices was $24 per barrel. In contrast, the standard deviation of prices for the most recent 20 years was $31 per barrel. In the
first quarter of 2008, immediately before the Great Recession, real oil
prices increased 41%, from $104 per barrel to $146 per barrel, a 50year high. Since 2008, real oil prices have been volatile, with crude
plummeting to $43 per barrel in the first quarter of 2009 before rising
to $116 by the second quarter of 2011, and subsequently declining
to current pricing.
$140
Historical Crude Oil Price Per Barrel
(Real 2014 $)
$120
$100
$80
$60
$40
$20
$0
1969 1973 1977 1981 1985 1989 1993 1997 2001 2005 2009 2013
The real price of West Texas Intermediate crude oil in February 2015
averaged about $51 per barrel, which is 51% below its $105 peak in
June 2014, but 2% above the 50-year average of $50 per barrel. At
$43 per barrel in mid-March 2015, real crude prices are 2.7 times
their 50-year low of $16 per barrel, reached in 1998. This compares
to a real price of $103 per barrel in 1981; real prices today are 58%
below this mark.
Table of Contents
Over the past 50 years, real oil prices have generally been $20-50 (in
2014 dollars), while the ratio of oil to natural gas prices has a norm of
6.8x. As fracking over the last 7 years massively increased natural
gas production, natural gas prices fell dramatically. At natural gas
prices of $3-5 per MMBtu (million British thermal units), the price of
oil should be $20-45 today. Yet just 6 months ago, to our utter
confusion, oil prices were well in excess of $100. Thus while we do
not claim to understand the timing of the collapse of oil prices, nor its
“emperor has no clothes” speed, we understand today’s oil price far
better than we did when it was above $100.
Comparing Renewable Energy Resources
Several years ago we conducted a very simple exercise to calculate
oil prices based on economic growth and elasticities of supply and
demand. Repeating this analysis indicates that since 2004, global
real GDP has risen by about 31%. If the elasticity of demand with
respect to real GDP is (a very high) 4, while the price elasticity of oil
The Sun Is Shining And Canaries Are Still Chirping
Canary Watch Box
Tax Inversion Is Not A Crime – In Fact, It Is Good
Oil Economics
The Linneman Letter Look-back: Oil Prices
Central Bank Interventions Must End
Linneman Perspectives
The Impact Of Immigration On Citizen Welfare
Ten Facts You Should Know About U.S. Immigration
The Survey Of Household Economics And Decision Making
Real Estate Capital Markets
The Linneman Letter Look-back: China: From Net Importer to Exporter
Housing Market Update
Market Close-up: Minneapolis Office
Market Close-up: Phoenix Industrial
Market Close-up: Chicago Multifamily
Market Close-up: Atlanta Hotel
Office Market Outlook
Industrial Market Outlook
Multifamily Market Outlook
Retail Market Outlook
Hotel Market Outlook
Seniors Housing And Care Market Outlook
Vacancy/Occupancy And Absorption Projections
®
For more information about a subscription to
The Linneman Letter, contact Doug Linneman
at [email protected].
Volume 15 Issue 1
demand is zero and there is no increased supply due to higher oil
prices, the price today should be 2.24 times the $36 price in 2004,
or about $80. But if the elasticity with respect to real GDP is a more
realistic 2, the price today should be about $49. Add to this a 2%
increase in global supply (all due to increased U.S. output),
some degree of demand elasticity with respect to price, and the
collapse of the OPEC cartel, making oil prices in the range of $30-60
feel “about right”. Perhaps we will finally be proven right about oil!
Better late than never.
®
10
5
0
1987
1991
1995
1999
2003
2007
Average 1983-2009
Historical Energy Prices
140
$ per Barrel
2011
Ratio
(Real 2014 $)
16
120
14
100
12
10
80
8
60
6
40
4
20
2
0
1983
0
1987
1991
1995
1999
2003
Crude Oil
2007
$ Per Thousand Cubic Feet
1983
2011
Natural Gas
U.S. Oil Imports
400
350
300
250
200
150
100
1990
1993
1996
1999
2002
2005
Barrels
2008
2011
U.S. Net Import of Gas and Oil
12
2014
Average LTM
4.0
3.5
10
3.0
8
2.5
6
2.0
4
1.5
1.0
2
0.5
0
1973
0.0
1978
1983
1988
Crude Oil
1993
1998
2003
Natural Gas
2008
2013
Trillion Cubic Feet (Gas)
Fracking and deep sea production have not only pushed down
prices by increasing oil supplies, but it has also made it far more
difficult for OPEC to maintain an effective cartel. While Saudi Arabia
could reduce its production to a point that would offset U.S. fracking
and deep sea production, this would impose a staggering cost on its
domestic economy. The largest beneficiaries of any Saudi production
curtailment would be Iran and Russia, but the Saudis are unwilling to
subsidize their Iranian enemy (or their Russian ally), with whom they
are waging proxy wars in Syria, Iraq and Libya. One does not subsi-
20
15
Millions of Barrels
It is important to appreciate the scale of U.S. oil production
expansion and the scale of output reduction required by Saudi Arabia
in order to maintain oil prices. In 2010, the U.S. produced roughly 2
billion barrels of oil annually, representing 7.4% of global output. And
at that time, many said we had reached “peak oil”, both in the U.S.
and globally. We have always written that “peak oil” is a tragically
flawed concept, as it ignores the power to innovate in terms of both
supply and demand. In 2014, thanks to fracking and deep sea
production, the U.S. produced 3 billion barrels, achieving a 10.8%
market share. This 50% increase in output in just 4 years is due to
innovation. In fact, U.S. production is up by 1 billion barrels while the
output of the rest of the world (which refuses to embrace fracking)
is down by 500 million barrels.
(Real 2014 $)
25
Million Barrels Per Day (Oil)
The U.S. has net imports of 5.2 million barrels of oil daily. At a price
decline of $60 per barrel, this amounts to a net gain of $114 billion
for U.S. consumer wallets, or about 0.7% of GDP. This is an
enormous gain to the U.S. economy, even though oil producers and
related services have both suffered severe capital losses. But these
capital losses are more than offset by the gains to U.S. consumers of
oil products. This will prove particularly beneficial to those in the
lowest 20th percentile of the income distribution, who spend roughly
3% of their income on gasoline. These consumers have de facto
received an enormous subsidy thanks to U.S. fracking, which has
disrupted the pricing dynamics of OPEC.
Ratio of Crude Oil to Natural Gas Prices vs. Historical Average
30
Volume 15 Issue 1
Of course, not everyone wins, as oil producing areas will notably
suffer. For example, at oil prices below about $65 per barrel, the
Bakken region is generally not a viable extraction area. Houston and
Dallas will also see notable slowing in their oil focused economies.
Large capital losses have also been suffered by the owners of oil
extraction and servicing companies, while their lenders will likely
incur loan losses.
In the near term, the biggest problem for U.S. oil producers is the
lack of growth capital. Much as real estate owners lever up in times
of peak property values, oil producers have taken on staggering
amounts of debt over the past two years. At today’s oil prices, not
only will additional debt flows be shut down, but many producers will
struggle to service their debt burdens.
Over the next year or two, many U.S. oil producers will struggle
under the weight of huge debt burdens incurred during the heady
days of $100 oil. This debt burden will challenge the growth capacity
of many oil and natural gas producers, even if on a project basis,
IRRs support further drilling. Given their debt burdens, these
®
27.2 Total
27.7 Total
25
20
15
10
25.2
ROW
24.7
ROW
2 USA
3 USA
5
0
2014
2010
USA
Rest of World
Crude Oil Production
12
Million Barrels Per Day
In a classic example of Adam Smith’s Invisible Hand theory, U.S. oil
consumers have gained from the efforts of fracking innovators and
entrepreneurs who were simply seeking profits. It did not result from
the endless “energy” and “self sufficiency” policies created by the
U.S. Energy Department (under 40 years of different administrations).
The answer to economic progress is self-interest driven innovation,
not edicts by mandarins. This is equally true for job growth. In short,
fewer political photo opportunities and more private enterprises are
the surest routes to economic progress for the poor, the rich and
everyone in between.
(Billion Barrels Annually)
10
8
6
4
2
0
1950
1958
U.S.
40
1966
1974
Russia
1982
Iran
1990
1998
Qatar
2006
2014
Saudi Arabia
U.S. Share of Gas and Oil Production
35
30
Percent
In order to offset increased U.S. production, Saudi Arabia would
need to reduce their oil production by about 40%, or a billion barrels
a year, costing them $50-60 billion, or nearly 10% of Saudi Arabia’s
GDP. Thus, absent U.S. innovation (which continues), global
production would have fallen, meaning oil prices would be rising
rather than falling. And in spite of producing massively more oil than
in 2010, U.S. proven oil reserves far exceed their 2010 levels. Yet
again, so much for claims of “peak oil”. Believe in “markets”, not
“peaks”. This output increase has not only enriched the U.S., but it
has also provided the marginal capacity that broke OPEC.
Oil Production Summary
30
25
20
15
10
5
0
1980
1984
1988
1992
1996
Crude Oil
2000
2004
2008
2012
Natural Gas
Production Cost Curve Transformed
Breakeven oil price, $/bbl
dize countries with whom you are at war! Thus, the breaking of the
OPEC cartel was inevitable, as large marginal supplies in the U.S.
make Saudi curtailment too painful both economically and politically.
120
110
100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
Shale has
flattened the
oil supply
curve
0
10,000
20,000
30,000
Cumulative peak production, kbd
40,000
50,000
Volume 15 Issue 1
producers will lack the free cash flow and borrowing capacity to
undertake profitable new drilling. This means that drilling will fall farther, even for natural gas, and faster than the economics of drilling
profitability suggest. This is especially true of fracking for natural gas,
for which drilling economics remain largely unchanged. As happens
with real estate development, periods of high prices fuel inordinate
production, which sows the seeds for future excess supply. During
that time, little new exploration occurs, which in turn drives the next
cyclical price increase. Eventually the debt of over-levered companies
will be restructured, or defaulting or at-risk borrowers will be
absorbed into firms with strong balance sheets. As that occurs,
drilling will cautiously resume in the face of attractive project level
IRRs. These dynamics, which will play out in the oil and gas sector
over the next few years, are all too familiar to real estate developers.
Oil Breakeven Price ($/Bbl)
Kuwait
54
Qatar
UAE
60
77
Iraq
101
Saudi Arabia
106
Oman
107
Venezuela
118
Nigeria
123
Bahrain
125
Algeria
131
Iran
131
WTI Oil Breakeven Price ($/Bbl)
24.2
25.6
32.4
Marcellus Shale - SW Liquids Rich
Marcellus Shale - Super Rich
Utica - Wet Gas
Mississippian Horizontal - East
Utica - Liquids Rich
Eagle Ford - Liquids Rich
Niobrara - Wattenberg
Wolfcamp - N. Midland
Bone Spring (1st / 2nd) - NM
Eagle Ford - Oil Window
Yeso
Cana Woodford Shale - Oi
Wolfcamp - S. Midland
Cana Woodford Shale
Mississippian Horizontal - West
Wolfberry
Bakken Shale
Three Forks
Bone Spring (3rd) - W TX
Wolfcamp - N. Delaware
Uinta - Green River
Uinta - Wasatch (H)
Granite Wash - Liquids Rich Horiz.
Uinta - Wasatch (V)
Barnett Shale - Southern
Cotton Valley Horizontal
42.2
44.0
46.1
46.1
53.9
55.0
55.3
58.5
59.9
61.6
61.6
64.1
64.6
64.7
66.9
68.5
68.5
68.8
72.2
73.1
75.0
84.5
90.0
NYMEX Natural Gas Breakeven Price ($/MMBtu)
Marcellus Shale - Super Rich
Utica - Liquids Rich
Eagle Ford - Liquids Rich
Mississippian Horizontal - West
Marcellus Shale - SW Liquids
Utica - Wet Gas
Granite Wash - Liquids Rich
Cana Woodford Shale
Cotton Valley Horizontal
Marcellus Shale - NE
Marcellus Shale - SW
Fayetteville Shale
Barnett Shale - Core
Horn River Basin
Barnett Shale
Barnett Shale - Southern
Pinedale
Piceance Basin Valley
Haynesville Shale - Core LA / TX
Eagle Ford Shale - Dry Gas
Woodford Shale - Arkoma
Haynesville/Bossier Shale - NE
®
0.25
0.25
0.25
0.29
0.62
1.35
2.47
2.50
2.94
3.02
3.26
3.27
3.34
3.65
3.66
3.70
3.75
3.81
4.13
4.25
5.05
5.37