Vetoes and agenda: why does the Brazilian President veto bills proposed by herself? Danilo Buscatto Medeiros Univeristy of Virginia Thirty Years of Democracy in Brazil: A Research Workshop April 20, 2015 Abstract The Brazilian Constitution authorizes the President to introduce bills and also to veto partially (line-item) or totally the bills the legislature pass. Both prerogatives have been largely used since the Constitution was enacted in 1988. The success and dominance of the executive on legislative outcome can be partially explained by the existence of both constitutional powers. The paradigmatic case is the legislation vetoed by the Brazilian President that was initiated by herself. To explain this puzzle, this paper focuses on the role of the rapporteur, the actor who can be decisive in negotiating modifications within the legislature. The policy preferences of the rapporteur are hypothesized as critical to the legislative outcome. The expected action of a rapporteur who does not share the preferences with the President is the tentative to approximate the bill to her own ideal point, which might result in a presidential veto. The preliminary analysis points out that this argument does not hold. The spatial distance between the President and the rapporteur is not associated with the incidence of veto. Rapporteurs are important to the decision-making process, but as channels for bargains on amendments. Vetoes are used by the President to promote coalition’s goals that were not achieved in the legislature. Introduction The legislative powers of the executive are critical features of presidential democracies. The constitutional prerogatives available to presidents define how they interact with legislatures and whether gridlock is a threat to the regime stability. The capacity to initiate bills and to veto partially (line-item) or totally the legislation passed in the Congress are crucial to governability. The prerogative to propose bills reinforce the role of the president as an agenda-setter in the law-making process. The veto power constrains the legislators to take into account the presidential preferences when passing legislation, resulting in moderation regarding the possibility of presidential veto. In systems where both prerogatives are guaranteed to the president, a bill may be initiated and - after passing in the legislature - vetoed by the executive. In fact, this puzzling situation is more common than one would imagine. For instance, in Brazil since the enactment of the constitution 23% of the bills initiated by the president were vetoed. Why do presidents veto bills proposed by themselves? This paper proposes a research agenda to assess this political phenomenon. I analyze the Brazilian case aiming to offer an explanation for the vetoes which seriously take into account the decision-making process, the relationship between the President and Congress and the coalition management. Committees play an important role in formating the legislation. The rapporteurs designated to evaluate each bill have power to influence the committee decision (which can be a final report to the floor indicating rejection or approval with or without modifications on the original bill) and also the floor decision (by defending amendments before the other congressmen). The rapporteur is an institutional channel to promote negotiations within the coalition (multiple preferences are represented) and among parties of the coalition and the opposition. Giving this scenario I develop the following hypothesis for the Brazilian case: the closer the preferences of the rapporteur and the president, the lower the likelihood of the legislation being vetoed by the latter. The argument is that when the spatial distance is high, the rapporteur works to push the legislature to approve amendments that is considered by the president and the government coalition as unacceptable. As a consequence of this kind of 1 modification in the original bill, the president reacts vetoing the legislation - it works as a damage control. By contrast, when the spatial distance is low, the rapporteur works to preclude modifications on the committee and on the floor, considerably decreasing the chance of a presidential veto. Preliminary results suggest that the hypothesis do not hold. The spatial distance does not seem to be relevant to the legislative outcome. However, the results also indicate that bills tend to be vetoed when they are amended in the legislature. By now, one answer could be that the rapporteur plays a decisive role in this moment, which is related to the occurrence of veto. We need a better understanding of how (and which) amendments are approved in order to offer a complete explanation on presidential vetoes in presidential bills. 1 Vetoes and agenda A general statement about the strategic interaction between political actors when making laws is that the existence of presidential veto power forces the legislators to consider the preferences of the executive when passing legislation, resulting in moderation. In the scenario where the legislators do not have complete information about the preferences of the President, veto occurs when the Congress does not correctly anticipate what are the boundaries for the presidential acceptance. The interaction can be more complicated whereas vetoes are a sequential game and political actors learn with each others actions (Cameron, 2000). Considering that the focus of my investigation is the vetoed bills initiated by the President, it is given that the legislators can assume that the preferences is around the position of the original bill. When analyzing the Brazilian case it is important to take into account the flexibility and strength of the veto prerogative. As Shugart and Carey (1992, p. 134) stress, the line-item veto is more powerful and flexible than the total veto once it allows the President to interpose just the parts of the legislation that she disapproves - hence, the cost of a partial veto is lower. Vetoes do occur in Brazil. One may say that the legislators do not always anticipate the 2 preferences of the President. An alternative explanation is that the whole process - from the introduction of the bill to the presidential decision to veto or not - is not characterized by the conflict between Executive and Legislative, but it is the tentative to aggregate the preferences of the majority around a common negotiated agenda (Figueiredo and Limongi, 2009). My argument is that the rapporteur (“relator”) plays a key role in organizing the bargaining and his position is decisive to the legislative outcome (i.e. how distant the policy is moved from the position of the President), which, in turn, affects the likelihood of a presidential veto. Therefore, this paper aims to address the following hypothesis: in the policy-making process, the closer the preferences of the rapporteur of a bill proposed by the President are to the President’s preferences, the lower the likelihood of the legislation being vetoed by her. The dependent variable indicates whether the bill initiated by the President was vetoed by herself. The independent variable is the spatial distance between the President’s and the rapporteur’s preferences. The idea implicit in the hypothesis above is that a change in the distance between the two political actors mentioned will affect the likelihood of a presidential veto. The semantic definitions and the operationalization of both variables will be discussed in an appropriate section bellow. The proposed hypothesis can be applied to any separation of powers system where the President has constitutional veto power and members of Congress are designated to work as rapporteurs. However, regarding the motivation of this research - why do Presidents use the veto power on bills initiated by themselves? - the scope of my hypothesis is bounded by two factors: (1) the constitution has to authorize the President to veto and to propose ordinary bills, and (2) the legislative process define that rapporteurs have a positive power. The former basically restricts the scope of my hypothesis to a reduced number of countries. According to Shugart (2008) Presidential democracies exist almost exclusively in the Americas (Cyprus, Indonesia, Philippines, South Korea, Benin, Ghana, Malawi and Nigeria are some of the exceptions). Furthermore, strong presidential agenda power (the Executive’s capacity to direct influence the law-making process, introducing bills and changing the timing od the legislative process, for example) is a fundamental characteristic of Latin American 3 separation of powers systems (Aleman and Tsebelis, 2005). The second source of limitation, the existence of a rapporteur system, is even more restrictive. In general, rapporteurs are members of legislative committees selected to analyze bills, debate their content, and legal and financial issues with other relevant actors (i.e., representatives in general, members of the Federal administration, interest groups, unions and other organized groups), collect amendments and present a final report informing the committee if she concluded that the bill should be rejected, approved as originally proposed or approved with modifications - in this case, the rapporteur can add the amendments introduced by other congressmen or reformulate the project with her own modifications. The committee has the option to approve or not the report. The rapporteur may also have a role in the debate on the floor, presenting his analysis of the bill to all members of Congress. In short, although rapporteurs cannot control the agenda, they are endowed with powers to influence whether the bill will become law and to what extent it will be modified. Hence, rapporteurship is not an institution present in every legislature. However, our knowledge is limited about this institution because it does not exist in the American Congress and the British Parliament: “The rapporteur has no direct parallel in the Anglo-American experience but is a prominent device in the EP and many European legislatures, including the Camera dei Deputati (Italy), the Bundestag (Germany), the Nationalrat (Austria), the Tweede Kamer (Netherlands), the Chambre des Reprsentants (Belgium), and the Scottish Parliament” (Yoshinaka, Mcelroy and Bowler, 2010, p. 458). Moreover, the literature about this issue is limited to the European Parliament (Benedetto, 2005; Daniel, 2013; Hurka, 2013; Kaeding, 2005; Yoshinaka, Mcelroy and Bowler, 2010). In general, this literature concludes that rapporteurs are critical political actors within the European Parliament (EP) in shaping the legislative outcome. The powers to draft reports on proposed legislation and negotiate across political groups are the keys to understand the importance of the rapporteurs in the EP policy-making. For now, the limited knowledge about rapporteurships in presidential systems bounds our abilities to test the hypothesis to other countries than Brazil. However, what do we know about Brazilian policy-making process? In a nutshell, Brazil is a presidential multiparty system where the Executive is endowed 4 with agenda powers and the legislative process is concentrated in the hands of the speakers and the party leaders. On the one hand, the President has constitutional prerogatives to introduce ordinary bills, to request urgency to this bills, to veto totally and partially and she is the only actor that is authorized to publish decree-law (“Medidas Provisorias”) and to introduce the budgetary legislation (which can be changed by the legislative). On the other hand, the ordinary legislative work is organized in two-steps: committees analyze the bill and present a report indicating its approval or rejection1 ; if the decision is to support the approval, the bill goes to the floor to be discussed and voted. This process occurs in both houses, the Chamber of Deputies and the Federal Senate. Nevertheless, the agenda is determined by the speaker and the party leaders. They decide which committee will analyze each bill and they also define the timing for modifications and discussion. Some bills are never voted in the floor because those actors simply do not put them on the agenda. Party leaders control offices and positions in the Congress. The combination of a strong president that distributes offices in order to form a coalition in a highly fragmented political system with a centralized legislative process guarantees stability and governability (Figueiredo and Limongi, 1999, 2000). Hence, Brazil is a paradigmatic case of coalitional presidentialism (Cheibub and Limongi, 2010). That being said, one question has to be answered: what is the role of rapporteurs in Brazilian policy-making? In short, “the committee’s rapporteur (‘relator’) is assigned the task of collecting amendments and making a legislative recommendation. Rapporteurs incorporate proposed amendments (their own as well as those proposed by other legislators)” and present a final report to the committee or in some cases (especially when urgency is requested to the bill) an oral report is made directly on the floor. Although other actors have mechanisms to undermine the power of the rapporteur (i.e., the speaker and the political leaders control the agenda), the latter can exert a decisive role controlling the modification process (Freitas, Medeiros and Moura, 2008; Freitas, 2010). This power does not prevent other amendments to be approved, but reduces their chances in a system of asymmetric information. Thus, we build on the hypothesis developed by Hurka (2013, p. 279) for the European Parliament: 1 Another possibility is to simply do not make any decision until another actor, as the speaker for example, request some action on that bill. 5 “Amendments of regular committee members are more likely to get adopted if they do not have to compete with an amendment tabled by the rapporteur”. The distribution of powers in the Brazilian Congress and the results for the policy-making in the European Parliament provide basis to believe that despite the fact that Brazil is characterized by a centralized legislative process, rapporteurs are important for the legislative outcome and the other actors pay attention in their decisions and actions. In some extent this work aims to discuss with a broad literature in the legislative studies field regarding an important distinction about decision-making processes. On one hand, in decentralized systems the committees are the political actors responsible for the agenda-setting. In this type of institutional arrangement the committees have the capacity and autonomy to redefine the content of the policies and they also have prerogatives to exert veto power in the legislative bargaining. On the other hand, in centralized decision-making processes the majority leader (or the majority party, or the leader of the government coalition) assumes this position. Party leaders are the actors responsible to organize the legislative agenda and to identify the timing to modify the bills and the legislation. In centralized decisionmaking processes, the committees do not play a decisive role once party control is the key for legislative outcome. Having said that, it seems that presidential systems with centralized decision-making processes are not contemplated by the theoretical models. This is manifest even in the work of Cox and McCubbins (1993, 1994) in which the President is not the agenda-setter, but parties control the legislative actions by means of the committees. The results for the Brazilian case could be useful to offer insights about the reasons of presidential veto in multi-party presidential systems, especially in Latin America - as Aleman and Schwartz (2006) remember “[f]amous for their long lists of presidential powers and their elaborate bill-to-law procedures, the constitutions of Latin America all allow the President to veto bills passed by Congress.”. The literature about why vetoes occur in multiparty separation of powers systems is growing, but it is still limited by the same explanatory variables: partisan affinities of the President and Congress and levels of significance of legislation. We are proposing a different hypothesis that can shed light in the study of the executive-legislative relations and also in the literature about coalition management. We 6 intend to do this analyzing vetoes in a critical situation - when Presidents veto legislative outcome which was initiated by herself. We follow (Palanza and Sin, 2014, p. 767) in the understanding that “vetoes are a crucial bargaining element in separation of power systems, influencing the complex relationship between the President and Congress”. That’s the main reason to study presidential vetoes with the goal to assess the broad policy-making process. The idea is to offer explanations for the vetoes within the legislative process. We developed a hypothesis that focus in the affinities of the President and the rapporteurs. To sum up, the argument elaborated is that when the spatial distance between the rapporteur and the President is high, the former works to push the legislature to approve modifications on the original bill which will be considered unacceptable or undesired by the President and the government coalition. As a consequence of this kind of alteration in the Executive’s initiative, the President reacts vetoing (line-item or totally) the legislation - it works as a damage control that the President may have to set once the legislation passes. By contrast, when the spatial distance is low, the rapporteur works to preclude modifications on the committee and on the floor, considerably decreasing the chance of a presidential veto.The assumption made here is that the Executive introduces bills close to her preferences and the rapporteurs, given their crucial position, work to approximate the legislation in the direction of their ideal points. However, the rapporteurs are constrained by the possibility of a presidential veto and by the actions of party leaders. The rapporteurs have to take into account the preferences represented on the floor. Although they are critical to the bargain process and control some resources to negotiate amendments and influence other legislators’ positions, the floor commonly makes the final decision. 1.1 Who are the rapporteurs? It is necessary to know how legislators are selected to work as a rapporteur. Formally, the committee chair is responsible for choosing who will be the rapporteur. However, the factors influencing the chair’s decision are almost unknown. The work of Santos and Almeida (2005) concludes that the expertise of a legislator in a specific area is decisive to her selection as rapporteur of a bill in the same area. They also demonstrate that when the President is 7 the bill’s author and the chair of the committee is member of a party that is not in the government coalition, she chooses a rapporteur whose ideal point is far (but not too far) from the median of the coalition. However, they do not explain how the decision is made - i.e., whether the chair take the decision by herself or other political leaders negotiate the designation with the chair. The dependent variable in the study of Santos and Almeida (2005) is the number of bills in which each legislator worked as a rapporteur. Thus, they are not explaining the reason why a legislator is selected as a rapporteur, but why some legislators are selected more frequently than others. The idea that the chair of the committee randomly selects a legislator to work as a rapporteur seems implausible. The chair of the committee is also selected and this process can encompass another chain of factors and interactions. Although the chair of each committee is elected every year, the party leaders previously bargain the chairs. The most important finding made by Santos and Almeida (2005) is that at least in some cases, the position of the legislator is important to her designation as a rapporteur of a bill initiated by the Executive. The chair selects the rapporteur because of her position and this decision is motivated by the role that the rapporteur may have in the legislative outcome. Although we need to know more about the rapporteur selection process, endogeneity seems a real threat. Moreover, if Santos and Almeida (2005) were correct there is a considerable probability of bias in the direction of high levels of spatial distance (at least when the chair of the committee is a member of the opposition). On the other hand, if the President’s (direct or indirect) participation in the rapporteur selection could be confirmed, the bias probably have another direction: low spatial distance, once the President would work to have rapporteurs that would not threaten her intentions regarding that bill. We still need more literature to improve our knowledge on this issue. 8 2 Concept Formation and Measurement In this section I discuss the theoretical constructs of the research hypothesis presented above and I explain how they are operationalized. 2.1 Presidential veto The concept of presidential veto is defined as the constitutional right of the President to not enact - or in some systems, to partially enact - a bill approved by the legislature. Our conceptualization build on the definition of Aleman and Schwartz (2006, 100) “A veto is a formal act of rejection, in effect a contrary vote. So a presidential veto is a vote by the President against a bill that has been passed by the legislative branch but not yet enacted though enactment was a presidential option”. The operationalization of this concept is straightforward: the indicator of presidential veto is a dichotomous variable that points out the final decision of the President for each bill that the legislature passed. The President has three options: full enactment, partial enactment (line-item veto) or total rejection. President is here interpreted not as an individual but as the Executive’s chief. Thereafter, if the President A proposes one bill that is vetoed by the President B, I classify this bill as initiated and vetoed by the President herself. To be clear: I’m collapsing partial and total vetoes in the same category (vetoed). I’m aware that they can have different implications to the legislative bargaining in multiparty separation of power systems and the President may have different reasons to resort to one or the other (Aleman and Schwartz, 2006; Tsebelis and Aleman, 2005; Palanza and Sin, 2014). However, total vetoes in bills initiated by the Brazilian President are rare events. We just have eight total vetoes since 1988 and te last one was in 1995, during the first year of Cardoso’s administration. Moreover, I am not interested in evaluating the motivations that lead the President to resort to one type of veto or to the other; my goal is to test what can affect the likelihood of veto in general. 9 2.2 Spatial distance and preferences Spatial distance is the theoretical construct that backs the independent variable of this study. The concept of spatial distance is defined as the difference between two actors’ preferences - in my case, the President and the rapporteur. Thus, preferences are conceptualized as summary of the choices made (and also the potential choices on future or hypothetical decisions) by an actor over policy alternatives. For instance, actors who have close preferences will choose the same alternative in almost all policy decisions; by contrast, actors who have distant preferences will frequently choose divergent alternatives. This definition assumes that these preferences can be measured and compared. Preferences are operationalized here as ideal points, which will be estimated using roll calls. In any given roll call each legislator will decide her vote comparing the distance of the two alternatives, ”yay” or ”nay”, to her most preferred policy (Zucco Jr. and Lauderdale, 2011). This definition is rooted in the spatial model of voting, which assumes that policy alternatives can be represented as points in a Euclidean space and political actors choose between these alternatives based on a defined position (Enelow and Hinich, 1984; Hinich and Munger, 1997).This allows us to localize actors in the space and compare positions. Spatial models assume that actors have single-peakedness preferences, namely only one alternative will be the most preferred one. Thus, this decision can be interpreted as a point in a space. This point is the ideal point. With the information of each decision is possible to form a spatial map that summarizes the votes. Ideal point estimation using roll calls is a statistical method, which means that although it is assumed that legislators will choose the closer alternative to their position it is also assumed that voting is probabilistic (Poole, 2005). In other words, the legislative behavior in real world roll calls has a stochastic component and the ideal point is an estimator of that behavior. This idea of an ideal point that summarizes the policy positions of a legislator is embedded in the belief system proposed by Converse (1964, p. 207): “a configuration of ideas and attitudes in which the elements are bound together by some form of constraint or functional interdependence”. Poole and Rosenthal (1985) build on Converse’s concept to theorize that 10 once one know how a legislator voted in a couple of roll calls it is possible to predict how the same legislator will behavior in other issues. To estimate the ideal points I adopt the Optimal Classification (OC) method (Poole, 2000, 2005; Rosenthal and Voeten, 2004), which is different from the parametric methods, as the more famous W-NOMINATE (Poole and Rosenthal, 1985, 1997), because it maximizes the correct classification of the legislative choices. As argued by Rosenthal and Voeten (2004, 622), “the optimal classification method does not rely on distributional assumptions about errors to uncover metric information from binary roll-call data. The optimal classification method seeks to find ideal points for legislators and separating hyperplanes for roll calls such that the number of classification errors is minimized. A classification error for a legislator on a roll call occurs when the legislator’s ideal point is such that his or her vote is inconsistent with the separating hyperplane for the roll call”. The following steps describe how OC method works (Poole, 2005): 1. Generate starting values for the legislators, the Xi , from an eigenvalue eigenvector decomposition of the legislator-by-legislator agreement score matrix. 2. Given the Xi , find the optimal estimates of the normal vectors, the Nj . 3. Given the Nj , find the optimal estimates of the Xi . 4. Go to step 2. Comparing choices of each legislator in each roll call it is possible to summarize each position in a multidimensional map. Each dimension varies from -1 to 1 and legislators receive an estimate in each of them. It is important to assert that I will use the ideal point estimated for the first dimension. In the Brazilian Congress one-dimension correctly classify around 90% of the votes, and the addition of a second dimension does not significantly improve the model (Leoni, 2002; Freitas, Izumi and Medeiros, 2013). Therefore, my independent variable measures the difference of the ideal point of the rapporteur and the government leader (a legislator selected by the government coalition to represent its interests within the legislative). Giving the impossibility to estimate the President’s an ideal point comparable with the legislators’ - since she does not vote - I followed Leoni (2002) 11 and used the position of the government leader as a proxy of how the President behavior in the legislative. We are considering the government leader as an institutional position and not as an individual. This is possible for two reasons: leaders can be changed during the presidential term and they also indicates a vote as the government leader (this indication does not count as a vote, it is just a signaling of which is the government coalition position on that issue). It is important to make clear that spatial distance is not an indicator of the agreement or disagreement between the rapporteur and the government leader in each bill I selected to analyze. This would be possible only if every bill has a recorded voted on the floor, which is not the case. In turn, spatial distance is a measure of the difference of the general behavior of these two actors expressed in roll calls. As noted by Clinton (2012, p. 80) “Roll calls appear to offer an ideal opportunity for measuring the preferences of political elites because I observe elites registering their individual support on many proposed policies”. That’s an important advantage of estimating ideal points based on roll calls: the outcome is based on real choices about policies alternatives and not on hypothetical situations. Ideal points estimations produced by roll call analysis does not have a direct and obvious meaning. To identify and interpret what the ideal point represents is a task to be performed by the researcher and this can vary from each legislative setting (Poole, 2001; Clinton, 2012). What does explain the legislative behavior expressed by voting in Congress? The pioneer research about the ideal points in the United States showed that ideology, the liberal-conservative continuum, describes the ideal points in the first dimension (Poole and Rosenthal, 1997). In Brazil the substantive meaning of the political space revealed by roll call analyses is under dispute. Ideology was the first interpretation offered to the ideal points in the Chamber of Deputies Leoni (2002). More recent studies, however, demonstrated that the division between government and opposition is a better fit for the ideal points estimated (Zucco Jr., 2009; Freitas, Izumi and Medeiros, 2013). In short, the correlation between the ideal points and the percentage of votes that legislators cast following the government guidelines is high. In a study combining roll call analysis with survey data, Zucco Jr. and 12 Lauderdale (2011, p. 391) argue that “there exists a single ideological dimension in Brazilian politics, but the analysis of legislative behavior suggests that the government-opposition dynamic constitutes an important non-ideological aspect of political conflict”. But at the same time they assert that both dimensions tend to overlap, which means that it is difficult to separate the position in the left-right scale from the support (or lack of support) given to the government appeal. The interpretation of ideal point estimates could be complicated, especially if other motivations rather than preferences over policy alternatives take particular votes. Rosenthal and Voeten (2004, p. 620) identify five sources of problems if one estimates ideal points using parametric methods (as the W-NOMINATE): “variation in discipline across parties, unstable party memberships, proxy voting, near perfect two-dimensional spatial voting, and parliamentary institutions that provide incentives for strategic voting”. In the Brazilian case, party-switching and strategic behavior (i.e., incentives and constraints offered by parties and government that affect the votes) could lead a legislator to “cast votes for reasons other than the relative proximity of the alternative to the legislator’s most-preferred policy” (Clinton, 2012, p. 83). In sum, ideal point as an operational definition seems to overlap with the theoretical construct. The former as the estimator of the combination of the most preferred policy alternatives and the latter defining preferences as a map of the choices made by political actors. The idea that both the ideal point and the preferences can be used to predict future behavior of the political actor results in a approximation of them. However, since it is possible that ideal points reflect other factors than preferences over policy alternatives, the correspondence between the construct and the indicator may be threatened. Nevertheless, the interpretation of the Brazilian political dimension as the division between government and opposition does not represent a big problem, because it is still measuring the choices made - my goal is not to measure the “true” and static preferences, but to estimate the public positions taken by political actors. In the Brazilian case this means that legislators whose parties are members of the government coalition cast votes, in general, supporting the government. More problematic is the possibility that a legislator take a decision in a roll call regarding the risk of 13 being punished by her party. To minimize this problem I estimated the ideal points with a nonparametric method, the Optimal Classification, which does not make any assumption about the distribution of errors and the utility function underlying parametric models. As I have mentioned above, OC minimize the errors of the estimative. In other words, its robustness “to the stochastic nature of the data makes it [OC] an ideal candidate for studying strategic behavior in legislatures” (Rosenthal and Voeten, 2004, p. 620). 3 Data Analysis In this research I am recurring to the Brazilian Legislative Database organized by the Brazilian Center of Analysis and Planning (“Banco de Dados Legislativos - CEBRAP”). This dataset contain information on both roll calls and lawmaking. Before describing the variables used in this preliminary study, I alert that some simplifications were made. First, only information about the decision-making process in the Chamber has been considered. Bills initiated by the Executive always begin in the Chamber. The inclusion of data about the Federal Senate has to be better planned and developed. Moreover, the Senate works just as reviewer and tends to approve what passed in the Chamber. Second, only one rapporteur/committee for each bill is considered. This decision was made to simplify our analysis and also to capture the action of the most important rapporteur, the one that is designated by the committee which area of expertise is related to the bill. Other two constitutional and financial committees evaluate each bill and their reports are technical. 3.1 Variables Among all bills initiated in the Brazilian Congress, my selection of cases includes bills introduced by the President (the goal of this research is to understand Executive-Legislative relations regarding presidential prerogatives) that passed in the legislature (thus, the President can decide to use or not her veto power). I analyze all 627 bills initiated by the President 14 and passed by the legislative since the first year of the new constitution (1989) and the end of the last presidential term (2010). I consider the following variables in my study. The dependent variable is the existence of presidential veto in the bill. It is coded as 0 (the President enacted the bill) and 1 (the President vetoed the bill). As we can see in the Table 1 bellow the distribution of bills per President is very similar (except for Sarney), but the proportion of vetoes dramatically decreased. Collor vetoed almost 40% of the bills included in the analysis. Table 1: Distribution President Sarney Collor Franco Cardoso Cardoso II Lula Lula II Total of bills enacted and vetoed by President Enactments Vetoes Total 25 3 28 58 38 96 62 20 82 96 24 120 73 30 103 79 15 94 90 14 104 483 144 627 Source: Brazilian Legislative Database - CEBRAP The independent variable is the spatial distance between the rapporteur and the government leader (proxy of the President’s ideal point). Roll calls were used to estimate the ideal points. Then, the difference between the ideal points were calculated. The distribution of this variables is shown on Graph 1. It is very impressive that 50% of the cases the distance is very close to zero (i.e., the rapporteur’s ideal point is almost the same as the government leader’s ideal points). The expectation is that this variable has a positive effect in the likelihood of veto. 15 0 1 2 Density 3 4 5 Figure 1: Distribution of the Spatial Distance 0 .5 1 1.5 distance Source: Brazilian Legislative Database - CEBRAP The following control variables were selected: • Amendment: Indicates if a bill was modified in the Congress. I expect a positive effect once I assume that the President tends to not accept modifications in her own bills. • Urgency: Indicates if a urgency rule was requested. Urgencies are important to accelerate the processing of the bill. It is an evidence that party leaders (the main requesters of urgencies) consider this bill very important. I expect a positive effect because salient bills (and urgency increases the saliency of a bill calling attention of the media and other political actors) can induce the President to review some parts of her own bill, enhancing the likelihood of a veto. • Committee Rule: Indicates if the bill passed by just committee decision, without the participation of the floor. The Speaker can decide that a bill does not need to be voted in the floor, and if no legislator request to vote it the bill can be approved just in the committee. I expect a negative effect because the floor is an important locus for the opposition discuss the bill’s. • Same term: Indicates if the bill was introduced and approved in the same presidential term. I expect a negative effect because when the President in power changes the 16 agenda also changes, increasing the chance of veto. • Honeymoon: Indicates if the bill was approved in the first three months of a presidential term. According to Palanza and Sin (2014, 774) “during honeymoon periods following the beginning of a new administration, the probability of vetoes should be smaller” because the Congress tends to pass bills close to the President’s ideal point. Thus, a negative effect is expected. • Minority: Indicates if a bill was approved during a minority government coalition. When the government does not control the majority, the Congress tends to pass bills far to the President’s ideal point. A positive effect is expected. We also control by legislative term in order to assess differences in the agenda, the composition and other temporal factors. The legislative term just summarizes theses issues. A multi-level analysis including detailed information about each term would be a better method, but I do not have resources to do that by now. The content and the significance of the legislation are not considered here. As Palanza and Sin (2014) demonstrate for the Argentinian case, the latter (which is related to the former) is critical for the presidential veto behavior. As I am analyzing Executive bills I assume that all pieces are evaluated as highly significant at least to the Executive agenda. 3.2 Preliminary Analysis: the logistic regression To test our hypothesis I use a logistic regression model. This decision is based on the fact that my dependent variable is binary. Logistic regression is a nonlinear regression model, which estimates the probability of our dependent variable be 1 (event occurrence). First of all, I present the boxplot of the independent variable (spatial distance) by the values of the dependent variable (occurrence of presidential veto). The result is shown on Graph 2. The distribution of spatial distance is very similar in both scenarios. The median is almost the same. The only difference seems to be the existence of outliers when bills are enacted instead of vetoed. This descriptive analysis lead me to believe that there is no relation 17 between the variables present in my hypothesis. Figure 2: Distribution of Spatial Distance, by occurrence of veto (enactment vs. veto) Vetoed bills 1 0 .5 Spatial distance 1.5 Enacted bills Source: Brazilian Legislative Database - CEBRAP To produce more robust conclusions about the interaction between the dependent and the independent variables I ran four logistic regression models. In the first all controls are included. In the second all controls but the legislative terms are included. The third and fourth models are variations of the first and the second but without the variable amendment (modification in the Congress). The effect of having a modification is so large that lead me to test a model without this variable. The models with the legislative term variable use the legislature initiated in 1987 as the basis. The results are presented in Table 2. In model 1 just one variable is statistically significant at the 5% level: amendment. Holding other variables constant, the passage from not having amendments to having amendments increase the odds of presidential in 802.1%. The effect of distance is negative and it is not statically significant in all four models. The interpretation of this effect in the first model is that, holding everything constant, each additional unit in spatial distance will decrease the odds of presidential veto in 29.2%. The signal of the effect is the opposite of which I was expecting. In the second model the effect of a minority coalition in the odds of presidential veto is 18 positive and statistically significant at the five 5% level. This could be related to the fact that President Collor never had a majority coalition and he was the President that more frequently used the veto power. Presidents Cardoso and Lula governed with minority coalitions for short periods. In the models without the amendment variable, other variables became statistically significant at the 5% level. This is the true for the occurrence of committee rule and the dummy variable indicating if a bill was approved in the same presidential term. The explanatory power of amendments is so high that minimizes the effect of other variables. In the Graph 3 the average marginal effect for each variable in the second model is estimated and it is possible to identify the difference of the magnitude of the marginal effect of amendments in the presidential veto. Spatial distance Amendment Urgency Committee rule Same term Honeymoon Minority 1991 term 1995 term 1999 term 2003 term 2007 term Observations Pseudo R2 Table 2: Logistic Regression (1) (2) Presidential veto Presidential veto 0.708 (-1.24) 0.827 (-0.71) ∗∗∗ ∗∗∗ 9.021 (6.85) 9.687 (7.11) 1.112 (0.42) 1.091 (0.36) 0.597 (-1.48) 0.538 (-1.88) 0.668 (-1.57) 0.616 (-1.93) 1.067 (0.11) 0.939 (-0.11) 1.447 (1.42) 1.750∗ (2.35) 1.488 (1.06) 0.725 (-0.73) 1.234 (0.52) 0.762 (-0.61) 0.697 (-0.68) 627 627 0.162 0.151 Exponentiated coefficients; z statistics in parentheses ∗ p < 0.05, ∗∗ p < 0.01, ∗∗∗ p < 0.001 Source: Brazilian Legislative Database - CEBRAP 19 results (3) Presidential veto 0.692 (-1.40) (4) Presidential veto 0.849 (-0.66) 0.989 0.397∗∗ 0.579∗ 1.139 1.245 2.045∗ 0.846 1.663 0.828 0.819 627 0.058 1.005 0.362∗∗ 0.530∗∗ 0.983 1.468 (-0.05) (-2.76) (-2.22) (0.22) (0.91) (2.00) (-0.40) (1.32) (-0.45) (-0.39) 627 0.036 (0.02) (-3.22) (-2.67) (-0.03) (1.74) Figure 3: Average Marginal Effects with 95% CIs -.2 Effects on Pr(Veto) 0 .2 .4 Average Marginal Effects with 95% CIs distance alter urg comm_rule sameterm honeymoon Effects with Respect to minority Source: Brazilian Legislative Database - CEBRAP In sum, our hypothesis are completely frustrated by the data analysis. The evidence is present even in the rudimentary boxplot. There is no relation between spatial distance and presidential veto. The regression analysis also showed that the effect is not significant and it is negative (I hypothesized a positive effect). 4 Conclusions This paper is a preliminary tentative of bringing the legislative process and the coalition management into the explanation of the paradoxical cases of presidential vetoes in presidential initiatives. This phenomenon seem to be associated with the existence of modifications made by the legislature when it passed the legislation. The hypothesis develop in this exploratory working paper - the higher spatial distance between the rapporteur and the President, the higher the likelihood of a presidential veto - did not hold the preliminary tests. This could be a result of the difficulty of measuring spatial distance, using government leader as a proxy of the President, bias or endogeneity. The rapporteur may have an institutional position and her ideal point might not be decisive 20 to the legislative output. Nevertheless, the strong effect of the existence of amendments in the presidential veto require the following question: how are amendments approved in the Congress? According to Freitas (2013) the rapporteur plays a critical role in the decisionmaking process, once she is decisive in negotiating the modifications within the parties of the coalition and also with the opposition. In the Brazilian separation of powers system may be a channel for parties bargain their positions over policies, allowing compromises to pass the legislation with majoritarian support. The presidential veto, in this scenario, is an expression of unresolved problems which have to be managed by the Executive and the coalition after passing the legislature. Vetoes are used by the President to promote coalition’s goals that were not achieved in the Congress. References Aleman, Eduardo and George Tsebelis. 2005. “The Origins of Presidential Conditional Agenda-Setting Power in Latin America.” Latin American Research Review 40(2):3–26. Aleman, Eduardo and Thomas Schwartz. 2006. “Presidential Vetoes in Latin American Constitutions.” Journal of Theoretical Politics 18(1):98–120. Benedetto, Giacomo. 2005. “Rapporteurs as legislative entrepreneurs: the dynamics of the codecision procedure in Europe’s parliament.” Journal of European Public Policy 12(1):67– 88. Cameron, Charles M. 2000. Veto bargaining: presidents and the politics of negative power. Political economy of institutions and decisions Cambridge, UK ; New York: Cambridge University Press. Cheibub, Jose Antonio and Fernando Limongi. 2010. “From Conflict to Coordination: Perspectives on the Study of Executive-Legislative Relations.” Revista Ibero-Americana de Estudos Legislativos 1(1):38–53. Clinton, Joshua D. 2012. “Using Roll Call Estimates to Test Models of Politics.” Annual Review of Political Science 15(1):79–99. 21 Converse, Philip E. 1964. The nature of belief systems in mass publics. In Ideology and Discontent, ed. David E. Apter. New York: The Free Press of Glencoe. Cox, Gary W. and Mathew D. McCubbins. 1993. Legislative Leviathan: Party Government in the House. Berkeley: University of California Press. Cox, Gary W. and Mathew D. McCubbins. 1994. “Bonding, Structure, and the Stability of Political Parties: Party Government in the House.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 19(2):215–231. Daniel, William T. 2013. “When the Agent Knows Better than the Principal: The Effect of Education and Seniority on European Parliament Rapporteur Assignment.” JCMS: Journal of Common Market Studies 51(5):832–848. Enelow, James M. and Melvin J. Hinich. 1984. The spatial theory of voting: an introduction. Cambridge ; New York: Cambridge University Press. Figueiredo, Argelina and Fernando Limongi. 1999. Executivo e Legislativo na nova ordem constitucional. Rio de Janeiro: Editora FGV. Figueiredo, Argelina and Fernando Limongi. 2000. “Presidential Power, Legislative Organization, and Party Behavior in Brazil.” Comparative Politics 32(2):151–170. Figueiredo, Argelina and Fernando Limongi. 2009. Poder de agenda e polticas substantivas. In Legislativo Brasileiro em Perspectiva Comparada, ed. Magna Incio and Lcio Renn. Belo Horizonte: Editora UFMG. Freitas, Andra Marcondes de. 2013. Presidencialismo da Coalizo Doctoral dissertation Faculdade de Filosofia, Letras e Cincias Humanas, Universidade de So Paulo So Paulo: . Freitas, Andrea, Mauricio Izumi and Danilo Medeiros. 2013. How Coalitions Structure Preferences? A Study on Legislative Behaviour in Brazil (1988-2010). In 41st ECPR Joint Sessions of Workshops. Mainz, Germany: . Freitas, Rafael. 2010. Poder de agenda e participao legislativa no presidencialismo de coalizo brasileiro Masters thesis Faculdade de Filosofia, Letras e Cincias Humanas, Universidade 22 de So Paulo So Paulo: . URL: http://www.teses.usp.br/teses/disponiveis/8/8131/tde-31052011-155033/pt-br.php Freitas, Rafael, Danilo Medeiros and Samuel Moura. 2008. Padres de Atuao das Comisses do Congresso Nacional (1988-2006). In 32 Encontro Anual da Anpocs. Caxambu: . Hinich, Melvin J. and Michael C. Munger. 1997. Analytical politics. Cambridge ; New York: Cambridge University Press. Hurka, Steffen. 2013. “Changing the output: The logic of amendment success in the European Parliaments ENVI Committee.” European Union Politics 14(2):273–296. Kaeding, Michael. 2005. “The world of committee reports: rapporteurship assignment in the European Parliament.” Journal of Legislative Studies 11(1):82–104. Leoni, Eduardo. 2002. “Ideologia, democracia e comportamento parlamentar: a Cmara dos Deputados (1991-1998).” Dados 45(3):361–386. Palanza, Valeria and Gisela Sin. 2014. “Veto Bargaining and the Legislative Process in Multiparty Presidential Systems.” Comparative Political Studies 47(5):766–792. Poole, Keith T. 2000. “Nonparametric Unfolding of Binary Choice Data.” Political Analysis 8(3):211–237. Poole, Keith T. 2001. “The Geometry of Multidimensional Quadratic Utility in Models of Parliamentary Roll Call Voting.” Political Analysis 9(3):211–226. Poole, Keith T. 2005. Spatial models of parliamentary voting. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Poole, Keith T. and Howard Rosenthal. 1985. “A Spatial Model for Legislative Roll Call Analysis.” American Journal of Political Science 29(2):357–384. Poole, Keith T. and Howard Rosenthal. 1997. Ideology & Congress. New Brunswick: Transaction Publishers. 23 Rosenthal, Howard and Erik Voeten. 2004. “Analyzing Roll Calls with Perfect Spatial Voting: France 19461958.” American Journal of Political Science 48(3):620–632. Santos, Fabiano and Acir Almeida. 2005. “Teoria informacional e a seleo de relatores na Cmara dos Deputados.” Dados 48(4):693–735. Shugart, Matthew Soberg. 2008. Comparative ExecutiveLegislative Relations. In The Oxford Handbook of Political Institutions, ed. Sarah A. Binder, R. A. W. Rhodes and Bert A. Rockman. Oxford University Press. Shugart, Matthew Soberg and John M. Carey. 1992. Presidents and assemblies: constitutional design and electoral dynamics. Cambridge; New York: Cambridge University Press. Tsebelis, George and Eduardo Aleman. 2005. “Presidential Conditional Agenda Setting in Latin America.” World Politics 57(03):396–420. Yoshinaka, Antoine, Gail Mcelroy and Shaun Bowler. 2010. “The Appointment of Rapporteurs in the European Parliament.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 35(4):457–486. Zucco Jr., Cesar. 2009. “Ideology or What? Legislative Behavior in Multiparty Presidential Settings.” The Journal of Politics 71(03):1076–1092. Zucco Jr., Cesar and Benjamin Lauderdale. 2011. “Distinguishing Between Influences on Brazilian Legislative Behavior.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 36(3):363–396. 24
© Copyright 2024