J. OF PUBLIC BUDGETING, ACCOUNTING & FINANCIAL MANAGEMENT, 9(3), 440-466 FALL 1997 PUBLIC INVESTMENT, PRODUCTIVITY, AND ECONOMIC GROWTH IN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES Mohsin S. Khan and Manmohan S. Kumar* ABSTRACT. This paper estimates a neoclassical model of growth in which investment is separated into its public and private components. Estimates are also obtained for the effects of public and private investment on total factor productivity. The paper then examines whether the speed of convergence in real per capita incomes across developing countries is influenced by the shares of the two types of investment. The results show that both public and private investment have different effects on economic growth and productivity -- a relatively high share of public investment is associated with a decrease in the speed of convergence. INTRODUCTION The role of public sector investment in determining private sector productivity and long-run economic growth has been the subject of a number of recent studies (Aschauer, 1989a, 1989b; Ford and Poret, 1991; Munnell, 1990; Rubin, 1991). This interest has been marked in industrial countries, particularly in the United States, where the productivity slowdown after the first oil-price shock in 1973-74 has been regarded as due, in part, to inadequate public investment in infrastructure (Munnell, 1990). In the case of developing countries, the respective roles of public and private investment in the growth process have come under increasing scrutiny. The conventional wisdom is that in these countries public investment in infrastructure and in human capital formation is likely to increase the productivity of private capital and have a beneficial _______________ * Mohsin S. Khan, Ph.D., and Manmohan S. Kumar, Ph.D., are in the International Monetary Fund. Dr. Khan's research interest is in macroeconomics of developing countries. Dr. Kumar's research interest is in finance in emerging capital markets. Copyright © 1997 by PrAcademics Press PUBLIC INVESTMENT IN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES 441 effect on growth. But, equally, public investment expenditures can crowd out private investment by using scarce resources and thus have an adverse effect on growth. At the empirical level, a number of studies on developing countries have concluded that public investment has a smaller impact on growth than does private investment (Coutinho and Gallo, 1991; Khan and Kumar, 1993; Serven and Solimano, 1990). Others maintain that this effect may even be negative (Khan and Reinhart, 1990). However, these studies have not looked specifically at the effects of the components of investment on total factor productivity. Also, to examine the relative effects of public and private investment, a number of other important issues related to differences in the two components of investment across developing country regions or across countries in different income groups need to be considered. From a policy perspective, if public investment does have a weaker impact on growth than private investment, it would highlight the need to rationalize public investment and the privatization of state-owned activities. From a theoretical perspective, if public and private investment have differential impacts on growth, there would be important implications for the determination of the steady-state growth path as well as for the convergence of real per capita incomes. (1) The empirical analysis in this paper covers a sample of 95 developing countries for the period 1970-90. The large sample allows for tests of the hypothesis that there are marked differences in the effects of the two components of investment on growth and productivity for four developing country regions--Africa, Asia, Europe and the Middle East, and Latin America. Such an examination is of considerable interest in view of the marked differences in the performance of developing countries during the last two decades. Asian countries, for instance, have in general had a significantly superior performance compared to African or Latin American countries (see Kumar, 1992; Ossa, 1990). To the extent that the steady-state conditions underlying the differential growth performance--reflecting, for example, the rate of technological change and population growth--are likely to be more similar across developing countries, looking specifically at these countries can yield additional insights into the process of convergence.(2) This article will first note the extent to which public and private investment may be complements or substitutes in developing countries, and describe the estimation equations used in the empirical analysis. Second, the 442 KHAN & KUMAR effect of public and private investment on growth as well as on total factor productivity will be empirically analyzed. Third, it will examine the implications of the results, in particular of the differential impact of public and private investment, for the speed of convergence to a steady state. Lastly, some concluding remarks will be made. THE ROLE OF PUBLIC INVESTMENT As indicated in Table 1, public sector investment in developing countries during the 1970s and 1980s accounted for nearly half of total investment (which was around 20% of GDP). This contrasts sharply with the situation in the industrial countries where, during the 1980s, public investment accounted for less than one-fifth of the total (of around 18% of GDP).(3) Of course, since the requirements in developing countries for infrastructure and related capital may have been greater than in the industrial countries, and given the indivisibilities entailed in the provision of such capital, the share of public investment in developing countries might be expected to be higher. But these data do raise the issue of the efficiency of public sector investment and its effect on output and productivity growth. It could be argued that public investment in infrastructure, by being complementary to private investment, could increase the marginal product of private capital. (4) This is most likely to be so in those developing countries where the existing stock of infrastructure capital is regarded as inadequate. Nevertheless, it has become evident over the last few years that public investment in infrastructure may not automatically have had a beneficial impact. In many cases, political-bureaucratic motivations led to excessive expenditures in infrastructure facilities. This occurred in part because the concern was with maximizing employment than with creating these facilities at low cost. Further, regional or other political considerations often resulted in the uneconomic location, size, or even sector of the investment projects. The above factors were reflected in several Latin American countries, for instance, where many of the public infrastructure investment projects in the late 1970s could not be justified on economic grounds. There were examples of this in the 1980s in Asia and Africa as well, particularly in the case of projects in the energy and transportation sectors (see, for instance, Krueger and Orsmond, 1990). PUBLIC INVESTMENT IN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES 443 444 KHAN & KUMAR A significant proportion of public sector investment in developing countries is also undertaken by state-owned enterprises. In most countries, industrial policy and the regulatory framework have linked private sector production directly to public sector activities both in goods and factor markets. For instance, an expansion of the capacity of public enterprises to produce industrial inputs--including production of basic metals, chemicals, and so on--is necessary before the private sector can undertake investments in sectors that are dependent on these basic inputs. On the other hand, given the pervasive role of public enterprises in many countries, capacity expansion by such enterprises can itself lead directly to an increase in private sector investment to provide additional inputs. (5) The above considerations suggest that while the public sector capital stock may be complementary to the private sector and have a positive effect on growth, its efficiency may be somewhat questionable. Moreover, in many developing countries public sector enterprises compete directly with the private sector in the provision of goods and services. In these cases, an increase in public investment could have an adverse effect on private investment both directly, as well as indirectly via the public sector budget constraint. In the case of the latter, financing public investment by increasing taxes, for instance, could further exacerbate distortions in the economy and increase the costs of inputs, leading to an adverse effect on future output growth and private investment. If financed by market borrowing, public investment could have an adverse effect on both the cost and availability of credit to the private sector. In order to evaluate the differential impact of private and public sector investment on growth, the empirical analysis undertaken in this paper utilizes a variant of the neoclassical growth model. In this well-known model, capital accumulation, growth of labor force, and technical change are the key determinants of real per capita income. The formal specification of the model is as: where Y and L denote real output and labor respectively, á refers to the share of aggregate capital in income, S is the aggregate saving (and investment) rate, PUBLIC INVESTMENT IN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES 445 n and ã are respectively the exogenously given growth rate of labor and technology, ä denotes the rate of depreciation of the capital stock, and å is an error term. (6) The above model was extended by introducing separately public and private capital stock. Assuming that both types of capital stock depreciate at the same rate ä, real output per capita can be specified as follows: where, in addition to the above variables, Sg and Sp now denote public and private investment respectively, and á and â denote the shares of public and private capital in income, respectively. The specification of equations 1 and 2 assumes that all countries are at their steady states. However, it is possible to extend equation 2 in a more general way to assess the effects of various explanatory variables on per capita growth, rather than on the level of income per capita. Following Mankiw, Romer and Weil (1992), equation 2 can be transformed into an equation for the steady- state growth path as follows: where the left-hand side of the equation is now the growth of per capita income, ë = [(n+ã+ä)(1-á-â)] is the speed of convergence, y(0) is income per effective worker at some initial date, and the other variables are defined as before.(7) Equation 3 forms the basis for the empirical analysis of the effect of public and private investment on per capita growth in this paper. However, in view of the recent literature on growth, human capital--which has received considerable emphasis in explaining cross-country differences in long-run growth--was also incorporated as an explanatory variable.(8) Secondly, macroeconomic instability, which has also been shown to adversely affect 446 KHAN & KUMAR long-run growth, was taken into account in assessing the effect of the different forms of investment. (9) This was done by introducing the average value of budgetary deficits--one of the main indicators of macroeconomic instability--as an additional explanatory variable. It should also be noted that since high budgetary deficits are often associated with high public investment, by excluding them from the empirical estimation, one may obtain biased results of the effect of public investment on growth. EMPIRICAL RESULTS Equations 1 and 2 for the level of per capita real income are two of the main estimating equations. The former equation provides a "reference" by which the significance of the estimates obtained from equation 2 of the impact of private and public sector investment can be assessed. Estimates were also obtained for several variants of equation 3, which describes the behavior of per capita growth of real income. Determinants of Per Capita Real GDP The main estimates of equations 1 and 2 are given in Table 2. These results show the role of aggregate investment as well as of public and private investment, population growth, and technological change during the last two decades, in explaining the cross-country differences in the levels of per capita real GDP in 1990. As noted earlier, while this framework assumes that countries were in their respective steady states in 1990, still the estimates do provide a useful starting point for an assessment of both the relevance of the neoclassical model for developing countries, and the relative importance of public and private sector investment. (10) The first two columns in Table 2 correspond to equation 1, while columns 3 and 4 correspond to equation 2. Consider first the former set of results, which provide estimates of the basic neoclassical model with aggregate investment. Column 1 shows that two basic variables—the investment ratio and population growth--account for over 40 percent of the variation in real per capita GDP in 1990 across the full sample of developing countries. (11) The coefficients of the investment ratio as well as of population growth have the expected signs and are highly significant. The extent to which the importance of capital investment differs across the four developing country regions of Africa, Asia, Latin America (including Caribbean countries), and Europe and the Middle East is examined by PUBLIC INVESTMENT IN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES 447 TABLE 2 Determinants of Real Income Per Capita(1) ____________________________________________________________ (1) (2) (3) (4) ------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------Constant 3.20 -0.32 -2.63 0.41 (1.40) (1.29) (1.35) (1.19) Investment (total) 1.40(a) (0.20) Investment (public) 0.39(a) (0.13) Investment (private) 0.86(a) (0.11) Population and -2.49(a) -1.44(a) -2.80(a) -1.63(a) technical change (0.52) (0.47) (0.50) (0.44) Investment dummies Africa (Total) (Public) (Private) 1.21(a) 0.41(a) 0.67(a) (0.18) (0.16) (0.12) Asia 1.35(a) 0.20 1.00(a) (0.18) (0.23) (0.20) Latin America 1.48(a) 0.20 1.17(a) (0.18) (0.18) (0.16) Middle East 1.46(a) 0.85(a) 0.54(a) (0.17) (0.17) (0.21) R -2 0.45 0.62 0.50 0.67 S.E.E. (0.60) (0.51) (0.59) (0.47) ___________________________________________________________ (1) For detailed description of the data see the Appendix. Standard errors are given in brackets; (a) denotes statistically significant at the 5 percent level. including slope dummies for total investment for each of the regions. (12) The results in Column 2, which allow for slope differences, indicate a considerable improvement in the overall fit of the equation, which now explains over 60 percent of the variation in the 1990 per capita real income. While each of 448 KHAN & KUMAR the slope dummy variables is statistically significant, the coefficients across regions show large variation. For instance, for Africa, the coefficient of investment is around 1.20, whereas for the Middle East and Latin America it is around 1.45, suggesting a marked difference both in the efficiency of investment, and in the share of capital in total income. The differential effect of public and private sector investment is examined in columns 3 and 4 of Table 2. The first of these columns shows that there is a very large difference between public and private investment in explaining the cross-country levels of per capita real GDP. Specifically, the coefficient on private investment is twice as large as that on public investment, and highly significant, whereas public sector investment has a more limited impact. Thus, the hypothesis that public and private sector investment have a similar impact is decisively rejected. The differential impact of the two components of investment across the four developing country regions is examined in column 4 by introducing slope dummies for each of the regions for both public and private sector investment. The equation now explains nearly two-thirds of the crosscountry variation in per capita real GDP. The impact of private sector investment is statistically significant for all regions, although it differs widely across them, with the largest impact in Asian and Latin American countries. On the other hand, in all regions, except Europe and the Middle East, public sector investment has a markedly smaller impact; the coefficient in fact is not significantly different from zero for Asian and Latin American countries. Determinants of Per Capita Real Growth A more realistic framework is to consider the transition to the steady state and the roles played by public and private sector investment. This is undertaken by estimating equation 3, which allows for an investigation of the convergence issue. The dependent variable now is the growth of per capita real GDP in developing countries. The basic results obtained by estimating equation 3, with aggregate investment as the main explanatory variable for the period 1970-90 and the two sub-periods--1970-80 and 1980-90--are provided in Table 3. Column 1 shows that nearly a third of the cross-country variation in per capita GDP growth over the 20-year period is explained by the aggregate investment ratio, initial per capita real income, and population growth, and all the variables have the expected signs and are statistically significant. The first variable of PUBLIC INVESTMENT IN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES 449 key interest is the initial income variable, which yields a rate of convergence of 0.01. This last result implies that once the cross-country variation in the investment and population growth variables is taken into account, the poorer developing countries (measured by their per capita income in 1970) narrowed the gap between them and the richer countries at a rate of one percent a year.(13) This is a somewhat higher rate than that obtained in existing studies which are based on a combined sample of developing and industrial countries. (14) The second variable of special interest is the investment ratio. The coefficient of this variable suggests that a one percentage point increase in the investment ratio across developing countries is associated with an increase in per capita GDP of three-quarters of a percentage point. This is again somewhat larger than the value reported in the earlier studies. Next, consider the separate roles played by public and private sector investment in determining per capita growth. As indicated in column 4 of Table 3, for the period 1970 to 1990, while both types of investment had a positive impact, their magnitude differed considerably, with private investment having a much stronger impact than public sector investment. However, there are marked differences between the two sub-periods. For instance, during the 1970s, both public and private investment had a similar effect and it was only during the 1980s that the greater impact of private sector investment emerged. It could be argued that in the earlier period the stock of infrastructural capital was lower in most developing countries, and thus the returns from such investment were higher. This would suggest greater complementarity between private and public investment than may have been the case during the last decade.(15) Finally, consider two additional sets of variables, which the earlier discussion noted could be expected to have an impact in explaining the crosscountry differences in per capita GDP growth. The first is the stock of human capital, which is measured by the proportion of population with school enrollment at the secondary school level, at the beginning of the period.(16) The second variable is the government's budgetary balance. As Column 7 in Table 3 shows, for the period 1970-90, both variables have a positive and statistically significant coefficient suggesting that the higher the school enrollment or fiscal balance (that is, the lower the fiscal deficit), other things equal, the higher the subsequent growth in per capita real income. 450 KHAN & KUMAR PUBLIC INVESTMENT IN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES 451 Two-Stage Least Squares Estimates and Panel Data There are two types of extension that can be made to the above analysis. The first is econometric and arises from the fact that since the estimation procedure does not take into account the correlation between the right-handside variables, such as private investment and the error term, the estimates could be biased and inconsistent. The reason for using OLS is that, as Madalla (1977), and Chow (1983) have emphasized, other techniques are much more sensitive to model mispecification; in that sense OLS is robust. Nevertheless, in order to examine whether using alternative estimation procedures alters the results in any marked manner, estimates using TwoStage Least Squares (TSLS) were also obtained. A second extension concerns the use of cross-sectional data. It could be argued that the use of these data means that information on the dynamics of the growth process is not taken into account. It should be noted, however, that the main issues examined in the paper are more appropriately examined in a cross-sectional context; for instance, the issue of convergence of per-capita incomes across countries is by definition concerned with differences in the long-run growth rates across countries. Nevertheless, the relationship between public and private investment and growth was examined using pooled time-series cross-section data to assess the robustness of the results reported above.(17) The results from using TSLS, which are shown in Table 4, suggest conclusions that are broadly similar to those obtained using the OLS. There is clear evidence of convergence, but the speed of convergence is lower. Private investment has a decidedly higher impact on growth compared to public investment, and the human capital variable has a positive coefficient that is not statistically significant. With regard to the use of panel data, there are two additional issues that should be noted. The first is the period over which the time series data are averaged--since the use of annual data would be clearly inappropriate for analyzing the growth process and in any case would exhibit excessive noise. The procedure adopted was to average growth over a period ranging from 3 to 5 years. (18) This is a more general procedure than that used in the literature where growth has been arbitrarily averaged over five-year periods. The second issue concerns the use of specific model estimation procedures for panel data: the results presented use OLS on full sample.(19) 452 KHAN & KUMAR Since the panel procedures assume common slope coefficients for all observations, they are rather restrictive. Nevertheless, even with this restriction, the results presented for the three- and five-year horizons reinforce the earlier findings using cross-sectional data (Table 4, columns 3 to 6). A number of additional interesting results also emerge. For instance, given the shorter time horizon, there is now virtually no relationship between initial GDP and subsequent growth. The human capital variable, while positive, still has a statistically insignificant effect. The result that stands out is the relatively similar effect of private and public investment have on growth in Asia, and the Europe and Middle East region. In these regions it would appear that in the short run public investment can provide a boost to growth, much as does private investment, but this effect is not sustained over time. Effects on Productivity As noted earlier, the two main channels through which public investment may affect growth is by influencing factor accumulation and by promoting or hindering the efficiency of resource use. While there has been considerable discussion of how public investment may affect private investment in developing countries, its effect on the efficiency of resource use has been analyzed much less. If public investment in infrastructure is complementary to private investment, one would expect to see a positive relationship between economy-wide efficiency and the share of public investment in total investment. If, however, public investment resources are misallocated or are utilized suboptimally, they may have only a limited, or even a negative, effect on efficiency. A commonly used proxy for efficiency of resource use is total factor productivity (TFP), obtained residually as that part of output growth not accounted for by changes in capital and labor (that is, the “Solow residuals”). As shown by the International Monetary Fund (1993), growth in TFP has accounted for over a quarter of overall growth in developing countries over the last two decades, and over a third of the growth in the fastest-growing developing countries. Despite the importance of this factor, there has been limited analysis of the determinants of long-run TFP in developing countries generally, and more specifically the relationship between economy-wide efficiency and the share of public investment in the total. The studies that have tried to address this issue have found a negative relationship between total government expenditures (consumption plus investment) and proxies for efficiency, such as incremental capital-output ratios (Gallagher, 1991; King and Levine, 1992; Odedokun, 1992),(20) but they have not looked at the efficiency effects of public investment. PUBLIC INVESTMENT IN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES 453 TABLE 4 Public and Private Investment: TSLS and Panel Data Results(1) ___________________________________________________________ Two-stage least squares Panel data 3 years 5 years (1) (2) (3) (4) ------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------Constant -9.08(a) -8.01(a) -0.38(a) -0.53(a) (2.62) (0.61) (0.14) (0.20) Initial per per capita GDP 0.13 (0.13) -0.16 (0.12) -0.003 (0.01) -0.001 (0.10) Population and Technical change -3.21(a) (0.89) -2.10(a) (0.10) -0.11(a) (0.04) -0.15(a) (0.07) Human capital(2) 0.02 (0.01) 0.003 (0.01) 0.001 (0.01) Trade orientation 0.32 (0.36) Foreign direct investment 0.03 (0.05) 0.01 (0.02) 0.54(a) (0.18) 0.05(a) (0.01) 0.06(a) (0.01) 0.19(b) (0.12) 0.02(a) (0.01) 0.02(b) (0.01) Asia 0.13 (0.20) 0.05(a) (0.01) 0.06(a) (0.02) Latin America 0.08 (0.14) 0.01 (0.01) 0.01 (0.01) 0.12 (0.19) 0.04(a) (0.01) 0.04(a) (0.01) 0.37 0.12 0.12 Private investment 0.57(a) (0.28) Public investment 0.36(a) (0.13) Dummies: Africa Middle East and Europe R2 0.25 0.02 (0.04) S.E.E. (0.27) (0.33) (0.13) (0.16) ________________________________________________________________ (1)The Panel data results, in Columns 3 and 4 use data averaged over 3 years (6 observations per country) and 5 years (4 observations per country). (a) and (b) denote statistically significant at the 5 and 10 percent level. (2) Secondary school enrollment ratio . 454 KHAN & KUMAR The relationship between TFP and the share of public and private investment was investigated here in the context of an estimating equation which takes into account other determinants of TFP. A number of studies have examined the impact of macroeconomic variables on productivity growth and found that the inflation rate, budget deficit, terms of trade, and the degree of outward orientation of the economy appear to have some weak influence on the overall rate of productivity growth (see Fischer, 1993; King and Levine, 1992).(21) In view of these findings, the following equation was estimated: where TFP denotes average total factor productivity in any given country, and Ð, TOT, X, and D denote inflation, terms of trade, degree of trade orientation and debt to GDP ratios respectively; Sg and Sp as before denote the shares of public and private investment. The results of estimating this equation for the entire period 1970-1990, as well as for the two sub-periods 1970-1980 and 1980-1990, are presented in Table 5.(22) As indicated in column 1 of Table 5, for the period 1970 to 1990, while both public and private investment had a positive effect on productivity, their magnitude differed markedly, with private investment having a much stronger, and statistically significant, effect. The addition of other explanatory variables, while improving the goodness-of-fit of the equation, does not change this result markedly (column 3). As indicated in columns 5 and 7, a similar result holds over the two sub-periods. However, it is noticeable that in the second period, the difference between the effects of the two types of investment is less marked although again it is only the effect of private investment that is statistically significant. IMPLICATIONS FOR THE SPEED OF CONVERGENCE This section looks at the implications of the above empirical findings for the speed of convergence among developing countries. Since private investment appears to have had a considerably larger impact on per capita growth than public investment, the steady-state growth rate of an economy would increase in proportion to the share of private investment. However, this result says very little about the speed with which the steady-state path is PUBLIC INVESTMENT IN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES 455 attained, or the speed of convergence among countries. For instance, even if the steady-state growth is significantly higher because of private investment, the speed of transition towards this steady state, or the rate of convergence, may remain unaffected. From the policymaker's perspective, whether or not the speed can be affected by policy changes may perhaps be as important as the effect of policy changes on the growth path itself. This is so since the transition to an optimal growth path, in the framework utilized above, is likely to last a considerable length of time, and any measures that can speed up that process would be regarded as highly desirable. Hence, in the literature on the determinants of long-run growth and convergence, while the emphasis has been mainly on factors determining the steady-state growth path, the issue of the speed of transition has also received significant attention (see, for example, Barro, 1991; Barro and Sala-i-Martin, 1992; Lucas, 1988; Mankiw, Romer and Weil, 1992; Romer, 1989). The methodology for examining this issue is to introduce an additional regressor in equation 3, which is an interactive term consisting of the product of the log of initial income and public investment ratio. The specific form of this equation is as: As suggested by equation 5 above, if the coefficient on this interactive term, plus the coefficient on the initial income term, is smaller than that on the initial income term alone (without the additional regressor), it would mean that countries with more public investment have a higher speed of convergence.(23) If the combined coefficient is unchanged, it would mean that the share of public investment does not affect the speed of convergence. If, however, it is larger, then public investment slows down the rate of convergence. This procedure is then repeated with private investment and a comparison is made of the speed of convergence. 456 KHAN & KUMAR PUBLIC INVESTMENT IN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES 457 The results of estimating equation (5) are given in Table 6. Column (1) of this table indicates that without separating the impact of public and private investment, the implied rate of convergence among the developing countries was 0.013. However, as column 2 indicates, when the interactive term is TABLE 6 Public and Private Investment and Speed of Convergence(1) ___________________________________________________________ (1) (2) (3) -----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------Constant -2.59(a) -3.34(a) -2.31(a) (0.89) (0.84) (0.85) Initial per Capita GDP -0.23(a) (0.07) -0.18(a) (0.07) -0.31(a) (0.07) Investment ratio (total) 0.76(a) (0.12) 1.01(a) (0.16) 0.61(a) (0.14) -0.03(a) Initial GDP and Public Investment (0.01) 0.03(a) Initial GDP and Private Investment (0.01) Population and technical Change -0.79(a) (0.32) -0.89(a) (0.31) -0.92(a) (0.32) Human Capital 0.18(b) (0.10) 0.17(b) (0.09) 0.18 (0.11) Implied rate of Convergence 0.013 0.01 0.017 R2 0.35 0.39 0.39 S.E.E. (0.33) (0.41) (0.41) ___________________________________________________________ (1) The dependent variables is per capita GDP growth during 1970-90. For other notes see Table 2. 458 KHAN & KUMAR introduced, although the coefficient on this term is negative, the combined effect (in terms of the coefficient on the initial income) is now smaller. This yields a speed of convergence that is somewhat slower than the speed of convergence without the interactive term. However, as column 3 shows when a similar procedure is undertaken with private investment, although the coefficient on private investment is positive, the net effect is greater. Thus an increase in private investment increases the speed of convergence by around a third compared to an increase in public investment. CONCLUDING REMARKS This paper has attempted to assess empirically the role of public and private investment in explaining differences across developing countries in the level of per capita real GDP, in real GDP growth, and in total factor productivity. In the context of a neoclassical framework, the empirical analysis provides clear evidence that during the last two decades, public sector investment had a markedly smaller role in explaining cross-sectional differences in growth and productivity than private investment. Although there are significant regional differences in the impact of the two types of investment, the broad results are robust to the use of panel, rather than crosssection, data and alternative estimation techniques. Moreover, the empirical evidence not only suggests that the steady-state growth rate of an economy may have increased in proportion to the share of private investment in the total, but also that the speed with which the steady-state path was attained may have been faster. The above results suggest that there is a need to enhance the productivity of public sector investment by identifying the types of investment that are likely to have positive net returns. At the same time, measures should be undertaken to remove impediments to private sector investment. This has been done since the early 1990s by many developing countries that have undertaken macroeconomic stabilization, as well as structural reforms in the financial, labor, fiscal and trade sectors. A continuation of these reforms would further reduce distortions, have positive incentive effects, and stimulate PUBLIC INVESTMENT IN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES 459 private investment. This would in turn lead to faster economic growth and increased economy-wide efficiency. NOTES 1. In the recent literature on convergence of real per capita incomes across countries, only the role of aggregate investment has been emphasized. No attempt has been made to examine the respective roles of public and private investment. See, for instance, Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1992); Mankiw, Romer, and Weil (1992). 2. Existing studies have combined developing and industrial countries, and thus their results are applicable to both groups; see Barro (1991) and Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1992). 3. This is based on an unweighted average for the OECD countries, excluding Turkey. 4. See Blejer and Khan (1984). For industrial countries, Aschauer (1989a, 1989b) finds that investment in infrastructure has had a very strong positive effect on private sector productivity. However, these findings remain controversial largely because the marginal productivity of infrastructure implied by his estimates is considered implausibly high [see, for example, Ford and Poret (1991), and Rubin (1991)]. 5. See, for instance, Chibber and van Wijnbergen (1988), who show that in Turkey in the 1980s, despite high real cost of capital, private investment boomed because of public enterprise investment. 6. This equation can be derived from a Cobb-Douglas production function. For details, see Khan and Kumar (1993). 7. For the derivation of equation (3) and the discussion of issues related to the speed of convergence, see Khan and Kumar (1993). 8. For a discussion of the importance of human capital in the growth process, see Barro (1991), Levine and Renelt (1992), and Lucas (1988). 9. For an analysis of the relationship between macroeconomic instability and growth, see Fischer (1993), and Frenkel and Khan (1990). 10. The sample of countries and the data are described in the Appendix. PUBLIC 460 INVESTMENT IN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES 460 KHAN & KUMAR 11. Standard errors based on White's (1980) heteroscedasticity-consistent covariance matrix differed little from those obtained by OLS and reported here. 12. The slope dummies take the value of the investment ratio for countries in the given region and zero otherwise. 13. See Barro (1991) for the relationship between the rate of convergence, and the speed with which the gap between rich and poor countries is narrowed. 14. See, for example, Mankiw, Romer, and Weil (1992). 15. An analysis of the regional differences in the impact of public and private investment on growth yielded results that were similar to the ones obtained above concerning determinants of per capita GDP. For details, see Khan and Kumar (1993). 16. This is similar to the proxy used by Barro (1991). 17. See Knight, Loayza, and Villanueva (1993) for a detailed discussion of estimates of the basic Solow model using panel data. 18. When the average is for 3 years, there are 6 observations per country, giving a pooled sample for the 95 countries of 570 observations. With a 5-year average, there are 4 observations per country giving a sample of 380 observations. 19. See Cheng (1986) for a discussion of the different procedures that could be used to estimate the model. 20. The study by Gallagher only examined the African countries, while the other two studies have examined a wider range of countries over the last two decades. 21. Fischer (1993) finds that it is only in the case of pooled time series crosssection data, rather than in the cross-section regressions, that the effect of inflation and budget deficit on productivity growth is significant, concluding that the significant results mainly reflect the time-series variation between these regressors and productivity growth. 22. The estimates of productivity residuals were obtained for each of the 95 countries in the sample for each year between 1970 and 1990, using estimates of total capital stock obtained by applying the perpetual inventory method, and labor force. The Solow residuals were computed using a common Cobb-Douglas production function (see Appendix for details). PUBLIC INVESTMENT IN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES 461 23. From equation (5) it can be seen that the partial effect of initial income on growth is given by two components: first, the coefficient on the initial income variable by itself; and secondly, the coefficient on the initial income variable times the share of public investment. REFERENCES Ahmad, S. A. (1992), "Regression Estimates of Per Capita GDP Based on Purchasing Power Parities," (unpublished paper), Washington, DC: World Bank, International Economics Department. Aschauer, D. A. (1989a), "Does Public Capital Crowd Out Private Capital," Journal of Monetary Economics, 24: 171-188. Aschauer, D. A. (1989b, September/October), "Public Investment and Productivity Growth in the Group of Seven," Economic Perspectives: A Review from the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, 13: 13-25. Barro, R. J. (1991), "Economic Growth in a Cross-Section of Countries," Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106: 407-443. Barro, R. J. and Sala-i-Martin, X. (1992), "Convergence," Journal of Political Economy, 100: 223-251. Blejer, M. I. and Khan, M. S. (1984, June), "Government Policy and Private Investment in Developing Countries," IMF Staff Papers, Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund. Cheng, H. (1986), Analysis of Panel Data, Oxford: Cambridge University Press. Chibber, A. and van Wijnbergen, S. (1988, October), "Public Policy and Private Investment in Turkey," World Bank PPR Working Paper, Washington, DC: World Bank. Chow, G. C.(1983), Econometrics, New York: McGraw-Hill. Coutinho, R. And Gallo, G. (1991), “Do Public and Private Investment Stand in Each Other’s Way,” (unpublished paper), Washington, DC: World Bank. Fischer, S. (1993), "The Role of Macroeconomic Factors in Growth," Journal of Monetary Economics, 32: 485-512. 462 KHAN & KUMAR Ford, R. and Poret, P. (1991, Autumn), "Infrastructure and Private-Sector Productivity," OECD Economic Studies, 17: 63-89. Frenkel, J. A. and Khan, M. S. (1990, August), "Adjustment Policies and Economic Development," American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 72: 815-820. Gallagher, M. (1991), Rent-Seeking and Economic Growth, Boulder, CO: Westview Press. International Monetary Fund (1993, May), "Convergence and Divergence in Developing Countries," World Economic Outlook, Washington, DC. Khan, M. S. and Reinhart, C. M. (1990, Jannuary), "Private Investment and Economic Growth in Developing Countries," World Develop-ment, 18: 19-27. Khan, M. S. and Kumar, M. S. (1993, June), "Public and Private Investment and the Convergence of Per Capita Incomes in Developing Countries," IMF Working Paper (No. 93/51) Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund. King, R. G. and Levine, R. (1992), "Financial Indicators and Growth in a Cross-Section of Countries," PPR Working Paper Series (WPS 819), Washington, DC: World Bank. Knight, M., Loayza, N. and Villanueva, D. (1993, March), "Testing Theories of Economic Growth: A Panel Data Approach," IMF Staff Papers, Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund. Krueger, A. and Orsmond, D. (1990, November), "Impact of Government on Growth and Trade," (Unpublished Paper) Durham: NC: Duke University. Kumar, M. S. (1992, May), "Fiscal Adjustment in Developing Countries," Annex V, World Economic Outlook, World Economic and Financial Surveys, Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund, pp. 72-77. Levine, R. and Renelt, D. (1992, September) "A Sensitivity Analysis of Cross-Country Growth Regressions," American Economic Review, 82: 942-63. Lucas, R. E., Jr. (1988, July), "On the Mechanics of Economic Development," Journal of Monetary Economics, 22: 3-42. PUBLIC INVESTMENT IN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES 463 Mankiw, N. A., Romer, D. and Weil, D. N. (1992, May), "A Contri-bution to the Empirics of Economic Growth," Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107: 407-437. Madalla, A. S., (1977), Econometrics, New York: McGraw-Hill. Munnell, A. (Ed.), (1990, June), Is There a Shortfall in Public Capital Investment? (Conference Series No. 34): Boston: Federal Reserve Bank of Boston. Odedokun, M. O., (1992, May), "Multi-country Evidence on the Effects of Macroeconomic, Financial and Trade Policies on Efficiency of Resource Utilization in Developing Countries," IMF Working Paper (WP/92/53), Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund. Ossa, C. (1990, June), "The Diversity of Growth Rates Among Developing Countries," Development Policy Review, 8: 115-129. Romer, P. M., (1989), "Capital Accumulation in the Theory of Long-run Growth" in R. Barro (Ed.), Modern Business Cycle Theory, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Rubin, L. S., (1991), "Productivity and the Public Capital Stock: Another Look," Working Paper No. 118, Washington, DC: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Rui, C. and Gallo, G. (1991, October), "Do Public and Private Investment Stand in Each Other's Way," WDR Background Paper, Washington, DC: World Bank. Solow, R. (1956, February), "A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth," Quarterly Journal of Economics, LXX: 65-94. Serven, L. and Solimano, A. (1990) "Private Investment and Macroeconomic Adjustment: Theory, Country Experience, and Policy Implications," (Unpublished Paper), Washington, DC: World Bank, Macroeconomic Adjustment and Growth Division. Summers, R. and Heston, A. W. (1988, March), "A New Set of International Comparisons of Real Product and Price Levels: Estimates for 130 countries 1950-1985," Review of Income and Wealth, 34: 1-25. Summers, R. and Heston, A. W. (1991), "The Penn World Tables (Mark V): An Expanded Set of International Comparisons, 1950-88," Quarterly Journal of Economics, XLVIII: 327-68. 464 KHAN & KUMAR White, H. L., (1980, May), "A Heteroscedasticity-Consistent Covariance Matrix Estimator and a Direct Test for Heteroscedasticity," Econometrica, XLVIII: 817-35. APPENDIX Sample and Data Definitions 1. Sample of developing countries The sample consists of 95 developing countries divided into the following four geographical regions: a. Africa: Algeria, Benin, Botswana, Burkina Faso, Burundi, Cameroon, Cape Verde, Central African Republic, Chad, Comoros, Congo, Cote d'Ivoire, Djibouti, Equatorial Guinea, Ethiopia, Gabon, Gambia, Ghana, Guinea, Guinea-Bissau, Kenya, Lesotho, Liberia, Madagascar, Malawi, Mali, Mauritius, Mauritania, Morocco, Niger, Nigeria, Rwanda, Sao Tome and Principe, Senegal, Seychelles, Sierra Leone, Somalia, Sudan, Swaziland, Tanzania, Togo, Tunisia, Uganda, Zaire, Zambia, and Zimbabwe. b. Asia: Bangladesh, China, Fiji, India, Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia, Myanmar, Nepal, Pakistan, Papua New Guinea, Philippines, Sri Lanka, and Thailand. c. Latin America: Argentina, Barbados, Bolivia, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Costa Rica, Dominican Republic, Ecuador, El Salvador, Guatemala, Guyana, Haiti, Honduras, Jamaica, Mexico, Nicaragua, Panama, Paraguay, Peru, Surinam, Trinidad and Tobago, and Venezuela. d. Europe and Middle East: Cyprus, Egypt, Hungary, Jordan, Malta, Oman, Poland, Syria, Turkey, Yemen, and Yugoslavia. 2. Data Definitions and Sources y: n: I: Ig : real GDP per capita (in 1985 international prices); population growth; ratio of total fixed investment to GDP; ratio of public sector fixed investment to GDP (public sector includes general government, nonfinancial state enterprises, and principal autonomous agencies); Ip : ratio of private sector fixed investment to GDP; Hs : gross enrollment ratio at secondary level; and PUBLIC INVESTMENT IN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES 465 GBG : public sector balances as a percent of GDP. For Tables 2 and 3, all ratios and growth rates are averages for the period 1970-80, 1980-90, and 1970-90; Hs is for the beginning of each period. In Table 4, the ratios are averages for 3 and 5 years, and H s is again for the beginning of each period. Data on y were obtained largely from Summers and Heston ((1988) and (1991)) for the period up to 1985 and were extended to 1990 using per capita growth rates from the IMF's World Economic Outlook (WEO) database; for some low-income countries data were obtained from Ahmad (1992). Data on n were obtained from the WEO database. Data on I, Ig, Ip, Kg and Kp were obtained from the World Bank, supplemented by data from the International Finance Corporation database on private investment and from the WEO database. Data for H s for the period up to 1980 are from the UNESCO publication "Trends and Projections of Enrollment by Level of Education and by Age" (March 1983), and from UNESCO Statistical Yearbooks thereafter. Estimates of public and private capital stock were obtained using the perpetual inventory method, data on public and private gross investment, and estimates of initial capital stocks in 1960. The depreciation rate for the two types of capital stock was assumed to be similar and varied between 4% and 5% per annum. Estimates for total factor productivity were obtained as Solow residual using aggregate capital stock (public plus private) and labor force. Calculation of the Solow residuals imposes a common Cobb-Douglas production function across all developing countries in which the share of capital is higher (0.4) than in the industrialized countries (see, IMF, 1993; Fischer, 1993). An experimentation with the share of capital ranging from 0.35 to 0.45 yielded results that were very similar to those reported in the text.
© Copyright 2024