Should Canada unilaterally adopt global free trade? Dan Ciuriak and Jingliang Xiao May 2014 Should Canada unilaterally adopt global free trade? Dan Ciuriak and Jingliang Xiao May 2014 Table of Contents About the Authors ................................................................................................................................3 About the Paper .....................................................................................................................................3 Executive Summary .............................................................................................................................4 Regional trade agreements are not the only option .........................................................4 The benefits of unilateral tariff elimination........................................................................5 Introduction ............................................................................................................................................7 Background .......................................................................................................................................... 11 The Gains from Trade Revisited ........................................................................................... 12 Trade Policy in a “Made in the World” Production Paradigm: The Rise of Unilateralism .............................................................................................................................. 16 The Pros and Cons of FTAs ..................................................................................................... 18 The Cost of Rules of Origin and the Opportunity Cost of Unilateral Free Trade .. 22 Empirical Strategy ............................................................................................................................. 30 The Level of Protection ............................................................................................................ 32 Taking into account non-utilization of preferences ...................................................... 33 The Welfare Cost of ROOs Compliance ............................................................................... 34 Alternative Closures ................................................................................................................. 34 Results .................................................................................................................................................... 37 Conclusions .......................................................................................................................................... 42 Canada’s gains from unilateral liberalization ................................................................ 43 The opportunity costs of unilateral liberalization are limited .................................. 45 Unilateral liberalization requires active political management .............................. 45 The bottom line .......................................................................................................................... 46 References ............................................................................................................................................ 47 2 Should Canada unilaterally adopt global free trade? Dan Ciuriak and Jingliang Xiao May 2014 About the Authors Dan Ciuriak is Director and Principal, Ciuriak Consulting Inc. and Research Fellow at the C.D. Howe Institute. He specializes in international trade, finance and development. He has wide-ranging experience in the analysis and formulation of public policy, development of legislation, economic analysis in support of litigation (both private and state-to-state), and training and technical assistance in applied trade analysis and modeling. Previously, he was Deputy Chief Economist at the Department of Foreign Affairs and International Trade (DFAIT) with responsibility for economic analysis in support of trade negotiations and trade litigation. Prior to this, he served as Deputy to the Chair of the APEC Economic Committee and as Finance Counsellor at Canada's Embassy in Germany. Mr. Ciuriak holds a Masters in Economics from McMaster University. Jingliang Xiao is a Research Associate with Ciuriak Consulting Inc. He holds a Ph.D. in Economics from the Centre of Policy Studies, Monash University, Australia. His Doctoral Thesis: “A Dynamic Financial CGE Model of the Chinese Economy” was developed under the supervision of Peter Dixon, a leading expert in the field. He also holds the designation of Chartered Financial Analyst (CFA). His research interests include international trade and financial CGE modeling. About the Paper This paper was commissioned for the Canadian Council of Chief Executives (CCCE) as part of an effort to articulate a vision for the future of Canada’s trade agenda. The Canadian Council of Chief Executives brings CEOs together to shape public policy in the interests of a stronger Canada and a better world. Member CEOs and entrepreneurs represent all sectors of the Canadian economy. The companies they lead collectively administer C$4.5 trillion in assets, have annual revenues in excess of C$850 billion, and are responsible for the vast majority of Canada’s exports, investment, research and development, and training. The opinions in this paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the CCCE or its members. To be added to our mailing list or for additional information please contact [email protected]. 3 Should Canada unilaterally adopt global free trade? Dan Ciuriak and Jingliang Xiao May 2014 Executive Summary In recent years, the action in trade negotiations has shifted to various forms of bilateral and regional free trade agreements (FTAs). Since 2006, Canada, for example, has concluded trade agreements with nine individual states as well as agreements in principle with the European Union and South Korea. By definition, these agreements create new market access opportunities, but they can be costly and cumbersome for businesses to use. To take advantage of preferential tariffs, firms must demonstrate compliance with the rules of origin set out in each agreement. To comply with restrictive rules of origin, they must also sometimes bear the cost of sourcing inputs from higher-cost preferential zone suppliers. As a consequence, the utilization rates of bilateral and regional FTAs are often low and the incremental volumes of trade generated by such agreements can be substantially below the levels anticipated based on full utilization of preferences. The administrative costs to firms of accessing preferential tariffs – not to mention the costs to border agencies of administering those tariffs – should be taken into account when evaluating the economic gains from trade agreements, yet such costs are generally ignored in impact assessments. Given these considerations – but also recognizing that Canada cannot stand still while its competitors negotiate preferential deals of their own – the question must be asked: “Is there an alternative?” Regional trade agreements are not the only option It has long been recognized that a tariff on imports is equivalent to a tax on exports (Lerner, 1936). To put it another way, tariffs distort domestic prices and raise the cost of production inputs, which in turn makes it more expensive for companies to produce goods for export. Conversely, the reduction or elimination of tariffs on production inputs – as Canada did in Budget 2010 – can make exports more competitive. Accordingly, a country can in 4 Should Canada unilaterally adopt global free trade? Dan Ciuriak and Jingliang Xiao May 2014 principle improve its competitiveness and export prospects by using a lever that is fully within its own control – that of relaxing its own import restrictions. The Australian Productivity Commission, in a major review of Australia’s bilateral and regional trade agreements, emphasized the comparatively greater scope for unilateral policy reforms. It also noted the potentially counterproductive effects of delaying such reforms to preserve “negotiating coin” – the ability to trade off tariff reductions in the context of a specific set of trade negotiations. According to the World Economic Forum’s Global Competitiveness Report 2013-2014, Canada ranks 14th overall among countries with low trade-weighted average tariff rates. States with more liberal tariff regimes include Singapore, Finland, Germany, the United States, Sweden, Hong Kong, the Netherlands and the United Kingdom. This hints at the positive competitive effects of tariff elimination. The concept of “unilateral free trade” – unilaterally dismantling all barriers to trade without seeking reciprocal action on the part of foreign governments – is not new. Hong Kong has long functioned as a free port. Singapore’s tariff is effectively zero across the board. These two city-states are ranked best in the world by the World Bank at facilitating trade and both perform exceedingly well in global economic rankings. China’s Premier Li Keqiang has endorsed Shanghai’s ambition to become a tariff-free zone and hence strengthen its position as one of the world’s pre-eminent supply chain hubs. The benefits of unilateral tariff elimination Using a general equilibrium model, this paper explores the potential benefits of unilateral free trade for Canada. On the one hand, eliminating all tariffs would cost the federal government roughly $4 billion a year in revenue. Offsetting that, there would be some savings for government on the $75 million currently budgeted for collection of border taxes and the management of free trade agreements. More importantly, this paper projects output gains on the order of one per cent of Gross Domestic Product (GDP) – approximately $20 billion a year based on the level of GDP in 2013 – in additional economic activity due to the cost savings to firms engaged in trade. 5 Should Canada unilaterally adopt global free trade? Dan Ciuriak and Jingliang Xiao May 2014 As shown in the table below, such benefits exceed those from mutual tariff elimination under any of the major preferential trade agreements that Canada has been pursuing. Accordingly, unilateral liberalization deserves serious consideration. In comparing estimated gains from unilateral liberalization and preferential liberalization through trade agreements, it is worth noting that not only do the gains from the unilateral route come without the distortions associated with FTAs, they are certain to be realized since the question of utilization of preferences would not enter into the equation. Estimated GDP Gains for Canada: Unilateral Liberalization and Selected FTAs, percent Agreement Study Unilateral Liberalization Present study (preferred scenario) Unilateral Liberalization Present study (smallest impact with ROOs effects) Trans-Pacific Partnership (TPP12) Petri, Plummer and Zhai (2013) CETA Canada EU Joint Study (goods) CETA Canada-EU Joint Study (all measures) Canada-Korea FTA Ciuriak and Chen (2008) – goods (preferred scenario) Canada-India FTA Canada-India Joint Study (Canadian estimate) Canada-India FTA Canada-India Joint Study (Indian estimate) Sources: as given in the table. % of GDP 1.05% 0.26% 0.40% 0.27% 0.77% 0.11% 0.41% 1.02% As the simulations in the study serve to illustrate, the effects of tariff elimination in narrow but highly protected sectors cascade through the economy, driving structural adjustment not only in these sectors but also in sectors where industrial input tariffs have already been eliminated. The simulations suggest that Canada’s selective approach to trade liberalization is holding Canada back and reducing our economy’s long-term growth potential. Unilateral tariff elimination would propel us forward toward a more productive and technologically advanced industrial base, raising Canada’s attractiveness as an investment destination and the overall standard of living. 6 Should Canada unilaterally adopt global free trade? Dan Ciuriak and Jingliang Xiao May 2014 Introduction In recent years, the action in trade negotiations has moved decisively to the bilateral/regional sphere. In part, this reflected the repeated failures to conclude the Doha Round of WTO negotiations, which until the December 2013 breakthrough on trade facilitation seemed hopelessly stalled. In part, it also reflected the fact that preferential free trade agreements (FTAs) have their own attraction – they allow likeminded states to go further and faster in addressing trade issues than can be achieved multilaterally. However, while FTAs expand trade and generate associated efficiency and economic welfare gains, the FTA route is not without its compromises and complications. As former US Trade Representative Susan Schwab remarked: [bilateral/regional agreements] are of uneven quality. Some … eliminate virtually all barriers between signatory countries, while others exclude whole swaths of commerce. Yet they all exclude, and therefore discriminate against, the vast majority of other trading nations, including most developing countries. And they skew commerce and global supply chains through complex rules that dictate how much of a product must be made in a given location to qualify for duty-free treatment.1 The term “spaghetti bowl” was coined by Jagdish Bhagwati as early as 1995 to capture the distortions introduced by proliferating discriminatory trade arrangements. Because FTAs have not been integrated as they have proliferated, there is a lot more spaghetti in the bowl today.2 FTAs are also costly to use for businesses. There are fixed costs of accessing trade preferences – the administrative costs of demonstrating compliance with rules of Schwab (2011). Bhagwati (1995). The rapid growth in East Asia of FTAs in recent decades has prompted the coining of the corresponding term, “noodle bowl”, to describe the complex trade rules setting that has emerged in the Asia Pacific (see, e.g., Kawai and Wignaraja, 2010). Abreu (2013; 9) provides a detailed up-to-date review of the state of play and trends. She observes that “preferential rules of origin are increasingly becoming an economic, political and trade instrument. Within that context, there seems to be a tendency to design stricter rules of origin that are complemented with various flexibilities, implemented differentially: either temporary or permanent; regime-wide, sector- or product-specific; and towards all or selected RTA partners – e.g. for LDCs.” In short, the maze is growing more, not less, complex. 1 2 7 Should Canada unilaterally adopt global free trade? Dan Ciuriak and Jingliang Xiao May 2014 origin (ROOs). There are also variable costs – the penalty that firms pay by sourcing from higher-cost preferential zone suppliers to comply with restrictive ROOs. Because of these costs, utilization rates of preferences are often low and the extent of trade engendered by FTAs is often substantially below levels predicted on the assumption of full utilization. Moreover, the administrative cost of accessing the regime by firms and of administering the regime by border agencies should be recognized in evaluating the gains from trade generated by FTAs; however, these costs are generally ignored in impact assessments.3 FTAs are also are hard to get – especially for a middle-ranked economic power like Canada which tends not to be on other countries’ “A” list for negotiations. The recently announced agreement between Canada and the European Union took over half a decade to progress from joint study to reaching an agreement in principle; the CanadaKorea negotiation took nine years to complete. And of course, being a middle power, Canada has weaker bargaining power in a bilateral context. Yet, recognizing that a country cannot stand still while its competitors are seeking to undercut its global market position by carving out preferential deals of their own, the question must be asked: “Is there an alternative?” FTAs are not the only alternative to WTO agreements to improve a country’s competitive position in the global economy. Unilateral liberalization is another option. It has long been recognized that a tariff on imports is equivalent to a tax on exports (Lerner, 1936). For example, the removal of a tax on imports boosts imports. This leads to production cost reductions that make exports more competitive. The competitive pressure of new import entry into the domestic market is another channel through which domestic competitiveness is increased. The expansion of two-way trade results in more domestically-oriented companies participating in international trade – both as exporters and as importers of intermediate goods and services – which boosts their productivity through knowledge gained from interaction with foreign clients and suppliers. In the longer run, exchange rate adjustments also work to restore trade Note that conventional trade modelling of FTAs quantifies trade diversion and thus takes into account the variable costs of FTAs. 3 8 Should Canada unilaterally adopt global free trade? Dan Ciuriak and Jingliang Xiao May 2014 equilibrium. In short, liberalizing imports works through various channels to expand exports. According to the World Economic Forum’s Global Competitiveness Report 2013-2014, Canada is a highly open economy but still ranks 14th overall behind a number of countries. For example, Singapore, Finland, Germany, the United States, Sweden, Hong Kong, the Netherlands, and the United Kingdom all have a lower trade-weighted average tariff rate than Canada and all are highly competitive. This hints at the positive competitive effects of lower trade protection. Further, while a major selling point of FTAs is that they enable forward movement on services and investment and other “new” issues, the reality is that old-fashioned trade in goods still accounts for an outsized share of Canada’s international earnings and payments (Table 1). Table 1: Share of Canada’s International Receipts and Payments by Source, 2012 Receipts Share Total 73.5% 8.2% 7.2% 0.5% 89.4% ofShare ofPayments Share of Share Commercial Total Commercial Goods 462,528 82.2% 474,544 68.7% 82.0% Commercial Services 51,597 9.2% 48,247 7.0% 8.3% Earnings on FDI 45,390 8.1% 45,129 6.5% 7.8% Royalties and Licenses 2,944 0.5% 10,465 1.5% 1.8% Total “Commercial” 562,459 100.0% 578,385 83.7% 100.0% Other Receipts/Payments 66,548 112,837 Total Receipts/Payments 629,007 100.0% 691,222 100.0% Source: Statistics Canada, Balance of Payments Statistics; note that the estimate for royalties and license receipts is for 2011 and sourced from the IMF, converted to Canadian dollars at the 2011 Bank of Canada annual average exchange rate. As can be seen, commercial services, earnings on direct investment and intellectual property charges account for only about 15-16% of the overall total receipts or payments, or about 18% of total “commercial” trade (i.e., excluding international transportation payments and tourism). Moreover, liberalization of goods trade leverages trade in embedded business services and technology.4 Liberalization of goods trade thus remains a key element of any trade policy. On the share of business services embodied in goods exports, see, e.g., Koopman et al. (2011); Table 5. Note that receipts on international transactions include, in the case of goods and services 4 9 of Should Canada unilaterally adopt global free trade? Dan Ciuriak and Jingliang Xiao May 2014 Accordingly, a country can in principle improve its competitiveness and export prospects by using a lever that is fully within its own control – reducing its own import restrictions. The Australian Productivity Commission, in its major review of Australia’s bilateral and regional trade agreements, emphasized the comparatively greater scope for unilateral policy reforms and the potentially counterproductive effects of delaying such reforms to preserve “negotiating coin” for negotiated agreements. The Productivity Commission concluded that such “coin” was of limited value for an economy in Australia’s position5 – which is not unlike Canada’s position. There are some examples of countries that have adopted unilateral free trade. Hong Kong has long functioned as a free port. Singapore’s tariff is effectively zero across the board. These two city-states sit close to the top of the rankings in the World Bank’s Doing Business survey in the Trading Across Borders comparisons and both perform exceedingly well in global economic rankings. Notably, China’s Prime Minister Li Keqiang is championing an idea to establish an extensive free trade zone in Shanghai to make this mega city the world’s leading supply chain hub.6 Meanwhile, Gordon Crovitz, the Wall Street Journal’s Information Age columnist, has observed that “The global information and technology industries in particular have thrived in nearly Hong Kong-like conditions.”7 Of course, what is feasible for cities or city states – or for particular industries – may be more problematic for larger, diversified economies. Is unilateral free trade an option that can realistically be considered by a large continental economy such as Canada, either as an alternative or complement to engagement in FTAs to improve its global competitive position? exports, the value of imported inputs; subtracting the import content of exports would modify the shares of net earnings reported in Table 1. 5 Productivity Commission (2010); see in particular the discussion at 214-216. The Commission also noted that unilateral liberalization did not involve binding the tariffs at the new lower levels; this retained negotiating leverage. On both accounts – limited benefits in terms of leverage and limited costs from unilateral liberalization – the issue of negotiating coin amounts to small potatoes. 6 The Economist “Free-trade zone for Shanghai: Mr Li's big idea,” 13 June 2013. The Shanghai free trade zone will initially be limited to a circumscribed area in Shanghai’s Pudong New Area but may eventually be increased to cover the entire Pudong district. Other Chinese industrial hubs are lobbying for similar treatment. 7 See Gordon Crovitz, “A Better Way to Free Trade,” Wall Street Journal, 18 August 2008. 10 Should Canada unilaterally adopt global free trade? Dan Ciuriak and Jingliang Xiao May 2014 We explore this question in this paper, paying particular attention to the context in which the global economy operates today, in which products are “made in the world” in global value chains. Section 2 considers the role of trade policy in the current global economic context, summarizes the well-rehearsed arguments concerning the utility of FTAs in achieving trade policy aims, and considers the cost of rules of origin and the opportunity costs of unilateral liberalization. Section 3 sets out an empirical strategy to evaluate the gains for Canada from unilateral liberalization. Section 4 sets out the results. Section 5 provides a discussion and draws policy conclusions. Background This section summarizes research to provide evidentiary support for the following claims that underpin the cost-benefit analysis in this paper of unilateral liberalization: That the gains from trade for Canada are very significant and that, even at Canada’s advanced stage of trade liberalization, the remaining unrealized gains are important. That unilateral trade liberalization is emerging as the trade policy paradigm for a “made in the world” production paradigm. That preferential trade agreements liberalize trade incompletely because of the costs of accessing preferences. That there are significant welfare costs associated with accessing preferences. That the scale of the fiscal costs for Canada of moving to unilateral free trade can easily be offset in a technical sense. That the opportunity costs to Canada of moving to unilateral free trade are moderate. 11 Should Canada unilaterally adopt global free trade? Dan Ciuriak and Jingliang Xiao May 2014 The Gains from Trade Revisited The economist’s case for trade is essentially about imports. Short-run considerations and the firm-level dynamics to be discussed below aside, a country would only ship valuable goods and services abroad in exchange for something it considers more valuable – this could be gold in a traditional mercantilist perspective, cheaper consumer goods in a modern static economic welfare analysis based on consumer surplus, or advanced technology and production inputs in a dynamic growth framework. Whichever perspective one adopts, the main objective of trade is what is imported; exports are the price a country pays in order to have access to imports. Economic theory points out the advantages to engaging in trade: deepening trade through mutual specialization in areas of comparative advantage allows trading partners to expand their combined production beyond what would be possible without trade. But the point of trade remains the imports, including both goods and services and, in a broader sense, the technology embedded in imports or acquired from abroad through licensing arrangements. Knowledge spillovers that firms obtain in international markets and the pro-competitive effects of imports on domestic markets simply add gravy. The following question then arises: given where Canada presently is in terms of remaining trade constraints and the resulting share of trade in the economy, how significant are the remaining gains from trade? Formally, across a widely used class of theoretical trade models, the gain from trade (that is, the change in real income from trade liberalization) can be evaluated based on the share of imports in total domestic expenditure and the degree of substitutability of imports for domestic production.8 Arkolakis et al. (2012) show that the real income gains from moving from autarky to an observed level of import penetration under widely used applied trade models can be calculated by the following expression: 1 − λ −1/ε , where λ is the share of domestic goods in domestic expenditure and ε is the substitution elasticity which measures the degree of substitutability of imports for domestic production. Based on this equation, the gains from trade are greater: (a) the 8 Note: the trade elasticity has different structural interpretations in the various models. This affects how we understand the gains to arise but not affect the size of the gains in these models. 12 Should Canada unilaterally adopt global free trade? Dan Ciuriak and Jingliang Xiao May 2014 higher the share of imports in domestic final expenditure; and (b) the less that domestic production is substitutable for imports. The intuition is straightforward: Canada, which accounts for less than 3% of global GDP, produces only a small share of all the varieties of goods produced in the world, including intermediate production inputs. That being said, if Canadian-produced goods are highly substitutable for foreign products, the gain from switching to the imported variety is small. If, however, Canadian-produced goods are not close substitutes (or if, in the case of intermediate inputs, there are no suitable Canadian products) then the gains from trade become large. Following Arkolakis et al. (2012), we evaluate the gains from trade for Canada. Canada’s import share is about three times larger than that of the United States and accordingly its income gains from trade are also about three times larger. Measured using the assumptions in Arkolakis et al, we obtain a range of 2.3% to 4.6% as a share of GDP for Canada, compared to the 0.7% to 1.4% range for the United States reported in the latter study.9 However, Ossa (2012), in his paper entitled “Why Trade Matters After All”, applies the same approach but disaggregates imports across sectors and takes into account that some goods and services are non-traded and that in some industries critical inputs must be imported (i.e., there is no domestic supply and as a result the trade elasticity falls to near zero). Using 2000 data, he estimates Canada’s welfare gains from trade at about 50%, given the import share of final consumption in that year. As the title of his article states, trade is important after all.10 Modern trade theory adds an additional wrinkle to the above results. The new consensus trade theory emphasizes firm-level heterogeneity – even within the same industry – and firm level dynamics in terms of exit and entry and innovation. The Canada’s import share is about 21% whereas that of the United States is about 7%; both figures are based on the methodology employed by the OECD. 10 Costinot and Rodriguez-Clare (2013) develop this point further; they provide estimates of the income gains from trade for Canada under various theoretical models; these estimates range from 3.8% in the simple Armington model to as high as 39.8% in a Melitz-type model with imperfect competition. Melitz and Redding (2014) show that, when productivity of firms is increased by trade, the gains from trade expand as the stages of production in a sequential production model increase. 9 13 Should Canada unilaterally adopt global free trade? Dan Ciuriak and Jingliang Xiao May 2014 theory takes into account the existence of fixed costs of engaging in international markets, either to export or to import intermediate goods and services, and demonstrates gains from trade through a number of different channels: the reallocation of market share from less to more productive firms;11 the dynamic effect flowing from export market entry to product and production process innovation;12 the productivity gains from access to imported intermediate goods and services;13 and “learning by exporting” by firms that enter into international trade, including through the relaxation of firm-level credit constraints as global financial markets learn about new exporters (i.e., entry into exporting signals dynamism and profitability).14 At the same time, the firm-level trade literature provides new insights into the complex global strategies of multinational firms;15 the factors that motivate the formation of global value chains (GVCs) such as the “servitization” of manufacturing,16 and the emergence of a growing “trade in tasks”.17 This theory generates predictions that align well with many observed facts, including inter alia: not all firms export and only, larger, more productive firms tend to enter export markets; there is constant entry and exit from export markets; trade liberalization drives up average productivity in import-competing industries (exit of least productive firms); and countries start to export in new areas following the reduction of trade barriers (i.e., there is an “extensive margin” response to trade liberalization – firms entering into exporting or existing exporters introducing new products into export markets). Melitz (2003), Bernard, Eaton, Jensen and Kortum (2003). Melitz and Trefler (2012). 13 Kasahara and Rodrigue (2008) 14 Silva, Afonso and Africano (2012) provide a good review of the historical background of scholarship on the “learning by exporting” concept. See Ciuriak (2013) for a recent survey of the now extensive literature on this topic. 15 Antràs and Helpman (2004, 2008), Helpman (2006). 16 Neely et al.(2011). 17 Grossman and Rossi-Hansberg (2008, 2012), Van Assche (2012). 11 12 14 Should Canada unilaterally adopt global free trade? Dan Ciuriak and Jingliang Xiao May 2014 Importantly, the gains from trade at the extensive margin of trade are additional to the gains evaluated under models that do not take into account firm-level heterogeneity. Felbermayr et al. (2013) find that the failure to account for these gains in an accounting exercise such as conducted by Arkolakis et al. (2012) results in a significant underestimation of the gains, although there is considerable variation in the degree of underestimation by country, and for Canada the underestimation is fairly small (between 0.3% to 0.5% of real income gain under alternative assumptions).18 To summarize, the absolute size of the gains from trade for Canada are open to debate; however, they are clearly: increasing with the degree of openness of the economy measured in terms of the share of imports; inversely related to the substitutability of Canadian production for foreign production – in particular, if foreign products and intermediate production inputs do not have close substitutes in Canada the gains rise steeply; and increasing at the extensive margin through the entry of new products and new firms into trade. For a relatively highly open economy such as Canada, the remaining gains from trade liberalization are likely to be moderate in size when evaluated in terms of additional income gains; however, the gains at the extensive margin remain highly important given the impetus to productivity and innovation at the firm level that is associated with firms entering international markets as exporters or as importers of intermediate inputs. Trade theory today has been grafted onto an underlying theory of industrial dynamics in which firms must continually make technology bets. Successful bets allow firms to continue in business; unsuccessful bets lead to the exit ramp. Firms and products come and go; there is a constant churn. The theory fits available evidence well. While the Arkolakis et al. (2012) evaluation of the gains from trade included the workhorse Melitz model that incorporates firm-level heterogeneity, it did so under restrictive assumptions that eliminated the extensive margin impacts that firm-level models generate. See on this point Felbermayr et al. (2013). In the latter study, the absolute gains from trade for Canada vary from 2.5% to 8.7% depending on the specific assumptions applied in this study (see Felbermayr et al. (2013), tables 2 and 3). 18 15 Should Canada unilaterally adopt global free trade? Dan Ciuriak and Jingliang Xiao May 2014 It is the firms that make the jump from domestic orientation to global orientation that drive productivity growth in an economy and that ultimately generate the exports that pay for imports. The cohort of exporting firms must however be constantly replenished (that is the message of the extensive margin). Policies that constrain the emergence of these firms – including those that raise the cost of leading-edge production inputs and those that generate general equilibrium effects that raise the cut-off point for new exporter entry – undermine an economy’s dynamism. Such policies – in Canada’s case a tariff legacy from an era that has come and gone – are a liability today. Trade Policy in a “Made in the World” Production Paradigm: The Rise of Unilateralism O’Rourke (2000; 841) in his review of British trade policy in its free trade era in the 19th Century observes that “One of the most important functions of economic history is to alert economists to the obvious fact that the ‘correct’ model may vary over time, whether the issue is the relationship between tariffs and growth, or the determination of the level and structure of protection.” Reviewing the evolution of trade policy in a long historical perspective does indeed generate insights into some recent trends in this area. As O’Rourke recounts, Britain’s free trade policy, which was virtually sacrosanct after 1846, came increasingly under question, particularly after the turn of the century. The British faced rising competition from industrializing Germany and the United States, both of which were using tariff protection to support industrialization. For much of the 20th Century, trade policy globally was then marked by protectionism as countries sought to industrialize behind tariff walls. In the postwar era, trade liberalization was achieved only through reciprocal agreements, initially on a multilateral basis under the GATT and subsequently under regional agreements. A considerable body of economic literature was developed to explain the phenomenon, with a key idea being that reciprocal negotiations enabled countries to break out of a terms-of-trade-driven “Prisoner’s Dilemma”. Insofar as tariffs force foreign exporters to lower their prices, a country improves its terms of trade through trade protection. However, when all countries engage in this, the result 16 Should Canada unilaterally adopt global free trade? Dan Ciuriak and Jingliang Xiao May 2014 is a sub-optimal global production system with all losing. Reciprocal negotiations represented a rational way out of this bind.19 In the late 20th Century, however, unilateral trade liberalization emerged again but with a very different dynamic – driven not by the world’s industrial leader as was the case in nineteenth century Britain, but by developed and developing countries alike. As documented by Martin and Ng (2004), between 1983 and 2003, globally, applied tariffs declined from 29.9% to 9.3%, with autonomous liberalization accounting for 2/3 of the liberalization (compared to about 25% by multilateral cuts and only 10% by FTAs). Poorer countries (such as China and India) made greater unilateral tariff cuts than the richer.20 As Baldwin (2011) argues, this move was associated with the incipient change in the global production paradigm (in his terms the “great unbundling”), evidence for which is that unilateral liberalization was (a) particularly pronounced in parts and components, and (b) associated with outsourcing of labour-intensive production from rich countries to the developing economies. As global integrative trade accelerated in the 1990s, so did unilateral liberalization. Supporting this thesis is the fact that advanced industries that have emerged in the context of the new global production paradigm operate globally under effectively free trade conditions.21 Canadian trade policy has been generally well attuned to these realities. The move to abolish tariffs on 1,541 industrial inputs in Budget 2010 was undertaken with the express intent to “reduce customs compliance costs, allow for simplification of the tariff structure and eliminate the administrative burden of complying with rules of origin and with drawback regulations related to imports under these tariffs.”22 The See Bagwell and Staiger (2011) for a formal exposition of this argument. Another rationale that has been advanced to explain the need for reciprocity is that international treaties enable governments to make credible commitments to their own private sectors; see e.g., Maggi and Rodriguez-Clare (2007). 20 The basic source is a World Bank mimeo by Will Martin and Francis Ng, which has been widely cited in the literature; and Schiff, Hoekman and Goto (2006). See also Langhammer (2011). 21 See, Gordon Crovitz, “A Better Way to Free Trade,” Wall Street Journal, 18 August 2008. 22 Red-Tape Reduction Commission, “Making Canada a Tariff-Free Zone for Industrial Manufacturers,” (archived); see links to Budget 2010, Annex 5: Tax Measures: Supplementary Information and Notices of Ways and Means Motions, Customs Tariff Measures; and Bill C-9, An Act to implement certain provisions of the budget tabled in Parliament on March 4, 2010 and other measures. 19 17 Should Canada unilaterally adopt global free trade? Dan Ciuriak and Jingliang Xiao May 2014 recognition of the administrative burdens associated with meeting duty drawback regulations is important: even without ROOs, tariffs put administrative hurdles in the way of global systems of production; with ROOs, the hurdles rise. The above discussion points to several conclusions. First, the major trade policy issue of the day is no longer the terms-of-trade prisoner’s dilemma. This has been in part tamed by the WTO tariff bindings and perhaps even more forcefully by the emergence of the “made in the world” production paradigm that makes tariffs a decidedly suboptimal form of industrial policy. Self-interest now drives countries towards free trade. Second, some states and some global industries operate under essentially free trade conditions – and prosper. The times have changed and so apparently has the optimal trade policy. Is there a residual case for reciprocity? Put another way, are there significant opportunity costs to unilateral liberalization? We turn to this question next. The Pros and Cons of FTAs The pros and cons of preferential trade agreements have been dealt with in considerable depth in the literature23 and do not bear more than a quick summary. The positive case for FTAs can be summarized as follows: They allow faster and deeper trade and investment liberalization than is possible at the multilateral level. They allow experimentation in terms of developing WTO-plus trade rules that can then be rolled out at the multilateral level if successful. Some areas of international commerce are intensely bilateral in nature and can only be effectively negotiated on a bilateral basis, e.g., services sectors where mutual recognition of credentials of service providers is involved They serve as building blocks towards multilateral trade liberalization by consolidating a large number of countries into a handful of trading blocs facilitating negotiations towards a multilateral agreement. See in particular the recent in-depth reviews of preferential trade in the WTO’s 2011 World Trade Report (WTO, 2011), and Australia’s Productivity Commission (2010). 23 18 Should Canada unilaterally adopt global free trade? Dan Ciuriak and Jingliang Xiao May 2014 They trigger a domino effect as non-participants have an incentive to join regional groups or form their own (“competitive trade liberalization”). Some of the measures negotiated in preferential agreements are non-discriminatory and thus generate benefits on a multilateral basis. The concerns that have been raised concerning FTAs can be summarized as follows: They introduce discrimination into the trading system which in turn generates trade diversion that reduces the welfare gains from the trade that is created by the agreement. They generate welfare costs to non-participants. The fixed costs of accessing preferences skew the playing field for private sector firms in favour of the large, weakening the dynamic renewal of the private sector through competition. They induce investment patterns that are globally suboptimal resulting in future adjustment costs when preference erosion eventually exposes the inefficient industries, whose growth was induced by preferences alone, to global competition. The asymmetric bargaining power can result in the parties with weaker bargaining power being locked into policies that are suboptimal for them. FTAs have been used for global standards competition; differing standards can create prohibitive non-tariff barriers to trade between blocs. They constitute an inefficient path to multilateral free trade – and indeed can serve as a stumbling block by creating rents that generate lobby activity to protect existing preferences. They can generate political frictions among beneficiary and excluded countries – as, for example, the WTO trade disputes over bananas illustrate. Anecdotal evidence can be adduced for all of these arguments as they typically were inspired by specific examples. However, with a few notable exceptions, systematic evidence is not available to allow a comprehensive evaluation. Regarding the question of whether FTA trade creation dominates trade diversion or vice versa, the conventional wisdom at this point is that trade creation is the norm and trade diversion the exception, and that where diversion is observed it is fairly minor (Freund and Ornelas, 2010). That being said, the outcome depends heavily on the height of tariffs facing third parties – the higher these tariffs, the greater the scope for 19 Should Canada unilaterally adopt global free trade? Dan Ciuriak and Jingliang Xiao May 2014 welfare-reducing trade diversion.24 From a Canadian perspective, the low general level of tariffs facing non-FTA parties means that trade diversion is likely to modest. On the building block/stumbling block question, the discussion has moved beyond conjecture to theoretical exposition, where it has been shown that FTAs can be either (Aghion, Antràs and Helpman, 2006). Empirical analysis shows that, for the two largest trading economies, the United States and the EU, multilateral tariff reductions for preferentially traded goods are significantly lower than for non-preferentially traded goods. This suggests a stumbling block effect (Limão, 2006). Limão (2007) also provides evidence that the non-trade objectives of preferential agreements work to hinder multilateral trade liberalization. Regarding the domino effect of preferential agreements, the proliferation of FTAs certainly suggests the action of a building block effect. The push to conclude the USKorea FTA hot on the heels of the EU-Korea FTA is a case in point. The same dynamic was cited by the Government of Canada as propelling the Canada-Korea FTA that was finally concluded in April 2014. Much of the evidence on the trade creating/trade diverting effect of RTAs comes from the gravity model literature. Estimates of the impact of FTAs vary widely; see, for example, Hoekman, Schiff and Goto (2006), who report very significant variation from one PTA to the next as regards the degree of overall increase in imports and exports and increase in intra-PTA imports. To some extent, differences reflect methodological issues – most importantly taking into account the endogeneity of FTAs and the question of direction of causality (does intensity of trade induce countries to form FTAs or does the decision to enter into a PTA generate the observed trade intensity?). Baier and Bergstrand (2007) provide a good discussion of the issues. From an a priori perspective, the one thing that is hard to square is a finding that FTAs only create trade and do not divert trade. This follows from two methodological considerations. First, there is a “compression effect” from the presence of sunk costs of entering foreign markets; as a result, firms enter fewer markets than they otherwise would. By the same token, at least some firms that have options across different foreign markets and choose the PTA partner must be diverted by the PTA. Second, from the perspective of standard Armington-type trade models, the substitution elasticities across competing sources of imports are generally understood to be higher than between domestic products and foreign products (reflecting a “home bias” in consumer preferences). Accordingly, insofar as preferences induce substitution away from domestic products they are likely to have even more powerful effects in inducing substitution away from competing imports from third parties. This effect would be much stronger with high tariffs against third parties, as indicated by the Hoekman, Schiff and Goto (2006) results. 24 20 Should Canada unilaterally adopt global free trade? Dan Ciuriak and Jingliang Xiao May 2014 On the spaghetti bowl effect, there is little evidence that consolidation is taking place – for example, the modalities under the Trans-Pacific Partnership and the 16-member ASEAN Regional Economic Cooperation Agreement negotiations mean that agreements in these negotiations – if reached – will add another layer of preferential rules rather than consolidate and harmonize existing agreements.25 That being said, a key positive feature of the TPP is that it will reportedly allow for regional cumulation under its rules of origin, thereby working to reduce the spaghetti bowl effect. Finally, regarding the effectiveness of FTAs, according to an evaluation by the WTO (2011), although the share of global trade flowing between members of preferential agreements has doubled since 1990, the share of trade that actually utilizes preferences appears to be remarkably small: “In a sample covering imports of the 20 largest importers from all their trading partner countries – accounting for 90 per cent of world merchandise trade in 2008 – only 16 per cent qualified as preferential trade, assuming full utilization of preferences.” And of course the evidence shows that preferences are not fully utilized. The brief survey above of the extensive analysis that has been conducted on FTAs reminds that the introduction of discriminatory treatment into trade, a key derogation from the fundamental MFN principle of the multilateral system, inevitably generates costs that must be weighed against the benefits of FTAs. The TPP is unlikely to straighten out the noodle bowl of Asia Pacific FTAs. As noted by Ravenhill (2009; 29), “Factors that might sustain a positive momentum towards multilateralization of the current noodle bowl effect … have been significantly constrained in Asia. The TPP is no exception to this generalization.” Thus, the TPP parties have agreed that, as in the case in the P4 agreement, existing bilateral agreements between the proposed TPP members would remain in force (Capling and Ravenhill, 2011), although the P4 itself will be replaced by the TPP9 (Petri, Plummer and Zhai, 2011; 17). Barfield (2011), in his discussion on this subject, emphasizes that the United States has strong defensive and offensive reasons to maintain existing bilateral schedules in the goods negotiations. Accordingly, while some TPP members (including Australia and New Zealand) have pushed for multilateralizing the schedules, the result to date is a compromise under which countries are able to make offers on a bilateral basis or to the TPP membership as a whole. As emphasized by Capling and Ravenhill (2011), with this architecture the TPP will fall far short of the aspirations of multilateralizing regionalism. Instead, “it will be more of a ‘gap-filling’ exercise that creates additional bilateral agreements between TPP members where they are currently lacking.” As regards the ASEAN-led RCEP negotiations (which aim to forge a regional PTA amongst the ASEAN+1 partners, namely ASEAN, China, Japan, Korea, India, Australia and New Zealand), the Guiding Principles adopted by leaders in launching the negotiations stipulate that the existing ASEAN+1 agreements, which constitute the opening basis for the negotiations, will remain in place. 25 21 Should Canada unilaterally adopt global free trade? Dan Ciuriak and Jingliang Xiao May 2014 The Cost of Rules of Origin and the Opportunity Cost of Unilateral Free Trade The Cost of Rules of Origin to Trading Firms From the perspective of the present inquiry, the key feature of FTAs is that they are costly to use for trading firms. The costs include both fixed costs (the deadweight administrative costs of accessing the regime) and variable costs (the penalty that firms pay in terms of complying with restrictive rules of origin by sourcing from higher-cost preferential zone suppliers). As Hakobyan (2012) observes, administrative costs include, in addition to keeping track of inputs and properly documenting the contribution of each input to the value of the final product, the retention of documentation proving the origin of goods (for US GSP purposes, this is five years). These costs rise with the degree of processing as the number of inputs increases. Because of the presence of fixed costs, the unit costs of ROOs fall with the size of transactions, thus favouring larger exporters. Kawai and Wignaraja (2010; 12) comment on this effect in a sample of Asian exporters: “FTAs entail large fixed costs— e.g., learning about FTA provisions, tailoring business plans to complex tariff schedules, and obtaining certificates of origin—and larger firms are better able to muster the requisite financial and human resources than small- and medium-size enterprises." Brenton (2010; 172) emphasizes the “sophisticated and expensive accounting procedures [needed] to show precisely the geographic breakdown of the inputs”. Use of a preferential regime may also be affected by the extent of exporters’ knowledge of the regimes and by the fact that those trying to meet all the requirements of the regime may be stymied by various factors, including some beyond their control. For example, in a Canadian context, Kunimoto and Sawchuck (2006; 280) comment as follows: “Recent discussions with Canadian exporters and importers revealed that for small shipments and exporters with limited knowledge of NAFTA and small-sized firms are likely to pay MFN duties rather than incur the additional expense of meeting the NAFTA requirements. In addition, firms who could not get sufficient numbers of certificates of origin from their suppliers chose MFN and paid duty rather than claiming NAFTA status.” 22 Should Canada unilaterally adopt global free trade? Dan Ciuriak and Jingliang Xiao May 2014 Since these types of problems are likely to be reduced through a “learning by doing” effect, the biggest hindrance might be to new exporters. The low level of utilization of preferences for small shipments thus might also reflect low utilization by irregular or new exporters. With regular “churning” of the population of exporters, there would be a continual flow of new exporters trying to cope with the system and thus an ongoing learning cost imposed on industry.26 Additional costs can be generated by the need to demonstrate that goods transhipped through third countries remain under customs supervision during such transit and do not enter the domestic market or undergo processing in the transit country (Brenton, 2010; 172). The costs in this case can include the time and costs generated by practical problems such as obtaining necessary supporting documents from foreign border agencies or logistics providers. Various attempts have been made to quantify the costs of utilizing preferences. The literature on the cost of meeting ROOs is growing but cannot yet be characterized as definitive. This reflects the difficulty of systematically translating technical measures codified in voluminous and highly detailed legal documents into dollar terms (Cadot et al., 2002). Further, given the range of costs (paper burden, time costs, and hassle factor) and the heterogeneity of the incidence of costs on different types of exporters and export transactions, direct measurement is for all practical purposes impossible. Indirect methods based on the observed behaviour of exporters must accordingly be used to infer the costs. On this basis, the “ballpark” that has emerged for ROOs administrative costs (which tend to be on the order of one-third or so of the total cost of compliance with a PTA) is about 1 to 7% expressed as an ad valorem equivalent relative to the value of the exported good: Koskinen (1983) for Finnish exports under the EC-EFTA FTA: 1.4 to 5.7%. Herin (1986) for EFTA ROO documentation requirements: 3 to 5%. Cadot et al. (2002) and Carrère and de Melo (2004) for Mexican exports to the United States: 1.94% and 1.72% respectively. Kawai and Wignaraja (2010; 11), in a sample of 841 firms, find that about 28% use FTA preferences but an additional 25% indicated they planned to use the preferences, consistent with compliance involving a learning effect. 26 23 Should Canada unilaterally adopt global free trade? Dan Ciuriak and Jingliang Xiao May 2014 Anson et al. (2005) for Mexican exports to the United States: about 2% Francois, Hoekman and Manchin (2006) and Manchin (2006): the threshold value (defined as the difference between the MFN and preferential tariff rates) below which preferences lose their attraction to trading firms because of compliance costs is about 4 to 4.5%. Kunimoto and Sawchuck (2006) for Canadian exports to the United States: 1.05%. Cadot et al. (2006) for administrative compliance costs associated with rules of origin: 2% under NAFTA and 6.8% under PANEURO. Keck and Lendle (2012) using transaction-level data, find fixed costs equal to US$14 to US$1,500 per transaction. As a generalization, the effective costs of ROOs are likely to vary with the complexity of the product, the size of the sale, the experience of the exporter, the shipping routes used, and so forth. Distance appears to matter. We discuss these issues more fully below in consideration of utilization of preferences. The Public Administration Cost of Rules of Origin Administering FTAs also represent a deadweight cost that must be deducted from the gains from trade generated by the regime; this cost is generally ignored in quantitative evaluations of the impact of FTAs. The size of administrative costs varies by ROO regime: the EU family of ROOs differ in this regard from the NAFTA family and from those used elsewhere such as in Latin America (see, e.g., Izam, 2003). As well, the efficiency of customs departments varies. The scope for administrative savings from full elimination of customs duties is beyond the scope of this paper. However, it is possible to provide some quantitative context. The Canada Border Services Agency’s planned spending for collection of border taxes and the management of free trade agreements in FY 2013/14 was $74.84 million, although targeted to fall to $63.92 million in FY2014/15 and beyond. Total full-timeequivalent personnel dedicated to this was 870, slated to fall to 792 in FY2014/15.27 Canada Border Services Agency, Report on Plans and Priorities 2013/14: Revenue and Trade Management Program, http://cbsa-asfc.gc.ca/agency-agence/reports-rapports/rpp/20132014/report-rapport-eng.html. 27 24 Should Canada unilaterally adopt global free trade? Dan Ciuriak and Jingliang Xiao May 2014 The NAFTA Rules of Origin Regulations28 alone run to 556 pages; accordingly, the cost of administering FTAs is clearly non-trivial and there would be some savings in this area. However, only $4 billion of the total $23 billion in taxes collected at the border annually comes from customs duties. Even with the elimination of customs duties, a large revenue collection system would still remain at the border. For example, under unilateral free trade, Canada would likely retain its trade remedy capability which involves applying anti-dumping, anti-subsidy or safeguard duties and administering price undertakings. While the above considerations suggest that there would be some administrative cost savings, these would not be of a scale to materially impact the assessment of the gains from a move to unilateral free trade. The Welfare Costs of Rules of Origin Tariffs are transparent and create transfer payments that become tax receipts which can be used for public purposes. By contrast, regulatory requirements that raise firms’ costs create deadweight losses through expensive compliance procedures. As pointed out by Sykes (2001), non-tariff measures are for this reason a relatively inefficient form of protection compared to tariffs. Consider for example the marginal transaction at which utilization of a preference is made. For this transaction, the exporting firm incurs a cost that is, at the limit, equal to the tariff revenue that would have been collected by the importing country’s government, had the exporter chosen the MFN route. The firm is in principle indifferent as to which cost it bears and the trade effects are therefore the same regardless of which option the firm chooses.29 However, the welfare cost of the firm using the preference is substantially higher than the welfare cost of paying the tariff. This can be seen directly from the standard formula for calculating the welfare impact of imposing a tariff, which is equal to the sum of change in consumer welfare and producer welfare in the importing country plus government revenue raised by the SOR/94-14, Consolidated. Minister of Justice, http://laws-lois.justice.gc.ca This follows from the fact that the trade effects of a border measure stem from the impact on the firm’s behaviour, including its pricing decisions in the export market. If a firm is indifferent as to which cost it chooses to assume – paying the tariff or the administrative costs of compliance – the trade impact of the tariff is the same as that of the administrative costs of compliance. 28 29 25 Should Canada unilaterally adopt global free trade? Dan Ciuriak and Jingliang Xiao May 2014 tariff.30 There is no government revenue generated in the case of administrative costs incurred by the firm. The welfare costs of imposing a tariff are thus less than those of imposing ROO compliance burdens. The incidence of these welfare costs depends on whether the exporting firm passes on the costs to the customer in the importing country or bears the cost itself. However, in balanced two-way trade, the welfare of both trading partners is reduced by a substantially greater amount by compliance with the ROOs than by paying the equivalent tariff. The Utilization of Preferences Actual data on the utilization of preferences are scarce. By and large, studies on preference utilization have relied on United States International Trade Commission data, which provide estimates of the value of imports by tariff program, or on Eurostat data, which are less valuable for this purpose as they do not indicate which preferential program was used. Data for other countries have generally not been available. For example, Low et al. (2009) reported an attempt to obtain Canadian data, an attempt which they abandoned.31 Keck and Lendle (2012) however obtained data for Canada and Australia from WTO sources that were generated as special compilations by the respective governments as part of a WTO transparency activity. The available evidence shows that, consistent with expectations based on the presence of compliance costs, much trade flows through the WTO-mandated “most favoured nation” (MFN) channels, paying the MFN duty, even where preferential channels are available. Utilization rates depend on a range of factors. For example, Hakobyan (2012), studying utilization of the US Generalized System of Preferences finds that utilization (a) increases with the preference margin, the size of the export shipment, the local content share and regional cumulation allowed, and the remoteness of beneficiary countries; Thus, when a tariff is imposed, under typical market conditions, the sum of consumer and producer surplus will be negative. But this negative impact will be reduced by the value of government revenues from the tariff. In the case of a non-tariff measure, there is no offsetting tariff revenue benefit and the negative impact of the measure is thus greater. 31 Reported in Keck and Lendle (2012), note 8. 30 26 Should Canada unilaterally adopt global free trade? Dan Ciuriak and Jingliang Xiao May 2014 and (b) declines with the degree of processing. The last point is notable as it implies that FTAs are less effective in stimulating trade in complex goods and by the same token less effective in generating growth in advanced technology goods which rely on globally sourced inputs. For Canada, 8% of imports in the Keck and Lendle (2012) data enter under positive MFN rates without eligibility for any preference, while 28.9% face positive MFN rates but are eligible for preferences. Of the latter, close to 90% of trade flows through the preferences. On this basis, preference utilization is high (surprisingly so in view of much of the earlier literature). At the same time, the significance of preferences for overall trade is low: only 25.9% of the value of Canada’s imports flowed through preferential channels in 2008 under tariff lines where the MFN rate was above zero. The total utilization rate was in 2011 was very similar at 26.9% despite the unilateral elimination of input tariffs in the 2010 Budget. Table 2: Utilization of Canada’s Preferential Regimes Imports (USD million) % All imports 341,169 MFN = zero 215,299 MFN > 0 / No preferences available 27,418 MFN > 0 / Preference available but not used 10,099 MFN > 0 / Preference available and used 88,352 Total Preference-eligible trade in non-zero MFN tariff lines 98,451 Preference Utilization as percent of value of preference-eligible trade Preference Utilization as percent of total trade 100.0% 63.1% 8.0% 3.0% 25.9% 28.9% 89.7% 25.9% Source: Keck and Lendle (2012) In ad valorem terms, Keck and Lendle (2012) identify a clear threshold of about 1% for tariffs below which utilization falls to 17%. Above that, for tariffs in the 1% to 2.5% range, utilization is fairly high at about 75%, but well short of full utilization. The picture for the United States in the Keck and Lendle data set is similar to that for Canada. This suggests that compliance costs with Canada’s ROO regime range up to 2% in ad valorem terms and even higher for some transactions. The picture becomes considerably more complicated when the utilization rate is assessed on the basis of the value of transactions: utilization rates only go above 50% 27 Should Canada unilaterally adopt global free trade? Dan Ciuriak and Jingliang Xiao May 2014 in Canada when duties reach the range of USD 1,000-10,000. This suggests that, for shipments with values in the low six-figure range, in about half of the preferenceeligible shipments, the company opts for the MFN route to avoid ROO compliance costs (whether time or money or bother). Is it possible to reconcile a high percentage-of-value rate and a low percentage-oftransactions utilization rate below a certain cut-off? This is straightforward. As concluded by Keck and Lendle (2012), this implies that compliance costs are largely fixed. In a context where a large portion of trade is accounted for by very large volumes of transactions by large multinational firms, which can afford dedicated staff to deal with ROOs compliance, the overall share of trade that will flow through preferential channels, even where the saving is small in percentage terms (but large in dollar terms), will tend to be large. At the same time, smaller entrepreneurial exporters are more likely to pay the MFN rate until the tariff costs becomes significant in dollar terms. It is also reasonable to infer that some SMEs that are close to the threshold for exporting decide against entering into trade altogether. In a dynamic context, an important element is change at the extensive margin. Firms that are able to enter into trade tend to be “better” in many dimensions but also tend to become even better because of their trade engagement. Features of the trade system that cut-off new entry dampen this dynamic.32 Moreover, there is likely to be a reduction of varieties of imports. The Fiscal Cost of Unilateral Liberalization Tariff revenues represent only a small part of overall Canadian federal tax revenue (1.8% in the 2013/14 budget plan) and an even smaller part of total budgetary revenue (1.5%). Yet the $4 billion (rising to $5 billion over the current budget planning period) raised through customs duties is a non-negligible element in the overall fiscal picture for the federal government as it works to reduce the deficit. This raises the issue of replacing the revenue foregone under unilateral liberalization. 32 As demonstrated by Melitz and Redding (2014), the gains from trade become arbitrarily large when productivity is endogenous to trade engagement. Constraints on this channel of productivity gains are thus significant. 28 Should Canada unilaterally adopt global free trade? Dan Ciuriak and Jingliang Xiao May 2014 The answer to this issue is straightforward: the conventional recommendation given to small, trade-dependent economies is to shift taxes from the border to internal taxes, principally to a value-added tax such as the Harmonized Sales Tax (HST). Canada participates on the Executive Board of the IMF, which routinely makes these recommendations to developing countries33 and which provides significant levels of technical support to help them actually make this switch. Shifting Canada’s own customs duties to the HST would be to simply follow the advice Canada officially – if indirectly – gives others. Based on the 2013/14 budget plans, the shift could be accomplished in an essentially revenue-neutral fashion by eliminating customs duties and raising the HST by about 2 percentage points.34 The budget plan projects HST revenues to grow by 4.9% per year and customs revenues to grow by 5.1% per year over the forecast period. Since both customs duties and the HST are borne by consumers, the latter group should be collectively indifferent (although there would be some distributional effects). The Opportunity Cost of Unilateral Liberalization It is often argued that dismantling trade barriers unilaterally deprives a country of “negotiating coin” in extracting concessions from foreign partners. In a WTO context, Canada would still retain significant negotiating leverage since the WTO negotiations are about bindings; however, in a FTA context, having fewer concessions to offer in applied tariff terms would be a factor. That being said, the main area where Canada has significant remaining protection is in agriculture. The consensus view amongst trade observers is that politically credible leverage on agriculture can only be brought to bear in the context of a multilateral round where the scope for cross-sectoral tradeoffs across a large number of participants generates the basis for a deal. We see no reason to disagree. 33 This recommendation, when made to countries with large informal sectors, was recently questioned by Emran and Stiglitz (2005). An IMF Working Paper (Keen, 2007) responds, arguing that, with proper tax design, “the usual prescription that a small economy should not deploy tariffs remains valid.” 34 A back-of-the-envelope calculation suggests about 1.75 percentage point increase in the HST would offset the $4 billion loss of customs duty revenues. 29 Should Canada unilaterally adopt global free trade? Dan Ciuriak and Jingliang Xiao May 2014 There are of course a range of other areas where FTAs may affect domestic policy. This kind of pressure could only be brought to bear by the United States or the European Union and Canada has already reached deals with both. Accordingly, opportunity costs should not be a major concern to Canadian policy makers. Against this background, we evaluate the impact on Canada of moving to unilateral free trade, embracing fully the emerging paradigm for global production. Empirical Strategy To evaluate the impact of unilateral liberalization, we employ a computable general equilibrium (CGE) model. CGE models integrate data on bilateral trade flows, trade protection, and domestic support together with national input-output tables that describe the sale and purchase relationships between producers and consumers within each economy. Unilateral liberalization is simulated as the removal of all existing tariffs and allowing the CGE model to calculate the implied economic adjustments in terms of trade flows, the level of national economic output (gross domestic product), employment and economic welfare. For this purpose, we apply the widely used Global Trade Analysis Project (GTAP) model in conjunction with version 8 of the GTAP data base which has a base year of 2007. However, the analysis raises a number of practical issues. First, the Canadian economy has grown in terms of population (7.1%), real GDP (7.4%), and per capita real income (0.3%) between 2007 and 2013 (Table 3 below). The cyclical position of the economy is different: Canada was at a cyclical peak in 2007 but is 1.7% below potential in 2013 and the unemployment rate is 1.2% higher. The exchange rate in 2013 is somewhat higher, the trade share of GDP is lower, and the external balance has swung from a small surplus to a significant (-3.5%) deficit. Similarly, the fiscal accounts have deteriorated with the general government balance swinging from a surplus of 1.5% of GDP to a deficit of -2.8% of GDP, while the net public debt has grown from about 23% of GDP to about 36% of GDP. Accordingly, we update the economic data from 2007 to 2013 using the dynamic GTAP model simulated on updated macro variables, e.g., regional real GDP, labor inputs, population levels, etc. (Table 3). 30 Should Canada unilaterally adopt global free trade? Dan Ciuriak and Jingliang Xiao May 2014 Table 3: The Canadian Economy: 2007 and 2013 Subject Descriptor 2007 2013 % change Gross domestic product (CAD billions at 2007 prices) Gross domestic product (CAD billions at current prices) Gross domestic product (USD billions at current prices) Gross domestic product deflator Population (millions) Gross domestic product per capita (CAD, 2007 prices) Gross domestic product per capita (CAD, current prices) Employment (millions) Unemployment rate (%) Output gap (% of potential GDP) General government revenue (CAD billions) General government total expenditure (CAD billions) General government revenue (% of GDP) General government total expenditure (% of GDP) General government net lending/borrowing General government net lending/borrowing General government net debt (% of GDP) General government net debt (% of GDP) Exchange Rate (CAD/USD) Value of oil imports (USD billions) Value of oil exports (USD billions) Two-way goods trade (% of GDP) Current account balance (USD billions) Current account balance (% of GDP) 1,566 1,566 1,458 1.000 32.88 47,625 47,625 16.8 6.1 1.7 628 605 40.1 38.6 22.834 1.5 359 22.9 0.930 33.5 79.3 54.8 11.36 0.8 1,682 1,873 1,844 1.113 35.21 47,784 53,191 17.7 7.3 -1.7 711 764 38.0 40.8 -53.272 -2.8 671 35.9 0.978 49.0 108.9 50.2 -64.91 -3.5 7.4% 19.6% 26.5% 11.3% 7.1% 0.3% 11.7% 5.5% 13.3% 26.4% 5.2% 46.1% 37.3% Source: IMF World Economic Outlook, April 2013; Bank of Canada (exchange rate); authors’ calculations. Second, Canada’s GTAP protection data must be updated to take account of changes Canada introduced that are not reflected therin. The Comprehensive Economic Partnership Agreement with the European Union and the Canada-Korea FTA, which were agreed as this paper was being finalized, could not be taken into account. Third, while it is straightforward to eliminate estimated levels of protection against non-FTA partners, it is necessary to evaluate the remaining protection effectively faced by FTA partners due to the non-utilization of preferences because of rules of origin and 31 Should Canada unilaterally adopt global free trade? Dan Ciuriak and Jingliang Xiao May 2014 possibly other measures. Since the protection data in GTAP assumes full utilization of preferences, we adjust the policy shock to reflect non-utilization. Fourth, we reflect the costs of using preferences (Petri, Plummer and Zhai, 2011). Fifth, there are a number of issues related to how the simulations are conducted, in particular, the choice of specific closure rules that are imposed on CGE models and the simulation of liberalization of sectors facing very high levels of protection. We discuss these methodological issues and associated data issues below. The Level of Protection Canada implemented a major tariff cut in March 2010 covering 1,541 items mainly in manufacturing inputs and machinery and equipment. We update the GTAP protection data to reflect the post-Budget 2010 situation. The differences in the level of protection of the sectors affected are set out in Table 4. Table 4. Tariff Pre and Post-Budget 2010 by GTAP Sector in % Pre-Budget2010 Post-Budget2010 % change Petroleum & Coke Gas Fabricated Metal Products Chemical Rubber Products Electronic Equipment Non-Ferrous Metals Textiles Other Machinery & Equipment Iron & Steel Non-Metallic Minerals Other Mining Lumber Motor vehicles Leather Wearing Apparel 0.31 0.03 0.94 0.56 0.20 0.05 6.40 0.43 0.10 0.72 0.02 1.27 0.91 9.03 12.53 0.02 0.01 0.67 0.43 0.16 0.04 5.35 0.36 0.09 0.65 0.02 1.20 0.88 8.72 12.51 -93.7% -64.7% -28.5% -22.5% -20.9% -19.8% -16.3% -16.2% -13.0% -9.9% -6.0% -5.4% -3.8% -3.4% -0.2% Source: Authors’ calculations based on WTO data and GTAP v8 database 32 Should Canada unilaterally adopt global free trade? Dan Ciuriak and Jingliang Xiao May 2014 Taking into account non-utilization of preferences Since preferential tariffs are not fully utilized, the effective tariff rate on imports under tariff lines which have a preferential rate of zero is a weighted average of the share that uses the preference and pays zero tariffs and the share that pays the MFN tariff (which of course in many cases is zero). Importantly in the present study, this includes imports from the United States, Canada’s main trading partner. In this sense, a move to unilateral free trade is a case of the Canada-US FTA redux and would thus be a relatively “big deal”. The major difference between the impact on Canada-US trade of the 1989 FTA and a future MFN tariff elimination would be as regards the lower level of effective tariff protection today than prior to the FTA and the fact that the United States would not be reciprocating. As noted earlier, data on preference utilization under Canada’s various tariff programs has been compiled by the Canadian government as part of a transparency exercise in the WTO; a non-confidential version of these data at the 6-digit HS code level that were reported in Keck and Lendle (2012) has been made available to us by the WTO, graciously facilitated by Alexander Keck and Andreas Lendle (whose assistance is greatly appreciated). We use data for 2011 preference utilization for each individual RTA to which Canada is party, aggregated to the level of the GTAP product groups. Table 5: Canadian Imports under FTAs flowing through preferential and MFN channels MFN PTA United States Mexico EFTA Israel Chile Colombia Peru Costa Rica 58.58% 41.42% 94.48% 5.52% 72.99% 27.01% 88.13% 11.87% 92.51% 7.49% 90.02% 9.98% 60.25% 39.75% 98.19% 1.81% Source: Authors’ calculations based on WTO data Note that, as per the preceding discussion on tariff utilization, the apparent rate of utilization is affected by the prevalence of zero MFN rates; the data in Table 5 accordingly merely serve to illustrate the weightings to be applied in calculating the remaining level of protection under tariff lines where preferences are available and should not be interpreted as representing the rate of utilization of non-zero preferences, which is much higher (as shown in Table 2 above). What these data do confirm in a Canadian context, however, is the finding on a global basis that the overall share of trade that flows through preferences is often surprisingly 33 Should Canada unilaterally adopt global free trade? Dan Ciuriak and Jingliang Xiao May 2014 small; moreover, considering the number of tariff lines which Canada has autonomously moved to zero, it is the latter phenomenon that is dominating trade policy impacts in Canada as well as internationally. Finally, Canada’s General Preferential Tariff (GPT) preferences for up to 72 developing countries were withdrawn in the 2013/14 budget, starting 1 January 2015. This will effectively raise the impact of unilateral liberalization, should Canada go this route following the implementation of this announced measure. The Welfare Cost of ROOs Compliance To capture the removal of the deadweight administrative cost of compliance with Canada’s rules of origin (which are evaluated in the literature as being amongst the most restrictive35), we apply an estimate of 2% for intra-NAFTA ROOs costs and a 3% cost of trade to flows that utilize preferences under Canada’s other FTAs. We implement this in the GTAP model as a reduction to transportation margins of 2% (3%) in sectors where the utilization rate is 100%, of 1.0% (1.5%) in sectors where the utilization rate is 50%, and so forth. In the GTAP model framework (which assumes perfect competition) these cost savings are fully passed on to Canadian consumers or to firms purchasing intermediate goods. In a real world setting where perfect competition does not apply, these savings would likely be partly retained by the foreign supplier as increased profits (this would be especially the case in sectors where “pricing-to-market” practices apply). Nonetheless, the global welfare gains from reduced costs would still rise by the full extent of the elimination of the wasteful activity of complying with the ROOs red tape. Alternative Closures In CGE simulations, the modeller must decide which “closure” to use – that is, which variables in the model are to be exogenous (i.e., fixed at predetermined values specified by the modeller) and which are to be endogenous (i.e., the values for which are solved by the model). Choice of closure influences results significantly. 35 See, e.g., Estevadeordal and Suominen (2004). 34 Should Canada unilaterally adopt global free trade? Dan Ciuriak and Jingliang Xiao May 2014 Under the GTAP model’s default microeconomic closure, the factor endowments (i.e., the total supply of labour, both skilled and unskilled, as well as of capital and land) are fixed; factor prices (i.e., wages and return to capital and land) adjust to restore full employment of the factors of production in the post-shock equilibrium.36 Under alternative microeconomic closures that are sometimes used, the return to capital or to labour can be fixed and the supply of capital and/or labour then adjusts to restore equilibrium.37 Each of these rules makes an extreme assumption about the supply of labour and/or capital: it is either perfectly elastic or perfectly inelastic. The reality is likely to be somewhere in between. The GTAP model can be simulated to approximate intermediate values of the elasticity of supply of capital and/or labour. The modeller’s assumptions for these parameters, based on empirical evidence drawn from outside the model, then determine how tariff elimination impacts on the economy. For example, for labour, the more inelastic is labour supply, the greater the extent to which gains are achieved in the form of wage increases. Conversely, the more elastic is labour supply, the greater the extent to which gains are achieved in the form of additional jobs. Similarly, for the economy as a whole, the gains reflect either improved prices or increased output—or some combination of the two—depending on the assumptions about supply-side elasticities in the closure. With regard to the long-run supply of labour, the economic literature supports a positive but not infinite supply elasticityi.e., somewhere between the two extreme assumptions for labour market closures. On the basis of recent empirical evidence, we adopt a labour market closure for Canada based on fixing the elasticity of labour supply at approximately one.38 With regard to the long-run supply of capital, for Canada, a small open economy that has relatively untrammelled access to capital, the most 36 This is sometimes described as reflecting a medium-term time horizon in which labour supply is relatively “sticky.” 37 The closure rule in which the rate of return to capital is fixed is sometimes described as reflecting longer-run “steady-state” growth conditions, For an example of the implications of fixing the return to capital and allowing investment to adjust, see Gilbert (2001), Gilbert reports net economic welfare gains for Korea that are 2.7 times larger, and for the U.S. that are 2.4 times larger, with this closure compared to standard closure. For an example of the use of the labour market closure rule under which the wage rate is fixed, see Francois and Baughman (2005). 38 For a discussion of the elasticity of supply of labour see Ham and Reilly (2012). This study finds statistically significant inter-temporal labour supply elasticities of 0.9 with the Panel Study of Income Dynamics (PSID) data set and 1.0 with the Consumer Expenditure Survey (CES) data set. 35 Should Canada unilaterally adopt global free trade? Dan Ciuriak and Jingliang Xiao May 2014 plausible assumption for capital supply is that it is relatively elastic; this corresponds closely to the steady state closure rule for capital. The second aspect of closure is macroeconomic closure. Two approaches are available here: the standard approach with the GTAP model, which is used in the present simulations, is to allow the current account to adjust to the trade shock, with passive accommodation by international investment flows. The change in the current account implies a change in domestic investment. In the GTAP model, the change in investment is reflected in the profile of final demand, which in turn affects the profile of production and trade but does not feed through into the productive capacity of industries/regions. The alternative macroeconomic closure is to fix the current account, implicitly assuming no international capital mobility.39 This particular closure (which is used, for example, in a TPP study by Petri, Plummer and Zhai, 2012) serves to illustrate the principle articulated by Lerner (1936) regarding the equivalence between an import tariff and a tax on exports. We include a simulation based on this closure to illustrate the boost to exports through general equilibrium effects that Canada would obtain by eliminating import tariffs. Given the high degree of sensitivity of the results to the specific assumption made (see for example the estimates for the Canada-Korea FTA in Ciuriak and Chen, 2008), we report the results of simulations for four alternative closures: (i) (ii) (iii) Fixed Endowments: labour and capital supply fixed (the standard or default closure), wages and the rates of return adjust to restore post-shock equilibrium. Steady State: labour supply and rates of return fixed; wages and capital supply respond to restore post-shock equilibrium. Dynamic Supply Response: wages and labour supply both adjust in equal proportions (supply elasticity of unity) and capital is determined by the flow of investment which responds to rates of return. Gilbert (2001) compares the impact of using alternative macroeconomic closures in the context of modelling the U.S.-Korea FTA. The fixed current account simulations substantially reduce the economic welfare gains for Korea (to 3/5 the level of the simulation with flexible current account) and marginally (by 5%) for the United States. 39 36 Should Canada unilaterally adopt global free trade? Dan Ciuriak and Jingliang Xiao May 2014 (iv) Import/Export Tax Equivalence: the fixed endowments scenario with the current account fixed. Each of these closures is simulated with and without the welfare impacts of ROOs included to illustrate the implications of taking these costs into account. Canada’s supply-managed sectors pose special problems: meat products (mainly poultry) and dairy face very high tariffs (85% and 193% respectively) in the GTAP data set. A high level of initial protection translates into very large changes in trade flows. The size of the flows is largely determined by the elasticity of substitution – i.e., consumers are assumed to have a limited preference for imported meat and milk, which attenuates the trade response. However, in reality both the meat products and dairy sectors feature producers with varying cost structures. While some of the highercost producers would be driven out of the market, the more cost efficient would survive and continue to produce at the lower world price. Accordingly the supply curve would also play a role in attenuating the inroads of imported meat products and dairy rather than consumer preferences alone. For small changes in tariff protection, the impact of the supply schedule could safely be ignored in evaluating the order of magnitude of change; for large changes, however, ignoring the supply schedule would result in exaggerated impacts. For these two sectors, we reduce the GTAP substitution elasticity by half to take account of this factor. The adjustment is crude and a sector-specific analysis would be required to determine the scale of impacts more accurately. However, for the purposes of the present analysis which is to identify orders of magnitude of impact on the Canadian economy from unilateral liberalization, we believe the adjustment is adequate. Accordingly, in all, we report the results for eight simulations, with the above adjustments to the meat products and dairy sector as noted. Results Unilateral liberalization results in real GDP gains for Canada that range from a modest 0.257% if endowments are fixed and the external balance is also constrained to remain unchanged, to 1.045% in the preferred dynamic scenario in which labour supply responds proportionately to wage increases, and investment responds to the change in 37 Should Canada unilaterally adopt global free trade? Dan Ciuriak and Jingliang Xiao May 2014 rates of return. To put these results into perspective, these gains are equivalent in terms of order of magnitude to the effect of tariff cuts estimated for the Canada-EU Comprehensive Economic Partnership of 0.27% of GDP and indeed to the overall impact of the latter Agreement of 0.77% of GDP.40 Comparing the top and bottom panels in Table 6 below shows the additional gains from full utilization of tariff reductions already granted under existing FTAS and the lapsing of existing administrative costs of ROOs compliance. The additional GDP gain is significant: the average boost across the four closures we employ is about 25%, with the size of the boost rising with the extent of increase in trade induced by liberalization. Consistent with the gains in real GDP, economic welfare as measured by household income improves in all the simulations in an amount roughly commensurate with the scale of gains in real GDP. However, reflecting the effect of ROOs compliance in raising costs for firms, the elimination of the ROOs requirement has a much stronger effect on economic welfare than on GDP. As shown in Table 6, the gains in welfare are 125% larger on average across the four closure scenarios that reflect the elimination of ROOs. Table 6: Impacts on Income and Output (percent) Household Income Real GDP With ROOs costs taken into account Fixed Endowments Steady State Dynamic Supply Response Import/Export Tax Equivalence 0.359 0.498 1.139 0.307 0.273 0.510 1.045 0.257 Without ROOs costs taken into account Fixed Endowments Steady State Dynamic Supply Response Import/Export Tax Equivalence 0.146 0.198 0.703 0.126 0.247 0.337 0.789 0.242 Source: Calculations by the authors See Table 29, Canada-EU (2008), at p. 55. Note that both the simulations reported here and the Canada-EU Joint Study liberalize all sensitive sectors; accordingly, the simulations are comparable in that respect, although the specific CGE models used for the simulations differ (e.g., the Joint Study incorporates imperfect competition). 40 38 Should Canada unilaterally adopt global free trade? Dan Ciuriak and Jingliang Xiao May 2014 The cut in protection results in a decline in Canadian consumer prices. On average, the reduction is about 1.17%. There is a modest degree of variation across the different closures; these differences reflect the differing extents to which the impact of liberalization is channeled into price versus quantity responses. Meanwhile the rate of return to capital in Canada increases in the scenarios where it is not fixed and investment leads the gains in all the scenarios. Unilateral liberalization is thus an investment-promoting policy that should work to make the economy more competitive. It is important to bear in mind that this investment income does not include the impact on foreign direct investment that would likely be triggered by a strategic decision by Canada to become a free trade zone. Such impacts can be modelled in a CGE context by dividing each domestic sector into domestically owned and foreigninvested segments. This is beyond the scope of the present study, however. The government expenditure impacts reflect primarily price developments. Table 7: Impacts on Consumption and Investment (percent) Consumption CPI With ROOs costs taken into account Fixed Endowments 0.634 Steady State 0.801 Dynamic Supply Response 1.382 Import/Export Tax Equivalence 0.574 Without ROOs costs taken into account Fixed Endowments 0.398 Steady State 0.461 Dynamic Supply Response 0.925 Import/Export Tax Equivalence 0.375 Investment Rate of ofGovernment Return Expenditure -1.053 -1.244 -1.197 -1.194 0.952 0.651 1.861 0.004 0.749 0.000 0.940 0.695 -0.249 -0.160 0.606 -0.263 -1.086 -1.158 -1.168 -1.139 0.360 0.246 1.057 0.002 0.285 0.000 0.531 0.264 -0.324 -0.291 0.302 -0.330 Source: Calculations by the authors Canada’s imports increase by 3.4% on average across the four scenarios, but exports increase by a similar order of magnitude (2.7% on average) even though the cut in Canada’s protection levels is not reciprocated. This illustrates Lerner’s proposition concerning the equivalence of import and export taxes in a general equilibrium context: a tax on Canada’s imports is also a tax on its exports. 39 Should Canada unilaterally adopt global free trade? Dan Ciuriak and Jingliang Xiao May 2014 Table 8: Impacts on Trade Flows and the External Balance With ROOs costs taken into account Fixed Endowments Steady State Dynamic Supply Response Import/Export Tax Equivalence Without ROOs costs taken into account Fixed Endowments Steady State Dynamic Supply Response Import/Export Tax Equivalence Exports Imports Terms of Trade Trade Balance 2.307 2.982 2.792 2.874 3.306 3.329 3.964 3.051 0.149 0.026 0.096 0.045 -$3,416 -$932 -$4,445 -$98 2.172 2.427 2.421 2.385 2.261 2.269 2.718 2.164 -0.400 -0.448 -0.428 -0.440 -$1,886 -$946 -$2,934 -$633 Source: Calculations by the authors Since both imports and exports expand faster than GDP, Canada’s degree of openness increases, a result that we would interpret as increasing the competitiveness of the economy. The trade balance changes little in real (pre-shock price) terms but unilateral liberalization does tend to produce a terms of trade decline (through the competitive impact of imports on domestic prices) which results in a negative impact on Canada’s trade balance in value terms of about US$2.2 billion on average across the four scenarios in which ROOs costs are taken into account and about US$1.6 billion in the scenarios which ignore these costs. Regarding bilateral trade impacts, there is a significant compositional shift, reflecting the removal of the distortions created by the remaining uneven tariffs and negotiated preferences. The big winner is China: Canada’s imports from China expand by $7.07 billion. Meanwhile, imports from the United States – Canada’s largest preferential source – lose market share (despite the removal of the costs of ROOs compliance), reflecting the rebalancing. In the dynamic response scenario, the level of imports from the United States still increases due to the income effects generated in the Canadian economy from liberalization. In scenarios in which the income effects are smaller, imports from the United States decline in absolute terms driven by their loss of market share as preferential distortions are removed. 40 Should Canada unilaterally adopt global free trade? Dan Ciuriak and Jingliang Xiao May 2014 Table 9: Major Bilateral Import Impacts Source Country Base Imports Post-Liberalization Change % change China Taiwan Japan EU28 Mexico India United States 54,328 3,825 12,386 52,425 11,357 4,693 283,059 61,400 3,850 13,860 55,932 11,323 4,997 284,249 7,072 25 1,473 3,507 -34 304 1,190 13.02% 0.66% 11.89% 6.69% -0.30% 6.47% 0.42% Source: calculations by the authors. The column in “Base imports” shows the estimated imports without policy shocks, the column in “Post-Liberalization” shows the imports in scenario (iii) with removal of the cost of ROO compliance. Note that the increase in imports from the EU includes liberalization that would now be implemented pursuant to the CETA. There would be a complex rebalancing of the trade effects across Canada’s partners to reflect this deal which was announced as this study was being finalized. On the export side, Canadian exports increase to all trading partners more or less proportionately with the level of initial exports; accordingly, the major export destination – the United States – is the destination where Canada registers the largest export gains. In terms of sectors, unilateral liberalization has highly heterogeneous effects (see Table 10 below, where the sectors are ranked by the impacts in the dynamic response scenario with ROOs costs taken into account). The usual sensitive sectors experience a major increase in net imports: textiles, apparel, and leather goods, along with dairy (we reiterate the caveat concerning the crude level of precision of the estimates for sectors with very high levels of initial protection). However, a range of sectors producing higher value-added goods – including business services – gain in terms of net exports as the general equilibrium effects dominate the partial effect of import protection reduction. Considered as an industrial policy, unilateral liberalization moves Canada up the value chain. This latter result speaks to the question of whether there is any net benefit to Canada’s economy of liberalizing highly protected sectors, now that industrial input tariffs have been eliminated. As these simulations show, even with liberalization of industrial inputs, there is in fact powder left in the barrel to promote industrial adjustment towards a more competitive structure for the Canadian economy. 41 Should Canada unilaterally adopt global free trade? Dan Ciuriak and Jingliang Xiao May 2014 Table 10: Major Sectoral Impacts: Net Exports by Simulation Sector (i) (ii) (iii) (iv) (i)* (ii)* (iii)* (iv)* Motor vehicles & parts Transport Equipment Chemical & Rubber Products Non-Ferrous Metals Paper Products Meat Products Machinery & Equipment Business Services Electronic Equipment Vegetable Oils Beverages & Tobacco Leather Products Textiles Other Manufactures Apparel Food Products Dairy Products 451 329 548 209 265 189 435 205 130 -140 -172 -202 -321 -182 -1,125 -1,419 -1,832 569 401 664 297 321 200 586 266 172 -133 -169 -201 -315 -167 -1,117 -1,399 -1,829 306 457 542 206 334 135 348 236 40 -135 -197 -229 -421 -271 -1,208 -1,500 -1,908 614 400 658 275 321 202 688 278 219 -135 -168 -199 -308 -159 -1,113 -1,398 -1,828 952 300 441 207 141 178 185 -9 18 -154 -184 -211 -329 -327 -1,163 -1,489 -1,845 1,259 493 751 437 288 206 583 153 131 -138 -177 -209 -312 -284 -1,143 -1,436 -1,837 867 485 467 257 239 132 103 33 -87 -147 -214 -242 -434 -446 -1,253 -1,574 -1,923 1,376 492 736 384 288 214 851 186 255 -143 -173 -204 -295 -265 -1,130 -1,433 -1,835 Source: calculations by the authors. The simulations (i) through (iv) follow the sequence in the previous tables; the simulations with * refer to the simulations that take into account ROOs administrative costs. Conclusions Reciprocal trade liberalization, both multilaterally and through preferential trade agreements (FTAs), has dominated trade policy over much of the postwar era. However, in recent decades, by far the largest share of progress on trade liberalization has been accounted for by autonomous, unilateral liberalization undertaken by governments out of self-interest to improve their own economies. The reality of the transition has been overshadowed by the frenetic activity in negotiating FTAs. Yet there is a clear disconnect between the pace of implementing FTAs and the share of global trade flowing through the preferential windows they create. This disconnect can be explained in part by the reduction in value of preferences from low MFN tariffs, and in part by the technological revolutions that enabled the 42 Should Canada unilaterally adopt global free trade? Dan Ciuriak and Jingliang Xiao May 2014 emergence of global value chains and the “made in the world” production paradigm which have induced unilateral liberalization for domestic competitive reasons. While not widely recognized, we may in fact be witnessing the twilight of reciprocity in trade policy. Reciprocity was a critical feature of the policy framework that largely liberalized the global trading system – and at the multilateral level there remains room for a reciprocal agreement to address the major bastions of protection remaining where the shift to unilateralism has been less evident. FTAs, however, have not succeeded in liberalizing the difficult areas – and in other sectors account for much less liberalization than has occurred via the autonomous route. Simply put, a new paradigm is taking shape, a seamless two-way trading system for a made-in-the-world production system based on unilateral liberalization. The question is: can Canada contemplate catching this wave and riding it to its logical conclusion? Canada’s gains from unilateral liberalization Canada is not particularly distant from a free trade frontier. Nonetheless, unilateral liberalization of goods trade has a significant positive impact on the economy. This reflects the fact that Canada still collects $4 billion worth of customs duties annually. Moreover, because of the administrative costs that are incurred to access “free trade” agreements, a significant cost burden is imposed on goods that enter the country on a duty free basis. Unilateral liberalization eliminates these costs, generating substantial welfare benefits. The scale of gains rivals those from mutual tariff elimination under a major FTA (Table 11). Accordingly, unilateral liberalization deserves a similar level of policy consideration as any major FTA that Canada may contemplate. In comparing estimated gains from unilateral non-preferential liberalization and preferential liberalization, not only do the gains from the unilateral route come without the distortions and welfare costs associated with FTAs, they are certain to be realized since the question of utilization of preferences would not enter into the equation. Further, it is important to recognize that trade in goods covers 4/5 of the value of Canada’s commercial receipts and a major part of Canada’s international sales of business services and technology is embedded in goods exports. Most importantly, these gains are there for the taking by Canada acting on its own at the time and on terms of its own choosing. 43 Should Canada unilaterally adopt global free trade? Dan Ciuriak and Jingliang Xiao May 2014 Table 11: Estimated GDP Gains for Canada: Unilateral Liberalization and Selected FTAs, percent Agreement Unilateral Liberalization Unilateral Liberalization Trans-Pacific Partnership (TPP12) CETA CETA Canada-Korea FTA Canada-India FTA Canada-India FTA Sources: as given in the table. Study Present study (preferred scenario) Present study (smallest impact with ROOs effects) Petri, Plummer and Zhai (2013) Canada EU Joint Study (goods) Canada-EU Joint Study (all measures) Ciuriak and Chen (2008) – goods (preferred scenario) Canada-India Joint Study (Canadian estimate) Canada-India Joint Study (Indian estimate) % of GDP 1.05% 0.26% 0.40% 0.27% 0.77% 0.11% 0.41% 1.02% As the simulations in the present study serve to bring out, liberalizing narrow but highly protected sectors cascades through the economy driving structural adjustment not only in these sectors but also in sectors where industrial input tariffs have been eliminated. Importantly, the simulations indicate that Canada’s selective protection – which constitutes a “legacy” industrial policy – is holding Canada back from moving forward towards a technologically more advanced industrial structure with higher long-term growth potential. Of particular importance, the movement to unilateral free trade stimulates investment more than consumption, and triggers a relatively balanced expansion of imports and exports, increasing the degree of openness of Canada’s economy. Both effects should work to make Canada’s economy more competitive. Moreover, the rebalancing of the source of imports in Canada’s trade due to the elimination of preferences is striking and indicative of the importance of trade diversion caused by the pattern of existing preferences. The elimination of trade diversion adds further to Canada’s global competitiveness. Two important caveats must be noted. First, the main purpose of a move to unilateral free trade would be to improve Canada’s positioning in the global competition for investment. The present scenario does not reflect the impacts on FDI decision-making. We anticipate that this would actually be the main source of gains from a unilateral liberalization policy. Accordingly, the results reported here undoubtedly underestimate the gains. 44 Should Canada unilaterally adopt global free trade? Dan Ciuriak and Jingliang Xiao May 2014 Second, in a global value chain context, the extent of rebalancing of import-sourcing may be constrained relative to what is shown in the simulations by the continuing application of NAFTA ROOs to Canadian exporters. The opportunity costs of unilateral liberalization are limited Unilateral liberalization does not involve tariff bindings under the WTO. Assuming that Canada retains significant “negotiating coin” given its present degree of openness, it still has something to table in multilateral trade negotiations, since binding reduces the trade costs associated with uncertainty of market access. Unilateral liberalization requires active political management Full unilateral liberalization would target a number of sectors, such as dairy, that have resisted liberalization even with the leverage provided by reciprocal negotiations. It would be naïve to believe that the political costs would be accepted for the size of gains indicated by this study. To be politically feasible, full unilateral liberalization would likely have to be part of a broader and bolder initiative to position Canada as a global production hub, which would generate its own countervailing lobby. An intermediate step would be an “everything but…” approach which in effect adopts a negative list to govern Canada’s imports. This builds on the idea that some advanced technology sectors are already effectively operating on the basis of global free trade – Canada would simply be extending this to all sectors except the few named in the negative list. Finally, given the benefits that China would obtain, it would appear to be politically important for Canada to combine unilateral liberalization with a bilateral agreement with China that delivers Canada concrete advantages in the Chinese market. Canada has a Reciprocity Agreement with China under discussion; accelerating and building on this would provide the necessary quid pro quo from China to allow Canada to move on full unilateral liberalization since it would transfer part of the liberalizing impact to a reciprocal deal with China (underscoring that reciprocity, while clearly of diminishing importance, still retains advantages). 45 Should Canada unilaterally adopt global free trade? Dan Ciuriak and Jingliang Xiao May 2014 The bottom line Overall, a policy of unilateral liberalization appears to be something that Canada can contemplate and should evaluate in greater detail, including its political economy aspects. Most important would be the possible impacts on Canada as a destination for foreign direct investment. The gains described above are significant; in our view they understate the impact because they do not reflect the increased attraction that Canada would have to globally mobile industrial capital. In taking a decisive step towards unilateral free trade, Canada would be aligning with what has been the main trade liberalizing mode globally over the past few decades. Nonetheless, because the reality of this trend has not been widely recognized, Canada would be capturing some “first mover” advantages. Can Canada realistically aspire to being a global production hub? This first analysis suggests that a fuller investigation and a related policy debate would seem most worthwhile. 46 Should Canada unilaterally adopt global free trade? Dan Ciuriak and Jingliang Xiao May 2014 References Abreu, Maria Donner. 2013. “Preferential Rules of Origin in Regional Trade Agreements,” WTO Staff Working Paper ERSD-2013-05 22 March 2013. Anson, José, Olivier Cadot, Antoni Estevadeordal, Jaime de Melo, Akiko Suwa-Eisenmann, and Bolorma Tumurchudur. 2005. “Rules of Origin in North–South Preferential Trading Arrangements with an Application to NAFTA,” Review of International Economics 13(3), August: 501–517. Antràs, Pol and Elhanan Helpman. 2004. “Global Sourcing,” Journal of Political Economy 112(3): 552-580. Antràs, Pol and Elhanan Helpman. 2008. “Contractual Frictions and Global Sourcing,” in: Elhanan Helpman, Dalia Marin and Thierry Verdier (eds.), The Organization of Firms in a Global Economy. Harvard University Press: 9–54. Arkolakis, Costas, Arnaud Costinot and Andréz Rodríguez-Clare. 2012. “New Trade Models, Same Old Gains?” American Economic Review 2012, 102(1): 94–130. Baier, Scott L. and Jeffrey H. Bergstrand. 2007. “Do free trade agreements actually increase members’ international trade?” Journal of International Economics 71: 72–95. Barfield, Claude. 2011. “The Trans-Pacific Partnership: A Model for Twenty-First-Century Trade Agreements?” International Economic Outlook 2, June. American Enterprise Institute. Bernard, Andrew B., Jonathan Eaton, J. Bradford Jensen, and Samuel S. Kortum. 2003. "Plants and Productivity in International Trade," American Economic Review 93(4): 1268-1290. Bagwell, Kyle and Robert W. Staiger. 2011. “What Do Trade Negotiators Negotiate About? Empirical Evidence from the World Trade Organization,” American Economic Review 101, June: 1238–1273. Bhagwati, Jagdish N. 1995. “U.S. Trade Policy: The Infatuation with Free Trade Agreements,” in Jagdish N. Bhagwati and Anne O. Krueger (eds), The Dangerous Drift to Preferential Trade Agreements, Washington, DC: American Enterprise Institute, 1995. Bhagwati, Jagdish N, David Greenaway and Arvind Panagariya. 1998. “Trading preferentially: Theory and Policy,” Economic Journal 108(449): 1128-1148. Brenton, Paul. 2010. “Preferential Rules of Origin,” Chauffour, J. P. and Maur, J.C. (eds), Preferential Trade Agreement Policies for Development: a Handbook, Washington DC: The World Bank. Bureau, Jean-Christophe, Raja Chakir, and Jacques Gallezot. 2006. “The Utilisation of Trade Preferences for Developing Countries in the Agri-food Sector,” Journal of Agricultural Economics 58(2): 175-198. Cadot, Olivier, Celine Carrere, Jaime De Melo and Bolormaa Tumurchudur. 2006. “Product-specific rules of origin in EU and US preferential trading arrangements: an assessment,” World Trade Review 5(2), July: 199-224. Canada-EU. 2008. Assessing the costs and benefits of a closer EU-Canada economic partnership: A Joint Study by the European Commission and the Government of Canada. http://trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/html/141032.htm Canada-India. 2013. Canada-India Joint Study Group Report: Exploring the Feasibility of a Comprehensive Economic Partnership Agreement. http://www.international.gc.ca/trade-agreements-accordscommerciaux/agr-acc/india-inde/study-edude.aspx?lang=eng Capling, Ann and John Ravenhill. 2011. “Multilateralising regionalism: what role for the Trans-Pacific Partnership Agreement?” The Pacific Review 24(5): 553-575 Ciuriak, Dan. 2013. “Learning by Exporting: A Working Hypothesis,” Working Paper, available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1926811; latest version 2 January 2013. Ciuriak, Dan and Shenjie Chen. 2008. “Preliminary Assessment of the Economic Impacts of a Canada-Korea Free Trade Agreement,” in Dan Ciuriak (ed.), Trade Policy Research 2007. Ottawa: Foreign Affairs and International Trade Canada: 187-234. 47 Should Canada unilaterally adopt global free trade? Dan Ciuriak and Jingliang Xiao May 2014 Costinot, Arnaud and Andrés Rodríguez-Clare. 2013. “Trade Theory with Numbers: Quantifying the Consequences of Globalization,” Handbook of International Economics, Volume 4, edited by Gita Gopinath, Elhanan Helpman, and Kenneth Rogoff, North Holland. Estevadeordal, Antonini and Kati Suominen. 2004. “Rules of Origin: A world Map and Trade Effects,” InterAmerican Development Bank Felbermayr, Gabriel J., Benjamin Jung, and Mario Larch. 2013. “Icebergs versus Tariffs: A Quantitative Perspective on the Gains from Trade,” CESifo Working Paper: Trade Policy, No. 4175, March. Francois, Joseph F., Bernard Hoekman, and Miriam Manchin. 2006. “Preference Erosion and Multilateral Trade Liberalization,” World Bank Economic Review 20(2), 197-216. Francois, Joseph F., and Laura M. Baughman. 2006. “US–Canadian Trade and US State-Level Production and Employment,” in John M. Curtis and Dan Ciuriak (eds.), Trade Policy Research 2005 (Ottawa: Foreign Affairs and International Trade Canada: 2006). Freund, Caroline and Emanuel Ornelas. 2010. “Regional trade agreements: blessing or burden?” CentrePiece Summer 2010, 16-19. Gilbert, John P. 2001. “GTAP Model Analysis: Simulating the Effect of a Korea-U.S. FTA Using Computable General Equilibrium Techniques,” Appendix B in Imborn Choi and Jeffrey J. Schott, Free Trade Between Korea and the United States, Washington DC: Institute for International Economics. Grossman, Gene and Esteban Rossi-Hansberg. 2008. “Trading Tasks: A Simple Theory of Offshoring,” American Economic Review 98(5): 1978-1997. Grossman, Gene and Esteban Rossi-Hansberg. 2012. “Task Trade between Similar Countries,” Econometrica 80(2): 593-629. Hakobyan, Shushanik. 2012. “Accounting for Underutilization of Trade Preference Programs: The U.S. Generalized System of Preferences,” Working Paper, Middlebury College. Ham, John C. and Kevin Reilly. 2012. “Implicit Contracts, Life Cycle Labor Supply and Intertemporal Substitution,” Working Paper. Helpman, Elhanan. 2006. “Trade, FDI, and the Organization of Firms,” Journal of Economic Literature 44(3), September: 589–630. Hoekman, Bernard and Çaglar Özden. 2005. “Trade Preferences and Differential Treatment of Developing Countries: A Selective Survey,” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 3566, Washington DC: World Bank. Izam, Miguel. 2003. “Rules of Origin and Trade Facilitation in Preferential Trade Agreements in Latin America,” Serie Comercio internacional, N° 28, Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean. Kasahara, Hiroyuki and Joel Rodrigue. 2008. “Does the Use of Imported Intermediates Increase Productivity?” Journal of Development Economics, 87(1): 106-118. Kawai, Masahiro and Ganeshan Wignaraja. 2010. “Asian FTAs: Trends, Prospects, and Challenges,” ADB Economics Working Paper Series No. 226, Asian Development Bank. Keck, Alexander and Andreas Lendle. 2012. “New evidence on preference utilization,” Staff Working Paper ERSD-2012-12, WTO. Keller, Wolfgang. 2009. “International Trade, Foreign Direct Investment, and Technology Spillovers,” NBER Working Paper 15442. Keller, Wolfgang. 2004. "International Technology Diffusion," Journal of Economic Literature 42(3), September: 752–782. Kunimoto, Robert and Gary Sawchuck. 2006. “NAFTA Rules of Origin,” in John M. Curtis and Aaron Sydor (eds), NAFTA @ 10. Ottawa: Foreign Affairs and International Trade Canada, 2006: 275-312. 48 Should Canada unilaterally adopt global free trade? Dan Ciuriak and Jingliang Xiao May 2014 Lerner, Abba P. 1936. “The Symmetry between Import and Export Taxes,” Economica 3(11) New Series: 306313. Limão, Nuno. 2007. “Are preferential trade agreements with non-trade objectives a stumbling block for multilateral liberalization?” The Review of Economic Studies 74(3): 821-855. Limão, Nuno. 2006. “Preferential Trade Agreements as Stumbling Blocks for Multilateral Trade Liberalization: Evidence for the US,” American Economic Review 96(3): 896-914. Linden, Greg, Kenneth L. Kraemer and Jason Dedrick. 2007. “Who Captures Value in a Global Innovation System? The case of Apple's iPod,” Mimeo. Irvine CA: Personal Computing Industry Center. Maggi, Giovanni, and Andres Rodriguez-Clare. 2007. “A Political-Economy Theory of Trade Agreements,” American Economic Review, 97(4): 1374–1406. Martin, Will, and Francis Ng. 2004. “A Note on Sources of Tariff Reductions in Developing Countries 19832003,” World Bank. Melitz, Marc J. and Stephen J. Reddding. 2014. “Missing Gains from Trade?” NBER Working Paper No. 19810, January 2014. Melitz, Marc J. and Daniel Trefler. 2012. “Gains from Trade when Firms Matter,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 26(2), Spring: 91–118. Melitz, Marc J. 2003. “The Impact of Trade on Intra-Industry Reallocations and Aggregate Industry Productivity,” Econometrica 71(6): 1695-1725. Neely, Andy, Ornella Benedetinni, and Ivanka Visnjic. 2011. “The servitization of manufacturing: Further evidence,” paper presented at the 18th European Operations Management Association Conference, Cambridge, July 2011. O’Rourke, Kevin H.O. 2000. “British trade policy in the 19th century: a review article,” European Journal of Political Economy 16: 829–842. Ossa, Ralph. 2012. “Why Trade Matters After All,” NBER Working Paper No. 18113. Petri, Peter A., Michael G. Plummer and Fan Zhai. 2013. “Adding Japan and Korea to the TPP” Mimeo, 7 March 2013. Petri, Peter A., Michael G. Plummer and Fan Zhai. 2011. “The Trans-Pacific Partnership and Asia-Pacific Integration: A Quantitative Assessment” East-West Center Working Paper No. 119. Ravenhill, John. 2009. “Extending the TPP: The Political Economy of Multilateralization in Asia,” paper prepared for the Asia‐Pacific Trade Economists’ Conference, ARTNeT, UNESCAP and UNDP, Bangkok, November 2‐3, 2009. Schwab, Susan C. 2011. “After Doha: Why the Negotiations Are Doomed and What We Should Do About It,” Foreign Affairs May/June 2011 Silva, Armando, Oscar Afonso and Ana Paula Africano. 2012. “Learning-by-Exporting: What We Know and What We Would Like to Know,” The International Trade Journal 26(3): 255-288. Sykes, Alan O. 2001. “ ‘Efficient Protection’ Through WTO Rulemaking,” in Roger Porter, Pierre Sauve, Arvind Subramanian & Americo Zampetti (eds.), Efficiency, Equity and Legitimacy: The Multilateral Trading System at the Millennium. Washington: Brookings Institution: 114-141. Van Assche, Ari. 2012. “Global Value Chains and Canada’s Trade Policy: Business as Usual or Paradigm Shift?” IRPP Study No. 32, Montreal: Institute for Research on Public Policy, June 2012. World Trade Organization. 2013. “Made in the World.” http://www.wto.org/english/res_e/statis_e/miwi_e/miwi_e.htm. 49
© Copyright 2024