J. OF PUBLIC BUDGETING, ACCOUNTING & FINANCIAL MANAGEMENT, 24 (1), 83-113 SPRING 2012 WHY MONEY CANNOT BE SPENT AS BUDGETED? LESSONS FROM CHINA’S RECENT BUDGET REFORMS1 Jun Ma and Li Yu* ABSTRACT. To modernize budgeting system is a challenge issue in many developing countries. To some scholars (Schick, 1998a, 1998b; Ma, 2009a), developing countries must first put into place basic budgetary controls before moving to more advanced models of budgeting. This approach of “basic first,” however, is questioned by others (e.g., Andrew, 2006). Drawing on China’s recent budget reforms, this essay reconfirms the validity of the “basics first” approach. In China, budget reform since 1999 has begun to install budgetary controls for state finance, leading to an enhancement of budgeting capacity and financial accountability. However, governments at the same time have begun to be plagued by the unexpected problem of delays in spending and the accumulation of significant underexpenditures. Contrary to what many people may believe, we contend that this somewhat odd problem arises not because the new budgeting system has exercised too much control but rather because the new system is not yet effective in exerting budgetary controls. INTRODUCTION This essay addresses a somewhat odd problem occurring in China’s budgeting execution since the 1999 budget reform. Before 1999, government finance in China had been carried out without effective budgetary controls. In 1999, a budget reform was initiated, which established budgetary controls both within and over the government. For more than ten years, these controls have led to an ----------------* Jun Ma, Ph. D., is a Professor, Research Center for Chinese Public Administration and School of Government, Sun Yat-sen University, P. R. China. His research interests are in public budgeting. Li Yu, Ph.D., is an Assistant Professor of the School of Public Management, Southern China Normal University. Her research interests are in public budgeting. Copyright © 2012 by PrAcademics Press 84 MA & YU enhancement of financial accountability and budgeting capacity in China. Meanwhile--and very unexpectedly--governments at all levels and nationwide have been plagued by the problem of spending delays and the accumulation of significant under-expenditures. This indicates not only low operational efficiency in financial management but also ineffective policy implementation, and has greatly limited the state’s ability to achieve its goals (Ma, 2009a). Why is it so difficult to spend money as budgeted? Is it because the new budgeting system has exercised too much control? Should China pull back somewhat from its effort of imposing budgetary controls in the public sector? These questions are crucial for the next steps in China’s budget reforms. However, even in the Chinese literature, little attention has been given to them. The authors of this paper seek to fill this vacuum despite difficulties in data collection. The difficulties arise mainly from the fact that even ten years after the implementation of budget reform, budget information, especially regarding actual expenditures, is not open to society. This study therefore relies heavily on data collected during our fieldwork conducted from 2003 to 2009. Our fieldwork was conducted in seven provincial-level budgeting systems, including two in the rich coastal region (Guangdong and Fujian), three in central China, where the economy is middling (Hebei, Hubei, and Hunan), and two in the poor western region (Yunan and Gansu) as well as in four municipal budgeting systems, including Taiyuan (the capital city of Shanxi Province, located in central China), Guangzhou and Wuhan (capital cities of Guangdong and Hubei provinces, respectively), and Xiamen (in Fujian Province). In each place, we interviewed financial officials from the finance department as well as several departments (e.g. the planning commission) also holding budgeting authority, different functional departments, the audit department, and the budget supervision office of the legislature. In each place, we interviewed about16 respondents, and each interview lasted roughly fifty minutes. To enhance our understanding of the issues addressed, we also collected and analyzed available documents issued by finance departments, audit offices, and the legislatures at all levels, along with information disclosed in official news reports. We expect that this study will provide some lessons useful for other developing and transitional countries which have been struggling to modernize their budgeting systems. In his oft-cited WHY MONEY CANNOT BE SPENT AS BUDGETED? LESSONS FROM CHINA 85 essay, Schick (1998a) contended that before moving to more advanced models of budgeting, developing countries should first put into place basic budgetary controls in order to implant formality into the governing process. To Schick (1998b), although budgetary controls may reduce efficiency, “the cost is justified when the rule of law is implanted in the public administration” (p. 122). In 2006, Andrews questioned this “basics-first” approach. First, while budget basics may be important, they are not necessarily a prerequisite for a performance-based budgeting reform. Second, budget basics may impede the progression of performance-based budgeting reforms. This is especially true when budgetary controls are unfair and unrealistic. Third, Andrews (2006) contended, factors other than budget basics have affected the progression toward performancebased budgeting. Recently, drawing on Chinese budget reforms, Ma (2009a) endorsed the basics-first approach. He contended that at least in the case of China, it is upon the establishment of basic budgetary controls that China has begun to develop the basic capacity to budget. Is the stage of building budget basics as critical as Schick (1998a, 1998b) and Ma (2009a) assert? The examination of the occurrence of underexpenditures in China’s budget execution will help to enhance our understanding of this issue. Usually, one of the biggest problems in budget execution in transitional and developing countries is overspending and the accumulation of budget arrears (Martinez-Vazquez & Boex, 2000; Schiavo-Campo & Tommasi, 1999, chap. 7). It is true that in a number of developing countries, underspending is a very old problem, usually coexisting with offbudget spending and even occurring in investment expenditures which are on-budget (Schiavo-Campo & Tommasi, 1999, chap. 6). But in China, underexpenditure occurs in almost all programs, and the amounts of it are larger. It is quite easy for observers to attribute the occurrence of underexpenditures to the establishment of budgetary controls since the reform. However, we argue that the occurrence of underexpenditures in China has not resulted from the establishment of budgetary controls since the reform; it instead is attributed to the fact that the establishment of these controls has been incomplete. In the remainder of this paper, we first describe China’s 1999 budget reform, a necessary prerequisite for understanding China’s current circumstances. We then describe the delays in spending and 86 MA & YU the accumulation of unspent monies that have occurred since the implementation of the budget reform, and this is followed by an examination of the problems associated with the occurrence of underexpenditures. Then, we explore possible causes of underexpenditures. Our conclusion and discussion are presented in the last section. THE 1999 BUDGET REFORM From 1949 to 1978, state finance in China was plan oriented: resources were allocated according to a plan, and the budget was merely a tool of plan implementation. From the onset of economic reform in 1978, the planned economy, and hence the plan-oriented state finance system, disintegrated. However, until the 1999 budget reform, there was no effective budget system to fill the vacuum. Consequently, state finance during the period from 1978 to 1999 resembled what Caiden (1989) calls prebudgeting (see in Ma, 2009a, 2009b; Ma & Ni, 2008). On the one hand, state finance was fragmented and decentralized, and consequently lacked effective administrative controls within the government. The fragmentation of budgeting authority within the government is evident in three aspects. First, in addition to the finance department’s serving as the central budget agency (CBA), there existed quasi-central budget agencies (quasiCBAs), e.g., the planning commission (now renamed the Commission of Development and Reform), which held allocative authority over certain fiscal resources. Second, from the 1980s onward, there was a rapid expansion in off-budgetary finance, wherein every department extracted and then spent off-budgetary funds with no supervision. Third, because of the lack of departmental budgets, the finance department tended to allocate budgetary funds in a lump sum to each department which then held so-called secondary budgetary authority to decide where to spend these monies. Meanwhile, financial management was overly decentralized. There was no single treasury account; public monies were dispersed to a variety of accounts that were opened and tightly controlled by various government units which would happily spend monies with no outside supervision (Ma, 2009a, 2009b; Ma & Ni, 2008). On the other hand, for many years state finance in China tended to maximize executive discretion at the expense of legislative WHY MONEY CANNOT BE SPENT AS BUDGETED? LESSONS FROM CHINA 87 oversight. While the government at each level would annually submit its budget to the legislature (the People’s Congress) for review and approval, the budget contained only budgetary revenues and expenditures and was always compiled in aggregate totals, with little information about specific activities or details of objectives of expenditure. Therefore, the People’s Congress merely acted as a rubber stamp in the budgetary process (Ma, 2009a, 2009b; Ma & Ni, 2008). In 1999, China initiated a budget reform which included three major parts: departmental budget reform (DBR), treasury management reform (TMR), and government procurement reform (GPR). The DBR requires that governmental budgets be compiled on a departmental basis. In order to compile departmental budgets, standardized budgetary formats and procedures were enforced. The principle of comprehensiveness, which requires departments to include all of their revenues and expenditures in their budgets, was strictly enforced. Detailed expenditure objectives were adopted in order to present detailed information about planned activities and relevant costs. This served to remove much of the secondary budgetary power that departments had previously enjoyed. In order to reduce arbitrary decisionmaking in resource allocation, new methods of budgeting were adopted: while basic expenditures (personnel and operation expenditures) are budgeted according to a system of fixedquota management (dinge guanli), a modified version of zero-based budgeting was adopted for program expenditures designed for achieving certain policy goals. The TMR was aimed to create a centralized treasury management system to replace the old, decentralized system. A single treasury account system was created. Upon which, a new system of fiscal direct disbursement (FDD) was installed to centralize fiscal disbursements. The GPR was designed to create a centralized procurement system to replace the previous decentralized system. It has centralized in the finance department those procurement activities that were formerly dispersed throughout various bureaus. Open and competitive bidding was emphasized. FDD was adopted for the disbursement for many government procurements, especially large project procurements that in the past were often plagued by corruption scandals (Ma, 2009a, 2000b; Ma & Ni, 2008). 88 MA & YU Facilitated by the DBR, legislatures began to exercise the power of the purse at all levels. Governmental budgets are now submitted earlier to the legislature for review, and, more importantly, as budgets are more comprehensive and broken down to departmental-level details, the legislature can substantially review governmental budgets. Consequently, legislatures have gradually, and for the first time, gained real supervisory power over the government budget and are beginning to place checks and balances on the government’s budgetary decisionmaking (Ma, 2009a, 2009b; Ma & Ni, 2008). The goal of the reform is to create a modern public budgeting system in China, complete with the establishment of budgetary controls both within and over the government. The reform has begun to transform the finance department into a CBA capable of exerting uniform budgetary controls within the government. The DBR centralizes budget authority during budget compilation, while the other two reforms have begun to install ex ante outside controls in budget execution. Meanwhile, facilitated by the DBR, the legislature has begun to play a substantial supervisory role in the budgetary process. The two types of budgetary control have not, however, been equally emphasized in the reform. At present, achievements have been made mainly in the dimension of budgetary controls within the government; with regard to legislative controls, many challenges lie ahead (Ma, 2009a, 2009b; Ma & Ni, 2008). THE OCCURRENCE OF UNDEREXPENDITURES The establishment of budgetary controls has led to a centralization of spending authority, to increased transparency, and to a tightening of expenditure controls, all of which in turn have enhanced budgeting capacity and financial accountability in China (Ma, 2009a, 2009b). For instance, fund diversions, a persistent problem under the previous system, have decreased since the reform (Ma & Ni, 2008). One would therefore expect that budget implementation would be more effective than before. Unfortunately, since the reform, a new and somewhat odd problem has beset China’s budget execution: money cannot be spent as expected or budgeted. At the end of each fiscal year (from January 1 to December 31), a large amount of budgetary funds have not been spent as budgeted, and most of them must be carried over to the next year and even the year after that. WHY MONEY CANNOT BE SPENT AS BUDGETED? LESSONS FROM CHINA 89 These delays in spending and the amassing of a large amount of unspent monies occurred shortly after the implementation of budget reform. By the end of 2001, when the new treasury management system was launched in six pilot central budgetary units, all of them except the Chinese Science Academy had accumulated unused funds (Table 1). TABLE 1 Unused Funds in Six Central Government Units, 2001 (in ¥100 Million) Appropriat ed Funds Ministry of Water Resources Ministry of Science & Technology Ministry of Finance Legal System Office Chinese Science Academy National Natural Science Fund Total Paid Funds Unused Funds 10048.83 5752.44 4296.39 5869.25 4561.69 1307.56 211.77 207.66 4.11 7.61 6.01 1.6 750 750 0 282.6 100.89 181.71 17170.06 11378.69 5791.37 Unused Rate (%) 42.76 22.28 1.94 21.02 0.00 64.30 33.73 Source: Zhang, Lin, Lou, Xu & Li (2002). This accumulation of unused funds continued to take place and became a salient problem nationwide in subsequent years’ budget execution. Between 2002 and 2006, the spending of budgeted funds at the central level was generally slow in the first half or the first three-quarters of each fiscal year. The highest rate of spending usually occurred in the fourth quarter (see Figure 1). Usually, on the last day of the second quarter, only 41% of budgeted expenditures had been carried out (Zhu, 2007). The year 2009 saw no improvement: at the central level, from January to the end of November, only ¥5623.6 billion of a ¥7623.5 billion total budget had been spent; the expenditure rate was 73.8%. In other words, the government was faced with rushing to spend the remaining ¥2000 billion in the last month (Xinhua Net, 2009). 90 MA & YU FIGURE 1 Average Percentage of Expenditure Executed Quarterly Against the Budget Approved between 2002 and 2006 39.5 Fourth Quarter 23.5 Third Quarter 24.1 Second Quarter 17.1 First Quarter 0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 Source: Zhu (2007). The situation is similar at the provincial level. During the years since the implementation of the reform, underexpenditures have been repeatedly singled out for criticism in almost all provincial-level governments’ budget execution reports, actual expenditure reports, and auditing reports, and reviewing reports of standing committees of provincial legislatures. It is a problem for both rich and poor provinces. For example, in Jiangsu, one of the richest provinces in China, the expenditure rate of budgeted funds for the first three quarters of 2005 was only 36.3% (Zhu, 2006). In Shanxi, a province with a mid-level economy and finances, the average budgetary expenditure rate from 2000 to 2004 was only 39.84% during the first six months of each year (Zheng, 2004). In the western province of Sichuan, at the end of June 2006, only 36.3% of the year’s budgeted funds had been disbursed (Chen, 2007). Most surprisingly, underexpenditure was also a problem even in the poorest, most money-hungry provinces. For example, the impoverished northwestern province of Gansu has been troubled by spending delays and the accumulation of unspent monies for years. At the end of August 2006, less than 50% of budgeted funds had been spent, and the expenditure rate for the ¥6.8 billion budget was just above 45%, reduced by 5.15% from the same period in 2005 (Zhou, 2006). Underexpenditures are both good and bad news. They are good news because they mean that the budgetary controls created by the WHY MONEY CANNOT BE SPENT AS BUDGETED? LESSONS FROM CHINA 91 reform have helped curb misallocation, embezzlement, diversion, and other forms of fiscal malfeasance persistent in the older system. Prior to the reform, agencies could easily spend every penny on hand without any difficulty. But the steady institutionalization of budgetary controls has made it harder to misuse and squander funds. For example, the creation of the single treasury system and the adoption of a centralized disbursement system have significantly enhanced finance departments’ ability to monitor fund flows (Ma & Ni, 2008; Yang, 2004, pp. 245, 285). In the 2002 and 2003 fiscal years, facilitated by the new centralized treasury system, the treasury division of the Ministry of Finance (MOF) detected and prevented malfeasance in using and disbursing funds in 61 central-function units and 427 budgetary units, saving ¥2.96 billion in public funds (Wang, Wang & Zhe, 2004). In 2004, 40% (¥6.9 billion) of the ¥ 17.3 billion surplus was generated by the adoption of the centralized disbursement system. The centralized procurement system also contributed substantial savings (MOF, 2006, pp. 140–41). Most importantly, unspent monies are now retained in the coffer of the treasury’s single account and cannot be squandered by agencies. However, underexpenditures are bad news when they are linked to low operational efficiency and ineffective policy implementation. The delay in spending early in the fiscal year has always been followed by a rush to spend at the end, usually associated with waste. Both at the central and local levels, during the years since the budget reform, the rates of expenditure were highest in the last month of the fiscal year. From 2002 to 2006, at the central level, on average 24.2% of the year’s budgetary expenditures were made in December, compared with an average of only 17.1% for the preceding quarter (Zhu, 2007). The situation at the local level was no better. For example, in Jiangsu Province in 2005, 38.9% of the whole year’s budgetary expenditures were made in December (Zhu, 2006). In Anhui Province, of ¥29.42 billion actual expenditures made in 2007, 24. 5% (¥7.19 billion) were made in December (Liu, 2008). Even worse, most of these monies were actually not spent but were simply recorded as disbursed in accounts, resulting in an increasing accumulation of unspent monies, most of which were carried over from one year to the next. For example, according to the 2003 central audit report, at the end of 2002, unspent monies in 129 central budgetary units amounted to ¥64.603 billion. By the 92 MA & YU end of 2003, that amount had reached more than ¥58.938 billion (Li, 2003). In 2006, unspent monies increased by 10% from the previous year; in some central departments the increase was much greater, and certain departments left 50% of their annual budgetary appropriations unspent (Zhu, 2007). Unspent monies can occur in both basic and program expenditures, the two basic budgetary classifications in the new Chinese budgetary system. Basic expenditures are budgeted for public agencies’ personnel costs (e.g., wages and benefits) and operation costs (e.g., facilities maintenance, vehicles), while program expenditures are budgeted for the agencies’ specific policy goals. Unspent monies have accumulated mainly in program budgets. In 2006, of the ¥57.4 billion unspent funds in the MOF’s treasury centralized disbursement system, 93.6% were program expenditures (Zhu, 2007). In China, as in many other countries, unspent monies are classified as fiscal surplus. In program budgets, there are four types of fiscal surplus, which can be grouped into two categories (see Table 2). TABLE 2 The Four Types of Fiscal Surplus Subcategories Institutional Requirements Net Surplus (a) Monies remaining after programs have Spending been completely executed. authority will be surrendered to (b) Unutilized monies resulting from the finance termination of certain programs due to department for policy changes or plan adjustments. (c) Monies that have accumulated after two diversion to fiscal years of no monies having been spent other uses. for the planned program or money left after the third year of program execution. (d) Unspent monies occurring in programs Usually, after a Specific review process, executed but unfinished or programs Surplus of carryover whose implementation has been Program occurs. Expenditures postponed to the following year. Source: MOF (2006). WHY MONEY CANNOT BE SPENT AS BUDGETED? LESSONS FROM CHINA 93 Using this classification, Table 3 presents the fiscal surpluses that amassed in program expenditures at the central level from 2004 to 2007. Most of them are in nature a kind of inefficient surplus associated with unfinished programs. In 2004, their percentage in the total fiscal surplus of program expenditures was as high as 90.94%, and in 2007 it remained as high as 81.06%. Put differently, these are not efficient surpluses -- savings generated as a result of efficiency improvements after programs have been completely implemented. TABLE 3 Surpluses in Program Expenditures, 2004-2007(in ¥100 Million) Number of Central Budgetary Units with Surpluses Total Surplus of Program Expenditures Total Net Surplus Total Specific Surplus of Program Expenditures (SSPE) 2004 12 2005 11 2006 17 2007 19 63.02 29.69 18.99 47.31 0.21 1.99 2.44 6.24 57.31 24.99 16.52 38.35 (90.94%) (84.17%) (86.99%) (81.06%) Note: Percentages in parentheses are the share of the SSPE in the total surplus of program expenditures. Source: NAO (2005, 2006, 2006, 2008). Problems with budget execution also mean that there has been a failure in policy implementation. This is especially true when the unspent funds are concentrated in program budgets designed to achieve specific policy goals. Even more regrettable is the fact that they tend to amass mainly in the budgets of programs designed to improve the quality of life of the citizenry, programs which are desperately needed. For instance, from January to August 2007, in many such programs at the central level, less than 50% of funds budgeted were spent: only 44.9% of the funds for health care were spent, only 48.2% of funds for city and rural community affairs were spent, and only 48.8% of funds for environment protection were spent (Zhu, 2007). In Anhui Province, in 2007, only 74.8% of the funds budgeted for education and 77.4% of the funds for health care were spent, resulting in a large carryover of ¥7,200 million and ¥ 94 MA & YU 3,300 million, respectively (Liu, Z., 2008). This inefficiency in budget execution has greatly impeded the state’s ability to achieve its policy goals. WHAT HAS CAUSEED THE PROBLEM? A number of factors contribute to delays in spending and the amassing of underexpenditures. Some are technical, such as problematic accounting methods (MOF, 2006, p. 140), and hence are easy to deal with. Unfortunately, most are associated with institutional weaknesses in the newly created budgeting system, and these are not easy to handle. It is mainly because of these institutional weaknesses that underexpenditures occurred in China. One form of institutional weakness is the still weak budgetary control developed since the reform, and another is related to the low “capacity to budget” whose improvement demands a refinement of the newly developed budgetary controls rather than lessening these controls. Legislative Controls Remain Weak Since the reform, legislatures have begun to exert the power of the purse in the budgetary process. However, legislative controls are still weak. As far as underexpenditures are concerned, respondents in the fieldwork tended to note the following two factors which are related to weak legislative control. Mismatch between Fiscal and Budgetary Years There has been a mismatch between the fiscal and budgetary years. While the fiscal year runs from January 1 to December 31, the budgetary year starts later; at the national level, it starts after the legislature approves the budget in mid-March. Then, it will take at least 15 days for the finance department to authorize the spending authority to functional departments. This suggests that only after April will departments start to execute the budget. But on December 31, the spending of budgeted funds must cease as the fiscal year has ended. Consequently, at the national level only eight or nine months is left for budget execution, particularly for program budgets. We found during fieldwork that generally, for basic expenditures, departments are allowed to spend the amount in last year’s budget WHY MONEY CANNOT BE SPENT AS BUDGETED? LESSONS FROM CHINA 95 before the legislature approves the new budget, but for program expenditures, such a practice is seldom allowed. This explains why it is program budgets rather than basic budgets that are beset by underexpenditures. The execution of program budgets is further delayed as their executions are required either to go through a complex authorizing procedure or to follow the centralized procurement system, or both, as is the case with infrastructure expenditures. For example, in Guangzhou government, under the current procedure, construction cannot start before August, even if bureaus have successfully gone through the authorizing procedure. In this case, only five months is available for carrying out infrastructure construction (Su, 2006). The mismatch between the fiscal and budgetary years is in fact an issue related to legislative supervision. If it is accepted that only after the legislature has passed the budget will the government be legally able to spend money, the fiscal year should start from the date the legislature passes the budget and end before the legislature passes the next budget. Following this logic, one option for China would be to have its fiscal year run from April 1 of one year to March 31 of the next year. Such a move would help to enshrine the power of the purse and at the same time give the government three more months to execute the budget. Weak Legislative Control over the Use of Overcollected Revenues by Government The second factor contributing to the problem of underexpenditures is weak legislative control over the government’s use of overcollected revenues. Since 1994, each year the amount of fiscal revenues actually collected has tended to surpass the amount approved in the budget. As Table 4 shows, in most of the period after the year 2000, overcollected revenues have constituted approximately 9–10% of the total budget. According to the 1994 Budget Law, as long as the budget is balanced, any changes the government makes to the budget are not considered budget adjustments and therefore do not need to be submitted to the legislature for approval. As the use of overcollected revenues will not result in deficit, such a change to the budget is not a budget adjustment and hence does not need legislative approval. In 96 MA & YU TABLE 4 Overcollected Revenues, 1997–2007 (in 100 million¥) 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 Total (All Levels) 244.06 170 568 1042 1611 899 1190 2785 2372 3307 7239 Percentage of the Budget (%) 2.90 1.80 5.30 8.40 10.90 5.00 5.80 11.80 8.10 9.30 – Total (Central) 76.88 179.94 510 680 748 374 524 1262 1034 1960 4168 Percentage of the Budget (%) 1.60 3.40 8.70 9.80 8.90 3.50 4.40 9.10 6.40 10.20 – Source: Ma, Niu, Yue, & Lin (2008); Han, Du, & Wang (2008, March 7). this context, legislatures at all levels cannot do anything to rein in the governments in the use of overcollected revenues and the latter has a great deal of discretion over the use of this money. Usually, governments tend to use this money either for supplements or to finance new programs because it is forbidden to use this kind of money to compensate welfares of civil servants and operating expenditures of bureaus. However, only in the last two months of the fiscal year will the government be certain there are overcollected revenues. Therefore, it is usually in the last two months of the fiscal year, and even in the last month, that the government allocates overcollected revenues to specific programs, despite the fact that it is close to the end of the fiscal year. In this way, most of such money allocated to programs of departments cannot be spent simply because time available for program implementation is much limited. To be worse, this money has become a tool the government uses for circumventing legislative supervision. This is especially true in places where the legislature is trying to strengthen its oversight over the budget. In order to bypass legislative control, as we found during fieldwork, the government will try to increase the size of this sort of money which can be used, as noted earlier, without legislative approval. One way to achieve this is to deliberately underestimate WHY MONEY CANNOT BE SPENT AS BUDGETED? LESSONS FROM CHINA 97 budgetary revenues at the beginning of the budgetary year and then collect revenues over the budgeted amount during budget execution. The legislature is not blind to the problems associated with overcollected revenues. To solve these problems, in 2006, the MOF, under pressure from the National People’s Congress, began to transfer a certain portion of the overcollected revenues into the newly created Central Budget Stability and Adjustment Fund (CBSAF) which can only be used in subsequent years. In 2008, the MOF further formalized this system. Accordingly, under most circumstances overcollected revenues must be surrendered to the CBSAF; without the authorization of the legislature, governmental departments are no longer allowed to directly use this revenue for supplements or new programs during budget execution. Despite these efforts, the use of this money at the end of the fiscal year is still a dominant practice. At the central level, the government continues to use this revenue without any ex ante approval by the legislature although an ex post report must be submitted to the legislature. As Table 5 shows, around 80% of this revenue continues to be spent during the course of the fiscal year, usually in the form of supplements. TABLE 5 Overcollected Revenues Transferred into the CBSAF, 2006–2008 (in ¥100 Million) 2006 2007 2008 The Amount of Overcollected Total Revenues As a Percentage Collected over Revenues Transferred of the Total Budgeted Amount to the CBSAF 500 2,573 19.43% 1,032 4,168 24.76% 192 1,082 17.74% Source: MOF (2007, 2008, 2009). In some localities, such as Fujian, Hebei, and Jiangxi, provincial legislatures have begun to strengthen their supervision over this kind of revenue. Usually, before a department can use this revenue, it must receive legislative approval (Ma, Niu, Yue & Lin, 2008, pp. 186– 98 MA & YU 187). But in many others, governments continue to have a great deal of discretion over the use of this revenue. Administrative Controls Remain Weak in Certain Areas The budget reform has centralized much power into the finance department, which consequently is moving toward becoming a CBA. However, the centralization mainly applies to off-budgetary funds previously held by various departments, and the finance department is still far from being a real CBA, capable of implementing a uniform budgetary control within the government (Ma, 2007; Ma & Yu, 2007). The Remaining Fragmentation of Budgeting Authority The newly developed budgeting system remains fragmented at all levels, with quasi-central budget agencies (quasi-CBAs) continuing to enjoy budget authority over certain monies. Usually, the finance department turns certain monies over to these quasi-CBAs such as the planing commission, which then allocates the monies to specific programs. Although the new system requires all monies to be allocated to specific spending objectives at the beginning of the budgetary year, quasi-CBAs tend to allocate “their funds” any time they please. Usually, a large proportion of these funds had not been allocated to specific programs at the time the budget was submitted to the legislature for approval, yet, even in the last month of the fiscal year, quasi-CBAs allocated monies to specific programs. Because budgetary funds left to these quasi-CBAs are substantial, the fragmentation of budgeting authority by actions such as described here has been one of the major causes of underexpenditure, as pointed out by Zhu Zhigang (2007) when he was vice minister of finance. Reformers are not blind to the problems associated with this fragmentation. In 1999, the MOF created a system for constraining the budgeting power of these quasi-CBAs. Under the new system, at the beginning of the budgetary year, the Commission of National Development and Reform (CNDR), the largest quasi-CBAs at the central level, is allowed to retain only 25% of the funds it controls as reserve funds, and the other 75% must be allocated to specific objectives of expenditure. Other quasi CBAs, such as the Ministry of Science and Technology (MST), are allowed to retain in reserve only 3% of the total funds given to them. Since 1999, the MOF has WHY MONEY CANNOT BE SPENT AS BUDGETED? LESSONS FROM CHINA 99 repeatedly emphasized that funds controlled by these quasi CBAs must be allocated to specific objectives of expenditure as early as possible (Ma, Niu, Yue & Lin, 2008, p. 156). However, as repeatedly revealed by annual audit reports, this system has failed to serve as an effective constraint. For example, as Table 6 shows, the CNDR, which is responsible for the budget of infrastructure investments, reserved more than half the funds it controls during the period from 2003 to 2005. The CNDR retained in reserve an amount two times higher than the permitted percentage of 25%. TABLE 6 Investment Expenditures Being Allocated to Specific Objectives of Expenditure at the Beginning of Budgetary Years, 2003–2005 (in 100 million ¥) Total of budgetary investment expenditures Total funds directly retained as discretionary money Total funds for programs waiting for feasibility approval or programs involving many subprograms Total funds needing to be further allocated Percentages of investment funds unallocated to specific objectives of expenditure at the beginning of the budget year 2003 304.49 76.13 2004 2005 304.5 354.4 74.8 87.03 54.96 40.3 0 56.9% 22.98 15.1 1.67 57.2% 68.5% Note: Calculated from data disclosed by Li, J. H. (2003, 2004, 2005). Other quasi CBAs, such as the MST, did exactly the same thing. In 2003 at the beginning of the budget year, the MST retained all of its ¥1.701 billion so-called Three Funds for Scientific and Technologic Development (TFSTD) as reserve funds, and it was not until August and even November that these monies were allocated in the form of supplementary budgets to other departments and localities. This consequently left only four months—and in some cases only one month—for budget execution (Li, 2003). In March ,2004, of the total of ¥7.6 billion TFSTD controlled by the MST, only 24% of it (¥1.8 100 MA & YU billion) was allocated to specific departments or programs, and as much as ¥ 1.9 billion was appropriated after December 25 (Li, 2004). From our investigation,local governments are no better than the central government. For example, in 2006, it was found that the Department of Transportation of Hainan’s provincial government had retained 32.18% ( ¥ 282 million) of its ¥ 877 million program expenditures as reserve funds, an amount higher than the permitted percentage of reserve funds, which is 20% of the total program expenditures (Lin, 2007). Separation of the Budgetary and Policy Processes The budget reform aimed to develop a budgetary system able to control the decision making of public managers as well as politicians. Certain achievements have been made, but mainly in normalizing the behavior of departments and their managers. With regard to the actions of politicians, the reform has yet to provide an effective constraint (Ma, 2007). The result has been a separation of the process of budgeting and policymaking in China. First, after the budget has been approved by the legislature, the government and standing committee of the Chinese Communist Party initiate and make new policies, which the finance department must allocate funds to implement. Second, individual politicians initiate or make new policies during budget execution. In many situations, the finance department must also allocate funds for these new projects (Ma & Hou, 2005). In sum, as several respondents pointed out in our fieldwork, while the finance department appears to control the budget, in reality it cannot control policies, and consequently it cannot really control the budget. This split between budget and policy has created a number of uncertainties in the process of budget execution. To deal with these uncertainties, at the beginning of the budgetary year, finance departments have to retain a certain proportion of funds as reserve funds, to be used during budget execution to meet these unexpected expenditure demands, usually in the form of budget supplements (Ma & Hou, 2005). The inevitable consequence of this practice is that many spending decisions are made during the already delayed budget execution, exacerbating the problem of underexpenditure. For WHY MONEY CANNOT BE SPENT AS BUDGETED? LESSONS FROM CHINA 101 example, in Anhui Province, in 2007, there were ¥3.19 billion worth of budgetary supplements. This represented 10.84% of the province’s total budgetary expenditures ( ¥ 29.42 billion) for the year (Liu, 2008). Ineffective Controls over Unspent Funds If the finance department were able to effectively control unspent funds-for instance, by returning such funds to the fiscal coffer and effectively constraining bureaus’ rush to spend at the last moment of the fiscal year, then departments would be forced to improve their operational efficiency in budget execution. Until this becomes the case, department officials have little interest in improving how they spend their budgetary funds because they know that unspent monies can easily be carried over to next year. Since 2005, the MOF has struggled to tighten its control over unspent funds, especially net surpluses amassed in program expenditures. It has implemented three measures: (a) Departments are now required, in compiling their budgets, to include their previous year’s net surpluses in their budgetary requests, and the MOF will take those surpluses into consideration while making the new budget; (b) During the course of the fiscal year, if a department demands supplements or initiates new expenditures, last year’s surpluses will be the first resource taken into consideration as a source of financing; (c) Departments that have accumulated large surpluses must reduce their budgetary requests in compiling their new budgets (MOF, 2006, pp. 137–147). However, in most situations, it is difficult for the finance department to assert authority over the unspent monies. Annual audits over the past several years have repeatedly found certain unused funds were kept or hidden by departments. For example, the audit of 2007 revealed that the CNDR had accumulated a ¥24 million surplus in two programs that were budgeted in the year 2000. One program had been completed, and the other had been terminated, but the CNDR had kept unused monies in its transactional account for administrative expenses for seven years. Similarly, by the end of 2006, the General Bureau of Broadcast and Communication had accumulated a ¥12.84 million surplus across 102 MA & YU three programs, and none of these unspent funds had been rebudgeted into the following year’s budget (NAO, 2008). The same problem exists at the local level. For example, in Sichuan provincial government’s 2005 program budgets, the Office of Poverty Alleviation accumulated a ¥ 547,000 surplus, the Law Enforcement Bureau a ¥ 526,000 surplus, and the Industry and Commerce Bureau a ¥ 400,000 surplus. In all cases, the departments used the surpluses to compensate their operating expenses without any supervision from the finance department (Huang, 2006). Certain provincial governments have adopted measures to tighten the management of unspent funds. For example, in order to increase the speed of spending while controlling waste, the Gansu provincial government issued a notification in 2004. It required departments still holding funds that had not been allocated to specific programs or appropriated to specific units on December 20 to provide a formal justification for their delays in spending. Without an acceptable explanation, unspent funds were to be surrendered to the finance department and diverted to other uses (GOGSPG, 2004). However, as admitted by Zhou Duoming, then the director of the provincial finance department, the problem became worse in 2006 (Zhou, 2006). Fragmented Budgeting Authority in Fiscal Transfers at the Central Level Since the 1994 fiscal reform, which centralized a large amount of fiscal revenues to the central government, China has witnessed a rapid increase in central fiscal transfers, most of which are in the form of earmarked funds. From 1994 to 2007, earmarked fiscal transfers from central level to localities increased from ¥36.1 billion to ¥689.15 billion. In 2004, earmarked fiscal transfers accounted for over 57% of all central fiscal transfers, and between 2005 and 2007, this share ranged from 48% to 49%.2 However, at the central level, budgeting authority over fiscal transfers is very fragmented. Almost all ministries are able to grab monies, ostensibly in the name of various transfer programs, from the MOF. Usually, these funds are budgeted in aggregate total. This therefore grants ministries a secondary budgeting authority to further WHY MONEY CANNOT BE SPENT AS BUDGETED? LESSONS FROM CHINA 103 allocate these funds to various subprograms that have been submitted by various subnational departments during the execution of the central budget. The fragmentation therefore created a long chain of applying, authorizing, and then appropriating fiscal transfers from the center to localities. As the auditor general, Liu Jiayi (2008) recently pointed out that fragmentation has been a major reason for the delay in budget execution and the occurrence of underexpenditures. For instance, in 2007, 50 counties submitted 40,000 programs for agricultural subsidies to relevant central ministries, well indicating how fragmented the central budgeting authority is. And, 39% of which took more than six months to go through the whole process from submission to authorization, and 32% of which took more than six months to go through the process from authorizing to appropriating. Of these 50 counties, 45% received the promised money in the fourth quarter, and even after the fiscal year ended, while¥0.45 billion still had not been appropriated to localities. Consequently, 43% of the 50 counties didn’t finish their programs in 2007 (Liu, 2008). Budgeting Capacity Remains Lower China’s budgeting capacity has certainly improved since the budget reform. However, the development of the capacity to budget is a long and time-consuming learning process, and China’s overall ability remains low (Ma, 2009a). This has contributed to the accumulation of underexpenditures. Low Capacity in Budget Compilation In a system that is not subject to any controls, spending (usually squandering) is the easiest thing to do. Once budgetary controls have been put in place, spending is subject to supervision and monitoring and is no longer as easy as before: for the budget to be efficiently executed, it must be reasonable, predictable, accurate, and specific. In many situations, problems of budget execution, including underexpenditures, arise mainly from deficiencies in budget compilation, as scholarship has found to be true in many developing countries (Schiavo-Campo & Tommasi, 1999, chap. 6). After initiating DBR, China has witnessed a steady improvement of capacity in budgeting (Ma, 2009a). However, it is a process of 104 MA & YU “learning by doing.” It will take time for managers in both finance departments and spending departments to understand the procedural rules of the new system, to collect information about the operation of departments and especially about various programs proposed, and to improve their capacity for budget analysis. In his speech addressing the low efficiency in budget execution, Zhu Zhigang (2007) sharply criticized the low quality of budgets compiled and submitted by functional departments, saying that it was one of the major causes of the accumulation of such a large amount of unspent monies. According to him, in many situations, it was difficult for budget reviewers to understand and then review in a meaningful way many program budgets submitted by departments. It is apparent that some departments do not have a clear and full understanding of the operation of programs they proposed, do not accurately estimate the cost of each program, and may just casually group several and even many different programs into a same package only for the purpose of grabbing monies from the MOF. Budgets compiled as such are inevitably unrealistic, and thus difficult to implement. This is especially true as their implementation is now subject to the newly created procedural rules of expenditure control. The following two cases are illustrative of this point. It was found that in 2005, the Ministry of Agriculture appropriated ¥669 million of its program budgets to the subunits responsible for program implementation as late as November. This was simply because at the stage of budget compilation, the ministry actually didn’t have specific programs for its budgetary requests (Zhu, 2007). Ironically, the MOF itself is also beset by low capacity in budgeting. In 2007, it was found that of the ¥ 255.8 million expenditures budgeted for four MOF programs, only ¥83.7625 million was spent as expected. As much as 67% was unspent. As revealed by the annual audit report, this was simply because the MOF’s budget for these four programs was inaccurate (NAO, 2008). Subnational governments are no better than the central government. Respondents from the treasury branches of finance departments always complained that it wasn’t uncommon that many programs in departmental budgets were difficult to implement simply because the budgets tended to be inaccurate, unrealistic, and in some cases even unacceptable. Under these circumstances, if the WHY MONEY CANNOT BE SPENT AS BUDGETED? LESSONS FROM CHINA 105 treasury office responsibly carries out its function of expenditure control, money cannot be spent. Low Capacity in Cash Management Cash management lies at the core of budget execution. To smoothly execute the approved budget, the finance department must be able to efficiently manage cash flows and make a good match between incoming and outgoing cash. At the very least, monies must be managed to ensure they are available over time to meet approved and acceptable expenditure needs when agencies decide to carry out their programs. This requires a realistic and well-planned cash budget. Currently, at the beginning of budget execution, all departments will negotiate with the finance department about their expenditure plans. However, at all levels, the capacity in cash management is low; what exists is a form of cash control rather than cash management. Usually, as many respondents pointed out in our fieldwork, the finance department tends to impose a much tighter cash control on fund releases in the first half of the fiscal year, but in the latter half of the fiscal year, especially the last quarter, loosens its control in order to spend money before the close of the fiscal year. This therefore delays budget execution and leads to underexpenditures. Moreover, the finance department at present lacks the capacity to develop expenditure plans well to meet the cash needs of different activities of different departments, which requires a scientific analysis of the characteristics and regularities of their activities and then cash outflows. Consequently, respondents from spending departments complained that when they need money to carry out a program, they may not get it from the finance department, and sometimes, when the money finally arrives, it is already impossible for the department to carry out the program. For example, the carrying out of certain infrastructure constructions must avoid the rainy season, which comprises the whole summer and early autumn in many places in China. The best season for the department to carry out these projects is the period from the November of one year to the March of next year. But, when the date of December 31 arrives, the department can no longer use its monies. It must wait until May of the next year to once again start using the funds to finish whatever projects remain 106 MA & YU unfinished, but by that time, the rainy season is again coming. This illustrates how inefficient cash management has delayed budget execution and led to the accumulation of unspent monies. CONCLUSION AND DISCUSSION China is not the only country beset with underexpenditures. For example, as Andrews (2006) points out, in South Africa, the combination of a control-oriented financial management staff and cumbersome disbursement controls has caused delays in the spending of relevant funds (e.g., poverty relief funds) and the accumulation of significant underexpenditures. But, to a large extent the blame for China’s current budgetary woes of underexpenditures should not go to the control system created in the wake of the budget reform. Instead, we argue that the unexpected phenomenon of underexpenditure occurs because the budgeting system remains ineffective at imposing budgetary controls both within and over the government. Over the past several years, as the issue has become more and more salient, governments and legislatures at all levels have started to adopt measures to improve operational efficiency. Many governments have begun to ask departments to submit explanations for delays in budget implementation and have warned that they will take back spending authority over unspent money. At the central level, the legislature and the MOF have repeatedly demanded that quasi-CBAs ensure an earlier allocation and appropriation of funds to specific spending objectives while obeying the predetermined percentage of reserve funds. Some local legislatures have tried to impose ex ante controls over in-year use of overcollected revenues (Ma, Niu, Yue & Lin, 2008, pp. 176–177). However, these measures have achieved little, and the problem of underexpenditures remains a nationwide salient problem. This should not be a surprising finding, because a thorough resolution of this problem demands further adjustment of the power structure between the government and legislature and between various parts of the government (e.g., between the finance department and quasi-CBAs). As Willoughby (1918) argued nearly a century ago, budgetary reform is essentially a kind of political reform which will reshape the power structure. To solve the problem of underexpenditures, China must transform the finance department WHY MONEY CANNOT BE SPENT AS BUDGETED? LESSONS FROM CHINA 107 into a real CBA, capable of imposing uniform budgetary controls within the government. This first requires wresting budgeting authority from the quasi-CBAs. If that can be achieved, the finance department will gain budget authority over the large amount of funds currently controlled by these quasi-CBAs, and then those monies will be subject to the same controls as the funds budgeted for other program expenditures. The finance department must also be given greater power and independence so that it is able to enforce budgetary controls over other departments and resist pressure from politicians. Finally, its authority over spending departments must be strengthened so that it is able to take back spending authority related to unused funds. Besides this, China also needs to greatly strengthen legislative controls over the government. The mismatch between the budgetary and fiscal years should be addressed. If it is accepted that only after the legislature has passed the budget will the government be able to spend money, then the fiscal year should start from the date the legislature has passed the budget and end before the legislature deliberates on the new budget. Such a change in setting the fiscal year would give the government three or four more months to execute the budget. Moreover, China needs to strengthen legislative control over the government’s discretion as to overcollected revenues. This requires a revision of the legal definition of budget adjustment and enforcement of a new rule that every request for supplements or funds for new programs must be submitted to the legislature for approval. In this case, it will be difficult for the government to create and freely spend overcollected revenues in budget execution, which has been a major source of the accumulation of underexpenditures. Undoubtedly, both sorts of power restructuring will encounter much political and bureaucratic resistance. The effort to transform the finance department into a real CBA will be resisted by the quasiCBAs and other functional departments. Some of the quasi-CBAs, such as the CNDR, are currently more powerful than the finance department in China’s political structure. Efforts to strengthen the power of the legislature will encounter much more political resistance because currently the Chinese Communist Party is hesitant to move in that direction. Another lesson that can be drawn from the Chinese experience is that the capacity to budget does matter. In the case of China, 108 MA & YU although at all levels of government the capacity to budget has begun to develop and is improving, it remains generally low in the areas of budget compilation and financial management. This also contributes to the delay in budget execution and the accumulation of unspent funds. Nevertheless, the low capacity in budgeting has not been caused by the newly implemented budgetary controls. On the contrary, it is upon the establishment of these controls that China has begun to develop the basic capacity to budget, as Ma (2009a) has argued. To further improve its capacity to budget, China must not loosen budgetary controls—it must refine them. At China’s current stage of developing a modern public budgeting system, a welldesigned budgetary control system is a necessity. Without effective budgetary controls, misuse of public money will remain as prevalent as it was before budget reform (Ma, 2009b; Ma & Ni, 2008). Under such circumstances there is no hope for Chinese governments to develop the capacity to budget. Moreover, to develop the capacity in budgeting, the finance department, functional departments, and the legislature require sufficient and reliable information about the operation of departments and especially programs. Before budget reform, even functional departments themselves were unable to have such information because monies and hence activities were fragmented even within a department (Ma, 2009a; Ma, 2005). It has only been thanks to the process of installing budgetary controls that all budgetary participants have become aware of the necessity of reliable budgetary information and sound budgetary analysis, and then taken actions to collect and analyze information. Put another way, at this stage of developing a modern budgeting system in China, a well-designed system of budgetary controls will help with the development of a budgeting capacity. In the era when decentralization is in vogue, it is expected that the above argument may be unpopular with audiences. However, as suggested by the Chinese experience, agenda setting for budget reforms must have a historical sense. A reforming package that well fits the needs of one country may not be necessarily suitable for the needs of another country. Budgetary systems in different stages of development face different problems and hence require different resolutions. The Chinese experience is illustrative for other developing and transitional countries either still lacking a proper budgeting system or struggling to create such a system. To a large extent, the argument here echoes Schick’s (1998a, 1998b) call to WHY MONEY CANNOT BE SPENT AS BUDGETED? LESSONS FROM CHINA 109 put budgetary basics first before moving to a more advanced model of budgeting. NOTES 1. This research is supported by 985-3 Research Funds of Sun Yat- sen University. 2. Calculated on data from Li (2006, p. 51), Jin (2007a, 2007b), and Liu Jiayi (2008). REFERENCES Andrews, M. (2006). “Beyond ‘Best Practice’ and ‘Basic First’ in Adopting Performance Budgeting Reform.” Public Administration and Development, 26(2): 147-161. Chen, Z. Y. (2007, August 4). “Audit Report on Sichuan Provincial Level Budget Execution and Other Fiscal Revenues and Expenditures.” Sichuan Daily. General Office of the Gansu Provincial Government (2004). An Urgent Notification on Quickening Spending Speed to Ensure the Completion of the Annual Fiscal Budget. (Ordinance of the Gansu Provincial Government General Office [2004-141]). Gansu, China: Author. Han, J., Du, Y., & Wang, Y. L. (2008¸ March 7). “Overcollected Fiscal Revenues Reached to a New Highest: Where the 723.9 Billion Yuan Over-Collected Fiscal Revenues Go?” Xinhua News. Huang, J. S. (2006, August 4). “Audit Report on the Execution of the 2005 Provincial Budget and Other Fiscal Revenues and Expenditures. Sichuan Daily. Jin, R.Q. (2007a). “The Report on the 2006 Central and Local Budget Execution and the 2007 Central and Local Budget Draft.” Presented on March 5, 2007 to the 5th Session of the 10th National People’s Congress. Jin, R.Q. (2007b). “A Report of the State Council on the Normalization of Fiscal Transfers.” Presented on June 27, 2007 to the 28th Session of the 10th National People’s Congress’s Standing Committee. 110 MA & YU Li, J. H. (2003). “Audit Report on the Central Budget Execution and other Fiscal Revenues and Expenditures in 2002.” Presented on June 25, 2003 to the 3rd Session of the 10th National People’s Congress’s Standing Committee. Li, J. H. (2004). “Audit Report on the Central Budget Execution and other Fiscal Revenues and Expenditures in 2003.” Presented on June 23, 2004 to the 10th Session of the 10th National People’s Congress’s Standing Committee. Li, J. H. (2005). “Audit Report on the Central Budget Execution and other Fiscal Revenues and Expenditures in 2004.” A Report Submitted on June 28, 2005 to the 16th Session of the 10th National People’s Congress’s Standing Committee. Li, P. (2006). A Graphic Interpretation of Intergovernmental Fiscal Relationship of the Chinese Government. Beijing: Chinese Fiscal & Economic Press. Lin, D. (2007). “Audit Report on Hainan Provincial-Level Budget Execution and Other Fiscal Revenues and Expenditures in 2006.” Presented on July 24, 2007 to the 32nd session of the 3rd Provincial People’s Congress’s Standing Committee. Liu, J. Y. (2008). “Audit Report on the Execution of Central Budget and Other Fiscal Revenues and Expenditures in 2007.” Presented on August 27, 2008 to the 4th session of the 11th National People’s Congress’s Standing Committee. Liu, Z. P. (2008). Audit Report of the Anhui Provincial-Level Budget Execution and Other Fiscal Revenues and Expenditures in 2007. A report submitted on August 20, 2008 to the 4th session of the 11th Provincial People’s Congress’s Standing Committee. Ma, J. (2005). “The Goal of Chinese Public Budget Reform.” Journal of Central Finance and Economic University, 10: 1-15. Ma, J. (2007). “The Politics 0f Chinese Budget Reform.” Journal of Sun Yat-sen University, 3: 67-74 . Ma, J. (2009a). “If You Cannot Budget, How Can You Govern?” Public Administration and Development, 29 (1): 3–15. WHY MONEY CANNOT BE SPENT AS BUDGETED? LESSONS FROM CHINA 111 Ma, J. (2009b). “The Dilemma of Developing Financial Accountability without Election.” Australia Journal of Public Administration, 68 (Special Issue): 62–72. Ma, J., & Hou, Y. L. (2005). “The Separation of Policy-Making and Budgetary Process in China’s Provincial Budgeting.” Comparative Economic and Social System, 5: 64-71. Ma, J., & Yu, L. (2007). “A Study of China’s Central Budgeting Agency.” Journal of Central Normal University of China, 46 (2): 1725. Ma, J., Niu, M. L., Yue, J. L., & Lin, M. H. (2008). Readers for Public Budgeting. Beijing, China: Chinese Development Publisher. Ma, J. & Ni, X. (2008). “Toward a Clean Government in China.” Crime, Law & Social Change, 49 (2): 119–138. Martinez-Vazquez, J., & Boex, J. (2000). “Budgeting and Financial Management in Transitional Economies.” (Andrew Young School of Policy Studies ISP Working Paper No. 00-6). Atlanta, GA: Andrew Young School of Policy Studies. Ministry of Finance (2006). A Guideline for Compiling Central Departmental Budgets (2007). Beijing, China: Chinese Fiscal and Economic Press. Ministry of Finance (2008, January 18). Notification on Further Strengthening the Management over Budget Execution. (Ordinance of the Treasury of the MOF, 2008[1]). Beijing, China: Author. National Audit Office (2008, March 24). The Report Audit Results Report # 31(7). Beijing, China: Author. Schiavo-Campo, S., & Tommasi, D. (1999). Managing Government Expenditure. Manila, Philippines: Asian Development Bank. Schick, A. (1998a). “Why Most Developing Countries Should Not Try New Zealand’s Reforms.” World Bank Research Observer, 13 (1): 123–131. Schick, A. (1998b). Contemporary Approach to Public Expenditure Management. Washington, DC: World Bank. 112 MA & YU Su, W. B. (2006, January 1). “There Are Reasons for Municipal Infrastructures’ “Rush To Completion at the End of the Year.” Guangzhou Daily. Willoughby, W. F. (1918). “The Budget as an Instrument of Political Reform.” Proceedings of the Academy of Political Science in the City of New York, 8 (1): 56–63. Xie, X. R. (2008). “Report on the 2007 Central and Local Budget Execution and the 2008 Central and Local Budget Draft.” Presented on March 5, 2008 to the 1st Session of the 11th National People’s Congress. Xie, X. R. (2009). “The Report on the 2008 Central and Local Budget Execution and the 2009 Central and Local Budget Draft.” Presented on March 5, 2009 to the 2nd Session of the 11th National People’s Congress. Xinhua Net. (2009, December 13). “Finance Departments of the Whole Country Have to Spend 2000 Billion in December.” [Online]. Available at http://news.xinhuanet.com/fortune/200912/13/content_12638034.htm . ( Retrieved on Sept. 20 2010). Yang, D. L. (2004). Remaking the Chinese Leviathan. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press. Zhang, T., Lin, Y., Lou, H., Xu, C. W., & Li, C. Y. (2002). “An Investigative Report on the Enforcement of 2001 Fiscal Treasury Management Reform in Pilot Units.” In Y. C. Zhang. (Eds). On Fiscal and Tax Reform (pp. 684–696), Beijing, China: Economic Science Press. Zheng, J. G. (2004). “Report on Actual Expenditures of Shanxi Provincial Finance in 2003.” In Standing Committee and Budget Working Committee of the National People’s Congress (Eds.). A Compilation of the Budget and Actual Expenditure 2004 (pp. 143–153). Beijing, China: Chinese Democracy and Legal System Publisher. Zhou, D. M. (2006, October 23). “Deeply Realizing the Importance of Quickening Spending Progress.” Gansu Daily. Zhu, Y. P. (2006). “Audit Report on Provincial Budget Execution and Other Fiscal Revenues and Expenditures in 2005.” Presented on WHY MONEY CANNOT BE SPENT AS BUDGETED? LESSONS FROM CHINA 113 July 26, 2006, to the 24th session of the 10th Standing Committee of Jiangsu Provincial People’s Congress. Zhu, Z. G. (2007). “Strictly Implementing Budgets To Ensure All Budgets Of The Year Are Executed.” Speech at the Special Meeting on Strengthening Central Units’ Budget Execution, September 19, 2007. Retrieved on January 10, 2008, from the website of the Ministry of Water Resources: http://www.forestry.gov.cn/subpage/content.asp?lm_Tname=jhy zj&lmdm=5100&f_lmname=&id=913.
© Copyright 2024