WHAT OBJECTIVES CAN BE ACHIEVED THROUGH ELECTRICITY SUPPLY AUCTIONS INSTEAD OF “KEEPING THE LIGHTS ON”? Some comments about the new way to ensure Supply Adequacy and to improve the performance of electricity markets in Brazil, Chile and Peru CARLOS GOMERO RIGACCI ∗ [email protected] ABSTRACT: It is generally agreed that the process of deregulation implemented in most of the Latin American electricity markets has shown a positive balance. However, some weaknesses regarding supply adequacy have also been among the results. The problem is that, apparently the market itself has not been enough to encourage new investment in power generation in order to meet the growing demand of some countries. Thus, the wellknown model of capacity payments has shown its powerlessness to avoid some crisis in countries such as Brazil, Chile and Peru. The crisis has forced these countries to look for new alternatives to promote more investment in generation. The most important is the auctioning of energy to be bought by the consumers creating a competitive process between incumbent plants and newcomers. This mechanism for the purpose of this paper is called Supply Electricity Auctions, and it implies selling forward contracts in a centralized manner. This paper aims to analyze the objectives that this scheme can achieve, highlighting those that are solely “to keep the lights on”. The paper finds that the model could reach other important objectives such as enhancing demand responsiveness to prices, making more contestable markets and reducing market power, among others. TABLE OF ABREVIATIONS ESA EU FERC IEEE MW NERC OECD OSINERG PJM PPA SA UK US ∗ Electricity Supply Auctions European Union Federal Energy Regulatory Commission Institute of Electrical and Electronics Engineers Mega Watts North American Electrical Reliability Council Organization for Economic Co-Operation and Development Organism Supervisor of the Energy Investment Pennsylvania, New Jersey and Maryland Pool Power Purchase Agreement Supply Adequacy United Kingdom United States LLM Candidate in Energy Law & Policy. Mr. Gomero is a lawyer with relevant experience in policy making in both the electricity and oil & gas sectors. He has been a member of the Peruvian Ministry of Energy and Mines staff of advisers. 1. INTRODUCTION When the state left electricity market in private hands as a consequence of the process of deregulation, there was confidence in that private agents would have sufficient incentives to achieve the best market performance. The state would not be responsible anymore for developing new investment and, in fact, the search for efficiency in general terms was considered achieved. In spite of this, the new electricity model established has suffered some shortcomings since its implementation in the 1990s. Thus, many countries have experienced energy shortage problems such as Chile in 1998; California, Yugoslavia and Brazil in 2001; Venezuela and India in 2002; Dominican Republic and Norway in 2003; China and Peru in 2004; among others. Even though the shortage problems observed in the cited countries were associated with many other deficiencies of the new model; it is possible to say that, in general, a common problem is that since the beginning of the process of deregulation-liberalization, the reserve margins (the difference between the whole capacity in the system and the peak load or maximum demand) have clearly fallen. 1 In this context, many countries are implementing reforms to avoid problems in the future. Some of them are trying to return to more regulated markets while others are trying to solve the problem by deregulating more. Electricity Supply Auctions (ESA) is a new modality to get resource adequacy that has been implemented in Latin American countries such as Brazil, Colombia, Mexico, Chile and Peru. Some states of the United States (US) (such as New Jersey, New England and Illinois) and Spain have already experienced electricity auctions or are thinking about implementing 1 OECD/IEA, Security of Supply in Electricity Markets. Evidence and Policy Issues, pp. 28-32, (Paris, France: OECD/IEA, 2000). This text discusses the experiences of UK, Australia and US (California and PJM). Available in: http://www.iea.org/textbase/nppdf/free/2000/security2002.pdf. Likewise, Wen (et al.) has pointed out that the reserve margins have been significantly declining in Sweden and Norway since deregulation/liberalization started several years ago. The same problem is being faced by New York where demand has gone up 12.2% since 1993, while generating capacity only up 2.6%. See: Wen, F. (et al.), Generation Capacity Adequacy in the Competitive Electricity Market Environment. In: International Journal of Electrical Power and Energy Systems No 26, p.266 (2004). 2 them. 2 However, there is a big difference between a simple electricity auction and ESA: In ESA the back-up for the auctioned contracts is physical (there is necessarily an increase in the capacity of the system), while in a common electricity auction there may not necessarily be back-ups. It is note worthy to mention early that some of the comments of this paper are applicable to simple electricity auctions as well. The experiences of these countries in auctions contrast with the existent available theory. In this context, the paper attempts to identify what other objectives, if any, may be achieved by this regulatory instrument. The reason for which Brazil, Chile and Peru have been chosen for the analysis is based on the similarities among their electricity systems. However, it is not the objective of the paper to analyze the regulatory regimes of those countries but just to present the problems associated with supply adequacy that they faced. 2. ANALYTICAL FRAMEWORK 2.1 POWER GENERATION, REGULATION AND DEREGULATION Under the normative theory of economic regulation 3 the existence of regulation is explained by the presence of market failures. In electricity markets, and specifically in power generation, those market failures were explained by the presence of natural monopolies. Thus, the characteristic of being a natural monopoly justifies the state intervention in power generation. The common argument to support this theory (generation as natural monopoly) was the efficiency of the power plants. It was argued some time ago that the most efficient size power plant was approaching 1000 MW and now that capacity has been reduced by new technologies. 4 2 New Jersey carries out auctions of energy since 2002. In Illinois, an auction for 30000 MW will take place next September. Likewise, this year New England would be approved by the FERC to carry out capacity auctions next year. Finally, Spain will make energy auctions from July 2006 to meet the new demand. See: http://www.mtpc.org/RenewableEnergy/public_policy/DG/resources/2006-03_ISONE_capacity_settlement_summary.pdf, and: http://www.chicagobusiness.com/cgi-bin/news.pl?id=20935. 3 Viscusi, W. (et al.), Economics of Regulation and Antitrust, (4th ed.), pp. 376-379 (London, UK: MIT Press, 2005). 4 Stoft, S., Power Systems Economics. Designing Markets for Electricity, pp.9-10 (United States: IEEE Press, 2002). 3 This idea, however, has been rejected in theory and in practice because, first, natural monopolies do not explain the existence of regulation and, second, because power generation, is not, in fact, a natural monopoly. On the one hand, the positive theory of regulation points out that regulation is explained by more complex facts rather than the existence of natural monopolies.5 On the other hand, the experience shows that power generation is able to be competitive. Within this context, all over the world, the possibility to leave the power generation to the market forces has been part of the process of deregulation which implies that the market forces replace government regulation and/or non market institution in controlling the performance of the power sector. 6 Thus, if regulation is about controlling prices of monopoly suppliers and restricting entry to the markets, deregulation implies to remove the control on prices and entry of new suppliers. 7 The consequence has been to consider power markets as competitive market places, trusting in competition as the best way to allocate resources. But more important, giving to the private agents the responsibility of electricity provision. 2.2 “KEEPING THE LIGHTS ON”. THE PROBLEM OF SUPPLY ADEQUACY In simple words, Supply Adequacy (SA) is the condition of an electricity system which makes it able to face the growth of the demand in the long run. Of course, the capacity of the system not only has to be enough to deal with the maximum demand of the market, but also it should have a gap to cover its increases (reserve margin). Even though SA and Reliability are concepts commonly used as synonyms, SA is one part of the broad concept of Reliability. In electricity industries, Reliability is the degree of performance of the elements of the bulk electricity system that results in electricity being delivered to customers within accepted standards and in the desired amount (Reliability is measured by the frequency, duration, 5 Viscusi, W. (et al.), op. cit., pp.380-382. Teplitz–Sembitzky, W. Regulation, Deregulation, or Reregulation – What is needed in the LCDs Power Sector?. WB, Industry and Energy Department, Energy Series Paper No 30, p.2 (1990). 7 Hunt, S., Making Competition Work in Electricity, p.7 (New York, United States: John Wiley & Sons Inc., 2002). 6 4 and magnitude of adverse effects on the electricity supply). 8 This concept can be addressed by considering two aspects of the electricity system: Security and Adequacy. While Security is the ability of the electricity system to withstand sudden disturbances such as electric short circuits or unanticipated loss of system elements; Adequacy is the ability of the electric system to supply the aggregate electrical demand and energy requirements of the customers at all times, taking into account scheduled and reasonably expected unscheduled outages of system elements. 9 Both concepts are related but do not imply the same. Thus, an inappropriate policy on operating reserves could cause insufficient security to the system in spite of adequate capacity, though it is relatively cheap to maintain sufficient operating reserves in an adequate system. 10 Certainly, SA is a relatively new concern in the industry due to the fact that it was born with the process of deregulation. Before the replacement of the State in the organization and performance of the industry, there was a mandatory expansion in the industry which implied that the State decided which generation units have to be installed in the system and when. 11 Now, instead, markets participants decide on their own, according to their business expectations, whether they want to build a certain facility or not. Even when the goal of SA is to minimize consumer costs including the cost of blackouts, the real problem is to restore the missing money that prevents adequate investment in generating capacity 12 . Thus, what SA tries to solve is related to the adequate return for investment in power generation which is necessary to cover not only the current, but also the future demand. Naturally, this problem is more critical in countries with high rate of economic growth. 13 8 NERC, Glossary of Terms, p.21 (1996) in: http://www.gisb.org/pdf/weq_glossary072804w10.pdf (last visited 14 April, 2006) 9 Ibid. 10 Stoft, S., op. cit., pp.135-136. 11 Vásquez, C. (et al.), A Market Approach to Long-term Security of Supply, IEEE Transactions on Power Systems, Vol. 17 No 2, p.1 (2002) in: http://www.pcb.ub.es/ieb/arriagaII.pdf (last visited 28 June, 2006). 12 Ibid. 13 It is illustrative in the case of China: in 2004, it installed 51000 MW of generation; in 2005, 68400 MW and to this year is planned to install 79500 MW. See: Fu, S. (et al.), Resource Adequacy Problems in China and Proposed Solutions, IEEE/Power Engineering Society, Transmission and Distribution Conference and 5 2.3 INVESTMENT AND MISSING MONEY PROBLEM Economic theory says that the spot market should be enough to give the right incentives to new investment in power generation. If spot prices are sufficiently high, it will address the expansion of the capacity through the participation of newcomers or investment of the incumbents. The entry of the new capacity will cause the fall in spot prices and, as a result, lower investment and shortages. That is how a common market works. The question that arises immediately is, what is wrong with spot markets? Why do they not give suitable incentives to build new plants? Or why does the theory not work? Some schools of thought point out that well-functioning markets are always reliable because the lights only go out if a consumer wants them to, given the price. Thus, at the end of the day, only the lack of consumers' response to prices is the reason for worry about SA and the reason for capacity markets, installed capacity requirements, price caps, and other holdovers from regulation. 14 However, in reality, it is possible to identify four causes 15 for which the electricity market cannot trust only in the spot prices to deal with SA: (i) Risk aversion of peaking plants; (ii) Oligopolistic behaviour and entry barriers; (iii) Consumers’ demand-responsiveness to prices; and, (iv) Price caps. 2.3.1 RISK AVERSION OF PEAKING PLANTS In ordinary circumstances, a potential entrant should see the spot price and its own capacity to determine if it is convenient to invest. If, from this calculus, the total costs and a reasonable profit margin are covered, the investment should be done. The case of peaking plants is quite different. They have to consider that their units will only generate a few hours a year, when the market price is highest. As a result, they would receive no remuneration most of the time and a high income in a few occasions. 16 This Exhibition Asia Pacific, pp.1-2 (2005) in: http://conference.epri.ac.cn/t-d2005ap/speech/PL2-1.pdf (last visited 12 April, 2006). 14 Hunt, S., op. cit., pp.75-76. One example is the case of UK in 1996. In February 1996, UK was severely short of generating capacity. Blackouts were a possibility but they did not happen in practice. Just it was needed to increase the prices to accommodate the consumption. See p.82. 15 Vasquez, C., op. cit., p.1. 16 Ibid. 6 means that risk-averse firms could feel that the volatility of the income makes the projects too risky and, as a consequence, will not invest. 2.3.2 OLIGOPOLISTIC BEHAVIOUR AND ENTRY BARRIERS Power generation industries are more like oligopolistic markets than competitively perfect. This supposes that the incumbent utilities may under-invest in order to raise market prices when the barriers to entry are sufficiently high to deter the entry of potential entrants. It is common to accept that oligopolistic markets are one of the reasons for which the spot prices do not give the suitable incentives to new capacity investment, but in practice, this feature is more related to the prices the consumers have to pay and not necessarily to SA. In fact, if there were no entry barriers the behaviour of the incumbents does not matter at all because the new entry would be easy. The real problem, hence, are the entry barriers of the industry which is indeed an intrinsic problem in electricity industries due to the existence of high capital investment and sunk costs. It is clear, however, that oligopolistic behaviours could make worse the problem due to the impact that prices may have on consumers, but it is beyond the worries about SA. 2.3.3 DEMAND RESPONSIVENESS TO PRICES In most cases, the consumers are isolated from spot prices by regulated tariffs or price caps and, as a result, they see no advantage for hedging against high prices.17 If the consumers receive the real price signals there would be no concerns about SA 18 , but the lack of metering and real-time billing, and the ability of the load to take power from the grid without a prior contract with a generator 19 are certainly obstacles to give right signals to investment. Both problems make impossible for the market to assess, even approximately, the value placed on reliability by consumers. Without information on this 17 Ibid. See Hunt, S., op. cit. Supra Note 14. 19 Stoft, S., op. cit., p.15 18 7 value, the market cannot determine the adequate level of capacity, since this is defined by the value of reliability. 20 2.3.4 PRICE CAPS One of the main reasons for the missing money problem is that occasional market price increases are limited by administrative actions such as price caps. By preventing prices from reaching high levels during times of scarcity, these administrative actions reduce the payments that could be applied towards the fixed operating costs of existing generation plants and the investment costs of new plants. 21 The logical consequence is the reduction of incentives to maintain generation plants but mainly to build new generation facilities. The result is well-known: if the generators have no sufficient incentives to invest in new infrastructure, there will be shortages and blackouts in the future. According to this, it is possible to say that reliability and incentive to invest are linked. 22 In short, from the perspective of the generating plants, price caps are a tool for discouraging investment. Figures 1 and 2 (taken from Hogan W.) attempt to explain this effect. 20 Cramton, P., and Stoft, S., The Convergence of Market Designs for Adequate Generating Capacity, A White Paper for the Electricity Oversight Board, The Harvard Electricity Policy Group p.3 (2006) in: http://www.ksg.harvard.edu/hepg/Papers/Cramton_Stoft_0406.pdf (last visited 14 April, 2006). 21 Hogan, W., On an “Energy Only” Electricity Market Design for Resource Adequacy, John F. Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University, p.2 (2005). In: http://ksghome.harvard.edu/~whogan (last visited 2 May, 2006). 22 Stoft, S., op. cit., pp.76-77. 8 Figure 1: Returns for generators based on a marginal scheme Figure 2: The effect of price caps in the return of generators 3. MODELS TO ENSURE SUPPLY ADEQUACY The solution for the missing money problem seems to be obvious: the market must provide sufficient incentives to new investment. The real problem, however, is how to give those incentives. How to avoid the missing money problem without reducing the welfare through high prices to the consumers. 9 In order to solve this problem, theory suggests some alternatives to complement the market and provide the payments deemed necessary to support an appropriate level of SA. 23 This topic leads to the treatment of the models to ensure supply. With some variants, it is possible to identify five existing models for ensuring SA: 24 3.1 ENERGY ONLY MARKET Energy-only markets work in California, Australia and New Zealand. In these countries, generators are only remunerated by the produced energy. On-peak energy prices may be quite high and must be allowed to rise in order to send the right signals. 25 The majority of systems around the world do not adopt this model because of the problems that they could create with respect to the price levels. 26 3.2 ENERGY PLUS CAPACITY PAYMENT This method is used in Brazil, Chile, Peru, Spain, UK and many other countries. The concept of Capacity Payment is rooted in the theory of peak load pricing, which application in the context of electricity power was pioneered by Boiteux. 27 This model derives from the correct notion that charging the marginal cost at all hours will give generators just enough revenue if they also charge the “marginal cost of capacity” at peak times. 28 The capacity payment is set to a “value of lost load” (VOLL), which is an estimate of the value of consumers that is multiplied by the “loss of load probability” (LOLP) and paid to all available capacity, no matter whether a generator is dispatched or not. 29 The capacity 23 Hogan, W., op. cit. p.1. Gülen, G., Resource Adequacy and Capacity Schemes, CEE, University of Texas at Austin, (2002). In: http://www.beg.utexas.edu/energyecon/thinkcorner/Capacity_payments.pdf (last visited 2 May, 2006). See also: Fu, S., (et al.), op. cit., p.2. 25 Gülen, G., op. cit., p.2. 26 For more details about energy only markets, see: Hogan, W., op. cit. 27 Oren, S., Ensuring Generation Adequacy in Competitive Electricity Markets, University of California at Berkeley, p.6 (2003). In: http://www.ieor.berkeley.edu/~oren/workingp/adequacy.pdf (last visited 2 May, 2006) 28 The investment cost not recovered through marginal cost pricing. 29 Fu, S. (et al.), op. cit., p.2 24 10 payments are collected from customers and may be set as a fixed charge or a fixed-variable charge (in this case, the dispatched plants may have a premium 30 ). The idea behind this concept is that the spot price of energy pays just for the short-run marginal cost of generation but not for the fixed costs. For this reason, capacity must be paid in order to maintain plants that are only used in dry years and that do not earn inframarginal profits to pay for capital costs (peak plants). 31 3.3 ENERGY PLUS CAPACITY OBLIGATION This method is applied in Northeast US, including PJM, New York and New England. In this case, the obligation for capacity is imposed on the consumers (commonly distributor concessionaries or retailers) by forcing them to sign long-term contracts with power suppliers. 32 The authority determines how much capacity will be bought and sold, but not the prices. This model is commonly named capacity market because inside them there is an organized market for the availability, and the plants may buy and sell their capacity and, as a consequence, the price of the capacity is obtained through market forces. Even though in the model of the cited countries, the regulator determines the amount of firm capacity that each one of the consumption entities has to buy, in practice it admits the possibility of a full requirement (for 100% of the load), like in Peru. 3.4 ENERGY PLUS CAPACITY INVESTMENT RETURN PAYMENT Used in China, the goal of this model is to pay back the total investment for construction of power plants, including interests. 33 The idea is to give more incentives for investors to build power plants. The investors not only will not be worried about the return of 30 This is the case of Peru where capacity payments have a fixed component (it does not matter if the plant is dispatched), and a variable one (dispatched plants are rewarded). 31 Fisher R., and Serra, P., Regulating the Electricity Sector in Latin America, Economia, LACEA, p.164 (2000). In: http://muse.jhu.edu/demo/economia/v001/1.1fischer.pdf (last visited 2 May, 2006). Inframarginal profits are those earned by the base-load plants (these are not paid according with their marginal costs of production, but with the marginal cots of production of the peak-load plants which is, at the same time, the marginal cost of the whole system). 32 Fu, S. (et al.), op. cit., p.3. 33 Ibid. 11 investment, but also will receive the right to operate in the market and earn more money only for the energy supplied. 34 Thus, after the recuperation of the investment, this model works as an Energy Only Market. 3.5 ENERGY PLUS LONG TERM BILATERAL FORWARD CONTRACT BACKED BY PHYSICAL CAPACITY (ESA) This model may be seen as a type of capacity obligation because the authority obligates to the distributor concessionaries and large consumers, to have their entire load duly covered by bilateral forward contracts. Its particularity, however, is based principally in two criteria: (i) The capacity obligation is more specific and complex. Consumers have to offer their load in an open auction with some anticipation (3 or 5 years ahead of time) to let the participation not only of incumbents but also of newcomers (in that time it is possible to build a plant). This is the characteristic of a common electricity auction, such as those made in New Jersey, Illinois or Spain; and, (ii) The bilateral forward contracts which are sold in the auction imply a physical commitment to develop new capacity. In other words, the contracts obtained from the auction will not be mere financial contracts. The winners of the auction have to develop the capacity to cover the necessary amount of energy established in their contract. 35 This model is applied in Brazil, Chile and Peru 36 but there are proposals to apply it in California (under a concept called capacity tag). Likewise, in FERC/EU directives are 34 Ibid., p.4. The physical capacity does not mean that the winner of the auction will produce necessarily all the energy for the counterpart. The rules of dispatch are still applicable and, as a result, the winner most of the time will be enforced to buy energy in the wholesale market to attend the obligation established in the contract. 36 Last year, the government of Peru (The Ministry of Energy and Mines and OSINERG) submitted to the Parliament a proposal to reform the electricity sector which has been approved and should be enacted this month (July 2006). One of the proposed reforms is the implementation of ESA. The text of the proposal and its foundations are in the document named White Book. Project to assure the efficient development in power generation. See infra note 47. 35 12 being included establishing that the agents should show mid-long term supply coverage to meet future demand. 37 This model requires the consumers to sign long-term bilateral forward contracts with power suppliers able to back-up the commitment of delivery with physical capacity. Normally it would encourage the construction of new plants in times of shortage. The particularity of these contracts is based on the arrangement that they are auctioned in such a way that new investors can also bid to obtain the right to supply electricity. 4. ELECTRICITY SECTOR RESTRUCTURING IN LATIN AMERICA 38 4.1 BACKGROUND Likely, the biggest revolution introduced by reformers of the electricity sector in Latin America was the notion that the profitability of the market would determine investment in capacity generating. In fact, this idea was unprecedented in Latin America where most generating companies were owned by the state and followed government directives in investment. 39 With the reform, the supply side started to receive right signals in terms of prices and, as a result, investment was attracted by the profitability of the industry. With the exception of Chile, whose electrical market was restructured in 1982, the rest of the Latin American countries began their process of reform during the 1990s. The reform, almost like in the whole world, implied the separation of activities in generation, transmission and distribution – which additionally act as a retailer with respect to residential consumers. Only Colombia implemented a retail market. Almost in all the countries the reform was accompanied by the privatization of the sector. 37 Moreno, R. (et al.), Energy Supply Auctions to Stimulate Generation Investment, Submitted to IEEE Transactions on Power Systems p.1 (2005). In: http://www2.ing.puc.cl/power/paperspdf/morenorudnickmontero.pdf (last visited 3.April, 2006). 38 Rudnick, H., California Crisis Influences Further Reforms in Latin America. IEEE Power Engineering Review, p.1 (2002). In http://www2.ing.puc.cl/power/paperspdf/californiacrisis.pdf (last visited 17 April, 2006) 39 Fisher, R., and Serra, P., op. cit., p.164. 13 Additionally, such reform schemes were conditioned by the main hydroelectric characteristic of the systems (Over 70% of installed capacity in the region is hydro – see Figures 3 and 4). Figure 3: Sources of electricity generation (2003) 40 Figure 4: Electricity markets in Latin America 41 40 Source: Rudnick, H., (et al.), South American Reform Lessons. Twenty Years of Restructuring and Reform in Argentina, Brazil and Chile. IEEE Power & Energy Magazine Vol.3 (2005) in: http://www2.ing.puc.cl/power/paperspdf/rudnickbarrososkerkblanco.pdf (last visited 12 April, 2006). 41 Source: Ibid. 14 In general terms, all the countries have constituted centralized pools but with different schemes for dispatch. Chile, Peru, Bolivia, Brazil, and Central America use a centralized economic dispatch based on audited costs 42 , while Argentina uses bids with caps. Only Colombia accepts unrestricted bids. All of them have incorporated a scheme of capacity payment (as an adequacy signal), besides the energy one. Latin American reform was based on the spot prices as adequate signal to new investment in power generation. Thus, any disequilibrium between supply and demand would increase/decrease the price and, as a result, increase/decrease the incentives to new investment. On the other hand, the risks as a consequence of the volatility of the spot prices were managed through forward contracts among the agents. Some studies about the performance of the industry after the reform 43 agree that, in general, the process has been successful. 4.2 ELECTRICITY CRISIS IN BRAZIL, CHILE AND PERU In recent years, however, concern has grown on signals of a decreased interest by the private sector in continuing the high rate of investment both in generation and transmission. This has been worsened with supply deficits in Brazil, Chile and Peru, affected by severe droughts. Because of that, the need for the so called: second generation reforms have been considered a necessity. 44 Table 1 attempts to show, in general terms, the causes of the crisis in the selected countries for this study. 42 Currently, though, Brazil has turned out into a dispatch system based on price bidding. See infra Table 1. See, for instance: Fisher, R. and Serra, P., op. cit. See also: Rudnick, H., and Montero, J., Second Generation Electricity Reform in Latin America and the California Paradigm. Journal of Industry, Competition and Trade Vol.2, 1/2 (2002). 44 Rudnick, H., op. cit., pp.1-2 (2002). 43 15 Table 1: Electricity Crisis in Brazil, Chile and Peru Crisis Brazil (2001) 45 Causes Physical generation capacity was insufficient (the generation system was not capable of supplying the load under contract). Chile (1998) 46 Drought and lack of demand responsiveness to prices. Chile (2004) 47 Peru (2004) 48 Effects Rationing of 20% of the energy from June 2001 to February 2002, in regions corresponding to 80% of the country’s population. Rationing of 450 GW of the energy was imposed by 81 days between November 1998 and June 1999. Argentina cut the Excessive increase of natural gas supply to prices because of the the country. use of alternative fuels. Low investment because price caps were perceived insufficient. Drought and lack of Excessive increase of demand prices because of the responsiveness to use of alternative prices. sources. Low investment because price caps were perceived insufficient. 45 Main reforms Change the cost-based system dispatch by a price bidding scheme. Mandatory ESA for the whole system, Reinforcing of the faculties of the supervisory entity (non important reforms). Mandatory ESA for the whole system. Mandatory ESA only for uncontracted demand. Rudnick, H., (et al.), op. cit., p.52. Díaz, C., (et al.), Electricity Crisis of 1998-1999: Causes, Consequences and Lessons, Centre for Applied Economics, Working Paper No 81, (2000). In: http://www.webmanager.cl/prontus_cea/cea_2000/site/asocfile/ASOCFILE120030328124018.pdf (last visited 17 April, 2006). 47 Rudnick, H, and Mocarquer, S., Contract Auctions to assure Supply Adequacy in an Uncertain Energy Environment, IEEE Power Engineering Society General Meeting, Montreal, Canada, June 18-22, p.2 (2006). In: http://www2.ing.puc.cl/power/paperspdf/rudnickmocarquermontreal.pdf (last visited 15 April, 2006). 48 Ministry of Energy and Mines of Peru and OSINERG, White Book: Project to ensure the efficient development in power generation. In: http://www.minem.gob.pe/electricidad/index.asp (last visited 15 April, 2006) 46 16 5. ELECTRICITY SUPPLY AUCTIONS 5.1 GENERAL CONCEPTS As it was said above, ESA are just one way to provide incentives to the investors and “to keep the lights on”. Thus, ESA might be simply defined as a model to ensure SA. However, likely the most important characteristic is being forgotten: Electricity supply is ensured through auctions of energy which implies a process through which consumers (distribution concessionaries or large clients) offer to the market (installed plants and potential investors) a given amount of energy to be supplied in the next years. In practice, this is like selling a forward contract. 49 The fact that there is an auction through which the bilateral forward contracts will be agreed is certainly relevant, since it opens the possibility to have a competitive process and to obtain market-based prices. Another important characteristic of this model which is necessary to keep in mind, is that the energy to be supplied by the winners of the auction, necessarily increases the capacity of the system because it is required for the existence of physical capacity and not merely the compromise to deliver the electricity. 5.2 TYPES OF ESA There are many types of ESAs depending on the conditions of the contracts to be sold. For example, it is possible to sell in the auctions not forward contracts but options contracts, in which the consumer could have reserved the option to take the energy -paying a premiumonly if the spot prices are above the fixed price in the contract. However, in terms of impact in the whole electricity system, it is possible to talk about two types of ESAs. The first is a model applicable to the whole demand in the electricity system and the second, just applicable to the uncontracted demand. (i) ESA to the whole demand 49 The bilateral forward contracts could have diverse modalities. For instance, there is an interesting application of this model based in financial call options in Colombia. See: Vásquez, C., op. cit. 17 Implemented in Brazil and Chile, this type of ESA implies mandatory auctions for the entire demand of the system and the elimination of the bilateral forward contracts in its original conception (contracts one to one). Each period (e.g. a year), the consumers have to offer their entire load to generators. (ii) ESA as residual mechanism Implemented in Peru, it supposes to apply the model only for the uncontracted demand (those load that have not been covered by the ordinary mechanism) and, of course, it does not imply necessarily the replacement of the bilateral forward contracts. In this type, the consumers have the opportunity to get contracts in the common bilateral forward market (contracts one to one) only if there are remaining loads without contracts; these must be offered in the auction. 5.3 EFFECTS OF ESA As a general rule, considering that the real foundation for the implementation of ESA is ensuring SA in power generation, their direct effect is to guarantee a suitable return to investors and, as a result of that, encourage investment. However, unlike other models in ensuring SA, ESA may achieve many other objectives: (i) Enhancing the existence of long-term contracts. Hedging risks. One of the most important characteristics of ESA is associated with the existence of longterm contract as a way to ensure SA. This model recognizes the weakness of the spot prices to promote new capacity investment. Long-term contracts can and should be a significant part of any electricity market undergoing deregulation 50 because they are the best way to hedge the risks that represent 50 Borenstein, S., The Trouble with Electricity Markets (and some solutions), Program on Workable Energy Regulation (POWER), University of California Energy Institute, Working Paper PWP-081, p.7 (2001). 18 the volatility of spot prices. For this reason, ESA makes possible to achieve objectives associated with risk management. 51 (ii) Financing Contract auctions not only encourage investment, but also allow investors to get financing easily. In fact, with this kind of forward contracts, it is possible to get off-balance sheet financing (Project Finance). Getting a contract in an auction is like having a PPA. This feature is widely acknowledged in theory. 52 It is evident that from the financial point of view it is different to deal with a merchant plant (in which the project is entirely dependent on the volatility of prices) rather than to deal with a project that enjoys off-take contracts. In the first case, the project would only sell electricity in the spot market, and only when it is dispatched. In the latter, the project will sell electricity anyway; even when it is not dispatched (in this case the project will receive a price fixed in the contract and would have to pay the spot price to the dispatching producer). 53 (iii) Promoting competition and reducing market power A principal goal of auction theory is the design of auctions that produce competitive prices. In this sense, ESA can lead to competitive power prices. But, what is the competitive price in ESA?. Moreno (et al.) 54 points out that the floor for the price is defined by the expected spot market. That is, generators will not sign a contract with a price lower than the expected market spot price. It has an evident explanation: considering that generators can decide getting a contract or selling the energy in the spot 51 Long-term contracts have important effects on managing risks in prices, quantity, fuel and availability. See Hunt, S., and Shuttleworth, G., Competition Choice in Electricity, pp.121-129 (West Sussex, UK: John Wiley & Sons, Inc., 1996). 52 Hunt, S., op. cit., p.77. 53 Behind the wholesale contracts there are many modalities such as the contract for differences, futures or options which work in a different manner and usually respond to more sophisticated marketplaces. In the Latin American markets, wholesale contracts are normally organized as spot contracts or internal transfers between generators. 54 Moreno, R., (et al.), op. cit., p.2. 19 market, the expected value of selling in the spot market must be, at least, the same to induce the decision to bid in the auction. Thus, the condition to trade the contract is that the present value of cash flows in the scenario with contract has to be higher than the present value of the cash flows in the scenario without contract. 55 Figure 5: Scenarios of payments with contract and without contract Source: Moreno (et al.), op. cit. Thus, the possibility to reduce market power is based on two criteria. First, it is explained by the presence of a competitive process created by the auction and the effect caused by the entry of new plants in the market. 56 Second, because long-term contracts leave little energy to be traded through the spot markets. This function of the forward contract market has been discussed first time by Allaz and Vila 57 , but it has been well explained in a context of the UK electricity market by Green. 58 The reason is almost intuitive: if there is less electricity traded in the spot market 55 Ibid. Charles River Associates Inc. and Market Design, Inc., White Paper on PPA Auction Design Issues, p.10 (1998) in: http://faculty-gsb.stanford.edu/wilson/archive/E542/classfiles/alberta_ppa_auctions.pdf (last visited 13 April, 2006). 57 Allaz, B. and Vila, J., Cournot Competition, Forward Markets and Efficiency, Journal of Economic Theory, Vol. 59 (1993). 58 Green, R., The Electricity Contract Market in England and Wales, The Journal of Industrial Economics, Vol. 47, No 1 (1999). Green points out that the incentives of the generators to raise prices in the spot market are reduced because their potential earnings would be limited to the uncontracted portion of their sales. 56 20 (as a result of more contracted energy), there would be less incentives to the incumbents to raise prices. Furthermore, this result is especially applicable when the suppliers are over-contracted (when they have commitments for more energy than their real capacity), because the need for buying in the spot market would cause a slope in prices. 59 (iv) Promoting non-regulated prices and reducing uncertainty The reform introduced by the analyzed countries has effect to avoid price cap regulation because the price obtained in the auction is passed-through to the consumers. Even though all the countries have established a limit to the final prices in the auction (which indeed could be seen as a limitation to reach competitive prices), the important fact is that, at least, the regulation (price caps fixed periodically by the authority) would be diminished by market signals. Defining the price to the consumers only for the result of the auction could have no sense if the market is highly concentrated and there are high barriers to entry as in power markets. 60 The most prudent so far, is to put a limit to the resulting price. Likely the next step, with more experience especially about the auction design, the price may be exclusively a result of the auction. The importance of this feature in countries where price caps are effective (like Brazil, Chile and Peru), is that the regulatory agency is usually under constant attack each time it sets prices. Any movement in prices generates a reaction from any immersed part in the problem; if the price rises, the consumers exercise pressure to force down the prices. 61 If the prices fall, the companies do the same trying to increase them. Additionally, the fact that the prices are not set anymore by the administrative authority will reduce the uncertainty each period the prices are fixed (in Peru for example, the energy price caps are fixed every year). With the auctions, the prices will be known with an anticipation of 3 or more years. 59 Stoft, S., op. cit., pp.347-348. Collusion could be a problem. See infra. 61 It is especially critical in Peru where the Parliament and the Executive Power intervene continuously in the regulatory process. 60 21 (v) Enhancing demand responsiveness to prices One of the elements to be achieved by competitive markets is demand responsiveness to prices. The reason to look for more consumer response is that it makes it possible to limit price rises because the consumers will receive right signals through market-based prices. This feature is essential in cases of relative scarcity of supply. In fact, some authors think that if the consumers received adequate price signals, there would not be possibility for blackouts. 62 Even when price caps imposed in each auction could limit this effect, it has been pointed out that contract auctions incorporate a real market signal in the price to the consumer 63 , because the price caps are not necessarily included in the theoretical model. The price caps imposed are a result of the possibility of collusion among bidders, but it is evident that the model can and should work without caps. (vi) Making more contestable markets The theory of contestable markets shows that pure profits may be eliminated even though the industry contains only a few firms and experiences no actual entry. 64 In this case, potential entrants act as modulator of the market replacing actual competition. Even though contestable markets are based on the level of entry barriers, it is also relevant the effect that ESA may cause on making markets more contestable for potential investors often restricted to the spot market. 65 In such a way, the threat of entry will cause the incumbents to increase their contract cover, which will make their behaviour in the spot market more competitive and reduce the average pool price. Newbery 66 says that what defines the entry are the variable costs. If the new investment has lower variable costs than existing capacity, the incumbents deter the entry (they will take 62 Hunt, S., op. cit., p.69. See also: Borenstein, S., op. cit. p.5. Rudnick, H., and Mocarquer, S., op. cit., p.2 (2005). 64 Lipsey, R. and Chrystal, K., Economics (10th ed.), p.210 (New York, United States: Oxford University Press, 2004). 65 Moreno, R., (et al.), op. cit., p.2. 66 Newbery, D., Competition, Contracts and Entry in the Electricity Spot Market, Rand Journal of Economics, Vol.29 No 4, p.744 (1998). 63 22 more contracts). If the variable costs of new investments are higher than existing capacity, they allow the entry. This statement, of course, does not take into account the existence of auctions. In the presence of ESAs, the cost of the investment is not important at all, because the incumbents have no opportunity to deter new entry (all can participate in the auction). The only case in which the Newbery’s conclusion would be applicable is the case of Peru where the proposal of reform includes a design of auctions only for the non-contracted energy under the ordinary model. Only in this case can the incumbents exercise some strategic behaviour to this respect. (vii) Establish market values - Efficiency A well-designed auction process should result in payments that reflect the true market values of the contracts. These are prices at which arms-length buyers and sellers are willing to transact. Related to this is the notion of economic efficiency. Under normal conditions, providing for the establishment of market values leads to efficient outcomes. With the ordinary forward contracts model (ordinary bilateral contracts - without auctions) efficiency is not necessarily achieved. Efficiency is established when Forward contracts/PPAs are owned by those who value them the most, and it is only possible to know when participate all the potential sellers of energy. 5.4 THE BAD NEWS Indeed, the model may have some weaknesses. These problems, though, are more associated with its design rather than with intrinsic negative effects. (i) Collusion Collusion is always a problem in auctions, especially when the markets are highly concentrated. Power generation markets are generally oligopolistic and, as a consequence, it is always present the possibility to find out anti-competitive behaviours. Obviously, this weakness does not disqualify the model. It is just necessary to take some contingent measures in order to enhance a real competitive process. In fact, there are huge developments about auctions that may help to deal with collusion. 23 (ii) What is the best form of auction? Auction Models This problem is, again, a design problem. In theory, there are four types of auctions: 67 1. English, in which the buyer starts bidding at the low price and the highest bidder wins and pays the last price bid. An English auction is the familiar “going, going, gone!” auction; 2. Vickrey (second price), in which buyer submits sealed bids, and the winner pays the price of the highest losing bid; 3. Dutch, in which the auctioneer starts very high and calls out progressively, lower prices. The first buyer to accept the price wins. 4. Sealed-Bid (first price), in which buyers submit sealed bids, and the winner pays the price that is bid. What is the best type of auction? There is no response so far. The question is in fact, what the auctioneer (usually the regulator) wants. In the case of ESA, the auctioneer usually wants the lowest price. It is necessary to say that even when theoretically the four type of auction have the same result (due to the revenue equivalence theorem 68 ), in practice it does not happen necessarily. 69 This gives an idea about the importance of looking for the best type of auction accordingly with each electricity system. (iii) What if there are no bidders? In an ideal scenario in which the collusion is not possible, the inexistence of offers in the auction probably indicates that the prices are not sending right signals. That is, that the prices do not cover the fixed and variable costs of a plant. The design of the auction, however, can help to deal with this. In fact, an auction may have many rounds in order to succeed. 67 Stoft, S., op. cit., p.99. Ibid, p.100 69 Moreno, R., (et al.) found different results depending of the type of auction using the Chilean market as model. See p.8. 68 24 (iv) Forecasting the demand This feature appears to be, indeed, an intrinsic problem of the model. Considering that ESA implies to sign contract in ahead of time, it is based on a forecasted load. The problem arises since the forecasted demand and the real demand may not match. Naturally, this problem may cause under-investment or over-investment because the plants are built as a result of the initial requirement. One way to deal with this is establishing tolerance ranges, say 10%. Thus, if the forecast of the company does not match with the real demand by less than 10%, there will not be major consequences. If the forecast exceeds the threshold, usually sanctions are imposed. (v) The installation of the plants is not so simple This is another intrinsic problem of the model because the construction of a plant is not only a buyer/seller’s decision, but also it is under the general regulation. Thus, if the plant does not satisfy, say, the environment requirements to be built, it will not be possible to fulfil the contract. This problem, though, could be addressed if the auctions are organized with some anticipation. 6. CONCLUSIONS In spite of its problems, it was found that the ESA may achieve important objectives rather than just “keeping the lights on”. Principally, they allow the possibility to improve the market performance through increasing competition, increasing demand responsiveness to prices, enhancing long-term contracting, among others. In general terms, it is possible to say that ESA trust in long-term contracts as a mechanism to expand the electricity system and, accordingly, give the right price signals to consumers. Both characteristics make the model, apparently, ideal. In fact, the Brazilian experience (2004), involving 24,000 MW on average in a transaction of almost US$ 27,000 millions, shows that the model can be successful in practice. 25 Of course, SEA is not the solution to all the problems in power generation markets, but what is certain is that we are in front of a new conception to guarantee long-term investment in generating capacity. Likewise, in the long-term, SEA could imply the end of price caps in power generation sectors and the birth of real market prices to residential consumers, which seems to be the next step in the development of electricity markets. 26 BIBLIOGRAPHY 1. Books Hunt, S., Making Competition Work in Electricity, (New York, US: John Wiley & Sons, Inc., 2002). Hunt, S., and Shuttleworth, G., Competition Choice in Electricity, (West Sussex, UK: Wiley & Sons, Inc., 1996). Lipsey, R. and Chrystal, K., Economics (10th ed.), (New York, US: Oxford University Press, 2004). OECD/IEA, Security of Supply in Electricity Markets. Evidence and Policy Issues, (Paris, France: OECD/IEA, 2000). Stoft, S., Power Systems Economics. Designing Markets for Electricity, (US: IEEE Press, 2002). Viscusi, W., Harrington, J. and Vernon, J., Economics of Regulation and Antitrust, (4th ed.) (Massachusetts, US: MIT Press, 2000). 2. Articles In a Periodical Borenstein, S., The Trouble with Electricity Markets (and some solutions), Program on Workable Energy Regulation (POWER), University of California Energy Institute, Working Paper PWP-081 (2001) Green, R., The Electricity Contract Market in England and Wales, The Journal of Industrial Economics, Vol. 47, No 1 (1999). Newbery, D., Competition, Contracts and Entry in the Electricity Spot Market, Rand Journal of Economics, Vol. 29 Nº 4 (1998). Rudnick, H., and Montero, J., Second Generation Electricity Reform in Latin America and the California Paradigm. Journal of Industry, Competition and Trade Vol. 2, 1/2 (2002). Teplitz–Sembitzky, W., Regulation, Deregulation, or Reregulation – What is needed in the LCDs Power Sector?. World Bank - Industry and Energy Department, Energy Series Paper Nº 30 (1990). 3. Others Internet Charles River Associates Inc. and Market Design Inc., White Paper on PPA Auction Design Issues, (1998) http://faculty- 27 gsb.stanford.edu/wilson/archive/E542/classfiles/alberta_ppa_auctions.pdf visited on 13 April 2006). (last Cramton, P., and Stoft, S., The Convergence of Market Designs for Adequate Generating Capacity, A White Paper for the Electricity Oversight Board, The Harvard Electricity Policy Group (2006) http://www.ksg.harvard.edu/hepg/Papers/Cramton_Stoft_0406.pdf (last visited on 14 April 2006). Díaz, C., Galetovic, A and Soto, R., Electricity Crisis of 1998-1999: Causes, Consequences and Lessons, Centre for Applied Economics, Working Paper No 81, (2000). In: http://www.webmanager.cl/prontus_cea/cea_2000/site/asocfile/ASOCFILE1200303 28124018.pdf (last visited on 17 April 2006). Fisher R., and Serra, P., Regulating the Electricity Sector in Latin America, Economia, LACEA, (2000). http://muse.jhu.edu/demo/economia/v001/1.1fischer.pdf (last visited on 02 May 2006). Fu, S., Bai, X., and Wang, H., Resource Adequacy Problems in China and Proposed Solutions, IEEE/Power Engineering Society, Transmission and Distribution Conference and Exhibition Asia Pacific, (2005) http://conference.epri.ac.cn/t-d2005ap/speech/PL2-1.pdf (last visited on 12 April 2006). Gülen, G., Resource Adequacy and Capacity Schemes, CEE, University of Texas at Austin, (2002). http://www.beg.utexas.edu/energyecon/thinkcorner/Capacity_payments.pdf (last visited on 02 May 2006). Hogan, W., On an “Energy Only” Electricity Market Design for Resource Adequacy, John F. Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University, (2005). http://ksghome.harvard.edu/~whogan/Hogan_Energy_Only_092305.pdf (last visited in 02 May 2006). Ministry of Energy and Mines of Peru and OSINERG, White Book: Project to ensure the efficient development in power generation. http://www.minem.gob.pe/electricidad/index.asp (last visited on 15 April 2006). Moreno, R., Rudnick, H and Montero, J., Energy Supply Auctions to Stimulate Generation Investment, Submitted to IEEE Transactions on Power Systems (2005). http://www2.ing.puc.cl/power/paperspdf/morenorudnickmontero.pdf (last visited on 03 April 2006). NERC, Glossary of Terms, (1996) http://www.gisb.org/pdf/weq_glossary072804w10.pdf (last visited on 14 April 2006). 28 Oren, S., Ensuring Generation Adequacy in Competitive Electricity Markets, University of California at Berkeley, (2003). http://www.ieor.berkeley.edu/~oren/workingp/adequacy.pdf (last visited on 02 May 2006). Rudnick, H., California Crisis Influences Further Reforms in Latin America. IEEE Power Engineering Review, (2002). http://www2.ing.puc.cl/power/paperspdf/californiacrisis.pdf (last visited on 17 April 2006). Rudnick, H, and Mocarquer, S., Contract Auctions to assure Supply Adequacy in an Uncertain Energy Environment, IEEE Power Engineering Society General Meeting, Montreal, Canada, June (2006). http://www2.ing.puc.cl/power/paperspdf/rudnickmocarquermontreal.pdf (last visited on 15 April 2006). Rudnick, H., Barroso, L., Skerk, C. and Blanco, A., South American Reform Lessons. Twenty Years of Restructuring and Reform in Argentina, Brazil and Chile. IEEE Power & Energy Magazine Vol.3 (2005) http://www2.ing.puc.cl/power/paperspdf/rudnickbarrososkerkblanco.pdf (last visited on 12 April 2006). Vásquez, C., Rivier, M. and Pérez-Arriaga, I., A Market Approach to Long-term Security of Supply, IEEE Transactions on Power Systems, Vol. 17, Nº 2 (2002). http://www.pcb.ub.es/ieb/arriagaII.pdf (last visited on 28 June 2006). Wen, F., Wu, F. and Ni, Y., Generation Capacity Adequacy in the Competitive Electricity Market Environment, International Journal of Electrical Power and Energy Systems Vol. 26 (2004). http://www.paper.edu.cn/scholar/download.jsp?file=wenfushuan1&title=Generation%20capacity%20adequacy%20in%20the%20competitive%20el ectricity%20market%20environment (last visited 2 July 2006). 29
© Copyright 2024