2/2015 39 (2) 2015 ARTUR ŚWISTAK, SEBASTIAN WAWRZAK and AGNIESZKA ALIŃSKA In pursuit of tax equity: lessons from VAT rate structure adjustment in Poland ANA KUNDID NOVOKMET Cyclicality of bank capital buffers in South-Eastern Europe: endogenous and exogenous aspects MIRNA DUMIČIĆ Financial stress indicators for small, open, highly euroized countries: the case of Croatia ANA PERIŠIĆ and VANJA WAGNER Development index: analysis of the basic instrument of Croatian regional policy Vol. 39, No. 2 | pp. 115-243 June 2015 | Zagreb udc 336 issn 1846-887x Publisher Institute of Public Finance, Smičiklasova 21, Zagreb, Croatia Editor-in-Chief Katarina Ott Production Editor Marina Nekić Editorial Board (Institute of Public Finance) Marijana Bađun Anto Bajo Predrag Bejaković Vjekoslav Bratić Mihaela Bronić Martina Fabris Katarina Ott Ivica Urban Goran Vukšić Editorial Advisory Board Hrvoje Arbutina (Faculty of Law, Zagreb, Croatia) Will Bartlett (London School of Economics and Political Science, London, UK) Helena Blažić (Faculty of Economics, Rijeka, Croatia) Balázs Égert (OECD, Paris, France) Edgar L. Feige (Professor of Economics Emeritus at the University of Wisconsin, Madison, Wisconsin, USA) Božidar Jelčić (Faculty of Law, Zagreb, Croatia) Evan Kraft (American University, Washington D.C., USA) Peter J. Lambert (University of Oregon, Department of Economics, Eugene, USA) Olivera Lončarić-Horvat (Faculty of Law, Zagreb, Croatia) Dubravko Mihaljek (Bank for International Settlements, Basel, Switzerland) Peter Sanfey (European Bank for Reconstruction and Development, London, UK) Bruno Schönfelder (Technical University Bergakademie Freiberg, Faculty of Economics and Business Administration, Freiberg, Germany) Miroslav Verbič (Faculty of Economics / Institute for Economic Research, Ljubljana, Slovenia) Athanasios Vamvakidis (Bank of America Merrill Lynch, London, UK) Hrvoje Šimović (Faculty of Economics and Business, Zagreb, Croatia) Financial Theory and Practice is abstracted and indexed in: DOAJ (Directory of Open Access Journals, Lund University, Sweden) EBSCO Publishing Database EconLit (American Economic Association’s electronic database), JEL (Journal of Economic Literature, Pittsburgh, Pennsylvania, USA) HRČAK (Portal of Scientific Journals of Croatia) IBSS (International Bibliography of the Social Sciences, ProQuest, Cambridge, UK) RePEc (Research Papers in Economics) Editorial Office Institute of Public Finance – Financial Theory and Practice Smičiklasova 21, Zagreb, Croatia, P.O. BOX 320 phone: +385 (0)1 4886 444; 4819 363; fax: +385 (0)1 4819 365 web-site: www.fintp.hr; e-mail: [email protected] Subscription Annual subscription amounts 400 kuna Payments to account no. HR7024840081100661775, Institut za javne financije, Zagreb; quoting: subscription to Financial Theory and Practice, 2015 Printed in 115 copies The journal comes out four times a year The journal is co-financed by the Ministry of Science, Education and Sport of the Republic of Croatia Computer typesetting and printing Denona d.o.o., Zagreb, Marina Getaldića 1 2/2015 Reviewed scientific journal Vol. 39, No. 2 I pp. 115-243 I June 2015 I Zagreb Financial Theory and Practice publishes scientific articles in the field of public sector economics, and also welcomes submissions of applied and theoretical research papers on a broader set of economic topics such as economic growth and development, the role of institutions, transition to the market economy and EU integration. Empirical analysis is preferably related, but not limited, to the experience of countries in Central and Eastern Europe and Southeast Europe. Submission of papers Submission of a paper will be held to imply that it contains original unpublished work and is not being submitted for publication elsewhere. All papers have to pass through a double blind peer-reviewing process. Guidelines for authors can be found at www.fintp.hr. Financial Theory and Practice is published in accordance with the highest level of professional ethics and standards. Ethical guidelines for journal publication can be found at www.fintp.hr. 2/2015 TABLE OF CONTENTS 115 Articles ARTUR ŚWISTAK, SEBASTIAN WAWRZAK and AGNIESZKA ALIŃSKA In pursuit of tax equity: lessons from VAT rate structure adjustment in Poland 139 ANA KUNDID NOVOKMET Cyclicality of bank capital buffers in South-Eastern Europe: endogenous and exogenous aspects 171 MIRNA DUMIČIĆ Financial stress indicators for small, open, highly euroized countries: the case of Croatia 205 ANA PERIŠIĆ and VANJA WAGNER Development index: analysis of the basic instrument of Croatian regional policy 237 Book review MAJA VEHOVEC (Ed.) Health care from an economic perspective (Anto Bajo) In pursuit of tax equity: lessons from VAT rate structure adjustment in Poland ARTUR ŚWISTAK, M.A., M.P.S., PhD candidate* SEBASTIAN WAWRZAK, M.A., PhD candidate* AGNIESZKA ALIŃSKA, PhD, Assoc. Prof.* Article** JEL: D12, H23, H24, K34 doi: 10.3326/fintp.39.2.1 The authors wish to thank Ruud de Mooji, Francisco Vazquez and Robert Sierhej (all IMF), and three anony mous referees for their valuable comments. All errors and omissions are the authors’ only. Research project is funded by National Science Centre, Poland (Grant No. DEC2013/09/B/HS4/03610). ** Received: May 20, 2014 Accepted: February 15, 2015 * A previous version of this paper was presented at the conference Tax Reforms: Experiences and Perspectives organized by the Institute of Public Finance, Faculty of Economics and Business, Zagreb and Faculty of Eco nomics, Rijeka in Zagreb on June 20, 2014. Artur ŚWISTAK International Monetary Fund, Fiscal Affairs Department, 1900 Pennsylvania Ave NW, Washington, DC 20431, USA email: [email protected] Sebastian WAWRZAK Warsaw School of Economics, al. Niepodległości 162, 02554 Warsaw, Poland email: [email protected] Agnieszka ALIŃSKA Warsaw School of Economics, al. Niepodległości 162, 02554 Warsaw, Poland email: [email protected] 116 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 115-137 (2015) Abstract In 2011, in the aftermath of the economic crisis, Poland increased its value added tax rates. Despite an already large VAT policy gap, further rate differentiation was used to address distributional concerns and to protect the most vulnerable households. We find that the changes to the VAT rate structure hardly improved the overall progressivity of the VAT and the tax system as a whole. While providing only minimal relief to the poor, taxation of food products at a super reduced rate greatly subsidized the richer households. With a small change to the income tax structure, the government could have secured more progressivity at a lower cost in terms of revenue foregone. Keywords: value added tax, household consumption, income distribution, tax progressivity, VAT reduced rates, Polish tax reform experience artur świstak, sebastian wawrzak, agnieszka alińska: in pursuit of tax equity: lessons from vat rate structure adjustment in poland 1 INTRODUCTION The effectiveness of pursuing vertical equity objectives through value added tax (VAT) has been long questioned in economic literature (Cnossen, 1982; Tait, 1988; Ebrill et al., 2001; OECD, 2010). Yet policymakers invariably exhibit a particular liking for VAT rate differentiation. Even if desperate to raise revenue, they seem to prefer to increase the general VAT rate rather than to eliminate reduced rates and exemptions. This is the experience of the EU countries that undertook fiscal consolidation in response to the recent financial crisis (IMF, 2013). Most of them favored outright VAT rate increases over the much advocated base broadening and closing the gap between standard and reduced rates (Garnier et al., 2013). The Polish experience has not been different. While seeking additional revenue the government opted for a universal VAT increase rather than abolition of re duced rates. In 2011 both the standard and the reduced rates were raised by one percentage point. At the same time, the rate on most food products was further lowered thus widening the VAT rate gap. Such rate adjustment was driven by the government desire to protect the most vulnerable and improve the overall progres sivity of the tax regime (PRM, 2010). But the question is raised as to whether pursuing these objectives through VAT is the right policy choice. Can we afford to help the poor by subsidizing the rich? The objective of this paper is to evaluate the distributional impact of the 2011 changes to VAT rate structure in Poland and assess whether the reform was suc cessful in achieving distributional objectives or perhaps there might have been better alternatives to mitigate the impact of general VAT increases. We use data from the household budget survey and estimate the impact of VAT for households across the income distribution for the actual reform and an alternative scenario where the VAT rate on food is not reduced. In our analysis we measure VAT inci dence in two ways: (1) relative to consumption which we take as a proxy for life time income, and (2) against annual income. We use gross rather than disposable income in order to arrive at a comparable benchmark for VAT and income tax burden. 2 VAT AND DISTRIBUTIONAL EQUITY 2.1 OBJECTIVES OF VAT RATE DIFFERENTIATION Value added tax is one of the most popular taxes. In one or another form it has now been implemented worldwide by an overwhelming majority of countries. The ac tual causes and consequences of the spread of VAT have been little investigated empirically (Keen and Lockwood, 2010). Yet countries find it a good replacement to their often obscure and less efficient production, trade or retail sales taxes. Once introduced, VAT becomes an inherent part of tax systems. VAT owes its remarkable popularity to its design. Many features are undeniably appealing. By taxing domestic consumption VAT raises significant amounts of revenue in an efficient and stable manner. On average it raises revenue amounting to seven percent of GDP in high income countries and five percent of GDP in low income countries with an upward trend (Keen, 2013b). It serves as an effective replacement for trade taxes being now successively curtailed due to regional inte gration and ongoing trade liberalization. Most importantly, however, VAT raises revenue without hampering investment and savings. It is also fairly simple in There are only a few instances where it was abolished, e.g. Malta, Vietnam, Grenada; and this happened mostly due to poor planning and implementation, rather than VAT design per se (Grandcolas, 2005). Most of these countries have now reintroduced a form of VAT. Although VAT revenue exhibits a pattern of procyclicality (see Ebeke and Vazquez, 2014) its fluctuation is less pronounced than income taxes. artur świstak, sebastian wawrzak, agnieszka alińska: in pursuit of tax equity: lessons from vat rate structure adjustment in poland The remainder of the paper is divided into three parts. First, we briefly review theoretical aspects of VAT distributional impact, focusing on the rationale and ef fects of rate differentiation as well as measurement of VAT incidence. Then, we describe the Polish VAT structure and performance and explain in greater detail the VAT reform analyzed. Finally, we evaluate changes in VAT redistribution as a result of the reform. financial theory and practice 39 (2) 115-137 (2015) There is no shortage of Polish literature analyzing the redistributive effects of in direct taxes (see for example: Nagel and Neneman, 1995; Radziukiewicz, 2011; Dobrowolska and Starzynska, 2011). Amongst foreign academics, perhaps the first insights into the Polish VAT rate structure and its implications were provided by Cnossen (1998). Only recently, with Poland’s accession to the EU has the cov erage of the equity aspects of VAT in Poland improved. Many academics (e.g. Borselli et al., 2012) and various European institutions (e.g. European Commis sion, 2011) embarked on analyzing the structure, performance and redistributive impact of the Polish VAT, mostly as part of broader and comparative studies. To the best of our knowledge, however, the incidence of the recent adjustments of the VAT rates in Poland has not been subject to a rigorous analysis. This paper is aimed to partially fill this gap. 7 118 terms of compliance. If well designed it has most of the attributes of a “good” tax (IMF, 2011; Bird and Gendron, 2007). financial theory and practice 39 (2) 115-137 (2015) artur świstak, sebastian wawrzak, agnieszka alińska: in pursuit of tax equity: lessons from vat rate structure adjustment in poland Although there are plenty of reasons to praise VAT, its distributional impact raises a lot of concerns amongst policymakers.3 Over the years, VAT has gained a reputa tion as a regressive tax and this perception seems nowhere close to fading away. It does persist, at least at policymaker’s level, and results in various attempts to make VAT a more progressive tax (e.g., Matheson and Swistak, 2014). Rate dif ferentiations and exemptions are used for this purpose. On the surface the policy argument seems to be straightforward – with lower VAT rates on basic products, e.g. food, the poorer households may consume more and their total VAT payments represent a smaller share of their incomes than would be the case if all goods were subject to the standard rate. Yet the richer households also benefit from reduced rates, in absolute terms even more – all at the cost of foregone revenue, efficiency loss and increased complexity (Tait, 1988; IMF, 2011; Matheson and Swistak, 2014). There are only a handful of countries where VAT concessions are hardly used at all, New Zealand and Australia being commonly cited as flagship examples. These are countries with relatively new VATs and they managed to rely on economic and administrative logic rather than cultivating historical and compromised solutions (Cnossen, 2003). This is the experience of most EU member states, where VAT concessions continue to be widespread. Apart from a few notable exceptions, in cluding Bulgaria and Denmark, most European countries rely on them heavily. The list of items commonly subject to reduced rates, including a zerorate, is lengthy and encompasses food products, medicines, housing, books and newspa pers, and many others, not excluding clothing, energy products, and even alco holic beverages. Addressing distributional concerns is not the exclusive reason for the adoption of reduced VAT rates. They are also used, rightly or wrongly, to change the relative prices of goods and services and steer consumption in a direction conforming to other policy objectives. For example, lower taxation of labor intensive services in the EU, e.g. hairdressers, window cleaning or repair services, was meant to in crease demand for these services, mostly selfsupplied at home rather than pro cured in the market, and thus boost employment (Copenhagen Economics, 2007). Norway used VAT rate differentiation to promote healthier diets (Gustavsen and Rickertsen, 2013). Many countries tax merit goods and services, e.g. medicines, textbooks, sport and cultural services, at a lower level (or exempt them) to encour age their consumption, as being in public interest and benefiting the whole society. Similarly, rate differentiation is used to correct externalities by way of applying reduced rates to energysaving appliances (OECD, 2010). The justification for The other Achilles heel of VAT is the need for refunds of excess credits. In many countries, especially devel oping ones where the tax administration capacity is low, this feature of VAT raises a lot of concerns. 3 2.2 VAT INCIDENCE In theory a uniform and comprehensive VAT imposes a flat burden on all con sumption expenditure (Tait, 1988). In this sense, VAT is proportional – all taxpay ers give up an equal share of their consumption to pay the tax. This is true regard less of their personal characteristics, consumption preferences or even source of income used to finance their spending. Whether they are rich or poor, single or with dependents, healthy or disabled all taxpayers forego a fixed percentage of their private spending to meet the VAT liability. The same holds true whether they buy staple food or lavish meals in expensive restaurants, rely on private cars or use public transport, rent or buy a house. Under a broadbased and uniform VAT, all taxpayers – as long as they spend – are equally burdened with VAT. Neverthe less, in practice achieving proportional distribution is hardly possible, for even under a welldesigned VAT a portion of spending escapes taxation.6 The actual distribution of VAT payments is, nevertheless, very sensitive to the rate structure and exemptions built into the VAT and to the patterns of consumer pref erences (Ebrill et al., 2001). Relative to consumption the use of preferences may make VAT a progressive tax. In such a setting the share of VAT payment rises with 4 The Romanian authorities are currently looking to apply the same reduction to meat products to counter act fictitious imports and tax evasion in the meat industry (see news by Simona Bazavan on: http://business review.eu/featured/romanianauthoritiesconsidercuttingthevatformeatproductsto9pct/). 5 The third possibility – at least in theory – would be to test VAT incidence against wealth. This discussion, however, goes beyond the scope of the paper. 6 This happens for administrative reasons, e.g. exemption of small traders as a result of the VAT threshold. Such a design benefits mostly low income households as they are more likely to buy from nontaxed small businesses. They are also more likely to buy from individuals (e.g. used goods) and informal businesses. artur świstak, sebastian wawrzak, agnieszka alińska: in pursuit of tax equity: lessons from vat rate structure adjustment in poland The focal point of the discussion of the vertical equity of VAT is the question of who bears the burden. Fairness requires taxes to take into account the taxpayers’ ability to pay, hence implying that the share of income taken in taxes increases as income rises (progressivity). Even though such a statement may be difficult to defend on efficiency grounds this is a strong political expectation: taxes should be progressive or at least not regressive. Measuring progressivity of VAT is challeng ing. The notion of income redistribution would imply that VAT incidence should be tested against income. Yet the VAT base is consumption and not income. Should the VAT incidence be assessed against consumption, as the nature of the tax im plies, or income, as the incidence theory suggests? Below we briefly review con ceptual arguments for using both metrics.5 119 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 115-137 (2015) VAT reduced rates is also offered on administrative grounds. Some countries, e.g. France, the Netherlands, and Poland, tax construction services related to renova tion and maintenance of private dwellings at a reduced rate, and others, e.g. Ice land, effectively zerorate them through reimbursement of VAT paid on such serv ices, with a view, at least partially, to counteracting tax evasion in the construction sector. In 2013 Romania reduced its VAT rate on bakery products on the very same grounds – to tackle tax evasion.4 0 the level of consumption as better off households spend more on fully taxed goods and services than those less affluent, where their spending on lightly taxed or zero rated basic products, e.g. food, constitutes a large proportion of their consump tion. financial theory and practice 39 (2) 115-137 (2015) An intuitive approach to the measurement of the distributional impact of any tax, including a VAT, would be to use income as denominator. Early empirical studies, including those by Musgrave et al. (1974) or Pechman (1985), favored the annual incidence approach, similar to that used for income tax evaluation. Such an ap proach renders VAT a regressive tax. This is inevitable. As poorer households save little and consume higher shares of their current income, VAT accounts for a larger proportion of their earnings than the VAT paid by the rich. artur świstak, sebastian wawrzak, agnieszka alińska: in pursuit of tax equity: lessons from vat rate structure adjustment in poland Some argue, however, that measurement of VAT incidence against annual income is misleading (Gaspersen and Metcalf, 1994; Metcalf, 1997; Creedy, 1998). This is because, in line with permanent income hypothesis and lifecycle considera tions (Friedman, 1957), income levels tend to vary over time, with young and old households earning low incomes and middle aged households disproportionally higher, i.e. high enough to pay back past borrowing and save for future consump tion. In anticipation of future changes in income levels households prefer to smooth their consumption so it is higher than income in the early years of a life time cycle, lower in the middle and again higher at the end. In theory, given the above considerations, one could argue that all income is con sumed over the lifetime. From this perspective any consumption tax, including VAT, is a proportional tax (Gaspersen and Metcalf, 1994; Athreya and Reilly, 2009). When rate differentiation is used the incidence of VAT shifts towards richer consumers as they tend to consume more goods and services taxed at a standard rate. Using the lifetime incidence Decoster et al. (2010) find that actual VATs in a number of European countries are slightly progressive. The same approach has been used in a number of individual VAT studies. For example, Arsic and Altipar makov (2013) show that Serbian VAT is proportional. The same results may be found in Slintakova and Klazar (2010) for the Czech Republic, and in Braz and Correia da Cunha (2009) for Portugal. Proponents of the lifetime approach argue that measuring VAT incidence at any given point in the lifecycle renders blurred results. In a lifetime sense, neither young nor old households are poor nor are highearners rich at their peak. Since consumption fluctuates less from year to year than income it is a better measure of household wellbeing than total annual income and constitutes a good proxy for its lifetime income (Poterba, 1989). This reinforces the logic, mentioned above, that incidence of consumption taxes should be measured against their base – con sumption. 2.3 VAT AND INCOME TAX Value added tax, as an in rem and not personal consumption tax, is ill suited to pursue progressivity. Fortunately, VAT is not the only element of the tax system and its distributional impact should not be analyzed in isolation. If one is con cerned about fairness of taxation as a whole then an assessment of the overall im pact of taxes on income distribution should be made. An income tax, whose inci dence is usually measured on annual basis, is an obvious candidate. The inherent regressivity of a broadbased and singlerated VAT may be mitigated by progres sive personal income taxes. We show this correlation in a stylized way in figure 1. All things being equal both taxpayers and governments are indifferent to the form in which taxes are raised. What is important is the change in disposable income as a consequence of overall taxation. As income level rises, a smaller proportion of income is taken in VAT but this is counterbalanced by higher shares of personal income tax, making the tax system progressive. As argued in Atkinson and Stiglitz (1976) and Cnossen (1982) as long as a country can flexibly choose the rate struc ture under the personal income tax, then it has no reason to choose differential tax rates on the consumption of different goods and services.7 Such argumentation 7 In addition, progressivity of the tax system may be further enhanced by welldesigned property taxes and government transfers. artur świstak, sebastian wawrzak, agnieszka alińska: in pursuit of tax equity: lessons from vat rate structure adjustment in poland Finally and most importantly, the political economy argument has to be taken into account. The lifetime approach has a long horizon which is not attractive to poli cymakers and taxpayers. It hinges on the assumption that the incomes of younger households grow and exceed their needs in middle age allowing for savings to be used towards the end of the life cycle. This is too optimistic to convince currently poor individuals, with low skills, productivity and thus little potential for increased future earnings. It is not difficult to argue that the poor need help when they face life hurdles. And the governments provide it – either through transfers from the budget or taxation. Interestingly, in defining the beneficiaries of social programs, e.g. family allowances, housing benefits, etc., countries tend to rely on an annual income test. Income taxes are also annual – the tax scale is applicable to annual income and most of the allowances and credits apply annual ceilings. Examples where carryforward or carryback are used to smooth personal income over years are scarce. Given the above it is more reasonable to measure the incidence of consumption taxes against annual income. financial theory and practice 39 (2) 115-137 (2015) Unfortunately, lifetime income or consumption incidence does not seem to be ap pealing to policymakers. Indeed, not all households use up all their lifetime in come and much of it is passed on to the next generations in bequests. In welfare states, not all households rely exclusively on their own income and later on their savings – a system of benefits and state funded pensions plays a significant role. Also, households’ sizes and compositions change over time and it is hardly pos sible to have a household that follows the lifecycle of an earning individual. financial theory and practice 39 (2) 115-137 (2015) implies that income tax is an effective instrument of redistribution, which may not necessarily be true (Bird, 1987), as many poor individuals do not pay income taxes and the rich derive their wealth from nonwage income and usually escape progressive taxation.8 Yet, the same may be true for VAT. The poor, with no or little income, either do not participate in monetized economy or buy from infor mal or small businesses and thus pay little or no VAT. In turn, the rich may avoid part of the VAT burden by claiming their private consumption as business inputs (e.g. cars, accommodation, computer equipment and software, etc.) or exploit crosscountry rate differentiations and partly consume in lowertaxed jurisdictions (e.g. tourism, wellness and beauty, high tech devices, etc.). After all, in the case of the extremely rich, both income and consumption taxes fail to take a fair share of their annual incomes. artur świstak, sebastian wawrzak, agnieszka alińska: in pursuit of tax equity: lessons from vat rate structure adjustment in poland Figure 1 Stylized correlation of PIT and VAT incidence Tax burden Household income level PIT VAT Total Source: Authors. Although we give due credit to the imperfections of income taxes in addressing distributional concerns, we argue that it is a better way of attaining progressivity in the tax system than using rate differentiation under VAT. Our argument for a uniform VAT rate structure is the poor targeting and the concomitant unnecessary revenue loss due to rate differentiation; in addition, there are the complexities and costliness of VAT compliance and administration involved with differentiated rates. If a specific good is taxed at a lower rate, say, fruit and vegetables, bakery products or children’s clothing, such a good becomes more affordable to the poor and they pay less in VAT. But the more affluent households also benefit from this measure, even more in absolute terms. This translates into significant revenue loss and/or higher taxes elsewhere to make up for the revenue loss. In order to alleviate the plight of the poor, governments agree to give even higher tax relief to rich For example, in Poland, business and capital income are taxed at a flat rate of 19 percent, whereas labor income is subject to progressive tax rates. 8 Also, efforts required for a proper delineation between standard and lower taxed goods (e.g. children’s and adult clothing) drive up compliance and administration costs. Equity gains, once again, are likely to be outweighed by the increased ad ministration costs resulting from cost of interpretation, classification rules, issu ance of advanced rulings, complex filing, audits, disputes, etc.9 3.1 VAT STRUCTURE AND REFORM OVERVIEW After reviewing theoretical considerations on the redistributive effects of VAT we turn now to an incidence analysis of Polish VAT. Our focus will be on the distri butional impact of the 2011 adjustments to the VAT rate structure. We begin with a brief overview of VAT structure and performance, present details of the VAT reform and follow with our findings. Value added tax is the main source of government revenues for Poland, account ing for almost 44 percent of total tax collection. In 2011 it raised PLN 120.8 bil lion (USD 40.8 billion0) which totaled to 8.1 percent of GDP, around the average for EU member states. The revenue performance, measured as a ratio of actual and theoretical VAT collections, at only 45 percent in 2011, was one of the lowest in the EU though (EU, 2013). One of the reasons for the relatively wide VAT gap is the rate structure. Borselli et al. (2012) estimates that more than 40 percent of final consumption is subject to reduced rates, bringing down the effective VAT to less than 15 percent, only twothirds of the standard rate of 23 percent. Data from annual tax expenditure budgets prepared by the Polish Ministry of Fi nance confirms the generosity of VAT (MF, 2013). In 2011 they amounted to PLN 41.1 billion (or USD 13.9 billion), i.e. 2.7 percent of GDP and 34 percent of ac In 2013 alone, the Polish tax administration issued over 2,000 advanced rulings regarding the application of the VAT rate. Inquiries for interpretation or clarification included the application of a proper VAT rate to take away meals, furniture assembling, certain construction services performed in dwellings, drinks with addi tion of coffee, latex gloves, magazine and CD/DVD bundles, etc. (Data received from Ministry of Finance, Poland.) 0 All PLN values cited in this paper were converted into USD at PLN/USD exchange rate at 2.96 (average for 2011). Assumes total final consumption taxed at standard VAT rate and perfect tax compliance (no evasion). The other important reasons are exemptions and tax compliance. The recent European Commission study on VAT compliance gap found that in 2011 Poland lost 15 percent of their VAT (theoretical tax liability of VAT as legislated) due to imperfect tax compliance (EC, 2013). 9 artur świstak, sebastian wawrzak, agnieszka alińska: in pursuit of tax equity: lessons from vat rate structure adjustment in poland 3 REDISTRIBUTIVE IMPACT OF VAT RATE DIFFERENTIATION IN POLAND 123 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 115-137 (2015) taxpayers, an odd and costly manner of injecting progressivity into the tax system. Adoption of reduced rates could yield equitable results only if applied to goods and services whose absolute consumption falls as income rises. Given the conver gence of consumption patterns across all income levels, there are not many obvi ous candidates. Staple food, like rice, potatoes or flour may potentially conform to such a pattern. 124 tual VAT collections.13 The highest contributors to the overall value of tax expen ditures in the VAT were residential construction services, food products and med icines. Among the food products the most costly were meat, dairy and bakery, totaling respectively to PLN 2.9 billion (USD 1 billion), PLN 1.7 billion (USD 0.6 billion) and PLN 1.1 billion (USD 0.4 billion). financial theory and practice 39 (2) 115-137 (2015) artur świstak, sebastian wawrzak, agnieszka alińska: in pursuit of tax equity: lessons from vat rate structure adjustment in poland Unlike revenue performance, the stability of rates has long been a signature fea ture of the Polish VAT, putting it at the forefront of the EU member states (see EC, 2014). On its adoption in mid1993 VAT in Poland was imposed at the standard rate of 22 percent. A number of goods and services, including certain food prod ucts, clothing and accessories for children, energy products for household con sumption, telecommunication services and construction materials were taxed at a lower seven percent rate. In 2000, a second reduced rate of three percent was adopted to encompass previously exempted basic food products. Upon accession to the EU the list of goods and services subject to reduced rates as well as to ex emptions was further revised. In spite of such reshuffling the main rates, however, remained unchanged. Not until 2011, faced with the need to constrain public debt, did Poland decide to increase VAT rates. The adjustments of VAT rates were twofold. The standard and reduced rates rose by one percentage point – from 22 to 23 percent and from seven to eight percent respectively. The VAT increases coincided with the expiry of the preaccession derogatory regime. The concessional zerorate on books and periodicals (not newspapers) and the three percent rate on certain unprocessed food items, as being below the EU minimum of five percent required by the VAT Directive, were doomed for increases. The government, rather than use the re duced rate already in place decided to introduce a new one – a super reduced rate of five percent. Most of the food products, previously subject to the higher re duced rate (now at eight percent) were moved to the new lower five percent rate. Interestingly, the government, even though faced with the need to collect more tax revenues, did not decide to rely on only one reduced rate, let alone abolishing re duced rates altogether. Adoption of the super reduced rate of five percent, compro mising VAT revenue productivity, contradicted the objective of general VAT in creases. Such a policy choice was geared to address equity concerns and improve progressivity of VAT. As stated in the justification to the bill introducing new rates, it was the Government’s desire to alleviate the impact of VAT increases on the poorer households via lower taxation of food which “constitutes significant part of spending by the less affluent part of the society” (PRM, 2010). The Gov ernment chose to achieve this explicitly by way of rate differentiation, a three 13 The actual cost of revenue foregone may be in fact higher since – in line with the adopted benchmark – only such VAT concession were considered to be a tax expenditure that deviates from the standard VAT design as provided in the EU VAT Directive. Hence, for example most of exemptions granted to services provided in public interest (e.g. public bodies, postal, broadcasting or social services) and financial, including insurance, services were not seen as VAT concessions and thus not estimated. percentage points lower taxation of food. No corresponding measures on the reve nue side were proposed and adopted. financial theory and practice 39 (2) 115-137 (2015) Such a policy was not conceptually different from the approach taken in the past when reduced rates on Internet services and construction materials were abol ished. In every single case it was an explicit government desire to correct the distributional impact of VAT rate changes and the only differences was in the choice of measures for achieving that. Table 1 summarizes the VAT changes and the corresponding compensating measures. 125 Table 1 Summary of VAT rate changes and compensating measures in Poland Year 2008 0 Compensating measure Income tax allowance of PLN 760 (USD 257) per year Cash rebate equal to 12.3 percent of Repealing of reduced rate spending on construction materials on construction materials previously taxed at a reduced rate Standard and reduced rate increased VAT rate on food products lowered by one percentage point (from 22 by three percentage points (from eight and 7 to 23 and 8 percent, respectively) to five percent) Source: Polish legislation (available at: www.orka.sejm.gov.pl). In the next two sections, we analyze the 2011 adjustments to the VAT rate struc ture. For simplicity we call these adjustments a “reform” though such a policy measure falls short of a genuine tax reform. Like the other changes to VAT rates listed in table 1, it appears to be merely a oneoff adjustment mitigating the effects of VAT increases, triggered either by revenue needs or solely by the ongoing tax harmonization. 3.2 DATA AND METHODOLOGY We take a very simple approach to our analysis. First, using data from 2011 house hold budget survey, compiled by the Central Statistical Office of Poland (Główny Urząd Statystyczny – GUS), we estimate the VAT burdens for households at differ ent income levels. First VAT burden (Bc) is measured against lifetime income using consumption as a proxy: (1) where: Tvd denotes monthly amount of VAT paid by households from a given decile group (d), Cd denotes monthly consumption spending by households from a given decile group (d), artur świstak, sebastian wawrzak, agnieszka alińska: in pursuit of tax equity: lessons from vat rate structure adjustment in poland 2004 VAT rate change Repealing of reduced rate on Internet access services 126 d represents decile group from 1 to 10. Then VAT burden (Bi) is measured against annual gross income (GI): (2) financial theory and practice 39 (2) 115-137 (2015) The data set we obtained presents monthly consumption expenditure compiled from 37,584 representative households on a quarterly rotation basis. The survey excludes spending on purchases of residential property14, formally treated as in vestment spending. artur świstak, sebastian wawrzak, agnieszka alińska: in pursuit of tax equity: lessons from vat rate structure adjustment in poland The detailed information on consumption spending allows us to assign a VAT rate applicable to a given expenditure item and calculate the amount of tax. In cases where it was not readily apparent what rate (or exemption) should be used we made necessary assumptions and apportionment. For example, data on bread con sumption does not allow for immediate distinction between fresh bread, defined as bread to be consumed within 14 days and taxed at five percent, and nonperishable bread with an expiration date longer than 14 days, taxed at eight percent. An im portant caveat has to be made here. Since the household budget survey does not allow us to establish from where all the goods and services were procured we as sume that all nonexempt items are taxable. This does not necessarily have to be true, as part of the spending, especially on grocery, takes place at small establish ments and greenmarkets, not to mention informal businesses, and as such is ex empt. For the lack of data we did not make an attempt to correct those values and acknowledge that such an approach may overstate the actual VAT burden for the poorer households, as they are more likely to buy from nontaxed suppliers. In cases where consumption items are exempt from VAT, e.g. healthcare services, we assume that VAT paid on inputs is passed through to consumers in the final price of the exempt good or service. To derive the amount of VAT, for simplicity, we assume that taxable inputs constitute 40 percent of the final price and they all carry VAT at the standard rate.15 Taking these assumptions into account the amount of tax (Tvd) is derived as follows: (3) where: βd denotes the share of total consumption (Cd) subject to the standard VAT rate (sr), reduced VAT rate (rr), super reduced VAT rate (srr) or exempt from VAT (e), r denotes the applicable VAT rate – standard (sr), reduced (rr), or super re duced (srr). Although this category includes spending on newly built houses and apartments, which are subject to VAT in Poland, it does not critically impact our analysis for the 2011 VAT reform as it entailed changes in taxation of food products and a few merit goods. Nevertheless, on an aggregate level, it understates the VAT burden falling mostly on the rich and not the poor who usually selfbuild. 15 The rigorous approach would dictate to use supplyuse (or inputoutput) tables to approximate for the value of input VAT. 14 Since incomes reported in the household budget survey for each decile are net amounts (NI), we calculate the gross (pretax) income (GI) that it would be neces sary to earn, the difference being the amount of tax paid (Ti). 7 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 115-137 (2015) For measurement of the VAT burden against annual income we choose to rely on gross rather than net income. Gross income is the most sterile benchmark availa ble and allows for comparisons of burdens generated by different taxes. Such an approach is motivated by a belief that taxes are interchangeable and this is the overall tax burden that matters for taxpayers.16 Reliance on disposable income, already adjusted for income tax payments, blurs and – in general – inflates the actual incidence of VAT. (4) (5) where: SSCd denotes the amount of social security contributions, HCd denotes the amount of health contributions, ITd denotes income tax payment. Since (6) and (7) and (8) where: rssc denotes the rate of social security contributions, rhc denotes the rate of health contribution, rit denotes the applicable rate of income tax, A is the amount of personal basic tax allowance, γ denotes the share of health contribution allowed for deduction against in come tax, CTC is the amount of child tax credit. Naturally, the two general taxes – PIT and VAT – are not the only taxes falling on households. There are other, including property taxes and excise taxes, but these are ignored. The analysis of the progressivity is also limited to the tax system only and all government transfers aimed at helping the poor, e.g. family bene fits, unemployment benefits, disability benefits, are not taken into account. 16 artur świstak, sebastian wawrzak, agnieszka alińska: in pursuit of tax equity: lessons from vat rate structure adjustment in poland Two important qualifications apply. First, all income received by a household is labor income taxed at progressive rates (18 and 32 percent) with a basic tax allow ance. Second, social security and health contributions are treated as taxes and form part of a tax wedge. This approach is not different from OECD Taxing Wages (OECD, 2013a) methodology and the European Commission and Eurostat’s Taxation Trends publications (EU, 2013). This implies: 128 Equation (4) may be transformed as follows: (9) financial theory and practice 39 (2) 115-137 (2015) artur świstak, sebastian wawrzak, agnieszka alińska: in pursuit of tax equity: lessons from vat rate structure adjustment in poland To derive the amount of gross income and tax paid we use a simple Excelbased micro simulation technique, similar to that employed by the OECD for estimates of the tax burden in Taxing Wages (OECD, 2013b). In calculation of income tax we made the following assumptions. Each wage earner has only one job and lives and works in the same city. Each works throughout the whole year and has no sick or maternity/paternity absence, nor does he or she benefit from any other social support. If there are children in a household the earning parent(s) live with them and have the right to benefit from the child tax credit. A loneparent allowance, but not family cash allowance7, is included in the calculation where applicable. If there are two working adults in a household they are deemed a married couple and are taxed jointly. Unless specifically indicated, no tax allowances and further de ductions are used. All income is earned in Poland and does not escape taxation. Both data on expenditure and income are reported for one person. To arrive at household income and expenditure we use the modified OECD equivalent scale, which attributes a weight of 1 to the first household member, 0.5 to the remaining members over 14 years old and 0.3 to each child (below 14 years old). Calculations for VAT and PIT tax burden are performed for a number of different households: (1) single adult household, (2) a married couple with two children, (3) a married couple with one child, and (4) a single parent household – one adult and one child. It is assumed that all the adults work and children do not. To evaluate the distributional impact of the reform we compare two rate structures – the actual and a potential one, i.e. one the government could have chosen in the absence of equity concerns. The actual structure, as implemented in 2011, oper ates a standard rate of 23 percent, reduced rate of 8 percent and super reduced rate of 5 percent, applicable to food products and a few merit goods (actual scenario). The potential rate structure operates only two rates – 23 percent and the reduced 8 percent, implying that the government chooses not to “improve” VAT incidence (base scenario). VATexempt consumption is kept constant in our calculations. We use the same consumption dataset for both scenarios. Our analysis is therefore static and it does not take into account any behavioral response to changes in the level of taxation. Also, a full passthrough of VAT burden in consumer prices is assumed. Family cash allowance is a social subsidy available to families with children, having very low income per family member. It is not a tax measure. 7 3.3 FINDINGS The 0 VAT rate structure adjustment only slightly improved the progressivity of VAT – measured against both lifetime and annual income. It did so at a very high cost to the budget. While providing only minimal relief to the poor it greatly subsidized the richer households. 18.5 -0.0 -0.1 18.0 -0.2 -0.3 17.5 -0.4 17.0 -0.5 -0.6 16.5 -0.7 16.0 -0.8 -0.9 15.5 <10% 10- Base scenario 20- 30- 40- Actual scenario 50- 60- 70- 80- >90% Change in effective VAT rate (right axis) Source: 2011 Household Budget Survey, GUS, Authors’ calculations. Annual income incidence analysis renders similar results. In line with expecta tions our calculations confirm that the Polish VAT is regressive and the 2011 re form only slightly improved its income redistribution. The adoption of a 5 percent rate brought the VAT burden down by 1.2 percentage points for the first income decile and by 0.2 percentage points for the highest. Although the balance tips to the poorest the VAT remained a regressive tax. In figure 3 we show the shift in the overall burden of VAT measured against gross income. We do not plot results for Interdecile comparisons between first and last income decile may blur the results due to the pronounced impact of exemptions. The highest income decile consumes disproportionally more exempt services (i.e. health, recreation, culture), thus benefiting more than the poorer households. Bearing in mind that our analysis regards reduced rates we do not consider any changes in exemptions and keep it constant in our calculations. 18 artur świstak, sebastian wawrzak, agnieszka alińska: in pursuit of tax equity: lessons from vat rate structure adjustment in poland Figure 2 VAT distribution measured against consumption (%) financial theory and practice 39 (2) 115-137 (2015) In the base scenario, i.e. without lowering the tax rate on food, the average VAT rate amounts to 17.8 percent. Lower taxation of food brought this rate down to 17.2 percent and benefited mostly the poor – the lowest income decile gained 0.84 and the highest 0.38 percentage points. In this sense the reform was progressive. However, the reform did not significantly change the overall VAT incidence meas ured against annual consumption (as a proxy for lifetime income). As we show in figure 2 the actual reform only slightly tipped the balance of VAT burden towards the richer households – the ninth income decile paid 1 percentage point more in VAT than the first one. In the base scenario this difference would be only 0.6 per centage point.18 129 130 the first income decile for presentational purposes only. We will include it in fur ther analysis and discussion. Figure 3 VAT distribution measured against gross income (%)* financial theory and practice 39 (2) 115-137 (2015) 15 14 13 12 11 10 artur świstak, sebastian wawrzak, agnieszka alińska: in pursuit of tax equity: lessons from vat rate structure adjustment in poland 9 8 10- 20- 30- 40Base scenario 50- 60- 70- 80- >90% Actual VAT * Gross income of a household composed of two working adults and two children below 14 years old. Source: 2011 Household Budget Survey, GUS, authors’ calculations. As argued earlier, VAT is just another tax paid by households, and should be ana lyzed together with their income tax payments. Our calculations show that distri bution of the overall tax wedge, i.e. ratio of tax payments and gross income, to a large extent hinges on the income tax burden. This implies that in an annual per spective VAT regressivity is counterbalanced by income taxes, especially for the richer part of society (last five income deciles). Since the income tax provides for a number of familyrelated tax preferences – joint taxation of spouses, joint taxa tion of single parents and their not working children (loneparent allowance) and child tax credits – the degree to which the VAT burden is corrected by income taxation depends on household composition. In figure 4 we present income tax and VAT distribution for four classes of households: a single adult, single parent with a child, a married couple with two children, and a married couple with one child. In addition, as previously, we plot in the effect of 2011 VAT reform as a hypothetical addition to the actual tax burden. As can be seen in figure 4, VAT disproportionally burdens households in the first income decile, regardless of their composition. These results are not surprising, given that the consumption, as reported in the household budget survey, exceeds almost twice the income of households in the first decile. There are two important remarks to make. First, as noted in the literature (e.g. Arsic and Altiparmakov, 2013), data for this group is often subject to measurement errors, implying that actual income may be higher. Second, as we already noted, a significant portion of consumption spending by the poorest households is not subject to VAT, implying that their actual VAT payments may be lower than our calculations indicate. 50 1 Adult 45 45 40 40 35 35 30 30 25 25 50 <10% 10- 20- 30- 40- 50- 60- 70- 80- >90% 1 Adult 1 Child 20 45 40 40 35 35 30 30 25 25 <10% 10- 20- 30- 40- 50- 60- 70- 80- >90% VAT Addition (Base scenario) 2 Adults 2 Children 50 45 20 <10% 10- 20- 30- 40- 50- 60- 70- 80- >90% 20 <10% 10- 20- 30- 40- 50- 60- 70- 80- >90% VAT (Actual) Income Tax Source: 2011 Household Budget Survey, GUS, authors’ calculations. Finally, bearing in mind that the objective of this paper is to evaluate the 2011 VAT reform, we should note that regardless of the class of household the gain from 5 percent VAT rate did not significantly alter the overall tax burden house holds face. A small adjustment to the income tax structure could yield better re sults in terms of tax distribution than lowering VAT on food consumption. Whatever the addition to VAT progressivity through lower VAT rates it is clear from our analysis that they benefit households across all income levels. The 2011 reform aggravated this. In absolute terms (dollar value) most benefits of the re form accrued to the rich households. On average the lowest income decile saved in VAT payments PLN 47.24 (USD 15.96) per annum, whereas the highest income decile gained more than twice this amount – PLN 101.23 (USD 34.20). We show the results in figure 5 below. artur świstak, sebastian wawrzak, agnieszka alińska: in pursuit of tax equity: lessons from vat rate structure adjustment in poland 20 2 Adults 1 Child 50 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 115-137 (2015) Figure 4 Overall tax wedge faced by different classes of households (%) 131 132 Figure 5 Gains from 2011 VAT Reform (left axis in USD, right axis in percent) financial theory and practice 39 (2) 115-137 (2015) 40 1.8 35 1.6 30 1.4 1.2 25 1.0 20 0.8 15 0.6 10 0.4 5 0.2 0 <10% 10- 20- artur świstak, sebastian wawrzak, agnieszka alińska: in pursuit of tax equity: lessons from vat rate structure adjustment in poland VAT gain (left axis) 30- 40- 50- 60- 70- Share of income 80- >90% 0.0 Share of consumption Source: 2011 Household budget survey, GUS, authors’ calculations. The cost of the reform, what we estimate to be at around PLN 2.6 billion (USD 0.9 billion) or 0.2 percent of GDP, brought down the VAT revenue by 3.2 percent, as compared with the base scenario. Most of the revenue the government decided to forego to help the poor accrued to higher income households. The poorer part of the society (first three income deciles) benefited by 22 percent and the richer (last three income deciles) by 39 percent of the total revenue foregone. Bearing in mind that those poorer households procure their food products from nontaxed suppliers (greenmarkets, small traders or informal businesses) more often than the richer ones, their benefits from the reform are even smaller than indicated by our calcula tions. The consumption patterns provide valuable insights into VAT’s inability to ad dress distributional equity concerns. In Poland they do not deviate from the pre dictions of economic theory. Total consumption of households increases as their disposable income rises. In line with this the basket of goods and services pro cured changes – the share of spending on food and other essentials (e.g. energy, cold water) declines and expenditure on durable goods, e.g. means of transport and various services, including tourism, recreation, restaurants, culture, educa tion, rises. In figure 6 we show changes in consumption of chosen classes of goods and services. In absolute terms, with only a few exceptions, food spending increases. It merely represents a lower share of their incomes and total consumption basket. The low est income decile spent PLN 171.22 (USD 57.85) monthly for food and nonalco holic drinks, which represented 36.4 percent of total consumption, whereas the highest decile spent more than twice this amount – PLN 371.65 (USD 125.56) accounting for only 16.7 percent of total spending. The interdecile ratio of abso lute spending is not uniform for all food items. The sharpest increase in consump Figure 6 Share of consumption for selected classes of goods and services (%) 40 133 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 115-137 (2015) tion may be observed, amongst other, for fish, tropical fruit, fruit juices, mineral water, chocolate and butter. Spending on bread, milk and certain vegetables is fairly constant and there are only a few items where it declined, potatoes and sugar being the most prominent ones. This dooms any efforts to improve progres sivity of taxation through reduced VAT rates to ineffectiveness, at least it terms of revenue. 35 30 20 15 10 5 0 <10% 10- 20- 30- 40- 50- 60- 70- 80- >90% Percentile of adult equivalent net income Food Clothing and footwear Recreation and culture Transport Restaurants and hotels Source: 2011 Household Budget Survey, GUS, authors’ calculations. 4 CONCLUSIONS Polish society is not egalitarian but income inequality is smaller than in many other OECD countries. With an after tax Gini coefficient at 0.3 in 2010 equity is sues, as it seems, should not be a major concern. Yet Poland in 2011, while in creasing VAT by 1 percentage point, as part of its fiscal consolidation effort, de cided to lower its rate on food and a few merit goods – from 8 to 5 percent – to ease the tax burden for the poor. No other mitigating measures, either through in come tax or on the spending side, were adopted. We find that the 2011 VAT reform only slightly improved the distribution of VAT and the overall progressivity of the tax system. It did so at a very high cost to the budget. While providing only minimal relief to the poor it greatly subsidized richer households. The three last income deciles gained as much as 39 percent of the total benefits of the reform which – in terms of revenue forgone – we estimated at PLN 2.6 billion (USD 0.9 billion) or 0.2 percent of GDP. The three first income deciles benefited only 22 percent of this amount with all the likelihood for this number to be even lower as poorer households more often than richer buy from nontaxed suppliers, including greenmarkets, small traders and informal businesses. artur świstak, sebastian wawrzak, agnieszka alińska: in pursuit of tax equity: lessons from vat rate structure adjustment in poland 25 134 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 115-137 (2015) The attempt to alleviate the plight of the poor does not seem to have been neces sary. Measured against consumption, as a proxy for lifetime income, VAT would be anyway mildly progressive and the reform hardly changed that. When its an nual incidence is considered – an approach favored by policymakers – VAT with out further rate reduction on food would have imposed a higher burden on the poorer part of the society. Again, the rate adjustment did not change this regressive property of the VAT. A closer look at the combined income and VAT tax burden faced by households reveals that the regressive nature of VAT to a large extent is counterbalanced by progressive income tax. With a small change to the income tax structure the government could have secured more progressivity at a lower cost in terms of revenue foregone. artur świstak, sebastian wawrzak, agnieszka alińska: in pursuit of tax equity: lessons from vat rate structure adjustment in poland The Polish experience with VAT rate structure adjustment confirms that any ef forts to pursue progressivity through reduced rates are doomed to be ineffective. There are several reasons for this, but consumption patterns are the underlying one, especially in the case of food. In line with economic theory, spending on food declines as income increases. It declines as a share of income but not in absolute terms. In such a setting the richer by definition benefit more, at a high cost of rev enue forgone and loss of efficiency. There are only a few inferior food products whose consumption declines as income rises. The Polish household budget survey reveals only two – the potato and sugar. Although consumption patterns differ with income, consumption per se does not constitute a good basis for addressing distributional concerns. This renders VAT the tax least suited for the pursuit of distributional equity objectives for they inher ently relate to the income and personal characteristic of taxpayers. Reliance on a broadbased and singlerated VAT for revenue generation and use of progressive income taxes may yield far better results. As noted in Keen (2003a) “even poorly targeted [government] spending may be a better way to support the poor than a reduced rate.” Helping the poor by subsidizing the rich is one of the most impru dent and deceitful policies and one that no society can ever afford. Pursuing dis tributional equity through the differentiation of VAT rates is one such policy and should be avoided. 135 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 115-137 (2015) artur świstak, sebastian wawrzak, agnieszka alińska: in pursuit of tax equity: lessons from vat rate structure adjustment in poland REFERENCES 1. Arsic, M. and Altiparmakov, N., 2013. “Equity aspects of VAT in emerging European countries: A case study of Serbia”. Economic Systems 37, pp. 171 186. doi: 10.1016/j.ecosys.2012.12.003 2. Athreya, K. B. and Reilly, D., 2009. “Consumption smoothing and the mea sured regressivity of consumption taxes”. Economic Quarterly, 95 (1), pp. 75100. 3. Bird, R. and Gendron, P., 2007. The VAT in Developing and Transitional Countries. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. doi: 10.1017/ CBO9780511619366 4. Bird, R., 1987. “A new look at indirect taxation in developing countries”. World Development, Vol. 15, No. 9, pp. 11511161. doi: 10.1016/0305 750X(87)901847 5. Borselli, F., Chiri, S. and Romagnano, E., 2012. “Patterns of reduced rates in the European Union”. International VAT Monitor, January/February, pp. 13 21. 6. Braz, C. and Correia da Cunha, J., 2009. “The redistributive effects of VAT in Portugal”. Economic Bulletin, Banco de Portugal, Winter, pp. 7186. 7. Business Review, 2013. Romanian authorities consider cutting the VAT for meat products to 9 pct. [online]. Available at: <http://businessreview.eu/fea tured/romanianauthoritiesconsidercuttingthevatformeatproductsto9 pct/>. 8. Caspersen, E. and Metcalf, G., 1994. “Is a Value Added Tax regressive? An nual versus lifetime incidence measures”. National Tax Journal 47, pp. 731 746. 9. Cnossen, S., 1982. “What rate structure for a valueadded tax?” National Tax Journal, 35, pp. 205214. 10. Cnossen, S., 1998. “VATs in CEE countries: A survey and analysis”. De Economist, 146 (2), pp. 227255. doi: 10.1023/A:1003291011259 11. Cnossen, S., 2003. “How much tax coordination in the European Union?” International Tax and Public Finance, 10, pp. 625649. doi: 10.1023/ A:1026373703108 12. Copenhagen Economics, 2007. Study on reduced VAT applied to goods and services in the Member States of the European Union, [pdf]. Available at: <http://ec.europa.eu/taxation_customs/resources/documents/taxation/vat/ how_vat_works/rates/study_reduced_vat.pdf>. 13. Creedy, J., 1998. “Are consumption taxes regressive?” The Australian Economic Review, 31, pp. 107116. doi: 10.1111/14678462.00057 14. Decoster, A. [et al.], 2010. “How regressive are indirect taxes? A microsimu lation analysis of five European Countries”. Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, 29, pp. 326350. doi: 10.1002/pam.20494 15. Dobrowolska, B. and Starzynska, W., 2011. Redystrybucyjne efekty opodat kowania konsumpcji gospodarstw domowych podatkiem VAT. In: A. Bor 136 16. 17. financial theory and practice 39 (2) 115-137 (2015) 18. 19. artur świstak, sebastian wawrzak, agnieszka alińska: in pursuit of tax equity: lessons from vat rate structure adjustment in poland 20. 21. 22. 23. 24. 25. 26. 27. 28. 29. 30. kowska and U. LagnowskaSzczesniak, eds. Spoleczno-Ekonomiczne Determinanty Konsumpcji w Polsce. Uniwersytet Opolski, pp. 113137. Ebeke, C. and Vazquez, F., 2014. Cyclical Behavior of VAT Revenues in Eu rope. Selected Issues Paper, IMF (Forthcoming). Ebrill, L. [et al.], 2001. The Modern VAT. International Monetary Fund. doi: 10.5089/9781589060265.07 European Commission (EC), 2011. A retrospective evaluation of elements of the EU VAT system. TAXUD/2010/CC/104 [pdf]. Available at: <http://ec.eu ropa.eu/taxation_customs/resources/documents/common/publications/stud ies/report_evaluation_vat.pdf>. European Commission (EC), 2013. Study to quantify and analyse the VAT Gap in the EU-27 Member States. Final Report. TAXUD/2012/DE/316 [pdf]. Available at: <http://ec.europa.eu/taxation_customs/common/publications/ studies/vatgap.pdf>. European Commission (EC), 2014. VAT Rates Applied in the Member States of the European Union. Situation at 13th January 2014 [pdf]. Available at: <http://ec.europa.eu/taxation_customs/resources/documents/taxation/vat/ how_vat_works/rates/vat_rates_en.pdf>. European Union (European Commission and Eurostat), 2013. Taxation trends in the European Union. 2013 edition, Publication Office of the European Union, Luxemburg. European Union Council Directive 2006/112/EC of 28 November 2006 on the common system of value added tax. Friedman, M., 1957. A theory of consumption function. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Garnier, G. [et al.], 2013. “Recent Reforms of Tax Systems in the EU: Good and Bad News”. Taxation Papers, Working Paper, No. 39. Available at: <http://ec.europa.eu/taxation_customs/resources/documents/taxation/gen_ info/economic_analysis/tax_papers/taxation_paper_39.pdf>. Grandcolas, C., 2005. “The Occasional Failure in VAT Implementation: Les sons for the Pacific”. Asia-Pacific Tax Bulletin, 12, pp. 613. Gustavsen, G. and Rickertsen, K., 2013. “Adjusting VAT rates to promote healthier diets in Norway: A censored quantile regression approach”. Food Policy, 42, pp. 8895. doi: 10.1016/j.foodpol.2013.07.00 IMF, 2011. Revenue Mobilization in Developing Countries. Board Paper, March 2013. Available at: <http://www.imf.org/external/np/pp/eng/2011/ 030811.pdf>. IMF, 2013. Fiscal Monitor: Taxing Times, October 2013. Keen, M. and Lockwood, B., 2010. “The value added tax: Its causes and con sequences”. Journal of Development Economics, 92 (2), pp. 138151. doi: 10.1016/j.jdeveco.2009.01.01 Keen, M., 2013a. “Targeting, Cascading, and Indirect Tax Design”. IMF Working Paper, WP/13/57. Available at: <http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ ft/wp/2013/wp1357.pdf>. 137 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 115-137 (2015) artur świstak, sebastian wawrzak, agnieszka alińska: in pursuit of tax equity: lessons from vat rate structure adjustment in poland 31. Keen, M., 2013b. “The anatomy of the VAT”. IMF Working Paper, WP/13/111. Available at: < http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2013/wp13111.pdf>. 32. Matheson, T. and Swistak, A., 2014. “Modernizing the Icelandic VAT”. IMF Country Report No. 14/291. Available at: <http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ ft/scr/2014/cr14291.pdf>. 33. Metcalf, G., 1997. “The National Sales Tax: Who Bears the Burden?” CATO Policy Analysis, No. 289. 34. Ministerstwo Finansów (MF), 2013. Preferencje podatkowe w Polsce, Nr. 3 [pdf]. Available at: <http://www.finanse.mf.gov.pl/documents/766655/8294824/ 20140401+preferencje+podatkowe+w+Polsce.pdf>. 35. Musgrave, R. A., Case, K. E. and Leonard, H., 1974. The distribution of fiscal burdens and benefits. Public Finance Quarterly, (2), pp. 251311. 36. Nagel, T. and Neneman, J., 1995. Effects of a Reform of Private Consumption Taxation in Poland. In: M. Belka and H.G. Peterson, eds. Economic Transformation in Poland: reforms of Institutional Settings and Macroeconomic Performance. Frankfurt: Campus Verlag, pp. 212237. 37. OECD, 2010. “Choosing a Broad Base – Low Rate Approach to Taxation”. OECD Tax Policy Studies, No. 19. Paris: OECD. 38. OECD, 2013a. Methodology and limitations in Taxing Wages 2013. Paris: OECD. 39. OECD, 2013b. Taxing Wages 2013. Paris: OECD. 40. Pechman, J. A., 1985. Who Paid the Taxes:1966-85? Washington: Brookings Institution Press. 41. Poterba, J. M., 1989. “Lifetime incidence and distributional burden of excise taxes”. American Economic Review, 79 (2), pp. 325330. 42. Prezes Rady Ministrów (PRM), 2010. Projekt ustawy o zmianie ustawy o finansach publicznych oraz niektórych innych ustaw. Uzasadnienie (Druk nr 3576) [doc]. Available at: <http://orka.sejm.gov.pl/Druki6ka.nsf/0/C9C153E 56DBDADA5C12577D7002BF9B1/$file/3576uzasadnienie.doc>. 43. Radziukiewicz, M., 2011. Redystrybucja dochodów. Kto zyskuje? Kto traci? Warszaw: Polskie Wydawnictwo Ekonomiczne. 44. Slintakova, B. and Klazar, S., 2010. “Impact of harmonization on distribution of VAT in the Czech Republic”. Prague Economic Papers, (2), pp.133149. 45. Tait, A. A., 1988. Value Added Tax. International Practice and Problems. Washington: International Monetary Fund. Cyclicality of bank capital buffers in South-Eastern Europe: endogenous and exogenous aspects ANA KUNDID NOVOKMET, PhD* Article** JEL: G, G8, P34 doi: 10.3326/fintp.39.2.2 * This paper is based on author’s PhD dissertation. The author would like to thank two anonymous referees for their useful comments and suggestions. ** Received: June , 04 Accepted: December 19, 2014 The article was submitted for the 2014 annual award of the Prof. Dr. Marijan Hanžeković Prize. Ana KUNDID NOVOKMET University of Split, Faculty of Economics, Department of Finance, Cvite Fiskovića 5, 21 000 Split, Croatia e-mail: [email protected] 40 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 139-169 (2015) ana kundid novokmet: cyclicality of bank capital buffers in south-eastern europe: endogenous and exogenous aspects Abstract The interdependence between the regulatory capital ratio and macroeconomic indicators, with reference to the phenomena cyclicality and pro-cyclicality is a widely emphasized disadvantage of the capital adequacy concept. Redesign of the aforementioned concept towards the countercyclical capital requirements is a kind of recognition of the creators of the Basel standards of the previous oversights in its development. This paper aims to explore empirically the direction, intensity and significance of endogenous and exogenous determinants of the changes in banks’ capital buffers by taking into consideration both the impact of the macroeconomic properties and the bank-specific characteristics of South-Eastern Europe. More than 80 commercial banks in the period from 2000-2010 have been encompassed by the research. Use of a dynamic panel analysis led to the conclusion that the bank capital buffers decreased during the observed period, with the exception of certain years during the economic expansion, which confirms the appropriateness of regulatory requirements considering the countercyclical capital buffers. Nevertheless, it might be that capital building and spending in the future will not follow the pattern from the last decade due to the specificities of the observed period, as well as the banking sector ownership transformations, economic and credit growth as well as asset prices growth in the post-transitional period, and finally, the real crisis which spilled over onto the financial sectors. Keywords: bank capital buffers, cyclicality, commercial banks, South-Eastern Europe 1 INTRODUCTION The capital requirements regulation for banks, in common with the practice of referring to capital adequacy as the ultimate measure of the banking stability, has persisted as the key instrument of prudential oversight worldwide for a more than two decades, despite criticisms from both the academic community (Daníelsson et al., 2001; Rodríguez, 2003; Saidenberg and Schuermann, 003; Benston, 007; Moosa, 00) and the banking lobbies (Herring, 007; Kane, 007a, b). The phenomena of capital requirements cyclicality and pro-cyclicality, among other controversies, are rather important points of reference when the adequacy of this regulatory concept is being disputed (Jackson et al., 1999). While cyclicality stands for macroeconomic impacts on a bank’s performance, pro-cyclicality implies a bank’s reaction to the macroeconomic environment which amplifies macroeconomic fluctuations (Marcucci and Quagliariello, 2008:47). Examinations intent on determining the implications of capital requirements for the size of banking intermediation and which directly or indirectly tackled the question of the macroeconomic consequences of the observed regulatory measure long dominated researches on the effects of capital requirements implementation. Moreover, in the first decade of the capital adequacy standard implementation in practice the relationship between the capital requirements and the volume as well as the structure of banking activities was at the centre of research. In fact there was an endeavour to explain the credit contraction recorded at the beginning of the 1990s in the countries that signed the Basel Accord by the adoption of the capital requirements. Thus the hypothesis that the bank capital channel (i.e. For these reasons, this research does not aim to simulate or estimate the macroeconomic consequences of the implementation of capital requirements, indirectly throughout the bank credit activity level, but rather concentrates on the cyclicality in the volume of ana kundid novokmet: cyclicality of bank capital buffers in south-eastern europe: endogenous and exogenous aspects On the other hand, the bank capital channel works out only if the following assumptions are satisfied (Francis and Osborne, 2009b:1): if banks do not have a sufficient capital buffer through which they could insulate themselves from the movements in the credit supply when regulatory changes occur; if capital enlargement is a costly process; if economic agents are highly dependable upon bank loan financing. If the phenomena of demand-driven and supply-driven credit rationing are taken into consideration, the macroeconomic effects of “adequate” capitalization might be an argument for a reasonable or, on the other hand, a more stringent criticism of the (supra)national prudential authorities. Thus, the importance of principles and practice of the occurrence of business and economic cycles is temporarily downgraded, while primacy in the explanations of movements in the aggregate credit and investment level is given to the effects of the capital requirements or to the supply side of the process. It is in this sense that the phrase capital crunch is used to indicate the cause of pro-cyclicality or, to be more precise, the contraction in credit activities, particularly in the case of more weakly capitalised banks and of loan categories assigned with high risk weights (for example, loans to small and medium-sized firms, which are anyway highly dependent on bank financing). However, the capital requirements are not the only relevant factor of the credit activity level and structure, and recent researches with inconsistent conclusions brought this issue sharply into focus. Gambacorta and Mistrulli (2004) empirically confirm that the bank capital might cause shocks in aggregate lending; Brissimis and Delis (2009) prove that bank specificities cannot be the main reasons for the aforementioned conclusions; while Berrospide and Edge (00) verify the modest impact of bank capital on lending. A solution to reconcile these contradictions is modelled by Miyake and Nakamura (007), who ascribe to capital regulation long-term stabilising effects that address the macroeconomic consequences of negative shocks to productivity. On the other hand, in the short term it can have a pro-cyclical effect, because of which the tightening of capital regulation needs timing precisely; this is the key practical implication of their research. Generally, there are two groups of conclusions present in this type of research: () the implementation of capital requirements did not induce the credit shock, () the implementation of capital requirements combined with another supply-side and with demand-side determinants of the credit level contributed to the development of the credit shock. 4 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 139-169 (2015) the hypothesis of the financial accelerator induced by bank capital) provided the impulse that led to the credit crunch, a regulatory mechanism that had pro-cyclical effects, was examined in many empirical investigations. Most research on the macroeconomic effects of the implementation of the capital requirements was oriented to the identification of the relationship between the credit volume fluctuations (and consequently the economic output) and the more restrictive capital regulation. Likewise, Van den Heuvel (008) calculated that the compliance with capital requirements leads to a permanent loss in the volume of consumption in the United States in the range of from 0.% to %. 4 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 139-169 (2015) capital requirements (i.e. regulatory indicators of financial leverage, to be more precise, capital buffers). Additional justification for the exogenous treatment of economic trends in the analysis of the capital requirements efficiency is found in Quagliariello (2008), while Saidenberg and Schuermann (003:8) point out that if capital requirements procyclicality even exists, it is not clear how it can be confirmed. A distinction of the direct effects deriving from the capital requirements prescriptions from the effects induced by the shifts in the economic cycles remains an empirical challenge, although pro-cyclicality has always previously been the most tested aspect of the capital requirements effects. However, if the assumption of pro-cyclicality is a consequence of cyclicality is accepted (Quagliariello, 2008:103; Marcucci and Quagliariello, 2008), then research that explores the capital buffers or regulatory capital cyclicality might indirectly serve as a support for a certain conclusions on the macroeconomic implications of the implementation of capital requirements i.e. on the pro-cyclicality of capital requirements. ana kundid novokmet: cyclicality of bank capital buffers in south-eastern europe: endogenous and exogenous aspects The size of banks’ regulatory capital is a volatile category, what might be a consequence of endogenous and exogenous factors. Thus, it is justified to question the role of economic cycles in the (non)functionality of capital requirements. Nevertheless, there are only a few research works that combine microeconomic or bank-specific and macroeconomic determinants of capital requirements volatility. With reference to the aforementioned, this research acknowledges the empirical background in the following papers: Bikker and Hu (2002), Ayuso et al. (2004), Bikker and Metzemakers (2007), Jokipii and Milne (2008), Stolz (2007), Francis and Osborne (2009a), and Stolz and Wedow (2011). By taking into consideration cyclicality in the capital itself rather than its cyclical implications, the paper is in line with the current trends in empirical research into the issues and challenges related to capital adequacy standards; theoretical and empirical findings have shown that capital alone cannot be held responsible for a contraction in credit activity, as used to be argued, irrespective of whether increases in capital requirements or shocks in capital size were concerned. Moreover, banks pro-cyclical behaviour might be mitigated by maintaining surpluses of capital above those regulatorily required (i.e. capital buffers) and with their accumulation in the periods of economic expansion, which is currently being promoted within the Basel III framework. Whatever the case might be, new versions of the aforementioned regulatory concept should not be designed without empirical evidence on the endogenous and exogenous determinants of capital buffers cyclicality being provided and taken into consideration. 2 CYCLICALITY OF BANK CAPITAL BUFFERS: A REVIEW OF EMPIRICAL RESEARCH A certain novelty of empirical research into the interdependence between the capital requirements and macroeconomic trends is found in the empirical analysis of the impact of macroeconomic tendencies on the volatility of the regulatory capital level. Following the methodological framework developed by Shrieves and Dahl (1992), the changes in bank capitalization (ΔCAPj,t) are determined with both exogenous factors (Ẽj,t) and endogenous, controllable or discretionary adjustments (ΔCAPMj,t), which can be summarized as follows: () () Altogether, the following equation can be written: (3) financial theory and practice 39 (2) 139-169 (2015) Furthermore, the discretionary changes in capital (ΔCAPMj,t) are defined as the difference between the target capital level (CAP*j,t) and the capital level in the previous period (CAPj,t-): 43 where α is adjustment speed in the capital level. Thus, banks have to weigh the costs and benefits from holding a certain level of capital above the minimally prescribed. In such a manner, when determining the discretionary capital they have to bear in mind the following costs: the remuneration cost of capital requested by the shareholders, the costs of the franchise value loss, the costs of reputation loss, bankruptcy costs, the costs of regulatory interventions and sanctions and the costs of adjustment to the requirements of the regulator and the market participants, for example, the credit rating agencies, potential and existing shareholders, uninsured depositors and ana kundid novokmet: cyclicality of bank capital buffers in south-eastern europe: endogenous and exogenous aspects The aforementioned formula takes into account the fact that banks can have deviations from the target capital level, i.e. that they are not always in a position to make ad hoc adjustments to the targeted capital levels. Thus, banks usually maintain a higher level of regulatory capital than that prescribed, which is also the key conclusion of the capital buffer theory (Milne and Whalley, 2001). The surplus of capital above the minimally prescribed level (by the regulators) is replaced by the formulation of capital buffer in the rest of the paper, with the following note in mind: prudential authorities may request banks that they perceive to engage in unusually high risk-taking behaviour to maintain a capital adequacy level higher than that which is minimally prescribed. Therefore, the capital buffer or the discretionary capital can be an outcome of the bank’s discretion (as an object of regulation), as well as, the regulator’s discretion. Whatever the case might be, it is evident that banks usually have the higher capital levels than those minimally prescribed, while the motives for the maintenance of the capital buffers might be strategic or reputational (Lastra, 2004:230; Bikker and Metzemakers, 2007:13; Jokipii and Milne, 008:44), i.e. have to be supported by the following considerations: – cheaper refinancing and borrowing in the future, i.e. the market discipline functionality (practiced by the bank clients, creditors, credit rating agencies, shareholders), – avoiding the costs of regulatory interventions in case of insufficient capitalization, – granting loans in a recession, i.e. reduced pro-cyclical effects of bank capital (not missing the chance for future bank growth), – financing mergers and acquisitions, – expansion in the business of banking, – a more flexible bank management, and – protection against unexpected losses. 44 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 139-169 (2015) ana kundid novokmet: cyclicality of bank capital buffers in south-eastern europe: endogenous and exogenous aspects other, wholesale creditors of banks (Ayuso et al., 2004:253). Consequently, the targeted capital level is ambiguously determined. Moreover, it is dependent upon the bank specificities, which are proxied by numerous bank-specific variables in empirical researches. Further, an exogenous changes of capital might be the outcome of regulatory pressures for an increase of capital or unexpected changes in the volume of earnings caused by operating income volatility or loans value impacting the level of provisioning, and is connected to or is, in the first place, originated by the general economic context (Shrives and Dahl, 1992:446-447). Whatever the case might be, due to the manner in which the measure of capital requirements has been designed, the level of risks taken and the changes in the risk level ought to be reflected in the capital level. According to Shrieves and Dahl (1992) a positive relationship between risk and capital is explained by banks’ efforts to mitigate bankruptcy costs or by the risk aversion of bank managers, while a negative impact of risk on capital can be the consequence of oversights in the deposit insurance premiums. The level of risks taken is correlated with the expected or achieved return (which is an outcome of the size and the structure of bank activities). Altogether, this makes bank profitability as well as growth indicators the endogenous factors of volatility in capital requirements. And finally, the cyclicality of capital requirements is determined by bank characteristics and macroeconomic trends. The key methodological features and conclusions of the reviewed empirical researches (encompassed by table ) on the exogenous determinants of capital requirements cyclicality can be summarized in the following points: – Research methodology selection. Almost all the research works reviewed employ dynamic panel analysis. – Data sample unit. Researches usually observe commercial and savings banks or savings banks and cooperatives (Ayuso et al., 2004; Lindquist, 2004; Stolz, 2007; Jokipii and Milne, 2008; Stolz and Wedow, 2011), which enables subsamples to be analysed and conclusions to be made as to how much capital requirements of various groups of credit institutions are volatile due to cyclical movements and how much volatility is caused by bank specificities, banking sector characteristics and by a given bank’s being a certain kind of credit institution. Research that focuses on savings banks and cooperatives usually has significantly larger data samples (according to number of observations) than those that take into consideration solely commercial banks (Boucinha and Ribeiro, 2007; Francis and Osborne, 2009a). – Data sample spatial characteristics. Researches that consider the banking sector of a certain country are the most frequent (Ayuso et al., 004; Lindquist, 004; Boucinha and Ribeiro, 2007; Stolz, 2007; Francis and Osborne, 2009a; Stolz and Wedow, 2011), while Stolz (2007) and Stolz and Wedow (2011) focus solely on one region of one observed country, i.e. the western part of Germany, due to the disparities in the economic development of the two parts after the unification of the country. Cross-country analyses are usually related to the political or economic affiliation of a country to a certain association, e.g. the Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) (Bikker and Metzemakers, 2007) or the European Union (EU) (Jokipii and Milne, 008). An exception to this is constituted by Fonseca and González (2010) and Fonseca et al. (2010), who analyse the banking sectors of 70 and 92 countries worldwide, respectively. Excluding the last mentioned research works, ana kundid novokmet: cyclicality of bank capital buffers in south-eastern europe: endogenous and exogenous aspects According to the presented research findings, it is evident that there is a gap in the empirical literature on the research issue for the South-Eastern European countries. In fact, as the capital adequacy standard was aimed at the most developed countries, or rather, at internationally active banks originating in these countries, it is explainable why research works for those countries outnumber those for developing countries, which adopted the Basel Committee recommendations in their national regulatory acts at a later date. However, numerous researchers warn that the effects and implementation of capital requirements might be significantly different in countries at different economic development levels (e.g. Caprio and Honohan, 1999; Morisson and White, 2005). This paper acknowledges that idea. 145 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 139-169 (2015) it can be concluded that investigations have been carried out only for developed countries, which means that there is an urgent need to bridge the research gap with respect to the banking sectors of developing countries. Interestingly, in this theme, research into European countries dominates, while there is little or no research related to the United States (except a part of the research by Jokipii and Milne, 0). – Data sample time period characteristics. The shortest time period range, that of 7 years, is encompassed by Lindquist (004), while the longest time period is found in Ayuso et al. (2004), Bikker and Metzemakers (2007), Boucinha and Ribeiro (2007), Stolz (2007) and Fonseca et al. (2010) with more than 11 years encompassed by the data sample. Empirical researches at the level of a single country’s banking sector have not taken into consideration data later than the year 006 (Francis and Osborne, 2009a). – Variables selection. Most of the research aims to examine the impact of macroeconomic and bank-specific variables on the capital buffers which is set out as the dependent variable, while some researches, e.g. Bikker and Metzemakers (2007) and Francis and Osborne (2009a) use also the capital adequacy indicator. Other ones likewise Stolz (2007) or Stolz and Wedow (2011) use an indicator of regulatory capital over total assets or equity to total assets ratio, as do Bikker and Metzemakers (007). Economic trends are usually described by taking into account the real gross domestic product (GDP) growth. – Impact of economic cycles on capital requirements volatility. All research (at the level of the overall sample, as there are some differences in the subsample approach) confirmed that capital buffers increase in an economic downturn, and that they tend to decrease in periods of economic expansion. – Other conclusions. Commercial banks have lower capital buffers than savings banks and/or cooperatives (Lindquist, 004). In addition, the results reveal a positive relationship between capital buffers and economic growth in small banks and in cooperatives (Jokipii and Milne, 008) due to the earnings-retaining policy of these credit institutions in periods of expansion and a slower growth of placements (and thus the risk-weighted assets) as they mainly finance themselves with their core deposits. Jokipii and Milne (2008) confirmed that there is a difference in the cyclicality of capital buffers between the newly acceded countries and the older member countries of the European Union; in the older member countries there is a negative correlation between capital buffers and economic growth, while in the newly acceded countries there is a positive correlation. 29 OECD Bikker and Metzemakers countries; 199000 (007) Lindquist (004) 3 savings banks and 6 commercial banks/Norway; 1995-2001 Dynamic panel data model; GMM estimator The return on equity and the ratio of non-performing loans negatively impact the buffers. Lagged dependent variable has a positive influence. Bank size has a negative effect, as does growth of loans. Commercial banks’ buffers are more robust to negative influences of the business cycles than savings banks. There are differences in the obtained results for the savings and commercial banks. A negative connection between the risk and the dependent variable is recorded for savings banks. The debt price and the buffers size are negatively related, which implies that banks with a lower regulatory capitalization pay higher costs of debt financing. Larger savings banks have smaller buffers than small-sized savings banks. There is also a negative To explore the GLS Random- relationship between the risk and capital for the commercial banks. A more stringent determinants of capital buffers with focus on the Effects Model regulatory oversight over the commercial banks increases the buffers. Besides, a negative impact of the reserves for unidentified losses, and a positive impact of the losses on the microeconomic variables. level of capital is confirmed, which might lead to the following conclusions: banks use reserves as an alternative to increasing capital buffers, and banks build up their buffers after the period of losses no matter what their price. Bank size negatively drives its buffers. The main conclusion is that banks do not enlarge their capital because of increased risks. In the equation in which the equity to assets ratio is the dependent variable, it was found that the lagged dependent variable has a positive impact. This means that banks gradually To explore the impact adjust their capital to the targeted level. Credit risk indicators have a negative impact on Dynamic of macroeconomic and capital, while the effect of the return on assets is a positive one. Results of the equation panel data bank-specific variables with the regulatory capital being a dependent variable are similar to the aforementioned, on the bank capitalization model; GMM with a significant difference in the (country level) cost of capital (or the average return on level and the regulatory estimator equity of the banking sector) in the previous period being significant and having a negative capital level. sign. Subsamples analysis (when the banks’ size was a criterion variable for the subsampling) reveals differences in the results for the banks according to their size. Methodology Results ana kundid novokmet: cyclicality of bank capital buffers in south-eastern europe: endogenous and exogenous aspects Data sample characteristics / Research assumptions Authors and goals spatial and time period attributes 4 commercial To explore the effects Ayuso, Pérez and savings of economic trends on and Saurina banks/Spain; capital buffers. (004) 1986-2000 There is no strong evidence of cyclicality in the equity financing with reference to the economic trends. There is some evidence of regulatory capital cyclicality. Economic growth negatively impacts the capital buffers of the commercial and savings banks. The commercial banks have, on average, lower capital buffers in comparison to the savings banks. The business cycle has a negative impact on the capital buffers. Main conclusions on the exogenous determinants of capital buffers cyclicality financial theory and practice 39 (2) 139-169 (2015) Table 1 A review of empirical research on capital requirements cyclicality 46 To explore the determinants of capital buffers. 7 banks/ Portugal; 1994-2004 492 savings banks and 2,159 cooperatives/ Germany (western part); 1993-2003 468 banks (commercial, savings and cooperatives)/ EU-25; 1997-2004 Boucinha and Ribeiro (007) Stolz (007) Jokipii and Milne (008) To explore the impact of economic trends on the capital buffers, as well as on the ratio of regulatory capital to total assets and risk-weighted assets to total assets. Dependent and independent variables (without dummy variables) are defined as changes, rather than the level of the observed indicator. To identify the dependence of the capital buffers on economic growth. Subsampling analysis according to the criterion of the newly acceded and older members of the EU, as well as the bank size and the bank type criterion are assumed to be relevant in explaining the relationship between economic growth and capital level. Research assumptions and goals Dynamic panel data model; GMM estimator Results reveal capital buffers cyclicality in dependence with the economic growth. Higher economic growth reduces buffers. Stock markets growth positively impacts the capital buffers. Main conclusions on the exogenous determinants of capital buffers cyclicality There is a difference in the cyclicality of the capital buffers between the new and the old members of the EU; whereas, in the old members a negative movement of the capital buffers and the economic growth is recorded, in the new members that relation is a positive one. That means that in the old members economic growth follows a reduction in capital and vice versa. In the new members economic growth follows growth in the capital buffers. A negative impact of the cost of equity (the return on equity) and of bank size on the capital buffers is confirmed. Credit risk positively determines the buffers in most of the subsamples. The lagged dependent variable has a positive impact on the capital buffers, as it was expected, which is also proven for reinvested earnings. The growth of loans reduces the buffers. There is a negative relationship between economic growth and capital buffers. Commercial, savings and big banks confirm a negative relationship, while the data sample which is composed of small-sized banks and cooperatives confirms a positive relationship. A positive relationship of the latter mentioned banks is a consequence of earnings-retaining policy, retaining earnings being more frequent in economic growth periods. Furthermore, small-sized banks and cooperatives have a slower growth of placements due to a mainly core deposit financing policy. The lagged dependent variable in the equation where the change in the capital buffers is There is inverse relationship between the dependent variable has a positive sign, as well as the ratio of liquidity and the ratio of loan economic cycles and the changes in capital loss reserves to total assets. The bank size and the return on assets have a negative impact buffers. on the changes in capital buffers. The lagged dependent variable has a positive impact on buffers, which confirms the assumption that banks gradually increase their capital buffers. A negative impact of the loan loss reserves proves that reserves are a substitute for the capital surplus. Banks with larger investments in stocks maintain larger capital buffers, while the bank size negatively impacts the buffers. Higher profitability and smaller volatility reduce the capital buffers. Dynamic panel data model; GMM estimator Dynamic panel data model; GMM estimator Results Methodology ana kundid novokmet: cyclicality of bank capital buffers in south-eastern europe: endogenous and exogenous aspects Data sample characteristics / spatial and time period attributes financial theory and practice 39 (2) 139-169 (2015) Authors 47 Banks with the higher quality of capital have higher capital adequacy ratios. The level of risk in the current period is negatively connected with capital, while the level of risk in the previous period is positively connected with capital. The ratio of loan loss reserves to total assets has a positive impact on capital. Bank size negatively drives the capital adequacy. Partial The market discipline proxy with the share of the subordinated debt in total liabilities Adjustment increases the capital adequacy. Variables which approximate the adjustment costs of Model; capital (lagged capital adequacy and the Tier indicator) positively impact the capital Random adequacy. Estimations of the various subsamples revealed the following results: large Effects Model, banks increase their capital adequacy more, if they are under the regulatory pressures, than Arellano-Bond small banks; banks with lower capitalization increase their capital adequacy more; if banks and Blundellare under regulatory pressure in periods of economic expansion they increase their capital Bond GMM more than in times of recession; banks under market pressures experience a weaker impact estimator of the capital requirements, and a higher impact of risk on the capital adequacy is expected in these banks. All the aforementioned results were obtained for the period 1998-2006. Similar results were obtained for the period from 1990-1995, with reference to the estimated parameters signs, but they usually lack statistical significance. To identify what, determines the banks’ capital adequacy levels, how and how much, and the nature of the role of prudential regulation in this process. The bankspecific and macroeconomic determinants of the bank capitalization are thus explored. Besides, the research aims to check whether the regulatory requirements’ impact changes depending on bank characteristics and the overall economic activity. The dependent variable is the capital adequacy ratio. The quality of capital is measured with the Tier capital. Risk is proxied by the riskweighted assets to total assets. 68 banks in the period 1998006 and 47 banks in the period 19901995; United Kingdom Francis and Osborne (2009a) Results Methodology Research assumptions and goals ana kundid novokmet: cyclicality of bank capital buffers in south-eastern europe: endogenous and exogenous aspects Authors A negative connection between GDP growth and the level of capital is recorded, and thus the (pro)cyclicality phenomenon asks for an additional empirical estimations. Main conclusions on the exogenous determinants of capital buffers cyclicality financial theory and practice 39 (2) 139-169 (2015) Data sample characteristics / spatial and time period attributes 48 ,36 banks/ 92 countries; 1990-2007 492 savings banks and 2,139 cooperatives/ Germany (western part); 1993-2004 Fonseca, González and Pereira da Silva (00) Stolz and Wedow (0) To explore the impact of economic trends on the capital buffers, as well as on the ratio of regulatory capital to total assets and the ratio of risk-weighted assets to total assets. Source: Author’s presentation. ,337 banks/ 70 countries; 1995-2002 Fonseca and González (00) To explore the determinants of capital buffers by taking into account the bank-specific variables and the disparities in the supervisory, regulatory and accounting standards of the observed countries. To explore the effect of capital buffers on the banks’ credit and deposit price in the developed and developing countries. Further, the determinants of capital requirements cyclicality are identified with a presumption of their lower volatility in the developing countries in comparison to the developed countries. Research assumptions and goals Dynamic panel data model; GMM estimator Dynamic panel data model; GMM estimator Dynamic panel data model; GMM estimator Methodology There is some evidence of a negative impact of the GDP growth on the capital buffers. There is a negative relationship between the GDP growth and capital buffers. An economic downturn positively affects the capital buffers. Weakly capitalized banks do not increase capital in periods of expansion and downturn (they decrease it, rather), nor do they decrease their risk-weighted assets in the downturn period (on contrary, they increase it). The cost of deposits in the previous period positively influences the buffers, while bank size has a negative impact. The credit price in the previous period positively impacts the buffers. There is a difference in the buffers’ movements during the business cycles depending on bank capitalization. Weakly capitalized banks reduce their buffers in periods of economic expansion and downturns. The lagged dependent variable positively impacts the buffers, while bank size has a negative sign. Banks with a higher liquidity tend to maintain larger capital buffers. Well capitalized banks increase their regulatory capital over the total assets in the economic expansion and downturn, while for weakly capitalized banks the results are opposite. Well capitalized banks do not change their risk-weighted assets during the business cycle, while weakly capitalized banks increase them during economic expansion and economic downturns. Main conclusions on the exogenous determinants of capital buffers cyclicality The lagged dependent variable positively impacts the capital buffers, as well as, market power (except if it is at a substantial level) and the costs of deposits. The bank size and the credit risk indicators negatively impact the buffers. Results ana kundid novokmet: cyclicality of bank capital buffers in south-eastern europe: endogenous and exogenous aspects Data sample characteristics / spatial and time period attributes financial theory and practice 39 (2) 139-169 (2015) Authors 149 150 3 EMPIRICAL RESEARCH CONCERNING THE BANKING SECTORS OF SOUTHEASTERN EUROPE 3.1. DATA, METHODOLOGY AND MODEL DEVELOPMENT financial theory and practice 39 (2) 139-169 (2015) Empirical research into the endogenous and exogenous determinants of the cyclicality of capital buffers has been carried out on a data sample of commercial banks from the 9 South-Eastern European countries that were active in the period from 2000-2010 and whose financial statements and financial indicators (which serve as approximations of the endogenous aspects of capital buffers cyclicality) were available in the Bankscope database. A distribution of banks by countries in the selected data set is given in the appendix (table A). Table 2 Data sources for the groups of indicators ana kundid novokmet: cyclicality of bank capital buffers in south-eastern europe: endogenous and exogenous aspects Variable Explanation and/or Data source Microeconomic indicators Microeconomic, i.e. financial, indicators of banks in the period from 000-00 were selected in the data sample according to the geographical criteria (Balkan States), status (active banks), type (commercial banks) and financial statements consolidation code (banks with consolidated (C and C) and unconsolidated statements (U)). Banking sector indicators Minimally prescribed capital adequacy ratio (for all the countries the officially prescribed indicator is taken into consideration, while for Romania in 2009 and 2010 the required rate is proxied by the IMF recommendations of 0%, minCAP due to the non-transparency of this information on the official website of the central bank of that country for the observed years). Minimally prescribed capital adequacy ratios by countries are encompassed in table A in the appendix. E_A Equity to assets ratio for the observed banking sector Bankscope, Bureau van Dijk Official websites of central banks by countries (various publications and decisions), the European Central Bank, annual publication Transition report in the period 000-00, Wisniwski (2005), Barisitz and Gardó (008), Jokipii and Milne (008), Athanasoglou (0) The World Bank (World Development Indicators & Global Development Finance) Macroeconomic indicator GDP growth Annual rate of growth of gross domestic product The World Bank (World Development Indicators & Global Development Finance) Dummy variables Dummy variable for an economic cycle (growth – dyEXP, downturn – dyREC) Dummy variables for the following years: 007 and 008 Source: Author’s presentation. Δ GDP (%) £ 0 (downturn – recession) Δ GDP (%) > 0 (growth – expansion) Years which indicate a shift in an economic trend Table 3 Definition of banks financial indicators employed in the econometric model Variable NPL_L ROA GROWL LLR_L dydevBUFLow, dydevBUFWella LOWCA, WELLCAb Absolute value of capital buffer = Bank capital adequacy ratio – Minimally prescribed capital adequacy ratio Non-performing (bad debt) and partially performing loans / Total loans Return on assets Growth of loans Loan loss reserves (identified and unidentified losses) / Total loans Undercapitalized banks in comparison to the regulatory prescriptions; Adequately capitalized banks Below-average capitalized banks; Above-average capitalized banks Group of indicators Regulatory capitalization ratio Credit risk (asset risk) indicator Overall profitability indicator Growth indicator Credit risk indicator Regulatory pressure variable Regulatory pressure variable a If a bank’s regulatory capital (capital adequacy ratio) is higher than the minimally prescribed plus a standard deviation of the minimally prescribed capital adequacy ratio, a bank is perceived to be a well-capitalized one (dydevBUFWell). In the opposite case, it is held to be under-capitalized (dydevBUFLow). b If a bank equity to assets ratio is higher than the average value of the aforementioned indicator for the banking sector in which a bank operates, a bank is perceived to be well-capitalized (WELLCA). In the opposite case it is considered undercapitalized (LOWCA). Source: Author’s presentation. The empirical research employed the econometric method of dynamic panel models. The collected secondary data have a time and spatial component, and a suitable data analysis method is thus an econometric method of panel analysis. Namely, use of the simple multiple regression is not possible as it cannot be assumed that there is an independence between the observations of one observed item during a time period (Škrabić, 2009:14). Thus, in a situation of the analysis of bank financial indicators, the indicators of one period are dependent on the same indicators in the previous period, i.e. there is a process of the firstorder autoregression. “The dynamic panel models contain the dependent variable which is being lagged for one or more periods” (Škrabić, 2009:29). Furthermore, the collected data ana kundid novokmet: cyclicality of bank capital buffers in south-eastern europe: endogenous and exogenous aspects ABBUFF Explanation 151 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 139-169 (2015) Banking sector indicators and macroeconomic indicators are taken from the official websites of central banks of the countries encompassed by the data sample as well as from the World Bank. Detailed insight into the data sources for the groups of indicators is provided in table . By taking into consideration the empirical background, an econometric model which encompassed the microeconomic variables from table 3 was developed. All the selected variables report annual values. The data were taken in euros, while delta (Δ) stands for the first difference of the observed variable value in order to cover the absolute changes in the variable in the two successive periods. 152 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 139-169 (2015) ana kundid novokmet: cyclicality of bank capital buffers in south-eastern europe: endogenous and exogenous aspects are characterized with a larger number of groups (N) than the time component (t), which this method handles very well. The empirical estimation of the panel data was performed using the dynamic panel model, to be more precise with the GMM (generalized method of moments) Arellano-Bond two-step estimator as well as the GMM Blundell-Bond two-step estimator. In the empirical work on the research issue both the “difference” GMM ArellanoBond and the “system” GMM Blundell-Bond estimator as a certain improvement of the Arellano-Bond in a case in which the autoregressive parameter value is near to one, and the number of observations is relatively small, were used. The preliminary data analysis using the Arellano-Bond estimator gave sufficient reasons for employing the improved estimator. By using the Arellano-Bond estimator the values of the lagged dependent variables were below 0.15 at worst. However, the specificities of the models in which the dependent variables were the first differences (absolute changes – Δ) of selected financial indicators, and where lagged absolute values of the same variables were used as independent variables, ask for an additional analysis if the estimated parameters of the aforementioned independent variables are high. Additional analysis can be obtained by dropping the variable from the model or by employing the Blundell-Bond estimator when there is large number of groups. Thus, from this point forward, only the Blundell-Bond estimations of the econometric model will be presented. The model’s quality is evaluated using the tests which are usually applied in the dynamic panel analysis likewise Sargan’s test as well as autocorrelation tests. The data were analysed in the statistical package STATA . The dynamic panel model for the selected variables is given with the following equation: (4) where i denotes an individual and t denotes time, μ is an intercept, γ is a parameter of the lagged dependent variable, β1, β2,..., βK are the parameters of the exogenous variables, xit are independent variables, αi is an individual-specific effect and εit the error term. The basic dynamic panel model on the dependence of changes in the banks’ capital buffers upon endogenous aspects has the following form: (5) The exogenous aspects of the macroeconomic variables influence are approximated with the dummy variables and various interaction terms. Namely, due to the small number of groups and observations for certain countries, the traditional use of the GDP growth rate and other macroeconomic variables was not an advisable solution. 3.2 RESULTS OF EMPIRICAL RESEARCH The descriptive data of the selected model variables precede the estimations of the econometric models. The mean value of the capital buffers (absolute level) has continuously decreased since the year 2001 (figure 1). This might lead to the conclusion that the South-Eastern European banks have used their capital buffers, i.e. that they have increased the volume of risk-weighted assets more than they have built up their regulatory Figure 1 The mean values of capital buffers (ABBUFF), the ratio of non-performing loans (NPL_L) and the ratio of risk-weighted assets to total assets (RWA_A) 60 24 50 20 40 16 30 12 20 8 10 0 4 2000 2001 2002 2003 ABBUFF (left) 2004 2005 2006 NP L_ L (left) 2007 2008 2009 2010 RWA _ A (right) Source: Bankscope. According to the figure 1 a conclusion on the cyclical movement of the ratio of nonperforming loans can be made. A quality improvement of the credit portfolio of the data sample banks is evident after the year 2002, what represents the first considerable effects of liberalization and almost completed ownership transformation of the banking sectors of the data-sample countries. A quality of credit receivables is getting worse in the last two observed years and reaches the mean value of 4%, as it was in the year 000. The lowest mean value of the non-performing loans to total loans was below 6% what was recorded in the years 2005 and 2006. When looking at the figure it is clear that there is cyclicality in the movement of capital buffers and in the variable which approximates a credit risk as the potential key bank-specific determinant of capital buffer. The ratio of loan loss reserves continuously falls down over the period 000-006 from the level slightly lower than 12% to the level of about 5% (figure 2). The reserves were stagnating, from 006 to 008 and in the last two observed years they rose up to the level of about 7%. These movements correspond to the impaired loans movements. The fact on the most of the bad loans being originated in good times makes the credit growth rates interesting for an observation. It is evident that the credit portfolio of the data sample banks was on average increasing a more than 40% annually until 008, while in the last observed year it ana kundid novokmet: cyclicality of bank capital buffers in south-eastern europe: endogenous and exogenous aspects 28 153 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 139-169 (2015) capital. Namely, when looking at the figure it is clear that the mean value of the ratio of risk-weighted assets to total assets was continuously on the increase until the year 2009, after which it started to decline. Besides, in certain countries minimally prescribed capital adequacy ratios increased, which serves as an additional explanation of tendencies for the capital buffers to decrease. In the year 2001 the mean value of the capitalization for the data-sample banks was 7 percentage points higher than the minimally prescribed value, while in the year 2010 the equivalent figure was less than 7 percentage points. 154 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 139-169 (2015) is on the level of just 10%. Although on the descriptive level, the aforementioned confirms the thesis on the credit activity “freezing” or the so called credit crunch as a radical form of the credit rationing process in the presence of the global financial crisis, and in the SouthEastern European area the shift towards negative economic tendencies with a stronghold in the serious structural problems. With reference to profitability (figure 3) it is observable that the mean value of the return on assets for the data-sample banks was higher than 0.5% until 2008, while from 2009 onwards that indicator is being zero or has a negative value. Figure 2 The mean values of the ratio of loan loss reserves (LLR_L) and the credit growth (GROWL) ana kundid novokmet: cyclicality of bank capital buffers in south-eastern europe: endogenous and exogenous aspects 12 70 11 60 10 50 9 40 8 30 7 20 6 10 5 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 0 2010 LLR_ L (left) GROW L (right) Source: Bankscope. Figure 3 The mean value of the return on assets (ROA) 1.5 1.0 0.5 0.0 -0.5 -1.0 -1.5 -2.0 2000 2001 Source: Bankscope. 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 Table 4 Panel data estimation of developed model with changes in capital buffers as dependent variable Explanatory variables DNPL_Lit ROAit ABBUFFi,t–1 LLR_Lit dy2007 dydevBUFLowit dydevBUFLowit* dy2008 dydevBUFWellit* dy2007 LOWCAit * dy2007 LOWCAit * dyREC a No. of observations No. of banks Sargan test (p-value) First-order autocorrelation (p-value) Second-order autocorrelation (p-value) Model 3 Model 4 Model 5 Model 6 -0.1139*** (0.048) 0.00** (0.0105) .334*** (0.1537) -0.408*** (0.0175) -0.0640*** (0.007) 0.5782*** (0.0545) 0.9903*** (0.3) -0.37*** (0.0149) 0.0229** (0.0098) 1.0745*** (0.1494) -0.3972*** (0.076) -0.0630*** (0.0067) 0.5673*** (0.0544) 0.9608*** (0.300) -.868*** (0.6899) -0.1253*** (0.06) 0.04** (0.0109) .08*** (0.1652) -0.3889*** (0.0165) -0.0545*** (0.0046) 0.5820*** (0.0539) -0.1139*** (0.048) 0.00** (0.0105) .333*** (0.1537) -0.408*** (0.0175) -0.0640*** (0.007) 0.5782*** (0.0550) -0.3*** (0.068) 0.0** (0.0095) .0*** (0.1469) -0.3970*** (0.068) -0.0635*** (0.006) 0.5780*** (0.0554) -0.06*** (0.06) 0.0253** (0.0) .77*** (0.706) -0.3907*** (0.068) -0.0572*** (0.0054) 0.5693*** (0.0548) – – – – – – – – – – – -3.4941*** (0.5903) – – – – – – 0.9903*** (0.3) – – – – – 1.4592*** (0.2649) – – -0.5561** (0.2559) -0.8738*** -0.7972*** -.033*** -0.8738*** -0.9019*** -0.783*** (0.2589) (0.2554) (0.2675) (0.2589) (0.807) (0.2839) – – – – – 66 66 66 66 66 66 88 88 88 88 88 88 0.063 0.0913 0.1105 0.063 0.0986 0.07 0.064 0.007 0.00 0.064 0.036 0.044 0.6785 0.6655 0.5902 0.6785 0.7594 0.4495 *** Statistically significant at 1% level, ** statistically significant at 5% level, * statistically significant at 10% level. Source: Author’s calculation. ana kundid novokmet: cyclicality of bank capital buffers in south-eastern europe: endogenous and exogenous aspects GROWLit Model 2 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 139-169 (2015) DABBUFFi,t–1 Model 1 155 156 Table 5 Panel data estimation of developed model with changes in capital buffers as dependent variable Explanatory variables financial theory and practice 39 (2) 139-169 (2015) DABBUFFi,t–1 DNPL_Lit ROAit ABBUFFit–1 ana kundid novokmet: cyclicality of bank capital buffers in south-eastern europe: endogenous and exogenous aspects GROWLit LLR_Lit dydevBUFLowit * dyREC Model 7 -0.1219*** (0.06) 0.04** (0.0109) 1.0898*** (0.1657) -0.3874*** (0.066) -0.0545*** (0.0047) 0.5706*** (0.0538) -1.9806*** (0.8179) dydevBUFWellit * dyREC * ABBUFFi,t–1 – dydevBUFWellit * dyEXP * ABBUFFi,t–1 – a No. of observations No. of banks Sargan test (p-value) First-order autocorrelation (p-value) Second-order autocorrelation (p-value) -0.9113*** (0.680) 66 88 0.0966 0.08 0.4980 Model 8 -0.347*** (0.060) 0.036*** (0.08) 1.0551*** (0.67) -0.3600*** (0.0175) -0.0649*** (0.0067) 0.5196*** (0.0498) – -0.1159*** (0.0) – -0.440 (0.2857) 66 88 0.0925 0.076 0.3948 Model 9 -0.07*** (0.0) 0.000** (0.0095) 0.9977*** (0.64) – -0.0501*** (0.0036) 0.5423*** (0.076) – – -0.0952*** (0.0145) -.663*** (0.44) 66 88 0.3385 0.0040 0.46 *** Statistically significant at 1% level, ** statistically significant at 5% level, * statistically significant at 10% level. Source: Author’s calculation. In the empirical estimation of the exogenous determinants of the cyclicality of the capital buffers, already specified the basic model has been supplemented with the dummy variables and various interaction terms which reflect the economic environment. As the years 007 and 008 are perceived to be the breaking points between the periods of the financial and economic stability and distress in the financial system functionality as well as indicating a shift towards economic downturn (as evident from the previous figures), the models have been supplemented with dummy variables for the years 007 and 008. Apart from that, the dummy variables that represent the periods of recession and expansion were used in the following way: positive GDP percentage changes stand for an expansionary period, while negative percentage changes denote a period of recession. With reference to this, and taking into consideration the empirical background, annual GDP growth and annual GDP decrease proxy the periods of expansion and recession in this paper, while in practice it is common to use two successive annual (percentage) GDP changes in order to reach a conclusion of whether an expansion or a recession is involved. The lagged dependent variable DABBUFFi,t–1, lagged value of capital buffers ABBUFFi,t–1 and credit growth GROWLit are in a negative relationship with the changes in capital buffers, while the changes in the non-performing loans DNPL_L it, the return on assets ROAit and the ratio of loan loss reserves LLR_Lit have a positive sign of the estimated parameters. From figure 1, which shows the movement of the capital buffers volume in the observed period, a negative sign of the lagged dependent variable was somewhat expected: since the year 00 onwards, a continuous decrease in the mean value of capital buffers was recorded. Analogously to this, the empirical estimation results confirmed that the lagged variable ABBUFFi,t–1 has a statistical significance and that the estimated parameter has a negative sign. The conclusion can be made that the growth of capital buffers in one period will have a negative impact on the capital buffers in the following period, i.e. the growth of capital buffers in one period leads to a decrease in the capital buffers in the following period and vice versa. This might be a consequence of the risk-weighted assets being increased and/or an increase in the minimally prescribed capital adequacy ratio, which occurred in certain South-Eastern European countries in the observed period (Bosnia and Herzegovina, Croatia and Serbia). All models report a positive influence of the changes in non-performing loans DNPL_L it on the changes in capital buffers, which might be interpreted in the following way: with an increase in the credit portfolio riskiness, banks increase capital buffers and vice versa. The mean value of capital buffers was continuously falling in the observed period, while the mean value of non-performing loans decreased in the first five years. Since the year ana kundid novokmet: cyclicality of bank capital buffers in south-eastern europe: endogenous and exogenous aspects 3.3. INTERPRETATION AND DISCUSSION OF RESEARCH RESULTS financial theory and practice 39 (2) 139-169 (2015) The empirical results of the estimated models with the changes in the capital buffers set out as a dependent variable obtained with the Blundell-Bond estimator are presented in the tables 4 and 5. From the correlation matrices given in the appendix it is clear that independent variables are not strongly correlated, except for some interaction variables, which are thus not simultaneously included in the model. In the model, which contains dy2007, the appearance of the variable dydevBUFWellit instead of dydevBUFLowit does not cause a sizeable deviation in results. Namely, the difference is visible in the sign of estimated parameter of this variable which becomes a positive one, while the constant term has a somewhat lower-estimated parameter and is statistically insignificant. Analysis shows that well-capitalized banks dominate within the sample, due to the results of the model with dydevBUFWellit * dy2007 and of the model with dy2007 being almost equal. Besides the presented models, models with other possible combinations of interaction terms were estimated, but those results are not presented here, as those variables which were assumed to improve the basic model were statistically insignificant. In addition, estimations of the data subsamples in which the economic cycle, i.e. the existence of expansion or recession was the criterion variable for the data subsampling were made. The results of the latter approach are given in the appendix (table A3). 157 158 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 139-169 (2015) ana kundid novokmet: cyclicality of bank capital buffers in south-eastern europe: endogenous and exogenous aspects 008 this has exponentially increased up to the level of the mean value from the beginning of the observed period (figure 1). Thus, according to the graphical presentation, no conclusion that an increase in the riskiness of assets caused an increase in the capital buffers can be made. On the contrary, a decrease in the riskiness of assets contributed to a reduction in capital buffers. In addition, subsamples analysis (table A3 in the appendix) reveals that in the period of economic expansion there is no significant linkage between the changes in the non-performing loans and the changes in capital buffers, while in the recessionary period there is a certain level of significance. Bank profitability measured by return on assets ROAit positively drives the changes in the bank capital buffers. The higher the return on assets, the higher the capital buffers and vice versa, a decrease in bank profitability reduces the capital buffers, which is logical if the bank regulatory capital structure is borne in mind. These tendencies are even more noticeable during economic expansion than in recession, and the estimated parameters from the table A3 in the appendix clearly serve as a proof. In the presented estimations, the sign of the estimated parameter of the lagged value of capital buffers ABBUFFi,t–1 is negative and significant. During the whole period the mean value of capital buffers was ., i.e. the banks had capital adequacy that was . percentage points on average higher than that minimally prescribed. Thus, a gradual “spending” of the capital surplus is expected. The aforementioned confirms the practice of having periods of capital accumulation and periods of capital “consumption”. For the observed data set the accumulation of capital above that regulatorily required occurred in the years 00 and 00 or even earlier, and after that the process of capital spending, i.e. a decrease in the capital buffers took place. Thus the value of capital buffers was “only” 6.88708 percentage points on average at the end of 00. Finally, it can be concluded that banks with higher initial capital buffers endeavour to maintain these levels, while the banks with the lower capital buffers tend to build up their levels of regulatory capital, which adds up to an empirical verification of the capital buffer theory. The ratio of loan loss reserves LLR_Lit has a positive sign, which implies that an increase/ decrease of reserves leads to an increase/decrease of capital buffers. This relationship is partly explainable by the fact that reserves, in a certain measure, contribute to a buildup process of regulatory capital (directly throughout the special reserves for unidentified losses in the supplementary capital I). Nevertheless, most of the loan loss reserves are the reserves for identified losses, whose costs are a deductible item in the income statement, and thus, indirectly, through their influence on profit, contribute to the regulatory capital variations. Therefore, an alternative interpretation is possible. The figure on the mean value of the ratio of loan loss reserves shows a long period of the ratio being decreased, together with the continuous fall of the capital buffers (figure 2). That is, a radical decline in the ratio of loan loss reserves is partially an outcome of the so called process of “cleaning” the credit portfolios of bad debt (i.e. exclusion of the bad debt from the banks’ balance sheets) which happened in the years of the observed banking sectors’ restructuration and rehabilitation (in the years 2000 and 2001). With reference to this, the average value of the ratio of net charge-off of loans to total loans was 6% in 000; it was below % in 00, The year 2007 positively influenced the changes in the capital buffers. Until 2007 capital buffers were, on average, trending down on a yearly basis. A slowdown in the credit growth that took place after the year 007 as well as a slowdown in the growth of riskweighted assets, due to the shift in lending activity favouring economic agents whose debt is assigned lower risk weights (e.g. the governmental sector), explain the tendency for there to be slower usage of (or smaller changes in) the capital buffers. The variable of ana kundid novokmet: cyclicality of bank capital buffers in south-eastern europe: endogenous and exogenous aspects Obviously, the changes (to be more precise, the droop in the observed data set) in the banks’ capital buffers can be explained in various ways. Besides the aforementioned factors, like a decrease in profitability or recorded losses, an increase in the risk-weighted assets as well as the minimally prescribed capital adequacy ratio, there is also the reason of the growth of loans. Empirical findings confirmed that the growth of loans GROWLit leads to a decrease in the capital buffers, due to an increase in the banks’ exposures, i.e. the volume of the risk-weighted assets when there is a speed-up in credit growth. Furthermore, the size of the banks’ capital buffers may vary due to the changes in the structure of exposures. A threat from the so called cosmetic adjustments of the capital adequacy ratio (i.e. the unchanged regulatory capital) or even from the false impressions of an increase in the capital buffers, due to loans being made to economic agents with lower risk-weights in crisis episodes, requires additional attention when the dynamics of the capital buffers movements are being explained. Namely, the maintenance of capital buffers at a certain level, besides by an increase in the regulatory capital, might be driven by the following factors: a decrease in the risk-weighted assets, a credit “freezing” process, continuity of recording profits and their reinvestment as well as by raising the minimally prescribed capital adequacy ratio. Thus, in the banking sectors that experienced periods of extremely large recapitalizations (e.g. the large banks in Croatia after an introduction of the marginal obligatory reserve) it is realistic to expect a further decrease in the capital buffers. Nevertheless, the credit crunch caused by the accumulated structural problems of the observed economies contributed to the capital buffers being enlarged in the recession period. 159 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 139-169 (2015) after which it remained at the same or a somewhat lower level. At the same time, after a sizeable growth of the capital buffers (in the first two observed years), a long period in their decline followed. Thus, in a period of a small frequency of the occurrence of risk events (loans charge-offs, costs recognition and value adjustments of reserves, due to an increase in non-performing loans), banks reduce their capital buffers, aimed at diminishing the effects of the unexpected losses. By taking into consideration a synchronization of the variables of the non-performing loans and the loan loss reserves as well as the appearance of a credit expansion in the period of their decrease (from 00-007), and on the contrary the appearance of the credit crunch in the period of their increase (from 007-00), a conclusion on the banks’ perceptions of credit risk and the pro-cyclicality of their credit activity can be made. Thus, a decline in the banks’ capital buffers is the consequence of a long period of expansive credit policies on the part of the banks, which are connected to their perceptions of reduced credit risks and the occurrence of risk events, and which are altogether reflected in their provisioning policies and loans classifications into groups according to their quality. 60 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 139-169 (2015) ana kundid novokmet: cyclicality of bank capital buffers in south-eastern europe: endogenous and exogenous aspects the regulatory pressures for an increase in capital is proxied by the two types of dummy variables that are interchangeably employed in the models, as well as the interaction terms which contain those dummy variables. The first approximation is set out in form of the banks with a lower or a higher capitalization in comparison to the minimally prescribed capital adequacy ratios for the country (dydevBUFLow and dydevBUFWell). The second one differentiates banks with a lower or a higher equity to assets ratio in comparison to a mean value of a certain banking sector in which the bank operates (LOWCA and WELLCA). Most of the banks from the South-Eastern European area were well-capitalized, which is supported by the fact of the sizeable capital buffers. That caused a number of options for a definition and analysis of the regulatory pressure impact as being rather small. Thus, the methodology that is regularly applied in the empirical background is borrowed in this paper. With reference to this, banks with a capitalization that is lower than or equal to that which is regulatorily required are treated as the banks under regulatory pressures, while banks that according to that criterion were well-capitalized were banks without regulatory pressures. Although this logic may be absolutely justified soon after the capital requirements standard was put into effect, when there was a substantial number of undercapitalized banks, a familiarity with the characteristics of banking sectors of the observed countries serves as a support for the conclusion that weakly capitalized banks are usually large banks or those that are “too big to fail”, while the banks with extremely high capitalization are usually small-sized banks (for which there was a poor data continuity in the available financial indicators), which do not serve prime customers, but most often riskier clients. However, that knowledge might contribute to the economic interpretation of the research findings. As was earlier pointed out, there were more well-capitalized banks (dydevBUFWell) than weakly capitalized banks (dydevBUFLow) in the data set, when the benchmark is the minimally prescribed capital adequacy ratio. In the case of the second dummy variables group (LOWCA and WELLCA) the differences between the subsamples’ size with reference to capitalization were not so remarkable. The obtained results confirm that the banks which are assumed to be under the regulatory pressure (dydevBUFLow) had a greater drop in the capital buffers. A literal and isolated approach would lead to a conclusion that bank capital requirements regulation did not add to the banks’ capitalization, i.e. that it did not fulfill its purpose. On the other hand, if there is an understanding that accumulation and consumption of capital are carried out in phases or cycles, and that in the observed data sample a decreasing trend in the capital buffers was recorded, then the obtained results are expected. If lower capitalization is linked to the larger banks, the estimated direction of influence is even clearer. This implies the following conclusion: the weakly capitalized banks at least maintained a certain capitalization level, as the volume of loans and the risk-weighted assets was continuously increasing during the observed period. Thus, capital adequacy regulation is not irrelevant, as might be concluded from the research results. Furthermore, the weakly capitalized banks could be perceived as the most efficient ones in terms of the cost of capital, as they keep the required capitalization at the minimum level, as do those whose market position obviously ensures them fast and successful recapitalization if necessary in periods of economic expansion, which is in contrast to the understanding that those banks are under regulatory pressures. Thus, higher bank capital buffers may not necessarily have positive connotations, if riskier operations and volatile secondary financial funds of the small-sized banks are borne in mind, which altogether has to be compensated with substantial capital surpluses. Empirical research into South-Eastern Europe confirmed that there is a certain amount of evidence for the cyclicality of changes in the capital buffers, which is an outcome of the financial characteristics of the observed banks, as well as the economic environment. In periods of economic expansion, banks increase their capital the most often as a consequence of market pressures and their appetites for risk taking, while in economic downturns or crisis periods, banks usually have to increase their capital due to the regulatory pressures. Meanwhile, the risk undertaken in the previous periods is already significantly being materialized. The research into South-Eastern Europe reveals that the changes in the level of the credit risks taken, as well as an increase in the profitability and the loan loss reserves, positively determine changes in the banks’ capital buffers, while the initial levels of capital buffers and credit growth negatively drive the changes in ca- ana kundid novokmet: cyclicality of bank capital buffers in south-eastern europe: endogenous and exogenous aspects 4 CONCLUSION The initial introduction of capital requirements was followed by a radical decrease in the aggregate credit level, and thus the problem of the capital requirements pro-cyclicality was heavily exploited and empirically examined in the 1990s. Nevertheless, when it is learned that the changes in the aggregate volume of loans could be also explained by some other effects, apart from the effect of regulatory restrictions, the cyclicality of the capital requirements begins to be more at the focus of research. Requirements for the better capitalization of banks regularly occur in periods of economic distress. In such times, the volume of the partially collectable and non-performing loans increase and with the drop in banks’ credit and investment activity, their profitability declines. In the aforementioned circumstances, credit and market risks enlarge, recapitalizations are less available, while deposits stagnate or in an even worse case they decline. All this leads to credit and, most often, equity rationing as well as fire sales of securities portfolios. In that case, the volume of the “free” regulatory capital or the capital buffers may neutralize any impairment of the key elements of the banking stability. Thus, it is rather important empirically to identify what drives the volume of the banks’ capital buffers. The discovery that there has been no empirical research into the determinants of changes in the capital buffers of South-Eastern European banks inspired this research. financial theory and practice 39 (2) 139-169 (2015) Using the interaction terms LOWCAit * dyREC and dydevBUFLowit * dyREC it is found out that the capital buffers of the weakly capitalized banks decrease in the recession period. This is additionally confirmed for well-capitalized banks (dydevBUFWellit * dyREC * ABBUFFi,t–1). A particularly negative influence on the changes in capital buffers was recorded in the year 008 (variable dydevBUFLowit * dy2008). On the other hand, well-capitalized banks, which dominate the sample, in the expansion periods reduce their capital buffers (dydevBUFWellit * dyEXP * ABBUFFi,t–1). To sum up, it might be concluded that at the data set level, capital buffers are continuously trending downwards, which is driven not only by the banks’ specificities, but also by the general economic conditions. 6 6 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 139-169 (2015) ana kundid novokmet: cyclicality of bank capital buffers in south-eastern europe: endogenous and exogenous aspects pital buffers. Furthermore, the capital buffers increase in only certain years of economic expansion, while during the recession they tend to decrease continuously. Although the applied methodology is not completely comparable to the earlier empirical estimations in the part of an approximation of the economic cycle, the conclusion can be made that the obtained results are comparable to the empirical background. Notwithstanding the initial capitalization level, banks mainly reduced their capital buffers over the observed period. Thus, an affirmation of the counter-cyclical capital buffers seems to be an adequate direction in the capital adequacy standard development. Nevertheless, a question can be asked as to the repercussions from the implementation of counter-cyclical capital buffers, as well as from the changes of the regulatory capital structure towards a higher share of the Tier capital. Namely, the cost of capital is an integral part in loan pricing, and thus it remains questionable what the implications of the mentioned regulatory restrictions will be in addition to those from the selected or regulatory required capital buffers to the risk and return of banks with a time lag. The importance of getting an empirical answer to this question for South-Eastern European countries is additionally supported by the high risk premiums of the observed countries, which enlarge the cost of capital and other financing sources of banks in the crisis periods. Thus, there is a great challenge for the prudential authorities in their attempts to maintain the banking sectors’ stability, which can be summarized in the following: with the discussed regulatory changes, they must not encourage banks to adjustments in their operations such as to reveal the countereffectiveness of the regulatory actions in the long-term. Examinations show that the risk-free rate (which reflects the country risk premium) in the estimations of the cost of equity capital, using the CAPM model, represents up to /3 of the overall cost of the bank equity capital (e.g. King, 2009). APPENDIX 63 Table a1 Distribution of banks by countries in the selected data sample Number of banks (N=88) Croatia 15 Romania 3 Bulgaria Greece Slovenia 7 Macedonia 7 Bosnia and Herzegovina 7 Albania 4 Source: Author’s presentation. Table a2 Required regulatory minimum in the capital adequacy ratio in the South-Eastern European countries in observed years Country 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 Albania Bosnia and Herzegovina 0 0 0 Bulgaria Greece 8 8 8 8 8 8 8 8 8 8 8 Croatia 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 8 8 8 8 8 8 8 8 8 8 8 8 8 0 0 8 8 8 8 0 8 8 8 8 8 8 8 8 8 8 Macedonia Romania Serbia Slovenia 8 Source: Official websites of central banks across countries (various publications and decisions), ECB, annual publication Transition report in the period from 2000-2010, Wisniwski (2005), Barisitz and Gardó (2008), Jokipii and Milne (2008), Athanasoglou (2011). ana kundid novokmet: cyclicality of bank capital buffers in south-eastern europe: endogenous and exogenous aspects Serbia financial theory and practice 39 (2) 139-169 (2015) Country ana kundid novokmet: cyclicality of bank capital buffers in south-eastern europe: endogenous and exogenous aspects 1.0000 0.0572 0.1819 -0.4745 -0.3953 -0.0160 -0.0660 -0.0348 -0.0344 -0.0660 0.0016 0.0892 -0.0339 -0.1554 -0.4054 1.0000 -0.1516 -0.0799 -0.1655 0.0838 -0.0986 0.0376 -0.0124 -0.0986 -0.0612 0.1314 0.0478 0.0355 -0.1044 Source: Author’s calculation. deltaABBUFF deltaNPL_L ROA lagABBUFF GROWL LLR_L dy2007 dydevBUFLow BUFLow_~2008 BUFWell~2007 LOWCA_dy2007 LOWCA_dyREC BUFLow_dyREC B~REC_lagA~F B~EXP_lagA~F deltaA~F deltaN~L 1.0000 -0.0464 0.0939 -0.0318 0.1252 -0.1117 -0.0436 0.1252 0.0598 -0.1887 -0.1289 -0.1733 0.0525 1.0000 0.1417 0.1703 0.0371 -0.0756 -0.0504 0.0371 -0.0684 -0.1970 -0.0683 0.3504 0.8433 ROA lagABB~F 1.0000 -0.1584 0.3881 -0.0493 -0.0145 0.3881 0.2198 -0.1987 -0.0448 -0.1483 0.2338 GROWL 1.0000 -0.1344 -0.0030 -0.0159 -0.1344 -0.0816 -0.0237 0.0059 0.0751 0.1347 LLR_L 1.0000 -0.0445 -0.0280 1.0000 0.7027 -0.1684 -0.0397 -0.1343 0.1165 1.0000 0.6297 -0.0445 -0.0312 0.1999 0.8931 -0.0449 -0.0688 1.0000 -0.0280 -0.0197 0.0654 0.3483 -0.0283 -0.0433 1.0000 0.7027 -0.1684 -0.0397 -0.1343 0.1165 1.0000 -0.1184 -0.0279 -0.0944 -0.0167 1.0000 0.2358 0.0909 -0.2605 1.0000 -0.0401 -0.0614 1.0000 -0.2077 1.0000 dy2007 dydevB~w BUF~2008 BUF~2007 LOW~2007 LOWCA_~C BUFLow~C B~REC_~F B~EXP_~F . correlate deltaABBUFF deltaNPL_L ROA lagABBUFF GROWL LLR_L dy2007 dydevBUFLow BUFLow_dy2008 BUFWell_dy2007 LOWCA_dy2007 LOWCA_dyREC BUFLow_dyREC BUFWell > _dyEXP_lagABBUFF (obs=341) financial theory and practice 39 (2) 139-169 (2015) PrinT ouT a1 From STATA 12: Correlation matrix 64 1.0000 B~EXP_~F 1.0000 0.3895* -0.0510 0.0065 0.1447* 0.6764* -0.0268 -0.0634 1.0000 -0.0575 -0.0299 -0.1524* 0.0250 -0.0789* -0.0216 0.0764* 0.0180 -0.0744* -0.1163* -0.2385* 0.0497 1.0000 0.2192* 0.0343 -0.0089 -0.0553 -0.0295 -0.0147 -0.0699 -0.1454* -0.0493 0.3956* 0.8715* 1.0000 -0.1673* 0.1352* -0.0459 -0.0162 0.2117* 0.0996* -0.1381* -0.0573 -0.0945* 0.2987* 1.0000 -0.0716* 0.1241* -0.0138 -0.0577 -0.0900* -0.0184 0.0401 0.1404* -0.0035 LLR_L 1.0000 -0.0199 1.0000 -0.0131 0.6425* 1.0000 0.0625 -0.1395* -0.0683* 1.0000 0.2858* -0.0345 -0.0227 0.2474* 1.0000 -0.0119 -0.0771 -0.0520 0.0623 -0.0207 -0.0282 0.0261 -0.0503 -0.1904* -0.0489 Source: Author’s calculation. B~EXP_lagA~F dydevBUFLow BUFLow_~2008 BUFWell~2007 LOWCA_dy2007 LOWCA_dyREC BUFLow_dyREC B~REC_lagA~F B~EXP_lagA~F 1.0000 -0.1529* -0.0903 -0.1661* 0.0400 -0.0556 0.0162 -0.0105 -0.0996 -0.0203 0.1687* 0.0496 0.0361 -0.1083* GROWL 1.0000 -0.0228 -0.0200 0.9948* 0.6585* -0.1037* -0.0347 -0.0771 0.0261 dy2007 1.0000 -0.1051* dydevB~w BUF~2008 BUF~2007 LOW~2007 LOWCA_~C BUFLow~C B~REC_~F 1.0000 0.0595 0.0968* -0.7010* -0.3680* 0.0648 0.0025 -0.0187 -0.0016 0.0025 0.0128 0.0565 -0.0119 -0.2319* -0.6339* ROA lagABB~F ana kundid novokmet: cyclicality of bank capital buffers in south-eastern europe: endogenous and exogenous aspects deltaABBUFF deltaNPL_L ROA lagABBUFF GROWL LLR_L dy2007 dydevBUFLow BUFLow_~2008 BUFWell~2007 LOWCA_dy2007 LOWCA_dyREC BUFLow_dyREC B~REC_lagA~F B~EXP_lagA~F deltaA~F deltaN~L financial theory and practice 39 (2) 139-169 (2015) . pwcorr deltaABBUFF deltaNPL_L ROA lagABBUFF GROWL LLR_L dy2007 dydevBUFLow BUFLow_dy2008 BUFWell_dy2007 LOWCA_dy2007 LOWCA_dyREC BUFLow_dyREC BUFWell_dyREC_lagABBUFF > EXP_lagABBUFF, star(5) PrinT ouT a2 From STATA 12: Correlation matrix (statistically significant at the 5% level) 165 66 Table a3 Subsamples results when economic trend is criterion variable for the data subsampling (REC is for recession, EXP is for expansion) Explanatory variables financial theory and practice 39 (2) 139-169 (2015) DABBUFFi,t–1 DNPL_Lit ROAit ABBUFFi,t–1 ana kundid novokmet: cyclicality of bank capital buffers in south-eastern europe: endogenous and exogenous aspects GROWLit LLR_Lit a Number of observations Number of banks Sargan test (p-value) First-order autocorrelation (p-value) Second-order autocorrelation (p-value) REC=1 -0.1191*** (0.0404) 0.086** (0.04) 0.3983** (0.844) -0.674*** (0.06) -0.073** (0.034) 0.5085*** (0.30) 0.9302 (0.8258) 105 75 0.487 0.0658 0.9297 EXP=1 -0.70*** (0.030) 0.0091 (0.0192) 1.7256*** (0.373) -0.3400*** (0.0154) -0.044*** (0.0073) 0.4982*** (0.060) -1.8949*** (0.3477) 6 73 0.487 0.0658 0.9297 *** Statistically significant at 1% level, ** statistically significant at 5% level, * statistically significant at 10% level. Source: Author’s calculation. 67 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 139-169 (2015) ana kundid novokmet: cyclicality of bank capital buffers in south-eastern europe: endogenous and exogenous aspects REFERENCES 1. Ayuso, J., Pérez, D. and Saurina, J., 2004. Are Capital Buffers Pro-cyclical? Evidence from Spanish Panel Data. Journal of Financial Intermediation, 3(), pp. 249-264. doi: 10.1016/S1042-9573(03)00044-5 . Athanasoglou, P., 0. Bank Capital and Risk in the South Eastern European Region. [pdf] Munich Personal RePEc Archive, 300 (May). Available at: <http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/300//MPRA_paper_300.pdf>. 3. Barisitz, S. and Gardó, S., 2008. Financial Sector Development in Serbia: Closing Ranks with Peers. Focus on European Economic Integration, 2, pp. 94-119. 4. Benston, G. J., 007. Basel II and Bankers’ Propensity to Take or Avoid Excessive Risk. Atlantic Economic Journal, 35(4), pp. 373-382. doi: 10.1007/s11293-0079093-7 5. Berrospide, J. M. and Edge, R. M., 2010. The Effects of Bank Capital on Lending: What Do We Know, and What Does it Mean?. [pdf] Federal Reserve Board, Finance and Economics Discussion Series, 44 (August). Available at: <http://www. federalreserve.gov/pubs/feds/00/0044/0044pap.pdf>. 6. Bikker, J. A. and Hu, H., 2002. Cyclical Patterns in Profits, Provisioning and Lending of Banks. [pdf] De Nederlandsche Bank, Staff Reports, 86 (May). Available at: <http://www.dnb.nl/binaries/sr086_tcm46-46863.pdf>. 7. Bikker, J. A. and Metzemakers, P. A. J., 2007. Is Bank Capital Procyclical? A Cross-Country Analysis. Kredit und Kapital, 2 (August), pp. 1-29. 8. Boucinha, M. and Ribeiro, N., 007. The Determinants of Portuguese Banks’ Capital Buffers. [pdf] Banco de Portugal Financial Stability Report, pp. 153-164. Available at: <https://www.bportugal.pt/en-S/BdP%0Publications%0Research/ AR0070_e.pdf>. 9. Brissimis, S. N. and Delis, M. D., 2009. Identification of a Loan Supply Function: A Cross-Country Test for the Existence of a Bank Lending Channel. Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions & Money, 19(2), pp. 321-335. doi: 10.1016/j.intfin.2008.01.004 10. Caprio, G. and Honohan, P., 1999. Restoring Banking Stability: Beyond Supervised Capital Requirements. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 3(4), pp. 43-64. doi: 10.1257/jep.13.4.43 . Daníelsson, J., Embrechts, P., Goodhart, C., Keating, C., Muennich, F., Renault, O. and Song Shin, H., 00. An Academic Response to Basel II. [pdf] Special Paper, London School of Economics Financial Markets Group and Economic & Social Research Council Research Centre, 30 (May). Available at: <http://www. bis.org/bcbs/ca/fmg.pdf>. 12. Fonseca, A. R. and González, F., 2010. How Bank Capital Buffers Vary Across Countries: The Influence of Cost of Deposits, Market Power and Bank Regulation. Journal of Banking & Finance, 34(4), pp. 892-902. doi: 0.06/j.jbankfin.2009.09.020 13. Fonseca, A. R., González, F. and Pereira da Silva, L., 2010. Cyclical Effects of Bank Capital Buffers with Imperfect Credit Markets: International Evidence. [pdf] 68 14. financial theory and practice 39 (2) 139-169 (2015) 15. 6. ana kundid novokmet: cyclicality of bank capital buffers in south-eastern europe: endogenous and exogenous aspects 7. 18. 19. 0. . . 23. 4. 25. 26. Banco Central do Brasil, 6 (October). Available at: <http://www.bcb.gov.br/ pec/wps/ingl/wps216.pdf>. Francis, W. and Osborne, M., 2009(a). On the Behaviour and Determinants of Risk-Based Capital Ratios: Revisiting the Evidence from UK Banking Institutions. [pdf] Financial Services Authority, 3 (March). Available at: <http://www. fsa.gov.uk/pubs/occpapers/op31.pdf>. Francis, W. and Osborne, M., 2009(b). Bank Regulation, Capital and Credit Supply: Measuring the Impact of Prudential Standards. [pdf] Financial Services Authority, 36 (September). Available at: <http://www.fsa.gov.uk/pubs/occpapers/ op36.pdf>. Gambacorta, L. and Mistrulli, P. E., 004. Does Bank Capital Affect Lending Behavior?. Journal of Financial Intermediation, 13(4), pp. 436-457. doi: 0.06/ j.jfi.2004.06.00 Herring, R. J., 007. The Rocky Road to Implementation of Basel II in the United States. Atlantic Economic Journal, 35(4), pp. 411-429. doi: 10.1007/s11293-0079094-6 Jackson, P., Furfine, C., Groeneveld, H., Hancock, D., Jones, D., Perraudin, W., Radecki, L. and Yoneyama, M., 1999. Capital Requirements and Bank Behaviour: The Impact of the Basle Accord. [pdf] Bank for International Settlements, Basle Committee on Banking Supervision, (April). Available at: <http://www.bis.org/ publ/bcbs_wp1.pdf>. Jokipii, T. and Milne, A., 2008. The Cyclical Behaviour of European Bank Capital Buffers. Journal of Banking & Finance, 32(8), pp. 1440-1451. doi: 0.06/j. jbankfin.2007.12.00 Jokipii, T. and Milne, A., 0. Bank Capital Buffer and Risk Adjustment Decisions. Journal of Financial Stability, 7(3), pp. 165-178. doi: 0.06/j.jfs. 00.0.00 Kane, E. J., 007(a). Basel II: A Contracting Perspective. Journal of Financial Services Research, 32(1-2), pp. 39-53. doi: 10.1007/s10693-007-0020-5 Kane, E. J., 007(b). Connecting National Safety Nets: The Dialectics of the Basel II Contracting Process. Atlantic Economic Journal, 35(4), pp. 399-409. doi: 10.1007/s11293-007-9095-5 King, M. R., 2009. The Cost of Equity for Global Banks: A CAPM Perspective from 1990 to 2009. [pdf] Bank for International Settlements Quarterly Review, September, pp. 59-73. Available at: <http://www.bis.org/publ/qtrpdf/r_qt0909g. pdf>. Lastra, R. M., 004. Risk-Based Capital Requirements and Their Impact upon the Banking Industry: Basel II and CAD III. Journal of Financial Regulation and Compliance, 12(3), pp. 225-239. doi: 10.1108/13581980410810803 Lindquist, K.-G., 2004. Banks’ Buffer Capital: How Important is Risk. Journal of International Money and Finance, 23(3), pp. 493-513. doi: 0.06/j.jimonfin.2004.01.006 Marcucci, J. and Quagliariello, M., 2008. Is Bank Portfolio Riskiness Procyclical? Evidence from Italy Using a Vector Autoregression. Journal of International Fi- 27. 29. 30. 32. 33. 34. 35. 36. 37. 38. 39. ana kundid novokmet: cyclicality of bank capital buffers in south-eastern europe: endogenous and exogenous aspects 31. 169 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 139-169 (2015) 8. nancial Markets, Institutions & Money, 8(), pp. 46-63. doi: 0.06/j.intfin.2006.05.00 Milne, A. and Whalley, A. E., 2001. Bank Capital Regulation and Incentives for Risk-Taking. [pdf] Cass Business School Research Paper, December. Available at: <http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=299319>. Miyake, A. and Nakamura, T., 007. A Dynamic Analysis of an Economy with Banking Optimization and Capital Adequacy Regulations. Journal of Economics and Business, 59(1), pp. 14-27. doi: 10.1016/j.jeconbus.2005.12.00 Moosa, I. A., 2010. Basel II as a Casualty of the Global Financial Crisis. Journal of Banking Regulation, 11(2), pp. 95-114. doi: 10.1057/jbr.2010. Morrison, A. D. and White, L., 2005. Crises and Capital Requirements in Banking. The American Economic Review, 95(5), pp. 1548-1572. doi: 10.1257/000282 805775014254 Quagliariello, M., 2008. Does Macroeconomy Affect Bank Stability? A Review of the Empirical Evidence. Journal of Banking Regulation, 9(2), pp. 102-115. doi: 10.1057/jbr.2008.4 Rodríguez, L. J., 2003. Banking Stability and the Basel Capital Standards. Cato Journal, 23(1), pp. 115-126. Saidenberg, M. and Schuermann, T., 003. The New Basel Capital Accord and Questions for Research. [pdf] Wharton Financial Institutions Center, 03-4 (May). Available at: <http://fic.wharton.upenn.edu/fic/papers/03/0314.pdf>. Shrieves, R. E. and Dahl, D., 1992. The Relationship Between Risk and Capital in Commercial Banks, Journal of Banking & Finance, 16(2), pp. 439-457. doi: 10.1016/0378-4266(92)90024-T Stolz, S. M., 2007. Bank Capital and Risk-Taking: The Impact of Capital Regulation, Charter Value, and the Business Cycle. Kiel Studies. Berlin Heidelberg: Springer-Verlag. Stolz, S. and Wedow, M., 2011. Banks’ Regulatory Capital Buffer and the Business Cycle: Evidence for Germany. Journal of Financial Stability, 7(2), pp. 980. doi: 10.1016/j.jfs.2009.09.00 Škrabić, B., 2009. Determinante razvoja financijskog sustava zemalja središnje i istočne Europe. Specijalistički poslijediplomski rad. Zagreb: Ekonomski fakultet. Van den Heuvel, S. J., 2008. The Welfare Cost of Bank Capital Requirements. Journal of Monetary Economics, 55(2), pp. 298-320. doi: 0.06/j.jmoneco.007..00 Wisniwski, S., 2005. Bankers’ Perspectives – Dynamic Banking in a Changing Market. In: I. Matthäus-Maier and J. D. von Pischke, eds. EU Accession – Financial Sector Opportunities and Challenges for Southeast Europe. Germany: Springer, pp. 3-6. doi: 10.1007/3-540-26963-0_1 Financial stress indicators for small, open, highly euroized countries: the case of Croatia MIRNA DUMIČIĆ, MSc* Review article** JEL: E44, E50, G0 doi: 10.3326/fintp.39.2.3 Special thanks go to Ana-Maria Čeh and two anonymous referees for exceptionally useful suggestions and comments. The views stated in this work are the viewpoints of the author and do not necessarily express the stance of the Croatian National Bank. ** Received: June , 04 Accepted: February 0, 05 * The article was submitted for the 2014 annual award of the Prof. Dr. Marijan Hanžeković Prize. Mirna DUMIČIĆ Croatian National Bank, Trg hrvatskih velikana 3, 10000 Zagreb, Croatia e-mail: [email protected] 7 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 171-203 (2015) Abstract The main objective of this paper is to construct high-frequency composite indicators of financial stress for Croatia that will enable the monitoring of the total level of financial stress and its components on the domestic financial market. Emphasis is put on the choice of variables appropriate for small, open, highly euroized economies characterised by bank-centric financial systems dominantly owned by foreign banks, shallow financial markets and dependence on foreign capital. Keywords: financial stress, financial stability, financial markets, systemic risk, composite index, Croatia mirna dumičić: financial stress indicators for small, open, highly euroized countries: the case of croatia 1 INTRODUCTION Many research papers refer to the strong and negative relation between stress episodes on the financial markets and financial and macroeconomic stability, and emphasize their adverse impact on overall economic activity (Hubrich and Tetlow, 2012; Kliesen et al., 2012). In developing an analytical framework for monitoring financial markets, the objective is to encompass all of the most important stress sources that might cause the materialization of systemic risks. For this purpose, individual indicators could be used. Nevertheless, in order to reduce the volume of data from financial markets, while obtaining information about the total level of stress in the financial system, these indicators are often aggregated into composite indices. The stronger the initial shock, the higher the correlation among the different segments of the financial system. This makes the use of aggregated data, reflecting developments in various segments of the financial system, the starting point for an analysis of financial stress and systemic risk (Kota and Saqe, 2013). The main goal of this paper is to construct high-frequency financial stress indicators for Croatia, which will enable the monitoring of the level of overall financial stress in the domestic financial system, as well as in particular segments of the financial market, and which will provide timely indication of possible stress episodes and systemic risks materialization. In addition to the analysis of stress periods, there is an emphasis on the importance of information that indices can provide in tranquil periods on the financial markets. In a review paper about the measurement of financial stress, Kliesen et al. (2012) show that most of the composite financial stress indicators are constructed for highly developed financial markets with diversified financial instruments and numerous financial indicators. However, by adjusting the set of variables included in the index, they can also be useful for the analysis of developments in less developed financial systems. The main focus of this paper is thus not on development of a methodology for computing composite indices, but on the identification of variables that reflect financial stress in small, open, highly-euroized economies, characterized by bank-centric financial systems dominated by foreign banks, shal- 2 FINANCIAL STRESS AND THE CHANNELS THROUGH WHICH IT AFFECTS FINANCIAL AND MACROECONOMIC STABILITY There is no universally accepted definition of financial stress. Dufrénot et al. (0) describe it as a situation in which there is an enhanced probability of turbulence in the financial markets accompanied with a currency or balance of payments crisis, a sudden stop in capital inflows or capital outflows, stock market crashes or the inability of a government to meet its liabilities. Holló (0) considers financial stress as disturbances in the financial system that unexpectedly affect the price and turnover of financial instruments, which can be accompanied by the collapse of systemically important financial institutions and the inability of the financial system to carry out its main role and allocate financial resources, resulting in a considerable economic slowdown. It can be concluded that financial stress implies disturbances in the normal functioning of financial markets and in the process of financial intermediation that can spill over onto the real sector (Hakkio and Keeton, 2009; Balakrishnan et al., 2009). mirna dumičić: financial stress indicators for small, open, highly euroized countries: the case of croatia The paper is divided into five main parts. After an introduction there is a detailed explanation of the theoretical concept of financial stress, and the specific features of stress episodes are described, together with the channels through which they can influence financial and macroeconomic instability from the perspective of a small, open and highly euroized economy. The third section presents the problems involved in constructing FSIs, and a review of the methods of aggregating individual indicators into a composite index is given. Part four explains the variables assessed as being appropriate for the construction of the FSIs for Croatia, considering the characteristics of the financial system, and the country’s economic and monetary characteristics. In order to check the robustness of the results, the indices are calculated by three methods. The main trends in financial stress in the period from early 00 to the end of 03 are also described, as well as the stress episodes identified by the Markov switching model. The final part briefly summarizes the main results and contributions of this paper. 73 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 171-203 (2015) low financial markets and dependence on foreign capital because of het shortfall in domestic savings. Apart from that, the focus is on the transmission mechanism of financial market shocks to these countries. Particular attention is directed to cases in which the main transmission channel of monetary policy is the exchange rate, and in which there is no classical reference interest rate. In such situations, the domestic money market is not necessarily a relevant source of bank funding, and the interest rates in this market segment have a negligible impact on the borrowing costs for domestic sectors as they depend on trends in world financial markets and levels of risk premiums for the country and the parent banks of domestic banks. Therefore, the analysis of variables that reflect financial stress in a small open economy is the most important contribution of this paper. Its practical contribution inheres in the potential use of the FSIs for economic policy makers and financial market participants. 74 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 171-203 (2015) Although all stress episodes have their own specific features, Sinenko et al. (2012) accentuate their common attributes, such as increased uncertainty related to the value of financial assets and to the expectations of future economic developments, high expected financial losses, increased risk aversion and the general tendency of investors to keep less risky and more liquid financial assets. All of this increases the instability and volatility of prices on financial markets and results in rising risk premiums. Therefore, apart from the level, as a measure of financial stress the volatility of given variables is also often used. mirna dumičić: financial stress indicators for small, open, highly euroized countries: the case of croatia Financial stress is an inherent characteristic of a financial system. However, even when it is not high, such information should not be neglected. Sinenko et al. (2012) emphasize that prolonged periods of relatively low financial stress compared to the long-term average have often been accompanied by an exaggerated optimism on the part of market participants. This has resulted in excessive credit activity, a rise in the prices of different asset classes and the accumulation of macroeconomic imbalances due to increased current account deficits and external debt. All of this has increased risks to financial stability. If disturbances indicated by highfrequency indicators endure, there is a great probability that they will shortly affect low-frequency indicators through financial or trade channels. Increased instability on financial markets usually results in higher risk aversion, causing a rise in risk premiums and in the financing costs of domestic sectors. If combined with reduced liquidity or even completely frozen financial markets, this may result in the strong slowdown of capital flows. The research has shown that emerging markets are more affected by this than developed countries because of their increased vulnerability to potential sudden changes in capital flows (Catao, 006). Financial institutions’ interlinkages are also an important source of financial stress. In most European countries banks are the most important financial intermediaries, and their exposure to financial stress can result in high macroeconomic costs (Schou-Zibell et al., 2010). Because of their role, problems induced by the financial stresses that they have can rapidly spill over to other segments of the financial system, such as the interbank money market or the payments system. The links among financial institutions in the money market present potential channels for the rapid spillover of risks and difficulties among financial institutions in a short period. The speed of this process is proportional to the level of uncertainty and information asymmetry. An enhanced level of uncertainty related to financial stress can reduce the banks’ willingness to make loans. This motivates them to tighten their lending standards, which reduces the demand for loans as borrowers might postpone or give up on investments (Hubrich and Tetlow, 2011). In less developed financial systems the role of bank loans in the financing of the economy is usually higher than in devel- oped countries, in which the securities market is a noteworthy source of funding. This makes the influence of financial stress on loan conditions and the loan supply via this channel much more important for developing countries. 3 THE CONSTRUCTION OF A COMPOSITE INDEX Specific features of small open economies with shallow financial markets and lack of indicators used for the calculations of FSIs for developed countries imply a great challenge in the choice of variables reflecting financial stress. According to the literature, the most important potential sources of stress are the credit market, foreign exchange market, inter-bank money market and capital market (Oet et al., 2011; Jakubik and Slačik, 2013). In addition to domestic data, due to the increased liberalization of financial flows and the fact that in most countries movements on the domestic financial market are heavily dependent on international developments, data from foreign financial markets are also used. But, even if the created indicators cover at a given moment all important potential sources of financial stress, it is necessary continuously to re-examine the appropriateness of the set of selected variables and to adjust it to the development of and trends in the financial system. Therefore, FSIs calculated for different countries are not always directly mirna dumičić: financial stress indicators for small, open, highly euroized countries: the case of croatia In highly euroized countries, one of the most important channels for possible spillovers of financial stress onto financial and macroeconomic indicators is the exchange rate. In such cases a significant part of the economy is exposed to a currency-induced credit risk deriving from the currency mismatches in debtors’ assets and liabilities. If a strong depreciation of the domestic currency occurs, there is an increased likelihood of a considerable deterioration of the loan quality. In these countries, the main monetary policy transmission channel usually is not the interest rate, but the exchange rate. Therefore, the information contained in movements in domestic interest rates differs from those on developed markets, in which the interest rate transmission channel is functioning. In addition to that, in some banking systems that are dominantly foreign owned and that are reliant on parent bank funding, domestic money market interest rates can have an almost negligible impact on the cost of domestic sector borrowing. This cost primarily depends on the perception of the country risk and parent banks’ risks, as well as on the liquidity of international financial markets. financial theory and practice 39 (2) 171-203 (2015) In dominantly foreign owned banking systems, the parent banks of domestic banks represent an important transmission channel of financial stress from international to domestic financial markets. Parent banks’ problems measured in their increased risk premium affect not only the funding costs for their subsidiaries, but also their strategy related to the operations of the subsidiary banks. This can strongly influence credit activity and real economic developments in the countries where they have large exposures. Balakrishnan et al. (2009) confirm that the most pronounced channel for the transmission of financial stress to European emerging markets during the recent crisis was through the western European banks. 75 76 comparable, but they can provide useful information about the financial stress dynamics in different markets. Kliesen et al. (2012) present a detailed review of indicators and methods used for the construction of FSIs, while Jakubik and Slačik (2013) provide a useful example of the construction of financial instability indices for CEE countries, including Croatia. financial theory and practice 39 (2) 171-203 (2015) mirna dumičić: financial stress indicators for small, open, highly euroized countries: the case of croatia In the literature about early warning systems, use is often made of binary methods, in which tranquil periods are marked with a zero and a crisis period with a one. But in the construction of the FSIs, the objective is to create a continuous measure that will show the level and the development of financial stress (Balakrishnan et al., 2011). Financial markets’ conditions are never either absolutely good or absolutely bad, as might be concluded according to binary indicators, and they should be observed relatively over a period of time (Oet et al., 2011). Therefore, Illing and Liu (2006) observe financial stress through a continuous variable, where extreme values mark a crisis episode. Such an approach emphasizes the index dynamics, rather than precise definitions of the beginning or end of a crisis episode. Commonly used methods for aggregating individual indicators into a composite index include aggregation via variance-equal weights, principal component analysis, aggregation with the use of variance-equal or chained weights of variables transformed with the use of the empirical cumulative distribution function and aggregation in which the shares of given markets in the total financing of the economy are used as weights (Jakubik and Slačik, 2013; Illing and Liu, 2003; Sinenko et al., 2012; Puddu, 2008; Holló, 2012). Although similar results are obtained irrespective of the method used, each one of them has certain drawbacks. The shortcoming of variance-equal weights aggregation derives from the initial assumption that all the variables included in the index are equally important. In this manner, greater importance is given to those market segments represented in the index with more variables (Puddu, 2008). On the other hand, weighting based on a single component in factor analysis results in a fixed set of weights for the whole analysed period (Oet et al., 2011). In the transformation of variables with the cumulative distribution function the assumption is that the gap between neighbouring variables is equal, which is usually not the case, because during long stable periods the relatively small volatility of the original variables can seem greater after transformation than it actually is (OeNB, 03). At the same time, the weights determined by all of these three methods have no economic significance, unlike the method where shares of individual markets in total loans in the economy calculated by aggregating bank loans, corporate and government bonds and shares are used as weights (Illing and Liu, 003). The potential use of the latter approach is relatively limited in less developed countries. Hence, for calculating the FSIs for Croatia the first three methods are used. Calculation of the FSIs with various methods is the first test of the robustness of the results. 3.1 WEIGHTING BASED ON vARIANCE-EqUAL WEIGHTS (FSI_vEW) Weighting based on variance-equal weights is the most often used method for the calculation of composite indices (Kliesen et al., 0). It implies the aggregation of standardized variables into a single index, in which every variable has an equal weight: in which k is the number of variables included in the index, is the sample arithmetic mean for the variable Xi and σi is the sample standard deviation for the variable Xi. financial theory and practice 39 (2) 171-203 (2015) () 77 3.2 AGGREGATION OF vARIABLES TRANSFORMED BY THE CUMULATIvE DISTRIBUTION FUNCTION (FSI_CDF) . () In this manner every observation is turned into the corresponding percentile of the cumulative distribution function and takes a value between 0 and 1. Following Sinenko et al. (2012), for the aggregation of transformed variables in the index, weights for every variable are determined as a share of the transformed variable in the sum of total transformed variables: (3) and the total index is obtained as: . (4) 3.3 PRINCIPAL COMPONENT ANALYSIS (FSI_PCA) In practice, this method is used for easier interpretation of a large number of variables which are transformed into a smaller number of uncorrelated variables or principal components (Anh and Mägi, 2009). This technique reveals the main drivers behind data variation and the interlinkages between variables that are not necessarily obvious. The correlations of the variables in the groups identified are greater within the groups than among the groups. FSIs are determined as the first principal component that explains the greatest part of the joint movement of the variables used for the construction of the index: FSI_pcat = xtα (5) mirna dumičić: financial stress indicators for small, open, highly euroized countries: the case of croatia Every variable included in the index is initially transformed with the use of the cumulative distribution function. The greatest value of a given variable has the highest rank and indicates the greatest degree of financial stress, while rank one refers to the lowest recorded value of the indicator (Oet, 2011). Values around the median correspond to the average level of stress. After the rank of every observation within the time series has been determined, the empirical cumulative distribution function is calculated as: 178 in which α is the weight vector (of the dimension number of individual variables x 1) and xt is the vector of the values of the indicator (of the dimension number of individual variables x 1) on the basis of which the indices are evaluated. The loadings determine the variables that have the greatest contribution to the explanation of the joint movement of all the components of the aggregated index (table A1). financial theory and practice 39 (2) 171-203 (2015) mirna dumičić: financial stress indicators for small, open, highly euroized countries: the case of croatia 4 FINANCIAL STRESS INDEX FOR CROATIA In choosing variables for FSI construction, the objective was to take into consideration as many as possible of the relevant segments of the domestic and foreign financial systems that might affect the level of financial stress in Croatia. Focus has been put on the specific features of the domestic financial markets, the availability of high frequency data, the economic and monetary characteristics of the country and relevant developments in foreign financial markets that might affect the stability of the domestic financial system. Daily data from 30 January 2001 to 18 December 2013 were used and risks were divided according to the stress origin – domestic or foreign, and also according to market segments (table 1). Apart from such a division, the main difference compared to the financial instability indices constructed by Jakubik and Slačik (2013) is that these FSIs include more variables for each market segment, as well as additional market signals and sources of risks such as risks related to the mother banks, bid-ask spreads and country risk premiums. Due to the high degree of euroization and the fact that in Croatia the main transmission mechanism of monetary policy is the exchange rate, several variables that reflect developments on the domestic foreign exchange market were used. Regardless of the direction in which the exchange rate moves, the increased EUR/HRK bid-ask spread and its volatility indicate higher instability and uncertainty related to the behaviour of market participants and signals an increased stress level. The forward exchange rate is an indicator of market expectations about future movements in the EUR/HRK exchange rate. Since this figure is not available for every day, particularly in the initial part of the observed period, the five-day moving average of this variable is used instead. The index also includes the level of the weighted exchange rate of the kuna to the euro, the Swiss franc and the US dollar. Although the EUR/HRK exchange rate is the most important for the Croatian economy as the external debt and most of the loans of domestic banks are in euros or indexed to the euro, Swiss franc movements have become an important potential source of stress because of the strong credit activity in this currency from 2005 to 2008. In this way the impact of the CHF/ HRK exchange rate has also been covered. At the end of 2008, Swiss franc loans accounted for 16% of total loans, or 24% of all loans denominated in or indexed to a foreign currency (CNB, 0). In spite of the importance of the exchange rate for financial stability and notwithstanding the fact there is no typical reference interest rate on the domestic money The spread between interest rates for short-term and long-term maturities reflects the liquidity risk premium and is often used as an indicator of money market developments. Since trading in maturities longer than a week in the domestic money market is negligible and there are many days when such transactions are not executed at all, it is not a reliable indicator for this market segment. In spite of this and the mentioned limitations of ZIBOR, the FSI includes the spread between the interest rate on the three-month treasury bills of the Ministry of Finance (MF) and the three-month ZIBOR. For ZIBOR there is a daily series of quotations, while the interbank interest rates for a three month maturity are available only when such transactions are executed, which significantly reduces the number of observations. This spread is the most commonly used variable for FSI calculations as it indicates the liquidity of the system by measuring the short-term credit risk and the premium on risk-free government treasury bills (Kliesen et al., 2012; Illing and Lieu, 2006). When money market liquidity is reduced or there is an increased risk that banks are unable to repay their liabilities it is expected to increase (Cardarelli et al., 2009). Another money market liquidity indicator is the use of Lombard loans. These are overnight collateralized loans available to the banks every day up to the prescribed amount of the nominal value of MoF treasury bills, at an interest rate set by the CNB. They are granted at the bank’s request at the end of the working day. An unpaid intraday loan is automatically considered a request for a Lombard loan. mirna dumičić: financial stress indicators for small, open, highly euroized countries: the case of croatia There are several overnight interest rates on domestic money market: the overnight interest rate in interbank trading, the interest rate on the Zagreb Money Market (ZMM) and Zagreb Interbank Interest Rate (ZIBOR). For calculating the FSI, the interbank interest rates have been used for the period from September 2002, while for the previous period the ZMM interest rates are used. The coefficient of correlation for these two series in the coinciding period exceeds 0.9, confirming this is a reliable time series for the price of overnight borrowing. The advantage of this variable over ZIBOR is that it is at this rate that transactions are really executed, while ZIBOR is based on the banks’ quotations which are not obligatory and do not necessarily represent the rate at which transactions are executed. Although ZIBOR largely tracks the movement of the interbank interest rates, it has not been perceived as the reference interest rate, which is confirmed by the CNB bank survey according to which the most important money market interest rate is the interbank interest rate (Ivičić et al., 2008). 179 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 171-203 (2015) market, which is also not a primary funding source for domestic banks, interest rate movements and their volatility can nevertheless indicate the (in)stability of the overall financial market. The dynamics and level of short-term interest rates in the observed period were primarily determined by the surpluses or deficits of banks’ kuna liquidity. Apart from the banks’ operations, the liquidity of the system depended on the CNB’s activities, which, when necessary, maintained the exchange rate stability by restricting kuna liquidity. 180 The use of Lombard loans can indicate liquidity problems in individual banks, and can also be used as an indicator of banking sector stability. financial theory and practice 39 (2) 171-203 (2015) Table 1 Variables used for the calculation of the FSI divided according to market segments Financial market segment Domestic markets variable EUR/HRK bid ask spread EUR/HRK volatility mirna dumičić: financial stress indicators for small, open, highly euroized countries: the case of croatia Foreign exchange market EUR/HRK forward exchange rate Exchange rate weighted according to commercial banks’ asset structure Level of O/N interbank interest rates Volatility of O/N interbank interest rates Money market Volatility of turnover on overnight market Spread between 3M MoF T-bills and 3M ZIBOR Lombard loans used Securities market Returns on CROBEX * (–1) and its volatility CROBIS return volatility Croatian kuna – denominated government bond maturing in 2019, bid-ask spread Measure Source Market liquidity, uncertainty, information asymmetry Uncertainty, information asymmetry, pressures on exchange rate stability Market expectations, appreciation or depreciation of domestic currency Bloomberg, author’s calculation Depreciation or appreciation of domestic currency CNB, author’s calculation Liquidity of banking system CNB Uncertainty, information asymmetry Uncertainty, information asymmetry, increased need for liquidity CNB, author’s calculation Market liquidity, credit risk Bloomberg, MF, author’s calculation Problems with liquidity of some participants of financial markets, indicator of stability of banks Uncertainty and information asymmetry on capital market Uncertainty and information asymmetry on bonds market Measure of market liquidity, reflects liquidity of bonds of a given issuer CNB, author’s calculation CNB CNB, author’s calculation CNB ZSE, author’s calculation ZSE, author’s calculation Bloomberg, author’s calculation Foreign markets LIBOR – OIS spread Money market EONIA volatility EURIBOR 6M and EONIA spread Uncertainty on global money market, risk of interbank loans on money market Uncertainty on euro money market, market liquidity Liquidity premium Bloomberg, author’s calculation Bloomberg, author’s calculation Bloomberg, author’s calculation Financial market segment Foreign markets variable EMBI for Croatia 181 Bloomberg Stability of operations of parent Bloomberg, author’s banks, costs of borrowing, calculation capital withdrawal Liquidity measure, reflects liquidity of securities Bloomberg, author’s calculation Measure of the expected shortterm volatility on the capital market Bloomberg It is not very likely that developments in the domestic capital market will significantly influence the overall financial stability, because it is still relatively underdeveloped and is not significant funding source for domestic corporates. Nevertheless, enhanced volatility in the stock prices induced by the instability in other market segments or macroeconomic developments can indicate an increased degree of risk and instability in the financial system. Hence the FSI includes return on Zagreb Stock Exchange index CROBEX and its volatility, since a fall in the prices of shares and their increased volatility can indicate stress in this market segment. Return on CROBEX is calculated as the annual change in the index multiplied by minus one so that a fall in the price of shares indicates an increased financial stress (Balakrishnan et al., 2009). The domestic debt securities market is characterized by low liquidity where government bonds account for more than 90% of bond market capitalization. CROBIS is a bond price index calculated on the basis of market capitalization calculated at the end of each trading day as average daily price weighted by the quantity for all bonds included in the index and its volatility is included in the FSI. The FSI also includes the bid-ask spread for the kuna-denominated government bond maturing in 2019, which measures the liquidity risk. A low level of this spread characterizes liquid markets with low transaction costs (Holló, 2012). From the variables representing the foreign financial markets, the index includes data from global money market, share prices and various forms of risk premiums calculated on the basis of data from the bond market, which affect the borrowing costs of domestic sectors. Particularly important for the domestic financial system is the liquidity of the euro money market as it affects the funding costs of parent mirna dumičić: financial stress indicators for small, open, highly euroized countries: the case of croatia VDAX Investor perception about risk of investing in Croatian government bonds, macroeconomic outlook of country Source financial theory and practice 39 (2) 171-203 (2015) Securities market CDS of parent banks of domestic banks weighted according to their share in banking sector assets Difference between bidask spreads for Croatian and German government eurobonds (04) Measure 182 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 171-203 (2015) banks. Developments in this market segment can have both direct and indirect impacts on the availability and price of borrowing for domestic sectors and capital flows. In the extreme case of market illiquidity, when there is a considerable fall in turnover and prices collapse beyond values justified by fundamentals, there is a large probability that domestic sectors’ funding will be considerably constrained or even made impossible. mirna dumičić: financial stress indicators for small, open, highly euroized countries: the case of croatia The average daily interest rate on overnight unsecured loans in euros (EONIA) shows the liquidity of the euro interbank market, and partially reflects movements on world financial markets. Its increased volatility suggests an amplified level of instability as well as information asymmetry among market participants. The sixmonth EURIBOR is among the most often used interest rates, as it represents the basis of the determination of many other interest rates. An increase in the spread between the six-month EURIBOR and EONIA implies an enhanced uncertainty level on the euro interbank market and an increase in liquidity risk premium. Although levels of these rates do affect the borrowing costs of domestic sectors, they are not included in the FSI because their growth is not necessarily linked to an increased stress. They generally closely follow the ECB reference interest rate, which is used to influence all other interest rates and depends on economic activity, inflationary expectations and the developments in the eurozone financial system. The spread between LIBOR and the overnight index swap (OIS) measures the stress on the international money market. OIS is an interest contract swap that reflects the expected level of the Fed’s reference interest rate, as well as the risk and liquidity on the money market. Because of the importance of the money market for the banks’ financing, as a measure of risk of interbank lending it also indirectly measures the health of the banking system. An increased LIBOR-OIS spread implies that banks could profit by borrowing from the Fed and lending to other banks, which makes sense only in cases of a more pronounced increase in credit risk. Because of the importance of the German capital market and the high correlation between Deutsche Boerse AG German Stock Index (DAX) and the CROBEX in the pre-crisis period, the VDAX index is used as variable reflecting movements on the European stock market. This indicator measures expected volatility of prices on the German stock market, and together with the Chicago Board Options Exchange Volatility Index (VIX), which measures the implicit volatility of prices of options on the S&P 500, it is often used as an indicator of risk aversion. The J. P. Morgan Emerging Market Bond Index (EMBI) reflects the risk on investment in Croatian securities and measures the country’s risk premium. It is related not only to global risk appetite, but also to the specific features of the domestic economy. It can be seen as a synthetic macroeconomic indicator as it presents in- vestor perception of the country’s macroeconomic perspective. A rise in this index reflects an increased level of financial stress and leads to a rise in domestic sectors’ borrowing costs. 4.1 THE MARkOv SWITCHING MODEL Although this research is primarily focused on FSI dynamics, in order to calculate the contribution of individual market segments to stress episodes and enable a better analysis of monetary policy reactions, their dates are calculated with the use of the Markov switching model. Crisis episodes could have also been defined exogenously, for example, as a period in which the value of the index exceeds a certain number of standard deviations or some boundary value set on the basis of a well informed assessment. The Markov switching model is suitable if the data dynamics changes through time (Yuan, 2011; Kuan, 2002). This model endogenously finds the boundary values for the determination of a stress episode and divides the sample into periods of enhanced and reduced stress. It also determines the likelihood of a transition from one regime to another (Dufrénot et al., 2011). It is assumed there are two regimes with different FSI dynamics. In the standard Markov switching model with two states in which yt is the FSI at the moment t and the arithmetical mean and variance are described by an unobserved state variable runs: (7) from which it follows that mirna dumičić: financial stress indicators for small, open, highly euroized countries: the case of croatia The risk premium for the parent banks of the largest domestic banks also considerably impacts the domestic financing costs. It is calculated by aggregating the CDS premiums for bonds of five parent banks – Unicredit S.p.A., Intesa Sanpaolo S.p.A., Société Generale, Erste Group Bank and Raiffeisen Zentralbank. Weights used were the shares of each individual domestic bank in the total assets of these five banks. This premium directly affects the price of borrowing for parent banks, which in the next step spills over onto the funding price for the subsidiary banks, and in the third step affects the borrowing costs for other domestic sectors through increased lending interest rates. Difficulties in parent bank could also reduce their available sources for financing domestic banks. financial theory and practice 39 (2) 171-203 (2015) Considering the importance of government borrowing on foreign financial markets, the index also includes the bid-ask spread for Croatian government eurobonds. In order to obtain long time series, the ten-year bond maturing in 2014 was used. The influence of general liquidity risk on global markets is excluded by reducing the bid-ask spread for the German government bond with comparable maturity from this spread for Croatian government bond. 183 184 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 171-203 (2015) where st is the current state of stress on the financial markets, μ1 and μ2 are the expectations, and σ1 and σ2 are standard deviations for the two regimes, while ε1 represents white noise. In this case st =1 can be seen as a steady state on the financial markets, while st =2 designates a state of increased financial stress. It is assumed that this variable follows a Markov process with the following transition matrix: mirna dumičić: financial stress indicators for small, open, highly euroized countries: the case of croatia where designates the likelihood of a transition from one regime to another, that is, the probability that the process is at time t in regime j, with the assumption that it was previously in regime i, and that (Yuan, 0). Calculation of dates and contributions to the episodes of financial stress was based on FSI_vew as it enables a more intuitive interpretation of the contributions of the individual components to the movement of the total FSI (Sinenko et al., 2012). 4.2 RESULTS OF THE MODEL The remainder of the paper presents indices obtained by different aggregation methods and describes the FSIs during the observed period, as well as the stress episodes and the CNB reactions related to financial market developments. Independently of the aggregation method, the indices are strongly positively correlated and result in similar information about the stress episodes (table ). Table 2 Coefficients of correlation between indices calculated by various methods IFS 1_vew IFS 2_pca IFS_3_cdf IFS 1_vew IFS 2_pca IFS_3_cdf 0.75 0.94 0.70 Note: Due to the smaller number of variables included in the FSI_pca it is not entirely comparable with the other two indices, which partially explains the lower correlation among them. Source: Author’s calculation. In order to additionally check the robustness of the results, FSI_vew and FSI_cdf are also calculated with the use of only those indicators included in the FSI_pca FSIs_vew are presented in the text itself (figures 1, 2, 3 and 4), while FSI_cdf and FSI_pca are presented in appendix, as well as in figures A1 and A3. The list of variables included in the calculation of the FSI-vew and the FSI_cdf is shown in table 1, while indicators included in the FSI_pca are shown in table A1 in appendix. (table 3). The correlation coefficients show even greater positive correlation among the indices and confirm the robustness of the results. IFS 1_vew IFS 2_pca IFS_3_cdf IFS 1_vew IFS 2_pca IFS_3_cdf 0.94 0.88 0.78 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 171-203 (2015) Table 3 Coefficients of correlation between indices calculated with the use of the same variables 185 Source: Author’s calculation. In order to obtain more detailed information from individual market segments, sub-indices have been additionally divided into several components. The domestic component FSI-D was divided into indices that describe the domestic foreign exchange market, money markets and securities market (FSI-D-FXM; FSI-DMM; FSI-D-SM – figure 3). In the same manner, the FSI-F was divided into subindices for the international money market (FSI-F-MM) and the international securities market (FSI-F-SM) (figure 4). Following the financial and macroeconomic developments that tended to bring about financial stress in Croatia, the period under observation is divided into five sub-periods: ) from 00 to the end of 00, 2) from 2003 to end-2004, 3) from 2005 to mid-2007, 4) from mid-2007 to the beginning of 2010, and 5) from 2010 to end-2013. These sub-periods, movements of total FSI and its components and the causes of identified stress episodes are described in the rest of the chapter. A comparison of movements of total FSI and its components with financial, macroeconomic and mirna dumičić: financial stress indicators for small, open, highly euroized countries: the case of croatia Useful data about financial stress were obtained by a calculation of sub-indices. In the first step the total FSI was divided into components related to the origin of the shocks that might lead to financial stress (figure 2, table 1). The sub-index FSI-D, which describes trends in the domestic components of overall financial stress, includes variables from the foreign exchange market, the money market and the securities market. The sub-index FSI-F, which reflects movements on foreign financial markets, includes indicators from the international money market and securities markets that are considered to affect the financial stress in the country through various channels. 186 monetary developments presents another verification of the robustness of the calculated composite indicators. Figure 1 Total FSI_vew Number of standard deviations 1.0 0.0 mirna dumičić: financial stress indicators for small, open, highly euroized countries: the case of croatia -1.0 FSI – total Source: Author’s calculation. Figure 2 Domestic and foreign components of total FSI_vew 2.5 2.0 Number of standard deviations financial theory and practice 39 (2) 171-203 (2015) 2.0 1.5 1.0 0.5 0.0 -0.5 -1.0 -1.5 FSI-D – domestic component Source: Author’s calculation. FSI-F – foreign component Figure 3 FSIs divided according to market segments: domestic money market, domestic securities market and domestic foreign exchange market 187 4.5 4.0 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 171-203 (2015) 3.5 Number of standard deviations 3.0 2.5 2.0 1.5 1.0 0.5 0.0 -0.5 -1.0 FSI – total FSI-D-MM – domestic money market FSI – total FSI-D-SM – domestic securities market 4.5 4.0 Number of standard deviations 3.5 3.0 2.5 2.0 1.5 1.0 0.5 0.0 -0.5 -1.0 -1.5 4.5 4.0 Number of standard deviations 3.5 3.0 2.5 2.0 1.5 1.0 0.5 0.0 -0.5 -1.0 -1.5 FSI – total Source: Author’s calculation. FSI-D-FXM – domestic foreign exchange market mirna dumičić: financial stress indicators for small, open, highly euroized countries: the case of croatia -1.5 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 171-203 (2015) Number of standard deviations Figure 4 FSIs divided according to market segments: international money market and international securities market mirna dumičić: financial stress indicators for small, open, highly euroized countries: the case of croatia FSI – total FSI-F-MM – international money market Number of standard deviations 188 FSI – total FSI-F-SM – international securities market Source: Author’s calculation. Figure 5 shows the periods determined as episodes of increased turbulences on the financial markets for an FSI_vew according to the Markov switching model. In order to verify the robustness and to confirm if the stress episodes have been correctly identified, they were also determined with the use of the FSI_cdf (appendix, figure A2). The stress periods are very similar, implying the robustness of the results. Nevertheless, it needs to be pointed out that the main objective of the identification of stress episodes is the analysis of the underlying developments and the market participants’ reactions, rather than determining their precise dates. The contributions of individual market segments and of individual sources of risks to the stress episodes were calculated for all eight stress episodes (figures 6 and 7). To simplify this analysis, episodes that were shorter-lasting but frequent in time are observed as a single stress episode. In the pre-crisis period up to the second half of 2008, there were five stress episodes. They were mostly affected by domestic financial market variables, but did not have pronounced systemic consequences. In the subsequent period, there were three stress episodes, two of which were extremely powerful not only for their intensity but also for their length, and for their strong negative impacts on the real economy. They were primarily initiated by shocks from international financial markets, although domestic indicators also contributed to them significantly. 2.0 1.0 0.6 0.5 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.0 0.2 -0.5 0.1 -1.0 1/01 4/01 7/01 10/01 1/02 4/02 7/02 10/02 1/03 4/03 7/03 10/03 1/04 4/04 7/04 10/04 1/05 4/05 7/05 10/05 1/06 4/06 7/06 10/06 1/07 4/07 7/07 10/07 1/08 4/08 7/08 10/08 1/09 4/09 7/09 10/09 1/10 4/10 7/10 10/10 1/11 4/11 7/11 10/11 1/12 4/12 7/12 10/12 1/13 4/13 7/13 10/13 0.0 FSI - total FSI – total Probability - right Probability – right Note: The shaded areas mark the stress episodes. Source: Author’s calculation. Figure 6 Contributions of individual FSI components to stress episodes: according to market segments (in %) 100 Foreign SM 80 Foreign MM Domestic SM Domestic SM 40 Domestic FXM Domestic FXM Domestic SM 20 -20 -40 Foreign SM Foreign MM Fomestic SM Domestic FXM Domestic FXM Domestic MM Domestic FXM 0 Domestic SM Domestic MM Domestic MM Domestic MM Domestic MM Domestic MM Foreign MM Foreign MM Foreign MM Domestic FXM Foreign MM Domestic SM Foreign MM Domestic FXM Domestic SM Domestic FXM Domestic MM Domestic SM Foreign MM Foreign SM Foreign SM Foreign SM Domestic MM Foreign SM Foreign SM Foreign SM -60 7/01-12/01 3/02-5/02 6/03-4/0 Source: Author’s calculation. 7/04-2/05 9/07-2/08 9/08-1/10 7/11-11/12 6/13-9/13 mirna dumičić: financial stress indicators for small, open, highly euroized countries: the case of croatia Number of standard deviations 0.8 1.0 Probability of transition to stress regime 0.9 1.5 60 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 171-203 (2015) Figure 5 Episodes of increased turbulence on the financial markets determined by the Markov switching model 189 190 Figure 7 Contributions of individual FSI components to stress episodes: according to sources and types of risk (in %) 100 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 171-203 (2015) Costsof for. borr. 80 For. banks' cred. risk 60 Uncert. SM Uncert. & liq. D-MM Curr. induced cred. risk 40 Uncert. SM 20 Curr. induced cred. risk Uncert. & liq. D-FXM mirna dumičić: financial stress indicators for small, open, highly euroized countries: the case of croatia 0 For. banks' cred. risk Dom. banks' cred.risk Uncert. & liq. D-MM Uncert. & liq. F-MM Uncert. SM Dom. banks' cred.risk Dom. banks' cred.risk Uncert. & liq. D-MM Uncert. & liq. D-FXM Uncert. & liq. D-MM Uncert. & liq. D-FXM Uncert. & liq. D-MM Uncert. & liq. F-MM Uncert. & liq. F-MM For. banks' cred. risk For. banks' cred. risk -20 -40 Uncert. & liq. D-MM Costsof for. borr. Costsof for. borr. Uncert. & liq. D-FXM Costsof for. borr. Uncert. & liq. F-MM Dom. banks' cred.risk Curr. induced cred. risk Costsof for. borr. Curr. induced cred. risk Liq.of govt. bonds Liq.of govt. bonds For. banks' cred. risk Uncert. & liq. F-MM Uncert. & liq. F-MM Uncert. SM Curr. induced cred. risk Curr. induced cred. risk Uncert. & liq. D-FXM Uncert. & liq. D-FXM Curr. induced cred. risk Uncert. & liq. D-FXM Uncert. & liq. D-FXM Uncert. SM Uncert. & liq. D-MM Uncert. & liq. F - MM Curr. induced cred. risk Liq.of govt. bonds Dom. banks' cred.risk Uncert. & liq. D-MM For. banks' cred. risk For. banks' cred. risk Dom. banks' cred.risk Uncert. SM Uncert. SM Liq.of govt. bonds For. banks' cred. risk Liq.of govt. bonds Costsof for. borr. Costsof for. borr. Costsof for. borr. Uncert. SM Uncert. & liq. F-MM -60 7/01-12/01 3/02-5/02 6/03-4/04 7/04-2/05 9/07-2/08 9/08-1/10 7/11-11/12 6/13-9/13 Source: Author’s calculation. 4.2.1 First period: from 2001 to 2003 The total FSI in the period from 2001 to 2003 was relatively volatile, but there were only two, fairly mild, stress episodes. The first one is related with the 9/11 attacks, which led to a rise in uncertainty and volatility on world financial markets and increased risk premiums. The FSI-F reveals that these turbulences were partially transmitted to the domestic financial market via the money market channel (figures 1, 2 and 4, column 1). The total FSI in this period was mostly affected by a speculative attack on domestic currency (figures 1 and 2, column 1). In the middle of August 2001, depreciation pressures on the EUR/HRK exchange rate arose, showing up much earlier than would usually have been expected, considering the seasonal inflow of foreign capital from tourism. This was encouraged by the speculative activities of some banks that in expectation of a considerable kuna depreciation started vigorously buying euros. In the shallow domestic market this additionally enhanced depreciation pressures (figure 3, column 1). The central bank intervened three times in the period between 9 August and 20 August and sold EUR 408m to the banks, which halted the depreciation pressures. In this period, a strong rise in the money market interest rates was recorded (figure 2, column 1). This encouraged some banks to use Lombard loans that they, in spite of their high rate of interest, considered as favourable within the market expectations regarding the exchange rate, so the central bank increased the interest rate for Lombard loans from 9.5% to 10.5%. The contributions calculated for this stress episode, which lasted from July to December 2001, confirm the importance of events and uncertainties on the foreign exchange market, and to a lesser extent of movements on the domestic money market, for the development of overall financial stress in the system (figures 6 and 7, column 1). The period from early 2003 to the end of 2004 was marked by a relatively low level of financial stress. This was an introduction into a quite long period of low risk premiums and low volatility of international market indicators (figures 1, 2, 3 and 4, column ). Developments on the domestic financial market in 2003 were influenced by the tightening of the CNB’s policy aimed at slowing down the credit expansion and banks’ foreign borrowing. Sanctions were introduced on the growth of domestic loans greater than 16% a year or 4% quarterly and banks were obliged to hold the minimum required amount of foreign currency claims of 35% in order to ensure appropriate foreign currency liquidity. The latter measure resulted in depreciation pressures on the kuna because of the augmented demand for foreign exchange and a reduction in primary liquidity in the banking system, as well as in a surge in the level and volatility of money market interest rates in the second half-year (figures and 3, column ). In September 2003, the CNB increased the percentage of the reserve requirement on foreign currency obligations that must be held in kuna from 25% to 35%, and additionally to 4% in November 003. These changes resulted in temporary appreciation pressures on the EUR/HRK exchange rate and increased volatility of money market interest rates (FSI-D-FXM; FSI-D-MM – figure 3, column 2). In February 2004, the minimum percentage of reserve requirements that were set aside in a special account at the CNB was increased from 40% to 60%; and by foreign exchange interventions the banking system liquidity was increased, which temporarily reduced the money market interest rates. mirna dumičić: financial stress indicators for small, open, highly euroized countries: the case of croatia 4.2.2 Second period: from 2003 to 2004 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 171-203 (2015) Domestic banking system liquidity in 2002 was relatively high and the year was marked by strong appreciation pressures due to large foreign capital inflows from tourism, enhanced foreign borrowing by the government and the commercial banks and the privatization of domestic enterprises. Through several foreign exchange interventions the CNB net created HRK4.8bn, which was partially sterilized by increasing the base for the kuna reserve requirement and by increased issuance of central bank T-bills. This ensured stability on the money and foreign exchange markets, which had been disrupted only for a short period due to the internal fraud in the treasury of Riječka banka (figure 3, column 2). The rapid CNB reaction ensured the necessary domestic and foreign currency liquidity for the normal operations of Riječka banka in the period until the new owner took it over, so this turbulence was only temporary and the crisis did not spill over to other financial institutions. This stress episode lasted from March to May 2002. 191 192 The most important sources of stress in the third stress episode from June 003 to April 2004 were developments and uncertainty on the domestic foreign exchange and domestic money market (figures 6 and 7, column 3). financial theory and practice 39 (2) 171-203 (2015) mirna dumičić: financial stress indicators for small, open, highly euroized countries: the case of croatia In July 004, interest rates surged again when the CNB imposed a marginal reserve requirement on an increase in foreign liabilities of banks, which was initially set at 24%, but has additionally been raised several times (figure 3, FSI-DMM, column 2). This resulted in considerable changes in banks’ liquidity and in oscillations of money market interest rates until early 2005. This strongly affected the FSI-D, particularly the FSI-D-MM (figures 2 and 3, column 2). Overnight interest rates went up to as high as 10%, but after several foreign exchange interventions they dropped to a relatively low %. The fourth stress episode lasted from July 2004 to February 2005 and was marked by developments on the domestic money market (figure 3, column 2; figures 6 and 7, column 4). 4.2.3 Third period: from 2005 to mid-2007 The third period was the longest period of low-level of financial stress in which there were no major turbulences in a single segment of the financial market and not a single stress episode was recorded (figures 1, 2, 3 and 4, column 3; figure 5). It was marked by high level of global liquidity, low risk appetite and the beginning of a gradual increase in reference interest rates by the Fed and the ECB prompted by exceptionally propitious economic trends. However, precisely in that period of benign market conditions a considerable deterioration in internal and external imbalances was recorded because of strong foreign borrowing, excessive credit activity and overheating of the domestic economy. Therefore, the CNB continued tightening its monetary, or rather macroprudential, policy. The marginal reserve requirement rate was gradually increased and reached 55% by the end of 2005. In early 2006, a special reserve requirement on newly issued bank debt securities, and increased capital requirements for currency-induced credit risk were introduced, the capital adequacy ratio was increased to %, at the beginning of 007 the annual credit growth was restricted to 12%, and in 2008 capital requirements for banks with higher than permitted credit growth were increased. These measures increased the overall level of financial system resilience by creating buffers against possible shocks. But in spite of CNB efforts aimed at slowing down systemic risk accumulation, it was precisely in this period of calm and stable conditions on the financial markets that systemic risks significantly increased. These risks materialized during the following stress episodes. 4.2.4 Fourth period: from mid-2007 to end-2009 The beginning of the fourth period was also the onset of the world financial crisis. In the second half of 2007 the first difficulties associated with sub-prime mortgages in the USA appeared. When issuers of securities based on these loans faced problems with their re-financing, the crisis spilled over from the mortgage market onto the interbank money market and spread globally (FSI-F – figure 2, column 4; FSI-F-MM – figure 4, column 4). Initially, these developments only slightly affected domestic FSIs (figures 1 and 2, column 4). The FSI-F increased, but its level was similar to the level recorded before the long-lasting tranquil period. It had stabilized at the beginning of 2008 and even started decreasing. Temporary stabilization on the international financial markets lasted until March 2008 and the collapse of the investment bank Bear Stearns. Although this crisis situation was solved promptly and there were no significant negative consequences for the rest of the financial system as the failed bank was taken over by the J. P. Morgan, the reduced confidence among market participants stimulated a new surge in volatility and nervousness on the international money market (figure 4, column 4). In spite of that, the influence of the FSI-F and FSI-F-MM on total FSI was not significant (figures 1 and 2, column 4). After the initial rise, the FSI-F did not change much until the collapse of Lehman Brothers in September 2008 (figures 2 and 4, column 4). This resulted in a previously unrecorded rise in global risk aversion and an increase in price volatility with a simultaneous plunge in liquidity and a rise in distrust among market participants. Therefore, both components of the FSI-F surged (figures 2 and 4, column 4). A sudden jump in the Croatian risk premium and a frozen international money market hindered the access of domestic sectors to foreign capital, which was reflected in all segments of the FSI-D (figure 3, column 4). In the fourth quarter of 2008, level and volatility of overnight interest rates rose considerably, and in November 2011 the FSI-D-MM reached a record level (figure 3, FSI-D-MM, column 4). This was induced by transactions on the capital market related to the takeover of INA d.d. by Hungary’s MOL. This led to a division of banks into those with considerable surpluses and those with notable liquidity deficits, leading to a surge in money market interest rates. Apart from that, the insta- mirna dumičić: financial stress indicators for small, open, highly euroized countries: the case of croatia The fifth identified stress episode lasted from September 2007 to February 2008 and was mostly attributable to uncertainty and volatility on the domestic and international money markets due to the increased credit risk and the fall in confidence among market participants (figures 6 and 7, column 5). financial theory and practice 39 (2) 171-203 (2015) A much greater impact on the total FSI came from the increased volatility in the domestic money market caused by the IPO of the domestic telecom company THT in October 2007 (figures 1, 2 and 3, column 4). At that time, an imbalance between money supply and demand arose as a small group of banks generated a considerable part of the demand for kuna, while participants with liquidity surplus required interest rates higher than usual. Although the system liquidity was at the usual level, the shallow money market had difficulties in adjusting to the large inflows or outflows of money, which contributed to the elevated interest rates levels and their increased volatility until the end of the year (figure 3, FSI-D-MM, column 4). 193 194 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 171-203 (2015) mirna dumičić: financial stress indicators for small, open, highly euroized countries: the case of croatia bility on world financial markets resulted in a partial withdrawal of bank deposits in October 2008. Banks were encouraged to retain more liquid assets, which increased the demand for foreign currency liquidity (figure 3, FSI-D-FXM, column 4). In order to maintain overall financial stability, the CNB was forced to restrict kuna liquidity (figure 3, FSI-D-MM, column 4). The CNB started releasing previously accumulated reserves and the first step was the abolition of the marginal reserve requirement in October 2008, which improved foreign currency liquidity in the banks and ensured the payment of international liabilities. This resulted in the preservation of a stable exchange rate and high level of international reserves, as well as in the highest recorded short-term money market interest rates. Due to the restricted kuna liquidity, the pressures on the foreign exchange market were reflected on the money market (FSI-D-MM), so in the initial phase of the escalation of the crisis it was only slightly reflected in the developments of the FSI-DFXM (figure 3, column 4). Instability on the money market at the end of the year and efforts to make it easier for government to finance within the country led in December 2008 to the lowering of the reserve requirement rate from 17% to 14%. System liquidity was improved and interest rates decreased noticeably. This was reflected in a considerable, but temporary, reduction of FSI-D-MM (figure 3, column 4). As well as through reverse repo auctions, banks obtained kuna liquidity by the intensive use of Lombard loans, even though their interest rate had increased from 7.5% to 9.0% and the regulations concerning the amount of securities needed as collateral had been strengthened. The first half of 2009 was influenced by global turbulences, frozen international money markets and a sudden stop in capital flows. Due to renewed depreciation pressures, in the first quarter of 2009 the CNB intervened three times in the foreign exchange market, at the first two auctions selling and, in the last auction at the end of February, buying euros. In this period a marked increase in the FSI-DFXM was recorded (figure 3, column 4). In order to stabilize the exchange rate, in January 2009 the CNB increased the percentage of the foreign currency reserve requirement set aside in kuna from 50% to 75%, and in order to ensure adequate foreign liquidity of the system in February the rate of minimum foreign currency claims was reduced from 28.5% to 20%. The developments on the foreign exchange market resulted in the first quarter of 2009 in a temporary, but a significant rise in the level and volatility of overnight interest rates and increased turnover in the money market because of the lower kuna liquidity (figure 3, FSI-D-MM, column 4). This stabilized at the end of February after the weakening of depreciation pressures, and both interest rates and volatility on the money market were reduced (figure 3, FSI-D-MM, FSI-D-FXM, column 4). By the end of the year, banking sector liquidity was satisfactory and the interest rates and the exchange rate remained stable (figures 1, 2 and 3, column 4). The end of 2008 and most of 2009 were marked by a major decline in the CROBEX and increased volatility of returns on both CROBEX and CROBIS, which were strongly reflected in the FSI-D-SM (figure 3, column 4). In the fifth period, the crisis in the government debt market in peripheral eurozone countries deepened in mid-2011. Apart from threatening banking sector stability, this crisis adversely affected the expectations of market participants, consumers and corporate sector related to the economic recovery. The renewed decline in investor risk appetite increased risk premiums, and stress spilled over onto the domestic financial system through a rise in the FSI-F (figures 1, 2 and 4, column 5). The risk premium for Croatia rose, absolutely and relatively, much more than the premiums for European emerging markets, and exceeded the record level reached in early 2009. These developments considerable enlarged the FSI-F-SM (figure 4, column 5). The increased reliance of subsidiaries on their parent banks during the fifth stress episode reflected a support of the owners to domestic banks, but also increased exposure to parent banks’ liquidity, their needs for capital, financing strategies and to developments in their home countries, as well as in those in which they had considerable exposures. The worsening of the international debt market conditions in the second half of 2011 led to a rise in the CDS premiums on the bonds of the parent banks of the five largest domestic banks. Their average level at the end of 2011 ranged about 500 basis points, almost twice as much as in the period after the escalation of the crisis, primarily because of the exposures to peripheral eurozone countries and concerns regarding the sustainability of their fiscal positions. Adverse developments in CDS premiums for Italy additionally increased the risk perception of Italian parent banks compared to those from Austria or France. This resulted in the partial withdrawal of the parent banks’ funding from domestic banks and increased pressures on the foreign currency liquidity (figures 3 and 4, column 5). During the seventh stress episode from July 0 to November 0 the major contribution to movement of total FSI and the increased level of stress came from the international securities and money market due to high volatility and strong mirna dumičić: financial stress indicators for small, open, highly euroized countries: the case of croatia 4.2.5 Fifth period: from the beginning of 2010 to end-2013 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 171-203 (2015) Unlike previous stress episodes, when some market segments alleviated stress disruptions, in the sixth episode from September 2008 to January 2010 all of them contributed to the increase of financial stress (figures 6 and 7, column 6). The greatest influence on these movements was made by the events on the international and domestic money markets. Since the stabilization of the EUR/HRK exchange rate was a key precondition for the preservation of overall financial stability in the country, interest rates on the domestic money market were, at that time, “sacrificed” in order to achieve that goal. 195 196 growth of uncertainty and risk aversion observed in an increase of FSI-F (figures 1, 2 and 4, column 5; figures 6 and 7, column 7). financial theory and practice 39 (2) 171-203 (2015) In spite of the negative macroeconomic trends in 2013 and the fall in the country’s credit rating, the EUR/HRK exchange rate remained stable, the liquidity of the system was high due to the CNB measures and the money market interest rates were low and stable. Components of FSI-D were quite low and decreased throughout the year (figures 2 and 3, column 5). mirna dumičić: financial stress indicators for small, open, highly euroized countries: the case of croatia The eighth stress episode lasted from mid-June to September 2013 and was driven by the cost of foreign borrowing, particularly trends in the international securities markets which assessed Croatia as a rather risky investment. This period was characterized by the Croatian credit rating downgrade to below investment level by all three major agencies (Standard and Poor’s, 13 December 2012; Moody’s, 1 February 2013; and Fitch Ratings, 20 September 2013). Notwithstanding this and the lack of economic recovery, Croatia still had access to the financial markets. The total FSI reacted relatively strongly to the first downgrade, while the negative reactions to the two further credit downgrades were somewhat milder (figure 1, column 50). Such moderate reactions were partially caused by the stabilization on the international financial markets. Government took advantage of favourable circumstances and issued two new bonds in the USA (in April, USD 1.5bn, yield at issue of 5.62%; November, USD 1.75bn, yield at issue of 6.20%). The end of the period was marked by improved world financial market conditions and a fall in general risk aversion (figure 4, column 5). Nevertheless, the Croatian risk premium remained elevated and FSI-F negatively contributed to the total FSI (figure 2, column 5). The reason for this were investors’ concerns regarding the lack of economic recovery, deterioration of fiscal indicators and absence of structural reforms that would create conditions for sustainable economic growth. Due to its inherent weaknesses, Croatia did not use the period of stable and unexpectedly favourable conditions in the domestic and international financial markets to ensure cheaper funding for the private sector, which would have been an important step towards economic recovery. Croatia therefore remained extremely vulnerable to any possible tightening of financial conditions, meaning that in the event of a more pronounced increase in risk aversion it could face a prohibitively high price of foreign capital. 4.3 COMPARISON OF FSIs AND INDICES OF FINANCIAL CONDITIONS Following Kliesen (2012) and in order to additionally check the robustness and usefulness of the results obtained, total FSI was compared with the financial conditions index (FCI) for Croatia. FCI is calculated by using the principal component analysis, on the basis of 28 macroeconomic and financial variables that reflect financing conditions in Croatia (for details see Dumičić and Krznar, 2013). FCI is available at a quarterly level, so the FSI was adjusted by calculating its quarterly averages. The coefficients of correlation imply a strong positive link between FCI and FSIs calculated by various methods. This correlation is even stronger if the level of the FSI of the previous quarter is used, suggesting a great influence of financial stress on overall financial conditions and the possible use of the FSI for predicting trends in financing conditions for domestic sectors in the forthcoming period. financial theory and practice 39 (2) 171-203 (2015) Figure 8 Comparison of total FSI with FCI 1.5 1.0 0.5 0.0 -0.5 -1.0 Financial conditions index FSI – total 2013Q3 2013Q1 2012Q3 2012Q1 2011Q3 2010Q3 2011Q1 2010Q1 2009Q3 2009Q1 2008Q3 2008Q1 2007Q3 2007Q1 2006Q3 2006Q1 2005Q3 2005Q1 2004Q3 2004Q1 2003Q3 -2.0 2003Q1 -1.5 FSI – total (t-1) Source: Author’s calculation (FCI is calculated on the basis of the data and methodology presented in Dumičić and Krznar, 2013). Table 4 Coefficients of correlation between FCIs and FSIs IFS_vew IFS_pca IFS_cdf FCI 0.57 0.58 0.6 FCI (t+1) 0.70 0.69 0.76 Source: Author’s calculation. 5 CONCLUSION Due to the adverse effects that financial market stress episodes have on financial and macroeconomic stability, the main objective of this paper has been to construct high-frequency financial stress indicators that will in good time inform economic policy makers of possible disruptions in the financial markets and be a useful tool for the analysis of risks that might jeopardize the financial and macroeconomic stability of the system. Another objective was to use the Croatian example to create an index that, in spite of the relatively limited accessibility of daily data, would still cover the most important specific features of a small, open, highlyeuroized country with shallow financial markets and majority foreign-owned mirna dumičić: financial stress indicators for small, open, highly euroized countries: the case of croatia Number of standard deviations 197 198 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 171-203 (2015) banks. Namely, most of the financial stress indicators were created for developed countries that are at a different level of economic and financial development and are characterized by institutional and regulatory arrangements different from those in emerging markets. Special attention has been devoted to the particular channels through which financial stress spills over from the financial markets to other segments of the financial system and the real sector in such countries. The identification of sources of financial stress and the factors that affect them, the understanding of the channels through which disruptions spill over to the remainder of the financial system and real sector, as well as the analysis of the policy makers’ activities in these periods can enable more effective preventive actions and better reactions in stress episodes. mirna dumičić: financial stress indicators for small, open, highly euroized countries: the case of croatia For the aggregation of individual indicators into a composite index, three methods were used – aggregation with the use of weightings based on equal-weight variances, aggregation of variables transformed with the use of the cumulative distribution function, and the principal component analysis. The indices constructed are highly correlated, which means that the aggregation method does not essentially affect the information contained in the index, confirming the robustness of the results. The Croatian example shows that the calculated FSIs present a useful tool for describing events on the financial markets as well as monetary and macroeconomic trends, also suggesting the robustness of results. By analysing the FSIs and the CNB reactions to the observed financial stress episodes, it can be concluded that the CNB was successful in the stabilization of the financial markets and the preservation of overall financial stability. Although FSIs did not exist in the observed period, they could have been useful in the process of identifying sources of stress disruptions, particularly in communication with public and market participants when explaining the preventive measures. Market participants and the public were often unaware of the possible threats to threatening financial stability, particularly during the stable periods on the financial markets. It can be expected that these indicators will continue to be developed and that their components will adjust to financial markets’ developments. In the next step, the indices might be used as an early warning tool for predicting trends in the financing conditions for domestic sectors or forecasting real economic developments (i.e. like Jakubik and Slačik, 2013). In combination with other techniques, like stress testing, various systems of early warning, and other composite indicators created for the analysis of financial stability in Croatia, such as FCI or indices of the accumulation and materialization of systemic risks, this indicator should enable a better monitoring of risks and ensure a prompt reaction of economic policy makers to possible stress episodes. FSI_cdf_domestic component 0.9 1.0 0.8 0.9 0.7 0.6 0.8 0.7 0.5 0.6 0.4 0.5 0.3 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.2 0.1 0.1 0.0 0.0 FSI_cdf_total Note: The shaded areas mark the stress episodes. Source: Author’s calculation. Probability – right Probability of transition to stress regime 1/01 4/01 7/01 10/01 1/02 4/02 7/02 10/02 1/03 4/03 7/03 10/03 1/04 4/04 7/04 10/04 1/05 4/05 7/05 10/05 1/06 4/06 7/06 10/06 1/07 4/07 7/07 10/07 1/08 4/08 7/08 10/08 1/09 4/09 7/09 10/09 1/10 4/10 7/10 10/10 1/11 4/11 7/11 10/11 1/12 4/12 7/12 10/12 1/13 4/13 7/13 10/13 1/01 4/01 7/01 10/01 1/02 4/02 7/02 10/02 1/03 4/03 7/03 10/03 1/04 4/04 7/04 10/04 1/05 4/05 7/05 10/05 1/06 4/06 7/06 10/06 1/07 4/07 7/07 10/07 1/08 4/08 7/08 10/08 1/09 4/09 7/09 10/09 1/10 4/10 7/10 10/10 1/11 4/11 7/11 10/11 1/12 4/12 7/12 10/12 1/13 4/13 7/13 10/13 0.9 0.8 0.7 0.3 0.2 FSI_cdf_total 0.9 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 FSI_cdf_foreign component Source: Author’s calculation. Figure a2 Episodes of increased turbulence on the financial markets determined by the Markov switching model mirna dumičić: financial stress indicators for small, open, highly euroized countries: the case of croatia 1/01 4/01 7/01 10/01 1/02 4/02 7/02 10/02 1/03 4/03 7/03 10/03 1/04 4/04 7/04 10/04 1/05 4/05 7/05 10/05 1/06 4/06 7/06 10/06 1/07 4/07 7/07 10/07 1/08 4/08 7/08 10/08 1/09 4/09 7/09 10/09 1/10 4/10 7/10 10/10 1/11 4/11 7/11 10/11 1/12 4/12 7/12 10/12 1/13 4/13 7/13 10/13 Figure A1 FSIs calculated with the use of the cumulative distribution function financial theory and practice 39 (2) 171-203 (2015) Number of standard deviations APPENDIX 199 Indices of financial stress calculated with the use of variables transformed with the cumulative distribution function 0.6 0.5 0.4 00 Financial stress indices calculated with the principal component analysis method mirna dumičić: financial stress indicators for small, open, highly euroized countries: the case of croatia FSI_pca_total Number of standard deviations financial theory and practice 39 (2) 171-203 (2015) Number of standard deviations Figure a3 FSIs calculated with the principal component analysis method FSI_pca_domestic component FSI_pca_foreign component Note: Number of variables included in the FSI obtained by the PCA method is smaller than in indices calculated by other methods because not all data are available since January 2001 and the exclusion of non-stationary variables. The usual methods of transforming variables with daily frequency to avoid this problem result in very volatile series. Source: Author’s calculation. Table a1 Loadings of parameters for variables included in the FSI_pca 0.0 0.3 0.09 0.68 0.5 0.69 0.50 0.57 0.55 0.6 0.28 0.36 0.34 0.4 mirna dumičić: financial stress indicators for small, open, highly euroized countries: the case of croatia Source: Author’s calculation. FSI_pca_total FSI_pca_domestic FSI_pca_foreign 0.45 0.3 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 171-203 (2015) variables/Index Returns on CROBEX Volatility of overnight interbank interest rates Exchange rate weighted according to banks’ assets structure Forward exchange rates CDS of parent banks of domestic banks weighted according to their share in banking sector assets EMBI risk premium for Croatia EONIA volatility LIBOR – OIS spread 0 0 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 171-203 (2015) mirna dumičić: financial stress indicators for small, open, highly euroized countries: the case of croatia REFERENCES 1. Anh, T. and Mägi, S., 2009. Principal Component Analysis – Final Paper in Financial Pricing. National Cheng Kung University. 2. Balakrishnan, R. [et al.], 2009. “The Transmission of Financial Stress from Advanced to Emerging Economies”. IMF Working Paper, WP/09/133. 3. Cardarelli, R., Elekdag, S. and Lall, S., 2009. “Financial Stress, Downturns, and Recoveries”. IMF Working Paper, WP/09/100. 4. Catao, L. A. V., 2006. “Sudden Stops and Currency Drops: A Historical Look”. IMF Working Paper, WP/0/33. 5. CNB, 0. Financial Stability, No. 9. Zagreb: Croatian National Bank. 6. CNB. Annual Reports 2000-2012. Zagreb: Croatian National Bank. 7. Dufrénot, G., Furceri, D. and Zdzienicka, A., 2011. Financial globalization and financial stress in Latin America: the case of Argentina, Brazil and Mexico. Preliminary version of the paper. Available at: <http://www.defi-univ.org/ img/pdf/paper_march2011pdf>. 8. Dumičić, M. and Krznar, I., 2013. “Financial Conditions and Economic Activity”. CNB Working Paper, W-37. Zagreb: Croatian National Bank. 9. Grimaldi, B. M., 2010. “Detecting and interpreting financial stress in the euro area”. ECB Working Paper, No. 4. 10. Hakkio, C. S. and Keeton, W. R., 2009. “Financial stress: what is it, how can it be measured, and why does it matter?”. Economic Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, (q ii), pp. 5-50. . Hubrich, K. and Tetlow, R. J., 0. “Financial stress and economic dynamics: the transmission of crises”. Finance and Economics Discussion Series, Federal Reserve Board. Washington, D.C. 12. Illing, M. and Liu, Y., 2003. “An Index of Financial Stress for Canada”. Bank of Canada Working Paper, No. 003-4. 13. Illing, M. and Liu, Y., 2006. “Measuring financial stress in a developed country: An application to Canada”. Journal of Financial Stability, 2 (3), pp. 24365. doi: 0.06/j.jfs.006.06.00 14. Ivičić, L. [et al.], 2008. “Results of the Fifth CNB Bank Survey”. Survey, S-15. Zagreb: Croatian National Bank. 15. Jakubik, P. and Slačik, T., 2013. “Measuring Financial (In)Stability in Emerging Europe: A New Index-Based Approach”. Oesterreichische Nationalbank, Financial Stability Report, No. 6. 16. Kliesen, K. L., Owyang, M. T. and Vermann, E. K., 2012. “Disentangling Diverse Measures: A Survey of Financial Stress Indexes. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, Review, 94 (5), pp. 369-397. 17. Kota, V. and Saqe, A., 2011. “A Financial Systemic Stress Index for Albania”. Bank of Albania Working Paper, WP03/4/03. 18. Kuan, C. M., 2002. Lecture on the Markov Switching Model. Academia Sinika: Institute of Economics. 03 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 171-203 (2015) mirna dumičić: financial stress indicators for small, open, highly euroized countries: the case of croatia 19. OeNB, 2013. Financial Stabilisty Report, No. 26. Oesterreichische Nationalbank. 20. Oet, M. V. [et al.], 2011. “The Financial Stress Index: Identification of Systemic Risk Conditions”. Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland Working Paper, No. /30. 21. Puddu, S., 2008. Optimal Weights and Stress Banking Indexes. Lausanne: HEC-Université de Lausanne. 22. Schou-Zibell, L., Albert, J. R. and Song, L. L., 2010. “A Macroprudential Framework for Monitoring and Examining Financial Soundness”. ADB Working Paper Series on Regional Economic Integration, No. 43. 23. Sinenko, N., Titarenko, D. and Arinš, M., 2012. “Latvian Financial Stress Index”. Discussion Paper, No. 1-2012. Riga: Latvijas Banka. 24. Yuan, C., 2011. “Forecasting Exchange Rates: The Multi-State MarkovSwitching Model with Smoothing”. International Review of Economics & Finance, 20 (2), pp. 342-362. doi: 10.1016/j.iref.2010.09.00 25. Zagreb Stock Exchange. Available at: <www.zse.hr>. Development index: analysis of the basic instrument of Croatian regional policy ANA PERIŠIĆ, mag. math.* VANJA WAGNER, mag. math.* Preliminary communication** JEL: R1, C18, C43 doi: 10.3326/fintp.39.2.4 The authors would like to thank Dubravka Šišak Jung, PhD as well as to two anonymous referees for their useful comments and suggestions. ** Received: June 1, 2014 Accepted: November 21, 2014 * The article was submitted for the 2014 annual award of the Prof. Dr. Marijan Hanžeković Prize. Ana PERIŠIĆ Polytechnic of Šibenik, Trg Andrije Hebranga 11, 22000 Šibenik, Croatia e-mail: [email protected] Vanja WAGNER University of Zagreb, Faculty of Science, Department of Mathematics, Bijenička cesta 30, 10000 Zagreb, Croatia e-mail: [email protected] 206 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 205-236 (2015) ana perišić, vanja wagner: development index: analysis of the basic instrument of croatian regional policy Abstract The development level assessment and categorization of Croatian local and regional units is based on the value of the development index which is the main instrument of Croatian regional policy. The development index is a composite indicator calculated as a weighted average of five socio-economic indicators. The goal of this paper is to analyze the uncertainty and sensitivity of the development index that arise from the procedures and indicators used in its construction. This analysis is then used to propose useful guidelines for future impovements. The methodology of the Croatian regional development index has been critically reviewed, revealing problems of multicollinearity and the existence of outliers. An empirical and relatively more objective multivariate approach for weight selection has been proposed. The uncertainty and sensitivity analysis were conducted using Monte Carlo simulations and variance-based techniques. Instead of a unique point estimate for the development level of territorial units an alternative confidence interval approach was considered. Keywords: development index, composite indicators, multivariate analysis, uncertainty analysis, sensitivity analysis, Croatia 1 INTRODUCTION The State has a constitutional obligation to promote the economic development of all the regions in Croatia and to promote economic progress and the social welfare of all citizens. Accurate assessment of the level of development of territorial units is crucial for regional planning and development policy, and is a key criterion for the allocation of various structural funds and national subsidies (Cziraky et al., 2005). Poor economic situations in local units entail low fiscal capacities, making them dependent on state subsidies and incapable of pursuing their own development (Puljiz, 2009). This prompted several groups of authors to propose that the criteria for allocating state grants and subsidies are unclear and non-transparent (Ott and Bajo, 2001; Bronić, 2008, 2010). Therefore, in 2009, a new Law on Regional Development inaugurated a new categorization of local (LGU) and regional (RGU) government units based on the value of a development index. The development index is a composite indicator calculated as the weighted average of five basic normalized socio-economic indicators: (1) income per capita (X1), (2) budget revenue per capita (X2), (3) unemployment rate (X3), (4) change in population number (X4), (5) educational attainment rate (X5), relative to the national average. The value of the development index for a territorial unit c is calculated using the formula (1) where xic, i = 1,2..., 5 represent the normalized value of a sub-indicator Xi for a territorial unit c. The indicators, their corresponding weights and other issues are determined by a government decree (Decree on Development Index, 2010). According to the values of their development indices, LGUs are categorized into 5 groups, while RGUs are classified into 4 groups. LGUs classified in groups I or II, and RGUs classified into group I are rated as lagging behind in development, and thus have a special status and are granted special support from the state level. The evaluation and classification of LGUs and RGUs on the basis of the development index are conducted every three years. ana perišić, vanja wagner: development index: analysis of the basic instrument of croatian regional policy The main goal of this study is to examine the existing methodology of the construction of the development index and to propose an improved method for its financial theory and practice 39 (2) 205-236 (2015) Poorly constructed or misinterpreted composite indicators may send misleading policy messages. Therefore, the validation of such models is of major importance, and many methods and approaches of model validation have been devised. Since models cannot be validated in the sense of being proven true (Oreskes et al., 1994), Rosen (1991) proposed that the justification for a composite indicator lies in its fitness for the intended purpose and in peer acceptance. However, a group of authors (Saisana and Saltelli, 2008) report that it is more defensible and correct to say that a model can be corroborated if it passes tests that assess the model’s capacity to explain or predict the “system” in a convincing and parsimonious way. In order to maximize their utility and minimize their misuse, composite indicators need to be developed using the best available evidence, documented transparently, and validated using appropriate uncertainty and sensitivity analyses. Uncertainty analysis focuses on how uncertainty in the input factors propagates through the structure of the composite indicator and affects the values of the composite indicator (Saisana et al., 2005). Sensitivity analysis examines the effects of variability and interactions of indicators as possible sources of instability. While in most cases the sensitivity and the uncertainty analysis are conducted separately, a synergistic use of an uncertainty and a sensitivity analysis during the development of a composite indicator could improve the structure (Nardo et al., 2005; Saisana et al., 2005; Tarantola et al., 2000; Gall, 2007). For example, Saisana et al. (2005) conducted uncertainty and sensitivity analyses using Monte Carlo simulation and variance-based techniques. Furthermore, Paruolo et al. (2013) suggest Pearson correlation coefficient as a measure of variable importance. Also, they conducted sensitivity analysis using variance-based techniques and applied these methods to various composite indicators. On the other hand, Hoyland et al. (2012) criticize the approach in aggregating variables into a composite index without incorporating uncertainty. They suggest a Bayesian approach when assessing uncertainty and apply this method to three composite indicators. Another group of authors (Nardo et al., 2008) provide directions for the construction of composite indicators and give recommendations for implementation of sensitivity and uncertainty analyses. Apart from the papers analyzing regional disparities in Croatia and the classification of Croatian LGUs and RGUs according to socio-economic development (e.g. Rimac et al., 1992; Grčić and Filipić, 2002; Cziraky et al., 2003, 2005; Perišić, 2014) there is a lack of related work regarding sensitivity of categorization and uncertainty in the construction of the development index. 207 208 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 205-236 (2015) calculation by taking into account the uncertainty and sensitivity of the categorization of LGUs and RGUs. Uncertainty of the development index is assessed considering the construction methodology and sensitivity is evaluated with respect to the indicators involved in its construction. Uncertainty and sensitivity analyses play an important role in the construction of composite indicators and because of their generality these methods can be applied in wide-ranging fields. The study also includes the analysis of data structure using multivariate methods. The methods presented in this paper can be useful to policymakers and experts in assessing the reliability of the composite indicators. 2 The meThODOlOgy Of mODellINg RegIONAl DevelOpmeNT IN CROATIA 2.1 The DevelOpmeNT Of The RegIONAl DevelOpmeNT pOlICy ana perišić, vanja wagner: development index: analysis of the basic instrument of croatian regional policy In its beginning, Croatian regional policy was focused on the renewal of areas affected by war. Some progress was made when the Law on the Areas of Special State Concern (ASSC) was implemented. These areas were established in order to encourage their more rapid development and thus they have a special status in the financing regime (Ott and Bajo, 2001). According to the Law on ASSC adopted in 1996, three categories of units were formed. The first two categories were defined on the basis of damage caused by the war in Croatia. The third category, introduced in 2002, comprises local units that are lagging behind in development according to four criteria: economic development, structural difficulties, demographic, and a special criterion (Bronić, 2008). The introduction of socio-economic criteria was a step forward in developing regional policy. Eleven indicators were used for the designation of the third category of ASSC: income per capita, share of population earning an income, municipality (direct) income per capita, unemployment rate, employment rate, social aid per capita, change in population number, educational attainment rate, population density, age index and vitality index (Puljiz et al., 2005). In addition to the four aforementioned socio-economic criteria, two special criteria related to border position and mine area status were used. In total, 185 LGUs enjoyed a special status; of these, 50 were classified in the first category, 61 in the second category, and 74 in the third category of ASSC. However, it appeared that the criteria for designation of ASSC were not related to the real socio-economic indicators. Bajo and Primorac (2013) report that preferential status was also given to some economically more developed (above average) LGUs. Furthermore, a group of authors (Maleković et al., 2011) conclude that the regional development approach, inherited from central planning, was inconsistent and lacking clearly defined goals, actors, and instruments. The regional policy has been often conducted within the scope of fiscal equalization and vice versa, whereby the instruments and the objectives of these policies often clashed, and the effects were neutralized at a high cost to the state budget. Consequently, laws related to regional policy needed to be changed. The introduction of a simple and transparent system of fiscal equalization based on appropriate criteria and fis- cal instruments remains a challenge for the Government (Bajo and Primorac, 2013). ana perišić, vanja wagner: development index: analysis of the basic instrument of croatian regional policy Supported areas were supposed to replace the ASSC, but instead, a parallel existence of different categories of underdeveloped areas occurred. This perennial problem will be solved by the adoption of a new Law on Regional Development. Furthermore, this new Law will introduce a uniform system for development level assessment of territorial units applicable to the whole state. The application of measures introduced by the new law is expected in 2015. Some of the novelties of the new Law are introduction of the category of urban area (and additionally, among such areas, agglomeration centers), the formation of the Council for regional development and binding all future measures to development index, which acts as the basic instrument for development level assessment of LGUs and RGUs (MRRFEU, 2013c). By changing the Law on ASSC, the Law on Regional Development, the Law on Hill and Mountain Areas and the Personal Income Tax Act, the Government endeavors to harmonize tax reliefs and distribution of grants to LGUs with their development level measured by the development index. The main changes in the grant distribution to LGUs involve redirecting the grants from the state budget to LGUs, according to the development index, in the amount of corporate income tax generated in their area, and changes in the basic personal allowance (Bajo and Primorac, 2013). By this, LGUs classified in categories I and II will obtain the right to the entire (100%) corporate income tax revenue collected in their area, in category III to aid in the amount of 75%, in group IV 60%, and in category IV 40%. A limitation of this distribution can be presented by following example: Tovarnik municipality, having the development index value of 74.82%, will obtain the right to Governmental support in the amount of 100%, while the City of Ozalj, with a development index value of 75.08%, will obtain the right to aid in the amount of 75%. These two marginal examples show that more legitimate support is needed. For example, introducing partially linear deductions would contribute to an equitable support system. financial theory and practice 39 (2) 205-236 (2015) The establishment of a comprehensive and coherent regional development policy system based on the principles of contemporary regional policy started along with the preparatory activities for the accession of Croatia to the European Union (Sumpor et al., 2012). The basis for the implementation of regional policy was the adoption of the Law on Regional Development in 2009. This Law regulates regional policy by introducing the development index as a basis for the socio-economic development assessment and categorization of territorial units. In addition to that, the development level of LGUs was assessed for the first time. According to the Ministry of Regional Development and EU Funds (MRRFEU), the single system based on the development index contributes to the simplicity and transparency of the whole system, enabling the better direction of incentives and the acquisition of a high-quality basis for the inclusion or exclusion of units from the supported areas (MRRFEU, 2012). 209 210 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 205-236 (2015) Adopting the new Law on Regional Development will stop there being two laws that define supported areas. However, ASSC again have a special status during assessment of the development level. The Decree on Amendments to the Decree on the Development index implies that the development index value of the LGUs in the ASSC will be reduced by 10 points (the adjusted index) if their original index value is higher than 75% (Decree on Amendments to the Decree on Development index, 2013). In this paper, two indices will be obtained for the local level (LGU): the unadjusted development index IV (without the reduction by 0 points for ASSC) and adjusted development index IKV (with the reduction by 0 points for ASSC). ana perišić, vanja wagner: development index: analysis of the basic instrument of croatian regional policy The methodology for construction of the development index for the period 20102012 is different from that used for the period 2006-2008. In 2013, the Decree on Amendments to the Decree on the Development Index introduced two main modifications: when calculating budget revenue per capita, revenues from the disposal of non-financial assets are excluded; also, the value of the development index is reduced by 10 points for LGUs from the first or second category of ASSC that have a value of the development index greater than 75%. The first modification prevented the impact of short-term funding sources in budget revenues on the value of development index. The second modification was introduced in order to assure the retention of the status of supported area for undeveloped LGUs that were affected by the war. By this modification, 24 LGUs from the first or second category of ASSC are, according to the adjusted development index, categorized as supported areas, although according to the unadjusted development index they belong to categories of middle or higher development level. 2.2 The CATegORIZATION Of lgUs AND RgUs ACCORDINg TO DevelOpmeNT INDeX According to the value of the development index, LGUs are classified into 5 groups (table 1). Table 1 also provides the number of LGUs classified into each group (N), average values of indicators X1,.., X5 along with standard deviation (in brackets). Large standard deviations indicate heterogeneity within the group. According to the development index, RGUs are classified into 4 groups (table 2). Table 2 also provides the number of LGUs classified into each group (N), average values of indicators X1,..., X5 along with standard deviation (in brackets). LGUs classified into categories I or II, and RGUs classified in category I are rated as lagging behind in development and thus have a special status. In Croatia, there are 556 LGUs, composed of 429 municipalities and 127 towns, with the City of Zagreb, the capital of Croatia, having the status of both county and town. More than one third of LGUs are located on ASSC, while according to the development index, almost one half of LGUs and more than a half of RGUs are categorized as areas lagging behind in development. 211 Table 1 The categorization of LGUs according to development index Category N I <50 47 II <50, 75> 217 III <75, 100> 173 IV <100, 125> 93 V >125 26 X2 X3 (%) X4 X5 (%) 13,049.28 (2,146.69) 18,095.3 (3,333.85) 23,355.31 (3,668.74) 28,557.11 (4,426.46) 29,938.73 (6,000.14) 748.87 (288.98) 1,020.29 (472.4) 1,912.6 (1,064.74) 3,556.06 (1,179.26) 7,060.54 (1,359.8) 37.67 (6.59) 22.89 (6.3) 14.89 (4.5) 10.84 (3.6) 8 (3.1) 86.20 (11.01) 92.83 (8.91) 99.92 (9.27) 108.1 (12.15) 119.48 (28.22) 54.07 (8.7) 62.17 (8.1) 72 (6.78) 80.35 (5.1) 83.32 (4.9) Source: Authors’ calculation. Table 2 The categorization of RGUs according to development index Category Development index value (%) N I < 75 12 II <75, 100> 3 III <100, 125> 3 IV >125 3 X1 X2 X3 (%) X4 X5 (%) 22,798 (2,494) 25,460 (785) 27,156 (2,746) 35,662 (5,655) 1,912 (472) 2,597 (506) 3,166 (337) 5,213 (682) 20.47 (4.78) 16.43 (3.58) 13.20 (1.95) 10.37 (2.46) 94.1 (2.67) 100.3 (3.57) 106.53 (2.55) 101.77 (2.4) 69.38 (3.93) 78.84 (4.32) 79.51 (3.71) 84.23 (3.14) Source: Authors’ calculation. 3 meThODOlOgICAl ASpeCTS Of The CONSTRUCTION Of COmpOSITe INDICATORS In the indicators literature there is a fundamental division between those who choose to aggregate variables into a composite indicator, the aggregators, and those who do not, the non-aggregators. The aggregators believe that composite indicators can capture reality and are meaningful. Moreover, they believe that composite indicators are extremely useful in garnering media interest and hence the attention of policy makers. On the other hand, the non-aggregators emphasize the arbitrary nature of the weighting process by which the variables are combined (Sharpe, 2004). Certain disagreements also exist as to how to select indicators and techniques for measuring disparities. Relying solely on economic indicators is questionable due to the fact that development either leaves behind, or in some ways even creates, large areas of poverty, stagnation, marginality, and actual ex- ana perišić, vanja wagner: development index: analysis of the basic instrument of croatian regional policy X1 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 205-236 (2015) Development index value (%) 212 clusion from economic and social progress is too obvious and too urgent to be overlooked (United Nations, 1969). The need for including more indicators for the purpose of measuring socio-economic development resulted in a considerable number of composite indicators. financial theory and practice 39 (2) 205-236 (2015) ana perišić, vanja wagner: development index: analysis of the basic instrument of croatian regional policy The main pros of using composite indicators are the ability of summarizing complex, multi-dimensional realities, an easy and direct interpretation, facilitation of communication with general public and reducing the amount of a set of indicators without dropping the underlying information base. The main cons are related to a problem of misleading policy messages if the indicators are poorly constructed or misinterpreted, they can invite simplistic policy conclusions, the selection of indicator and weight could be the subject of political dispute and lead to inappropriate policy (Nardo et al., 2005). If the construction process is not transparent and/or lacks sound statistical or conceptual principles, composite indicators can be misused and index values can be manipulated in order to support preferred policy. The basic steps in the construction of composite indicators are: theoretical framework construction, data selection, imputation of missing data, multivariate analysis, normalization, weighting and aggregation, uncertainty analysis, sensitivity analysis, linking to other variables, presentation and visualization (Nardo et al., 2005). 3.1 INDICATORS SeleCTION The strengths and weaknesses of a composite indicator are derived from the quality of the underlying variables. Variables should be selected on the basis of their relevance, analytical soundness, timeliness, accessibility, etc. The choice of indicators must be guided by the theoretical framework, limiting the developer’s subjectivity. The use of multivariate analysis helps to identify the data structure, and can increase both the accuracy and the interpretability of final results. Multivariate methods can also help to investigate the presence of multicollinearity. Multicollinearity causes an unequal variable position because multicollinear variables measure the same phenomenon, which in turn has a multiple contribution to the value of the composite indicator. An additional problem is the difficulty of interpretation, while it is hard to assess the impact of the individual variable. If two variables are highly correlated, the inclusion of both of them in the model may be redundant (Salzman, 2003). In the process of the construction of new composite indicator, the development index, the main criterion for variable selection was the estimation of the variable’s contribution to the objective estimation of socio-economic differences among territorial units. Thereby, income per capita and unemployment rate became key indicators of socio-economic disparities, while some indicators were excluded on the basis of their weak credibility, and too high or too low correlation with the key economic indicators (Puljiz et al., 2005). For instance, infrastructural indicators were rated as not reliable; the indicators “share of persons earning an income” and “income per capita” were highly correlated (coefficient of correlation was 0.93); the indicators Table 3 Indicators LGU Indicator min. max. xˉ skew X 7,105 42,175 21,609.14 6,088.6 0.38 X2 223 10,115 1,981.59 1,695.36 1.96 X3 (%) 4.5 54.48 18.94 9.24 0.86 41.3 247.8 98.3 13.8 31.65 90.41 68.58 11.07 X4 X5 (%) a 2.72a -0.36 The effect of an outlier, when the outlier is excluded, asymmetry coefficient is 0.65. Source: Authors’ calculation. ana perišić, vanja wagner: development index: analysis of the basic instrument of croatian regional policy Minimum value (min), maximum value (max), mean value ( xˉ ), standard deviation () and asymettry coefficient (skew) are presented in tables 3 and 4 for the LGUs and RGUs respectively. Variable X2 has the largest dispersion both on local and regional level. 213 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 205-236 (2015) “vital index” and “age index” had a too low correlation coefficient with the indicators “income per capita” and “unemployment rate” (Puljiz, 2007). Due to some methodological difficulties, gross domestic product per capita (GDP per capita) was not involved in the construction of the development index. However, the GDP per capita is still considered as a potential indicator while it is expected that the reliability of the estimation of GDP will grow (Puljiz, 2007). However, it is not possible to use the GDP per capita as an indicator on the local level because it is calculated on the regional and state level. The Decree on the Development Index prescribes the indicators used in the construction of the development index: income per capita, budget revenue per capita, unemployment rate, change in population number, and educational attainment rate. The indicator values have been acquired from MRRFEU (2013a, 2013b, 2010a, 2010b). Local/regional income per capita is calculated by dividing the total income in a tax period (one calendar year), generated by taxpayers, persons domiciled or habitually resident, in the territory of the local/regional unit, by the total population number of a local/regional unit. Budget revenue per capita is calculated by dividing the realized reduced local/regional budget revenue by the population number of a local/regional unit. Budget revenue is reduced by: receipts from domestic and foreign aid, subsidies and transfers, receipts derived pursuant to special contracts (co-financing by citizens), additional share in income tax, equalization aid for the decentralized functions and disposal of non-financial assets. Unemployment rate is determined by dividing the total number of unemployed persons by the sum of unemployed and employed persons in the area of the local/regional unit. Change in population number is expressed as the ratio of the number of the population in a local/region unit according to the last two consecutive censuses. Educational attainment rate is calculated as the number of persons with secondary education and higher, aged over 15 years, as a proportion of the total number of population aged 16-65 in the area of the LGU/LRU. 214 Table 4 Indicators RGU financial theory and practice 39 (2) 205-236 (2015) Indicator X X2 X3 (%) X4 X5 (%) min. 19,455 1,368 7.80 90.7 62.49 max. 42,175 5,997 25.90 109.1 86.93 xˉ 25,638.19 2,660.48 17.41 97.86 74.30 5,262.95 1,248.45 5.54 5.42 7.01 skew 1.66 1.36 0.17 0.50 0.15 Source: Authors’ calculation. 3.2 NORmAlIZATION ana perišić, vanja wagner: development index: analysis of the basic instrument of croatian regional policy Data normalization is often required because the indicators in a data set have different measurement units or large differences in their means or standard deviations. The normalization phase can be crucial for the accuracy of a composite indicator and accordingly for the ranking of units. The simplest normalization technique is ranking. This method is not affected by outliers. Standardization, or converting to z-scores, on the other hand, is one of the most popular normalization methods. It is affected by outliers since indicators with extreme values have a greater effect on the composite indicator value. The third widely used normalization method is the min-max method, which normalizes the indicators so that they have an identical range. Distance to a reference measures the relative position visà-vis a reference point (the reference could be the average value, minimum value, maximum value or some other value determined by the expert decision). Table 5 Evaluated normalization methods Normalization methods The calculation Standardization (z-score) (2) Min-max (3) Distance to a reference (4) Remark: xci is the value of indicator Xi for a local unit c; i represents the average value of indicator Xi across all units c; i is the standard deviation of indicator Xi; xi,min is the minimum value of indicator Xi across all units c; xi,max is the maximum value of indicator Xi across all units c; xi0 is the reference value for indicator Xi. By the Decree on the Development Index, the min-max method was selected as a suitable normalization method. The min-max normalization of an indicator Xi is conducted by subtracting the minimum value and dividing by the range of the indicator values. Furthermore, this normalized value is divided by the normalized state average value of the indicator Xi (formula 5) 215 (5) financial theory and practice 39 (2) 205-236 (2015) Since the extreme values are usually outliers, this normalization method should be revised (in the sense of excluding outliers or even changing the normalization method). Changing the minimum value of an indicator can affect the composite indicator values of all units. The normalization defined in formula 5 reduces the nominal value of each indicator to a distance to the minimum value relative to the distance of the national average to the minimum value. 3.3 WeIghTINg AND AggRegATION An a priori determination of weights for various components implies the existence of a universally acceptable human welfare/development function, which is not the case (Noorbakhsh, 1998). Thus, the empirical approach, as an alternative approach to weight setting, is worth pursuing. In order to generate a set of nonsubjective weights, PCA has been applied for the calculation of development index both for the period 2008-2010 and for 2010-2012. PCA enables the reduction of the variables by a small number of their linear combinations. The objective is ana perišić, vanja wagner: development index: analysis of the basic instrument of croatian regional policy Perhaps the most difficult aspect of constructing a multidimensional index is choosing weights for the components (Tofallis, 2013). A number of weighting techniques exist. Some are derived from statistical models, such as factor analysis, principal component analysis (PCA), data envelopment analysis, or from participatory methods that incorporate various stakeholders – experts, citizens and politicians, like budget allocation processes, analytic hierarchy processes and conjoint analysis (Nardo et al., 2008). The weights are often selected in order to reflect the relative importance of the indicator for the phenomenon to be measured. This approach is often criticized as too arbitrary since weighting can have a significant effect on composite index value and ranking of units. On the other hand, multivariate techniques present an empirical and relatively more objective option for weight selection, allowing for no control over the selection of weighting scheme. This is due to the fact that the weights are selected based on the data themselves. The problem of selecting an indicator’s weights is often bypassed by equal weighting, i.e. all variables are given equal weights. Composite indices generally seem to be additive, with equally weighted components (Booysen, 2002). This essentially implies that all variables are “worth” the same in the composite, but it could also disguise the absence of a statistical or an empirical basis, e.g. when there is insufficient knowledge of causal relationships or a lack of consensus on the alternative (Nardo et al., 2005). When a few highly correlated indicators exist and equal weighting is applied, double counting may be introduced into the index. Thus, it is desirable to perform correlation analysis prior to weight selection and to adjust weights according to results of correlation analysis. 216 to explain the variance of the data through a few linear combinations of the original data minimizing the information loss. Therefore, k ≤ 5 linear combinations Yj of variables Xi are chosen, maximizing the variance of the original data. k. (6) financial theory and practice 39 (2) 205-236 (2015) ana perišić, vanja wagner: development index: analysis of the basic instrument of croatian regional policy The first principal component, Y, is the linear combination of the variables that has the greatest possible variance. Various guidelines have been developed on the issue of how many linear combinations k should be retained. For instance: the latent root criterion (only components that have an eigenvalue greater than are retained), the a priori criterion, scree test and proportion of variance criterion (Hair et al., 1995). In practice, very few composite indices use PCA weights, in part because it is difficult to explain the process to non-statisticians, in part because the weights themselves change as the data changes over time, but mainly because the results using equal weights and PCA weights tend not to differ substantially (Foa and Tanner, 2011). Because the composite indicators describe multidimensional phenomena by a unidimensional construct, it is necessary to find an appropriate aggregation method. Additive aggregation is the simplest aggregation method and is independent of outliers. Linear aggregation, the most widespread method, is the summation of weighted individual indicators. An undesirable feature of linear aggregation is that it implies full compensability, such that poor performance in some indicators can be compensated for by sufficiently high values in other indicators. Geometric aggregation is better suited if the modeller wants some degree of non-compensability. 3.4 UNCeRTAINTy AND SeNSITIvITy ANAlySIS The absence of an “objective” way to determine weights and aggregation methods does not necessarily lead to rejection of the validity of composite indicators, as long as the entire process is transparent. A combination of uncertainty and sensitivity analysis can help gauge the robustness of the composite indicator and improve transparency (Nardo et al., 2008). The methodological choices, such as the treatment of missing data, indicator selection, choosing the normalization method as well as the aggregation method, and the weighting scheme have a major influence on the composite indicator. The goal of the uncertainty analysis is to evaluate how the subjective choices taken by the modeller are reflected in the confidence in the model. Since the development level of a territorial unit cannot be directly measured, it is not possible exactly to determine how well the composite index describes this phenomenon. However, a composite indicator needs to be validated. Thus, each construction of a composite index needs to involve uncertainty analysis and sensitivity analysis. Generally, uncertainties during the development of a composite indicator are associated with a number of factors: data error, choice of the mechanism for indicator inclusion and exclusion, the transformation of indicators, missing data, choice of normalization method, aggregation method and especially of the weighting scheme (Nardo et al., 2005). The uncertainty of a compos- ite index can be assessed by exploring the main sources of uncertainty, with the aim of capturing all possible synergy effects among uncertain input factors (Nardo et al., 2008), directly or by Monte Carlo simulation. financial theory and practice 39 (2) 205-236 (2015) High sensitivity to small changes in input information makes the composite index unstable and unreliable. Thus, when a composite index is being created, it is necessary to determine the effect of the variation in the individual indicator on the overall index value. Therefore, methods that are not based on the assumptions of the model, such as variance-based techniques, are used (Satelli et al., 2008). 217 For the composite index Y and indicators X1,…, Xk, the first-order sensitivity index is assessed as the contribution of an individual indicator X1 to the total output variance V(Y), where (8) is the variance of Y due to the uncertainty in Xi. In order to compute a variancebased sensitivity measure, the first factor Xi needs to be fixed to a specific value xi0 in its range. Then the mean of the output is computed by averaging over all factors but factor Xi, and the variance of the resulting function of xi0 is averaged over all possible values of the indicator Xi. Higher values of the sensitivity index Si indicate a higher dependance between the index Y and the individual indicator Xi. Analogously, it is possible to compute conditional variance to more than one factor (interactions) and then to compute high-order sensitivity indices. When an additive model is concerned (a model without interactions) the contribution of an individual indicator to the variance of a composite is entirely obtained by the firstorder sensitivity index and therefore formula (9) is valid. . (9) Si is a good model-free sensitivity measure, and it always gives the expected reduction of the variance of the output that one would obtain if one could fix an individual indicator (Saltelli et al., 2004). In general, . (10) For a non-additive model, instead of computing higher-order sensitivity indices, the total effect sensitivity index STi is obtained; this is determined by their sum. , (11) ana perišić, vanja wagner: development index: analysis of the basic instrument of croatian regional policy (7) 218 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 205-236 (2015) where represents the variance of the composite index Y due to the uncertainty of all indicators but indicator Xi. As in the first-order sensitivity indices, high values of the total effect STi indicate a higher dependence of the index Y on the variability of an individual indicator Xi. However, unlike the first-order sensitivity indices, this approach considers all possible interactions with other indicators. Therefore, by comparing the pairs (Si, STi) it is possible to compute the intensity of indicator interaction. 4 ReSUlTS 4.1 mUlTICOllINeARITy AND OUTlIeR pReSeNCe TeSTINg ana perišić, vanja wagner: development index: analysis of the basic instrument of croatian regional policy Correlation matrices of indicators on the local and regional level are presented in tables 6 and 7. The correlation of indicators is high and statistically significant (at significance level 1%). On the regional level, correlation coefficients of indicators income per capita and budget revenue per capita, and also budget revenue per capita and educational attainment rate are problematic in the sense of too high correlation. Table 6 Correlation matrix LGU X X2 X3 X4 X5 X1 X2 X3 X4 X5 0.92 -0.68 0.44 0.79 -0.67 0.55 0.81 -0.59 -0.57 0.66 X2 X3 X4 X5 Source: Authors’ calculation. Table 7 Correlation matrix RGU X1 X X2 0.51 X3 -0.67 -0.48 X4 0.25 0.51 -0.39 X5 0.73 0.55 -0.55 0.51 Source: Authors’ calculation. Multicollinearity was assessed using variance inflation factor and condition index. It can be concluded that multicollinearity is present since the value of variance inflation factor is higher than 7 and value of condition index is 13.8 (Bahovec and Erjavec 2009; Gujarati, 2004). The problem of multicollinearity can be solved by excluding one of the indicators or by replacing it with another indicator. For ex- Figure 1 Detection of outliers in LGUs using the squared Mahalanobis distance (d) for the period (a) 2006-2008 and (b) 2010-2012 d d 12 0 8 0 6 4 2 0 0 0 100 200 300 LGU 400 (a) Period 2006-2008 500 600 0 100 200 300 LGU 400 500 600 (b) Period 2010-2012 Source: Authors’ calculation. In both periods one outlier can be detected in the upper right side of the figure. For the period 2006-2008 the outlier is the municipality Dugopolje which has the largest development index and extremely high budget revenue per capita. In that period, the second largest development index corresponds to Kostrena municipality. This municipality, however, has a three times smaller budget revenue per capita. Furthermore, Dugopolje municipality has more than twenty times the budget revenue per capita of the average of all LGUs. Dugopolje municipality is an example of the failure of aggregation methods, since the deficit in one dimension can be ana perišić, vanja wagner: development index: analysis of the basic instrument of croatian regional policy Outliers were detected using Mahalanobis distance, where observations with large Mahalanobis distances were indicated as outliers (Ben Gal, 2005). Squared Mahalanobis distances (d) corresponding to LGUs for the period (a) 2006-2008, and (b) 2010-2012 are presented in figure 1. 219 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 205-236 (2015) ample, for the development index calculated for the period 2006-2008, the problem of multicollinearity was solved by excluding the indicator budget revenue per capita, and also by replacing this indicator with alternative indicators of regional budget strength (Perišić, 2014.). A high correlation of budget revenue per capita and income per capita is expected. Furthermore, local revenues depend mostly on tax revenues, especially on income tax and surtax on income tax (Ott, 2009). Therefore, the inclusion of both indicators may be redundant, especially when the key economic indicator GDP per capita is available on a regional level. This issue can be circumvented by introducing realized local/regional budget revenue in the total income of LGU/RGU: an alternative indicator of strength and independence of local budgets. In that case, the realized local/regional budget revenue should be reduced by receipts from domestic and foreign aid, subsidies and transfers, receipts derived pursuant to special contracts (co-financing by citizens), additional share in income tax, equalization aid for the decentralized functions and disposal of non-financial assets. 220 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 205-236 (2015) compensated by a surplus in another and thus create a false image on the unit’s development level. The extremely high budget revenue of Dugopolje municipality is the result of short-term funding sources, such as sale of land. A similar situation occurred with other LGUs. For the period 2010-2012 the municipality of Vir stands out as an outlier with an extremely high change in the population number (247.8). These examples show that outliers create a false image of the development level of a territorial unit, and also affect the value of the development index of all units. This effect, as well as the effect of different data range, is removed with transformation and normalization of the data. 4.2 pRINCIpAl COmpONeNT ANAlySIS ReSUlTS ana perišić, vanja wagner: development index: analysis of the basic instrument of croatian regional policy Principal component analysis is conducted for the development index, and calculated for both periods, 2006-2008 and 2010-2012. A priori only one linear combination was selected (k = 1), representing an alternative to the development index. It is statistically justified to retain only one component since only one principal component has the eigenvalue greater than 1, which satisfies the latent root criterion. Indicator weights have been calculated on the basis of PCA, and afterwards normalized. The resulting weights are represented in table 8. It is important to note that outliers have been excluded prior to performing the PCA. Table 8 Normalized indicator weights according to PCA, LGU and RGU level Normalized Income weights w1pCA pCA w Index LGU 2010-2013 Index LGU 2006-2008 Index RGU 2010-2013 Index RGU 2006-2008 Budget Unemployment Change in revenue rate population w2pCA w3pCA number w4pCA educational attainment rate w5pCA variance explained (%) 0.21 0.2 0.2 0.17 0.22 62 0.23 0.18 0.21 0.15 0.23 55 0.21 0.22 0.19 0.17 0.21 74 0.24 0.24 0.2 0. 0.22 66 Source: Authors’ calculation. One of the weaknesses of the weights derived from PCA is the minimization of the contribution of individual indicators which do not move along with other individual indicators. In case of development index, the indicator change in population number has the smallest weight determined by PCA because this indicator exhibits the weakest correlation with other indicators. However, weights derived from PCA assigned to demographic indicators are higher than those determined by the government decree, at both a local and a regional level. 221 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 205-236 (2015) According to the index computed with the use of PCA-derived weights (IPCA), in total 57 LGUs are classified into category I, and 211 LGUs are classified into category II. When using the adjusted development index (reducing the index value for 10 points for the undeveloped LGUs on the ASSC), category II contains 239 LGUs. Also, only three LGUs classified into categories I or II by the development index are now, according to PCA-derived index, classified into groups with a higher development level. On the regional level, there is no difference between the classification of RGUs according to government decree and the PCA derived index. The values of PCA derived indices are presented in table 0. 4.3 AlTeRNATIve NORmAlIZATION meThOD Development index, Ic, of a local unit c is calculated as the weighted average of five basic normalized socio-economic indicators (12) Section 3.2 gives a critical review of the normalization method used in the construction of the development index. The direct influence of the maximum value of an individual indicator on the LGU/RGU development index can be removed by combining the min-max normalization and averaging relative to the development index of Croatia (formula 13). The calculation of the development index as a weighted average of the same indicators, but on the state level, would result with an indicator less sensitive to extreme values. . (13) 4.4 UNCeRTAINTy ANAlySIS Of The DevelOpmeNT INDeX 4.4.1 Uncertainty analysis of the lgU development index Taking into account analogous indices of countries in the region, one can recognize weights and normalization method selection as the main sources of uncertainty. In total, 12 models have been obtained: 3 normalization methods are presented in table 5 and the normalization method determined by the government decree (formula 5); 3 weighting methods (weighting method determined by the government decree wV; weights derived from PCA for the period 2010-2012 wPCA (table 8); and equal weights wE = (0.2, 0.2, 0.2, 0.2, 0.2)). Indices computed with different normalization methods are not mutually comparable. Thus, the uncertainty was obtained due to the corresponding LGU ranks. For each model i = 1,...,12 and for each LGU c (c = 1,..., 556), the development index Ici and corresponding rank Rci were calculated. Figure 2 shows the smallest, greatest and the median rank value for a LGU c relative to the rank RcNV determined by the unadjusted development index Icv. ana perišić, vanja wagner: development index: analysis of the basic instrument of croatian regional policy . 222 Figure 2 Uncertainty analysis due to LGU rank, LGU level 500 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 205-236 (2015) 400 300 max Rj min Ri 200 00 ana perišić, vanja wagner: development index: analysis of the basic instrument of croatian regional policy 0 0 100 200 300 RjNV 400 500 Source: Authors’ calculation. Analysis of the data presented in figure 2 shows good agreement in low and high regions of RNV and certain jumps of the median rank for the middle region. This behavior may indicate a possible overestimation, or underestimation of certain LGUs, especially LGUs with medium development level. On the same set of units, it can be observed that a wider range of indicator values follow this behavior. This indicates the inability of a model to concisely estimate the development level of these units. Furthermore, this leads to significant disparities in the categorization based on development index compared to the categorization based on other models. A key issue in the construction of a composite indicator is determining the relative importance of indicators and by that choosing appropriate indicator weights. This is especially important because the sensitivity of the composite indicator, due to change in weights, opens up the possibility of manipulation of the categorization of units lagging behind in development. Thus, uncertainty due to change in weights is analyzed. For every LGU c, the minimum Icmin and maximum Icmax possible values of the index are calculated. Weights were chosen from the interval [0.1, 0.6] and scaled to a unity sum. (14) weights determined by the government decree. (c) Third simulation S3 was conducted by generating 2500 weights from the uniform distribution, where wiPCA represent weights determined from PCA. After being generating, all weights were scaled to unity sum. For each simulation, and for every LGU c, 500 values of development index Ic,k, k = 1,2,...,500 were calculated The first simulation is almost nonrestrictive, while the second and third simulation generate weights around values determined by the government decree wv, and PCA, wPCA. The percentage of simulations resulting in a classification corresponding to the development index IV is calculated for each simulation and each unit. The average percentage for each category is provided in table 9, as well as the average range of simulated indices, , where and are the maximum and minimum value in each simulation. Additionally, table 9 provides the frequency of incorrectly classified units (nw) which have the probability of wrong classification pw(c) higher than 0.45: (15) For simulations S1 and S2, the probability of incorrect categorization was estimated as the relative frequency of incorrect categorization of LGUs due to the categorization based on IcV. Also, for simulations S1 and S3, the probability was estimated due to a categorization based on IcPCA. ana perišić, vanja wagner: development index: analysis of the basic instrument of croatian regional policy Uncertainty analysis on the LGU level was performed using the Monte Carlo simulation. Three types of simulations were performed due to the distribution of weights: (a) The first simulation S1 was conducted by generating 2500 weights from the uniform distribution, . Afterwards, weights were scaled to a unity sum. The latter ensured for weights to range between 0.1 and 0.35, preventing domination of an individual indicator over others. (b) The second simulation S2 was conducted by generating 2500 weights from uniform distribution, , where wiv represents 223 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 205-236 (2015) Results obtained by formula (14) were compared to the results obtained by using the development index. The comparison showed that 56% of units classified into categories I or II by the development index are classified into categories III, IV or V when Icmax was used, i.e. 56% of the units from the supported areas are not rated as lagging behind in development. Similar results occur when the classification according to minimum possible index value, Icmin is analyzed. More than 43% of units classified into categories III, IV and V by the development index are now classified into categories that are lagging behind in development. 224 Table 9 Simulation result, LGU level Simulation financial theory and practice 39 (2) 205-236 (2015) a b Category retention (%) nw Imax–min I II III Iv v S1 87 92 80 82 98 71a 31b 0.14 S2 96 94 94 96 96 9 0.08 S3 96 94 94 95 98 6 0.08 Number of incorrect categorizations according to IV. Number of incorrect categorizations according to IPCA. ana perišić, vanja wagner: development index: analysis of the basic instrument of croatian regional policy Source: Authors’ calculation. The simulation S1, which is the least restrictive in the choosing of weights, resulted in 31 LGUs being incorrectly categorized due to the categorization based on the IPCA. This is a significantly lower number than the number of incorrect categorizations resulting from the categorization based on the development index IV (71 LGUs incorrectly categorized). Thus, it can be concluded that the categorization according to the development index IV is less confident than the PCA categorization. In addition to that, a greater confidence of the PCA-categorization can be obtained by considering smaller perturbations of weights around the values of wV or wPCA. Monte Carlo simulations open up the possibility of employing confidence intervals for the estimation of the development level of territorial units. Moreover, when using simulations it is possible to estimate the probability of incorrect categorization for every unit. This is particularly beneficial in the case of marginal units. For instance, Lećevica municipality, according to development index value (75.36%), is not categorized in the group of supported units. However, 84% of simulations S1 resulted in the categorization of this municipality in the group of supported units. A similar situation occurs with more than 20 LGUs (see appendix). Due to the large number of LGUs, interval estimations are presented only at a regional level (table 10). 4.4.2 Uncertainty analysis of RgU development index The Decree says that the methodology for the construction of the development index on the local level is the same as that for the regional level (Decree on the Development Index, 2010). However, one can pose the question whether one methodology can be reliably applied to two different cases? In particular, is it justified to select the same weights at a local and a regional level? For every RGU c, two types of development indices were computed: the development index IcV using weights determined by the government decree and the index IcPCA, computed using weights derived from PCA. Based on indices values, corresponding ranks were determined. The results are presented in table 10, where the ranks are presented in brackets. Icv (%) 7.18 (1) 5.56 (1) 7 (1) <0.06, 0.08> <0.05, 0.06> <0.06, 0.08> 24.03 (4) 18.43 (2) 22.42 (4) <0.19, 0.29> <0.16, 0.21> <0.20, 0.25> 22.65 (3) 18.73 (3) 21.74 (2) <0.19, 0.26> <0.17, 0.21> <0.20, 0.24> 21.96 (2) 23.29 (4) 21.84 (3) <0.21, 0.23> <0.23, 0.24> <0.21, 0.22> 30.25 (5) 33.81 (5) 29.01 (5) <0.26, 0.34> <0.31, 0.36> <0.27, 0.31> 39.75 (6) 38.70 (6) 41.54 (6) <0.35, 0.44> <0.36, 0.42> <0.39, 0.44> 49.11 (7) 46.07 (7) 49.21 (7) <0.47, 0.52> <0.44, 0.48> <0.48, 0.51> Karlovac KoprivnicaKriževci Lika-Senj 53.28 (9) 56.34 (8) 54.47 (9) <0.49, 0.57> <0.54, 0.59> <0.52, 0.57> 52.63 (8) 59.19 (9) 51.64 (8) <0.46, 0.59> <0.55, 0.64> <0.48, 0.56> 59.61 (10) 64.82 (10) 61.04 (10) <0.54, 0.65> <0.61, 0.68> <0.58, 0.64> Međimurje KrapinaZagorje Šibenik-Knin 64.79 (12) 69.65 (11) 62.03 (12) <0.58, 0.72> <0.64, 0.75> <0.58, 0.66> 62.78 (12) 73.24 (12) 61.45 (11) <0.56, 0.69> <0.68, 0.78> <0.58, 0.66> 83.04 (14) 80.93 (13) 82.14 (14) <0.80, 0.87> <0.79, 0.83> <0.80, 0.84> Varaždin 78.81 (13) 86.34 (14) 77.39 (13) <0.73, 0.84> <0.82, 0.90> <0.74, 0.81> IcpCA (%) 90% CI for IcS1 90% CI for IcS2 90% CI for IcS3 Split-Dalmatia 102.55 (15) 93.75 (15) 101.2 (15) <0.97, 1.09> <0.90, 0.98> <0.98, 1.05> Zadar DubrovnikNeretva Zagreb PrimorjeGorski kotar Istria 112.62 (16) 106.39 (16) 109.13 (16) <1.04, 1.23> <1.01, 1.12> <1.04, 1.14> 123.62 (18) 120.84 (17) 122.31 (18) <1.2, 1.28> <1.18, 1.23> <1.20, 1.25> 121.21 (17) 124.23 (18) 118.03 (17) <1.15, 1.28> <1.21, 1.28> <1.14, 1.22> 139.69 (19) 139.21 (19) 141.71 (19) <1.35, 1.44> <1.37, 1.41> <1.39, 1.44> 154.36 (20) 156.80 (20) 154.20 (20) <1.5, 1.59> <1.54, 1.6> 185.45 (21) 186.44 (21) 188.5 (21) <1.76, 1.93> <1.81, 1.92> <1.83, 1.93> City of Zagreb CI – interval estimation. Source: Authors’ calculation. <1.51, 1.57> ana perišić, vanja wagner: development index: analysis of the basic instrument of croatian regional policy ¯IcS1 (%) County of c ViroviticaPodravina Slavonski Brod-Posavina VukovarSirmium BjelovarBilogora PožegaSlavonia SisakMoslavina Osijek-Baranja financial theory and practice 39 (2) 205-236 (2015) Table 10 Comparison of the index value and corresponding rank (in brackets) 225 226 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 205-236 (2015) Due to the selection of weights, uncertainty analysis was conducted using Monte Carlo simulations. Analogously to the analysis conducted on the local level, 5,000 samples of weights from three types of uniform distributions were generated. For each simulation Sj and every RGU c, 1,000 values of development index k = 1,2,..., 1000, j = 1,2,3 were calculated. For 21 RGUs, interval estimations of development index, based on percentile index values, are computed with 90% confidence level. ana perišić, vanja wagner: development index: analysis of the basic instrument of croatian regional policy The comparison of lower bounds of the interval estimations obtained by simulations S1 and S3, shows that the development index IV underestimates the development level for following counties: Virovitica-Podravina, Slavonski Brod-Posavina, Vukovar-Sirmium, Bjelovar-Bilogora, Osijek-Baranja and Split-Dalmatia. These counties have a development index value lower than the lower bounds of interval estimations provided by simulations S1 and S3. Similarly, the comparison of the development index IV and the upper bounds of the interval estimations indicates a possible overestimation of the development level for the following counties: Bjelovar-Bilogora, Koprivnica-Križevci and Varaždin since the development index is higher than the upper interval bounds. The selection of weights doesn’t significantly affect the categorization of RGUs determined by the government decree, but it has an impact on the units ranking. According to the development index, the county of Split-Dalmatia is categorized in the second group, while according to the average simulated index and PCA derived index is categorized in the group having a higher development level. 4.5 SeNSITIvITy ANAlySIS Of The DevelOpmeNT INDeX 4.5.1 Sensitivity analysis of the development index, lgU level First order sensitivity indices Si and total effect sensitivity indices ST are calcui lated for indicators Xi, i=1, 2,..., 5. The results on the LGU level are presented in table . Table 11 Sensitivity indices (LGU level) I Si 1 2 3 4 5 0.084 0.145 0.087 0.021 0.022 STi 0.394 0.485 0.390 0.155 0.216 Source: Authors’ calculation. It can be concluded that a change in the value of a single indicator affects the values of the development index. This is due to the fact that a single indicator interacts with other indicators and thus the cumulative effect is observable on the value of development index. Significantly higher values of total effect sensitivity index indicate stronger interactions between economic indicators: budget revenue per capita, income per capita and unemployment rate. Figure 3 Interval estimates 227 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 205-236 (2015) The effect of small changes in the values of economic indicators on the sensitivity of the development index was examined directly by using the Monte Carlo simulations. For every regional unit c, 100 values of the indicator Xi, i = 1,..., 5 were generated from the normal distribution with a mean equal to the observed indicator value xci and variance i2 equal to the quarter of the sample variance. This way the simulation is limited only to small perturbations of the parameters, which can appear as the result of imprecise measurement or the fact that indicator values tend to change over time. 1.4 Development index .0 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 0 100 200 300 400 500 LGU Source: Authors’ calculation. Tabel 12 Category changed (%) Category according to Iv I II III IV V falling into lower category (%) Advancing into higher category (%) – 9 15 15 8 19 12 12 7 – Source: Authors’ calculation. The values of the development indices on the LGU level, together with corresponding interval estimations, are presented on figure 3. The interval estimations are assessed via simulations at the 95% confidence level. The LGUs that shift to categories with lower or upper development levels are determined by intersections of level boundaries according to IV and interval estimations. Table 12 provides the percentages of shifts between groups. LGUs switching between catego- ana perišić, vanja wagner: development index: analysis of the basic instrument of croatian regional policy 1.2 228 ries should be analyzed in more detail due to the possibility of incorrect classification. 4.5.2 Sensitivity analysis of the Development index, RgU level Table 13 Sensitivity indices (RGU level) 1 2 3 4 5 Si 0.084 0.039 0.119 0.021 0.022 0.439 0.322 0.481 0.239 0.221 ST i Source: Authors’ calculation. Similar to the results obtained with the sensitivity analysis of LGUs, the interaction of economic indicators emerges as the main source of variability of the development index on the RGU level. The values of the development indices on the RGU level together with corresponding interval estimations are presented on figure 4. Figure 4 Interval estimations (RGU level) 1.25 XXI XVIII I VIII XIII XIX V XVII II XV IX XX IV VI III XIV XI VII XVI X 0.75 XII ana perišić, vanja wagner: development index: analysis of the basic instrument of croatian regional policy I Development index financial theory and practice 39 (2) 205-236 (2015) First order sensitivity indices Si and total effect sensitivity indices ST are calcui lated for indicators Xi, i=1, 2,...,5. The results at the RGU level are presented in table 13. RGU Source: Authors’ calculation. Interval estimations of the development index for the counties Krapina-Zagorje, Split-Dalmatia, Dubrovnik-Neretva and Zagreb are partially placed in the categories of higher development level according to the category determined by the index IV. This indicates a possible underestimation of the specified counties. Thus, these counties should be analyzed in more detail. Using interval estimates allows for a briefer analysis of these marginal units considering the estimation of an incorrect classification of territorial units. The researchers’ subjective decisions, such as choosing normalization and aggregation methods and selecting indicators and corresponding weights, play an important role in the construction of a composite index. Thus, it is necessary to detect all sources of uncertainty and to analyze their consequences. One of the main features of the construction of composite indicators is the lack of consensus concerning relative weights selection. In this study, a development index derived directly from the data by principal component analysis was proposed as a reference index. The uncertainty of the development index, especially due to the weight selection, was analyzed using Monte Carlo simulations. This analysis indicated the inability of the development index to rank LGUs uniformly, particularly for LGUs categorized in groups II and III. Because weight selection is the main source of uncertainty, categorization on the basis of the development index was revealed to be less confident compared to the PCA-categorization. The analysis of the model determined by the Government decree indicated strong interactions of economic indicators which dominantly affect the variability of the development index, both on the local and the regional level. Because even small perturbations of input variables can significantly affect the categorization outcome, a special emphasis was placed on the inclusion of these methods in the ana perišić, vanja wagner: development index: analysis of the basic instrument of croatian regional policy The main goals of this paper were to assess the uncertainty of development index considering the construction methodology and to evaluate sensitivity considering the indicators involved in its construction. By taking this to account, useful guidelines for the improvement of the index can be proposed. Furthermore, the methodology of the construction of the development index is presented. In order to examine the data structure, multivariate analysis was conducted, indicating the presence of outliers. In particular, the results of multivariate analysis carried out at the regional level indicate the presence of collinearity between indicators income per capita and budget revenue per capita. This problem can be bypassed by excluding or replacing one of the collinear indicators or by correcting indicator weights. financial theory and practice 39 (2) 205-236 (2015) 5 CONClUSION Prior to the implementation of the development index, the categorization process of territorial units was often criticized as unbalanced and fragmented. A turnaround started with the employment of composite indices as a basis for the development level assessment of LGUs and RGUs. The development index is calculated as the weighted average of normalized indicator values relative to the state average. For many local units that are lagging behind in development, the categorization based on the development index is crucial for further development as it provides it different benefits and incentive intensity. 229 230 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 205-236 (2015) construction of composite indicators. The inclusion of uncertainties in the model is needed since the measurement errors are frequent, and for some indicators, data are often not provided on time. For this purpose, interval estimations are proposed instead of point estimation. Therefore, it is possible to incorporate uncertainties in the model. This also enables some units to be closely analyzed (for example, territorial units having the development index values 5 points away from the marginal values of the categories). ana perišić, vanja wagner: development index: analysis of the basic instrument of croatian regional policy Due to the lack of scientific papers on this subject, the intention of the authors was to emphasize the need for analyzing the sensitivity and the uncertainty of the development index and of composite indicators in general. Since composite indicators are increasingly used, this study provides useful guidelines for the application, as well as for development, of composite indicators in a wide variety of academic and professional fields. In three years a new calculation of the development index is expected. It will be interesting to observe the development of the construction methodology, especially the indicator selection process and quality, as well as the assessment of the relative importance due to the socio-economic conditions in the state. With the aim of the general acceptance of the development index, it is necessary to improve the transparency of the construction process. The methodology of the new calculation should follow the expected changes in the dynamics of indicators and their interaction in order to ensure a modern approach to the assessment of the development level of territorial units. AppeNDIX 231 Basic guidelines for improving the methodology of the development index financial theory and practice 39 (2) 205-236 (2015) 1) The correlation of indicators income per capita and budget revenue per capita should be corrected in one of the following ways: a) correction of weights, b) excluding an individual indicator, c) replacement with an alternative indicator. On the regional level, the inclusion of the indicator GDP per capita, as a key economic indicator, should be considered. 3) Alternative weighting methods should be considered. Furthermore, uncertainty analysis and sensitivity analysis should be conducted in order to improve the transparency and the quality of the development index. 4. Interval estimations of the development index should be provided prior to the categorization of LGUs and RGUs. LGUs/RGUs with the interval estimates overlapping partially with one of the supported groups should be more closely analyzed in order to avoid incorrect categorization. 5) An inclusion/exclusion of marginal units in/from supported areas should be considered. This can be achieved by using Monte Carlo simulations and estimating the probability of (incorrect) categorization (see section 4.4). 5.1) In particular, regarding simulation results, LGUs listed in table A1 should be considered for inclusion into group II, i.e. into supported areas. Table A also provides values of the development index and the percentage of the categorization in groups II and III from MC simulations S (see section 4.4.1). 5.2) Furthermore, LGUs listed in table A2 should be considered for inclusion into group III, i.e. exclusion from supported areas. Table A2 also provides the development index values and the percentage of the categorization in groups II and III from MC simulations S (see section 4.4.1). ana perišić, vanja wagner: development index: analysis of the basic instrument of croatian regional policy 2) The outliers should be excluded when using the min-max normalization. As an alternative normalization method we propose normalization relative to the state’s index value (given with formula 13). 232 Table a1 Proposal for the inclusion of LGUs into supported areas lgU financial theory and practice 39 (2) 205-236 (2015) Ozalj Development index 0.7508 Categorization into group (%) II III 0.876 0.124 ana perišić, vanja wagner: development index: analysis of the basic instrument of croatian regional policy Donji Vidovec 0.7517 0.902 0.098 Jesenje 0.7522 0.860 0.140 Sveti Martin na Muri 0.7525 0.760 0.240 Lećevica 0.7537 0.980 0.020 Petrijanec 0.7543 0.788 0.212 Donji Miholjac 0.7612 0.546 0.454 Krašić 0.7624 0.942 0.058 Klenovnik 0.7671 0.742 0.258 Vratišinec 0.7681 0.676 0.324 Hrašćina 0.7683 0.862 0.138 Pregrada 0.7688 0.872 0.128 Đelekovec 0.7689 0.926 0.074 Lepoglava 0.7695 0.584 0.416 Kraljevec na Sutli 0.7700 0.802 0.198 Mače 0.7728 0.766 0.234 Jalžabet 0.7775 0.550 0.450 Đurmanec 0.7829 0.570 0.430 Breznički Hum 0.7856 0.756 0.244 Bedenica 0.7901 0.562 0.438 Veliki Bukovec 0.8231 0.526 0.474 Table a2 Proposal for the exclusion of LGUs from the supported areas lgU Vrsi Imotski Nova Gradiška Beli Manastira a Development index 0.728 0.735 0.741 0.743 Categorization into group (%) II III 0.176 0.824 0.206 0.794 0.456 0.544 0.392 0.608 AASC, not categorized into supported areas on the basis of unadjusted development index. 6) Although this study did not involve the analysis of alternative aggregation methods, this would also be worth pursuing. In particular, one could consider the geometric aggregation as it delimitates the compensability between variables. RefeReNCeS 233 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 205-236 (2015) ana perišić, vanja wagner: development index: analysis of the basic instrument of croatian regional policy 1. Bahovec, V. and Erjavec, N., 2009. Uvod u ekonometrijsku analizu. Zagreb: Element. 2. Bajo, A. and Primorac, M., 2013. “Package of legislative amendments for a better Croatian regional policy”. Press Relase, No. 61. doi: 10.3326/ pr.2013.6 3. Ben Gal, I., 2005. Outlier detection. In: O. Maimon and L. Rockach, eds. Data mining Knowledge Discovery Handbook: A Complete Guide for Practitioners and Researchers. Kluwer Academic Publishers. doi: 10.1007/0-387-25465X_7 4. Booysen, F., 2002. “An overview and evaluation of composite indices of development”. Social indicators research, 59 (2), pp. 115-151. doi: 10.1023/ A:1016275505152 5. Bronić, M., 2008. “The Croatian Ministry of Finance’s Current Grants to Municipalities and Cities in the Areas of Special National Concern”. Newsletter, No. 35 [pdf]. Available at: <http://www.ijf.hr/eng/newsletter/35.pdf>. 6. Bronić, M., 2010. “Evaluating the current equalization grant to counties in Croatia”. Financial Theory and Practice, 34 (1), pp 25-52 [pdf]. Available at: <http://fintp.hr/upload/files/ftp/2010/1/bronic.pdf>. 7. Cziraky, D. [et al.], 2003. An econometric model for development level assessment with an application to municipality development classification. In: Z. Reić, ed. Enterprise in transition: proceedings of the 5th Conference on Enterprise in transition. Split: Faculty of Economics. 8. Cziraky, D. [et al.], 2005. Regional development assessment: A structural equation approach. European Journal of Operational Research, 174 (1), pp. 427-442. doi: 10.1016/j.ejor.2005.03.012 9. Foa, R. and Tanner, J. C., 2012. “Methodology of the Indices of Social Development“. Institute of Social Studies, Working Paper Series [pdf]. Available at: <http://www.indsocdev.org/resources/Methodology%20of%20the%20Social %20Development%20Indices_%20jan11.pdf>. 10. Gall, M., 2007. Indices of social vulnerability to natural hazards: A comparative evaluation. Doctoral thesis. University of South Carolina. 11. Grčić, B. and Filipić, P., 2002. “Evaluation of regional development and (im)balances: the Croatian case”. The Journal of Management Sciences & Regional Development, 12 (7), pp. 21-36. 12. Gujarati, D. N., 2004. Basic econometrics. New York: McGraw-Hill Companies. 13. Hair, J. F. [et al.], 1995. Multivariate data analysis: with readings. New Jersey: Prentice Hall. 14. Hoyland, B., Moene, K. and Willumsen, F., 2012. “The tyranny of international index rankings”. Journal of Development economics, 97 (1), pp. 1-14. doi: 10.1016/j.jdeveco.2011.01.007 234 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 205-236 (2015) ana perišić, vanja wagner: development index: analysis of the basic instrument of croatian regional policy 15. Maleković, S., Puljiz, J. and Tišma, S., 2011. “New opportunities for regional and local actors in Croatia in supporting socio-economic development”. Southeastern Europe, 35, pp.168-190. doi: 10.1163/187633311X585360 16. MRRFEU, 2010a. Vrijednosti indeksa razvijenosti i pokazatelja za izračun indeksa razvijenosti na lokalnoj razini [pdf]. Available at: <http://www.mrrfeu.hr/default.aspx?id=405>. Zagreb: Ministry of Regional Development and EU Funds. 17. MRRFEU, 2010b. Vrijednosti indeksa razvijenosti i pokazatelja za izračun indeksa razvijenosti na županijskoj razini [pdf]. Available at: <http://www. mrrfeu.hr/default.aspx?id=405>. Zagreb: Ministry of Regional Development and EU Funds. 18. MRRFEU, 2012. Strateški plan za razdoblje 2012.-2014. Zagreb: Ministry of Regional Development and EU Funds. 19. MRRFEU, 2013a. Vrijednosti indeksa razvijenosti i pokazatelja za izračun indeksa razvijenosti na lokalnoj razini [pdf]. Available at: <http://www.mrrfeu.hr/default.aspx?id=405>. Zagreb: Ministry of Regional Development and EU Funds. 20. MRRFEU, 2013b. Vrijednosti indeksa razvijenosti i pokazatelja za izračun indeksa razvijenosti na županijskoj razini [pdf]. Available at: <http://www. mrrfeu.hr/default.aspx?id=405>. Zagreb: Ministry of Regional Development and EU Funds. 21. MRRFEU, 2012. Strateški plan za razdoblje 2012.-2014. Zagreb: Ministry of Regional Development and EU Funds. 22. MRRFEU, 2013c. Glavne novine koje donosi Nacrt prijedloga Zakona o regionalnom razvoju Republike Hrvatske [online]. Available at: <www.mrrfeu. hr/default.aspx?id=1674>. Zagreb: Ministry of Regional Development and EU Funds. 23. Nardo, M. [et al.], 2005. Tools for Composite Indicators Building. Ispra: Joint Research Centre. 24. Nardo, M. [et al.], 2008. Handbook on constructing composite indicators [pdf]. Available at: <http://www.oecd.org/std/42495745.pdf>. 25. Noorbakhsh, F., 1998. “The human Development index: Some technical issues and alternative indices”. Journal of International Development, 10 (5), pp. 589-605. doi: 10.1002/(SICI)1099-1328(199807/08)10:5<589::AIDJID484>3.0.CO;2-S 26. Oreskes, N., Shrader-Frechette, K. and Belitz, K., 1994. “Verification, validation and confirmation of numerical models in the earth sciences”. Science, 263 (5147), pp. 641-646. doi: 10.1126/science.263.5147.64 27. Ott, K. and Bajo, A., 2001. “Lokalne financije i lokalni proračuni u Republici Hrvatskoj”. Financijska teorija i praksa, 25 (3), pp. 311-434. 28. Ott, K., 2009. Proračunski vodič za građane. Zagreb: Institut za javne financije. 235 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 205-236 (2015) ana perišić, vanja wagner: development index: analysis of the basic instrument of croatian regional policy 29. Paruolo, P., Saisana, M. and Saltelli, A., 2013. “Ratings and rankings: voodoo or science?”. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society: Series A (Statistics in Society), 176: pp 609-634. doi: 10.1111/j.1467985X.2012.01059.x 30. Perišić, A., 2014. “Multivariate Classification of Local and Regional Government Units According to Socio-Economic Development”. Društvena istraživanja, 23 (2), pp. 211-231. doi: 10.5559/di.23.2.0 31. Puljiz, J. [et al.], 2005. Novi pristup ocjenjivanju i kategorizaciji teritorijalnih jedinica prema razvijenosti. Zagreb: Institut za međunarodne odnose. 32. Puljiz, J., 2007. Proposal for new development categorisation on regional and local units in Croatia. Croatian international relations review, 12 (44/45), pp. 125-138. 33. Puljiz, J., 2009. Čimbenici regionalnog razvoja i regionalnih nejednakosti u Republici Hrvatskoj. Doctoral thesis. Split: Ekonomski fakultet. 34. Rimac, I., Rihtar, S. and Oliveira Roca, M. 1992. “Multivarijatna klasifikacija općina Hrvatske kao moguća metoda regionalizacije Republike”. Društvena istraživanja, 1 (1), pp. 87-99. 35. Rosen, R., 1991. Life Itself: A Comprehensive Inquiry into Nature, Origin, and Fabrication of Life. Columbia University Press. 36. Saisana, M. and Saltelli, A., 2008. Expert Panel Opinion and Global Sensitivity Analysis for Composite Indicators. In: F. Graziani, ed. Computational Methods in Transport: Verification and Validation. Springer Berlin Heidelberg, pp. 251.-275. doi: 10.1007/978-3-540-77362-7_1 37. Saisana, M., Saltelli, A. and Tarantola, S., 2005. “Uncertainty and sensitivity analysis techniques as tools for the quality assessment of composite indicators”. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society – A, 168 (2), pp. 307-323. 38. Saltelli, A. [et al.], 2004. Sensitivity Analysis in Practice: A Guide to Assessing Scientific Models. New York: John Wiley & Sons. 39. Saltelli, A. [et al.], 2008. Global Sensitivity Analysis. The Primer. New York: John Wiley & Sons. 40. Salzman J., 2003. Methodological choices encounterd in the construction of composite indices of economic and social well-being [pdf]. Available at: <http://www.csls.ca/events/cea2003/salzman-typol-cea2003.pdf>. 41. Sharpe A., 2004. Literature Review of Frameworks for Macro-indicators. Ottawa: Centre for the Study of Living Standards. 42. Sumpor, M., Jurlina Alibegović, D. and Đokić, I., 2012. Ocjena sustava strateškog planiranja i mogućnosti financiranja razvoja županija i lokalnih jedinica u kontekstu provođenja politike regionalnog razvoja Republike Hrvatske. Zagreb: Ekonomski institut Zagreb. 43. Tarantola, S., Jesinghaus, J. and Puolamaa, M., 2000. Global sensitivity analysis: a quality assurance tool in environmental policy modelling. In: A. Saltelli, K. Chan and M. Scott, eds. Sensitivity analysis. New York: John Wiley & Sons, pp. 385.-397. 236 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 205-236 (2015) ana perišić, vanja wagner: development index: analysis of the basic instrument of croatian regional policy 44. Toffalis, C., 2013. “An automatic-democratic approach to weight setting for the new human Development index”. Journal Population Economy, 26 (4), pp. 1325-1345. doi: 10.1007/s00148-012-0432-x 45. United Nations, 1969. Social policy and planning in national development. Report of the Meeting of Experts on Social Policy and Planning. Geneva: United Nations Economic and Social Council Commision for Social Development. 46. Uredba o indeksu razvijenosti, NN 63/10. Zagreb: Narodne novine. 47. Uredba o izmjeni i dopunama Uredbe o indeksu razvijenosti, NN 158/2013. Zagreb: Narodne novine. 48. Zakon o brdsko-planinskim područjima, NN 12/02, 32/02, 117/03, 42/05, 90/05, 80/08 and 148/13. Zagreb: Narodne novine. 49. Zakon o regionalnom razvoju, NN 153/09. Zagreb: Narodne novine. O zdravstvu iz ekonomske perspektive Health care from an economic perspective MAJA VEHOVEC (Ed.) The Institute of Economics, Zagreb, 2014, pp. 356 Book review by ANTO BAJO*1 doi: 10.3326/fintp.39.2.5 * Received: December 10, 2014 Accepted: December 11, 2014 Anto BAJO, PhD Institute of Public Finance, Smičiklasova 21, 10000 Zagreb, Croatia e-mail: [email protected] 238 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 237-243 (2015) The book “Health care from an economic perspective” is the result of a two-year effort by a team of economists from the Institute of Economics and their external associates. The book, edited by Professor Maja Vehovec, PhD, includes contributions of thirteen researchers. It has 356 pages, including a preface, the authors’ CVs, 56 tables and 92 figures. The nice cover illustration suggests the conclusions of the book regarding the need of economy, prudent behaviour and more effective healthcare system management. The book is divided into five parts featuring thirteen thematic contributions, which attempt to answer five key questions regarding the Croatian health system economics. maja vehovec (ed.): health care from an economic perspective Answers to the first question: How is health care financed and what are the expectations for the future? are offered by Dubravko Mihaljek in his article “How to Finance Health Care in Times of Economic Crisis?” and Tanja Broz and Sandra Švaljek in the “Healthcare Financing in Croatia: from Reform to Reform”. Mihaljek points out that while it is impossible to stop the growth of health care spending in the long run, healthcare financing can be made more effective. Since 1960, life expectancy has been extended by 11 years, to almost 80 years, which will affect cost control and efficiency improvement. Politicians have ignored this fact due to a short-term thinking horizon. From 2000 to 2010 alone, health care spending in advanced economies trended upwards from 9.9% to 12.4% of GDP. The share of public spending rose, while the share of private spending declined. The role of private health insurance schemes strengthened, but personal health care expenses decreased. Health care spending in Croatia stagnated over the last ten years (at 7.8% of GDP). However, government accounted for an above-average share in health care expenditures, as high as 85% (as compared with 72% in Central Europe and 73% in Western Europe). The government budget share increased, while the share of health insurance dropped to 67% in 2010. There are many unknowns regarding the structure of the Croatian health care financing: discrepancies exist between domestic statistics and those published by the World Health Organisation. Mihaljek deems that Croatia should take macroeconomic and microeconomic measures to curb the growth of government health care spending. Such measures have already been implemented in developed economies and they could be beneficial to Croatia as well. At the macroeconomic level, budget constraints and stricter quantity and price controls for health care services should be imposed. Microeconomic measures should include: partial restructuring of the health care system, increasing transparency in the health care billing practices (the payment of services by diagnosis-related groups, a wider choice of doctors and medical institutions when contracting with suppliers for health care services) and redressing the imbalance between primary and secondary health protection. Mihaljek also stresses the need for greater private sector participation in supplying goods to medical institutions, as well as for stronger competition among insurance companies. Broz and Švaljek analyse the implemented health care system reforms, providing information for evaluating their effects. There have been numerous rehabilitations maja vehovec (ed.): health care from an economic perspective Replies to the second question: What ought we to know about health insurance and private health expenditure? are given by Danijel Nestić and Ivica Rubil in the article “Private Health Expenditure in Croatia”, and Mario Puljiz in the contribution titled: “Voluntary Health Insurance: Croatia vs. Europe”. Nestić and Rubil argue that total private health expenditure in Croatia (about 1.2% of GDP) is extremely low and that little is known about its socio-economic characteristics. The information they used was based on a Household Budget Survey. Private expenditures account for about 15% of total health expenditures. Private insurance expenses account for just a small share in total private health expenditures in Croatia (0.5% of GDP). Hospitalisation costs are mainly covered from public sources. A survey on a sample of Croatian households corroborates the previously known findings of similar international surveys. In addition to income levels, the amount of private health expenditures is influenced by the level of education (high vs. extremely low educational levels), age, gender (women spend more on average for health) and settlement type (the urban population spends more on health). Propensity to buy supplemental insurance depends on gender (women are more prone to it), educational level (highly educated persons are more likely to buy supplemental insurance) and income (persons with higher income are more likely to opt for it). There are no plans in Croatia for any major health care system restructuring in terms of the sources of funding, and it is mainly considered in the context of the government budget. Puljiz points out that in Croatia, private insurance cannot be a substitute for compulsory insurance. It is necessary to define the basket of services covered by the public insurance and that provided under the 239 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 237-243 (2015) in the health care area (mostly involving hospitals) in Croatia. From 1994 to 2007 alone, their costs reach about HRK 9.7bn. Apart from the rehabilitation processes, health care co-payments have been increased and supplemental health insurance has been introduced. However, despite the applied measures, medical institutions continued to accumulate losses. In 2012 and 2013 alone, expenditures for the settlement of debts incurred by the Croatian Health Insurance Fund (HZZO) and hospitals amounted to HRK 6.5bn. Since 2004, the prices of drugs have gone up. Regrettably, the numerous reforms were not based on any elaborate strategy documents. The reform launched in 2008 was aimed at curbing public expenditures and the growth of drug prices by introducing international public tenders for particularly expensive drugs, and reducing benchmark prices of prescription drugs. Moreover, medical equipment procurement has been centralised, and the control of sickness benefits and hospital payments according to diagnosis and therapy-related groups has been stepped up. Under the reform, all additional sources of the health care system funding have been tapped. Croatia needs further health insurance market liberalisation and cuts in the number of those insured at the expense of the government budget. While the bulk of reforms are still carried out at the revenue side, expenditure reforms are also needed, along with an increase in the number of private health insurance schemes, given the exhausted public revenue capacities. A similar conclusion arises from an analysis of private health care expenses. 240 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 237-243 (2015) supplemental insurance. Voluntary health insurance accounts for as little as 2.44% of the total written premium of all insurance companies, which is indicative of an underdeveloped market. Further liberalisation is called for, as well as cuts in the number of budget-financed health care users. The use of supplemental and additional health insurance products by citizens could be encouraged by introducing various forms of tax relief. maja vehovec (ed.): health care from an economic perspective The third question: What are the key elements of health care spending and what are their specific qualities? is answered by Ivana Rašić Bakarić in the chapter “Primary Health Protection in between Efficiency and Availability”, and a group of co-authors (Maja Vehovec, Ivana Rašić Bakarić and Sunčana Sljepčević) who point to the key problem of the Croatian health care system in the article “Challenges of Hospital Restructuring”. Sunčana Sljepčević provides an “Evaluation of the Technical Efficiency of Hospitals”, and Tanja Broz analyses “Drug Consumption and the Specifics of Functioning of the Drug Market”. According to Rašić Bakarić, the primary health care expenditures have stood at HRK 2,95bn. Medical centres should be the main primary health protection providers. The problem lies in too few preventive medical examinations, the growing number of patient referrals to specialists and a relatively large number of patient visits per day. Every seventh patient is referred to a specialist medical examination. Thus, a general practitioner has 53.1 patient visits a day, and he/she spends 8 minutes on each of them. The basket of services included in the general/family medicine is not defined, which leads to differences in financial calculations. In most EU member states, primary health care handles 70-80% of health cases (as compared to only 50% in Croatia). Referring from primary to specialist health services is due to weaknesses in the current funding model which is not based on any standards. Vehovec, Rašić Bakarić and Sljepčević explain an old malady of the Croatian health care system, i.e. the non-transparency of costs, especially in hospitals which account for the largest share of total health expenditures, exceeding the EU member states’ average. The ratio between the number of hospital doctors and the number of population is unsatisfactory and is below the EU average (163 doctors per 100,000 inhabitants). The same is true for the numbers of hospital beds (56 per 10,000 inhabitants) and hospitals (1.3 per 100,000 inhabitants). Croatia is the leader among the EU member states in terms of duration of treatment (7.2 days). Below-average coverage of doctors has been observed in as many as 14 counties, with unequal access to medical services. Hospital expenditures stand at about HRK 11.3bn. The bulk of them (53%) are expenditures for employees, followed by material expenditures (for drugs and hospital energy consumption). One of the key challenges is the status of the HZZO, which only transfers budget funds to hospitals, without having any autonomy in deciding on the health system’s insurance policy based on the funds raised from compulsory health insurance contribu- Broz analyses “Drug Consumption and the Functioning of the Drug Market”, concluding that spending on drugs in Croatia exceeds GDP capacity. The drug market has no detailed and transparent statistical databases. Public spending on drugs accounts for about 80% of the total spending, which ranks Croatia among the EU member states with above-average shares of public spending on drugs in total health care spending. Drug expenses went up from HRK 3.8bn in 2004 to HRK 5.1bn in 2013. Against the backdrop of uncontrolled consumption and non-existent standards, an important question arises, namely How far are users involved in health care service evaluation? The answers are provided by Jelena Budak and Edo Rajh in an interesting part titled “Corruption in Croatia’s Health Sector: Myth or Reality”. Jelena Budak’s article deals with “Patients’ Assessment of the Quality of Work of maja vehovec (ed.): health care from an economic perspective In the part “The Technical Efficiency Evaluation of Hospitals“, Sljepčević analyses the efficiency of 54 hospitals using the 2010 data. Some of her findings are very interesting. Most of the specialised and clinical hospitals employ aboveaverage numbers of administrative and technical staff. The number of nurses grows, but is still below the EU average. Data on the number of discharged patients per hospital and on the rate of cured patients are unavailable, although they might be useful for performance analysis and hospital efficiency measurement. According to the author’s calculation, seven hospitals (a clinical hospital, three general and three specialised hospitals) operated at marginal efficiency in 2010. As much as 9.8% of these hospitals use 40% to 50% more inputs than the efficient hospitals, and 3.9% hospitals are capable of cutting the user of resources by 30% to 40%, which would represent considerable savings within the system. Four clinical hospital centres show different levels of efficiency, despite their similar business characteristics. The same is true for other types of hospitals (clinics, clinical hospitals, general and specialised hospitals). 241 financial theory and practice 39 (2) 237-243 (2015) tions. The general impression (confirmed by an interview) is that hospital managers know the solutions and even offer recommendations for reforms. The question remains, however, how to turn proposals into practice and does the medical profession actually want reforms. Hospital managers generally have a negative attitude towards the outsourcing of non-medical activities and do not feel responsible for salary and material cost overruns. They rather consider them a problem of the system. The relation between hospital revenues and the cost presentation model is non-transparent. Limits make up the bulk of hospitals’ budgets, but it is not clear how they are determined: on the basis of a historical cost model or some additional unknown criteria. So far, hospitals have been known for good doctors rather than successful management. Hospital financing should depend on performance indicators. It is necessary to improve the computerisation of hospitals, prescribe the appropriate standards, procedures and protocols and adopt strategic plans for each medical institution. 242 Health Care Personnel”. Maja Vehovec writes about “An International Comparison of Health Care Quality from a User Perspective”. financial theory and practice 39 (2) 237-243 (2015) Budak and Rajh hold that corruption exists and it results in unequal treatment of patients. Corruption is more prevalent in hospitals, due to their inefficiency (long waiting lists) and poor health system organisation. The most easily enforceable measure to combat corruption in the patient-doctor relationship is providing patients with transparent information on public health care. The knowledge of patients’ rights, especially to the information on the scope of services covered by health insurance and the official prices of health services, helps reduce informal costs. The privatisation of health care, breaking up a monopoly in the health services market, may be an effective step towards rooting out corruption. The key purpose of the research is to raise awareness of the problem. maja vehovec (ed.): health care from an economic perspective Budak emphasizes that there are no public opinion polls in Croatia reflecting citizens’ opinions on the quality of the public health system. Useful tools in this regard are surveys on the public perception of the quality of doctors’ work. Vehovec has interpreted the results of the European Health Care Index, making an international comparison of the health care quality from a user perspective. According to this index, Croatia is in the middle of the list of countries by health care quality rankings assigned by users. Is economic evaluation in health care an option or a necessity? Answers to this questions have been provided by Ana Bobinac in the article “An Introduction to Economic Evaluation in Health Care” and Dubravka Jurlina Alibegović, who discusses “The Role of Public-Private Partnership in the Economic Assessment of the Rational Use of Resources in Health Care”. Economic evaluations (cost-effectiveness analysis, cost-benefit analysis and cost and benefit analysis) are tools to improve the system’s efficiency and are necessary for carrying out the reforms. Of course, taking decisions on the implementation of evaluations and reforms continues to be the responsibility of politics. A useful means to improve efficiency could also be public and private partnership – a model that is yet to find widespread application in the health care system. The authors of the book have recognised the key macroeconomic challenges facing the health care system in Croatia, and opened the way to dealing with macroeconomic issues in order to review and improve efficiency. The main topics for future research into the health care economics in Croatia are the following: (a) evaluation of the success of hospital rehabilitation; (b) efficiency analyses of the completed decentralisation; (c) the manner of determining minimum financial standards; (d) asset management and valuation; (e) amount, structure and maturities of liabilities; (f) capital investments (an analysis for the period ending 2015, and plans by 2020); (g) financial analysis of the operations of medical centres, pharmacies and hospitals (by name and type of institution); and (h) organisation and practice of the financial management of hospitals. financial theory and practice 39 (2) 237-243 (2015) This book is, without doubt, a valuable piece of work which is yet to find its proper place in expenditure analyses. It could also serve as a practical guide in planning health care system reforms. An examination and review of efficiency can certainly increase accountability in the health care system. Croatia should step up the role of economy in health care and have more health professionals who are skilled in economics. 243 maja vehovec (ed.): health care from an economic perspective Publisher Institute of Public Finance, Smičiklasova 21, Zagreb, Croatia Editor-in-Chief Katarina Ott Production Editor Marina Nekić Editorial Board (Institute of Public Finance) Marijana Bađun Anto Bajo Predrag Bejaković Vjekoslav Bratić Mihaela Bronić Martina Fabris Katarina Ott Ivica Urban Goran Vukšić Editorial Advisory Board Hrvoje Arbutina (Faculty of Law, Zagreb, Croatia) Will Bartlett (London School of Economics and Political Science, London, UK) Helena Blažić (Faculty of Economics, Rijeka, Croatia) Balázs Égert (OECD, Paris, France) Edgar L. Feige (Professor of Economics Emeritus at the University of Wisconsin, Madison, Wisconsin, USA) Božidar Jelčić (Faculty of Law, Zagreb, Croatia) Evan Kraft (American University, Washington D.C., USA) Peter J. Lambert (University of Oregon, Department of Economics, Eugene, USA) Olivera Lončarić-Horvat (Faculty of Law, Zagreb, Croatia) Dubravko Mihaljek (Bank for International Settlements, Basel, Switzerland) Peter Sanfey (European Bank for Reconstruction and Development, London, UK) Bruno Schönfelder (Technical University Bergakademie Freiberg, Faculty of Economics and Business Administration, Freiberg, Germany) Miroslav Verbič (Faculty of Economics / Institute for Economic Research, Ljubljana, Slovenia) Athanasios Vamvakidis (Bank of America Merrill Lynch, London, UK) Hrvoje Šimović (Faculty of Economics and Business, Zagreb, Croatia) Financial Theory and Practice is abstracted and indexed in: DOAJ (Directory of Open Access Journals, Lund University, Sweden) EBSCO Publishing Database EconLit (American Economic Association’s electronic database), JEL (Journal of Economic Literature, Pittsburgh, Pennsylvania, USA) HRČAK (Portal of Scientific Journals of Croatia) IBSS (International Bibliography of the Social Sciences, ProQuest, Cambridge, UK) RePEc (Research Papers in Economics) Editorial Office Institute of Public Finance – Financial Theory and Practice Smičiklasova 21, Zagreb, Croatia, P.O. BOX 320 phone: +385 (0)1 4886 444; 4819 363; fax: +385 (0)1 4819 365 web-site: www.fintp.hr; e-mail: [email protected] Subscription Annual subscription amounts 400 kuna Payments to account no. HR7024840081100661775, Institut za javne financije, Zagreb; quoting: subscription to Financial Theory and Practice, 2015 Printed in 115 copies The journal comes out four times a year The journal is co-financed by the Ministry of Science, Education and Sport of the Republic of Croatia Computer typesetting and printing Denona d.o.o., Zagreb, Marina Getaldića 1 2/2015 39 (2) 2015 ARTUR ŚWISTAK, SEBASTIAN WAWRZAK and AGNIESZKA ALIŃSKA In pursuit of tax equity: lessons from VAT rate structure adjustment in Poland ANA KUNDID NOVOKMET Cyclicality of bank capital buffers in South-Eastern Europe: endogenous and exogenous aspects MIRNA DUMIČIĆ Financial stress indicators for small, open, highly euroized countries: the case of Croatia ANA PERIŠIĆ and VANJA WAGNER Development index: analysis of the basic instrument of Croatian regional policy Vol. 39, No. 2 | pp. 115-243 June 2015 | Zagreb udc 336 issn 1846-887x
© Copyright 2024