Bank regulation, exchange rate policy, overseas debt, and asset sales: how to untangle them? Geoff Bertram 31 March 2011 Preliminary • In the real world, market imperfections are pervasive. The history of economics is largely about analysing the nature of those imperfections and what can be done about them • The ‘market efficiency’ paradigm works from the presumption that for practical purposes real-world markets cannot be improved upon • The ‘mixed-economy’ paradigm starts from the presumption that markets won’t do everything, and even can be improved, and that some things should not be left to the market mechanism to solve but require collective choice, exercised through politics • Market failures quickly become bound up with issues of power: perfect markets would be democratic in the sense of dispersing power (not of solving distributional questions), but imperfect markets are all about the exercise of power by some at the expense of others • Even perfect markets leave open the question of the ideal distribution of wealth and income. A fundamental theoretical conclusion of twentieth-century neoclassical economic theory was that disagreements over distribution could not be resolved by apriori reasoning Thinking about New Zealand macroeconomics • Firstly, if indeed there are fundamental imbalances in the economy as a whole, it is important to understand how those imbalances have emerged from the interplay of market forces with policy and social structure, and to think about how policy can key variables with a long-run perspective • Secondly, in thinking about changes that might be made to policy settings, it is important to explicitly sort out – what mechanisms you think are at work – how particular policy changes would be supposed to deliver desired results – whether there is evidence for the causal mechanisms being appealed to • Thirdly, humility is a virtue in an economist. Three cautionary notes: – It’s seductively easy to overstate the scale and imminence of macroeconomic threats and then engage in “shock doctrine” arguments for instant radical changes. That’s where Think Big, Rogernomics, and the current renewed war on the welfare state came from. The essence of the approach is to underplay the resilience and sustainability of the market economy – Policies do have long-run effects on the shape of the economy and the distribution of wealth and income. Once set, those effects are not easy to reverse –institutional incentives and constraints in a market system are like the forms for concrete (the liquid settles to equilibrium in the liquid short run, then sets hard in the long run) – so there are real long-run costs and benefits from today’s policies – I have been one of those worried abut sustainability issues in New Zealand in the era of inflation targeting and floating exchange rate, and I have been pleasantly surprised by the absence of a macroeconomic ‘sudden stop’ since 1990. New Zealand did have two sudden stops in the preceding decades – one in the mid 1970s and one triggered by Rogernomics in the 1980s – but the deregulated economy has performed better than I expected. Migration has helped a lot, and the bank-facilitated inflow of capital funds has staved off the transfer problem that I thought possible early last decade. Those sudden stops did hurt both absolutely and relatively Eight Settler Economies' Per Capita GDP, 5-year moving averages, 1900-2000 Muldoon and oil shocks Rogernomics 25,000 Argentina 20,000 Chile Uruguay Australia 15,000 New Zealand South Africa 10,000 Canada USA 5,000 2000 1990 1980 1970 1960 1950 1940 1930 1920 1910 0 1900 1990 Purchasing-Power-Parity US$ 30,000 What are the ‘imbalances’ and why have they developed? • The current account deficit on the balance of payments, which is bound up with (i) the evolution of relative prices and the allocation of resources between tradables and nontradables; and (ii) the degree of capital inflow into the economy • The ability of deregulated ‘sheltered sectors’ to exercise market power while ‘exposed sectors’ are unable to do so, which drives part of the relative-price story (capital inflow drives another part) • The external debt, which flows from the current account deficit but itself plays a role in driving the deficit, via the exchange rate and domestic relative prices • The emergence and persistence of a financial sector rife with perverse incentives (i) for New Zealand households and firms to consume and borrow without facing the external costs of their decisions; and (ii) for the banks to drive credit expansion on a basis that looks dodgy (potentially ‘unsustainable’) in the longer run • The persistent drive by wealthy private interests to appropriate gains, socialise losses, and lessen the taxes they face – and the continual weakness of government policy and regulation in the face of the lobbying pressures these groups command • The worsening distribution of income and wealth, both wages/profits, and poor/rich (closely linked to the political success of neoliberal thinking: A couple of toy models from old textbooks • Useful for organising one’s thinking about a small open economy, used to be taught as central parts of the macroeconomics syllabus, and capture important elements in how New Zealand economists of the 1960s and 1970s used to think about macro • First, the macroeconomic identity that the market economy delivers ex post in each period • Second a loanable-funds model to see how the identity shows up in the balance of payments current account • Third some implications/consequences of recognising that output is comprised of two imperfectly-substitutable types of production: tradable and non-tradable The macro identity Disposable national income Y- π ≡ C + I + G + X – M Domestic Output absorption of goods Overseas and investment services income Trade balance (goods and services) Rewrites as: (S – I) + (T – G) ≡ (X - M - cyπ) Private savings Government savings ≈ Current account surplus The loanable-funds model at given Y Interest rate S+T Shifts with income Equilibrium interest rate with no capital flows in ‘World interest rate’ (here local population is relatively ‘impatient’) iw I+G Units of output Current account deficit Sudden stops do happen in the real world • Intertemporal optimisation models don’t all imply optimal outcomes! • Treasury and Bill English have both recently talked about economic imbalances Non-tradables Tradables Cullen saw the problem clearly back Cullen then presided over this in 2000 English sees the problem in 2010 From Budget 2010 Why that falling-behind of tradables? • Possibly a change in the economy’s resource endowment • More likely a result of economic incentives, i.e. relative prices • High nominal and real exchange rate squeezes the profitability of tradables unless their production costs fall rapidly • Prices moving in favour of non-tradables induce resource reallocation • [But note that a lot of non-tradables actually bring foreign exchange income – services in tourism, education, film production, software => there’s a need for more careful decomposition of output data] Toy model with tradables and non-tradables: Salter-Swan (1950s) Nontradables Social indifference curves Full equilibrium: internal and external balance A Production possibilities frontier Budget line for full employment, given relative price ratio Tradables What if the price of non-tradables rises relative to the price of tradables, while internal balance is maintained? Nontradables New output combination New consumption point New budget line B C A Original budget line Trade deficit Tradables Conclusion: internal balance is retained but external balance is not This leaves the economy with external debt accumulating over time Whether that is sustainable, and to what level of debt, depends on the attitudes of overseas investors Another Salter-Swan story: what if overseas capital flows in to buy up local assets? Nontradables New consumption point D New budget line at original relative price ratio A Inflationary excess demand for nontradables Original budget line Trade deficit Tradables What happens next? Answer: inflation driven by non-tradables prices until their relative price rises enough to bring demand and supply into balance at E Nontradables Internal balance restored at E New consumption point F D E F New budget line at new relative price ratio A Trade deficit Tradables Conclusion: internal balance is retained but external balance is not This leaves the economy with external debt accumulating over time Whether that is sustainable, and to what level of debt, depends on the attitudes of overseas investors That’s the same as the earlier case of an exogenous shock to non-tradable prices …. Which story dominates? First is the ‘hoover effect’; second is the ‘overseas takeover’ effect In the first case, policy would worry about driving down the domestic price ratio (e.g. by regulating non-tradables prices) to shift resources into tradables, and thus slow down offshore borrowing In the second case, policy would look at controlling the capital inflow with an eye on keeping tradables healthy in case of a sudden stop/transfer problem If you don’t know which causal mechanism prevails, be ready for both sorts of policy intervention So what do the data show? Take first the inflation-adjusted nominal exchange rate (RBNZ) http://www.rbnz.govt.nz/keygraphs/Fig8b.html Trade balance and RBNZ competitiveness 1988-2010 4,000 1.3000 3,000 1.2000 2,000 1.1000 1,000 1.0000 0 Trade balance (LH scale) 0.9000 Competitiveness (RHscale) -1,000 0.8000 -2,000 0.7000 -3,000 -4,000 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 0.6000 2015 March years Trade data from Infoshare; inverted real TWI from RBNZ But then there’s the Salter-Swan real exchange rate: the price ratio between non-tradables and tradables In terms of economic structure NZ faces a steady relative-price swing against tradables • I have attributed this to the failure to regulate monopoly utilities which have therefore been able to push up margins and pass on cost increases, while tradables producers have been squeezed • It may also reflect, though, changing relative supply cost… • The mechanism is a higher inflation rate for nontradables, which year by year moves prices in their favour Geoff Bertram 21 RBNZ, Monetary Policy Statement September 2010 p.2 Geoff Bertram 22 Salter-Swan Real exchange rate: two estimates, 2000=1 1.4 1.2 1 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 0 Ratio GDP deflator to import and export prices Ratio non-tradeables/tradeabbles prices Sheltered sectors pulling income from exposed? 1970Q1 1971Q2 1972Q3 1973Q4 1975Q1 1976Q2 1977Q3 1978Q4 1980Q1 1981Q2 1982Q3 1983Q4 1985Q1 1986Q2 1987Q3 1988Q4 1990Q1 1991Q2 1992Q3 1993Q4 1995Q1 1996Q2 1997Q3 1998Q4 2000Q1 2001Q2 2002Q3 2003Q4 2005Q1 2006Q2 2007Q3 2008Q4 2010Q1 Index, 1970-2010=100 New Zealand Real Exchange Rate: Two Versions 200.0 180.0 160.0 140.0 120.0 Nominal TWI 100.0 NZ/Relative world CPIs 80.0 Real TWI (=Col C / Col E *100) 60.0 Relative price of non-tradeables/tradeables, March 1988=100 40.0 20.0 0.0 New Zealand Current Account Balance and Merchandise Trade Balance, annual data 1951-2010 Current account balance LHS 10.0 Trade balance LHS 5.0 % of GDP 0.0 -5.0 -10.0 -15.0 March years 2010 2008 2006 2004 2002 2000 1998 1996 1994 1992 1990 1988 1986 1984 1982 1980 1978 1976 1974 1972 1970 1968 1966 1964 1962 1960 1958 1956 1954 1952 1950 -20.0 New Zealand Current Account Balance and Merchandise Trade Balance, annual data 1951-2010 Current account balance LHS 10.0 3.600 Trade balance LHS Salter competitiveness RHS 5.0 2.600 % of GDP 0.0 -5.0 -10.0 1.600 -15.0 March years 2010 2008 2006 2004 2002 2000 1998 1996 1994 1992 1990 1988 1986 1984 1982 1980 1978 1976 1974 1972 1970 1968 1966 1964 1962 1960 1958 1956 1954 1952 0.600 1950 -20.0 New Zealand Current Account Balance and Merchandise Trade Balance, annual data 1951-2010 Current account balance LHS Trade balance LHS 10.0 3.600 Salter competitiveness RHS RBNZ comoetitiveness RHS 5.0 2.600 % of GDP 0.0 -5.0 -10.0 1.600 -15.0 March years 2010 2008 2006 2004 2002 2000 1998 1996 1994 1992 1990 1988 1986 1984 1982 1980 1978 1976 1974 1972 1970 1968 1966 1964 1962 1960 1958 1956 1954 1952 0.600 1950 -20.0 New Zealand Current Account Balance and Merchandise Trade Balance, annual data 1951-2010 Current account balance LHS Bretton Woods 10.0 Supply shocks + inflation Float Trade balance LHS 3.600 Salter competitiveness RHS RBNZ competitiveness RHS 5.0 2.600 % of GDP 0.0 -5.0 -10.0 1.600 -15.0 March years 2010 2008 2006 2004 2002 2000 1998 1996 1994 1992 1990 1988 1986 1984 1982 1980 1978 1976 1974 1972 1970 1968 1966 1964 1962 1960 1958 1956 1954 1952 0.600 1950 -20.0 As external debt rises, the current account gets driven by investment income π Current account and investment income balance 0 -2000 -4000 -8000 -10000 -12000 -14000 -16000 March years Current account balance Investment income debit 2010 2005 2000 1995 1990 -18000 1985 $ million -6000 http://www.rbnz.govt.nz/keygraphs/Fig6.html Figure 4.1 The funding of the current account deficit: it’s the banks $bn 110 $bn 110 Cumulative current account deficits Cumulative increase in bank's net foreign liabilities 90 90 70 70 50 50 30 30 10 10 -10 -10 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 Net International Investment Position (Government plus Private) 160 140 120 80 60 40 20 0 Total Private and Government Net Overseas Liabilities Banks' net external liabilities Government Foreign-Currency Liabilities Government NZD liabilities held offshore 2010 2000 1990 1980 1970 1960 1950 1940 1930 1920 1910 -20 1900 % of GDP 100 Net International Investment Position (Government plus Private) 160 140 120 80 60 40 20 0 Total Private and Government Net Overseas Liabilities Banks' net external liabilities Government Foreign-Currency Liabilities Government NZD liabilities held offshore 2011 2010 2009 2008 2007 2006 2005 2004 2003 2002 2001 2000 1999 1998 1997 1996 1995 1994 1993 1992 1991 1990 1989 -20 1988 % of GDP 100 Who owes what exactly to whom? • It’s not helpful to just say “we” or “the country” are in debt or overextended. • The fact is that NZ residents basically owe the banks sums in NZD, with no exchange rate exposures • The banks are sitting on $318 billion of NZD assets funded by $96 billion of foreign currencies and $230 billion of NZD liabilities • The long-run worry for the banks is of capital losses in the event of depreciation: the NZD claims are collectible in NZD; the foreign-currency liabilities will revalue upwards if the NZD exchange rate falls • This is not the hedging issue as usually understood – it’s a longer-run balance sheet mismatch Consolidated Balance Sheets of the Banks January 2011 Liabilities, capital and reserves Jan-11 NZ dollar funding 1 NZ resident 2 Non-resident 3 Total 1+2 Assets Jan-11 NZ dollar claims 192.4 37.9 230.3 Foreign currency funding NZ resident (non-M3) Non-resident Sub-total to here 297.8 7.1 304.9 NZ resident (M3 institutions) Total 12.9 317.8 Foreign currency claims 4 NZ resident 5 Non-resident 6 Total 4+5 7.2 88.5 95.7 NZ resident Non-resident Total 7 Capital and reserves 8 Other iabilities 22.8 28.8 Foreign-currency fixed assets Shares in NZ companies Other assets 0.1 0.2 30.2 Government bonds NZ nots and coin Claims on the Reserve Bank 5 0.6 7.1 Total labilities Memo items: funding from associates total non-resident funding 377.6 Total assets 43.2 126.4 Memo items: financial claims on associates total non-resident claims 3.6 4 7.6 377.6 5.5 11.1 Equity International Investment Position 80,000 60,000 40,000 20,000 Equity assets 0 Equity Liabilities Net International Equity -20,000 -40,000 Dec-10 Jun-10 Dec-09 Jun-09 Dec-08 Jun-08 Dec-07 Jun-07 Dec-06 Jun-06 Dec-05 Jun-05 Dec-04 Jun-04 Dec-03 Jun-03 Dec-02 Jun-02 Dec-01 Jun-01 Dec-00 -80,000 Jun-00 -60,000 -200,000 Nov-10 Jun-10 Jan-10 Aug-09 Mar-09 Oct-08 May-08 Dec-07 Jul-07 Feb-07 Sep-06 Apr-06 Nov-05 Jun-05 Jan-05 Aug-04 Mar-04 Oct-03 May-03 Dec-02 Jul-02 Feb-02 Sep-01 Apr-01 Nov-00 Jun-00 Banks International Investment Psition 100,000 50,000 0 -50,000 Bank loan assets Banks liabilities Banks net position -100,000 -150,000 Government International Loan Position 20,000 10,000 0 General government assets -10,000 General government liablities Government net -20,000 Dec-10 Jun-10 Dec-09 Jun-09 Dec-08 Jun-08 Dec-07 Jun-07 Dec-06 Jun-06 Dec-05 Jun-05 Dec-04 Jun-04 Dec-03 Jun-03 Dec-02 Jun-02 Dec-01 Jun-01 Dec-00 -40,000 Jun-00 -30,000 Other sectors International Loan Position 40,000 20,000 0 -20,000 Other sectors assets Other sectors liablities -40,000 Other net -60,000 Dec-10 Jun-10 Dec-09 Jun-09 Dec-08 Jun-08 Dec-07 Jun-07 Dec-06 Jun-06 Dec-05 Jun-05 Dec-04 Jun-04 Dec-03 Jun-03 Dec-02 Jun-02 Dec-01 Jun-01 Dec-00 -100,000 Jun-00 -80,000 But there has been a break in the trend since the 2008 crisis (The interesting question domestically is whether the economy has saturated its demand for credit – i.e. whether deleveraging will continue for the next few years regardless of inducements to borrow) -5 -10 -15 Oct 2010 Jun 2010 Feb 2010 Oct 2009 Jun 2009 Feb 2009 Oct 2008 Jun 2008 Feb 2008 Oct 2007 Jun 2007 Feb 2007 Oct 2006 Jun 2006 Feb 2006 Oct 2005 Jun 2005 Feb 2005 Oct 2004 Jun 2004 Feb 2004 Oct 2003 Jun 2003 Feb 2003 Oct 2002 Jun 2002 Feb 2002 Oct 2001 Jun 2001 Feb 2001 Oct 2000 Jun 2000 % change in credit outstanding by sector, June 2000 to January 2011 30 25 20 15 Agriculture 10 Business Housing Consumer 5 TotalHousehold Total Credit 0 0.0 Jan 2011 Sep 2010 May 2010 Jan 2010 Sep 2009 May 2009 Jan 2009 Sep 2008 May 2008 Jan 2008 Sep 2007 May 2007 Jan 2007 Sep 2006 May 2006 Jan 2006 Sep 2005 May 2005 Jan 2005 Sep 2004 May 2004 Jan 2004 Sep 2003 May 2003 Jan 2003 Sep 2002 May 2002 Jan 2002 Sep 2001 May 2001 Jan 2001 Sep 2000 May 2000 Jan 2000 $billion Credit outstanding by sector 350.0 300.0 250.0 200.0 Consumer Housing 150.0 Business Agriculture 100.0 50.0 Funding the growth of NZ dollar assets of the banks and M3 institutions March 1988 - Jan 2011 350,000 300,000 250,000 Total NZD assets, M3 institutions Total NZD assets, registered banks 200,000 $ million Total NZ dollar funding, M3 institutions Total NZ dollar funding, registered banks NZ resident NZD funding, M3 institutions 150,000 NZ resident NZD funding, registered banks Total foreign currency funding, M3 institutions Total foreign currency funding, registered banks 100,000 Funding from associates, M3 institutions Funding from associates, registered banks 50,000 Sep 2010 Nov 2009 Jan 2009 Mar 2008 May 2007 Jul 2006 Sep 2005 Nov 2004 Jan 2004 Mar 2003 Jul 2001 May 2002 Sep 2000 Nov 1999 Jan 1999 Mar 1998 May 1997 Jul 1996 Sep 1995 Jan 1994 Nov 1994 Mar 1993 May 1992 Jul 1991 Sep 1990 Nov 1989 Jan 1989 Mar 1988 0 Back in 2009 I was worrying about the rapidly growing gap Funding of NZ banks, March 1988-September 2008 350,000 300,000 $58B 250,000 200,000 150,000 100,000 NZD claims on NZ residents, M3 institutions NZD claims on NZ residents, registered banks Total NZD funding, M3 institutions Total NZD funding, registered banks NZD funding from NZ residents, M3 institutions NZD funding from NZ residents, registered banks Nov 2010 Mar 2010 Jul 2009 Nov 2008 Mar 2008 Jul 2007 Nov 2006 Mar 2006 Jul 2005 Nov 2004 Mar 2004 Jul 2003 Nov 2002 Jul 2001 Mar 2002 Nov 2000 Mar 2000 Jul 1999 Nov 1998 Mar 1998 Jul 1997 Nov 1996 Mar 1996 Jul 1995 Nov 1994 Jul 1993 Mar 1994 Nov 1992 Mar 1992 Jul 1991 Nov 1990 Mar 1990 Jul 1989 0 Nov 1988 50,000 Mar 1988 NZ$ million $98B Three years on, it’s virtually frozen Funding of NZ banks, March 1988 - January 2011 350,000 October 2008 300,000 $67B 250,000 NZ$ millions $105B 200,000 150,000 100,000 NZD claims on NZ residents, M3 institutions NZD claims on NZ residents, registered banks Total NZD funding, M3 institutions Total NZD funding, registered banks NZD funding from NZ residents, M3 institutions NZD funding from NZ residents, registered banks Nov 2010 Mar 2010 Jul 2009 Nov 2008 Mar 2008 Jul 2007 Nov 2006 Mar 2006 Jul 2005 Nov 2004 Mar 2004 Jul 2003 Nov 2002 Mar 2002 Jul 2001 Nov 2000 Mar 2000 Jul 1999 Nov 1998 Mar 1998 Jul 1997 Nov 1996 Mar 1996 Jul 1995 Nov 1994 Mar 1994 Jul 1993 Nov 1992 Mar 1992 Jul 1991 Nov 1990 Mar 1990 Jul 1989 Nov 1988 0 Mar 1988 50,000 Meantime the Core Funding Requirement has begun to shift the maturity structure of bank funding Banks' foreign-currency funding by maturity 120000 B8.9 5 + B8.8 4 years < 5 years 100000 B8.7 3 years < 4 years 80000 B8.5 1 year < 2 years 60000 B8.4 90 days < 1 year B8.3 2 < 90 days 40000 B8.2 Other call 20000 B8.1 Transaction call Wholesale guarantee start and end Dec 2010 Sep 2010 Jun 2010 Mar 2010 Dec 2009 Sep 2009 Jun 2009 Mar 2009 Dec 2008 Sep 2008 Jun 2008 Mar 2008 Dec 2007 Sep 2007 Jun 2007 Mar 2007 Dec 2006 Sep 2006 Jun 2006 Mar 2006 Dec 2005 Sep 2005 Jun 2005 Mar 2005 0 Dec 2004 $ million B8.6 2 years < 3 years Foreign-currency funding under Wholesale Guarantee Banks' foreign-currency funding by maturity: % breakdown 100% 90% 80% 70% B8.9 5 + 60% B8.8 4 years < 5 years B8.7 3 years < 4 years 50% B8.6 2 years < 3 years B8.5 1 year < 2 years 40% B8.4 90 days < 1 year B8.3 2 < 90 days 30% B8.2 Other call B8.1 Transaction call 20% 10% 0% One black mark in the picture is the Wholesale Deposit Guarantee, which has made $10 billion of bank borrowing a taxpayer liability, with $8.5 billion owed in foreign currency, mainly USD That’s 6% of the banks’ gross foreign currency liabilities for which the exchange risk has been passed to society 0 Jan-09 Mar-09 May-09 Jul-09 Sep-09 Nov-09 Jan-10 Mar-10 May-10 Jul-10 Sep-10 Nov-10 Jan-11 Mar-11 May-11 Jul-11 Sep-11 Nov-11 Jan-12 Mar-12 May-12 Jul-12 Sep-12 Nov-12 Jan-13 Mar-13 May-13 Jul-13 Sep-13 Nov-13 Jan-14 Mar-14 May-14 Jul-14 Sep-14 Nov-14 NZ $ million New Zealand Wholesale Deposit Guarantee Scheme Liabilities 12,000 10,000 8,000 Kiwibank 6,000 Westpac ANZ 4,000 BNZ 2,000 0 Nov-14 Sep-14 Jul-14 May-14 Mar-14 Jan-14 Nov-13 Sep-13 Jul-13 May-13 Mar-13 Jan-13 Nov-12 Sep-12 Jul-12 May-12 Mar-12 Jan-12 Nov-11 Sep-11 Jul-11 May-11 Mar-11 Jan-11 Nov-10 Sep-10 Jul-10 May-10 Mar-10 Jan-10 Nov-09 Sep-09 Jul-09 May-09 Mar-09 Jan-09 NZ $ million New Zealand Wholesale Deposit Guarantee Scheme Liabilities by Currency 12,000 10,000 8,000 Yen 6,000 AUD USD 4,000 NZD 2,000 So can we be sanguine? • No, because at some point economic activity will pick up again and at that point the debt buildup could resume unless the banks are restrained or NZ households and businesses decide to operate within their current income • Also no because there is a big inflow of offshore funds from reinsurance coming up after the Christchurch earthquake, which will tend to hold the nominal exchange rate up and put pressure on domestic non-tradables prices • The RBNZ’s response to the latter will be to raise the OCR, reinforcing the exchange rate overvaluation and rewarding carry traders while putting financial stability again in jeopardy • There’s definitely a need for something extra in the policy mix • The Core Funding Ratio is a big step in the right direction but does not address currency mismatch in the banks’ balance sheets – only the extent of exposure to maturity mismatch • Over time it would be good to see the currency mismatch unwound, at least to some target level low enough to be free of concern about external debt sustainability • There is also a good case for restricting hot money flows by some variant of a Tobin tax or other regulatory capital controls • One way to shift the policy focus in that direction would be to explicitly widen the RBNZ’s objectives to include some notion of exchange rate targeting, both real and nominal • [That was the key role assigned to the ‘Bank’ in Salter’s original paper – he assigned fiscal policy to deal with inflation!] What about government debt? Breakdown of New Zealand Government Debt 300 250 Unspecified gross debt NZD government securities on issue 150 Gross foreign-currency debt 100 NZD debt held offshore Net foreign-currency debt -50 2010 2005 2000 1995 1990 1985 1980 1975 1970 1965 1960 1955 1950 1945 1940 1935 1930 1925 1920 1915 1910 0 1905 50 1900 % of GDP 200 Breakdown of New Zealand Government Debt 70 60 50 Unspecified gross debt NZD government securities on issue 30 Gross foreign-currency debt 20 NZD debt held offshore 10 -10 -20 2010 2005 2000 1995 0 Net foreign-currency debt 1990 % of GDP 40 What does that mean for fiscal policy? • First, there is a lot of headroom for borrowing • Second, there are really interesting analytical questions about the ways in which (and extent to which) changes in spending and the fiscal balance work their way through (i) to income (hence S and T) via Keynesian channels, or (ii) diretly to the current account (X-M-π) via financial-market channels • Third, state asset sales will draw in offshore funds, pushing the nominal exchange rate up and weakening the International Investment Position – perverse from the point of view of helping to raise savings A couple of lessons for macro policy • Prices matter in a market economy => price distortions produce distortions in economic structure • The RBNZ needs multiple instruments to achieve multiple objectives – or some other agency has to take on the issues that the OCR cannot touch • Inflation targeting causes a lot more collateral damage than its advocates usually acknowledge, in terms of real exchange rate impact of the interest rate • Setting out deliberately to move the exchange rate down by, e.g., regulating bank balance sheets, has an obvious downside: it drives up the prices of tradables and hence reduces real wages in terms of consumption goods insofar as household budgets contain more tradables than nontradables.
© Copyright 2024