What Are Cities Worth? Land Rents, Local Productivity, and the Total Value of Amenities David Albouy University of Illinois and NBER April 16, 2015 I would like to thank David Agrawal, Bob Barsky, John Bound, Gabriel Ehrlich, Rob Gillezeau, Michael Greenstone, Andrew Hanson, Andrew Haughwout, Jim Hines, Fabian Lange, Anne Mandich, Peter Mieskowski, John Quigley, Jordan Rappaport, Stuart Rosenthal, Michael Rossi, Nathan Seegert, Bryan Stuart and the participants of seminars at the Federal Reserve Banks of Kansas City and New York, Aarhus, Essex, LSE, Rice, Texas A&M, UC Berkeley (Haas), UI-Chicago, Maryland, Michigan, Virginia, and Hebrew. Kevin A. Crosby and Bert Lue provided excellent and diligent research assistance. The Center for Local, State, and Urban Policy (CLOSUP) at the University of Michigan and the National Science Foundation (Grant SES-0922340) provided valuable support. Any mistakes are my own. Please e-mail any questions or comments to [email protected]. Abstract This article examines how to use widely available data on wages and housing costs to infer land rents, local productivity, and the total value of local amenities in the presence of federal taxes and locally-produced non-traded goods. I apply the model to U.S. metropolitan areas, with the aid of visually intuitive graphs, and infer large differences in land rents and improved measures of productivity. Wage and housing-cost differences across metros are accounted for more by productivity than quality-of-life differences. Regressions using individual amenities reveal that the most productive and valuable cities are typically coastal, sunny, mild, educated, and large. Keywords: Land rents, productivity, amenities, hedonic valuation, non-traded goods, federal taxation. JEL Codes: H2, H4, J3, Q5, R1 1 Introduction This article demonstrates both analytically and graphically how to use widely-available data on wages and housing costs to infer land rents and measure local productivity and the total value of local amenities. I use an inter-city framework, based on Rosen (1979) and Roback (1982), that features two enhancements: federal taxes, and a production sector for "home" goods, such as housing, which are not tradable across cities. Albouy (2009) demonstrates that federal taxes increase tax burdens in places where wage levels are high, creating local fiscal externalities. Roback briefly models home goods, but ignores local productivity empirically, and uses a simpler model, equating land with housing, to estimate quality-of-life differences. The distinction between land and housing is important as housing prices are often substituted for difficult-to-find land rents – see Mills (1998) and Case (2007) – despite being influenced by other costs such as labor.1 Accounting for home goods distinguishes the local productivity of firms producing traded goods from those producing housing or other non-traded goods, i.e., "trade-productivity" from "home-productivity." I demonstrate that without land-rent data, the two productivities cannot be identified separately, I apply the model to U.S. Census data and assume, as previous researchers did implicitly – e.g., Beeson and Eberts (1989), Gabriel and Rosenthal (2004), and Shapiro (2006) – that homeproductivity is constant across cities to estimate local land values. Relative to most previous estimates of trade-productivity, the enhanced model puts more weight on high housing costs and less weight on local wages. Combining the value of trade-productivity to that of quality of life, from Albouy (2008), I measure each city’s “total amenity value," which goes beyond previous measures by accounting for non-residential land, local labor costs, and federal-tax externalities. The application ranks cities by their trade-productivity and total amenity value, with San Francisco topping both lists. A variance decomposition suggests that trade-productivity explains wage and housing-cost differences across cities more than quality of life. The illustrative empirical analysis on individual amenities is the first to simultaneously present 1 This paper does not address temporal issues that would make land rents deviate from land values by more than an interest rate, and so the terms "rents" and "values" are used interchangeably. 1 the value of multiple amenities to both firms and households. A few amenities statistically predict most of the variation in trade-productivity and total amenity value. Simple cross-sectional hedonic methods produce estimates of the impact of population and education levels on productivity consistent with more sophisticated analyses. Measuring their value per acre, the most productive and valuable cities are not only large and educated, but also mild, sunny, and coastal.2 Albouy (2009) derives most of the theoretical results applied here, emphasizing how federal taxes distort local prices and location decisions. The analysis below actually estimates what amenities are related to tax payments. Albouy (2008) provides the complementary quality of life estimates. Building from this model, Albouy and Stuart (2013) predict population levels in U.S. cities, while Albouy and Ehrlich (2012) integrate a land-value index using recent market transactions data, and estimate a cost function for housing together with differences in housing productivity. 2 Prices and the Value of Amenities across U.S. Cities 2.1 An Inter-City Model of Prices and Amenities with Taxes and LocallyProduced Non-Traded Goods Consider a system of cities, indexed by j, which share a homogenous population of mobile households, N . Households consume a numeraire traded good, x, and a non-traded "home" good, y, with local price, pj , measured by the flow cost of housing services. Firms produce traded and home goods out of land, capital, and labor. Within a city, factors receive the same payment in either sector. Land, L, within each city is homogenous and immobile, and is paid a city-specific price rj . Capital, K, is supplied elastically at the price {. Households, are fully mobile and each supplies a single unit of labor earning wage wj . Each owns an identical, nationally-diversified, portfolios of land and capital, providing non-labor income, I; total income, mj 2 I + wj , varies only with Articles that consider the local productivity of firms with only the traded sector include Rauch (1993), Dekle and Eaton (1999), Haughwout (2002), Glaeser and Saiz (2004), and Chen and Rosenthal (2008). Rappaport (2008a, 2008b) is the only author that accounts for locally produced goods, although he restricts home-productivity and tradeproductivity to be equal. Tabuchi and Yoshida (2000) use actual data on land rents, although later conflate them with housing costs. 2 wages. Federal income tax payments of (mj ) are rebated lump-sum. Cities differ in three general "urban attributes:" (i) quality of life, Qj ; (ii) trade-productivity, AjX ; and (iii) home-productivity, j AjY . These attributes depend on a vector of individual urban amenities, Zj = (Z1j ; :::; ZK ). This model of spatial equilibrium uses duality theory to elegantly map the three prices (rj ; wj ; pj ) one-to-one with the three attributes (Qj ; AjX ; AjY ), by assuming that workers receive the same utility regardless of their location, while all firms make zero profit. The appendix derives the following first-order approximations of these conditions, describing how prices co-vary with city attributes in terms of log differences from the national average, using hat notation, x^j = dxj =x. The zero-profit condition for home-good producers implies that land-rent differences are r^j = 1 p^j ^ Nw j 1 ^j AY + L L and N are the cost shares of land and labor in home production. The formula infers land rents from housing costs; p^j , subtracting away labor costs 1= L. (1) L ^ Nw j , and scaling up the inverse cost share Using this value to infer land costs for traded-good firms, trade-productivity differences are inferred from the combined zero-profit condition A^jX = L and N L p^j + L N N L w^ j + L L L A^jY : (2) are the cost shares in traded production. I assume traded production is less land intensive than home production, i.e., L= N < L= N . ^ j = sy p^j Q The mobility condition for households sw (1 0 )w^ j (3) ^ j , valued as a fraction of income, is higher in areas that have states that quality-of-life differences, Q high prices relative to wages, after adjusting for the marginal tax rate 0 , where sy is the effective share of income spent on home goods, and sw , the share of income from labor. Combining the 3 value of amenities to households and firms, the total value of amenities is ^j ^ j + sx A^jx + sy A^j = sR p^j + Q Y 0 sw sR L where sR = sy L + (1 sy ) L N w^ j + L sR ^j d j AY = sR r^j + m L is the income share of land and d j =m = 0 (4) sw w^ j is the value of fiscal externalities from federal taxes. The total value measure reflects those externalities plus the value of local land. It accounts for non-residential land and adjusts for labor costs, although it, like land values and trade-productivity, is downward-biased in cities that have high home-productivity. Researchers applying this model empirically have all used a reduced version that equates land with housing, i.e., with N = 0 and L = 1, and ignoring differences in AY . In estimating quality of life, Roback (1982) uses land values in (3), ignoring other cost factors that affect home goods. Subsequent analyses, such as Blomquist et al. (1988), Beeson and Eberts (1989), and Gyourko and Tracy (1989, 1991), use housing costs in lieu of land rents. In estimating trade-productivity, such measures put too little weight on housing costs and too much weight on wages, double-counting labor costs in housing. Even with the proper adjustments, low home-productivity, A^jY ,may be confused for high trade-productivity, A^jX , when data on actual land values are unavailable. 2.2 Estimated Wage and Housing-Cost Differentials I estimate wage and housing-cost differentials, (w^ j ; p^j ) with the 5-percent sample of Census data from the 2000 Integrated Public Use Microdata Series (IPUMS) as in Albouy (2009). The 276 cities are defined by 1999 OMB definitions of Metropolitan Statistical Areas (MSAs); nonmetropolitan area of each state are averaged together. The wage differentials are populationdemeaned coefficients of indicator variables, one for each MSA, in a regression of the logarithm of hourly wages, controlling for worker characteristics. I use an analogous regression for housing costs, combining gross rents with imputed rents from owner-occupied units. Appendix C provides more details on the variables and estimation procedure. 4 2.3 Land-Value, Trade-Productivity, and Total-Value Measures To calculate the differentials of interest, I parameterize equations (1), (2), (3), and (4), according to values in Albouy (2009) — explained in Appendix B — adjusting slightly for housing deductions and state taxes.3 The parametrization produces the following formulae: Differential Full Model Reduced Model Land rent r^j = 4:29(^ pj + A^jY ) 2:75w^ j ; = p^j Trade-productivity A^jX = 0:11(^ pj + A^jY ) + 0:79w^ j ; = 0:025^ pj + 0:825w^ j ^ j = 0:32^ Quality of life Q pj 0:49w^ j ; = 0:073^ pj 0:75w^ j Total amenity value ^ j = 0:39(^ pj + A^jY ) + 0:01w^ j ; = 0:10^ pj Lacking land-rent data, I impose the restriction that unobserved home-productivity differences are zero, A^jY = 0. This creates biases proportional to the housing-cost coefficients, being large for land rents, small for trade-productivity, and moderate for total value. I characterize previous studies by the "Reduced Model," which imposes A^jY = 0, L = 1; N = 0; and 0 = 0.4 Figure 1 plots the wage and housing-cost differentials across metro areas, together with four lines, or "curves", describing the (w^ j ; p^j ) combinations where the left-hand sides of equation are zero, i.e., at their national averages. The iso-rent curve describes cities on (1) where r^ = 0, namely p^j = ^ Nw j . The slope N illustrates how home-good prices rise with labor costs. The vertical distance between this line and a city’s marker, scaled by 1= L, provides that city’s inferred land rent. Figure 2 plots the inferred land-rent differentials against housing costs. It draws a line for how these rents are inferred from housing costs if wages are held at the national average, w^ j = 0. The dashed line’s rotation around the origin from the diagonal illustrates the division of p^j by the Let F0 and S0 be the federal and state marginal tax rates, F and S be the deduction on home-good purchases, and w ^Sj and p^jS be the wage and housing-cost differentials within state. The tax differential is then 3 d j = sw ( m 0 ^j Fw + 0 j ^S ) Sw sy ( 0 j ^ F Fp + 0 j ^S ) S Sp (5) The numbers in the text are regression-based approximations. 4 The simplifications are closest to Beeson and Eberts (1989), although their parameterization imposes r^j = j ^ ^ j = 0:073^ p^ ; AX = 0:028^ pj + 0:927w ^j ; Q pj 0:73w ^ j ; ^ j = 0:064^ pj 5 cost-share of land, L. The vertical distance between the dashed-line and the markers indicates the adjustments for labor costs. The zero-profit condition in Figure 1 indicates cities with average trade-productivity, A^jX = 0; using condition (2) with A^jY = 0. The slope, N L N = L, gives the rate at which land costs, proxied through housing costs, need to fall with wage levels for firms to break even. Cities above this line have above-average costs, indicating high trade-productivity. The trade-productivity estimates are graphed in Figure 3 against those from the reduced model. The methodological refinement of putting more weight on housing costs is not enormous, but nonetheless changes the relative rankings of many cities, putting Los Angeles in front of Chicago, Boston in front of Detroit, and Denver in front of Las Vegas. ^j = 0 The mobility condition in Figure 1, indicates cities with average quality of life, i.e., Q in (3). The positive slope of (1 0 )sw =sy indicates how local costs increase with wage levels to keep real income levels from rising. Households in cities above this line pay a premium relative to the wage level, which implies that their quality of life is above average (Albouy 2008). The iso-value curve, (4) with ^ j = 0, traces out cities with average total amenity values. The line is quite flat, as properly scaled, housing costs indicate them well. The term for wages, 0 sw sR N = L, reflecting tax externalities net of labor-cost adjustments, is almost zero under the parameterization. Figure 4 graphs the quality-of-life and trade-productivity estimates, transforming Figure 1 through a change of coordinate systems. The average mobility condition provides the horizontal axis for trade-productivity, while the average zero-profit condition provides the vertical axis for quality of life. The axes are scaled so that equidistant attribute differences have equal value. 2.4 The Most Trade-Productive and Valuable Cities Table 1 lists the estimated differentials for select cities, along with averages by Census division and metro-area size. Table 2 presents the top 20 rankings for trade-productivity, quality of life, and total amenity value. Appendix Table A1 presents a complete list of metro areas and non-metro 6 areas; Appendix Table A2 lists values by state. The relationship between trade-productivity and metro population, usually attributed to agglomeration economies, is illustrated in Figure 5. The most trade-productive metro area is San Francisco, only the fifth largest — New York, the largest, is second — reflecting the exceptional knowledge spillovers and innovation around Silicon Valley (Saxenian 1994, Florida 2008). The top ten most productive cities include five other large metros – Los Angeles, Chicago, Boston, Washington, and Detroit – and three small metros – Monterrey, Santa Barbara, and Hartford, which are very close to much larger metros. The least productive metro, Great Falls, MT, is remote, as are the two least productive states, South and North Dakota. Combining quality of life and trade-productivity, the most valuable metropolis is San Francisco. It is followed by six other Pacific cities – Santa Barbara, Honolulu, Monterrey, San Diego, Los Angeles, and San Luis Obispo – that offer exceptional quality of life and fairly high productivity. Next are large, highly productive, and somewhat amenable metros – New York, Seattle, Boston, Denver, Chicago, and Portland – and resort-like, yet economically vibrant, metros like Cape Cod, Santa Fe, Naples, Reno, and Fort Collins. Further down the list are smaller cities in less crowded areas, such as in Arkansas, Oklahoma, West Virginia, Mississippi, and the Dakotas. The relationship between total amenity value and city size in Figure 6 reflects the strong relationship between size and productivity, and the weak relationship between size and quality of life (Albouy 2008). The estimates imply that the highest-value metro area (San Francisco) has land on average 100 times more valuable per acre than the lowest-value land in McAllen, TX. 2.5 Explaining the Variation of Prices across Cities The theory of spatial equilibrium asserts that price variation across cities reflects differences in quality of life and productivity. A variance decomposition of the total value of amenities yields: ^ j ) + s2 var(A^j ) + 2sx cov(Q ^ j ; A^j ): var( ^ j ) = var(Q x X X 7 The relative importance of each attribute is reflected by the two variance terms: if one attribute is made constant, then the covariance term collapses to zero, and only the variance of the other attribute remains. The model implies similar decomposition formulae for wages, housing costs, and land rents. These statistical decompositions provide an interesting accounting of equilibrium relationships, but must be treated cautiously as attributes may be endogenous. For example, high quality of life may raise population, leading to endogenous trade-productivity gains from agglomeration. Table 4 displays the decompositions for all prices. Overall, trade-productivity accounts for a greater fraction of amenity value than quality of life, which can be seen in Figure 4. Quality of life has a greater influence on land rents by a slight margin. Variations in nominal wages – as well as federal-tax burdens – are driven mostly by trade-productivity, contradicting Roback’s (1982) claim that nominal wages vary more due to quality of life. Housing-cost variation is also driven mainly by trade-productivity. 3 Individual Predictors of Amenity Value Researchers commonly use the spatial equilibrium model to estimate the value of individual amenij ties (Z1j ; ::; ZK ) through regression methods. I illustrate the potential impact of amenities on the measures derived above using seven, mutually-consistent, linear regressions: vj = X Zkj kv + "jv ; k ^ A^X ; r^; d =m; ^ g. The amenity coefficients, where v 2 fw; ^ p^; Q; kv ; express the effect of a one- unit increase in an amenity, and share the same interrelationships as their corresponding regressors, v. Cross-sectional regressions of this kind are subject to well-known empirical caveats (see Gyourko et al. 1999), including omitted variables, simultaneity, and multi-collinearity. Estimates should not be interpreted causally. The regressors, listed in Table 4 and detailed in Appendix C, include both "natural" ameni8 ties, relating to climate and geography, and "artificial" ones, relating to local inhabitants, including metropolitan population and the share of the adults with college degrees. These are not true amenities, but likely determine amenities that are key to local trade-productivity, engendering agglomeration economies. The Wharton Residential Land-Use Regulatory Index (WRLURI) of Gyourko et al. (2008) controls for unobserved housing-productivity differences. The coefficients are grouped, ^ with effects on observed data w^ and p^ in columns 1 and 2; amenities to households and firms, Q and A^X , in columns 3 and 4; the combined value, ^ , in column 5; and their split between land values and federal tax revenues, sR r^ and d =m, in columns 6 and 7. The relationships between the natural amenities and trade-productivity, new to the literature, reveal interesting patterns. Sunshine, coastal proximity, low levels of cold (minus heating degree days) and low levels of heat (minus cooling degree days) appear to be amenities to firms, as well as to households. The small but significant positive effect of latitude on productivity evokes findings in Hall and Jones (1999) that social capital is higher in northern areas. The positive estimate for coastal proximity may reflect savings in transportation costs; the climate effects are more surprising, but could have a physiological basis. Long ago, Montesquieu (1748) hypothesized that extreme temperatures inhibit the ability of humans to work. Recent studies find that both indoor and outdoor workers are less productive in warm temperatures (Engineering News Record 2008). As most modern workplaces are indoors with air conditioning, these estimates need further study. The elasticity of wages with respect to population is estimated to be 3.8 percent, well inside the range surveyed by Rosenthal and Strange (2004) and Melo et al. (2009), despite concerns of endogenous migration. The elasticity of housing-costs to population is 5.6 percent, so that the elasticity for trade-productivity is 3.6 percent. Doubling a city’s population (an increase of 0.69 log points) increases the total value of its amenities by 1.5 percent of income, of which three-fifths is captured in local land values, the rest in federal taxes. The estimates in the second row associate a ten-percentage point increase in college-educated adults (1.3 standard deviations) with 7-percentage point increases in wages and productivity, and a 1.8 percentage point increase in quality of life. While these estimates may reflect selective mi- 9 gration, they resemble those of Moretti (2004) and Shapiro (2006), who use instrumental variable methods. In total, a ten-percent increase in college share is associated with a 7-percent increase in the total value of amenities, of which federal taxes expropriate one-fifth. The coefficients of determination (R2 ) reveal that this parsimonious set of amenities explains 88 percent of trade-productivity, and over 90 percent of land rents and total amenity value. Population, education, sunshine, coastal proximity, average slope and mild temperatures are all strongly associated with total amenity value. The results also imply that households are taxed for living in cities that are large, flat, cool, coastal, and educated. Estimates based on the full and reduced models produce different results both in magnitude and significance. Land rents effects diverge considerably from those for housing costs in the six cases where the federal tax differential matters. Reduced-model estimates of trade-productivity, based almost entirely on wages, would find hilliness (average slope) increases firm costs, but would not find excess heat to do so. Most researchers would also likely ignore impacts on non-residential land, which the total-value estimates include. 4 Conclusion The above analysis highlights the importance of considering taxes and housing, separately from land, when determining the value of local productivity and amenities in general. Wage and housingcost data appear to be largely adequate for inferring local levels of productivity in tradables, and the resulting measures appear sensible. Statistically, local labor demand factors (productivity) are more important in determining local wages and housing costs than supply factors (quality of life). Furthermore, a limited number of variables explain over seven-eighths of the variation in wages, trade-productivity and total amenity value. Extensions of this model could do more with internal structure, population heterogeneity, and dynamics. Nevertheless, a clean and intuitive framework for understanding cross-sectional variation of widely available data sources is informative and an important stepping stone to future work. 10 References Albouy, David (2008) "Are Big Cities Bad Places to Live? Estimating Quality of Life across Metropolitan Areas." NBER Working Paper No. 14472. Cambridge, MA. Albouy, David (2009) "The Unequal Geographic Burden of Federal Taxation." Journal of Political Economy, 117, pp. 635-667. Albouy, David and Gabriel Ehrlich (2012) "Metropolitan Land Values and Housing Productivity" NBER Working Paper No. 18110. Cambridge, MA. Albouy, David and Bryan Stuart (2013) "Urban Population and Amenities." mimeo, University of Illinois. Beeson, Patricia E. and Randall W. Eberts (1989) "Identifying Productivity and Amenity Effects in Interurban Wage Differentials." The Review of Economics and Statistics, 71, pp. 443-452. Blomquist, Glenn C., Mark C. Berger, and John P. Hoehn (1988) "New Estimates of Quality of Life in Urban Areas." American Economic Review, 78, pp. 89-107. Boskin, Michael J., Laurence J. Kotlikoff, Douglas J. Puffert, and John B. Shoven (1987) "Social Security: A Financial Appraisal Across and Within Generations." National Tax Journal, 40, pp. 19-34. Carliner, Michael (2003) "New Home Cost Components." Housing Economics, 51, pp. 7-11. Case, Karl E. (2007) "The Value of Land in the United States: 1975–2005." in Ingram, Gregory K., Hong, Yu-Hung (Eds.), Proceedings of the 2006 Land Policy Conference: Land Policies and Their Outcomes. Cambridge, MA: Lincoln Institute of Land Policy Press. Chen, Yu and Stuart Rosenthal (2008) "Local Amenities and Life-Cycle Migration: Do People Move for Jobs or Fun?" Journal of Urban Economics, 64, pp. 519–537. 11 Davis, Morris and Michael Palumbo (2007) "The Price of Residential Land in Large U.S. Cities." Journal of Urban Economics, 63, pp. 352-384. Dekle, Robert and Jonathan Eaton (1999) "Agglomeration and Land Rents: Evidence from the Prefectures." Journal of Urban Economics, 46, pp. 200-214. Engineering News Record (2008) "Hot or Cold, Weather Plays a Big Role in Job Productivity." August 11, p. 56. Florida, Richard (2008) Who’s Your City? How the Creative Economy Is Making Where You Live the Most Important Decision of Your Life. New York, NY: Basic Books. Gabriel, Stuart A. and Stuart S. Rosenthal (2004) "Quality of the Business Environment versus Quality of Life: Do Firms and Households Like the Same Cities?" The Review of Economics and Statistics, 86, pp.548-444. Glaeser, Edward L. and Albert Saiz (2004) "The Rise of the Skilled City." Brookings-Wharton Papers on Urban Affairs. Gyourko, Joseph, Albert Saiz, and Anita Summers (2008) “New Measure of the Local Regulatory Environment for Housing Markets: The Wharton Residential Land Use Regulatory Index." Urban Studies, 45, pp. 693-729. Gyourko, Joseph and Joseph Tracy (1989) "The Importance of Local Fiscal Conditions in Analyzing Local Labor Markets." Journal of Political Economy, 97, pp. 1208-31. Gyourko, Joseph and Joseph Tracy (1991) "The Structure of Local Public Finance and the Quality of Life." Journal of Political Economy, 99, pp. 774-806. Gyourko, Joseph, Matthew Kahn and Joseph Tracy (1999) "Quality of Life and Environmental Comparisons." in E. Mills and P. Cheshire, eds. Handbook of Regional and Urban Economics, Vol 3. Amsterdam: North Holland. 12 Haughwout, Andrew (2002) "Public Infrastructure Investments, Productivity and Welfare in Fixed Geographic Areas." Journal of Public Economics, 83, pp. 405-428. Hall, Robert and Charles Jones (1999) "Why Do Some Countries Produce So Much More Output per Worker than Others?" Quarterly Journal of Economics 114(1), pp. 83-116. Keiper, Joseph S., Ernest Kurnow, Clifford D. Clark, and Harvey H. Segal (1961) Theory and Measurement of Rent. Philadelphia: Chilton & Co. Krueger, Alan B. (1999) "Measuring Labor’s Share." American Economic Review, 89, pp. 45-51. McDonald, J.F. (1981) "Capital-Land Substitution in Urban Housing: A Survey of Empirical Estimates." Journal of Urban Economics, 9, pp. 190-211. Melo, Patricia C., Daniel J. Graham, and Robert B. Noland (2009) "A Meta-Analysis of Estimates of Urban Agglomeration Economies," Regional Science and Urban Economics, 39, pp.332-342. Mills, Edwin S. (1998) "The Economic Consequences of a Land Tax." in Dick Netzer (Ed.) Land Value Taxation: Can It and Will It Work Today. Cambridge, MA: Lincoln Institute of Land Policy Press. Montesquieu, Baron de (1748) De l’esprit des lois. Published anonymously. Moretti, Enrico (2004) "Workers’ Education, Spillovers and Productivity: Evidence from PlantLevel Production Functions" American Economic Review. 94(3), 2004, pp. 656-690. Moretti, Enrico (2013) "Real Wage Inequality." American Economic Journal: Applied Economics 5(1), pp. 65-103. Peiser, Richard B. and Lawrence B. Smith (1985) "Homeownership Returns, Tenure Choice and Inflation." American Real Estate and Urban Economics Journal, 13, pp. 343-60. 13 Poterba, James M. (1998) "The Rate of Return to Corporate Capital and Factor Shares: New Estimates using Revised National Income Accounts and Capital Stock Data." Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 48, pp. 211-246. Rappaport, Jordan (2008a) "A Productivity Model of City Crowdedness." Journal of Urban Economics, 65, pp. 715-722. Rappaport, Jordan (2008b) "Consumption Amenities and City Population Density." Regional Science and Urban Economics, 38, pp. 533-552. Rauch, James (1993) "Productivity Gains from Geographic Concentration of Human Capital." Journal of Urban Economics, 34, pp. 380-400. Roback, Jennifer (1982) "Wages, Rents, and the Quality of Life." Journal of Political Economy, 90, pp. 1257-1278. Rosen, Sherwin (1979) "Wages-based Indexes of Urban Quality of Life," in P. Mieszkowski and M. Straszheim, eds. Current Issues in Urban Economics, Baltimore: John Hopkins Univ. Press. Rosenthal, Stuart S. and William C. Strange (2004) "Evidence on the Nature and Sources of Agglomeration Economies." in J.V. Henderson and J-F. Thisse, eds. Handbook of Regional and Urban Economics, Vol. 4, Amsterdam: North Holland, pp. 2119-2171. Ruggles, Steven, Matthew Sobek, Trent Alexander, Catherine A. Fitch, Ronald Goeken, Patricia Kelly Hall, Miriam King, and Chad Ronnander (2004) Integrated Public Use Microdata Series: Version 3.0. Minneapolis: Minnesota Population Center. Saxenian, Annalee (1994) Regional Advantage: Culture and Competition in Silicon Valley and Route 128. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Shapiro, Jesse M. (2006) "Smart Cities: Quality of Life, Productivity, and the Growth Effects of Human Capital." The Review of Economics and Statistics, 88, pp. 324-335. 14 Tabuchi, Takatoshi and Atsushi Yoshida (2000) "Separating Urban Agglomeration Economies in Consumption and Production." Journal of Urban Economics, 48, pp. 70-84. Thorsnes, Paul (1997) "Consistent Estimates of the Elasticity of Substitution between Land and Non-Land Inputs in the Production of Housing." Journal of Urban Economics, 42, pp. 98-108. Valentinyi, Ákos and Berthold Herrendorf (2008) "Measuring Factor Income Shares at the Sectoral Level." Review of Economic Dynamics, 11, pp. 820-835. 15 TABLE 1: WAGE, HOUSING COST, LAND RENT, QUALITY-OF-LIFE, PRODUCTIVITY, FEDERAL TAX, AND TOTAL AMENITY VALUE DIFFERENTIALS, 2000 Adjusted Differentials Amenity Values Total Quality of Life Federal Tax Differential Amenity Value 0.29 0.13 0.06 0.14 0.10 0.15 0.21 0.10 0.13 0.07 0.13 0.04 0.12 0.02 0.03 0.11 0.10 0.07 0.06 0.01 0.05 -0.05 -0.01 0.05 -0.05 -0.10 -0.14 -0.23 0.14 0.18 0.20 0.14 0.12 0.08 0.03 0.06 0.03 0.05 0.01 0.05 -0.01 0.04 0.01 -0.05 -0.04 -0.03 -0.03 -0.02 -0.04 0.00 -0.03 -0.07 -0.05 -0.04 -0.02 -0.08 0.05 -0.01 -0.02 0.01 0.00 0.02 0.04 0.01 0.02 0.01 0.03 0.00 0.03 0.00 0.01 0.04 0.03 0.03 0.02 0.01 0.02 -0.01 0.01 0.03 -0.01 -0.02 -0.02 -0.04 0.32 0.26 0.24 0.23 0.19 0.18 0.16 0.12 0.12 0.10 0.09 0.07 0.06 0.05 0.03 0.02 0.02 0.01 0.01 -0.01 -0.01 -0.03 -0.04 -0.04 -0.08 -0.10 -0.11 -0.23 1.42 0.61 0.28 0.16 -0.33 -0.25 -0.83 -0.80 -1.02 0.12 0.07 0.09 -0.04 0.00 -0.04 -0.09 -0.11 -0.13 0.08 0.03 -0.01 0.03 -0.03 -0.01 -0.04 -0.03 -0.04 0.01 0.01 0.02 -0.02 0.01 -0.01 -0.01 -0.02 -0.02 0.16 0.07 0.05 0.00 -0.03 -0.03 -0.10 -0.10 -0.12 0.96 0.08 -0.29 -0.52 -0.91 0.16 0.02 -0.04 -0.10 -0.16 0.03 0.00 -0.01 -0.01 -0.02 0.03 0.01 -0.01 -0.02 -0.04 0.13 0.02 -0.04 -0.07 -0.13 Population Size Wages Housing Costs 7,039,362 399,347 876,156 401,762 2,813,833 16,373,645 21,199,865 3,554,760 5,819,100 2,581,506 9,157,540 2,265,223 7,608,070 3,876,380 3,251,876 5,456,428 6,188,463 2,968,806 4,112,198 2,945,831 5,221,801 2,395,997 2,603,607 4,669,571 2,358,695 1,592,383 1,083,346 569,463 0.26 0.07 -0.01 0.10 0.06 0.13 0.21 0.08 0.12 0.05 0.14 0.02 0.13 0.00 0.03 0.13 0.11 0.08 0.08 0.01 0.06 -0.06 0.01 0.07 -0.04 -0.09 -0.13 -0.21 0.81 0.66 0.61 0.59 0.48 0.45 0.41 0.31 0.29 0.24 0.22 0.17 0.15 0.13 0.08 0.05 0.05 0.02 0.01 -0.03 -0.04 -0.08 -0.10 -0.11 -0.21 -0.25 -0.28 -0.57 2.78 2.65 2.62 2.24 1.89 1.57 1.18 1.10 0.93 0.89 0.59 0.68 0.31 0.54 0.24 -0.13 -0.09 -0.14 -0.15 -0.17 -0.34 -0.20 -0.46 -0.68 -0.77 -0.85 -0.83 -1.86 Pacific New England Middle Atlantic Mountain East North Central South Atlantic West South Central West North Central East South Central 45,025,637 13,922,517 39,671,861 18,172,295 45,155,037 51,769,160 31,444,850 19,237,739 17,022,810 0.10 0.07 0.09 -0.06 0.02 -0.04 -0.08 -0.11 -0.12 0.39 0.19 0.13 0.00 -0.07 -0.08 -0.24 -0.25 -0.32 MSA Population MSA, Pop > 5 Million MSA, Pop 1.5-4.9 Million MSA, Pop 0.5-1.4 Million MSA, Pop < 0.5 Million Non-MSA areas 84,064,274 57,157,386 42,435,508 42,324,511 55,440,227 0.16 0.03 -0.03 -0.10 -0.16 0.32 0.04 -0.09 -0.19 -0.32 Main city in MSA/CMSA San Francisco Santa Barbara Honolulu Monterey San Diego Los Angeles New York Seattle Boston Denver Chicago Portland Washington-Baltimore Miami Phoenix Detroit Philadelphia Minneapolis Atlanta Cleveland Dallas Tampa St. Louis Houston Pittsburgh San Antonio Oklahoma City McAllen CA CA HI CA CA CA NY WA MA CO IL OR DC FL AZ MI PA MN GA OH TX FL MO TX PA TX OK TX Inferred Land TradeRent Productivity Census Division United States 281,421,906 0.13 0.30 1.00 0.13 0.05 0.03 0.12 total standard deviations Wage and housing price data are taken from the U.S. Census 2000 IPUMS. Wage differentials are based on the average logarithm of hourly wages for fulltime workers ages 25 to 55. Housing-cost differentials are based on the average logarithm of rents and housing prices. Adjusted differentials are the cityfixed effects from individual level regressions on extended sets of worker and housing covariates. See Appendix C.1. for more details. The inferred landrent, quality-of-life, trade-productivity, and total-amenity variables are estimated from the equations in section 2.3, using the calibration in Table A1, with additional adjustments for housing deductions and state taxes, described in footnote 3. TABLE 2: CENSUS METROPOLITAN AREA RANKINGS, 2000 Trade-Productivity Ranking Quality-of-Life Ranking Total Value Ranking 1 San Francisco Honolulu San Francisco 2 New York Santa Barbara Santa Barbara 3 Los Angeles San Francisco Honolulu 4 Monterey Monterey Monterey 5 Chicago Santa Fe San Diego 6 Boston San Luis Obispo Los Angeles 7 Santa Barbara San Diego San Luis Obispo 8 Hartford Cape Cod New York 9 Washington-Baltimore Grand Junction Cape Cod 10 Detroit Missoula Seattle 11 San Diego Naples Boston 12 Philadelphia Medford Santa Fe 13 Seattle Eugene Naples 14 Stockton Los Angeles Denver 15 Anchorage Corvalis Chicago 16 San Luis Obispo Fort Collins Sacramento 17 Sacramento Bellingham Reno 18 Minneapolis Wilmington Anchorage 19 Denver Sarasota Portland 20 Atlanta Burlington Washington-Baltimore Rankings based off of data in Appendix Table A1, which contains the full MSA/CMSA names. The quality-of-life ranking is originally from Albouy (2009) TABLE 3: VARIANCE DECOMPOSTION OF QUALITY-OF-LIFE AND TRADE-PRODUCTIVITY EFFECTS ON PRICE DIFFERENTIALS ACROSS CITIES Variance Decomposition Fraction of variance explained by Variance Quality of Life Productivity Covariance (1) (2) (3) (4) Land Rents Wages Housing Costs Tax Differential Total Value 1.002 0.019 0.093 0.001 0.015 0.370 0.018 0.184 0.113 0.181 0.287 1.132 0.498 1.276 0.503 0.342 -0.150 0.318 -0.398 0.317 Variances are calculated across 276 metro areas and 49 non-metro areas by state, weighted by population. Based on the full model described in the text with federal taxes. TABLE 4: THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN INDIVIDUAL AMENITIES AND HOUSING COSTS, WAGES, QUALITY OF LIFE, PRODUCTIVITY, LAND RENTS, FEDERAL TAXES, AND TOTAL AMENITY VALUES Standard Mean Deviation Observables Housing Cost Wage (1) (2) Amenity Type Quality Trade of Life Productivity (3) (4) Total Amenity Value (5) Capitalization Into Local Federal Land Rents Tax Payment (6) (7) Logarithm of Metro Population 14.63 1.32 0.056*** (0.007) 0.038*** (0.004) -0.001 (0.002) 0.036*** (0.004) 0.022*** (0.003) 0.013*** (0.002) 0.009*** (0.001) Percent of Population College Graduates 0.26 0.07 1.718*** (0.169) 0.714*** (0.069) 0.213*** (0.042) 0.748*** (0.067) 0.692*** (0.067) 0.540*** (0.062) 0.152*** (0.017) Whartron Residential Land-Use Regulatory Index (WRLURI) 0.05 0.93 0.008 (0.012) 0.004 (0.007) 0.001 (0.004) 0.004 (0.006) 0.003 (0.005) 0.002 (0.005) 0.001 (0.002) Minus Heating-Degree Days (1000s) -4.38 2.15 0.039*** (0.010) 0.014** (0.006) 0.006 (0.004) 0.015*** (0.005) 0.016*** (0.004) 0.013*** (0.004) 0.003* (0.002) Minus Cooling-Degree Days (1000s) -1.28 0.89 0.105*** (0.018) 0.017 (0.012) 0.025*** (0.007) 0.025** (0.010) 0.041*** (0.007) 0.040*** (0.007) 0.001 (0.003) Sunshine (percent possible) 0.60 0.08 1.248*** (0.129) 0.290*** (0.089) 0.260*** (0.044) 0.363*** (0.078) 0.493*** (0.052) 0.455*** (0.048) 0.038 (0.023) Inverse Distance to Coast (Ocean or Great Lake) 0.04 0.04 0.078*** (0.008) 0.024*** (0.005) 0.013*** (0.002) 0.027*** (0.004) 0.030*** (0.003) 0.027*** (0.003) 0.003*** (0.001) Average Slope of Land (percent) 1.68 1.59 0.023*** (0.005) -0.006* (0.003) 0.010*** (0.002) -0.002 (0.003) 0.009*** (0.002) 0.011*** (0.002) -0.003*** (0.001) Latitude (degrees) 37.76 4.86 0.009** (0.004) 0.008** (0.003) -0.001 (0.002) 0.007*** (0.003) 0.004** (0.002) 0.002 (0.002) 0.002** (0.001) -1.771 (0.168) -1.020 (0.149) -0.078 (0.061) -0.996 (0.129) -0.716 (0.067) -0.478 (0.058) -0.237 (0.038) 0.92 0.84 0.75 0.88 0.92 0.91 0.77 Constant Coefficient of Determination (R 2 ) 282 observations with complete data. Robust standard errors shown in parentheses. * p<0.1, ** p<0.05, *** p<0.01. Regressions weighted by metro population. Amenity variables are described in Section 3 and Appendix C.2. The coefficients on local land rents are multiplied by the factor s R = 0.10 to be compatible with total amenity value. Figure 1: Housing Costs versus Wage Levels across Metro Areas, 2000 0.7 0.8 San Francisco 0.6 Santa Barbara 0.5 Honolulu New York Cape Cod HI 0.3 0.2 0.1 0.0 -0.2 -0.1 Log Housing-Cost Differential 0.4 San Diego San Luis Obispo Los Angeles Santa Fe Naples Seattle Boston Denver Chicago Reno Sacramento Portland Washington-Baltimore CO Fort Collins Hartford Miami Sarasota AK Medford Grand Junction Phoenix Austin Detroit Philadelphia Las Vegas Wilmington Atlanta Albuquerque Springfield Minneapolis Tucson Fort Myers OR Nashville NV Orlando Columbus Dallas Cincinnati Norfolk Tampa VT Missoula NewPierce Orleans St. Louis Punta Gorda Fort Houston Fort WaltonMyrtle Beach Beach Flagstaff Bakersfield Bloomington AZ UTYuma -0.3 MT Killeen Jacksonville -0.4 Pittsburgh FL Falls San AntonioSyracuse Sioux Oklahoma City Ocala Kokomo Decatur Beaumont El Paso Great Falls Joplin SD -0.5 Monterey Gadsden Steubenville KY AL OK MS ND McAllen -0.2 -0.1 0.0 Log Wage Differential 0.1 0.2 METRO POP >5.0 Million Avg Iso-Rent Curve: slope = 0.64 1.5-5.0 Million 0.5-1.5 Million Avg Zero-Profit Cond: slope = -7.37 <0.5 Million Non-Metro Areas Avg Mobility Cond: slope = 1.53 Avg Iso-Value Curve: slope = -0.02 3.0 Figure 2: Housing Costs and Inferred Land Rents 2.5 San Francisco Santa Barbara Honolulu 2.0 1.5 0.0 0.5 1.0 New York Seattle Boston Reno Sacramento Sarasota Chicago Miami Washington-Baltimore Tucson Hartford -0.5 Jacksonville -1.5 Orlando Philadelphia Detroit Minneapolis Columbus Dallas St. Louis Great Falls Bloomington San Antonio -1.0 Inferred Land-Rent Differential (r) Monterey Diego San LuisSan Obispo Cape Cod LosHIAngeles Joplin El Paso SD OK ND -2.0 McAllen -0.5 0.0 0.5 Observed Housing-Cost Differential (p) Inferred Rent with Avg Wage: slope = 4.29 Diagonal L os Angele s Monte re y Santa Ba rbara Chi ca go Boston Hartford W a shi ngton-Ba lti more 0.10 Det roi t San Diego Sea ttl e Phil adel phia San L uis Obi spoSac ram e nt o Denve r Minne apol is Atla nt a L as Vegas 0.05 Honol ulu Cape Cod Naple s 0.00 Trade-Productivity (Ax) from Full Model 0.15 Figure 3: Trade-P roductivity Estimates Compared Reno Port la nd AK Phoenix Dal las Houston Kokom o Bakersfi Cincinna ti eld MiaAustin mCol i um bus NV ingt on Bloom St. Loui s 0.00 0.05 0.10 Productivity from Reduced Model ME TRO SIZE >5.0 Mil lion 1.5-5. 0 Mi lli on 0.5-1. 5 Mi lli on <0.5 Mil lion Non-Met ro Area s Dia gona l 0.20 Figure 4: Estimated Trade-Productivity and Quality of Life, 2000 Honolulu 0.15 Santa Barbara Monterey HI SantaSan FeCape LuisCod Obispo San Diego San Francisco 0.10 0.05 0.00 -0.10 -0.05 Relative Quality of Life (Q) Grand Junction CO Missoula Naples Medford Los Angeles Fort Collins VT WilmingtonSarasota Fort Walton OR Seattle MT Beach Denver Reno Tucson Jacksonville Punta Gorda Albuquerque Fort Myers Portland Miami Myrtle Beach AZ Great Falls Killeen Sacramento Boston New York Flagstaff Norfolk Austin Phoenix AK Fort Pierce FL New UT Orleans Orlando Chicago Springfield YumaTampa SD Nashville Sioux Falls Ocala NV Joplin Washington-Baltimore Oklahoma City Las Vegas Hartford Minneapolis Atlanta St.Columbus Louis OK Cincinnati San Antonio Philadelphia ND El Paso Dallas Detroit Pittsburgh KY Steubenville Bloomington Bakersfield MS AL Gadsden Syracuse Houston McAllen Decatur Beaumont -0.234 -0.156 Kokomo 0.078 -0.078 0.000 Relative Trade-Productivity (Ax) 0.156 0.234 METRO POP >5.0 Million Iso-Wage Curve: slope = 3.04 1.5-5.0 Million 0.5-1.5 Million Iso-Housing-Cost Curve: slope = -0.63 <0.5 Million Non-Metro Areas Iso-Land-Rent Curve: slope = -0.34 Iso-Value Curve: slope = -0.64 0.3 Figure 5: Trade-Productivity and Population Size San Francisco Los Angeles Monterey Santa Barbara 0.1 0.0 Kokomo Naples Bakersfield Springfield Fort Collins -0.1 Decatur Sacramento Minneapolis Denver Atlanta Las Vegas Dallas Portland Phoenix Houston Cincinnati Miami Austin Columbus St. Louis Nashville Orlando Pittsburgh Tampa New Orleans Honolulu Reno Bloomington Santa Fe Sarasota Syracuse Beaumont Albuquerque Fort Pierce Fort Myers Tucson Medford Yuma Wilmington Flagstaff Grand Junction Punta Gorda Sioux Falls Myrtle Beach Gadsden Ocala Fort Walton Beach Steubenville Missoula Killeen Chicago Boston Washington-Baltimore Detroit San DiegoSeattle Philadelphia Hartford San Luis Obispo Cape Cod -0.2 Relative Trade-Productivity (Ax) 0.2 New York Norfolk San Antonio Oklahoma City El Paso McAllen Joplin Jacksonville Great Falls 125000 500000 250000 1000000 2000000 MSA/CMSA Population 4000000 Log-Linear Fit: Slope = = .0683 (.0039) 8000000 16000000 Quadratic Fit Figure 6: Total Value of Amenities and Population Size 0.3 San Francisco Santa Barbara Honolulu 0.2 Monterey San Diego 0.1 Santa Fe Seattle Naples 0.0 Boston Chicago Sacramento Portland Reno -0.1 Los Angeles New York Denver Washington-Baltimore Miami Sarasota Phoenix Grand Junction Medford Austin Detroit Philadelphia Las Vegas Minneapolis Atlanta Albuquerque Wilmington Springfield Fort Myers Tucson Nashville Dallas Orlando Columbus Cincinnati Tampa Missoula Norfolk New Orleans St. Louis Fort Pierce Houston Punta Gorda Fort Walton Beach Bakersfield Flagstaff Myrtle Beach Bloomington Yuma Pittsburgh Kokomo Sioux Falls San Antonio Killeen Syracuse Oklahoma City Jacksonville Ocala Decatur Great Falls El Paso Beaumont Gadsden Joplin Steubenville Fort Collins -0.2 Total Amenity Value San Luis Obispo Cape Cod Hartford McAllen 125000 250000 500000 1000000 2000000 MSA/CMSA Population Log-Linear Fit: Slope = = .056 (.005) 4000000 Quadratic Fit 8000000 16000000 Appendix A Derivation of Theoretical Results The utility function U (x; y; Qj ) ; representing household preferences, is quasi-concave over x and y, and increases in quality of life, Qj . The dual expenditure function for a household, e(pj ; u; Qj ) minx;y fx + pj y : U (x; y; Qj ) ug , measures the cost of consumption needed to attain utility u, increases in pj , and decreases in Qj . Because households are fully mobile, all inhabited cities offer the same utility, u.5 Thus, firms in cities with high prices or low quality of life compensate their workers with greater after-tax income: e(pj ; u; Qj ) = wj + R + I (wj + R + I): (A.1) Operating under perfect competition, firms produce traded and home goods according to the functions X = AjX FX (LX ; NX ; KX ) and Y = AjY FY (LY ; NY ; KY ), where FX and FY are concave and exhibit constant returns to scale, so that any returns to scale are embedded within the factor-neutral productivities, AjX and AjY :The unit cost of producing a traded good is cX (rj ; wj ; {; AjX ) = cX (rj ; wj ; {)=AjX where c(r; w; i) c(r; w; i; 1) and c(rj ; wj ; {; Aj ) minL;N;K frj L+wj N +{K : Aj F (L; N; K) = 1g A symmetric definition holds for the unit cost of a home good, cY . Firms make zero profits in equilibrium. Therefore, for given output prices, more productive cities pay higher rents and wages, equal to the marginal revenue products of land and labor. In equilibrium, the following zero-profit conditions hold: cX (rj ; wj ; {)=AjX = 1 j cY (r ; w j ; {)=AjY (A.2) j =p : (A.3) For empirical application, I log-linearize conditions (A.1), (A.2), and (A.3). These conditions relate each city’s price differentials to its attribute differentials. The differentials are in logarithms: for any z, z^j = d ln z j = dz j =z = (z j z) =z approximates the percent difference in city j ^j of z; relative to the national geometric average z. The one exception to this notation is Q j j (@e=@Q) (1=m)dQ , which is the dollar value of a change in Q divided by income. Log-linearized versions of (A.1), (A.2), and (A.3) describe how prices co-vary with city at5 The use of a single index Qj assumes that amenities are weakly separable from consumption. The model generalizes to one with heterogenous workers that supply different fixed amounts of labor if these workers are perfect substitutes in production, have identical homothetic preferences, and earn equal shares of income from labor. Additonally, the mobility condition need not apply to all households, but only a sufficiently large subset of mobile marginal households (Gyourko and Tracy 1989). i tributes.6 sw (1 ^j Lr ^j )w^ j + sy p^j = Q ^j + N w^ j = A^j Lr 0 + ^ Nw j p^j = (A.4a) (A.4b) X j ^ AY (A.4c) These equations are first-order approximations of the equilibrium conditions around a nationallyrepresentative city, and thus use national shares. Equation (1) comes directly from (A.4c); equation (2) by substituting (1) with (A.4b); (4) follows from applying the defintion provided and simplifying. B Parameterization B.1 Expenditure and Cost-share Parameters To keep track of the notation, table A3 summarizes the key parameteter values, which refer to national averages. It presents values for the full model and the reduced model, which is closely related to Beeson and Eberts (1989), shown here for comparison. TABLE A3: MODEL PARAMETERS AND POSSIBLE VALUES Parameter Notation Full Reduced B-E Home-goods share sy 0.36 0.077 0.073 Income share to land sR 0.10 0.10 0.064 Income share to labor sw 0.75 0.75 0.73 Traded-good cost-share of land 0.025 0.025 0.028 L Traded-good cost-share of labor 0.825 0.825 0.927 N Home-good cost-share of land 0.233 1.0 1.0 L Home-good cost-share of labor 0.617 0.0 0.0 N 0 Average marginal tax rate on labor 0.361 0.0 0.0 Deduction rate for home-goods 0.291 0.0 0.0 "Reduced" model parameterization based on B-E (Beeson and Eberts, 1989) simplifications. B.2 Economic Parameter Choices The parameterization used here is the same as in Albouy (2009), although I review it below. Because of accounting identities, only six parameters are free, but choosing these requires reconciling 6 When simply linearized with Shephard’s Lemma, the equations are (@e=@Q)dQj = y dpj (1 0 ) dwj dAjX = (LX =X) drj + (NX =X) dwj p dAjY = (LY =Y ) drj + (NY =Y ) dwj dpj The first equation is log-linearized by dividing through by m, and the third, by dividing by p. ii slightly conflicting sources.7 Starting with income shares, Krueger (1999) makes the case that the labor share, sw is close to 75 percent. In practice, this reflects the previous literature that weights the wage differential by labor income, rather than household income. Albouy (2008) argues this number applies to a representative household, so higher-income households, with more income from capital, receive greater weight. It also averages in retirees and others on fixed or transfer income (e.g. students). The share is also consistent with data in the Survey of Consumer Finances. Theoretically, the use of sw in (3) implies that if a household moves, its wage may change, but not the flow income from previous savings. Poterba (1998) estimates that the share of income from corporate capital is 12 percent, and thus income from mobile capital, sI should be higher, and is taken as 15 percent. This leaves 10 percent for land sR . This is the same as in Shapiro (2006) and roughly consistent with estimates in Keiper et al. (1961) and Case (2007).8 Turning to expenditure shares, Shapiro (2006), Albouy (2008), and Moretti (2013) find that housing costs can also be used to approximate non-housing cost differences across cities. The cost-of-living differential is sy p^j , where p^j is equal to the housing-cost differential and sy is the expenditure share on housing plus an additional term to capture how a one-percent increase in housing costs predicts a b = 0:26-percent increase in non-housing costs. In the Consumer Expenditure Survey (CEX), the share of income spent on shelter and utilities, shous , is 0.22, although the share of income spent on other goods, soth , is 0.56, with the remaining 0.22 spent on taxes or saved (Bureau of Labor Statistics 2002). Thus, the coefficient on housing costs is equal to sy = shous + soth b = 0:22 + 0:56 0:26 = 36 percent. I choose the cost-shares to be consistent with the expenditure and income shares above. I use a value of 2.5 percent for L here. Beeson and Eberts (1989) use a value of 0.027, while Rappaport (2008a, 2008b) uses a value of 0.016. Valentinyi and Herrendorff (2008) estimate the land share of tradables at 4 percent, but their definition of tradables makes this an upper bound. Following Carliner (2003) and Case (2007), I use a cost-share of land in home-goods, taken as housing, L , at 23.3 percent: this is slightly above values reported in McDonald (1981), Roback (1982), and Thorsnes (1997), in order to take into account for secular increase in land cost-shares over time, seen in Davis and Palumbo (2007). Together the cost and expenditure shares imply that sR is 10 percent, consistent with other income shares. This seems reasonable as the remaining 83 percent of land for home goods includes all residential land, and most land used for commerce, roads, and government. The one remaining choice determines the cost-shares of labor and capital in both production 7 Nationally, the parameters obey the following identities: (i) sw + sI + sR = 1; (ii) L + K + N = 1; (iii) + K + N = 1; (iv) sw = sx N + sy N ; (v) sI = sx K + sy K ; (vi) sR = sx L + sy L . Furthermore, the share of land and labor in traded production are (vii) L = sx L =sR , (viii) N = sx N =sw . Other reduced models with L = 1; N = N = 0 include Shapiro (2006), who proposes values of L = 0:1; N = 0:75, and sy =sw = 0:32, implying L = 0:20 and N = 1; Gabriel and Rosenthal (2004) use values implying L = 0:5 and N = 1. Roback (1982, p.1273) considers a case with sy =sw = 0:035, which is too limited to provide other parameter values. The chosen values here are similar to Rappaport (2008a, 2008b) except that he more narrowly confines home goods to housing, using a smaller sy = 0:18 and a larger L = 0:35. His implied L = 0:17 is quite similar, whereas N = 0:87 is smaller. 8 The values Keiper et al. (1961) reports were at a historical low: that total land value was found to be about 1.1 times GDP. A rate of return of 9 percent would justify using sR = 0:10: Case (2007), ignoring agriculture, estimates the value of land to be $5.6 trillion in 2000 when personal income was $8.35 trillion, implying a smaller share. L iii sectors. As separate information on the cost share of capital, K and K , is unavailable, I set both of these shares to at 15 percent to be consistent with sI . Accounting identities then determine that N is 82.5 percent and N is 61.7 percent. B.3 Choice of Tax Parameters The federal marginal tax rate on wage income is determined by adding together federal marginal income tax rate and the effective marginal payroll tax rate. TAXSIM gives an average marginal federal income tax rate of 25.1 percent in 2000. In 2000, Social Security (OASDI) and Medicare (HI) tax rates were 12.4 and 2.9 percent on employer and employee combined. Estimates from Boskin et al. (1987, table 4) show that the marginal benefit from future returns from OASDI taxes is fairly low, generally no more than 50 percent, although only 85 percent of wage earnings are subject to the OASDI cap. HI taxes emulate a pure tax (Congressional Budget Office 2005). These facts suggest adding 37.5 percent of the Social Security tax and all of the Medicare tax to the federal income tax rate, adding 8.2 percent. The employer-half of the payroll tax (4.1 percent) has to be added to observed wage levels to produce gross wage levels. Overall, this puts an overall federal tax rate, 0 , of 33.3-percent on gross wages, although only 29.2 percent on observed wages. Determining the federal deduction level requires taking into account the fact that many households do not itemize deductions. According to the Statistics on Income, although only 33 percent of tax returns itemize, they account for 67 percent of reported Adjusted Gross Income (AGI). Since the income-weighted share is what matters, 67 percent is multiplied by the effective tax reduction given in TAXSIM in 2000 of 21.6 percent. Thus, on average these deductions reduce the effective price of eligible goods by 14.5 percent. Since eligible goods only include housing, this deduction applies to only 59 percent of home goods. Multiplying 14.5 percent by 59 percent gives an effective price reduction of 8.6 percent for home goods. Divided by a federal tax rate of 33.3 percent, this produces a federal deduction level of 25.7 percent. State income tax rates from 2000 are taken from TAXSIM, which, per dollar, fall at an average marginal rate of 4.5 percent. State sales tax data in 2000 are taken from the Tax Policy Center, originally supplied by the Federation of Tax Administrators. The average state sales tax rate is 5.2 percent. Sales tax rates are reduced by 10 percent to accommodate untaxed goods and services other than food or housing (Feenberg et al. 1997), and by another 8 percent in states that exempt food. Overall state taxes raise the marginal tax rate on wage differences within-state by an average of 5.9 percentage points, from zero points in Alaska to 8.8 points in Minnesota. State-level deductions for housing expenditures, explicit in income taxes, and implicit in sales taxes, should also be included. At the state level, deductions for income taxes are calculated in an equivalent way using TAXSIM data. Furthermore, all housing expenditures are deducted from the sales tax. Overall this produces an average effective deduction level of = 0:291: C C.1 Data and Estimation Wages and Housing-Cost Differentials Wage and housing-price data come from the United States Census data from the 2000 Integrated Public-Use Microdata Series (IPUMS), from Ruggles et al. (2004). iv To estimate inter-urban wage differentials, w^ j , I use the logarithm of hourly wages from fulltime workers, ages 25 to 55. These differentials should control for skill differences across workers to provide an analogue to the representative worker in the model and isolate the effect of a city on j ) a worker’s wage. Thus, I regress log wages on city-indicators ( jw ) and on extensive controls (Xwi j j j j j in the equation ln wi = Xwi w + w + "wi , and use the estimates of w for the wage differentials. Identifying these differentials requires that workers do not sort across cities according to their unobserved skills. An overstated wage differential for a city biases trade-productivity upwards and quality of life downwards. Below is a list of the controls used in the wage equation: 12 indicators of educational attainment; a quartic in potential experience, and potential experience interacted with years of education; 9 indicators of industry at the one-digit level (1950 classification); 9 indicators of employment at the one-digit level (1950 classification); 4 indicators of marital status (married, divorced, widowed, separated); an indicator for veteran status, and veteran status interacted with age; 5 indicators of minority status (Black, Hispanic, Asian, Native American, and other); an indicator of immigrant status, years since immigration, and immigrant status interacted with black, Hispanic, Asian, and other; and 2 indicators for English proficiency (none or poor). All covariates are interacted with gender. I first run the regression using census-person weights. From the regressions, I calculate a predicted wage is using the individual characteristics, not the MSAs, to form a new weight equal to the predicted wage multiplied by the census-person weight. Economically, these income-adjusted weights are more relevant since workers’ influence on prices is determined by their endowment and income share. The new weights are then used in a second regression, which is used to calculate the city-wage differentials from the MSA indicator variables. In practice, this weighting procedure has only a small effect on the estimated wage differentials. To estimate housing-cost, p^j , I use both housing values and gross rents, with utilities, to calculate a flow cost. Following previous studies, I calculate comparable imputed rents for owned units by multiplying reported housing values by a rate of 7.85 percent (Peiser and Smith 1985) and adding this to utility costs. To avoid measurement error from imperfect recall or rent control, the sample includes only units that were acquired in the last ten years. I then regress housing costs on j j j j flexible controls (Xpi ) – interacted with renter-status – in the equation ln pji = Xpi p + p + "pi , and use the estimates of jp for the housing-cost differentials. Proper identification of housing-cost differences requires that average unobserved housing quality does not vary systematically across cities. An overstated housing-cost differential biases both trade-productivity and quality of life upwards. Below is a list of the controls used in the housing-cost regression: v 9 indicators for number of units in structure (1-family home, attached; 1-family house, detached; 2-family building; 3-4 family building; 5-9 family building, 10-19 family building; 20-49 family building; 50+ family building; mobile home or trailer); 9 indicators for the number of rooms, 5 indicators for the number of bedrooms, number of rooms interacted with number of bedrooms, and the number of household members per room; 2 indicators for lot size; 7 indicators for when the building was built; 2 indicators for complete plumbing and kitchen facilities; an indicator for commercial use; and an indicator for condominium status (owned units only). All of these variables are interacted with tenure, i.e. renter status. Therefore the owner-occupied user-cost rate of 7.85 percent only matters in how it used to incorporate utility costs. I first run a regression of housing values on housing characteristics and MSA indicator variables using only owner-occupied units, weighting by census-housing weights. From this regression, I calculate a new value-adjusted weight by multiplying the census-housing weights by the predicted value from this first regression using housing characteristics alone. Economically, these weights reflect the number of efficiency units of housing each observation provides. I then run a second regression with these new weights for all units, rented and owner-occupied, on the housing characteristics fully interacted with tenure, along with the MSA indicators, which are not interacted. I take the house-price differentials from the MSA indicator variables in this second regression. As with the wage differentials, this adjusted weighting method has only a small impact on the measured price differentials. C.2 Amenity Data All climate and geographic data are calculated at the public-use microdata area (PUMA) level and averaged up to the metropolitan level, weighting by population. Population density is measured at the census tract level, and also population-averaged. Heating and cooling degree days (Annual) Degree day data are used to estimate amounts of energy required to maintain comfortable indoor temperature levels. Daily values are computed from each day’s mean temperature, (max + min)/2. Daily heating degree days are equal to maxf0; 65 meantempg and daily cooling degree days are maxf0; meantemp 65g. Annual degree days are the sum of daily degree days over the year. The data here refer to averages from 1970 to 2000 (National Climactic Data Center 2008). Sunshine Average percentage of possible. The total time that sunshine reaches the surface of the earth is expressed as the percentage of the maximum amount possible from sunrise to sunset with clear sky conditions. (National Climactic Data Center 2008). vi Average slope (percent) The average slope of the land in the metropolitan area. Coded by author using GIS software. Coastal proximity Equal to one over the distance in miles to the nearest coastline. Coded by author using GIS software. Violent crimes (per capita) These consist of the average of the four z-scores (standard deviations) for aggravated assaults, robbery, forcible rape, and murder (City and County Data Book 2000). Property crimes (per capita) These consist of the average of the four z-scores (standard deviations) for aggravated burglary, larceny, motor theft, and arson (City and County Data 2000). Air quality index (Median) An AQI value is calculated for each pollutant in an area (groundlevel ozone, particle pollution, carbon monoxide, sulfur dioxide, and nitrogen dioxide). The highest AQI value for the individual pollutants is the AQI value for that day. An AQI over 300 is considered hazardous; under 50, good; values in between correspond to moderate, unhealthy, and very unhealthy (Environmental Protection Agency 2008). Bars and restaurants Number of establishments classified as eating and drinking places (NAICS 722) in County Business Patterns 2000. Arts and Culture Index from Places Rated Almanac (Savageau 1999). Based on a ranking of cities, it ranges from 100 (New York, NY) to 0 (Houma, LA). vii APPENDIX TABLE A1: LIST OF METROPOLITAN AND NON-METROPOLITAN AREAS RANKED BY TOTAL AMENITY VALUE Full Name of Metropolitan Area San Francisco-Oakland-San Jose, CA Santa Barbara-Santa Maria-Lompoc, CA Honolulu, HI Salinas (Monterey-Carmel), CA San Diego, CA Los Angeles-Riverside-Orange County, CA San Luis Obispo-Atascadero-Paso Robles, CA New York, Northern New Jersey, Long Island, NY-NJ-CT-PA Barnstable-Yarmouth (Cape Cod), MA Non-metro, HI Seattle-Tacoma-Bremerton, WA Boston-Worcester-Lawrence, MA-NH-ME-CT Santa Fe, NM Naples, FL Denver-Boulder-Greeley, CO Chicago-Gary-Kenosha, IL-IN-WI Non-metro, RI Sacramento-Yolo, CA Reno, NV Anchorage, AK Portland-Salem, OR-WA Washington-Baltimore, DC-MD-VA-WV Fort Collins-Loveland, CO Non-metro, CO Stockton-Lodi, CA Hartford, CT Miami-Fort Lauderdale, FL Bellingham, WA Non-metro, CA West Palm Beach-Boca Raton, FL Non-metro, CT Madison, WI New London-Norwich, CT-RI Sarasota-Bradenton, FL Non-metro, MA Non-metro, AK Eugene-Springfield, OR Medford-Ashland, OR Phoenix-Mesa, AZ Corvalis, OR Grand Junction, CO Providence-Fall River-Warwick, RI-MA Austin-San Marcos, TX Modesto, CA Detroit-Ann Arbor-Flint, MI Raleigh-Durham-Chapel Hill, NC Philadelphia-Wilmington-Atlantic City, PA-NJ-DE-MD Population 7,039,362 399,347 876,156 401,762 2,813,833 16,373,645 246,681 21,199,864 162,582 335,381 3,554,760 5,819,100 147,635 251,377 2,581,506 9,157,540 61,968 1,796,857 339,486 260,283 2,265,223 7,608,070 251,494 693,605 563,598 1,183,110 3,876,380 166,814 1,121,254 1,131,184 148,665 426,526 293,566 589,959 247,672 366,649 322,959 181,269 3,251,876 78,153 116,255 1,188,613 1,249,763 446,997 5,456,428 1,187,941 6,188,463 Adjusted Differentials Housing Costs Wages 0.256 0.813 0.068 0.662 -0.010 0.605 0.103 0.590 0.058 0.479 0.129 0.450 0.036 0.452 0.209 0.411 0.005 0.395 -0.029 0.332 0.078 0.308 0.123 0.294 -0.060 0.290 -0.004 0.286 0.051 0.240 0.136 0.224 0.060 0.215 0.067 0.206 0.027 0.210 0.073 0.185 0.024 0.174 0.126 0.154 -0.061 0.150 -0.137 0.137 0.088 0.126 0.134 0.133 0.001 0.126 -0.065 0.127 -0.040 0.134 0.042 0.115 0.083 0.119 -0.038 0.110 0.050 0.110 -0.071 0.094 -0.068 0.108 0.035 0.090 -0.118 0.091 -0.136 0.084 0.028 0.075 -0.113 0.076 -0.180 0.079 0.018 0.073 0.009 0.067 0.056 0.059 0.130 0.053 0.016 0.044 0.114 0.052 Land Rents Linear 2.780 2.651 2.620 2.244 1.894 1.573 1.840 1.184 1.678 1.504 1.103 0.925 1.408 1.239 0.888 0.585 0.757 0.699 0.826 0.595 0.680 0.314 0.808 0.962 0.296 0.201 0.535 0.726 0.686 0.378 0.285 0.574 0.332 0.595 0.652 0.292 0.716 0.736 0.243 0.634 0.833 0.262 0.264 0.098 -0.130 0.143 -0.090 Quadratic 2.246 2.111 2.069 1.847 1.590 1.369 1.546 1.077 1.422 1.285 0.992 0.851 1.206 1.087 0.812 0.558 0.703 0.653 0.757 0.562 0.632 0.307 0.730 0.843 0.289 0.198 0.503 0.660 0.630 0.364 0.279 0.533 0.321 0.548 0.597 0.283 0.644 0.658 0.237 0.575 0.731 0.255 0.256 0.098 -0.139 0.141 -0.096 Quality of Life Value 0.138 0.176 0.204 0.137 0.123 0.081 0.124 0.029 0.121 0.126 0.061 0.034 0.127 0.095 0.054 0.005 0.040 0.033 0.053 0.023 0.047 -0.013 0.079 0.112 -0.002 -0.026 0.041 0.074 0.059 0.017 -0.007 0.053 0.006 0.066 0.063 0.012 0.088 0.095 0.012 0.081 0.114 0.014 0.016 -0.008 -0.047 0.011 -0.040 Rank 3 2 1 4 7 14 6 51 8 22 46 5 11 26 80 48 30 59 37 122 16 93 155 39 17 66 28 79 19 13 12 72 15 9 69 67 106 215 74 192 TradeProductivity Value 0.289 0.125 0.057 0.144 0.098 0.150 0.077 0.209 0.046 0.013 0.095 0.128 -0.017 0.027 0.066 0.131 0.071 0.075 0.043 0.077 0.037 0.116 -0.032 -0.094 0.083 0.120 0.015 -0.038 -0.017 0.046 0.078 -0.018 0.051 -0.046 -0.042 0.037 -0.084 -0.099 0.030 -0.081 -0.134 0.022 0.014 0.050 0.108 0.018 0.096 Federal Tax Rank Differential 1 0.045 7 -0.010 22 -0.022 4 0.005 11 -0.004 3 0.020 16 -0.011 2 0.044 26 -0.017 -0.016 13 0.011 6 0.024 60 -0.025 34 -0.011 19 0.008 5 0.030 0.009 17 0.011 29 -0.002 15 0.013 30 0.003 9 0.030 72 -0.022 -0.044 14 0.021 8 0.030 39 -0.003 82 -0.023 -0.021 27 0.009 0.015 63 -0.016 23 0.006 85 -0.023 -0.029 0.006 127 -0.037 147 -0.042 32 0.007 122 -0.035 200 -0.055 35 0.002 40 -0.001 24 0.014 10 0.035 38 0.008 12 0.030 Total Amenity Values Value 0.323 0.255 0.240 0.229 0.185 0.177 0.173 0.163 0.151 0.135 0.121 0.116 0.116 0.113 0.097 0.089 0.085 0.081 0.081 0.073 0.071 0.062 0.059 0.052 0.051 0.050 0.050 0.050 0.048 0.047 0.043 0.042 0.039 0.037 0.036 0.035 0.035 0.031 0.031 0.029 0.029 0.028 0.026 0.024 0.022 0.022 0.021 Rank 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 APPENDIX TABLE A1: LIST OF METROPOLITAN AND NON-METROPOLITAN AREAS RANKED BY TOTAL AMENITY VALUE Full Name of Metropolitan Area Salt Lake City-Ogden, UT Milwaukee-Racine, WI Colorado Springs, CO Portland, ME Burlington, VT Las Vegas, NV-AZ Minneapolis-St. Paul, MN-WI Chico-Paradise, CA Albuquerque, NM Atlanta, GA Wilmington, NC Springfield, MA Charlottesville, VA Fort Myers-Cape Coral, FL Non-metro, WA Redding, CA Tucson, AZ Non-metro, NV Charlotte-Gastonia-Rock Hill, NC-SC Non-metro, NH Non-metro, OR Nashville, TN Provo-Orem, UT Iowa City, IA Cleveland-Akron, OH Dallas-Fort Worth, TX Fresno, CA Orlando, FL Pittsfield, MA Columbus, OH Merced, CA Lancaster, PA Green Bay, WI Cincinnati-Hamilton, OH-KY-IN Allentown-Bethlehem-Easton, PA Asheville, NC Yakima, WA Charleston-North Charleston, SC Non-metro, VT Tampa-St. Petersburg-Clearwater, FL Missoula, MT Yuba City, CA Norfolk-Virginia Beach-Newport News, VANon-metro, DE New Orleans, LA Indianapolis, IN Richmond-Petersburg, VA Population 1,333,914 1,689,572 516,929 243,537 169,391 1,563,282 2,968,806 203,171 712,738 4,112,198 233,450 591,932 159,576 440,888 994,967 163,256 843,746 250,521 1,499,293 496,087 919,033 1,231,311 368,536 111,006 2,945,831 5,221,801 922,516 1,644,561 84,699 1,540,157 210,554 470,658 226,778 1,979,202 637,958 225,965 222,581 549,033 439,436 2,395,997 95,802 139,149 1,569,541 156,638 1,337,726 1,607,486 996,512 Adjusted Differentials Housing Costs Wages -0.024 0.038 0.043 0.032 -0.088 0.033 -0.078 0.019 -0.107 0.021 0.068 0.029 0.082 0.020 -0.090 0.043 -0.082 0.013 0.078 0.014 -0.134 0.017 -0.006 0.009 -0.113 -0.003 -0.105 -0.014 -0.083 -0.014 -0.094 0.001 -0.114 -0.010 0.008 -0.017 0.013 -0.033 -0.100 -0.030 -0.140 -0.024 -0.016 -0.030 -0.056 -0.030 -0.087 -0.032 0.012 -0.032 0.064 -0.037 -0.012 -0.039 -0.040 -0.046 -0.058 -0.033 0.023 -0.054 -0.010 -0.048 -0.015 -0.053 -0.019 -0.064 0.035 -0.070 0.002 -0.064 -0.159 -0.060 -0.027 -0.072 -0.095 -0.069 -0.197 -0.086 -0.057 -0.084 -0.251 -0.090 -0.073 -0.074 -0.109 -0.081 -0.081 -0.088 -0.070 -0.097 0.017 -0.096 0.006 -0.098 Land Rents Linear 0.226 0.018 0.384 0.299 0.386 -0.065 -0.142 0.432 0.282 -0.154 0.441 0.055 0.300 0.228 0.170 0.263 0.268 -0.097 -0.177 0.147 0.284 -0.086 0.024 0.105 -0.171 -0.338 -0.133 -0.088 0.021 -0.296 -0.180 -0.188 -0.223 -0.394 -0.280 0.181 -0.236 -0.036 0.173 -0.204 0.306 -0.115 -0.045 -0.155 -0.224 -0.459 -0.437 Quadratic 0.219 0.017 0.360 0.283 0.359 -0.067 -0.149 0.402 0.267 -0.161 0.405 0.055 0.281 0.215 0.162 0.248 0.252 -0.099 -0.182 0.140 0.264 -0.086 0.024 0.101 -0.176 -0.360 -0.135 -0.088 0.020 -0.310 -0.184 -0.192 -0.229 -0.420 -0.291 0.167 -0.242 -0.037 0.157 -0.208 0.271 -0.116 -0.047 -0.157 -0.228 -0.492 -0.466 Quality of Life Value 0.026 -0.009 0.055 0.051 0.065 -0.025 -0.032 0.053 0.049 -0.032 0.071 0.002 0.054 0.049 0.037 0.041 0.052 -0.011 -0.013 0.042 0.062 -0.001 0.019 0.034 -0.016 -0.044 -0.008 0.006 0.014 -0.028 -0.012 -0.011 -0.011 -0.038 -0.022 0.058 -0.009 0.025 0.073 0.003 0.101 0.009 0.027 0.010 0.005 -0.039 -0.033 Rank 55 107 25 33 20 150 171 29 34 174 18 87 27 36 38 31 123 90 64 45 127 205 104 78 70 159 121 117 116 186 141 23 108 57 86 10 76 53 81 189 178 TradeProductivity Value -0.015 0.037 -0.066 -0.060 -0.082 0.057 0.067 -0.067 -0.064 0.063 -0.104 -0.003 -0.090 -0.084 -0.067 -0.074 -0.091 0.005 0.007 -0.082 -0.113 -0.016 -0.048 -0.072 0.006 0.047 -0.014 -0.037 -0.050 0.013 -0.013 -0.017 -0.022 0.020 -0.005 -0.132 -0.029 -0.082 -0.165 -0.054 -0.208 -0.066 -0.095 -0.073 -0.065 0.003 -0.006 Federal Tax Rank Differential 57 -0.006 31 0.013 103 -0.025 97 -0.017 125 -0.026 21 0.018 18 0.026 104 -0.033 100 -0.020 20 0.024 155 -0.039 48 -0.005 136 -0.034 129 -0.028 -0.022 110 -0.032 139 -0.033 0.002 43 0.009 -0.025 -0.039 59 -0.003 87 -0.014 109 -0.022 44 0.005 25 0.019 56 -0.004 79 -0.008 89 -0.020 41 0.009 55 -0.002 61 -0.003 66 -0.002 37 0.014 49 0.002 197 -0.044 70 -0.004 123 -0.024 -0.050 94 -0.012 260 -0.063 102 -0.022 141 -0.029 -0.021 101 -0.015 45 0.009 50 0.006 Total Amenity Values Value 0.017 0.015 0.013 0.013 0.013 0.011 0.011 0.010 0.008 0.008 0.005 0.000 -0.004 -0.005 -0.005 -0.006 -0.006 -0.008 -0.008 -0.010 -0.011 -0.011 -0.011 -0.012 -0.012 -0.014 -0.017 -0.017 -0.018 -0.020 -0.020 -0.022 -0.025 -0.025 -0.026 -0.026 -0.027 -0.028 -0.032 -0.032 -0.033 -0.034 -0.034 -0.037 -0.037 -0.037 -0.037 Rank 41 42 43 44 45 46 47 48 49 50 51 52 53 54 55 56 57 58 59 60 61 62 63 64 65 66 67 68 69 70 71 72 73 74 75 76 77 78 79 80 81 APPENDIX TABLE A1: LIST OF METROPOLITAN AND NON-METROPOLITAN AREAS RANKED BY TOTAL AMENITY VALUE Full Name of Metropolitan Area St. Louis, MO-IL Bloomington, IN Fort Pierce-Port St. Lucie, FL Boise City, ID Visalia-Tulare-Porterville, CA State College, PA Tallahassee, FL Harrisburg-Lebanon-Carlisle, PA Jacksonville, FL Punta Gorda, FL Houston-Galveston-Brazoria, TX Richland-Kennewick-Pasco, WA Lawrence, KS Des Moines, IA Kansas City, MO-KS Non-metro, MD Greensboro--Winston Salem--High Point, NC Dayton-Springfield, OH Bakersfield, CA Fort Walton Beach, FL Lafayette, IN Spokane, WA Grand Rapids-Muskegon-Holland, MI Bryan-College Station, TX Lansing-East Lansing, MI Cedar Rapids, IA Flagstaff, AZ-UT Louisville, KY-IN Appleton-Oshkosh-Neenah, WI York, PA Columbia, SC Lincoln, NE Myrtle Beach, SC Reading, PA Albany-Schenectady-Troy, NY Sheboygan, WI Rochester, NY Bloomington-Normal, IL Champaign-Urbana, IL Gainesville, FL Savannah, GA Panama City, FL Janesville-Beloit, WI Yuma, AZ Rochester, MN Athens, GA Dover, DE Population 2,603,607 120,563 319,426 432,345 368,021 135,758 284,539 629,401 1,100,491 141,627 4,669,571 191,822 99,962 456,022 1,776,062 385,446 1,251,509 950,558 661,645 170,498 182,821 417,939 1,088,514 152,415 447,728 191,701 122,366 1,025,598 358,365 381,751 536,691 250,291 196,629 373,638 875,583 112,646 1,098,201 150,433 179,669 217,955 293,000 148,217 152,307 160,026 124,277 153,444 126,697 Adjusted Differentials Housing Costs Wages 0.005 -0.104 -0.127 -0.090 -0.085 -0.100 -0.083 -0.109 -0.032 -0.094 -0.139 -0.092 -0.110 -0.106 -0.011 -0.105 -0.050 -0.110 -0.167 -0.108 0.073 -0.111 0.029 -0.117 -0.148 -0.112 -0.030 -0.123 -0.001 -0.129 -0.033 -0.105 -0.046 -0.126 -0.021 -0.124 0.044 -0.132 -0.204 -0.125 -0.070 -0.123 -0.097 -0.128 0.004 -0.122 -0.138 -0.126 0.006 -0.126 -0.081 -0.137 -0.146 -0.128 -0.040 -0.138 -0.047 -0.138 -0.026 -0.138 -0.076 -0.145 -0.134 -0.150 -0.169 -0.135 -0.002 -0.146 -0.014 -0.132 -0.058 -0.146 -0.018 -0.136 0.024 -0.149 -0.082 -0.142 -0.148 -0.156 -0.081 -0.151 -0.153 -0.159 -0.002 -0.164 -0.106 -0.158 0.018 -0.164 -0.138 -0.153 -0.087 -0.158 Land Rents Linear -0.458 -0.036 -0.197 -0.239 -0.315 -0.010 -0.150 -0.420 -0.333 -0.006 -0.675 -0.584 -0.070 -0.444 -0.547 -0.360 -0.414 -0.475 -0.684 0.025 -0.336 -0.281 -0.532 -0.162 -0.557 -0.365 -0.145 -0.480 -0.463 -0.518 -0.410 -0.272 -0.116 -0.618 -0.526 -0.465 -0.532 -0.705 -0.385 -0.262 -0.426 -0.263 -0.699 -0.387 -0.753 -0.275 -0.439 Quadratic -0.489 -0.038 -0.200 -0.243 -0.326 -0.014 -0.152 -0.444 -0.345 -0.011 -0.762 -0.640 -0.073 -0.469 -0.592 -0.375 -0.435 -0.506 -0.767 0.017 -0.347 -0.287 -0.575 -0.164 -0.605 -0.378 -0.147 -0.510 -0.489 -0.555 -0.427 -0.277 -0.119 -0.676 -0.565 -0.490 -0.572 -0.788 -0.400 -0.267 -0.445 -0.267 -0.775 -0.401 -0.848 -0.281 -0.458 Quality of Life Value -0.034 0.032 0.011 0.010 -0.016 0.036 0.022 -0.029 -0.009 0.049 -0.072 -0.051 0.038 -0.022 -0.037 -0.022 -0.016 -0.030 -0.063 0.062 -0.006 0.008 -0.044 0.027 -0.046 -0.002 0.030 -0.023 -0.021 -0.032 -0.007 0.022 0.038 -0.046 -0.041 -0.019 -0.041 -0.061 -0.009 0.024 -0.011 0.026 -0.050 0.002 -0.061 0.016 -0.009 Rank 180 49 73 75 130 43 61 162 110 35 267 225 41 140 184 126 164 252 21 98 77 204 54 211 92 50 144 138 175 99 62 42 210 198 133 195 248 112 58 115 56 224 88 246 68 111 TradeProductivity Value -0.007 -0.110 -0.078 -0.077 -0.036 -0.120 -0.098 -0.020 -0.051 -0.143 0.045 0.011 -0.129 -0.037 -0.015 -0.037 -0.049 -0.030 0.020 -0.174 -0.069 -0.090 -0.010 -0.122 -0.008 -0.078 -0.129 -0.047 -0.052 -0.036 -0.076 -0.122 -0.148 -0.017 -0.026 -0.062 -0.029 0.003 -0.080 -0.134 -0.080 -0.138 -0.019 -0.100 -0.003 -0.125 -0.086 Federal Tax Rank Differential 51 0.008 166 -0.035 113 -0.019 112 -0.015 77 -0.008 173 -0.039 145 -0.026 65 0.000 90 -0.009 212 -0.042 28 0.025 42 0.014 190 -0.037 78 -0.001 58 0.009 -0.010 88 -0.006 71 -0.002 36 0.019 241 -0.052 106 -0.016 138 -0.022 53 0.003 176 -0.035 52 0.004 115 -0.016 191 -0.038 86 -0.005 91 -0.008 76 -0.003 111 -0.015 175 -0.029 217 -0.045 62 0.004 68 -0.005 98 -0.011 69 -0.006 46 0.011 119 -0.022 201 -0.035 120 -0.019 207 -0.036 64 0.007 151 -0.024 47 0.012 185 -0.037 133 -0.020 Total Amenity Values Value -0.038 -0.038 -0.039 -0.039 -0.039 -0.040 -0.041 -0.042 -0.042 -0.043 -0.043 -0.044 -0.045 -0.045 -0.046 -0.046 -0.047 -0.049 -0.050 -0.050 -0.050 -0.050 -0.050 -0.051 -0.052 -0.052 -0.052 -0.053 -0.054 -0.055 -0.056 -0.056 -0.057 -0.057 -0.058 -0.058 -0.059 -0.060 -0.060 -0.061 -0.062 -0.062 -0.063 -0.063 -0.063 -0.064 -0.064 Rank 82 83 84 85 86 87 88 89 90 91 92 93 94 95 96 97 98 99 100 101 102 103 104 105 106 107 108 109 110 111 112 113 114 115 116 117 118 119 120 121 122 123 124 125 126 127 APPENDIX TABLE A1: LIST OF METROPOLITAN AND NON-METROPOLITAN AREAS RANKED BY TOTAL AMENITY VALUE Full Name of Metropolitan Area Baton Rouge, LA Toledo, OH Melbourne-Titusville-Palm Bay, FL Non-metro, AZ Memphis, TN-AR-MS Birmingham, AL Non-metro, UT Omaha, NE-IA Daytona Beach, FL Little Rock-North Little Rock, AR Greenville, NC Tuscaloosa, AL Canton-Massillon, OH Fayetteville-Springdale-Rogers, AR Kalamazoo-Battle Creek, MI Greenville-Spartanburg-Anderson, SC Elkhart-Goshen, IN Buffalo-Niagara Falls, NY Benton Harbor, MI Columbia, MO Pittsburgh, PA Cheyenne, WY Montgomery, AL Rockford, IL Roanoke, VA Fayetteville, NC Jackson, MI Lewiston-Auburn, ME Hickory-Morganton-Lenoir, NC Peoria-Pekin, IL Glens Falls, NY Non-metro, ME Pensacola, FL Kokomo, IN Knoxville, TN Springfield, IL Non-metro, MT Tyler, TX South Bend, IN Lexington, KY Huntsville, AL Jackson, MS Billings, MT Scranton--Wilkes-Barre--Hazleton, PA Saginaw-Bay City-Midland, MI Non-metro, FL Rocky Mount, NC Population 602,894 618,203 476,230 603,632 1,135,614 921,106 524,673 716,998 493,175 583,845 133,798 164,875 406,934 311,121 452,851 962,441 182,791 1,170,111 162,453 135,454 2,358,695 81,607 333,055 371,236 235,932 302,963 158,422 90,830 341,851 347,387 124,345 808,317 412,153 101,541 687,249 201,437 596,684 174,706 265,559 479,198 342,376 440,801 129,352 624,776 403,070 1,144,881 143,026 Adjusted Differentials Housing Costs Wages -0.045 -0.169 -0.025 -0.164 -0.108 -0.171 -0.184 -0.163 0.008 -0.178 -0.019 -0.179 -0.134 -0.171 -0.080 -0.195 -0.157 -0.185 -0.099 -0.197 -0.081 -0.195 -0.098 -0.195 -0.079 -0.191 -0.139 -0.206 -0.020 -0.196 -0.071 -0.210 -0.047 -0.204 -0.027 -0.190 -0.076 -0.194 -0.180 -0.204 -0.041 -0.207 -0.246 -0.214 -0.129 -0.209 -0.002 -0.211 -0.106 -0.212 -0.198 -0.209 -0.014 -0.212 -0.125 -0.229 -0.127 -0.220 -0.022 -0.217 -0.110 -0.204 -0.201 -0.229 -0.154 -0.232 0.069 -0.237 -0.127 -0.231 -0.074 -0.222 -0.266 -0.239 -0.102 -0.234 -0.060 -0.235 -0.088 -0.241 -0.045 -0.244 -0.092 -0.246 -0.180 -0.252 -0.103 -0.236 -0.012 -0.239 -0.178 -0.247 -0.111 -0.246 Land Rents Linear -0.601 -0.636 -0.434 -0.194 -0.784 -0.716 -0.366 -0.617 -0.362 -0.572 -0.613 -0.564 -0.602 -0.503 -0.783 -0.706 -0.744 -0.742 -0.623 -0.380 -0.773 -0.240 -0.542 -0.897 -0.616 -0.351 -0.870 -0.639 -0.592 -0.869 -0.573 -0.426 -0.573 -1.208 -0.642 -0.749 -0.294 -0.722 -0.842 -0.790 -0.921 -0.801 -0.582 -0.728 -0.990 -0.569 -0.750 Quadratic -0.649 -0.694 -0.452 -0.197 -0.886 -0.794 -0.376 -0.663 -0.372 -0.609 -0.658 -0.599 -0.646 -0.526 -0.878 -0.771 -0.822 -0.824 -0.671 -0.390 -0.860 -0.245 -0.570 -1.033 -0.658 -0.359 -0.993 -0.683 -0.629 -0.989 -0.608 -0.439 -0.604 -1.531 -0.686 -0.823 -0.301 -0.786 -0.945 -0.872 -1.053 -0.886 -0.612 -0.793 -1.158 -0.597 -0.819 Quality of Life Value -0.031 -0.041 0.000 0.037 -0.060 -0.047 0.010 -0.019 0.019 -0.011 -0.022 -0.013 -0.024 0.005 -0.056 -0.031 -0.043 -0.054 -0.029 0.023 -0.047 0.056 -0.003 -0.069 -0.017 0.028 -0.064 -0.008 -0.008 -0.061 -0.020 0.027 0.003 -0.110 -0.011 -0.039 0.059 -0.025 -0.047 -0.033 -0.055 -0.031 0.013 -0.027 -0.074 0.010 -0.024 Rank 166 196 89 242 212 134 63 119 139 124 148 82 234 165 202 231 163 60 217 24 95 262 131 52 259 101 105 247 136 85 276 120 187 151 214 177 232 170 71 157 270 145 TradeProductivity Value -0.053 -0.037 -0.104 -0.163 -0.013 -0.034 -0.124 -0.084 -0.144 -0.100 -0.085 -0.099 -0.083 -0.132 -0.037 -0.078 -0.059 -0.042 -0.081 -0.164 -0.054 -0.217 -0.124 -0.024 -0.107 -0.178 -0.034 -0.123 -0.124 -0.041 -0.109 -0.184 -0.146 0.029 -0.125 -0.082 -0.236 -0.106 -0.072 -0.095 -0.062 -0.099 -0.169 -0.106 -0.035 -0.167 -0.114 Federal Tax Rank Differential 92 -0.005 81 -0.001 154 -0.023 -0.048 54 0.011 73 0.003 -0.033 128 -0.011 213 -0.036 150 -0.017 131 -0.014 146 -0.020 126 -0.017 195 -0.029 80 -0.002 114 -0.010 96 -0.006 84 -0.007 121 -0.019 230 -0.044 93 -0.005 263 -0.059 183 -0.029 67 0.005 162 -0.024 246 -0.051 74 0.001 180 -0.023 181 -0.028 83 -0.001 163 -0.033 -0.048 216 -0.034 33 0.030 184 -0.027 124 -0.016 -0.062 160 -0.021 108 -0.009 142 -0.015 99 -0.002 149 -0.015 236 -0.037 161 -0.022 75 0.003 -0.040 168 -0.022 Total Amenity Values Value -0.065 -0.065 -0.066 -0.067 -0.068 -0.069 -0.069 -0.072 -0.073 -0.075 -0.076 -0.077 -0.077 -0.080 -0.080 -0.081 -0.081 -0.081 -0.081 -0.082 -0.082 -0.083 -0.083 -0.084 -0.085 -0.086 -0.086 -0.087 -0.087 -0.088 -0.090 -0.090 -0.091 -0.091 -0.091 -0.091 -0.091 -0.093 -0.093 -0.094 -0.094 -0.095 -0.095 -0.095 -0.096 -0.097 -0.097 Rank 128 129 130 131 132 133 134 135 136 137 138 139 140 141 142 143 144 145 146 147 148 149 150 151 152 153 154 155 156 157 158 159 160 161 162 163 164 165 166 167 168 169 APPENDIX TABLE A1: LIST OF METROPOLITAN AND NON-METROPOLITAN AREAS RANKED BY TOTAL AMENITY VALUE Full Name of Metropolitan Area Davenport-Moline-Rock Island, IA-IL Wichita, KS Tulsa, OK Mobile, AL Non-metro, WY Lakeland-Winter Haven, FL Non-metro, ID Sioux Falls, SD Auburn-Opelika, AL San Antonio, TX Killeen-Temple, TX La Crosse, WI-MN Amarillo, TX Corpus Christi, TX Chattanooga, TN-GA Las Cruces, NM Rapid City, SD Eau Claire, WI Wausau, WI Non-metro, WI Syracuse, NY Waterloo-Cedar Falls, IA Fort Wayne, IN Pueblo, CO Oklahoma City, OK Non-metro, MI Non-metro, NC Erie, PA Springfield, MO Youngstown-Warren, OH Jacksonville, NC Topeka, KS Lubbock, TX Biloxi-Gulfport-Pascagoula, MS Evansville-Henderson, IN-KY Williamsport, PA Sherman-Denison, TX Augusta-Aiken, GA-SC Ocala, FL Lake Charles, LA Mansfield, OH St. Cloud, MN Macon, GA Goldsboro, NC Dubuque, IA Monroe, LA Lynchburg, VA Population 359,062 545,220 803,235 540,258 345,642 483,924 786,043 172,412 115,092 1,592,383 312,952 126,838 217,858 380,783 465,161 174,682 88,565 148,337 125,834 1,723,367 732,117 128,012 502,141 141,472 1,083,346 1,768,978 2,612,257 280,843 325,721 594,746 150,355 169,871 242,628 363,988 296,195 120,044 110,595 477,441 258,916 183,577 175,818 167,392 322,549 113,329 89,143 147,250 214,911 Adjusted Differentials Housing Costs Wages -0.078 -0.245 -0.065 -0.257 -0.096 -0.260 -0.129 -0.248 -0.174 -0.256 -0.116 -0.254 -0.186 -0.251 -0.149 -0.258 -0.132 -0.252 -0.088 -0.254 -0.245 -0.249 -0.126 -0.247 -0.146 -0.253 -0.099 -0.255 -0.098 -0.258 -0.205 -0.261 -0.232 -0.266 -0.118 -0.256 -0.074 -0.265 -0.116 -0.260 -0.037 -0.251 -0.127 -0.271 -0.049 -0.268 -0.168 -0.269 -0.133 -0.278 -0.102 -0.258 -0.150 -0.268 -0.108 -0.268 -0.185 -0.272 -0.077 -0.276 -0.286 -0.264 -0.135 -0.286 -0.166 -0.282 -0.132 -0.289 -0.093 -0.286 -0.126 -0.282 -0.134 -0.291 -0.078 -0.294 -0.170 -0.298 -0.066 -0.303 -0.099 -0.294 -0.100 -0.290 -0.059 -0.299 -0.183 -0.297 -0.148 -0.307 -0.126 -0.307 -0.137 -0.300 Land Rents Linear -0.838 -0.925 -0.849 -0.709 -0.619 -0.770 -0.565 -0.694 -0.716 -0.846 -0.393 -0.713 -0.684 -0.820 -0.837 -0.554 -0.501 -0.772 -0.934 -0.795 -0.973 -0.813 -1.014 -0.689 -0.826 -0.826 -0.736 -0.854 -0.658 -0.970 -0.344 -0.854 -0.750 -0.875 -0.970 -0.861 -0.879 -1.046 -0.810 -1.118 -0.988 -0.969 -1.117 -0.771 -0.909 -0.966 -0.911 Quadratic -0.936 -1.052 -0.945 -0.766 -0.655 -0.842 -0.592 -0.745 -0.773 -0.943 -0.404 -0.771 -0.734 -0.908 -0.930 -0.579 -0.520 -0.845 -1.063 -0.873 -1.127 -0.894 -1.180 -0.737 -0.909 -0.915 -0.796 -0.949 -0.699 -1.111 -0.353 -0.944 -0.810 -0.971 -1.105 -0.955 -0.976 -1.216 -0.883 -1.324 -1.129 -1.103 -1.326 -0.833 -1.012 -1.092 -1.017 Quality of Life Value -0.041 -0.048 -0.032 -0.016 0.007 -0.023 0.012 -0.006 -0.015 -0.039 0.040 -0.020 -0.010 -0.034 -0.035 0.019 0.033 -0.026 -0.049 -0.028 -0.069 -0.023 -0.063 -0.003 -0.020 -0.038 -0.013 -0.035 0.003 -0.052 0.051 -0.024 -0.009 -0.026 -0.047 -0.031 -0.028 -0.057 -0.010 -0.064 -0.048 -0.048 -0.068 -0.007 -0.024 -0.036 -0.031 Rank 199 218 172 128 142 97 125 188 40 135 113 179 181 65 47 154 222 264 143 254 94 137 182 84 227 32 147 109 156 213 168 158 235 114 258 219 220 261 100 146 183 169 TradeProductivity Value -0.088 -0.079 -0.104 -0.128 -0.165 -0.119 -0.174 -0.146 -0.132 -0.097 -0.220 -0.126 -0.142 -0.105 -0.105 -0.190 -0.212 -0.120 -0.086 -0.120 -0.056 -0.129 -0.067 -0.162 -0.135 -0.108 -0.148 -0.114 -0.175 -0.090 -0.254 -0.137 -0.161 -0.135 -0.104 -0.130 -0.137 -0.093 -0.166 -0.085 -0.110 -0.110 -0.079 -0.176 -0.150 -0.133 -0.140 Federal Tax Rank Differential 135 -0.014 116 -0.005 153 -0.013 188 -0.027 -0.037 172 -0.022 -0.043 215 -0.030 196 -0.028 143 -0.016 266 -0.061 187 -0.029 211 -0.033 159 -0.019 158 -0.018 254 -0.047 262 -0.052 174 -0.026 134 -0.011 -0.025 95 -0.008 189 -0.024 105 -0.004 228 -0.038 202 -0.024 -0.024 -0.034 167 -0.023 242 -0.043 137 -0.013 275 -0.077 206 -0.027 227 -0.037 203 -0.025 157 -0.017 192 -0.028 205 -0.028 140 -0.012 232 -0.036 130 -0.006 164 -0.019 165 -0.022 117 -0.007 243 -0.043 220 -0.029 199 -0.024 209 -0.030 Total Amenity Values Value -0.098 -0.098 -0.098 -0.098 -0.099 -0.099 -0.099 -0.099 -0.100 -0.100 -0.101 -0.101 -0.101 -0.101 -0.102 -0.102 -0.102 -0.103 -0.105 -0.105 -0.105 -0.106 -0.106 -0.106 -0.107 -0.107 -0.108 -0.108 -0.109 -0.110 -0.111 -0.112 -0.112 -0.113 -0.114 -0.114 -0.115 -0.116 -0.117 -0.118 -0.118 -0.119 -0.119 -0.120 -0.120 -0.121 -0.121 Rank 170 171 172 173 174 175 176 177 178 179 180 181 182 183 184 185 186 187 188 189 190 191 192 193 194 195 196 197 198 199 200 201 202 203 204 205 206 207 208 209 210 211 APPENDIX TABLE A1: LIST OF METROPOLITAN AND NON-METROPOLITAN AREAS RANKED BY TOTAL AMENITY VALUE Full Name of Metropolitan Area Shreveport-Bossier City, LA Muncie, IN Non-metro, IN Non-metro, SC Non-metro, OH Waco, TX Jackson, TN Bangor, ME Decatur, AL Albany, GA Charleston, WV Non-metro, NM Lima, OH Sharon, PA Non-metro, NY Laredo, TX Binghamton, NY Houma, LA Owensboro, KY St. Joseph, MO Florence, SC Non-metro, GA Non-metro, VA Clarksville-Hopkinsville, TN-KY Florence, AL San Angelo, TX Abilene, TX Decatur, IL Lafayette, LA Victoria, TX Alexandria, LA Casper, WY Duluth-Superior, MN-WI Johnson City-Kingsport-Bristol, TN-VA Hattiesburg, MS Utica-Rome, NY Great Falls, MT Elmira, NY Altoona, PA Non-metro, PA El Paso, TX Terre Haute, IN Cumberland, MD-WV Non-metro, IA Non-metro, IL Odessa-Midland, TX Fargo-Moorhead, ND-MN Population 392,302 118,769 1,690,582 1,205,050 2,139,364 213,517 107,377 90,864 145,867 120,822 251,662 783,991 155,084 120,293 1,503,399 193,117 252,320 194,477 91,545 102,490 125,761 2,519,789 1,550,447 207,033 142,950 104,010 126,555 114,706 385,647 84,088 126,337 66,533 243,815 480,091 111,674 299,896 80,357 91,070 129,144 1,889,525 679,622 149,192 102,008 1,600,191 1,877,585 237,132 174,367 Adjusted Differentials Housing Costs Wages -0.115 -0.308 -0.114 -0.304 -0.101 -0.306 -0.135 -0.311 -0.099 -0.306 -0.108 -0.311 -0.080 -0.322 -0.170 -0.324 -0.064 -0.326 -0.082 -0.316 -0.103 -0.331 -0.212 -0.324 -0.087 -0.322 -0.147 -0.319 -0.115 -0.304 -0.200 -0.332 -0.114 -0.313 -0.110 -0.338 -0.136 -0.338 -0.167 -0.335 -0.120 -0.341 -0.140 -0.330 -0.160 -0.334 -0.214 -0.342 -0.142 -0.348 -0.177 -0.348 -0.235 -0.349 -0.053 -0.349 -0.116 -0.356 -0.083 -0.356 -0.171 -0.358 -0.228 -0.366 -0.098 -0.356 -0.179 -0.363 -0.178 -0.364 -0.112 -0.342 -0.307 -0.373 -0.120 -0.345 -0.150 -0.363 -0.135 -0.364 -0.158 -0.369 -0.125 -0.372 -0.167 -0.365 -0.192 -0.381 -0.145 -0.369 -0.121 -0.382 -0.168 -0.382 Land Rents Linear -1.004 -0.989 -1.033 -0.960 -1.041 -1.038 -1.157 -0.921 -1.220 -1.129 -1.133 -0.806 -1.139 -0.963 -0.985 -0.870 -1.028 -1.146 -1.074 -0.976 -1.131 -1.029 -0.992 -0.877 -1.102 -1.006 -0.848 -1.349 -1.207 -1.299 -1.064 -0.941 -1.254 -1.064 -1.071 -1.159 -0.755 -1.148 -1.142 -1.190 -1.148 -1.251 -1.102 -1.105 -1.182 -1.304 -1.174 Quadratic -1.146 -1.126 -1.190 -1.082 -1.202 -1.195 -1.377 -1.023 -1.480 -1.334 -1.332 -0.872 -1.347 -1.083 -1.121 -0.952 -1.179 -1.350 -1.236 -1.096 -1.324 -1.173 -1.118 -0.959 -1.275 -1.132 -0.920 -1.699 -1.438 -1.598 -1.213 -1.038 -1.519 -1.211 -1.221 -1.367 -0.801 -1.348 -1.330 -1.405 -1.336 -1.502 -1.267 -1.264 -1.389 -1.588 -1.370 Quality of Life Value -0.042 -0.043 -0.050 -0.033 -0.052 -0.047 -0.063 -0.018 -0.072 -0.063 -0.052 0.002 -0.062 -0.033 -0.050 -0.008 -0.054 -0.054 -0.041 -0.026 -0.049 -0.040 -0.031 -0.004 -0.042 -0.025 0.004 -0.089 -0.057 -0.074 -0.031 -0.002 -0.069 -0.028 -0.029 -0.064 0.036 -0.061 -0.045 -0.053 -0.041 -0.060 -0.040 -0.027 -0.052 -0.063 -0.039 Rank 201 203 216 253 132 266 255 226 251 176 103 229 230 194 152 223 96 200 149 83 274 236 269 167 91 265 160 161 257 44 245 207 197 244 191 256 190 TradeProductivity Value -0.124 -0.122 -0.113 -0.140 -0.111 -0.118 -0.098 -0.169 -0.085 -0.099 -0.117 -0.202 -0.103 -0.151 -0.123 -0.194 -0.123 -0.123 -0.144 -0.168 -0.131 -0.146 -0.162 -0.206 -0.149 -0.177 -0.223 -0.080 -0.130 -0.104 -0.173 -0.219 -0.116 -0.180 -0.180 -0.125 -0.283 -0.132 -0.158 -0.145 -0.164 -0.139 -0.171 -0.192 -0.154 -0.136 -0.174 Federal Tax Rank Differential 182 -0.021 177 -0.023 -0.019 -0.026 -0.019 171 -0.019 144 -0.010 235 -0.034 132 -0.005 148 -0.014 170 -0.014 -0.046 152 -0.015 222 -0.033 -0.031 256 -0.045 179 -0.030 178 -0.018 214 -0.026 234 -0.036 194 -0.020 -0.031 -0.036 259 -0.049 218 -0.027 244 -0.038 268 -0.055 118 -0.005 193 -0.019 156 -0.010 239 -0.035 265 -0.048 169 -0.018 248 -0.037 247 -0.037 186 -0.028 276 -0.069 198 -0.031 225 -0.032 -0.027 231 -0.031 208 -0.023 238 -0.039 -0.039 -0.032 204 -0.020 240 -0.033 Total Amenity Values Value -0.121 -0.121 -0.122 -0.122 -0.123 -0.123 -0.125 -0.126 -0.126 -0.127 -0.127 -0.127 -0.129 -0.129 -0.129 -0.132 -0.133 -0.133 -0.133 -0.133 -0.133 -0.134 -0.135 -0.136 -0.137 -0.138 -0.139 -0.140 -0.140 -0.140 -0.142 -0.142 -0.143 -0.144 -0.144 -0.144 -0.145 -0.146 -0.146 -0.146 -0.146 -0.148 -0.150 -0.150 -0.150 -0.151 -0.151 Rank 212 213 214 215 216 217 218 219 220 221 222 223 224 225 226 227 228 229 230 231 232 233 234 235 236 237 238 239 240 241 242 243 244 245 246 247 248 APPENDIX TABLE A1: LIST OF METROPOLITAN AND NON-METROPOLITAN AREAS RANKED BY TOTAL AMENITY VALUE Full Name of Metropolitan Area Non-metro, MN Pocatello, ID Columbus, GA-AL Wichita Falls, TX Longview-Marshall, TX Beaumont-Port Arthur, TX Sumter, SC Non-metro, TN Dothan, AL Pine Bluff, AR Danville, VA Sioux City, IA-NE Gadsden, AL Anniston, AL Joplin, MO Fort Smith, AR-OK Enid, OK Non-metro, LA Non-metro, TX Non-metro, WV Non-metro, SD Jonesboro, AR Lawton, OK Wheeling, WV-OH Steubenville-Weirton, OH-WV Jamestown, NY Non-metro, AR Non-metro, KY Grand Forks, ND-MN Parkersburg-Marietta, WV-OH Non-metro, MO Non-metro, NE Huntington-Ashland, WV-KY-OH Non-metro, KS Non-metro, AL Johnstown, PA Texarkana, TX-Texarkana, AR Non-metro, OK Brownsville-Harlingen-San Benito, TX Non-metro, MS Bismarck, ND Non-metro, ND McAllen-Edinburg-Mission, TX Population 1,456,119 75,565 274,624 140,518 208,780 385,090 104,646 1,827,139 137,916 84,278 110,156 124,130 103,459 112,249 157,322 207,290 57,813 1,098,766 3,159,940 1,042,776 493,867 82,148 114,996 153,172 132,008 139,750 1,352,381 2,068,667 97,478 151,237 1,800,410 811,425 315,538 1,167,355 1,338,141 232,621 129,749 1,352,292 335,227 1,820,996 94,719 358,234 569,463 Adjusted Differentials Housing Costs Wages -0.157 -0.367 -0.125 -0.396 -0.140 -0.379 -0.234 -0.383 -0.136 -0.386 -0.035 -0.390 -0.178 -0.388 -0.185 -0.403 -0.181 -0.404 -0.156 -0.416 -0.151 -0.403 -0.147 -0.417 -0.133 -0.421 -0.183 -0.424 -0.254 -0.417 -0.187 -0.433 -0.218 -0.435 -0.167 -0.435 -0.200 -0.442 -0.205 -0.445 -0.291 -0.457 -0.240 -0.452 -0.260 -0.448 -0.178 -0.448 -0.178 -0.448 -0.140 -0.430 -0.238 -0.457 -0.182 -0.456 -0.204 -0.455 -0.153 -0.457 -0.256 -0.456 -0.261 -0.464 -0.160 -0.477 -0.240 -0.469 -0.174 -0.477 -0.190 -0.476 -0.185 -0.498 -0.255 -0.496 -0.211 -0.502 -0.202 -0.517 -0.244 -0.532 -0.260 -0.532 -0.212 -0.570 Land Rents Linear -1.142 -1.355 -1.237 -0.995 -1.280 -1.574 -1.170 -1.219 -1.232 -1.353 -1.312 -1.385 -1.440 -1.314 -1.086 -1.343 -1.267 -1.406 -1.341 -1.345 -1.157 -1.277 -1.204 -1.430 -1.429 -1.459 -1.306 -1.456 -1.387 -1.537 -1.248 -1.271 -1.603 -1.351 -1.568 -1.519 -1.625 -1.424 -1.570 -1.660 -1.610 -1.565 -1.861 Quadratic -1.327 -1.669 -1.473 -1.106 -1.542 -2.147 -1.361 -1.430 -1.450 -1.651 -1.586 -1.708 -1.810 -1.576 -1.223 -1.620 -1.490 -1.733 -1.611 -1.614 -1.310 -1.498 -1.384 -1.767 -1.766 -1.840 -1.541 -1.810 -1.683 -1.975 -1.449 -1.481 -2.098 -1.611 -2.019 -1.917 -2.124 -1.720 -1.998 -2.180 -2.052 -1.959 -2.641 Quality of Life Value -0.047 -0.061 -0.055 -0.008 -0.057 -0.108 -0.037 -0.038 -0.04 -0.053 -0.057 -0.06 -0.069 -0.046 -0.011 -0.045 -0.032 -0.058 -0.043 -0.042 0.001 -0.026 -0.016 -0.058 -0.058 -0.079 -0.028 -0.057 -0.046 -0.072 -0.023 -0.021 -0.074 -0.035 -0.067 -0.062 -0.068 -0.034 -0.057 -0.066 -0.048 -0.041 -0.079 Rank 249 233 102 237 275 185 193 228 239 243 263 209 118 206 173 153 129 240 241 273 208 268 271 250 260 238 221 272 TradeProductivity Value -0.163 -0.141 -0.152 -0.226 -0.149 -0.070 -0.182 -0.189 -0.186 -0.168 -0.163 -0.161 -0.15 -0.19 -0.246 -0.194 -0.219 -0.178 -0.206 -0.21 -0.279 -0.238 -0.253 -0.189 -0.189 -0.157 -0.237 -0.193 -0.21 -0.17 -0.251 -0.256 -0.177 -0.24 -0.189 -0.201 -0.2 -0.255 -0.221 -0.215 -0.25 -0.262 -0.228 Federal Tax Rank Differential -0.037 210 -0.016 223 -0.029 269 -0.053 219 -0.025 107 0.005 249 -0.037 -0.037 250 -0.037 233 -0.025 229 -0.030 226 -0.024 221 -0.021 253 -0.036 272 -0.059 255 -0.034 264 -0.045 -0.031 -0.041 -0.042 -0.062 271 -0.050 274 -0.058 251 -0.035 252 -0.036 224 -0.034 -0.049 -0.035 261 -0.042 237 -0.027 -0.059 -0.057 245 -0.027 -0.053 -0.031 258 -0.039 257 -0.033 -0.054 267 -0.041 -0.037 273 -0.047 -0.052 270 -0.039 Total Amenity Values Value -0.151 -0.152 -0.152 -0.152 -0.152 -0.153 -0.154 -0.159 -0.160 -0.161 -0.162 -0.162 -0.165 -0.168 -0.168 -0.169 -0.172 -0.172 -0.175 -0.176 -0.178 -0.178 -0.178 -0.178 -0.179 -0.180 -0.180 -0.180 -0.180 -0.180 -0.183 -0.184 -0.188 -0.188 -0.188 -0.191 -0.196 -0.197 -0.198 -0.203 -0.208 -0.208 -0.225 Rank 249 250 251 252 253 254 255 256 257 258 259 260 261 262 263 264 265 266 267 268 269 270 271 272 273 274 275 276 State Name APPENDIX TABLE A2: LIST OF STATES RANKED BY TOTAL AMENITY VALUE TradeFederal Adjusted Differentials Land Rents Quality of Life Productivity Tax Housing Differentia Population Wages Linear Quadratic Value Rank Value Rank l Costs Hawaii California New Jersey Connecticut Massachusetts New York Washington Colorado New Hampshire District of Columbia Alaska Maryland Oregon Rhode Island Illinois Nevada Arizona Delaware Utah Florida Vermont Michigan Virginia Wisconsin New Mexico Minnesota Pennsylvania North Carolina Ohio Georgia Maine Indiana Texas Idaho South Carolina Montana Missouri Tennessee Wyoming Louisiana Iowa Kansas Nebraska Alabama Kentucky Arkansas Oklahoma South Dakota West Virginia Mississippi North Dakota 1,211,537 33,871,648 8,414,350 3,405,565 6,349,097 18,976,457 5,894,121 4,301,261 1,235,786 572,059 626,932 5,296,486 3,421,399 1,048,319 12,419,293 1,998,257 5,130,632 783,600 2,233,169 15,982,378 608,827 9,938,444 7,078,515 5,363,675 1,819,046 4,919,479 12,281,054 8,049,313 11,353,140 8,186,453 1,274,923 6,080,485 20,851,820 1,293,953 4,012,012 902,195 5,595,211 5,689,283 493,782 4,468,976 2,926,324 2,688,418 1,711,263 4,447,100 4,041,769 2,673,400 3,450,654 754,844 1,808,344 2,844,658 642,200 -0.015 0.126 0.189 0.165 0.094 0.120 0.026 -0.016 0.033 0.126 0.050 0.110 -0.045 0.021 0.065 0.054 -0.027 0.043 -0.055 -0.060 -0.172 0.051 -0.035 -0.035 -0.148 -0.009 -0.011 -0.084 -0.024 -0.021 -0.160 -0.031 -0.041 -0.148 -0.100 -0.256 -0.106 -0.101 -0.193 -0.104 -0.140 -0.132 -0.174 -0.114 -0.121 -0.185 -0.178 -0.252 -0.161 -0.167 -0.234 0.530 0.458 0.336 0.278 0.251 0.199 0.181 0.172 0.164 0.154 0.130 0.126 0.106 0.082 0.063 0.054 0.019 -0.010 -0.023 -0.036 -0.056 -0.061 -0.085 -0.099 -0.136 -0.134 -0.135 -0.141 -0.143 -0.145 -0.171 -0.168 -0.203 -0.212 -0.214 -0.237 -0.247 -0.249 -0.264 -0.264 -0.293 -0.312 -0.319 -0.318 -0.326 -0.364 -0.369 -0.389 -0.392 -0.427 -0.495 2.311 1.615 0.919 0.737 0.816 0.524 0.706 0.781 0.613 0.314 0.418 0.239 0.579 0.294 0.091 0.082 0.158 -0.159 0.053 0.013 0.232 -0.402 -0.268 -0.328 -0.176 -0.548 -0.549 -0.373 -0.548 -0.562 -0.294 -0.633 -0.754 -0.502 -0.640 -0.313 -0.766 -0.787 -0.599 -0.844 -0.870 -0.975 -0.886 -1.051 -1.066 -1.050 -1.091 -0.974 -1.239 -1.370 -1.478 1.852 1.360 0.832 0.678 0.749 0.416 0.631 0.705 0.566 0.307 0.399 0.229 0.534 0.283 0.025 0.069 0.150 -0.167 0.046 -0.009 0.213 -0.444 -0.313 -0.371 -0.229 -0.629 -0.623 -0.403 -0.614 -0.637 -0.318 -0.730 -0.891 -0.538 -0.713 -0.330 -0.859 -0.899 -0.639 -0.990 -0.986 -1.131 -1.007 -1.264 -1.286 -1.223 -1.269 -1.088 -1.511 -1.738 -1.831 0.182 0.085 0.012 0.006 0.034 0.003 0.046 0.065 0.037 -0.015 0.016 -0.016 0.058 0.016 -0.013 -0.010 0.021 -0.025 0.021 0.020 0.071 -0.047 -0.010 -0.014 0.032 -0.039 -0.039 -0.003 -0.035 -0.037 0.027 -0.039 -0.045 0.007 -0.018 0.055 -0.026 -0.029 0.014 -0.032 -0.024 -0.034 -0.014 -0.046 -0.045 -0.023 -0.029 0.003 -0.045 -0.054 -0.041 1 2 18 20 9 22 7 4 8 . 15 29 5 16 26 25 13 33 12 14 3 49 24 28 10 43 41 23 39 40 11 42 46 19 30 6 34 36 17 37 32 38 27 48 45 31 35 21 47 50 44 0.045 0.148 0.186 0.160 0.101 0.116 0.040 0.006 0.044 0.116 0.054 0.101 -0.024 0.026 0.058 0.048 -0.019 0.033 -0.046 -0.051 -0.142 0.034 -0.036 -0.038 -0.132 -0.021 -0.023 -0.081 -0.034 -0.032 -0.145 -0.043 -0.054 -0.139 -0.102 -0.227 -0.111 -0.107 -0.181 -0.111 -0.142 -0.137 -0.172 -0.124 -0.130 -0.185 -0.181 -0.240 -0.169 -0.178 -0.238 10 3 1 2 5 4 12 16 11 . 8 6 20 15 7 9 17 14 26 27 39 13 23 24 36 18 19 29 22 21 41 25 28 38 30 48 32 31 46 33 40 37 43 34 35 47 45 50 42 44 49 -0.02 0.019 0.039 0.034 0.017 0.025 0.001 -0.01 0.004 0.028 0.009 0.025 -0.015 0.003 0.015 0.012 -0.008 0.011 -0.014 -0.015 -0.043 0.015 -0.006 -0.006 -0.034 0.002 0.001 -0.017 -0.002 -0.001 -0.036 -0.003 -0.005 -0.032 -0.019 -0.059 -0.02 -0.019 -0.042 -0.019 -0.027 -0.025 -0.035 -0.02 -0.021 -0.037 -0.035 -0.053 -0.03 -0.03 -0.046 Total Amenity Values Value Rank 0.211 0.18 0.131 0.108 0.098 0.077 0.072 0.069 0.065 0.059 0.051 0.049 0.043 0.032 0.024 0.021 0.008 -0.005 -0.008 -0.013 -0.02 -0.025 -0.033 -0.039 -0.052 -0.053 -0.054 -0.055 -0.057 -0.057 -0.066 -0.066 -0.08 -0.082 -0.083 -0.09 -0.097 -0.097 -0.102 -0.103 -0.114 -0.122 -0.124 -0.125 -0.128 -0.142 -0.144 -0.151 -0.154 -0.167 -0.193 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 . 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 43 44 45 46 47 48 49 50
© Copyright 2024