ACTSC 445: Asset-Liability Management Department of Statistics and Actuarial Science, University of Waterloo Unit 6 – Immunization References (recommended readings): Chap. 3 of Financial Economics (on reserve at the library: call number HG174 .F496 1998). What is immunization? • Redington (1952): Immunization implies the investment of assets in such a way that existing business is immune to a general change in the rate of interest. • Fisher-Weil (1971): A portfolio of investment is immunized for a holding period if its value at the end of the holding period, regardless of the course of rates during the holding period, must be at least as it would have been had the interest rate function been constant throughout the holding period. Implication: If the realized return on an investment in bonds is sure to be at least as large as the appropriately computed yield to the horizon, then that investment is immunized. • An immunization strategy is a risk management technique designed to ensure that for any small change in a specified parameter, a portfolio of debt instruments (e.g., T-bills, bonds, GICs etc) will cover a liability (or liabilities) coming due at a future date (or over a period in the future). It is a passive management technique because it takes prices as given and then tries to control the risk appropriately. (By contrast, active management techniques try to exploit changes in (1) the level of interest rates, (2) the shape of the yield curve (3) yield spreads, by using interest rate forecasts and identification of mispriced bonds) ⇒ asset allocation problem (i.e., must choose assets that will produce an immunized portfolio) Single-liability case We’ll start with the case where there is only one liability in the portfolio, with corresponding cash flow of Lt at some time t. The goal is to choose an asset cash flow sequence {At , t > 0} that will, along with Lt , produce an immunized portfolio. Let’s start with an example. Example I: Suppose an insurance company faces a liability obligation of $1 million in 5 years. The available market instruments are: 3-year, 5-year and 7-year zero-coupon bonds, each yielding 6% annual effective rate. • Portfolio A: Invest $747,258.17 in the 5-year zero coupon bond 1 • Portfolio B: Invest the same amount (i.e. $747,258.17) in a 3-year zero coupon bond. The maturity value at t = 3 is $889,996.44. • Portfolio C: Invest $747,258.17 in a 7-year zero coupon bond. The maturity value at t = 7 is $1,123,600.00. If the yields remain unchanged, then the 3 portfolios have the same value of $1 000 000 at time 5. To verify if these portfolios are immunized or not, we need to look at what happens if, immediately after the portfolio is acquired, the yield changes instantaneously to yˆ and remains constant at that level. First, note that for portfolio A, this change has no impact: its value at time 5 is still $1 000 000. But this is not true for portfolios B and C, as Tables 1 and 2 show. Table 1: Value of Portfolio B for different yields yˆ (%) 4.00 5.00 5.90 6.00 6.10 7.00 8.00 Value of Portfolio B at time 0 at time 5 791203.5944 962620.1495 768812.3874 981221.0751 749377.0511 998114.0975 747258.1729 1000000.0000 745147.2753 1001887.6824 726502.2044 1018956.9242 706507.8685 1038091.8476 Capital Gain at time 0 −43945.4215 −21554.2146 −2118.8782 0.0000 2110.8975 20755.9684 40750.3044 Implied Yield (%) 5.20 5.60 5.96 6.00 6.04 6.40 6.80 So for portfolio B, if the yields go up, then we realize a gain at time 5, because we can reinvest the proceeds obtained at time 3 at a high yield. But if the rates drop, then we realize a loss at time 5. The problem here is the reinvestment risk. Table 2: Value of Portfolio C for different yields yˆ (%) 4.00 5.00 5.90 6.00 6.10 7.00 8.00 Value of Portfolio C in year 0 at time 5 853843.6549 1038831.3609 798521.5425 1019138.3220 752211.5711 1001889.4658 747258.1729 1000000.0000 742342.0181 998115.8742 699721.6100 981395.7551 655609.8081 963305.8985 Capital Gain at time 0 106585.4820 51263.3697 4953.3982 0.0000 −4916.1548 −47536.5629 −91648.3647 Implied Yield (%) 6.81 6.40 6.04 6.00 5.96 5.60 5.21 The situation here is opposite from what we face with Portfolio B: if the rates drop, then we can sell the 7-year zero bond at a higher price at time 5, which results in a gain. But a yield increase produces a loss. The problem here is the interest rate or price risk. 2 Observations from Example I • With a single liability, the best immunization strategy is the one for which the asset cash flow coincides with the liability cash flow • When asset cash flows occur prior to (or after) the liability cash flow, the portfolio is subject to reinvestment risk (or market/interest rate/price risk). A valid question is: could we construct a portfolio containing cash flows occuring before and after the liability due date that could be immunized? Motivation: • Any initial capital loss may be offset in time by greater returns from reinvestment. • Similarly, any initial capital gain may be offset in time by lower returns from reinvestment. • Does there exist an “optimum” trade-off? I.e., a way to construct a portfolio like this that maximizes (in some sense) the gain? The following example studies this idea. Example II: Consider Portfolio D, which consists in an investment of $373 629.0864 in 3-year zerocoupon bonds, and $373 629.0864 in 7-year zero-coupon bonds. Their maturity values are, respectively, 444,998.22 and 561,800.00. Note that the Macaulay duration of this portfolio is 5. If the yields remain unchanged, then at t = 5 we have 373, 629.0864 × 2 × (1.06)3 = 1 000 000. If the rates change, then we get the following results: yˆ (%) 4.0 5.0 5.9 6.0 6.1 7.0 8.0 Value of Portfolio D at time 0 at time 5 822523.6247 1000725.7552 783666.9650 1000179.6986 750794.3111 1000001.7817 747258.1729 1000000.0000 743744.6467 1000001.7783 713111.9072 1000176.3396 681058.8383 1000698.8731 Capital Gain at time 0 75265.4518 36408.7921 3536.1382 0.0000 -3513.5262 -34146.2657 -66199.3346 Implied Yield (%) 6.01538 6.00381 6.00004 6.00000 6.00004 6.00374 6.01481 Hence with this portfolio, a gain is realized at time 5 for all alternative yields yˆ considered... Note that at time 0, there is a capital loss for portfolio D. More generally, we can look at the value of this portfolio at time t if the initial yield goes from 6% to yˆ. That is, we can consider the value Vt = 444 998.22(1 + yˆ)−(3−t) + 561 800.00(1 + yˆ)−(7−t) for t = 1, . . . , 10 and different yˆ’s. 3 t 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 if rate drops 4.00% 5.50% 5.90% 822524 765169 750794 855425 807253 795091 889642 851652 842002 925227 898493 891680 962236 947910 944289 1000726 1000045 1000002 1040755 1055047 1059002 1082385 1113075 1121483 1125680 1174294 1187650 1170708 1238880 1257722 1217536 1307018 1331927 y∗ 6.00% 747258 792094 839619 889996 943396 1000000 1060000 1123600 1191016 1262477 1338226 if 6.10% 743745 789113 837249 888321 942509 1000002 1061002 1125723 1194392 1267250 1344552 rate rises 6.50% 8.00% 729913 681059 777358 735544 827886 794387 881698 857938 939009 926573 1000044 1000699 1065047 1080755 1134275 1167215 1208003 1260592 1286523 1361440 1370147 1470355 Equivalently, we can look at the corresponding implied yield for the portfolio, which is the value i such that 747, 258.17 = Vt (1 + i)−t . t 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 if rate drops 4.00% 5.50% 5.90% 14.48 8.03 6.40 9.11 6.76 6.15 7.38 6.34 6.07 6.53 6.13 6.03 6.02 6.00 6.00 5.68 5.92 5.98 5.44 5.86 5.97 5.26 5.81 5.96 5.11 5.78 5.96 5.00 5.75 5.95 y∗ 6.00% 6.00 6.00 6.00 6.00 6.00 6.00 6.00 6.00 6.00 6.00 if rate rises 6.10% 6.50% 8.00% 5.60 4.03 −1.57 5.85 5.26 3.11 5.93 5.67 4.71 5.98 5.88 5.52 6.00 6.00 6.01 6.02 6.08 6.34 6.03 6.14 6.58 6.04 6.19 6.75 6.04 6.22 6.89 6.05 6.25 7.00 Observations from Examples I and II • Basic risk exposures: reinvestment risk and price risk • The existence and extent of either risk depends on the nature of the security as well as on the relative length of the period over which its return and risk are measured. • Over a period of time in which both risks are in effect, there are some obvious offsetting tendencies. • We saw in Unit 5 that the degree of capital loss/gain from a change in yields (i.e. price risk) depends on the duration of the securities held. Example II suggests that the time required to offset these capital gain/loss from reinvestment of the cash flows also depends on the duration of the securities held. 4 Target Date Immunization Here we generalize the ideas examined in Example II. Let Vk (y) be the value of a portfolio of securities at time k (measured in years) for a given ytm y (assume annual effective rate). Suppose the current ytm is y ∗ so that the value of the portfolio initially acquired is V0 (y ∗ ). • If there is no change in the ytm, the investment grows to V0 (y ∗ )(1 + y ∗ )k = Vk (y ∗ ) after k years. • If there is an instantaneously shift in yield from y ∗ to yˆ, then the year-k portfolio value becomes: Vk (ˆ y ) = V0 (ˆ y )(1 + yˆ)k • If the investment horizon is T years, then the realized return exceeds the initial yield y ∗ as long as VT (ˆ y ) ≥ VT (y ∗ ). The following result proves that if the portfolio is constructed so that its duration equals the investment horizon, then the price risk and reinvestment risk cancel out and the realized value of return is at least y ∗ . The resulting approach is called target-date immunization. Theorem: For a portfolio initially constructed at ytm y ∗ and with (Macaulay) duration D, then for any yˆ VD (ˆ y ) ≥ VD (y ∗ ). Remarks: • When the investment horizon equals the portfolio duration, the price risk and reinvestment risk cancel out. • The realized rate of return can never fall below its initial yield. Proof: First, we look at the behavior of Vk (y) as a function of y: we have that X Vk (y) = At (1 + y)k−t t and therefore dVk (y) X = (k − t)At (1 + y)k−t−1 dy t and d2 Vk (y) X = (k − t)(k − t − 1)At (1 + y)k−t−2 . dy 2 t Note that if t < k − 1 or t > k, then (k − t)(k − t − 1) > 0, and if t = k − 1 or t = k, then (k − t)(k − t − 1) = 0. Therefore dVk2 (y)/dy 2 ≥ 0, with a strict inequality as long as the cash flows are not concentrated at time t = k − 1 or t = k. Assuming this is not the case (i.e., assuming that dVk2 (y)/dy 2 > 0), we can set dVk (y)/dy to 0 to find at which y does the function Vk (y) is minimized. Doing this, we get P tAt (1 + y)−t dVk (y) X k−t−1 = (k − t)At (1 + y) = 0 ⇔ k = Pt . −t dy t At (1 + y) t 5 Trying to solve for y is hard, but notice that if y = y ∗ , then setting k = D makes the derivative equal to 0, which means that if k = D, then the minimum value for VD (y) is attained when y = y ∗ , which proves the result. Single-liability Immunization Putting it all together, if we have only one liability Lk at time k, the sufficient and necessary conditions to construct an immunized portfolio are: X At (1 + y ∗ )−t = Lk (1 + y ∗ )−k t>0 X tAt (1 + y ∗ )−t = kLk (1 + y ∗ )−k t>0 Remarks: • The first condition is necessary, and ensures that the PV of the assets equals the PV of liabilities. • The second condition (sufficient, given the first holds) equates the dollar duration of the assets to the dollar duration of the liabilities. (Note that if the first condition holds, then the second condition is equivalent to having the Macaulay duration of the assets equal to that of the liabilities, which is k.) Example II revisited: In Example II, the two conditions for immunization are satisfied: 1. PV of assets = 2 × 373, 629.0864 = 747 258.17 and PV of liabilities = 1 000 000(1.06)−5 = 747 258.17. 2. Dollar duration of assets = 3 × 373, 629.0864 + 7 × 373, 629.0864 = 3 736 290.9 and dollar duration of liabilities = 5 × 1 000 000 × (1.06)−5 = 3 736 290.9. This is why at time 5 (which is equal to D), we observe V5 (ˆ y ) ≥ V5 (y ∗ ) for all yˆ considered. Multiple-liability case: Redington Theory We now assume that there is a cash flow {Lt , t > 0} of liabilities, which in the context of an insurance company, could be arising from policy claims, policy surrenders, policy loan payments, policyholder dividends, expenses and taxes. Notation For a given interest rate y, the PV of assets, liabilities and surplus are given by X At X Lt A(y) = , L(y) = , and (1 + y)t (1 + y)t t t X At X Lt − S(y) = A(y) − L(y) = (1 + y)t (1 + y)t t t respectively. At the initial ytm y ∗ , A ≡ A(y ∗ ), L ≡ L(y ∗ ) and S ≡ S(y ∗ ) = A − L. The liability obligations are said to be 6 • fully funded if A ≥ L (or S ≥ 0); • underfunded if A < L (or S < 0); • exactly fully funded if A = L or S = 0. Redington’s Problem: How to structure the asset cash flows {At , t = 1, 2, . . .} so that there will be sufficient cash when liabilities {Lt , t = 1, 2, . . .} arise ? Equivalently, are there ways to ensure that S(y ∗ + ∆y) ≥ S(y ∗ )? S(y) y y* Figure 1: Desired behavior for S(y) The following conditions propose a way to achieve this, at least for small ∆y’s. Redington Immunization Conditions 1. S = 0, (PV matching criterion) 2. S 0 (y ∗ ) = 0, (duration matching criterion) 3. S 00 (y ∗ ) ≥ 0, (dispersion criterion) The first condition ensures the PV of assets and liabilities match. 0 0 The second condition is equivalent to having A (y ∗ ) = L (y ∗ ), which implies X X tAt (1 + y ∗ )−t = tLt (1 + y ∗ )−t . t>0 t>0 Together, conditions 1 and 2 imply that DA = DL (duration matching), where DA = X tAt (1 + y ∗ )−t A t>0 = X tLt (1 + y ∗ )−t t>0 L = DL . 00 00 Dispersion criterion: the third condition is equivalent to having A (y ∗ ) ≥ L (y ∗ ), which implies X t(t + 1)At (1 + y ∗ )−t t>0 A ≥ X t(t + 1)Lt (1 + y ∗ )−t t>0 7 L . Together, conditions 2 and 3 imply that X t2 At (1 + y ∗ )−t A t>0 ≥ X t2 Lt (1 + y ∗ )−t t>0 L . Together, conditions 1 and 3 imply that CA ≥ CL , i.e., convexity of assets ≥ convexity of liabilities. Mathematically speaking, these conditions come from Taylor’s theorem with a remainder, which tells us that 0 00 S(y ∗ + ∆y) = S(y ∗ ) + ∆yS (y ∗ ) + (∆y)2 S (y ∗ + δ)/2, 0 00 where 0 < δ < ∆y. Therefore, by requiring S (y ∗ ) = 0 and S (y ∗ ) > 0, we get that if ∆y is not too large, then S(y ∗ + ∆y) > S(y ∗ ). Example III Suppose there are two liability outflows: $10,000 and $26,620 at the end of years 5 and 8, respectively. An asset cash flow of $36,300 is scheduled at the end of year 7. Does this immunize the liabilities given y ∗ = 10%? Solution: The first and second conditions are met, since 10 000(1.1)−5 + 26 620(1.1)−8 = 36 300(1.1)−7 = 18 627.64 5 × 10 000(1.1)−5 + 8 × 26 620(1.1)−8 = 7 × 36 300(1.1)−7 = 130 393.47. However, losses occur for various values of yˆ, as seen in the following table. yˆ 0.08 0.09 0.10 0.11 0.12 A(ˆ y) 21181 19857 18628 17484 16420 L(ˆ y) 21188 19859 18628 17486 16426 S(ˆ y) −7.09 −1.65 0.00 −1.44 −5.36 The problem is that the dispersion criterion is not satisfied... We have that 7 × 8 × 36 300(1.1)−7 = 1 043 147.8 for the assets, while 5 × 6 × 10 000(1.1)−5 + 8 × 9 × 26 620(1.1)−8 = 1 080 403.1 for the liabilities. If, instead, we have an asset cash flow of $10,625.74 and $27,608.74 due in years 3 and 10, respectively, then conditions 1 and 2 are still satisfied since 10 625.74(1.1)−3 + 27 608.74(1.1)−10 = 18 627.64 3 × 10 625.74(1.1)−3 + 10 × 27 608.74(1.1)−10 = 130 393.47 8 Also, since 3 × 4 × 10 625.74(1.1)−3 + 10 × 11 × 27 608.74(1.1)−10 = 1 170 880.1, the dispersion criterion is now satisfied. Hence we can verify that a gain is realized for different values of yˆ: yˆ 0.08 0.09 0.10 0.11 0.12 A(ˆ y) 21223 19867 18628 17493 16452 L(ˆ y) 21188 19859 18628 17486 16426 S(ˆ y) 35.45 8.26 0.00 7.18 26.83 M-squared M 2 : another measure for interest-rate risk The M-squared of the asset flow {At , t > 0} is defined as MA2 = X wtA (t − DA )2 where wtA = t At (1 + y)−t A. Similarly, we can defined the M-squared of the liability flow, denoted ML2 . We have that the dispersion criterion, together with conditions 1 and 2, is equivalent to having MA2 ≥ ML2 . Example III revisited Let’s compute MA2 and ML2 for the two asset portfolios considered in Example III. • With A7 = 36 300, we have w7A = 36 300(1.1)−7 /18 627.64 = 1 (obvious since only one cash flow), and therefore MA2 = (7 − 7)2 = 0. • With A3 = 10, 625.74 and A10 = 27, 608.74, we have w3A = 10, 625.74(1.1)−3 /18 627.64 = 0.42857 A = 27, 608.74(1.10−10 /18 627.64 = 1 − w A = 0.571428, and therefore in this case, M 2 = and w10 3 A 0.42857 × (3 − 7)2 + 0.571428 × (10 − 7)2 = 12. • For the liability portfolio, we have w5L = 10 000(1.1)−5 /18 627.74 = 0.3333 and w9L = 26 620(1.1)−8 /18 627.74 = 1−w5L = 0.6667, and therefore ML2 = 0.3333×(5−7)2 +0.6667× (8 − 7)2 = 2. Properties of M 2 • M 2 ≥ 0 for all nonnegative cash flows • M 2 = 0 if there is only one cash flow... Hence for the multiple-liability case, we need more than one cash flow for the assets in order to satisfy Redington’s conditions. • Going further, consider the following bracketing strategy: let tL j , j = 1, . . . , n denote the times at which there are liability cash flows. Suppose we have an asset portfolio consisting of two L zero-coupon bonds at time t− and t+. If t− ≤ tL 1 , t+ ≥ tn , and Conditions 1 and 2 are satisfied, then the dispersion condition is satisfied. 9 • Can write M 2 = Var(T ), where T is a discrete random variable with probability distribution given by P (T = t) = wt . Note that in this framework, D = E(T ). Hence we can think of the dispersion condition as a variance condition. • Following the previous point, we can think of M 2 as a measure of immunization risk. Remarks on the Redington Model • Assumes a flat term structure. • Assumes a parallel yield shift. • Immunizes only for small instantaneous shifts in yield • Requires rebalancing dynamically (so that durations of assets and liabilities continue to be equal). • Assumes cash flows are not interest-sensitive. • The same discounting rate applies to both asset and liability cash flow. • Model inconsistency: based on Redington model, we can find a strategy that produces a “free lunch” ⇒ arbitrage. More precisely, since 1 00 0 S(y ∗ + ∆y) ≈ S(y ∗ ) + S (y ∗ )∆y + S (y ∗ )(∆y)2 ≥ S(y ∗ ) 2 00 for small ∆y under Redington’s conditions. That is, since S (y ∗ ) ≥ 0, we are guaranteed to make a profit when there is a small change in y ∗ . This is also called “second-derivative profit”. Rebalancing immunized portfolios The portfolio must be rebalanced (i.e. buying or selling assets) continuously so that the asset duration is aligned with the liability duration. Why? (1) The maturities decrease as time goes by; (2) If the yield changes, then it affects PVs and durations. The following example illustrates these ideas. Example IV: Assume a bullet liability of $20, 000(1.05)13 is due 13 years from now. An immunization strategy is adopted by investing in a 5-year zero bond and a perpetuity, both with ytm 5% (annual effective rate). (1) What should be the composition of the asset portfolio? (2) If the ytm remains at 5%, how should the asset portfolio be rebalanced in 1 year? Solution: Let A5 be the amount to be invested in the 5-year zero-coupon bond, and let A∞ be the amount to be invested in the perpetuity. Here the PV of the liabilities is L = 20 000. So we must have A = A5 + A∞ = L. Alternatively, we can write w5 = A5 /A and then solve for 5w5 + 21(1 − w5 ) = 13 since (i) the duration of the perpetuity can be shown to be (1 + y ∗ )/y ∗ = 21; (ii) A∞ /A = 1 − (A5 /A) = 1 − w5 . Thus we get w5 = 0.5, which means A5 = 10 000 and A∞ = 10 000. (2) Let A15 be the amount to be invested in the zero-coupon bonds (whose maturity is now 4 years) at time 1, and A1∞ be the amount to be invested in the perpetuity at time 1. We must have that A15 + A1∞ = 20 000(1.05) = 21 000. 10 Writing w51 = A15 /21 000, we also need to have 4w51 + 21(1 − w51 ) = 12, which means w51 = 9/17 and thus A15 = 11 117.647 and A1∞ = 9882.35. Implementation issues In general, there is not a unique solution that satisfies Redington’s conditions... Means we have several immunized portfolios to choose from. How should we choose? Must try to optimize some criterion ⇒ optimal asset allocation problem. More precisely, suppose there are n assets on the market, and let Pj be the price for 1 unit of asset j, for j = 1, . . . , n. Let nj and xj denote the total number of units, and total dollar amount invested in the j-th security, respectively: that is, xj = nj Pj . We can then try to maximize/minimize some objective function f (x1 , . . . , xn ) subject to constraints arising, among other things, from Redington’s conditions. For instance, the objective function could be to minimize the M -squared of the assets. In this case, we would have the following optimization problem: min MA2 subject to MA2 ≥ ML2 DA = DL A=L and possibly other constraints Possible other constraints could be, e.g., that a certain maximum amount can be invested in a given security. Possible other objective functions could be, e.g., to maximize the portfolio yield. Generalized Redington Theory of Immunization In this section, we’ll remove the assumption that the term structure is flat, and also the assumption that the interest rate change ∆y is small. We’ll introduce some new notation: Nt = At − Lt is the net cash flow at time t, and P (0, t) is the price at time 0 of a zero-coupon bond maturing for $1 at time t. The current surplus S is given by X S= Nt P (0, t). t>0 Consider an instantaneous shock in the term structure that changes P (0, t) to Pˆ (0, t), for each t > 0. Then the surplus value changes to X Sˆ = Nt Pˆ (0, t). t>0 As before, we’re wondering if it’s possible to construct the asset portfolio so that Sˆ − S ≥ 0 11 (1) for all shocks in the term structure. As it turns out, removing the assumption of a flat term structure with parallel shifts has the consequence that it is no longer possible to guarantee (1) for all {Pˆ (0, t), t > 0}, unless Sˆ = S, which can be shown to be equivalent to having Nt = 0 for all t > 0: that is, the assets are perfectly matched to the liabilities. Note that this means the arbitrage opportunities arising in the classical Redington model no longer exist in the generalized model. What we want to do now is to understand the behavior of Sˆ − S. First, we define nt = Nt P (0, t), the discounted value of the net cash flow Nt with respect to the original term structure. Note that X nt = S t>0 X tnt = Fisher-Weil dollar duration of surplus t>0 X t2 nt = Fisher-Weil dollar convexity of surplus. t>0 We then introduce the function g(t) = Pˆ (0, t) − 1, P (0, t) which we can view as the relative change in the spot rate for period t. Note that g(0) = 1/1 − 1 = 0. We can then rewrite the change in surplus as X X X nt g(t). (2) Nt P (0, t)g(t) = Nt (Pˆ (0, t) − P (0, t)) = Sˆ − S = t>0 t>0 t>0 The main result for the generalized Redington model is as follows: Theorem: If (1) the net cash flows {Nt , t > 0} satisfy either X nt (t − w)+ ≥ 0 for all w > 0 (3) t>0 or X nt (t − w)+ ≤ 0 for all w > 0; (4) t>0 (where x+ = max(x, 0)); (2) P t>0 tnt = 0, then there exists a value χ > 0 such that X 1 00 Sˆ − S = g (χ) t2 n t . 2 t>0 In other words, this result gives us two conditions that enable us to give a more compact expression for the change in surplus. This compact formulation will help us find ways of constructing portfolios that try to maximize Sˆ − S using linear programming. But before we do that, let’s first try to see where this result comes from. We’ll first show that X X Z t 0 00 ˆ S − S = g (0) tnt + nt (t − w)g (w)dw. (5) t>0 t>0 12 0 Assuming g is twice differentiable, we can use Taylor’s formula with integral remainder, which says that Z t 0 00 g(t) = g(0) + tg (0) + (t − w)g (w)dw. 0 Substituting (2) and using the fact that g(0) = 0, we have that (5) holds. The next step to prove the above theorem is to show that the second term in (5) can be written as X 1 00 g (χ) t2 n t . 2 t>0 To do that, we first write X t Z 00 (t − w)g (w)dw = nt 0 t>0 = X ∞ Z 00 (t − w)+ g (w)dw nt 0 t>0 Z ∞X 00 nt (t − w)+ g (w)dw. 0 (6) (7) t>0 To analyze this expression, we’ll use the following result: Theorem: (Weighted Mean Value Theorem for Integrals) If f and h are continuous functions on the interval [a, b] and h does not change sign on that interval, then there exists a number ε in [a, b] such that Z Z b b f (x)h(x)dx = f (ε) a h(x)dx a From this result, and assuming that the net cash flows {Nt , t > 0} satisfy either X nt (t − w)+ ≥ 0 for all w > 0 t>0 or X nt (t − w)+ ≤ 0 for all w > 0 t>0 then there exists χ > 0 such that Z ∞X Z 00 00 nt (t − w)+ g (w)dw = g (χ) 0 ∞X 0 t>0 nt (t − w)+ dw. t>0 Reversing back the order of summation and integration, we have Z ∞X X Z ∞ nt (t − w)+ dw = nt (t − w)+ dw 0 t>0 0 t>0 = X Z 0 t>0 = X t>0 13 t (t − w)dw nt nt t2 2 (8) To conclude the proof, we simply need to note that Condition (2) implies the first term in (5) vanishes. P Note: from (8), we see that the sum t>0 t2 nt can be either positive or negative, depending on which of (3) or (4) is satisfied; Also, the classical Redington model can be recovered as follows: Special case: parallel yield curve shift Assume the spot rate curve is given by the continously (annualized) compounded rates {s1 , . . . , sn }, and that P (0, t) = e−tst . If we assume that the shifts Pˆ (0, t) take the special form Pˆ (0, t) = ect P (0, t) = e−(st −c)t . for some constant c (positive or negative), then we get that g(t) = ect − 1. So in this case, under the conditions of Theorem 1, we get that X X 1 1 00 Sˆ − S = g (χ) t2 nt = c2 ecχ t2 n t . 2 2 t>0 t>0 P 2 In particular, if (3) is satisfied (which is equivalent to having t>0 t nt ≥ 0, i.e., the Fisher-Weil convexity of the surplus is non-negative), then Sˆ − S ≥ 0 for any c. How to use the generalized Redington model From Theorem 1, we know that under some conditions X 1 00 t2 n t . Sˆ − S = g (χ) 2 t>0 How do P we use this result? Ideally,00 we’d like to structure the assets and liabilities so as to maximize 00 g (χ) t>0 t2 nt ... But the factor g (χ) depends on the interest rate shock, which one cannot predict... In addition, we don’t even know whether that P quantity is positive or negative. Consequently, a more prudent approach is to try to minimize | t>0 t2 nt |. In what follows, we’ll briefly discuss how to formulate a linear programming model to solve the asset allocation problem within the generalized Redington model. Optimization Framework—Linear Programming To simplify things, assume the cash flows occur only at the end of each time period, and denote by Aj,t the cash flow at the end ofP the t-th period for an initial investment of $1 in the jth security. Hence for each j, we have that 1 = t≥1 Aj,t P (0, t). As before, let xj be the amount of money to be invested P in the jth security. Hence the aggregated cash flow at time t is given by At = j xj Aj,t . The asset allocation problem is to determine, for a given stream of liabilities {Lt } and surplus S, the “optimal” amounts xj . We can use linear programming to solve this problem, which, in this framework, can be formulated as follows: 14 ˛ ˛ ˛X ˛ ˛ ˛ 2 min ˛ t nt ˛ xj ˛ ˛ t>0 X subject to nt = S t>0 X tnt = 0 t>0 X nt (t − w)+ ≥ 0 or t>0 X nt (t − w)+ ≤ 0 for all w > 0 t>0 where At = X xj Aj,t j We’ll consider one by one the two possible cases given by (3) and (4). In other words, in each case we are guessing that the chosen condition can be made to hold, and try to find xj ’s that will minimize our while allowing that condition (and others) to hold. Note that since the sum P objective function, + is a piecewise linear function of w, to verify whether it’s positive or negative, we only n (t − w) t>0 t need to check its value at points w where nw 6= 0. Since we Passumed before that cash flows only occured at the end of periods, it means we only need to look at t>k nt (t − k)+ for k = 1, 2, . . . . P + Case 1: t>0 nt (t − w) ≥ 0 for all w > 0 R∞P P P P 2 In this case, P | t>0 t2 nt | becomes − w)+ dw = (1/2) t>0 t2 nP t . Furthert>0 t nt since 0 t>0 nt (t P P P more, minxj t>0 t2 nt ⇔ minxj t>0 t2 (At −Lt )P (0, t) ⇔ minxj t>0 t2 At P (0, t) ⇔ minxj t>0 t2 j xj Aj,t P (0, t) ⇔ P P P minxj j xj t>0 t2 Aj,t P (0, t) ⇔ minxj j xj Cj , where Cj = X t2 Aj,t P (0, t) t>0 is the Fisher-Weil dollar convexity of the jth security. Summing up, the following linear programming problem must be solved: min xj Cj xj subject to X nt = S t>0 X tnt = 0 t>0 X nt (t − k)+ ≥ 0 for k = 1, 2, . . . t>k X where nt = ( xj Aj,t − Lt )P (0, t) j and Cj = X t2 Aj,t P (0, t). t≥1 Case 2: P t>0 nt (t − w)+ ≤ 0 for all w > 0 Using a similar development, in this case we get the following formulation: 15 max xj Cj xj subject to X nt = S t>0 X tnt = 0 t>0 X nt (t − k)+ ≤ 0 for k = 1, 2, . . . t>k X where nt = ( xj Aj,t − Lt )P (0, t) j and Cj = X t2 Aj,t P (0, t). t≥1 Case where S = P t>0 nt =0 P In the case where S = t>0 nt = 0, we can say a little bit more about the structure of the nt ’s that is required to satisfy the constraints of the above linear programming problem. More precisely, we have: Proposition: Let ni be the discounted net cash flow at time ti , for i = 1, . . . , m. In order to satisfy P Pn both (i) m n = 0 and (ii) t n i=1 i i=1 i i = 0, the sequence {n1 , . . . , nm } must have at least two sign changes. Proof:(By contradiction) First, there must be at least one change of sign... Then, assume there is only onePchange of P sign of the formP +, − and that the sign change occurs. This Pmtk+1 is the first time P Pk k m k k implies n = |n | and t n = t |n |. However t n < t n k+1 i=0 i i=k+1 i i=0 i i i=k+1 i i i=0 i i i=0 i and Pm P m i=k+1 ti |ni | ≥ tk+1 i=k+1 |ni |, which gives us a contradiction. A similar reasoning can be used to show that a sign change of the form −, + also leads to a contradiction. We can then consider the case where we have exactly two sign changes, and study the two possibilities for that case: + − + or − + − (i.e., + − + means that there exist two indices 1 ≤ k1 < k2 ≤ m such that n1 , . . . , nk1 ≥ 0, nk1 +1 , . . . , nk2 < 0, nk2 +1 , . . . , nm ≥ 0). We get the following result, which is based on the concept of Karamata measures: P P Proposition: If m ni = 0, m i=1P i=1 ti ni = 0, and the sequence {n1 , . . . , nm } undergoes the sign change m sequence + − +, then n φ(t i ) ≥ 0 for any convex function φ(·). If the sequence in instead − + −, i=1 i Pm then i=1 ni φ(ti ) ≤ 0 for any convex function φ(·). The consequence of this result is that if the interest rate shock is such that the function g(·) is convex (for instance, the function g(t) = ect − 1 corresponding to a parallel shift is convex), and the sequence {n1 , . . . , nmP } undergoes exactly 2 sign changes, then using Proposition 2 and the fact that Sˆ − S = 00 (1/2)g (χ) t>0 nt g(t), we can figure out whether Sˆ − S is ≥ or ≤ than 0 depending on whether the sign change sequence is + − + or − + −. Example: (Single Premium Immediate Annuity (Shiu, (IME), 1990)) Consider an insurance company that issues single premium immediate annuity policies. It invests all the premiums it receives for the annuities in a noncallable P and default-free P bond. The company has the policy of matching asset and liability durations. Hence nt = 0 and tnt = 0. Therefore, unless the asset and liability cash flows are perfectly matched, {nt , t > 0} has at least two sign changes. Moreover, the (expected) annuity cash flows are non-increasing with time, whereas the cash flows from the bond are level with the exception of the last one, which is larger because of the principal repayment. Therefore 16 the sign change pattern is actually − + −. Thus from Proposition 2, we can conclude that for any parallel shift in the term structure, the company will lose money. Other immunization techniques To conclude this unit, we discuss a few alternative immunization techniques. Dedication Strategy: Cash Flow Matching This strategy uses a dedicated bond portfolio, which is constructed so that its monthly cash flows match the monthly cash requirements of liabilities. Hence this strategy eliminates interest-rate risk. Some applications of this strategy are for pension benefit funding, structured settlement funding, and guaranteed investment contract matching. A detailed example is presented in Unit 7. Usually, the dedicated portfolio is constructed by finding the cheapest combination of bonds that can provide, at each period, an asset cash flow that is at least as large as the liability cash flow. In other words, we need to solve min X At P (0, t) t>0 subject to At ≥ Lt for all t. Example: Consider funding a stream of liabilities of $300 000, $200 000, and $100 000 at the end of the first, second, and third year, respectively. Construct an optimal dedicated portfolio based on the following bonds. Bond Bond 1 Bond 2 Bond 3 Bond 4 Bond 5 Bond 6 Year 0 Price/unit 100.50 95.40 105.60 95.00 85.00 75.00 Cash Flow Per Unit of Investment at Year 1 at Year 2 at Year 3 10 10 110 8 8 108 12 12 112 100 0 0 0 100 0 0 0 100 Solution: Let xj be the amount of units of bond j in the dedicated portfolio. We need to solve min 100.5x1 + 95.4x2 + 105.6x3 + 95x4 + 85x5 + 75x6 subject to 10x1 + 8x2 + 12x3 + 100x4 ≥ 300 000 10x1 + 8x2 + 12x3 + 100x5 ≥ 200 000 110x1 + 108x2 + 112x3 + 100x6 ≥ 100 000 x1 , x2 , x3 , x4 , x5 , x6 ≥ 0 Using Excel (or Gnumeric) Solver, we find that the optimal solution is 17 x1 0 x2 0 x3 892.857 x4 2892.857 x5 1892.857 x6 0 and that solution exactly matches the liability cash flows. (Or, if we force the xj ’s to be integers x1 2 x2 0 x3 890 x4 2893 x5 1893 x6 ) 1 Advantages of Dedication • Easy to understand • Potential to eliminate interest-rate and reinvestment risk • Not necessary to rebalance (although can be done). Disadvantages of Dedication • Liabilities cash flow are not usually known with certainty. • Perfect matching is hard. Therefore, there is usually still a reinvestment risk, and an assumption on the reinvestment rate must be made. • Lack of flexibility: less interesting bonds (e.g., with lower yield) might be chosen only because of their maturity. Combination-Matching or Horizon-Matching A combination-matched portfolio is one that is duration matched with the added constraint that it be cash-matched for the first few years (usually 5 years). The main advantage of this method over pure immunization is that the liquidity needs are provided for in the initial cash-flow matched period: this eliminates the reinvestment risk for that period. Also, since most of the positive slope or inversion of a yield curve tends to take place in the first few years, by cash-flow matching that portion, we reduce the risk of non-parallel shifts. The disadvantage is that it is more expensive than immunization. Contingent Immunization • Blend of active management with immunization. • Requires to set a floor return, or safety net: portfolio is actively managed until the return hits the floor return; at that point, the portfolio manager must commit to an immunized portfolio to ensure the floor return for the remainder of the investment horizon. Example: Suppose the current interest rate is 10%, and that a manager’s portfolio is worth 10 millions. Assume a 5 year investment horizon. (i) What is the immunizable terminal value in year 5? (ii) The manager wants to pursue an active bond management strategy, provided the net terminal value is not below 15 millions. Find the corresponding floor return. (iii) Suppose that at time 2, the market interest rate is now 9%. What is the minimum value of the fund at time 2 that is required in order to guarantee that the minimum terminal value can be reached? Solution: (i) The immunizable terminal value in year 5 is 10×106 ×(1.1)5 = 16 105 100. (ii) (15/10)1/5 − 1 = 8.44718% (iii) 15 × 106 × (1.09)−3 = 11 582 752. 18 min. term. value trigger level cushion spread t* T Figure 2: Contingent Immunization Remarks on Contingent Immunization: • Has the potential of achieving higher return than an immunized portfolio, but with added uncertainty. • Requires an objective procedure to monitor the portfolio. • Portfolio must remain sufficiently liquid so that if it hits the trigger level, actions can be taken to immunize it. • Choice of the minimum return and investment horizon: a longer horizon gives more opportunity to actively manage the portfolio. We conclude this section with Figure 3, which shows different ALM strategies, going from safe to risky from left to right. combination matching contingent immunization immunization cash flow matching active management Figure 3: Spectrum of ALM strategies Optional Reading Material • Chapter 47 of Fabozzi (7th edition). • Asset-Liability Management, Society of Actuaries Professional Actuarial Specialty Guide, 2003. (UWD1931—also available from www.soa.org) • Immunization for Pension Plans, Educational Note, Canadian Institute of Actuaries, 1996 (UWD 1940). 19 Exercises 1. An insurance company faces a liability obligation of 4 millions in 3 years. The available market instruments are 2-year, 4-year and 5-year zero coupon bonds, each with a yield of 5%. (i) Find two portfolios that match the present value and duration of the liability. (Use the bond yield to discount the liability). For each portfolio found in (i), compute its value a time t = 0 and t = 3 years if there is an instantaneous change in the yield of (ii) 1%; (iii) -1%. 2. Consider a liability portfolio with a cash flow of 1 million at t = 2 years, and 4 millions at t = 5. An asset portfolio based on zero-coupon bonds with maturities of 1 or 6 years is to be constructed. Assume all securities have a yield of 6%. (i) Construct an asset portfolio that satisfies Redington’s two first conditions. What can you say about the fulfillment of Redington’s third condition? (ii) Compute the M-squared M 2 of each of the asset and liability portfolios and verify that Redington’s third condition holds. (iii) How should the asset portfolio be rebalanced at time 0.5 if the yield is now at 5% (assuming no rebalancing has been done so far)? (iv) Suppose now that different maturities carry different yields. More precisely, assume the (continuously compounded) spot rates for 1, 2, P 5 and 6 years are P 0.05, 0.055, 0.07 and 0.075. Construct an asset portfolio that satisfies both t nt = 0 and t tnt = 0. (v) Continuing with the setting given in (iv), what kind of sign change sequence is experienced by the {nt } sequence? Verify by looking at a parallel shift of 0.5% and then -0.5% that the surplus behaves as predicted. 3. You want to fund the following stream of liabilities: 150 000, 350 000 and 225 00 at the end of the first, second and third years, respectively. (i) Construct an optimal dedicated portfolio based on the following bonds (fractions are allowed): Bond Bond 1 Bond 2 Bond 3 Bond 4 Bond 5 Bond 6 Year 0 Price/unit 98.50 96.30 102.70 97.00 91.00 82.00 Cash Flow Per Unit of Investment at Year 1 at Year 2 at Year 3 8 8 108 6 6 106 10 10 110 100 0 0 0 100 0 0 0 100 (ii) Compare the initial amount that needs to be invested for the portfolio constructed in (i) with one that can only use zero-coupon bonds. 20
© Copyright 2024