Sovereign Defaults during the Great Depression: New Data, New Evidence Andrea Papadia, London School of Economics ([email protected]) Supervisors: Professor Albrecht Ritschl & Dr Olivier Accominotti The debt crisis of the early 1930s was a key event of the Great Depression and contributed to shaping post-WWII finance. I focus on two aspects of this episode: the maturity structure of countries’ debts and local borrowing by presenting a new dataset for over 20 countries constructed from original sources. While many authors have highlighted the large share of short-term debt in the interwar era, this has not been quantitatively linked to the sovereign defaults. To the best of my knowledge, I am the first to investigate the magnitude and impact of local debt for a wide range of countries. This is surprising given that some local authorities borrowed massively and that, in many cases, defaults began at the local level, then expanding to the national level. Through the use of the new data and panel data methods, I provide quantitative evidence for the suggestion in the historiography that the unusually high level of short-term debt of the interwar era was decisive in the 1930s crisis. Contrary to common knowledge, and the assumptions of almost all theoretical models, I furthermore show that, once country characteristics are controlled for, higher debt-to-GDP ratios and higher economy-wide reliance on foreign credit led to a lower, rather than higher, incidence of default. The interwar debt crisis: opportunism or ‘bad luck’? Recent research has highlighted the macroeconomic relevance of the interwar debt crisis. Ritschl and Sarferaz (2014) provide evidence that the German default aggravated the Great Depression in the US, while Accominotti (2012) shows that it sped up UK's exit from gold. Given that most defaults were concentrated in the early 1930s, their compound impact is likely to have had large effects on creditor nations. The importance of the defaults is not restricted to their impact on the Great Depression. The wariness of free capital mobility created by the financial crisis induced policy-makers – in a classic trilemma framework – to forgo the free movement of capital rather than either fixed exchange rates or an independent monetary policy after WWII (Obstfeld and Taylor, 1998). In the USA, the defaults were seen as a failure of banks to manage their conflicts of interest and this was used as a key justification for the 1933 GlassSteagall Act (Carosso, 1970; Benston, 1990). The narrative around the time of the debt crisis was that the economic slump revealed the international lending of the 1920s as misguided and excessive, leading to defaults in Latin America and Europe (Harris, 1935; Madden et al, 1937; Lewis, 1938). Indeed, US Congress investigations confirmed the distorted incentives, partial or false information and unorthodox practices of some key actors (Flandreau et al, 2010). Other research has stressed the ‘bad luck’ element of the defaults. Diaz-Alejandro (1983) and Fishlow (1986) identified the magnitude of the Great Depression shock as the main driver of default. Flandreau et al (2010) take their finding that distortions in international financial markets were not as pervasive as previously thought as evidence that ‘bad luck’ played the leading role in the defaults. A partial challenge to this view is represented by Eichengreen and Portes (1986) who found that both economic shocks and policy choices mattered: terms of trade deterioration and the foreign debt to export ratio were related to default, but so was the degree of fiscal adjustment following the onset of the Great Depression. New data on public debt Reinhart and Rogoff (2009) and Abbas et al (2010) provide historical series on public debt, but these have major shortcomings for the pre-WWII era due to issues of cross-country comparability originating from the different accounting standards used by countries. For the interwar period, they rely on data collected in a United Nations (1948) volume, which is also my starting point. The working version of this paper provides details of the limits of the UN data on a country by country basis. Whenever possible, the comparability of the data was improved by including or excluding certain items, but the overall picture remains imperfect. On the positive side, the different reporting techniques used reflect the perception of the public debt held by statistical offices and, presumably, countries’ authorities. In a study of default decisions, this should be the key variable of interest. Figure 1 – Short term debt as a share of total debt, 1927-19361 Data transcribed from the volume illustrate that default was more common in countries with larger shares of short-term debt (Figure 1). Below, I show that this correlation holds even after controlling for a wide range of economic and political variables. Figure 2 – Average share of central and local debt over total debt, 1927-19362 1 Unweighted average. Defaulters: Bulgaria, Czechoslovakia, Germany, Greece, Poland, Argentina, Bolivia, Brazil, Colombia, Peru. Non-defaulters: Belgium, Denmark, Finland, United Kingdom, Ireland, Netherlands, Norway, Switzerland, Venezuela, Japan, Canada, New Zealand. Cross-country comparability issues are, however, dwarfed by the failure to consider local public debt. By using a variety of original sources detailed in the working version of this paper, I show that sub-sovereign debt constituted around 25 per cent of total public debt on average (Figure 2). Its exclusion thus leads to a severe underreporting of public debt levels.3 My local debt estimates also reveal that the comparative debt burden picture is distorted by the omission of local debt due to vast cross-country heterogeneity (Figure 3). Countries with federal structures – such as Brazil and Germany – borrowed massively at the local level. In more centralised and less sizable countries – like Belgium and Bulgaria – local borrowing was almost insignificant. Given that all public debt, whether national or local, is serviced through resources generated by the country's economy, both the underreporting and the bias in relative debt burdens are problems for any study investigating sovereign defaults. In the econometric analysis, I also rely on data collected by other researchers, as well as additional newly transcribed data. The working paper version documents the sources and discusses data reliability in detail. Figure 3 – Average share of local debt over total debt, 1927-1936 Empirical strategy I study the determinants of default size – defined as the share of the principal of public-sector foreign Dollar bonds in default – by regressing it on a series of control variables. I treat Dollar bonds separately from others given that distinct bondholders categories were often treated differently (Eichengreen and Portes, 1988).4 I employ panel data techniques to account for unobserved time-invarying crosscountry heterogeneity (e.g. creditworthiness, institutional quality, default history), which is likely to have been a key driver of defaults (Reinhart et al, 2003). By relying on the timeseries variation of variables rather than their cross-sectional levels, panel data methods also minimise the impact of the cross-country comparability issues of the data discussed above. To account for endogeneity, I control for state-dependence (i.e. default status) and employ internal instruments for the lagged explanatory variables, represented by further lags 2 Unweighted average. Countries included: Belgium, Bulgaria, Denmark, Finland, Germany, United Kingdom, Ireland, Italy, Netherlands, Norway, Poland, Sweden, Switzerland, Argentina, Brazil, Colombia, Uruguay, Australia, Japan, Canada, New Zealand. 3 The principal sources for the local debt data are the Yearbooks of the German Statistical Office (Statistiches Reichsamt, 1936-39/40). For certain countries, these are integrated by publications of the Institute for International Finance, the Corporation of Foreign Bondholders and, most importantly, Moody's (1933-37), which are also used to estimate default size. 4 Data collection on Sterling bond defaults is currently under way and these will be included in the analysis as soon as possible. of the explanatory variables themselves. I run the dynamic Arellano-Bond (1991) generalised method of moments (GMM) estimator and carry out standard tests (Sargan and ArellanoBond), which confirm its validity. The model, includes country fixed-effects, time fixedeffects and a vector of controls 𝒙: 𝑑𝑒𝑓𝑎𝑢𝑙𝑡 𝑠𝑖𝑧𝑒𝑖,𝑡 = 𝛾 𝑑𝑒𝑓𝑎𝑢𝑙𝑡 𝑠𝑖𝑧𝑒𝑖,𝑡−1 + 𝒙𝑖,𝑡 𝜷 + 𝑙𝑖 + 𝑞𝑡 + 𝜀𝑖,𝑡 [1] I test three sets of channels. The first relates the severity of the economic slump to the incidence of default. The second investigates the influence of economic and political characteristics of countries (e.g. trade openness, financial fragility, reliance on borrowing). The third, examines whether the fiscal and monetary policies enacted had any effect on the default outcome. Findings Column one in Table 1 contains the baseline specification, column two adds economy-wide (public and private) US-originating debt over GDP, column three controls for default expectations by including bond yields and column four breaks down public debt into central and local. default size L.defaultsize L.total public debt/GDP L.short term debt/total debt L.trade/trade 1929 1 2 3 4 0.692*** (0.0756) -0.177*** (0.0676) 0.318*** (0.106) 0.0182*** (0.00601) 0.668*** (0.0800) -0.235*** (0.0680) 0.435*** (0.101) 0.0176*** (0.00674) -0.863*** (0.259) 0.663*** (0.0826) -0.135** (0.0684) 0.404** (0.158) -0.000738 (0.00599) 0.628*** (0.0837) L.total US debt/GDP L.bond yield -0.0216 (0.0153) L.central gov debt/GDP L.local gov debt/GDP Constant Observations Number of countries 0.364** (0.158) 0.0159* (0.00861) -0.235 (3.495) 169 23 2.015 (3.518) 145 20 4.660 (3.859) 129 20 -0.255 (0.173) 0.200 (0.378) 0.0471 (4.103) 148 21 Robust standard errors in parentheses. Time fixed-effects included in all specifications. L.=lagged. Insignificant controls not shown in the table: L.on gold, L.polity score, L.trade/GDP, L.GDP percapita, L.foreign debt/total debt, L.%change in deficit w/r 1929, L.%change in reserve ratio, L.banking crisis, L.GDP change over 1929. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 Table 1 – Arellano-Bond GMM estimation of the determinants of default size, 1927-36 Columns one to three indicate that the total public debt-to-GDP ratio is negatively associated with default size, while the result disappears in column four where central and local public debt are entered separately in the equation. This surprising result might be attributed to reverse causality: more creditworthy countries were able to borrow more, leading to a negative correlation between the debt-to-GDP ratio and default size. By controlling for country fixed-effects, however, I rule out this possibility, at least if creditworthiness is timeinvarying (or slow moving). An alternative and more plausible explanation is that countries with higher debt-to-GDP ratios were those whose public sector relied more on borrowing. Countries with higher debt burdens would benefit more from default, but would also be more adversely affected by being excluded from financial markets. Column two adds a further layer to this interpretation: the economy-wide dependence on US-originating credit also led to a lower incidence of default, giving further support to the idea that credit dependence discouraged countries from damaging their access to financial markets through default. I also find that the share of short-term debt is positively related to default. This result fits well with economic intuition and the Great Depression context. Difficulties in rolling over short-term debts are considered a key driver of default (Erce, 2012). Liquidity dried up on international financial markets in 1930 after the 1924-28 surge, piling up pressure on debtor countries, which had borrowed short-term on a large scale (Feinstein and Watson 1995). Indeed, the first item to be tackled in the German debt crisis was the short-term debt, which was suspended through the 1931 Standstill Agreement (James, 1986; Ritschl, 2013). South American countries – the other big defaulters of the interwar era – also relied heavily on short-term debt (Jorgensen and Sachs 1988). A result that might be difficult to reconcile with economic intuition is the fact that, in columns one and two, countries that saw a smaller deterioration in their trade compared to 1929 were more likely to default. The result, however, is not robust and disappears with the inclusion of further controls in columns three and four. Finally, I show that, contrary to previous findings (Eichengreen and Portes, 1986) and consistently with Eichengreen's (1992) later argument that policy responses to the Great Depression were either misguided – in core countries – or extremely limited – in the periphery, neither monetary nor fiscal policy played a role in the defaults. Robustness The results presented above are robust to different measures of economic contraction, trade deterioration and the inclusion of higher order polynomials of the debt-to-GDP ratio to account for nonlinearities. In the working version of the paper, I also present the results of cross-sectional estimations similar to those used by Eichengreen and Portes (1986), as well as the Blundell-Bond (1995) GMM estimator and the dynamic Tobit random-effects model suggested by Wooldridge (2005). These models rely on additional assumptions, which are not likely to be satisfied in this application and should be taken with caution. In any case, each of the main results of the Arellano-Bond estimation is confirmed by at least one of the two models. Conclusion The new data presented not only provides a more historically accurate picture of public debt burdens in the interwar era, but also turn out be a decisive element in explaining the defaults. The differences between the results of this paper and those of previous work are stark. However, as Eichengreen and Portes (1986), I show that mono-causal interpretations of the 1930s debt crisis, which assign the key role to either `bad luck` or opportunism should be ruled-out. The interwar debt crisis was a complex event in which exogenous shocks and discretionary choices both mattered. References Abbas, A. S. M., N. Belhocine, A. A. El Ganainy, and M. A. Horton (2010): ‘A Historical Public Debt Database’, IMF Working Paper, 10-245. Accominotti, O. (2012): ‘London Merchant Banks, the Central European Panic, and the Sterling Crisis of 1931’, Journal of Economic History, 72(1), 1-43. Arellano, M., and S. Bond (1991): ‘Some Tests of Specification for Panel Data: Monte Carlo Evidence and an Application to Employment Equations’, Review of Economic Studies, 58(2), 277-97. Benston, G. J. (1990): The Separation of Commercial and Investment Banking: The GlassSteagall Act Revisited and Reconsidered - a retrospective of the Pecora Commission's conclusions. Oxford University Press. Blundell, R., and S. Bond (1995): ‘Initial Conditions and Moment Restrictions in Dynamic Panel Data Models’, Journal of Econometrics, 87(1), 115-43. Carosso, V. (1970): Investment Banking in America. Harvard University Press. Diaz-Alejandro, C. (1983): ‘Stories of the 1930s for the 1980s’, in Financial Policies and the World Capital Market, Pedro Aspe Armella, Rudiger Dornbusch, and Maurice Obstfeld (eds). University of Chicago Press. Eichengreen, B. (1992): Golden Fetters: The Gold Standard and the Great Depression, 1919-1939. Oxford University Press. Eichengreen, B., and R. Portes (1986): ‘Debt and Default in the 1930s: Causes and Consequences’, European Economic Review, 30(3), 599-640. (1988): ‘Foreign Lending in the Interwar Years: the Bondholders' Perspective’, University of California Berkeley, Department of Economics Working Paper, 8886. Erce, A. (2012): ‘Selective Sovereign Defaults’, Federal Reserve of Dallas Working Paper, 127. Feinstein, C. H., and K. Watson (1995): ‘Private International Capital Flows in Europe in the Interwar Period’, in Banking, Currency, and Finance in Europe between the Wars, Charles H. Feinstein (ed). Oxford University Press. Fishlow, A. (1986): ‘Lessons from the Past: Capital markets during the 19th Century and the Interwar Period’, in The Politics of International Debt, Miles Kahler (ed). Cornell University Press. Flandreau, M., N. Gaillard, and U. Panizza (2010): ‘Conflicts of Interest, Reputation, and the Interwar Debt Crisis: Banksters or Bad Luck’, CEPR Discussion Paper, 7705. Harris, C. R. S. (1935): Germany's Foreign Indebtedness. Oxford University Press. James, H. (1986): The German Slump: Politics and Economics. Clarendon Press. Jorgensen, E., and J. Sachs (1988): ‘Default and Renegotiation of Latin American Foreign Bonds in the Interwar Period’, NBER Working Papers, 2636. Lewis, C. (1938): America's Stake in International Investments. The Brookings Institution. Madden, J. T., M. Nadler, and H. C. Sullivan (1937): America's Experience as a Creditor Nation. Prentice-Hall. Moody's (1931-37): Investment Manual: Government and Foreign. Moody's Investors Service. Obstfeld, M., and A. M. Taylor (1998): ‘The Great Depression as a Watershed: International Capital Mobility over the Long Run’, in The Defining Moment: The Great Depression and the American Economy in the Twentieth Century, Micheal D. Bordo, Claudia Goldin and Eugene N. White (eds). University of Chicago Press. Reinhart, C. M., and K. S. Rogoff (2009): This Time is Different: Eight Centuries of Financial Folly. Princeton University Press. Reinhart, C. M., K. S. Rogoff, and M. A. Savastano (2003): ‘Debt Intolerance’, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1, 1-74. Ritschl, A. (2013): ‘Reparations, Deficits, and Debt Default: the Great Depression in Germany’, in The Great Depression of the 1930s, Nicholas Crafts and Peter Fearon (eds). Oxford University Press. Ritschl, A., and S. Sarferaz (2014): ‘Currency vs. Banking in the Financial Crisis of 1931’, International Economic Review, 55(2), 349-73. Statistisches Reichsamt (1936-39/40): Statistisches Jahrbuch für das Deutsche Reich. Puttkammer & Mühlbrecht. United Nations (1948): Public Debt 1914-1946. Lake Success, New York. Wooldridge, J. M. (2005): ‘Simple Solutions to the Initial Conditions Problem in Dynamic, Nonlinear Panel Data Models with Unobserved Heterogeneity’, Journal of Applied Econometrics, 20(1), 39-54.
© Copyright 2024