Joint Ownership of Undertakings without Joint Control Minority shareholdings at a crossroad in competition law Luís Silva Morais1 Version of April 2015 Do not quote at this stage without authorization of the author To be included in LIBER AMICORUM – IAN FORRESTER (publication to occur in the course of 2015 1 PhD in Law – Lisbon Law University (Faculdade de Direito de Lisboa – FDL), Professor of FDL, Jean Monnet Chair of EU economic regulation, Chairman of CIRSF (Research Centre of Regulation and Supervision of the Financial Sector, in scientific cooperation with the Bank of Portugal and the Portuguese Authority of Supervision of Insurance and Pension Funds. Attorney-at-law – Founding Partners of Luis Silva Morais/Sérgio Gonçalves do Cabo, Law Firms, rl (based in Lisbon, Portugal, with representatives in Brazil, Angola and China/Macau) Table of Contents 1 – Introduction and Comprehensive Remarks 1.1. – General Overview 1.2. – Key Competition Law Issues in this Domain and the Evolving Case Law – The Special Importance of the Financial Sector in this Field 2. – Analytical Criteria for Assessment of Effects on Competition Arising from Ownership of Undertakings Short of Individual or Joint Control 2.1. – Identifying Relevant Situations Which Inherently Lead to Potential Restrictions of Competition 2.2. – Anticompetitive Effects Arising from Minority Shareholdings – How to Build a Reliable Analytical Grid in this Domain vis a vis the Option of Expanding the Scope of the MCR Envisaged in the Commission 2014 Proposals 2.3. – The Desirability of Flexible Solutions for Dealing with Minority Shareholdings 3. – Concluding Remarks 2 List of Abbreviations A – Author As - Authors CJEU – Court of Justice of the European Union EC – European Community EEC – European Economic Community Esp - Especially EU – European Union MCR – Merger Control Regulation TFEU – Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union 3 Joint Ownership of Undertakings without Joint Control Minority shareholdings at a crossroad in competition law2 Luís Silva Morais 1 – Introduction and Comprehensive Remarks 1.1. – General Overview 1.1.1. - In the context of competition law analysis we may identify some critical issues associated with the potential relevance of anticompetitive coordination arising from shareholdings in certain undertakings which allow the exercise of influence over the behavior of those entities. To some extent, such issues and their effects on competition bear resemblance to the competition law framework of joint ventures (and a host of situations of cooperation between undertakings comparable thereto).3 More precisely, these cases correspond to situations of acquisition or holding by an undertaking of shareholdings in a third undertaking which, without exceeding the threshold required for the acquisition of control, whether jointly or individually, may, nevertheless, influence the competitive relationships between the concerned undertakings. This type of minority shareholdings, due to the absence of any kind of control - as this concept has been perceived in EU competition law -4 does not lead to the emergence of concentration operations, nor to the creation of joint ventures, as such. Anyhow, its potential impact on the relationship between the involved undertakings may, under certain circumstances, raise issues of distortion of 2 This Paper was finalized on March 31, 2015. No developments subsequent to that date, either concerning the development of the Commission 2014 proposals on the reform of the MCR or further evolving case law in this domain have been considered. 3 On this parallel and its significance see in general Luís Silva Morais, Joint Ventures and EU Competition Law, Hart Publishing, 2013, point 1.5., Chapter 2, pp 182 ff and especially, point 6, Chapter 3, pp 481 ff. 4 See on the concept of control over undertakings under EU competition law Luís Silva Morais, Joint Ventures and EU Competition Law, cit. This concept has already been extensively analyzed and dealt with and, as such, it will not be further addressed here. See in particular for that analysis and relevant references points 3.1., 4.2., and 5 of Chapter 1 of Joint Ventures and EU Competition Law, cit. 4 competition, to some extent comparable, as aforementioned, to those associated with certain joint ventures. 1.1.2. - Furthermore, given this potential for competition law problems, the European Commission, through its DG Competition, has launched a public consultation to deal with an hypothetical ‘enforcement gap’ concerning these minority shareholdings and to find adequate normative solutions for any problems identified in this area. In the wake of the comments received, the Commission has recently presented specific proposals in its White Paper “Towards more effective EU merger control” published in July 2014.5 The underlying rationale of these proposals concerning minority shareholdings is to widen the scope of EU merger control in order to systematically address potential harm to competition arising from the acquisition of non-controlling minority shareholdings. Conversely, the envisaged review purports to avoid undue burdens to businesses, both by targeting only transactions that are, prima facie, problematic from a competition point of view and by adopting a system for the control of such situations that would be lighter than currently foreseen under the Merger Regulation for full mergers.6 While this proposal is certainly anchored on understandable concerns in terms of competition law, the procedural framework it contemplates is, to my view, debatable (as I shall put forward briefly infra, 2., esp 2.2.3.) Anyhow, whatever the final outcome of these reform proposals may be, the competition law treatment of minority shareholdings is definitely at a decisive crossroad in the context of EU competition law. Irrespective of the future rules that will be procedurally applicable de iure condito in the wake of a future reform of EU merger control rules, the substantive analysis of these situations and the relevant hermeneutical parameters to be retained in order to ensure an adequate level of legal predictability to undertakings and economic operators are of the essence now in this field. Hence, the current thoughts developed in this short paper, which purport to kindle a much needed discussion in this sensitive field; a discussion focused on the substantive problems to be addressed to deal with the actual competition law issues underlying minority shareholdings, no matter the specific procedural regime applicable thereto in the wake of the incoming reform of the EU merger control rules. Such intentional focus on substantive issues, regardless to some extent of the procedural 5 White Paper “Towards more effective EU merger control” available at http://ec.europa.eu/competition/consultations/2014_merger_control/. 6 See on this overall perspective pursued by the Commission in the proposals it has presented in the wake of the 2013 public consultation, e.g., Competition Policy Brief, Issue 15, October 2014, Minority Power – EU Merger Control and the Acquisition of Minority Shareholdings. 5 framework currently in flux, implies, somehow, an incursion in uncharted waters. Accordingly, this also represents, in my view, the best way to pay a modest tribute to the outstanding contribution of Ian Forrester for the development of competition law, always paving new analytical avenues and new areas of discussion that have fructified and led to a qualitative upgrade of competition law enforcement (and even to better normative solutions in certain areas of this complex and very dynamic body of law) – A fundamental contribution to which we are all indebted, competition law scholars and practitioners, courts, enforcement agencies and all the economic stakeholders in general who have some sort of interest in the enforcement of competition law. 1.2. – Key Competition Law Issues in this Domain and the Evolving Case Law – The Special Importance of the Financial Sector in this Field 1.2.1. – A particular concern with the competition law assessment of situations concerning minority shareholdings and related cases is, in my view, particularly relevant, given the rather high frequency with which they occur in the current context of business relationships in various economic sectors7 and considering that the potential impact on the competition process8 arising therefrom has not been appropriately dealt with in terms of enforcement of EU competition rules (hence evidencing a substantive enforcement gap, while not necessarily a procedural one, in this legal system). 7 In a worldwide context of relations between undertakings characterized by an increasingly complex set of interdependencies, even when these do not assume the more traditional forms of concentration between undertakings, one is confronted not only with the proliferation of more flexible processes of cooperation between undertakings carried out through joint ventures, but also of multiple cross-shareholding relationships. On the importance of these situations in modern industrialized economies, illustrating the most recent advances in this field, see, David Gilo, “The Anticompetitive Effect of Passive Investment”, in Mich L R., 2000, pp 2 ff. 8 The still relatively recent development in EU competition law of models of economic analysis of the functioning of markets in order to materialize or ensure a proper densification of legal parameters for the assessment of various situations, has been gradually allowing a deeper grasping of such type of repercussions, depending on the circumstances, of these cases of acquisition of shareholdings in third undertakings which do not imply transfers of control. See, in general, on the new perspectives disclosed by the advances in theoretical economic analysis of certain relationship nexus between undertakings, Robin A. Struijlaart, “Minority share acquisitions below the control threshold of the EC Merger Control Regulation: An economic and legal analysis”, in W Comp., 2002, pp173 ff. 6 Somehow, the insufficient attention granted to these situations of minority shareholdings may have resulted from some confusion between them and the situations relating to concentration operations in a given stage of evolution of EU competition law, prior to the adoption of the MCR (a ‘confusion’ in which, somehow paradoxically, the recent 2014 reform proposals of the Commission may have incurred again, although from a different normative standpoint). In this context, the assessment of a situation concerning the acquisition of a shareholding in a third undertaking without obtaining control thereof, made by the CJEU in its landmark “Philip Morris” ruling9 may have contributed for these rather grey areas (this judicial precedent being for a long time the only one dealing specifically with such matters until the recent ruling of the GC “Aer Lingus v. Commission”, of 201010). As far as the “Philip Morris” precedent is concerned, and regardless of the contrasting readings of the case, I understand that the CJEU has not sustained in this ruling the application of article 101.º TFEU to concentrations.11 What strikes me is the terminological vagueness of the content of this ruling, that should still be highlighted.12 Indeed, this relative vagueness should be regarded, in itself, as the main source of the intense 9 I refer here to the 1987 ruling of the CJEU normally identified and designated as “Philip Morris” – as it will also be referenced herein and throughout this analysis of competition law problems related with minority shareholdings short of joint control - corresponding actually to the ruling “BAT and Reynolds v. Commission”, Cases 142/84, 156/84. 10 See the ruling of GC “Aer Lingus v. Commission”, case T-411/07. 11 On the many contrasting hermeneutical readings proposed for the “Philip Morris” ruling following its adoption by the CJEU, see Willem Calkoen, J. Feenstra, “Acquisition of Shares in other Companies and EEC Competition Policy - The Philip Morris Decision”, in The International Business Lawyer, 1988, pp. 167 ff; E.-J. Mestmäcker, “Fusionskontrolle im Gemeinsamen Markt zwischen Wettbewerspolitik und Industriepolitik”, in EuR., 1988, pp. 349 ff, with these As. sustaining a reading of the ruling as acknowledging the applicability of the then article 85 EEC, currently article 101.º TFEU, to operations of concentration; sustaining the opposite view, albeit with not entirely coincident readings of the “Philip Morris” ruling, see, inter alia, V. Korah, P. Lasok, “Philip Morris and Its Aftermath – Merger Control?” in CMLR, 1988, pp. 333 ff; Bellamy, Mergers Outside the Scope of the New Merger Regulation Implications of the Philip Morris Judgment, in Annual Proceedings of the Fordham Corporate Law Institute - European/American Antitrust and Trade Law – 1988, Editor Barry Hawk, Fordham Corporate Law Institute, Matthew Bender, 1989, pp. 22-1 ff. 12 There is no room here to recast the depiction of the complex situation covered in the “Philip Morris” case, nor the outline of the analysis carried out by the ECJ. This case involved the acquisition by Philip Morris of a non controlling stake in a competitor (Rothmans International) with various related contractual engagements that might influence the structure of control of Rothmans International and its future evolution. However, there were some considerable ambiguities that could even be construed as conceptual flaws in the Court analysis in this case, as regards the use in the ruling of essential categories for the interpretation and application of article 101.º TFEU as the ones of “undertaking”, “legal or de facto control” on the activity of enterprises, “economic independence”, or “enterprise business behavior”. The not entirely clear use of these categories contributed to the ambiguity of the actual reach of the ruling in terms of contemplating the scrutiny under article 101.º TFEU of mere acquisitions of significant holdings in another independent competitor undertaking, short of acquisition of effective control, or comprehending also in that scrutiny acquisitions leading to effective control. 7 controversy among scholars concerning the reach of the precedent.13 Also, in the historic context in which the CJEU decided the case, the fluctuations in the terminology employed by the Court were, to a certain extent, “exploited” by the Commission in the long and troublesome process of negotiation of the Proposal for a then Community Regulation on concentration control, which had been on the table since 1973, in view of fostering the final adoption of the MCR. In fact, as the reach of that ruling was not completely clear, the Commission came to the point of considering, in that light, the possibility of reviewing the position it had initially adopted in its Memorandum on the problem of concentration in the common market, dated December 1, 1965, where it had sustained in principle the non applicability of article 101.º TFEU (then article 85.º EEC) to concentration operations14 thus paving the way, if that hypothetical reversal of hermeneutical reading was adopted, to a submission of certain categories of concentrations to that article 101.º regime. Although the subsequent approval of the MCR, has set aside the particular significance that was initially attached to the issue of a possible application to concentrations of the regime of article 101.º TFEU,15 the confusion thus created between these operations of concentration and situations of acquisition of minority shareholdings without obtaining control has lingered beyond this precedent in the context of EU competition law. 1.2.2. - Moreover, during the first stages of enforcement of the MCR, the problems originated by the duality of treatment of joint ventures, depending on whether they were qualified, or not, as concentrations, and the procedural issues concerning the definition of criteria for distinguishing these two basic subcategories of joint ventures16, continued somehow to 13 As referred in a previous footnote, various authors held that the “Philip Morris” ruling would stand for the application of article 85 EEC Treaty (current article 101.º TFEU) for purposes of direct control of certain concentration operations among, while other authors denied that this case law would have such a broad reach (besides various intermediate and composite views). 14 I refer here to the Memorandum of the Commission of 1 December 1965 - “Le Problème de la Concentration dans le Marché Commun”, Collection Etudes Serie Concurrence nº 3, Bruxelles, 1966 – corresponding to the first ‘ex professo’ analysis by the Commission of the issues related with direct control of concentrations. This 1965 Memorandum was adopted in the wake of a Report prepared by independent experts, the majority of which, curiously, had sustained the applicability of then article 85.º EEC to some concentrations (while the Commission diverged from that position and only contemplated the applicability under certain conditions of then article 86.º EEC - current article 102.º TFEU - to some concentration operations). See on that controversy putting it into historical context in terms of EU competition law, Aurelio Pappalardo, “Le Règlement CEE sur le Controle des Concentrations”, in Rev Int’l Dr Econ., 1990, pp. 3 ff. 15 See again on such developments and interplay, Luís Silva Morais, Joint Ventures and EU Competition Law, esp points 4.2., 4.3. and 4.4. of Chapter 1 , in which an appreciable part of this analysis, particularly as regards the historical framework and preceding normative developments, relies 16 I have previously highlighted the disproportionate relevance of procedural issues concerning the distinction between concentrative joint ventures and cooperative joint ventures during the period whilst 8 downplay a consistent autonomous treatment of potential problems of distortion of competition arising from situations of acquisition of minority shareholding without gaining control (situations not fitting nor the category of concentration, nor the category of joint ventures). Also, the importance attached by the Commission to the organization of an efficient EU merger control procedure, pursuant to the adoption of the MCR, and the administrative burden of the prior notification procedures within the context of the application of article 101.º TFEU (prior to the adoption of Regulation Nº 1/2003), further and decisively contributed to the relative “oblivion” of the issues of minority shareholdings which do not confer control.17 This relative substantive enforcement “gap” in the system of enforcement of EU competition rules, although undoubtedly less serious then has been in the past the lacuna in terms of direct control do concentrations (until 1989), should not linger on. In fact, several reasons contribute, in my view, the MCR was in force prior to its first reform (1997 amendment to the MCR). See, on this, and on the competition law analytical distortions associated with this distinction, Luís Silva Morais, Joint Ventures and EU Competition Law, esp point 4.4. of Chapter 1. Again a disproportionate focus on procedural issues and frameworks may be emerging with the new 2014 proposals of reform of the MCR in order to address the issues related with minority shareholdings. History may be repeating itself here. 17 In the US antitrust law system, a greater deal of attention has been, for some time now, devoted to this type of issues, by such influent authors as Philip Areeda and Donald Turner in the classical study, Antitrust Law (1980). Therein, these authors sustained that the “noncontrolling acquisition has no intrinsic threat to competition at all” (op. cit., par. 1203 d, 322). However, this understanding has been opposed by many US antitrust scholars, mostly after the adoption of the revised Merger Guidelines of 1982. See, for all, in regard of the development of such perception of the potential of distortion of competition inherent to the acquisition of minority shareholdings not granting their acquirer the control of the participated entity, Daniel O’Brien, Steven Salop, “Competitive effects of partial ownership: financial interest and corporate control”, in ALJ, 2000, pp 559 ff. Significantly, the importance attached to issues of distortion of competition that may be associated with this type of minority holdings has even led some scholars to propose adjustments to the traditional formula of the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index (HHI), in order to consider the variables pertaining to situations of holding of stakes in third undertakings without obtaining corporate control. I refer, namely, to the so-called “modified HHI” proposed by Timothy F. Bresnaham and Steven Salop (see the cit. authors in “Quantifying the competitive effects of production joint ventures” in International Journal of Industrial Organization, 1986, pp 155 ff). Furthermore, the US 1992 Horizontal Merger Guidelines (revised in 1997 and comprehensively reformed and replaced in 2010) contained a brief reference to issues associated with the holding of holdings in the share capital of undertakings, although such reference seem to be made to cross-shareholdings in undertakings participating in joint ventures (see the aforementioned Guidelines, cit., in paragraph 3.34 (c): “the Agencies also assess direct equity investments between or among the participants. Such investments may reduce the incentives of the participants to compete with each other”). In the new 2010 US Horizontal Merger Guidelines, its Section 13 on “Partial Acquisitins” covers specifically and more broadly these situations and acknowledges that such acquisition of minority shareholdings (or “partial acquisitions”) when “not resulting in effective control” may anyhow “present significant competitive concerns and may require a somehow distinct analysis from that applied to full mergers (…)” (if originating effective control, in my view, those cases should be deemed equivalent to concentration operations under EU competition law and will not correspond as such to these particular situations that I am herein considering and that justify autonomous treatment because these imply a change of competitive conditions short of control). The 2010 Guidelines, however, do not go to the point of specifying, as regards such “distinct analysis” of those minority acquisitions – that I consider bearing significant parallelisms with the analysis of partial function joint ventures under EU competition law – a “modified HHI” (in terms of structural analysis to be applied to such situations). 9 to the development of a new analytical treatment of that matter, to which I attach paramount importance (as confirmed by the aforementioned very recent developments of the “Aer Lingus v. Commission” case and of other cases18). In first place (i), the proliferation of these situations of acquisition of shareholdings without obtaining control in various business sectors and the consequent relevance of such cases for the practical operation of these sectors will lead to a predictable increase of its effect of restriction of competition and should trigger reactions from affected undertakings (and relevant affected stakeholders). Thus, in this area, a virtuous effect of circular type could occur, to the extent the filing of complaints by affected enterprises will tend to strengthen and render more systematic the Commission scrutiny (or, as the case may be, from EU Member States Competition Authorities) concerning these situations. Complementarily, once this increased attention from the Commission and other Competition Authorities is raised, the willingness of affected undertakings to react through the submission of complaints will also be greater. Also, a renewed attention of the Commission and on the part of other Competition Authorities may also arise from issues related with acquisition or holding of minority shareholdings that are brought forward in the context of concentration control proceedings or as sideeffects of some concentrations. 1.2.3. - Such a proliferation of cases of acquisition of minority shareholdings occurs, in particular - as highlighted in the context of US antitrust law - in the most dynamic business sectors, namely telecommunications, electronic communications, in general, or other hightech industries.19 18 See, in general, on these very recent developments in this domain, Enrique González-Diaz, Minority Shareholdings and Creeping Acquisitions: The European Union Approach, in 2011 Competition Law Institute - International Antitrust Law & Policy, Fordham University School of Law, Editor, Barry Hawk, cit, pp 423 ff. Complementarily, on the renewed analytical attention given to situations of acquisition of shareholdings without obtaining control, see, inter alia, Laurent Flochel, “Les Effets Concurrentiels des Prises de Participation Minoritaires”, in Concurrences, N.º 1-2012, pp 1 ff; Nadine Mouy, “Participations Minoritaires et Contrôle des Concentrations”, in Concurrences, N.º 1-2012, pp 10 ff; David Spector, Jacques-Philippe Gunther, David Bosco, Peter Kalbfleisch, Bernaerd van de Walle de Ghelcke, Peter Freeman, Andreas Bardong, “Merger Control and Minority Shareholdings: Time for a Change?”, in Concurrences, N.º 3-2011, pp 14-41. 19 Daniel O’Brien and Steven Salop refer to that fact in the context of the US antitrust law system , emphasizing, e.g., among other cases, the Federal Trade Commission’s decision on the case “Time Warner/Turner” (“Time Warner Inc., 61 Fed Reg. 5, 0301 – Sept. 25, 1996”). See, in that sense, As. cit., “Competitive effects of partial ownership: financial interest and corporate control”, cit., pp 560 ff. 10 The practice of acquiring and holding this type of shareholdings in competing undertakings is also extremely common in the financial sector currently under focus in the wake of the recent international financial crisis (maxime in the banking and insurance sub-sectors). Moreover, I consider symptomatic of the importance of those situations, the fact that, on several decisions on concentration operations in the financial sector, such as, inter alia, in the “Allianz/Dresdner” or “Nordbanken/Postgirot”,20 decisions, the Commission’s assessment has not only been focused upon the main aspects of the acquisition of corporate control itself, that encapsulated the concentrations at stake and corresponded to direct object of the proceedings, but also on the repercussions stemming from the networks of minority shareholdings held by the undertakings involved in the concentrations in other undertakings. I even believe that, at EU level, beside the traditional importance of such cross-shareholdings among financial institutions, as a general feature of several of the most developed financial systems,21 other factors have also accrued, contributing to a remarkable weight of these situations in the portfolio of several institutions. Such factors are related with the development of a complex integration process in the various sub-sectors of the financial system, leading to the gradual creation of EU-scale financial conglomerates, or groups with a significant position in certain areas of the EU that already surpass the thresholds of domestic markets. This process has involved some concentration operations between financial institutions, which have increased with the implementation of the EU single currency.22 However, due to the issues that such transactions tend to raise in the financial sector, either for prudential reasons, or by particularities of the domestic markets - particularly in the segments of retail activities - such integration process may involve, as intermediate stages, the acquisition of minority shareholdings in financial institutions of other EU Member States. 20 See the “Allianz/Dresdner” and “Nordbanken/Postgirot”decisions, dated, respectively, 19 July 2001 (case M.2431) and 8 November 2001 (case M.2567). Symptomatically, it was the Commission itself who raised the relevance of this type of analysis concerning minority shareholdings in those decisions relating to concentrations in the financial sector, in analyses produced in the context of the Competition Policy Newsletter, 2002, February (See in that Newsletter, the paper of Enzo Moavero Milanesi and Alexander Winterstein, “Minority shareholdings, interlocking directorships and the EC competition rules – recent Commission practice” (Newsletter, cit,. pp 15 ff). 21 See on the frequent situations of minority cross-shareholding in financial institutions in the more developed financial sectors, the Paper Competition in UK banking – a report to the Chancellor of the Exchequer, Don Cruickshank, cit. For a more general outlook of the global changes in EU financial systems, in the context of which the acquisition of minority shareholdings has proliferated, see The transformation of the European financial system, Editors, Vitor Gaspar, Philipp Hartmann, Olaf Sleijpen, European Central Bank, 2003. 22 On the increase of the number of cross-border concentrations associated with the implementation of the Euro and with the completion of the last stages of the monetary union, see Banking Integration in the Euro Area, European Central Bank, Occasional Paper Series, N.º. 6, December 2002, Ines Cabral, Franck Dierick, Jukka Vesala. 11 Conversely, the consolidation of domestic markets, which is also a reaction to these background movements within the EU national financial systems, is subject to natural constraints, dictated by the application of competition rules and national prudential standards so that, rather often, financial institutions unable to proceed further with certain concentration processes, choose to maintain various cross-shareholdings in other national entities.23 1.2.4. - At another level, and in second place (ii), the overcoming of this substantive enforcement gap in the EU system of enforcement of competition rules concerning the scrutiny of acquisition of minority shareholdings, not subject to merger control, may also, in principle, result from the very process of “decentralization” triggered by the adoption of Regulation (EC) No. 1 / 2003. Indeed, as I have already had occasion to highlight, one of the main reasons for this option, with the undeniable risks that it entails, corresponds to the creation of conditions for the Commission to focus on the treatment of most serious situations of potential breach of EU competition rules, as well as on the analysis and clarification of legal issues that, until now, have not been adequately or sufficiently discussed.24 23 On these acquisitions and holdings of stakes in financial institutions incorporated in other EU Member States and in domestic financial institutions, for different reasons, but related with the very same movement of integration of the financial sectors within the EU, evidencing yet unknown reach and boundaries, see, inter alia, Banking Integration in the Euro Area, European Central Bank, Occasional Paper Series, N.º 6, December 2002, cit. and Bank Mergers, Competition and Liquidity, European Central Bank, Occasional Paper Series, N.º 292, November 2003, Elena Carletti, Philip Hartmann, Giancarlo Spagnolo. 24 See various incidental references to these aspects related with the so-called “modernization” process of EU competition law, in my book Joint Ventures and EU Competition Law, cit., Chapters 1 and 2 (e.g. point 1.1. of Chapter 2). The process of decentralization of application of EU competition law carries with it some unavoidable risks in terms of legal predictability and consistency, which, in spite of the undeniable practical success of the first stage of implementation of Regulation (EC) N.º 1/2003 that decisively contributed to set aside initial doubts about the overall feasibility and consistency of such model, may have remained up to this date somehow overlooked by the Commission (see for a balance of this experience in the course of the first years of application of Regulation N.º 1/2003, albeit oversimplifying some critical issues in my view, Report of the European Commission to the Parliament and the Council - Report on the functioning of Regulation 1/2003, COM(2009) 206 final; Commission Staff Working Paper accompanying the Report on the functioning of Regulation 1/2003, SEC(2009) 574 final - their publication was mandated by article 44 of Regulation 1/2003). See, in general, on this modernization and decentralization process developed since 2003 considering its significant achievements but also the risks involved, Damien M. B. Gerard, The ECN – Network Antitrust Enforcement in the European Union, in D Geradin, I Lianos (eds.), Research Handbook on EU Competition Law, E Elgar, 2013.; F. Cengiz, “Multilevel Governance in Competition Policy: the European Competition Network”, Eur. L. Rev., 2010 pp 660 ff; H.F. Koeck and M.M. Karollus (eds), FIDE XXIII Congress: The Modernization of European Competition Law – Initial Experiences with Regulation 1/2003, Vienna: Nomos/facultas, 2008. Anyhow, the chief reason for incurring such legal uncertainty risks – however transitory these may be – is the creation of the conditions for a more demanding application of EU competition rules by the Commission, extending not only to the more obvious situations, more often addressed, of control of cartels bearing a high potential of distortion of competition, but also focusing on types of problems less frequently addressed which need hermeneutical 12 It happens that, in my view, the competition law scrutiny of such situations of acquisition of minority shareholdings, to which the Commission had not devoted systematic attention, despite this potential for disruption of competition in some situations, corresponds precisely to one of these fundamental issues, deserving further clarification and new hermeneutical definitions. 1.2.5. - It should, in any case, be acknowledged that the issues of distortion of competition associated with such situations have not been completely ignored by the Commission in the wake of the fundamental “Philip Morris” case (which originated the key aforementioned judicial precedent)25 and until the recent aforementioned 2014 reform proposals. In several cases, the Commission even sought to address these problems through the adoption of commitments by the undertakings involved in certain transactions.26 It did so, however, in the context of analysis of notifications of projects of creation of joint ventures under article 101.º TFEU and, above all, of notifications of concentrations within the context of the MCR, incidentally addressing these aspects as side issues in wider analytical processes. The new developments that I believe possible and desirable in this regard, on the contrary, relate to the substantive scrutiny and autonomous assessment of potential effects of restriction to competition associated with this type of situations of acquisition of minority shareholdings (to be undertaken by the Commission on its own initiative or following complaints filed by affected entities).27 Such developments may, of course, guidance and clarification, as is the case of an enhanced scrutiny the analysis of effects of restriction of competition inherent to certain situations of acquisition of minority shareholdings. 25 I shall further mention some situations addressed by the Commission in this regard. Anyhow, as mentioned, the key judicial precedent up to now has been the “Philip Morris” ruling, cit., recently supplemented by the GC ruling “Aer Lingus v. Commission”, cit. 26 I refer both to commitments of a structural and behavioral nature, in particular concerning rules and procedures on the flow of information between undertakings holding cross-shareholdings, as referred to below. 27 I herein refer to developments in the field of the interpretation and application of article 101.º TFEU. It should, however, be noted that the Commission pondered, in the Green Paper concerning the revision of the Merger Control Regulation, dated of 2001, cit., - and anticipating here the 2014 reform proposals the possibility, in the wake of related doctrinal suggestions, of extending this system of merger control to the acquisition of minority shareholdings, irrespective of the acquisition of control, likewise happens in some jurisdictions (see 2001 Green Paper, cit., para. 108). Nevertheless the Commission came to consider at that time disproportionate to submit all the acquisitions of minority shareholdings to the ex ante control set out in the MCR and – appropriately, in my opinion – such an option, mentioned in the 2001 Green Paper, was not enshrined in the second reform of the MCR. Conversely, I do not subscribe the positive view stated by the Commission in that 2001 Green Paper where it holds that only a very limited number of transactions (of the aforementioned type) prone to raise issues of distortion of competition would not be adequately dealt with within the framework of application of articles 101.º and 102.º TFEU (see 2001 Green Paper, cit., para. 109). As far as I am concerned, while the normative program enshrined in those provisions is, indeed, fit to cover the problems of restriction of competition usually generated by these situations of acquisitions of minority shareholdings (and cross-shareholdings or interlocking directorates 13 benefit from the experience gained in the past in the context of analysis of notification procedures ex vi article 101.º TFEU and the MCR, but must be subject to a more developed and systematic analytical treatment. Such a treatment should, in turn, be largely influenced by the analytical parameters developed in connection with joint ventures subject to the regime set out in article 101.º TFEU. 28 2. – Analytical Criteria for Assessment of Effects on Competition Arising from Ownership of Undertakings Short of Individual or Joint Control 2.1. – Identifying Relevant Situations Which Inherently Lead to Potential Restrictions of Competition 2.1.1. - The key problems of restriction of competition that I deem potentially associated with situations of acquisition of minority holdings in third undertakings, without obtaining control thereof, essentially relate with the development of behavioral coordination processes between the undertakings involved in these situations (falling as such under the prohibition set out in article 101.º TFEU). This applies especially to cases where such relationships are established between competitors. It may be, somehow, considered that in such situations there are conditions for the occurrence of what I have designated in the context of joint venture analysis as spill over effects in broad sense, impacting on the competitive behavior of undertakings bound by such participation relationships. In the case of non-full function joint ventures I have depicted in past analyses such spill over effects in broad sense as effects on effective or potential competition between participating undertakings in any given joint venture, construed or apprehended as the occurrence of repercussions triggered at a or bodies of the entities involved in those transactions), no systematic hermeneutical framework has, nonetheless, been consolidated so far on the basis of those provisions and oriented for that purpose; and hence, a substantive “gap” – not necessarily a procedural one - may be identified in the EU system of application of competition rules in this domain. 28 I believe that minority shareholdings in third undertakings – maxime cross-shareholdings between two or more undertakings – may generate effects of distortion of competition very similar to those associated with some types of joint ventures subject to the legal regime set out in article 101.º TFEU, which may be scrutinized in light of such legal regime, thus explaining my brief reference to this issue. The treatment of this subject requires, however, an ex professo analysis of these matters. For that reason, I merely identify and depict, in extremely succinct terms, some of the most relevant issues which may arise in this field and which would justify a greater deal of attention from the Commission and, through the hermeneutical guidance of this institution, from EU Members States Competition Authorities. 14 level of cooperation limited to certain entrepreneurial functions and which extend to the competitive behaviour, globally considered, of parent undertakings in the markets of final goods in which they operate and within which the specific functions pursued through the joint venture are projected to impact or to be performed. 29 30 Bearing in mind the potential relevance of these situations for the application of article 101.º TFEU, it is appropriate, in my view, to identify in a more systematic manner some paradigmatic situations of minority or joint shareholdings which do not involve the acquisition of control, but which should be brought in a more manner under the radar of competition law scrutiny. I am also assuming here that the substantive test of the article 101.º TFEU would largely be a consistent one for that purpose and that, in such normative context, one should not necessarily require a submission of those situations to the procedural framework of a reformed MCR, even if under the so called ‘targeted’ form of a ‘transparency system’ envisaged in the July 2014 White Paper (through which parties would be required, under reformed merger control rules, to produce a limited information notice on some acquisitions of non-controlling shareholdings provided these would give rise to a “competitively significant link”).31 Thus, I acknowledge that at least four types of situations should be identified, such as, namely:32 29 See the overall depiction of this type of effects of distortion of competition made in my book Joint Ventures and EU Competition Law, cit., esp p 251 ff. 30 Those situations of acquisition of minority shareholdings, whenever the acquirer possesses a high degree of market power may as well raise issues of abuse of dominant position, which may be challenged in the context of the application of article 102.º TFEU. However, these situations are very specific and not particularly relevant in relation to the similarity I herein seek to emphasize between the analysis of some types of joint ventures and these cases of acquisition of minority shareholdings which may originate anticompetitive behavioral coordination. This similarity obviously concerns the application of article101.º TFEU – and accordingly my very brief foray in the field of minority shareholdings is limited to such article 101. regime (on the basis of the assumption that certain issues of anticompetitive behavioral coordination do not exclusively result from joint control situations, usually associated with joint ventures, but may also be originated by joint shareholdings, regardless of the existence of joint control). Anyhow, on eventual issues pertaining to the application of article 102.º TFEU related to that type of holdings, see, in general, Robin Struijlaart, “Minority Share Acquisitions Below the Control Threshold of the EC Merger Control Regulation: An Economic and Legal Analysis”, cit., pp 173 ff. 31 Again, the limited purview of this paper does not involve as such a comprehensive or even a specific analysis of the proposals put forwards by the Commission under the July 2014 White Paper. Conversely my focus here is to address the potential for an effective competition law scrutiny under the substantive test of article 101.º TFEU regardless of changes of the procedural framework with the necessary regulatory cost these entail (also considering the substantive approximation or interplay between the substantive test of article 101.º TFEU and the substantive SIEC test under the MCR, as I have purported to evidence through the specific analysis of joint ventures in my book Joint Ventures and EU Competition Law, cit. (esp Chapter 2, points 1.2. and ff) 32 I take into consideration to some extent in this depiction of the most paradigmatic situations, the characterization set forth by John Temple Lang in International joint ventures under community law, in Annual Proceedings of the Fordham Corporate Law Institute – International Antitrust Law & Policy – 1999, Editor Barry Hawk, Fordham Corporate Law Institute, 2000, pp. 381 ff, esp. paragraph V. – Joint 15 - (i) Situations in which joint shareholdings with some impact in a given entity result from an agreement between the undertakings owning those shareholdings; - (ii) Situations in which such shareholdings are the result of agreements established between these undertakings, holding the shareholdings at stake, or between several undertakings controlled thereby; - (iii) Joint shareholdings resulting from of an agreement between an acquirer undertaking and the undertaking which is the object of such partial acquisition (provided the acquisition does not involve the transfer of control over that acquired undertaking); - (iv) Joint shareholdings in a given undertaking, held by two other undertakings, which did neither result from an agreement between these entities, nor from an agreement between any of such undertakings and the targeted undertaking. As regards the first three aforementioned types of situations, I think that the application of article 101.º TFEU is, in general, appropriate, with the possible apprehension of effects of restriction of competition scrutinized in light of this provision depending upon several factors, related with the actual conditions of operation of the markets at stake and with the variable layout of the involved undertakings, in a rather similar manner to that outlined in the framework of my study of the different functional types of joint ventures (that may not be qualified as concentrations).33 In this field of minority shareholdings, however, one particular factor may be of paramount importance in assessing the occurrence of adverse effects on competition and their expected intensity. I refer to the existence of representatives of undertakings holding shareholdings in third companies in the corporate bodies of these latter entities. Even more noteworthy and problematic at this level will be the combination of cross-shareholdings with reciprocal representation in the corporate bodies of the concerned undertakings.34 ownership and joint dominance – pp 423 ff). However, I do not fully agree with the systematization proposed by Temple Lang and I depart from some aspects of his analysis concerning the typical consequences of some of these situations in the context of the application of article 101.º TFEU. 33 See on this, referring to a proposed framework focused on four key functional sub-types of joint ventures, my book , Joint Ventures and EU Competition Law, cit., esp Chapter 3. 34 Notwithstanding the fact that I am recurrently taking into consideration the concept of undertaking with the very broad contours that it presents under EU competition law, undertakings using a corporate form deserve a particular attention. It should be noted that the above mentioned representation may assume a variety of legal forms. See, in that regard, and providing examples of such diversity, Enzo Moavero 16 2.1.2. - As regards the fourth (aforementioned) type of situations, the possibility of these cases falling under the regime of article 101.º TFEU has raised more controversy. Thus, authors such as John Temple Lang sustain that the absence of an element of agreement between the involved undertakings would not really be compatible with the application of article 101.º TFEU to those situations (merely acknowledging that, under certain circumstances, those cases may be subject to article 102.º TFEU).35 However, I do not share this view. While I consider that this type of situations corresponds, in principle, to legitimate acquisitions of shareholdings, given the absence of any initial agreement between the involved undertakings - relevant, as such, for the purposes of application of article 101.º TFEU - I believe, nonetheless, that the continued holding of such shareholdings may, under certain conditions, come to originate restrictions of competition caught under the prohibition set out in that provision. Such situations of acquisition of significant shareholdings in certain undertakings, without involving any agreement between the acquirer and the existing shareholders are more common than one might suppose. These may result, inter alia, from the acquisition of shareholdings in securities markets or from the acquisition of control over another undertaking which, in turn, holds a minority shareholding in the concerned participated undertaking.36 Some authors also consider certain additional legal qualifications or characterizations as regards the set of situations of acquisition of minority interests involving an agreement between the concerned undertakings. Indeed, authors such as Thompson and Meadowcroft and, more recently, Moavero Miolanesi and A. Winterstein37, acknowledge that, in some cases, minority interests in certain undertakings are acquired as an alternative to agreements with such undertakings that would be prima facie deemed as restrictive of competition (in other words, such purchasing agreements, Milanesi and Alexander Winterstein, “Minority shareholdings, interlocking directorships and the EC competition rules – recent Commission practice”, cit, pp15 ff. 35 See, in fact, in this regard, the cited A. in International joint ventures under community law, cit, 424: “If joint ownership of one company by two others comes about without any agreement between any two of them, Article 81 does not apply (…)”. 36 These most blatant situations of joint shareholdings not resulting from agreements between the involved undertakings are, e.g., mentioned by John Temple Lang, who draws competition law corollaries there from that I do not entirely subscribe, as aforementioned (see A. cit., International joint ventures under community law, cit, p 424). 37 See S. Meadowcroft, D. Thompson, Minority share acquisition: the impact upon competition, Office for official publications of the European Communities, Luxembourg, 1986. See, also, Moavero Milanesi, A. Winterstein, Minderheitsbeteiligungen und personelle Verflechtungen zwischen Wettberwerben –Zur Anwendung von Artikel 81 und 82 EG-Vertrag, in Handbuch der Europäischen Finanzdienstleistungsindustrie, Rolfes, Fisher, Fritz Knapp Verlag, Frankfurt, 2001. 17 under the conditions in which they occur, would have a similar effect to cooperation agreements, restrictive competition, to be entered into with the participated entity - “nichtangriffdenken”, in the qualification put forward by Milanesi and Winterstein).38 As far as I am concerned, I have some reservations to that legal qualification. In the event elements of cooperative agreement exist between the parties, they somehow prevail in the assessment of these situations and the aspects concerning minority interests which may occur, are ancillary elements in this process of cooperation between undertakings, to be perceived as a whole. I, therefore, reject in this domain, an analytical logic comparable to the one that leads to the identification of dissimulated cartels, construed under an apparent joint venture format and essentially oriented towards the price-fixing by the participating undertakings. 39 Indeed, in these latter cases there is ab initio a specific process of cooperation, explicitly undertaken between the participating undertakings, which can be actually used to serve other collusive non-specified purposes, of a serious anticompetitive nature. Conversely, in a significant proportion of cases of acquisition of minority shareholdings in third undertakings, even in cases that involve somehow an agreement between the involved undertakings, the parties do not assume, as such, any cooperation process to be developed beyond the mere acquisition acts in themselves. Such cooperation may, in particular, be induced by acquiring and keeping those shareholdings, but in that case, I sustain that the analysis of these situations should be carried out in order to ascertain possible negative effects of behavioral coordination between the involved undertakings and should not be oriented towards the qualification or characterization of such situations as alternative options to the establishment of ‘stricto sensu’ cooperation agreements between the parties (“nichtangriffdenken”, as suggested by Milanesi and Winterstein). The mere identification of effects of behavioral coordination induced by keeping certain minority shareholdings will be sufficient to lead to a competition law scrutiny in the context of the application of article 101.º TFEU, and any other complementary legal qualifications further complicate, unnecessarily, the proper analysis of these situations. Thus, I do not agree either with the analytical perspective of authors such as D. 38 See, in this regard, the cit As., in Minderheitsbeteiligungen und personelle Verflechtungen zwischen Wettberwerben –Zur Anwendung von Artikel 81 und 82 EG-Vertrag, cit. 39 On these situations of use of the joint venture legal format to establish (dissimulated) cartels, oriented towards the joint fixing of prices, see again my book Joint Ventures and EU Competition Law, cit., esp points 4.1.2. ff of its Chapter 3. Also in that book I acknowledged the possible use of purchasing joint ventures for the formation of buyers’ cartels (see esp , points 5.2.1. ff of its Chapter 3, cit.). 18 Reittman, who claim to identify certain situations in which undertakings acquire minority interests for the sole purpose of strengthening their market power.40 This effect of strengthening the market power of the undertakings concerned may indeed occur, through incentives for coordination, and, in the event it interferes, beyond a certain degree, in the competition process in certain markets, it should actually be scrutinized (in the field of article 101.º TFEU and, as such, autonomously from the field of merger control covered by the MCR). However, the rationale for the scrutiny of these situations by the competition authorities lies, in my view, in the identification of such type of predictable effects (and should be focused on such effects), rather than on a negative assessment intrinsically associated with a supposed project for strengthening the market power on the part of undertakings holding joint shareholdings short of joint control. The potential anticompetitive effect at stake, of reinforcement of market power interfering with the due functioning of the competition process of certain markets may, inter alia, occur, as suggested by the analysis of O’Brien and Salop, through unilateral effects due to the ability to influence a competitor’s behavior, which, in itself, will vary according to the degree of influence over the partially owned competitor (since these authors rightly emphasize the various possible degrees of influence, short of control ‘stricto sensu’, that an undertaking might exercise over its partially owned competitors and producing, accordingly, different corollaries, to be properly assessed, as regards its strengthening and correlative excessive projection or exercise of market power).41 40 On this analytical perspective, see D. Reitman, “Partial ownership arrangements and the potential for collusion”, in J. Ind. Ec., 1994, pp 313 ff. 41 See on this enhanced perspective of an antitrust theory of harm associated with minority shareholdings, D. O’Brien, S Salop, “Competitive effects of partial ownership: financial interest and corporate control”, in ALJ, 2000, pp 559 ff. See also on such perspective, A. Ezrachi, D Gilo, EC “Competition Law and the Regulation of Passive Investments Among Competitors”, in Oxford Journal of Law Studies, 2006, pp 327 ff. 19 2.2. – Anticompetitive Effects Arising from Minority Shareholdings – How to Build a Reliable Analytical Grid in this Domain vis a vis the Option of Expanding the Scope of the MCR Envisaged in the Commission 2014 Proposals 2.2.1. - In overall terms, I consider that the risks of distortion of competition associated with these situations of acquisition and holding of minority shareholdings correspond, to a large extent, to two of the categories of potential risks that I have identified previous analyses in relation to joint ventures subject to the regime of article 101.º TFEU.42 I refer to the risks of collusion concerning prices or quantitative output levels of goods or services and to risks of anti-competitive coordination at the level of the quality of those goods or services. In reality, such situations particularly when rather sizable holdings in third undertakings are at stake, lead to the emergence of specific and substantive interests in the results of these undertakings, which, in turn, may induce or influence either concerted actions or tacit “non-aggression” arrangements between the involved undertakings, with a view to maximizing the joint results of the same undertakings. Moreover, this incentive for the collusion of commercial behaviors or business “non-aggression” arrangements may be especially enhanced in situations of cross-shareholdings between competitors, coupled with reciprocal representation in the management of these undertakings. That results from the conditions that are hence objectively created for the flow of commercially sensitive information between these undertakings and for the inherent reduction of the levels of uncertainty concerning the behavior of competitors (this relative uncertainty on third party commercial behavior, it should be noted, constitutes the foundation of the whole competition process43). The probability of the occurrence of cases of 42 I refer here once more to my comprehensive analysis of joint ventures, especially non full function joint ventures, covered by article 101.º TFEU, developed in my recent book Joint Ventures and EU Competition Law, cit., and to the overall analytical framework and corresponding key risks for competition in connection with such joint ventures depicted in such book. In fact, those joint ventures seem to bear considerable affinities with minority shareholdings (and in any case more affinities to such joint ventures than with full mergers covered by the MCR as, in a different sense and in a somewhat contradictory manner, the July 2014 White Paper proposals seem to imply). See esp Joint Ventures and EU Competition Law, cit., Chapter 3, point 6. 43 The manner in which this uncertainty may come to materialize, or not, or, conversely, the strategies or perspectives of anticipation of strategic behaviors of competing undertakings is, as I have highlighted in my recent analysis of joint ventures (see, again Joint Ventures and EU Competition Law, cit., esp, points 2.3.2. ff, Chapter 3, and several footnotes included therein) at the centre of the new analytical models 20 collusion will also tend to be more intense in cases in which an undertaking holds minority stakes in more than one competitor, as this broadens the horizon of converging business interests and creates conditions for an additional significant decrease of competition between involved undertakings. 2.2.2. - Although the criteria and models of economic analysis that may influence the competition law assessment of effects of restriction of competition arising from the acquisition and holding of minority stakes are still rather flawed or not duly consolidated44, one may argue that the combination of cross-shareholdings, with a high level of concentration in the potentially affected markets,45 as well as the existence of significant barriers to entry in those markets, creates optimal conditions for the coordination of behaviors between undertakings (or even for the ‘cartelization’ of such behaviors). 46 In fact, this set of factors significantly contributes to reduce the incentives of undertakings to depart, for their own benefit, from the converging business orientations in the context of cartels or of situations of business cooperation comparable thereto.47 Such a reduction of the incentives to depart from convergent approaches reinforces, in turn, the viability and effectiveness of such anti-competitive coordination processes. Conversely, it is possible to consider as usually permitted situations, therefore not leading in principle to appreciable effects of restriction of competition, those in which minority stakes are held in markets with low degrees of proposed in the context of the so called game theory (somehow overcoming the former theoretical clashes between structuralist trends and the criticism of the Chicago School thereto). 44 These flaws of economic analysis will be, anyhow, wider in the EU competition law framework than those in the US antitrust law context. On these shortcomings of economic analysis, albeit smoothened by developments in economic theory in the latest two decades, see Robin A. Struijlaart, “Minority share acquisitions below the control threshold of the EC Merger Control Regulation: An economic and legal analysis”, cit., esp. pp 183 ff. As regards new advances in economic theory in this area, see K. Morasch, “Strategic alliances as stackelberg cartels – concept and equilibrium, alliance structure”, in International Journal of Industrial Organization, 2000, 257 ff. and Enrique González-Diaz, Minority Shareholdings and Creeping Acquisitions: The European Union Approach, in 2001 Competition Law Institute - International Antitrust Law & Policy, 2012, cited, above. Also referring to recent advances in this domain, see, esp. the Report commissioned by the OFT, Minority Interests in Competitors, 2010, and the much relevant OECD Policy Roundtable Concerning Minority Shareholdings, 2008. Conversely, some recent proliferation of economic analytical models in this domain, strikes me as overly theoretical and unfit to support an adequately foreseeable legal assessment. 45 In the “Philip Morris” case the CJEU already emphasized that the competition authorities’ scrutiny of minority shareholding acquisitions should be particularly stringent in markets evidencing a high level of concentration or an oligopolistic structure. 46 Furthermore, these cross-shareholding situations in markets featuring a high level of concentration and involving enterprises with significant market power may, also, as briefly pondered above, contribute to the creation of positions of collective dominance. 47 For a characterization of these mechanisms, termed in Anglo-Saxon doctrine as “incentive to cheat on cartel agreements”, see, for all, Josepf Brodley, “Joint Ventures and Antitrust Policy”, in Harv L. Rev., 1982, pp. 1523 ff, esp. pp 1544 ff. 21 concentration, involving undertakings with limited market shares and originating limited forms of representation in the management bodies of participated undertakings. Other relevant factors for the assessment of possible effects of distortion of competition resulting from this type of minority shareholdings are those concerning the nature and extent of the rights attached to such shareholdings.48 Hence, even when not conferring control of the participated undertakings, such shareholdings may, under certain circumstances, provide their owners with effective means in order to oppose to certain major decisions, or an influence that, in proportional terms, ranks beyond the quantitative dimension of the same shareholdings (very diverse factors, such as the degree of dissemination of the remaining share capital of the participated entity or the existence of certain rights that are contractually enshrined, e.g. in shareholders’ agreements in the case of corporate undertakings, may be taken into account in this context). Moreover, the association between these minority shareholdings and any cooperative agreements between the undertakings involved, even if these ones have a very limited scope or a very general nature, may also contribute to render more intense the incentives towards abstaining from competitive conduct, (which, in turn, may affect the competitive position of any one of these undertakings inter-connected through those nexus). These incentives may work twofold in the relationships between participant and participated undertakings. Indeed, not only the undertaking holding an appreciable shareholding in a third undertaking may be induced to coordinate its behavior with the latter, so as to safeguard the value of its investment – especially if both undertakings hold considerable market power – but also, the participated undertaking may be induced to avoid a more aggressive commercial interplay in relation to the participant undertaking in order to prevent any reactions from the latter that could significantly affect its activity (e.g. reactions in the sense of increasing the degree of interference in the activity of the participated undertaking or, conversely, in the sense of disposing of the shareholding, thus creating conditions of instability for the activity of the participated undertaking). 48 On this factor and on the preceding factor (dealt with above), enhancing or not, as the case may be, the possibility of partial acquisitions lessening competition, particularly by giving the acquiring undertaking the ability to influence the competitive conduct of the target undertaking, see the already mentioned Section 13 on “Partial Acquisitions” of the new US 2010 Horizontal Merger Guidelines (thus providing in the context of the US antitrust system a specific hermeneutical guidance in this domain that is still lacking in terms of the EU competition law system, both as regards Commission Guidelines on merger control or relevant Guidelines related with the application of article 101.º TFEU). 22 Moreover, in markets evidencing a significant degree of concentration and a substantial mutual interdependence of the undertakings involved therein, - as it frequently happens in the financial sector in terms that would accordingly justify greater attention on the part of Competition Authorities, particularly in the wake of the recent international financial crisis - the acquisition of minority shareholdings, even if they apparently are of an utmost passive nature, may, in itself, trigger a movement towards the strengthening of this interdependence (with ability to influence, in a dual sense, the behaviors of both the participating and participated undertakings).49 Ultimately, however, all relevant factors of assessment herein referred to – which, desirably, should be gradually consolidated in a systematic and foreseeable way in the enforcement practice of the Commission and of EU Member States Competition Authorities - must be properly weighed in the specific market context concerned. I also acknowledge, in any case, that the assessment of these situations tends to be subject to a greater degree of unpredictability than the analysis of the impact of joint ventures on the competition process. 2.2.3. – Given this relative lack of consolidation of the analytical criteria oriented towards competition law assessment of effects of restriction of competition arising from minority shareholdings - although as I tentatively envisage supra a comprehensive analytical framework for the assessment of those effects must be gradually delineated - the option of systematically covering the acquisition of these shareholdings through its submission to the EU merger control procedure, as currently contemplated for purposes of reform of the MCR in the wake of the July 2014 White Paper proposals, is to a large extent debatable. Conversely, it must be acknowledged that the Commission has somehow retreated from more far reaching options in terms of possible submission of the acquisition of minority shareholdings which had been pondered in the 2013 public consultation on changes to merger control rules (while, at the same time, also putting aside a diverse option, pondered in 2013, that would not imply regulatory burdens and costs to undertakings, since it would be based on a “self-assessment system” in which no filing under the MCR would be required and the Commission would simply be free to open ex officio investigations about certain acquisitions of minority shareholdings). 49 See on that type of influence induced by shareholdings of an apparently passive nature, and providing several relevant examples, David Gilo “The anticompetitive effect of passive investment”, cit., 2 pp ff. 23 The retained normative option in the July 2014 White Paper proposals involves a variant of the so called “transparency system” that had been pondered in the 2013 public consultation (through which entities acquiring minority shareholdings would have to file a short information notice leading to a subsequent Commission decision on whether or not to investigate the acquisition at stake). It may be characterized as a ‘targeted’ or ‘selective’ form of the transparency system that would require parties to submit an information notice under the MCR, but restringing such mandatory requirement to cases of acquisitions giving rise to a “competitively significant link”. Relevant transactions would in turn be deemed to originate a “competitively significant link” under a combination of three criteria. These would comprehend a first parameter based on the competitive relationship between the acquiring entity and the target of the acquisition (this latter one being either a competitor or an entity active in a market upstream or downstream from that of the acquirer, while, as pondered in the preceding section, I tend to consider the first element, acquisition of competitors, as the decisive one in most cases for ascertaining the competition law relevance of minority shareholdings). The second and third criteria involve a combination of a fixed quantitative parameter and a quantitative reference parameter in interplay with general and rather indeterminate qualitative parameters. Accordingly, a “competitively significant link” would also be deemed to occur if, on the one hand, the acquired shareholding reaches 20 per cent, or, on the other hand, it is between 5 and 20 per cent but is accompanied by “additional factors” (which correspond to the qualitative element involved in this overall pondering), comprehending seats on the board of directors and, therefore, direct participation in management decisions, de facto blocking minorities or access to commercially sensitive information of the target entity. Under the terms of the Commission proposal, any undertaking wishing to acquire a minority stake originating a “competitively significant link” as defined supra, would have to submit a short “information notice” informing the Commission of the transaction. On the basis of this mandatory information, the Commission would decide whether further investigation of the transaction would be needed (while Member States could also ask for a referral to pursue the case themselves). In the wake of the submission of an information notice a standstill obligation would be established. The Commission has been considering for 24 that purpose a waiting period of 15 working days (aligned with the current deadline under article 9 of the MCR for a Member Stare referral request following a full notification). In case no investigation would be initiated by the Commission, nor Member States would request a referral within such waiting period, then the parties would be free to implement the transaction. Nevertheless, the Commission would still have room to investigate the case after the waiting period, and even if the transaction had in the meantime been implemented, within a 4 to 6 month period after the information notice, thus preventing undue procedural pressure to initiate investigations during the waiting period (and avoiding, as such, investigations whose objective necessity would not be confirmed ex post) and also allowing time for relevant complaints by relevant stakeholders. On the whole, it is therefore unquestionable that through the July 2014 White Paper proposals the Commission has endeavored to avoid an excessive expansion of procedural requirements and the corresponding administrative burdens of prior notification of acquisition of minority shareholdings. Nonetheless, the scope of potential systematic control may still be too wide and, above all, too much prone to legal uncertainty. The regulatory risks and corresponding drawbacks associated with that level of legal uncertainty have to do largely with the latitude of the qualitative criteria used to identify or circumscribe “competitively significant links”. As I have pondered in the previous section, there is a vast array of analytical criteria which may be used to identify and assess the chief risks for competition attached to certain minority shareholdings and a significant part of these criteria are not univocal and require taking into consideration different market contexts (in which the so called ‘additional factors’ identified by the Commission to ascertain competitive links potentially adverse for competition may be valued differently). Furthermore, the relative lack of consolidation of the relevant analytical criteria in this domain - highlighted in the previous section - also creates significant hurdles for an adequate delimitation of cases that are to be subject to ex ante communication and for a balanced competitive assessment of the whole range of diverse effects on competition that may arise from such cases, when communicated to the Commission and, as such, specifically assessed. A second related area where legal safety and predictability could be possibly affected corresponds to the content and latitude of the disclosure requirements involved in the production of the “short information notice” in the cases that supposedly would generate competitively significant links. Particularly sensitive would be the level and extent of the requirements 25 concerning “some limited market share information” that the parties would have to produce under the envisaged system. In fact, there seems to be an inherent and unavoidable contradiction in the idea of, on the one hand, providing information at a very limited and low-key level and of, on the other hand, conveying some sort of references about market share of the involved parties (as these references are not conceivable if sustainable and credible at all without some exercise of market definition with all the analytical hurdles it carries with it). Considerations of legal safety and predictability, that are of the essence of the business practices involved in these kinds of transactions, also raise concerns as far as the timeframe for opening an investigation is concerned. In fact, if the Commission would use the maximum period of 4 to 6 months to decide on opening an investigation after the submission of the information notice, the rather contradictory consequence arising from it would be that potentially a significant number of acquisitions of minority shareholdings would be subject to a much higher degree of uncertainty or unpredictability than many full mergers involving the acquisition of control (given the known enforcement practice that leads to the approval of a large number of those transactions in less than 6 months).50 Another contradictory consequence of even a highly restrained ‘targeted’ or ‘selective’ form of ‘transparency system’ for ex ante control of minority shareholdings – as the one contemplated in the July 2014 White Paper – would be to establish more demanding requirements for the systematic scrutiny of those transactions, which do not transfer control, than for the competition law scrutiny of non full function joint ventures (which, since they affect the structures and ties of control, are prone to have more impact on the structures of the undertakings involved). 50 It must be acknowledged that, on the whole, the high level of concerns related with legal uncertainty or unpredictability attached to the ‘targeted’ or ‘selective’ form of ‘transparency system’ for ex ante control of minority shareholdings contemplated in the 2014 White Paper Proposals that I am taking into consideration here has been viewed in a widely different manner in many comments of this prospective reform of the EU merger rules, See, e.g. for a more favourable view to the envisaged changes to the MCR oriented towards the extension of its scope of application to minority (non-controlling shareholdings) without other substantive major changes to the MCR, Catalin Stefan Rusu, “(Non-Controlling) Minority Shareholdings as Self-Standing Transactions under EU Merger Control Analysis – Prospective Solutions”, in World Competition, 37 (4), 2014, pp 485 ff; Alec Burnside, “Minority Sahreholdings: An Overview of EU and National Case Law”, in e-Competitions, N.º 56676. Conversely, see for more critical views, although voiced from many different angles and different emphasis, e.g., Porter Elliott, Johan Van Acker, “A Critical Review of the European Commission’s Proposal to Subject Acquisitions of NonControlling Minority Stakes to EU Merger Control”, in ECLR, 36, Issue 3, pp 97 ff; Kadir Bas, “Reforming the Treatment of Minority Shareholdings in the EU: Making the Problem Worse Instead of Better?”, in World Competition, 38 (1), 2015, pp 77 ff. 26 Such normative contradiction or distortion would be even greater in connection to some sub-categories of non full function joint ventures that have a more lasting impact in the degree of integration of parent undertakings and of their key business assets, as it happens, e.g., with many production joint ventures (and it has to be remembered that the option of submitting these sub-categories of joint ventures to the MCR has been pondered in the not too distant past, but never retained ‘de iure condito’ as an option for the reform of the MCR).51 On the whole, regardless of an ultimate option of either adopting a ‘targeted’ or ‘selective’ form of ‘transparency system’ applicable to minority shareholdings under a reformed MCR or retaining a system of competition law scrutiny of these cases essentially based on the article 101 TFEU regime under a more proactive enforcement of such regime to these situations, particularly in some economic sectors (as in the financial sector and especially if minority shareholdings appear combined with interlocking directorships in the various related undertakings) what seems to me fundamental is to consolidate some analytical guidance in this domain. For that purpose, I consider of paramount importance the adoption of a proper set of Guidelines by the Commission in this domain in order to start building a reference analytical framework around the lines discussed supra, in 2.2.1. and 2.2.2. (either supporting a more vigorous and target oriented enforcement of article 101.º TFEU in connection with minority shareholdings and building largely on analytical parameters relevant for joint venture analysis, or supporting a reformed MCR that would cover some cases of minority shareholdings). 2.3. – The Desirability of Flexible Solutions for Dealing with Minority Shareholdings 2.3.1. - As mentioned above, infra, 2.2.1., 2.2.2. and also the preceding sections, and likewise sustained in the context of the assessment of joint ventures, some of the potential issues of distortion of competition inherent to these types of situations of acquisition of minority shareholdings should 51 See on this Luís Silva Morais, Joint Ventures and EU Competition Law, cit., esp point 4.4. and ff, Chapter 1. 27 be handled with as much flexibility as possible and, for that purpose, could be satisfactorily addressed through commitments from the undertakings involved.52 Among other commitments addressed in decisions adopted under notification procedures ex vi article 101.º TFEU or within the MCR,53 one may consider, e.g., engagements to refrain from acquiring additional or supplementary shareholdings, to refrain from seeking representation on boards of directors of participated undertakings or even to prevent the flow of commercially sensitive information by limiting the scope of action and the information available to non-executive directors. Particularly noteworthy on this last type of situations were the arrangements accepted in the Commission’s “Olivetti/Digital” decision, dated 1994. One of the concerned undertakings was represented in the other undertaking’s Board of Directors; however, the executive powers material for the management of the undertaking had already been delegated in the Chairman of the Board of Directors. This decision strikes me as especially significant for it was already adopted under the MCR, with the Commission clearly acknowledging an interpretation of the “Philip Morris” case law allowing the application of article 101.º TFEU to situations of acquisition of shareholdings which would not involve crossing the thresholds concerning a transfer of control, relevant for the purposes of application of the MCR.54 Equally important is the precedent corresponding to the “Warner-Lambert/Gillette” decision. However, in this case, the issues of distortion of competition addressed by the Commission mainly focused upon the application of article 102.º TFEU (which are not the focus of the analysis in this paper).55 In some cases, characterized by a particular sensitivity of the flow of certain business information – maxime, it should be reiterated in the 52 It should be borne in mind that, in relation to joint ventures I sustain, precisely, that the Commission should adopt a more creative and flexible approach, in order to ponder certain commitments oriented towards avoiding issues of distortion of competition in the context of the application of par 1 of article 101.º TFEU and without further intervening through the granting of exemptions (in line with what happens in the enforcement practice of assessment of joint ventures by federal US competition authorities). Moreover, the new EC Regulation N.º 1/2003, in terms that have been highlighted above, strengthened the normative support for the adoption of regulatory decisions that accept and make duly binding such type of commitments. 53 I refer herein, to the decisions adopted in the context of notification procedures under then article 85 EEC and article 81 EC (whilst Regulation No. 17/62 was in force), or under the MCR, concerning situations in which, incidentally, the problems arising from shareholdings detained by firms involved in cooperation agreements or by companies participating in concentrations have been brought up for discussion. 54 See the Commission decision “Olivetti/Digital” decision, dated 1994 (IV/43.410; OJ N.º L 309/24, 1994). 55 See the “Warner-Lambert/Gillette” decision, OJ N.º L 116/21, 1993. 28 financial sector - such commitments may even involve the termination of situations of representation in the management bodies of third competitor undertakings. One may consider in this regard, inter alia, as paradigmatic cases – not by chance concerning the financial sector – the ones concerning the Commission decisions “Generali/INA”, dated 2000, and “Nordbanken/Postgirot”, dated 2001.56 3. – Concluding Remarks On the whole, given the nature and contours of the complex web of minority shareholdings that characterize these days the functioning of vital economic sectors – such as the financial sector, with the high degree of interdependence between its operators, or digital and electronic communications markets, relying on networks of innovation that may be supported in not too publicized minority shareholdings held in various innovative undertakings in niche areas – an effective competition law scrutiny of these situations is essential. Beside effectiveness of this antitrust scrutiny, a flexible approach should be privileged in this domain, regardless of the procedural framework ultimately chosen to deal with these situations (either a more proactive enforcement of article 101.º TFEU in this domain or a tailored reform of the MCR under the lines contemplated in the Commission July 2014 White Paper, possibly with an appreciable fine-tuning to enhance flexibility of such control). Furthermore, at the current crossroad a proper consolidation of the overall analytical framework in this domain, developing the parameters I put forward infra, 2.2.1., 2.2.2. and others – that will stimulate a more active stance on the part of affected third parties, thus contributing to reduce the substantive enforcement gap on minority shareholdings – will also depend significantly on the issuing of Guidelines by the Commission for the treatment of those situations (a much needed development in either scenario, of reform of the MCR or of a more active enforcement of article 101.º TFEU in this field). 56 I refer here to the aforementioned Commission decisions “Generali/INA”, dated 2000, and “Nordbanken/Postgirot”, dated 2001, on concentration cases, respectively, COMP/M. 1712 and M.2567. 29
© Copyright 2024