German Children’s Welfare Between Economy and Ideology Karin Jurczyk, Thomas Olk and Helga Zeiher Introduction1 The objective of this study is to present selected dimensions of child welfare in contemporary Germany. The study’s argumentation does not apply descriptive logic, but rather an explicitly analytical perspective. The central thesis is that the welfare and well-being of children in Germany are influenced to a high extent by a clear discrepancy between children’s real forms of living (and those of their immediate family) on one hand, and ideological constructions of ‘a good childhood’ and the resulting ‘institutional framework’ of children’s lives on the other. Economic modernisation and policy decisions appear to be increasingly distancing themselves from the demands and needs of children and their life worlds. As a result, German society and the German welfare state – in contrast to the self-conception of the Scandinavian countries, for example – are considered ‘structurally indifferent’ (Bundesministerium für Familie und Senioren – BMFuS, 1994) towards children and families. Both the demands of modern economic life and the basic political-institutional conditions make it difficult for parents and potential parents to organise their lives with children, and have a negative effect on the well-being and happiness of children. The causes of these contradictions between modern children’s lives, on one hand, and dominant ideologies and institutions in society, on the other hand, are to be found a long way back in German history. The German welfare state is a typical representative of the ‘conservative welfare regime’ type according to the typology of Esping-Andersen (1990). It has been influenced throughout its historical development – as can be shown for all welfare states of this type – by the Catholic church and political Catholicism. This, and the experience of 1 Thomas Olk wrote the sections on Introduction, The social situation of children and families and Childhood in the German welfare state. Karin Jurczyk wrote the section on Small children’s time and space. Helga Zeiher wrote the section on Schoolchildren’s activities in time and space. Children’s Welfare in Ageing Europe National Socialism, prevented the concept of comprehensive care for citizens ‘from the cradle to the grave’ establishing itself in post-war Germany. Instead, the welfare state principle is complemented by the principles of solidarity and subsidiarity. Thus, the welfare state was in fact institutionalised as a mechanism of social balance; however, it has been understood from the very beginning as subordinated to both the economy and the private forms of welfare such as families, extended family networks, etc. This means, firstly, that the state is traditionally restrained in its interventions into families (see the section on Childhood in the German welfare state). However, it also means, additionally, that the entire state structure is typified by characteristics of countervailing power and decentralisation. For example, the Federal Republic of Germany is a federal state in which the 16 Länder possess a considerable share of political power. For this reason, many federal laws cannot be passed without the approval of the Upper House – the ‘Bundesrat’. In addition, the political regulation and financing responsibilities are distributed between the federation, the Länder and the local authorities. This has serious consequences for children’s welfare. For example, family policy is determined by the federation, educational policy by the Länder, and policies concerning social services for children and young people are primarily determined by local government. These ‘interlocking policies in the federal state’ lead to considerable regional differences in important areas of child welfare, e.g. in the school systems or in the provision of childcare facilities and further social policy-related provisions for children and families. These regional differences cannot be presented in detail within this study. In one regard however – that of differences between eastern and western Germany – regional differences must be taken into account. From 1949 to 1990, two German states coexisted, characterised by two completely differing policies towards children and families, and thus by differing societal positions of children. In 1990, the German Democratic Republic (GDR) was integrated into the Federal Republic of Germany (FRG), and the political and economic system of the FRG was transferred to eastern Germany. As this study focuses on children’s current situation, we will only make reference to the GDR past and the phase of transformation after unification in as far as conditions in the former GDR, today’s ‘eastern Germany’, show a particular form of life situations of children and families due to their different history. Further factors which cannot be taken into account are possible differences between urban and rural regions, and the specific situation of migrants. In 2003, Germany had a population of 82.5 mill. in 375,026 km². With a population density of 231 inhabitants/km², Germany is at fourth place in the European comparison, after the Netherlands, Belgium and the United Kingdom, and is 704 COST A19: Germany thereby one of Europe’s most densely populated regions.2 In addition, Germany has effectively been an immigration country for some time, whereby the main immigrant groups are foreigners and ‘Aussiedler’, emigrants from Germanspeaking regions of eastern Europe.3 The non-German population expanded from almost 700,000 in 1961 to 7.3 mill. in the year 2000. Additionally, approximately 3 mill. ‘Aussiedler’ have entered the Federal Republic since 1980 (Avenarius et al., 2003). This means that a significant percentage of children will also be influenced by their migration background in the years to come (Avenarius et al., 2003: 77). A migration background is assumed when at least one parent was born outside of Germany. Defined as such, we come to a migration percentage for the group of 15 year-olds – on which the PISA4 study provides information – in Germany in the early summer of 2000 of 21.7 per cent, with a percentage of non-Germans defined by nationality of only 9.3 per cent, a difference arising from taking naturalised citizens, ‘Aussiedler’ and asylum seekers and refugees into account. In this respect, there are stark regional differences. While the percentage of non-Germans among 15 year-olds in eastern Germany (including Berlin) is only 3.5 per cent, and the percentage of young people with migration background in this area is 7.6 per cent, the corresponding comparison values in western Germany are 11.7 per cent (nonGermans) and 27.1 per cent (young people with migration backgrounds). The following analysis of the living situation and welfare of children draws on the stock of available secondary statistical material (statistical data, governmental reports, administrational documents etc.) and sociological studies. Several problems and limitations result from these sources. For example, although the data situation on the lives of children and the sociological research situation on children’s welfare has certainly improved over the past few years, we have repeatedly come across gaps in the data situation and research desiderata. Also, not all data and sociological studies are focused on the children’s perspective. Despite these conditions, the following analysis is oriented towards describing the living situation of children – wherever possible on the basis of the available data – from the perspective of children, and selecting the population sector of children as a unit of reference of social 2 Cf. http://www.destatis.de/jahrbuch/jahrtab1.htm. The most important migrant groups are made up of labour migrants, asylum seekers and refugees, reunified family members and – unique to Germany – ‘Aussiedler’. This term refers to German nationals and members of German minorities from the former areas of the German Reich in eastern and central Europe, and from the former Soviet Union and its successor states, from Poland and Rumania. 4 PISA is the name of a recent school achievement study comparing OECD nations (15 year old pupils). German pupils’ relatively bad achievement results as well as a relatively high impact of social class on German pupils’ achievement results caused intense public debates (Baumert et al., 2001). 3 705 Children’s Welfare in Ageing Europe statistics. Only in those cases in which information from other perspectives contributes to completing the overall picture are non-child-oriented data sets and research findings used. The social situation of children and families5 Germany is lacking in children Neither an approach focusing on the living conditions and opportunities of children in the ‘here and now’, nor a perspective concentrating on the reproduction of human capabilities (‘Humanvermögen’) can ignore the basic fact that the number of children and the relative proportion of the upcoming generation in the overall population will continue to shrink in the coming decades. This development is connected with demographic factors such as a low fertility rate, increasing life expectancy and mobility behaviour. For example, the number of live births per woman has been below the level that would be necessary to keep up the structure of the population through the upcoming generation for several decades. The fertility rate per woman in Germany has been at 1.4 children for several decades.6 This fertility rate places Germany in the lower third in comparison to other industrial countries; only Austria, the Russian Federation and Italy have lower fertility rates (The World Bank, 2001: 106-108). In the past, increasing life expectancy and low fertility rates led to the percentage of children among the overall population decreasing from 27.8 per cent to 18.7 per cent, in the period from 1950 to 2001. In contrast, the percentage of over 65 year-olds rose from 9.5 per cent to 17.1 per cent, over the same period. This development will be continued more intensively in the decades to come. Population prognoses anticipate that the proportion of children will fall within the coming 50 years, from 18.7 per cent (2001) to approximately 14.4 per cent in the year 2050 (Statistisches Bundesamt, 2003b). Although the ratio of birth and death rates has been continuously negative since the 1970s,7 this development has been obscured by the years with high fertility rates, and by constantly high immigration rates into the 1990s. As these 5 Thanks to Maksim Hübenthal and Thomas Stimpel for their support in research and graphic presentation of the data. 6 To reproduce the population in the existing structure by upcoming generations, a fertility rate of approximately 2.1 children per woman would be necessary. The actual fertility rate thus causes each following generation to be approximately one third smaller than the previous generation. 7 Due to the falling fertility rate, deaths exceeded births for the first time in a time of peace in 1972 (Schwarz, 2002). 706 COST A19: Germany conditions are unlikely to apply in the future, the population will shrink, initially slowly but from 2020 onwards at an accelerated rate, whereby the decrease in the population of employable age will take effect earlier, and have even more serious consequences. The background to these developments are structural changes in birth patterns. For example, the reduction of births in the first half of the 20th century, compared to the preceding century, was mainly due to a reduction in the number of children born per couple, while the percentage of married couples even increased slightly. Among those born after 1950, in contrast, we can observe a significant reduction of marriage frequency, linked with a significant increase in the percentage of women remaining childless for their entire lives. While the proportion of lifelong childless women among those born in the 1930s was 10 per cent, it was already at 16 per cent for those born in 1950, and rose to 33 per cent for women born in 1970 (Birg and Flöthmann, 1993). The percentage of women remaining childless is above average for highly qualified women. For example, 42 per cent of women born between 1962 and 1966 and possessing a university or polytechnic degree will remain childless for their whole lives, while this figure is at 28 per cent for all women in western Germany (Grünheid, 2003).8 Studies on young people’s preferences for having children show that complex processes of weighing up and biographical decision-making lie behind this development. If we go by the findings of empirical surveys, a majority of young people under 30 in Germany would still like to have two or more children (Löhr, 1991). This fact leads us to believe that we are dealing, in many cases, with processes of postponing having children, which then eventually end in ‘voluntary’ childlessness. It appears that a growing discrepancy has emerged in Germany between subjective wishes for a life with children on one hand, and the economic, political and social conditions of realising this wish on the other hand, which we will refer to in more detail below. Children in Germany are at over-proportionate risk of poverty Since the 1990s, the material situation and the poverty risk of children have been the subject of an interest unprecedented in the history of the FRG from the media and the public sphere.9 Until now, older people and (widowed, divorced 8 This difference is less pronounced in eastern Germany. However, forecasts show that a corresponding development to the rest of the country is also gaining momentum in the former GDR (Grünheid, 2003). 9 For example, public debate on the Tenth Children’s and Young People’s Report (BMFSFJ, 1998), which claims to be the first comprehensive children’s report in Germany, was concentrated on the statements on child poverty laid out on only a few pages, and led to great controversy between the Christian-Liberal federal government of the time and the expert commission. 707 Children’s Welfare in Ageing Europe and/or single) women were regarded as at risk of poverty; children were thought to be materially relatively well secured in this respect. However, sociological poverty research has been pointing out a shift of poverty risk since the late 1980s, away from the traditional risk groups – such as older people, for example – to children and young people – or specific family arrangements with children – and coined the rather unfortunate term of ‘infantilisation of poverty’ to refer to the phenomenon (Hauser and Voges, 1999). These problem diagnoses were vehemently rejected, with reference to the unclear and controversial status of the poverty definitions applied, and the supposedly limited significance of deprivation in countries with high standards of living (Krämer, 2000). If we work on the basis of a relative concept of poverty, then it is true that the FRG is ranked in the mid-field in a comparison of frequency of child poverty in western countries; according to the well-regarded UNICEF study, 10.7 per cent of children in Germany were living in relative poverty in the mid 1990s, while the entire spectrum ranges from 2.6 per cent in Sweden to 22.4 per cent in the USA (UNICEF, 2000). Overall, in an international comparison Germany is a country with a high material standard of living. According to the findings of the Income and Consumption Survey (EVS), the average household income in western Germany showed a growth of 20.5 per cent in real terms from 1973 to 1998. In eastern Germany, net income showed an increase in real terms of 9.6 per cent between 1993 and 1998 (BMAuS, 2001: XVI). However, income and wealth are (also) unequally distributed in Germany, and this inequality has increased over the past decades. On the basis of data from the EVS survey, Becker and Hauser (2003: 33) illustrate that both the poverty and the wealth rate have risen in western Germany in the period since 1973. The growth of the poverty rate was even more pronounced than that of the wealth rate; the former rate rose by two thirds – from 6.5 per cent in 1973 to 10.9 per cent in 1998, whereby this increase took place at the end of the 1970s. However, the individual age groups were affected differently by this development. For children under 14 years, there are over-proportionate poverty rates at all times of the surveys, and also above average increases in poverty frequency.10 Child poverty is thus not a new problem, but rather an intensifying problem also increasingly affecting young people and young adults. In 1998, approximately every 6th child in western Germany was living on less than half 10 At this point, we must point out that the equivalence scale used in each measurement of the scope of child poverty is of great significance. Depending on which needs weightings are ascribed to further household members and children, different poverty rates are established. A high needs weighting for children leads to an increase in poverty frequency of children and households with many children, while low needs weightings have the opposite effect (cf. e.g. Faik, 1997). 708 COST A19: Germany of the average net equivalent income. In contrast to the general trend, only the poverty rates of the two oldest groups initially fell, only to rise again at a later point.11 At the other end of the income distribution scale – that is, in the ‘higher income bracket’12 – children and young people in particular, but also older people are underrepresented, while people in the central working age and an increasing number of 55 to 64 year-olds are over-proportionately represented. As well as registering poverty by relative poverty measures, we can also make use of the political definition of poverty when carrying out empirical poverty measurements. This uses the level at which public assistance is payable according to the Federal Public Assistance Act (BSHG) as a benchmark. Households and individuals falling below this threshold receive ‘continuous subsistence payments’ (HLU), according to the BSHG. Many analysts therefore refer to ‘combated poverty’ in this context. Population groups who rely on this form of state support are registered in the official public assistance statistics.13 The public assistance statistics also show an increase in the number of children affected by this form of politically defined ‘combated poverty’. The younger a child in Germany is, the greater is the probability that it lives in a family claiming public assistance. To explain this phenomenon: more than half of children claiming public assistance live in households with lone mothers, while just under a third live in family households in which married couples live with children. While children and young people of school age are particularly affected in the married couple households, toddlers and pre-school children are particularly frequently represented in lone parent households claiming public assistance (Federal Statistical Office Germany, 2004). 11 A such over-proportionate frequency of poverty among children can also be proved on the basis of other data sets. For example, Bacher and Wenzig (2002) come to the conclusion on the basis of the data of the Socio-Economic Panel (1999) that the risk of poverty in western Germany in 1999 was almost twice as high for children than for adults. They calculate a relation of 2.4 for eastern Germany (Bacher and Wenzig, 2002: 119). According to their analyses, the risk of poverty is linked with variables such as lone parent families, households with three or more adults, number of unemployed in the household, educational level and number of siblings. 12 The higher income bracket is defined as 200 per cent and above of the arithmetic mean average of the net equivalent income (Becker and Hauser, 2003: 35). 13 However, public assistance is only of limited use for measuring poverty, in that only those people affected by poverty can be registered who claim support payments. Lowincome individuals who do not claim public assistance, although they would be legally entitled to benefits, that is the ‘hidden poor’, are not registered using this procedure (Neumann and Hertz, 1998). 709 Children’s Welfare in Ageing Europe Figure 1. Children in the public assistance statistics – percentage of the respective population group of the same age. 10 8 All minors under 7 year-olds 7 to 11 year-olds 11 to 15 year-olds 15 to 18 year-olds percent per cent 6 4 2 0 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 Source: Federal Statistical Office Germany, 2004; public assistance data have no longer been analysed separately for eastern and western Germany since 2002. Figure 2 shows the divergence of poverty and wealth rates for the younger generation, in comparison to those of the medium and older population groups in western Germany. As comparison lines, the corresponding rates for the overall population are shown.14 The diagram shows that the wealth rate of children and young adults up to 24 years has remained slightly further behind the overall development over the time period, while the poverty rate of the younger generation has exceeded the generally rising trend. Of this development to the disadvantage of children we can observe a slight weakening in the phase from 1993 to 1998, which results from the improvement of the child benefit package (‘Familienlastenausgleich’) introduced in phases since 1993 (tax exemption of the minimum standard of living, particularly a significant increase in child benefit in 1996). However, other developments (such as the rise in unemployment rates, low collective wage agreements, reduction of bonuses above the collectively agreed level, etc.) have cancelled out these improvements. The result is that age-specific poverty rates have not fallen significantly, despite improvements in family policy (Becker and Hauser, 2003: 35). 14 The wealth rate for all individuals up to and including 24 years was compiled together, as the rates for the sub-groups are similar. 710 COST A19: Germany Figure 2. Development of the poverty and wealth rates* of the respective young generation (under 25 years) in western Germany**, 1973 to 1998. 18 Poverty/wealth rate (in %) 16 14 Poverty 0-6 y. Poverty 7-13 y. Poverty 14-17 y. Poverty 18-24 y. Poverty total Wealth total Wealth 0-24 y. 12 10 8 6 4 2 0 1973 1978 1983 1988 1993 1998 Year * Poverty threshold: 50 percent of the arithmetical mean average of net equivalent income. Wealth treshold: 200 percent of the arithmetical mean average of net equivalent income. **Excluding households with non-German heads. Source: Becker and Hauser, 2003: 35. Overall, we can make the following summary: while a rather decreasing group of children certainly profits from their parents’ growing wealth, increasing income inequality and growing poverty rates have contributed to a relative deterioration of the overall material situation of children. Children in both western and eastern Germany are over-proportionately affected by relative poverty and precarious wealth, whereby this does not apply to all children to the same extent. Demographic factors such as the type of family (particularly lone parent families and families with many children), the number of unemployed or inactive adults in the household and the educational level of the parents or guardians are decisive for the concrete material situation and/or poverty of households. Independent of the concrete material situation of the household in which children live, they may have their own more or less direct sources of money. They thus act as (potential) consumers on consumer markets and are correspondingly targeted by advertising. One important source of money from parents to children is pocket money. This is given by parents for educational reasons as a rule, so that children can learn to deal with money independently. In an empirical survey of parents in 1997, it emerged that 80 per cent of all those interviewed paid their children regular pocket money, four per cent paid this regular pocket money depending on specific conditions (school marks, help in 711 Children’s Welfare in Ageing Europe the household) and 16 per cent did not pay their children regular pocket money, but instead gave them money when they needed it (Rosendorfer, 2000: 47). Regular pocket money is paid more often in higher social classes than in lower classes, a fact which is particularly significant for those interviewed in the western part of Germany. Further, a higher proportion of west German parents give regular pocket money (83 per cent) than of east Germans interviewed (72 per cent). If funds are short in a household, children more frequently receive money when they need it. The level of pocket money varies considerably within the individual age groups. According to the survey, the majority of 10 to 11 year-olds receives a monthly amount; on an average of 10 ± 5 Euro. The group of 12 to 13 year-olds receives an average of 15 ± 8 Euro, the 14 to 15 year-olds receive 21 ± 9 Euro and the oldest group of 16 to 17 year-olds is paid 37 ± 24 Euro (Table 1). The amount of pocket money paid is not linked to income or social class. Predictably, most children and young people receive further money from other sources, the amount of which also rises with increasing age. Table 1 shows that help around the household is rewarded as a special activity for boys in particular, while it tends to be naturally expected of girls. With increasing age, the number of children earning their own additional money rises continually (see section on The power of school on children’s time). This corresponds to increasing income from part time jobs (Table 1). The amount of monthly additional income is between 1 Euro and 720 Euro, whereby this figure is also dependent on age. Boys and girls earn approximately the same amount and there are no east/west differences in the level of earnings. Table 1. Average monthly amount from various sources of money, 1997. Age groups 12-13 14-15 16-17 Source of Money years years years Amount in Euro Pocket money 10 15 21 37 Money from part time jobs 3 17 41 77 Money as gifts 7 11 12 15 Money for helping in the household 3 5 7 10 Money for good school marks 4 5 6 7 Source: Deutsches Jugendinstitut — DJI survey ‘Children and Money’, 1997, in: Rosendorfer, T. 2000: 51, (rounded figures). 10-11 years Six per cent of young people in the families interviewed in eastern and western Germany already have their own income, the majority in the form of payment 712 COST A19: Germany for a traineeship. The amount of own income varies between 77 Euro and 920 Euro per month, whereby most young people earn between 255 Euro and 410 Euro. One third of the young people pay some of the money they earn towards the household, on average approximately 72 Euro per month. Money given as gifts – particularly for birthdays and Christmas – also plays a significant role. The level of these annual gifts of money can amount to up to 3700 Euro. The fact that some children do not receive pocket money at all is not necessarily an indicator of poverty or low income of the family household (Feil, 2003: 48). On the contrary, more detailed analyses show that the largest per centage of children receiving money sporadically or not at all belongs to the age group of 6 to 8 year-olds. Some parents obviously start giving pocket money later. Overall, the available empirical studies show that the percentage of children from low-income families who do not get pocket money at all is at the average level for society. According to Feil (2003: 52), this is an expression of the fact that a certain group of low-income parents finds it important to pay their children pocket money so as not to disadvantage them, and to avoid them employing illegitimate means of satisfying their wishes. It is further supposed that parents with low income motivate their children to gain relative financial independence through their own work at an earlier point. According to private sector consumer analyses, the ‘total income’ of 6 to 17 year-olds thus coming into being in the year 2000 amounts to approximately 5 mill. Euro (Feil, 2003: 78). It is difficult to prove whether this sum has increased over the past few years, as is assumed in the debate on the subject, using the empirical findings available.15 The importance of children as actors on consumer markets is certainly not, however, limited to them spending the sums of money directly available to them. In fact, they exercise a considerable influence on their parents’ purchase choices.16 The area of consumer goods over which children exercise influence includes both non-durable goods such as food and body care products, and durables from the areas of clothing, electronic equipment, household and home equipment, cars, games and leisure. Such goods are bought by parents for children, the household or the whole family. Corresponding consumer surveys show that children’s influence is greater, the more children-specific the products named in the survey are. It further emerges that children show better product knowledge and brand awareness than their parents in certain product divisions (e.g. for selected food goods, but also for leisure products, in the computer sector and for entertainment electronics). However, we should not overestimate children’s purchasing influence. The 15 We must take into account that not all of the total is spent on the consumer markets during the year, but a considerable amount of this money is saved. 16 For this reason, private sector studies of the economic role of children differentiate between direct and indirect purchasing power (Feil, 2003: 77). 713 Children’s Welfare in Ageing Europe empirical findings show that parents do have conversations with their children about financial matters as a rule, but only one sixth of those interviewed stated that children are allowed to join in decisions on larger purchases for the family. Even in the case of larger purchases for children, parents reserve the right to make the purchase decision themselves (Rosendorfer, 2000: 83; also Feil, 2003: 101-103). Overall, we can infer that in the modern family ‘as a negotiation household’, children do partly influence purchase decisions, but these decisions must be understood as the result of the interplay of the differing preferences of all members of the family. Childhood in the German welfare state Child and family policy in the period of reconstruction The foundations for the specific position of children and families in German society were laid directly after the Second World War. During this phase of development, which one could also describe as the ‘golden years’ of the bourgeois family model, the private forms of family life and the institutional framework, as it was structured by the policy of the time, appeared to match perfectly. The child and family policy of the time followed guidelines considered a fundamental alternative to both the child and family policy of the National Socialist state and to those of the GDR. The aim was to institutionalise marriage and the family as sectors of the private sphere with their own logic, removed from state intervention. The social conservative policy of the Adenauer era was concerned with the protection and promotion of the family as an institution (Bast and Ostner, 1992; Münch, 1990: 160). Family policy abstained from any form of intervention in the internal matters of the family, restricting itself to additional measures of the promotion of families, such as supporting property and home-owning, transport policy and especially spreading family-related rhetoric. The state was to deal with economic assistance payments in an extremely reserved manner and every openly proclaimed pro-natalistic programme and policy was taboo, in view of the experiences with the National Socialist state’s intervention in the family.17 As 17 The state’s reservation was also expressed in the low level and the institutional structure of the first child benefit regulations of 1954. Child benefit was only provided from the 3rd child on. This child benefit was financed exclusively by the employer side and paid by ‘Familienausgleichskassen’ as self-administrative organs, in order to avoid a direct financial payment to families by the state. Since the child benefit act of 1954, economic support of children and families has mainly taken place according to the principle of the ‘dual system’ of financial support for families, which is based on a combination of tax-free allowances and child benefit payments. 714 COST A19: Germany raising children was considered an ancient natural task of the parents, any form of childcare above the level of half-day nurseries (for children of at least 3) and half-day schools was seen as an illegitimate form of ‘nationalisation’ of childrearing. In accordance with this family ideal, employment, social and family policy applied in the German welfare state in the 1950s and 1960s was oriented towards the ‘strong male breadwinner model’. In taxation law for example, joint tax assessment for married couples ensured (and continues to ensure) a significant privileged status for the singleearner marriage, or at best for the additional earner model. According to the regulations valid since 1958, the income of both partners is initially added together, and then halved to calculate the tax due. The tax due on the halfincome is finally multiplied by two. This form of taxation has the result that tax savings compared to singly assessed taxpayers are greater, the higher the income and the income difference. A married couple in which only one partner is in paid employment thus has the highest tax advantages. Ironically, the result of this Christian-conservative societal policy was not the recreation of the old German family (as a family of multiple children and multiple generations), but instead the spread of the modern family as described by Parsons (Bast and Ostner, 1992: 253). The accumulated marriage rates reached their highest levels in the 1950s and 1960s (Huinink, 1995: 218) and the net fertility rate increased again after the war, exceeding the necessary value of 1 to maintain the population for the first time in 1957, only to further exceed this level up until the mid-1960s (Huinink, 1995: 237). Under these conditions, the specific performance potential of this form of family reached its peak. Through the broad freeing up of wives and mothers for family-related tasks, expressed not least in the relatively low rate of mothers’ employment, it became possible to individualise the task of raising and caring for children to an unprecedented extent, as the care ratio in families rarely exceeded a level of 1:3 (Bertram, 1998). Closely linked to this development was a gradually beginning displacement of children from public spaces and their enclosure in the domestic space of family living communities (familisation of childhood). Using the welfare state typology of Esping-Andersen (1990) as a basis, the German welfare state in fact proved to be a prototype of the social-conservative welfare state regime, with its propagation of the male breadwinner/housewife family, the delegation of the tasks of raising children to families and the extensive reservation concerning family-related legal and monetary intervention in the 1950s and 1960s. 715 Children’s Welfare in Ageing Europe Family policy enters the 1980s In the course of the transition to the Christian-Liberal coalition under chancellor Helmut Kohl in 1982, a renewed paradigm shift took place in German policy towards children and families. Against the backdrop of an economic growth crisis, rising unemployment and increasingly tangible financing shortages in public budgets, the Kohl government implemented selective consolidation measures in various social security systems on one hand, and adopted a course of expansion in the area of family policy on the other hand. The new course in family policy, which can certainly be placed in line in the ‘tradition of great social reforms’ (Schmidt, 1998: 105), included both the gradual expansion of financial support for families, and completely new elements such as the introduction of the three ‘Ps’, i.e. parental benefit, parental leave and parental periods in pension insurance (Münch, 1990: 172). The introduction of parental benefit and parental leave in particular was intended to place family and paid work on an equal footing, and improve the freedom of choice between family and paid employment both for women and for men. Mothers and fathers were to be able to make a free choice of whether and how long they wanted to exit paid employment for the purpose of raising children.18 The Social Democrats had criticised these regulations strongly from the very beginning, as they feared a conservation of the traditional female role model, with the result that women would be displaced from the labour market. In fact, parental leave was, and still is, almost exclusively – in over 90 per cent of cases – taken up by mothers. However, this is primarily a result of the too low calculation of parental benefit, compared to wages and salaries earned on the labour market. As husbands tend to earn more than their wives, it is usually the woman who gives up her working income and takes parental leave, for purely financial reasons.19 So, although the political intention of the Christian-Liberal coalition was to increase freedom of choice, the concrete form of the regulations ended up re-cementing the traditional gender-specific division of labour. Additionally, the Christian-Liberal coalition introduced the recognition of periods of intensive child-rearing in pension rights, through the Survivors’ Pensions and Child Rearing Benefits Law (HEZG) of 1985. These periods of intensive child-rearing were intended to supplement parental leave and parental 18 During parental leave, part time employment of up to 19 hours per week was allowed. No previous employment was necessary to claim parental benefit. An employment guarantee was given by the old employer for the length of the parental leave. 19 Further, an interruption of a working career has always been linked with further disadvantages and problems. These concern both the chances for an adequate re-entry onto the labour market, and also missed career advancement and pay rises normally connected with continuous career courses. 716 COST A19: Germany benefit in long term social security, so that parents who have devoted themselves to raising children, and given up paid work to do so, do not have to fear excessive losses to their pension rights. During the transition from the 1980s to the 1990s, the child and family policy debate was given a completely new impetus by societal and political influences. In this context, we must refer to the fall of the GDR regime and the German unification it made possible. In the course of the transformation process of eastern Germany, western institutions were transferred to eastern Germany more or less one-to-one. However, the family and child policy regulations of the GDR, such as the extensive legal equality of women, the high level of labour market integration of women and mothers, the generous financial provisions for mothers and children and young families, and the extensive system of public childcare, from crèches to after-school care, were regarded as superior to the western institutions and provisions. When the much more liberal abortion laws of the GDR had to be adjusted to the new unified German constitutional reality in the early 1990s, it was possible, in view of these influences of east German ‘achievements’ on the west German debate, to push through a statutory entitlement to a half-day childcare placement for children between the ages of 3 and 6 years in 1992, after long discussions (Hauser et al., 1996: 88). We can see a further impetus for child and family policy discussion in the 1990s in the discovery of the ‘productive value’ of family work for society as a whole. Material disadvantages and losses connected with the decision to start a family, and the growing risk of poverty of children – or of specific family arrangements with children (infantilisation of poverty; cf. the section on The social situation of children and families) – led ever more frequently to public criticism of the insufficient state provisions for children and families.20 In this situation, the Fifth Family Report (BMFuS, 1994) pointed out the specific contribution made by families towards the production and reproduction of ‘human capabilities’ (‘Humanvermögen’). The central message of this report’s argumentation was that families create ‘positive external effects’ in carrying out their everyday lives, from which all other societal subsystems – the economy, social security, politics, etc. – profit. From a perspective of comprehensive economics, such positive effects of family production are not only the quantitative reproduction of the population and the securing of the following generation, but 20 From the late 1980s on, the federal constitutional court exercised a serious influence on political decisions in the area of child and family policy, through a serious of contentious rulings. We cannot go into this development in detail within this report (Gerlach, 2000). However, particularly with respect to the financial support for families, we can establish in hindsight over the last 15 years that the respective governments in power were forced to implement continuous further development of provisions for children and families by the rulings of the federal constitutional court. 717 Children’s Welfare in Ageing Europe particularly the creation and development of ‘human capabilities’ by raising children. As this production appeared to be no longer kept up in a natural way and without problems in the course of the pursuit of happiness and wealth of potential parents, the state was called for to create more positive basic conditions. From a child policy perspective, it is remarkable that the fact that birth rates are falling and children are thereby becoming ‘scarce’ in modern societies did not lead to a direct improvement of the social status and the material situation of children in Germany, but rather to an honouration of the value of parents’ childrearing activities. Thus, children’s own contribution, both to family welfare production and to self-socialisation and self-qualification, takes second place, from the political point of view, to the exclusive recognition of parents’ childrearing activities (Olk and Mierendorff, 1998). The practical result of this discussion was gradual improvements of financial provisions and tax relief within the ‘dual system’ of financial support for families in 1982, which were, however, unable to keep up with the increasing costs of living and of bringing up children overall. In view of this fact, the system of financial support for families was reformed once again in 1996 (Lampert, 1996: 166). Child allowance and child tax credit were greatly increased again, however the ‘dual system’ was abolished to the extent that potential claimants now had to decide between the two options, depending on which was more beneficial to them. The decisive improvement of provisions by the new regulations can be seen particularly in the fact that child allowance was not only raised from the third child on, but for the first and second child, to 102 Euro per child in 1996 and 112 Euro per child in 1997, so that the majority of families with up to two children is among those benefited. Overall, although these new laws improved the situation of low-income families, the relative material disadvantages of families with children compared to couples without children remained in existence to a great extent. We can also recognise the strongly pronounced familyism and conservatism in German child and family policy in the fact that it has been impossible to date to promote child-based policies and measures against the dominance of family policy, despite impulses and positive examples from other European countries (Mierendorff and Olk, 2003). Since the late 1970s, we have seen indications of transformation processes in this regard, which were reflected in the political arena in the development of new perspectives and approaches to a policy for children. For example, in 1988 a children’s commission was set up as part of the German parliament, children’s Ombudsmen have appointed in many local authorities, and the participation of children and young people in schools, Kindergartens and similar institutions has improved. On a legal regulation level, above all the UN Convention for the Rights of the Child of 1989, ratified in the FRG in 1991 – with restrictions – led to many different efforts to strengthen both the legal position of children and also the measures and policies for 718 COST A19: Germany children. Nevertheless, the necessity of an independent children-based policy is stubbornly questioned both in the public discourse and on the federal political level. Particularly from a family policy point of view, it is argued that an independent childhood policy constructs an unnecessary clash of interests between children and their parents, thereby damaging children in their development chances more than benefiting them. Policy for children and families under the ‘Red-Green’ coalition from 1998 to 2002 The SPD-Green Party government essentially extended the financial support for families in their first legislatory period from 1998 to 2002, through a total of three increases in child benefit and the introduction of further tax allowances (Bleses, 2003). Alongside these measures, parental leave was converted to the ‘parenting period’.21 With the new possibilities of taking simultaneous parental leave and the raised threshold of permitted working hours during the parenting period, it is easier for fathers and mothers to remain more strongly anchored on the labour market, even while rearing young children. The new parenting period thereby already paves the way towards improved compatibility of family and paid work for both parents. Further, the inclusion of periods of intensive childrearing in pension insurance was further extended retroactively as of January 2002, back to 1992. The survivors’ pensions were also changed so as to favour parents over childless insured parties. The ‘Red-Green’ coalition government had not left the previous developmental path of transfer-based family and child policy. This had the result that financial transfers significantly outweigh transfers in kind, in the form of services, in German child and family policy, in comparison to other European countries.22 The incentive and control effects of this transfer-oriented family 21 From now on, parents can take parental leave jointly for up to three years, whereby they are allowed to carry out paid work of up to 30 hours, rather than the previous 19 hours. With the agreement of the employer, a remainder period of the ‘parenting period’ of up to one year can be transferred to any point between the child’s 3rd and 8th birthday. With the part time law, parents have the additional right to part time work, in companies with over 15 employees, during the ‘parenting period’. 22 According to OECD data, approximately 71 per cent of the family policy budget in Germany is spent on monetary payments such as child benefit, and only 29 per cent on services. This percentage rate of services, i.e. mainly expenditure for childcare facilities, is among the lower values in the international comparison. In Denmark, for example, 59 per cent of expenditure is reserved for services. If we examine the structure of the family budget in detail, approximately 150 bill. Euro were subscribed to state payments for families with children in the year 2000, according to information from the German Federal Bank (German Federal Bank, 2002). 37,3 bill. Euro of this sum were made up 719 Children’s Welfare in Ageing Europe policy thus remain in effect. The interplay of the joint tax assessment of married couples and the non-contributory insurance of family members in the health and long term care insurance schemes, and not least the enormous deficits in the system of childcare under public responsibility had, and still do have, an effect of strongly pronounced negative incentives for an expansion of paid work by mothers (Dingeldey, 2002). Conversely, up to the present day, this has meant that those mothers who decide, against this incentive effect, for a combination of child-rearing and paid work have to tackle a variety of everyday practical and financial obstacles, in order to be able to live by this family model (cf. the section on Small children’s time and space). Policy for children and families under the ‘Red-Green’ coalition in the current period of legislation (2002-2006) The problems and disadvantages linked with this policy have since gained increasing attention in the discourse on family and child policy in the FRG. For these reasons, the SPD-Green Party coalition government announced a renewed paradigm shift in child and family policy for its second period of legislation (2002 to 2006), and has already partly put this into practice. In a significant departure from the previous wait-and-see attitude on the federal level in childcare policy, the federal government intends to improve the provision of public childcare facilities across the entire children’s age groups (all-day nurseries, after-school care in independent facilities and all-day schools). To this end, a total of 4 bill. Euro is to be made available from 2003 to 2007 for the Länder and local authorities primarily responsible in these policy areas, for the expansion of all-day schools, and subsequently from 2004 a further 1,5 bill. Euro for improved care through crèches and child-minders. Following a long phase of dominance of monetary provisions, the new motto is: services before money! of tax measures (30,7 bill. Euro of child benefit), 26,9 bill. Euro of transfers from local authorities (11,5 bill. Euro for intensive periods of child-rearing in the statutory pension insurance scheme, 4,1 bill. for public assistance, 3,7 bill. for parental benefit). 71 bill. Euro were spent on service provision (of which 7,4 bill. Euro for pre-school care, 55,3 bill. Euro for schools and higher education facilities) and 16 bill. Euro for social insurance provisions, of which 11,5 bill. Euro on non-contributory family insurance in health insurance schemes. The family budget defined as above rose from a share of 7,1 per cent of gross national product (GNP) in 1995 to 7,6 per cent in 1999. This increase results above all from the restructuring and increase of child benefit and tax allowance for children, increased construction grants for families and the re-evaluation of periods of intensive child-rearing in pension insurance. In contrast, services stagnated during this period. 720 COST A19: Germany However, these ambitious federal political objectives are faced with enormous implementation problems within the federal state. The provision of public childcare facilities for children of all age groups realised in the responsibility of local authorities is regulated by a federal law (i.e. the children’s and juveniles’ welfare act, KJHG, of 1990), however its practical application and financing is the responsibility of the Länder and in particular of the local authorities. The children’s and juveniles’ welfare act stipulates the standard nationwide basic conditions, but the concrete provisions are set in the regulatory statutes on the Länder legislatory level. The local authorities have a lower rank as institutions administrating childcare facilities (nurseries etc.). On the basis of the principle of subsidiarity, childcare facilities administrated by voluntary organisations (churches, charity organisations and further Third Sector organisations) have priority. Correspondingly, approximately 70 per cent of nursery places in western Germany are provided by voluntary organisations; additionally, facilities administrated by the parents (parents’ initiatives) have gained significance since the late 1970s. Local authority children’s and young people’s departments are responsible for establishing the level of requirements and for planning tasks. The construction and operating costs of the facilities are financed by the local authorities, whereby the Länder grant subsidies and the voluntary organisations perform certain services at their own cost. Parents also pay income-dependent contributions, which, however, only cover part of operating costs.23 This mix of regulation and financing responsibilities has been identified as a central obstacle to the politically intended expansion of nursery facilities (Kreyenfeld et al., 2002). For example, local authorities are free to choose which provision of after-school care and crèche places and nursery places providing care until the early afternoon and all-day nursery places to finance – excepting the nationwide right to a half-day nursery place between the ages of 3 and 6. The level of care provision thus depends on the financial scope and the priorities of the local authorities, in the final instance. One significant result of this situation is the strongly pronounced regional variation of care provision rates. Furthermore, the provision of childcare places differs extremely in eastern and western Germany, due to the different initial situations following unification and the demographic developments in both parts of the country (Table 2). While the care provision rate in eastern Germany has remained relatively high to the present day, 23 With regard to the assumption of costs, the rule applies in most Länder that up to 30 per cent of operating costs are assumed by the Land, 30 per cent by the local authority and 30 per cent by the corresponding voluntary organisation. The remaining 10 per cent is paid by the parents through socially tiered contributions. With regard to investment costs, there are considerable differences, according to regulations on the Länder legislatory level. As a rule, the Länder assume costs of up to 50 per cent. However, not every Land has legal regulations on the matter (Kreyenfeld et al., 2001: 43). 721 Children’s Welfare in Ageing Europe despite the closure of facilities and cuts totalling 30 per cent of spending between 1994 and 1998,24 provision in western Germany remains adverse. Spending in western Germany in the above time period rose only slightly, by only 10 per cent – starting from a low level of provision (Beher, 2001: 58). Table 2. Provision rates per 100 children, by age groups 1990/91, 1994 and 1998. 1990/91** 1994 1998 For children 0-3 years Germany 11.2 6.3 7.0 per 100 Western Germany 1.8 2.2 2.8 per 100 New Länder and East Berlin 54.2 41.6 36.3 per 100 For children 3-6 years Germany 87.0* 77.2 89.5 per 100 Western Germany 78.3* 73.0 86.8 per 100 New Länder and East Berlin 114.3* 96.2 111.8 per 100 For children 6-10 years Germany 13.8 17.2 16.0 per 100 Western Germany 5.5 5.1 6.1 per 100 New Länder and East Berlin 50.9 59.7 68.3 per 100 * The provision rate refers only to the 3 to 6 year-olds. ** The data for the new Länder including East Berlin were collected in 1991. *** The places for school-age children were supplemented in 1994 and 1998 by the number of children in after-school care on the school premises in East Berlin, SaxonyAnhalt, Thuringia, and in 1998 additionally in West Berlin. Source/calculation basis: Federal Statistical Office Germany: Subject series 13, series 6.3.1, 1998, In: Deutches Jugendinstitut, 2002: 34. The care situation is explored in more detail in the next section. 24 In view of the weak financial situation of eastern German local authorities, provision is likely to deteriorate with the forecast increase in birth rates in the eastern Länder. 722 COST A19: Germany Small children’s time and space: care between family and institutions25 Children within changing families The established tradition of assigning care, especially of the very young children, to the family is still going strong in Germany. Rooted in the 19th century, this concept is linked to the close association of femininity with motherhood, the exclusion of women from the public sphere and a moral valuation of the family space as the ‘proper’ world for mothers and children, whereas, in line with the formation of typical gender models, it was the fathers who, in the bourgeois family, represented the external world. In Germany, responsibility for care and the raising of children became increasingly restricted to the nuclear family. Care was privatised and made feminine, turned into a responsibility customised to each individual mother.26 Also at the start of the 21th century, living in a family shapes a child’s everyday life,27 and most children spend their childhood growing up together with their siblings or half-siblings.28 Looked at from a more detailed perspective, however, we find considerable differences between western and eastern Germany: in the West, the majority (77 per cent) of children up to the age of 18 have been living, from birth, with their biological married parents in a shared household; whereas the corresponding figure in the East is just 46 per cent (Alt, 2002: 236). Although the family pattern in western Germany is rather traditional, there are indications of changes towards increasing instability of the 25 I wish to extend my gratitude to Peggy Szymenderski and Andreas Lange for intellectual and practical support. 26 Development psychologists and anthropologists certainly agree that young children in particular depend on reliable love, provision, education and care in order to achieve their optimum development. To this end, the intimate frame of emotionally based relationships in a family which do not work on the principles of efficient time and cost management has as a rule been found to be especially suitable. Nevertheless, the effect may be reversed by failures in the intergenerational structure of a given family, so that the community and the state need to assume an interventionist role. For this reason, ‘care’ needs to be generally understood as a term defining the social responsibility of furnishing tangible and intangible provision that flows from the ontological fact of interhuman dependencies (Brückner, 2003). Care may be rendered both at a private family level and in a professional or honorary capacity. 27 In this context, ‘family’ is defined as a network that consists of the nuclear family living in a shared household plus relatives living in other places and other households (Bien, 1994). 28 Very few children live in non-family facilities. Institutional care has been on a steady decline since 1991. In 1998, 20–21 out of 10,000 children below the age of 15 lived in an institution (Bayer and Bauereiss, 2002). 723 Children’s Welfare in Ageing Europe conditions of growing up. These changes have clearer contours in eastern Germany. Concerning the number of siblings, the evaluations of the micro-census show rather that half (51 per cent) of all children were growing up with one further sibling in 1998, while only 16 per cent of all children had no further siblings (Bellenberg 2001: 27). In 23 per cent of families, three children under 18 were living together; in only seven per cent of families, children were living with three further siblings, and in four per cent with four further siblings. Although these facts hold approximately for both parts of Germany, the trend towards the two-child family is more prevalent in eastern Germany, at 58 per cent of all children, and family arrangements with three or more children are less common there than in western Germany. The family situation for children has been undergoing rapid change since 1988 (cf. Figure 3): Figure 3. Vital statistics of children in the old and new Länder of Germany, 1988-2000. 100% 80% 60% 40% 20% 0% West 88 West 94 West 2000 East 88 East 94 born in wedlock born out of wedlock born premaritally orphan or step-child single parent other East 2000 Source: Alt, 2003: 240. The increasing frequency of children living with a lone parent is also expressed in evaluations of data from the micro-census (Bellenberg, 2001: 24-26). For example, in 1998 2,6 mill. children under 18 years lived in a lone parent family arrangement or with two unmarried adults; this figure is equivalent to 17 per cent of all children, whereby this share has risen by five per cent since 1995. 724 COST A19: Germany The lone parent family frequently represents a limited life phase of approximately 5 to 6 years. Many mothers and fathers subsequently enter into a new partnership, in the form of a marriage or a long term unmarried relationship. During the period of lone parenthood however, the mother or father has to cope with all the tasks of bringing up children on their own, and also secure an income, which can lead to a lack of both time and economic means in this kind of family arrangement (Braches-Chyrek, 2002). Lone parent families can arise through the death of a partner or spouse, through splitting up or divorce. The current emergence of lone parent families is closely linked to the development of divorce frequency. As a consequence, an increasing number of children are exposed to disruption in their family situation, and differences between East and West Germany are once again substantial: in western Germany, one out of three children experiences one or more changes through childhood; in eastern Germany, more than 50 per cent of all children go through one or more transitions, and the overall rate of changes is higher as well. Special attention should be devoted to the growing share of children raised on a long-term basis by a single parent: no other lifestyle shows a similar growth rate. It is especially the ballooning number of divorces (37.2 per cent of all marriages end in divorce) which particularly affects children below the age of 18 (every second divorce involves one or more children; Engstler and Menning, 2003: 83) and makes for increasingly unstable terms of the growing-up process. Such changes may not just affect the subjective well-being of children but also – especially following a divorce and the transition to a lone parent form of living – their material situation (Joos, 2001); especially in terms of their housing environment when they remain with their newly single mother after separation and divorce (Hater, 2004). The current processes of change affecting the situation of children and their families are the result of contradictions accumulating over the past decades, and they directly impact on the children’s care situation. There is no ignoring of such contradictions in terms of: • bourgeois ideologies of the family (pattern of male bread-winner and female motherliness) and childhood (as a separated world of its own in which playing rules supreme), which no longer fit newly changed structures (working mothers, new family structures, availability of space); • modernised internal family structures and associated valuations assigned to family members (call for egalitarian relationships between generations and genders) which come up against a still rigid framework (traditional working worlds, social welfare systems); • flexibilisation and deregulation of employment which do not take account of (changed) families and their needs; 725 Children’s Welfare in Ageing Europe • the clash of gender and labour market policy goals which cannot be reconciled politically with the interests of children. The outcome is structural disharmony between (labour) market, family, government and the intermediary sector. Yawning gaps between ideologies and structures on the one hand and the interests of children and parents on the other will affect their everyday life. Certainly, the joint responsibility of society and family, and of the mother and father for education, care and raising of children is at the heart of the discourse today, but institutions will change at a snail’s pace only. Care is turning into a care crisis which is increasingly discouraging potential parents from begetting children (cf. the section on Childhood in the German welfare state). Germany is in a special situation inasmuch as two very different social logic approaches to organising care have been on a collision course since reunification. The western German model of family-based care combined with part-time work on the mother’s side has clashed with the eastern German model of community-based care with a high rate of full-time employment by the mother. Yet, the family was a sphere of critical importance for children also in eastern Germany. Because individuals were so highly socialised (and not always voluntarily so), the family was extremely important as a place to retreat into private life. Even though the rates of divorce, illegitimate children and single parents were much higher in the GDR than in the FRG, this nevertheless did not mean that the family was de-institutionalised. Quite on the contrary: attempts by the state to control private life rather strengthened the weight of the family (Meulemann, 1998). Parental employment patterns Parental employment29 constitutes a critical frame for the child’s everyday life: it determines whether and when parents are at home. With households shrinking in size, it also decides (indirectly) on the presence or absence of children in the parental household and on the need for non-parental care. Considering that most of the care work is rendered by women, maternal employment is of particular relevance for the time and space accorded to children. In spite of growing similarities, maternal employment still looks very different in eastern and western Germany: 29 Parental unemployment similarly impacts on the child’s everyday life. A parent’s loss of employment places a direct as much as indirect burden, both tangible and intangible, on the child. Even though non-working parents have more time at their disposal, this does not necessarily mean that they will devote more time and effort to caring for their children. Depression and loss of control in an unemployed parent will have a negative influence on the climate in a family (Walper, 1999). 726 COST A19: Germany Table 3. Actively employed women as a percentage of women aged 15-64 (2000).30 East Germany Percentage change 1996-2000 +0.1 Women with children 69.8 Of whom: youngest child aged < 3 years 40.4 +6.9 3-5 years 63.4 -2.0 6-14 years 76.3 -1.4 Source: Engstler and Menning, 2003: 107; own presentation. West Germany 56.8 Percentage change 1996-2000 +5.8 29.0 54.3 67.1 +3.4 +7.5 +5.2 The low rate of working mothers with children up to the age of three is explained by the fact that an overwhelming majority of them have taken up the state’s offer of parental timeout (see below). Although women with children up to the age of 6 are still distinctly more often employed in East than in West Germany, the share of working mothers is rising steadily in West Germany as well, and children of kindergarten age tend to have working mothers, most of them in part-time employment. East German women, on the other hand, still model themselves along the ideal of a mother of several children working fulltime who can reconcile work and family without any major internal or external conflicts, because child-care work is taken care of by the state, although this model is gradually but clearly fading. 43 per cent of women in western Germany and 27 per cent in eastern Germany, whose youngest child is three to six years old, participate in the year 2000 in the labour market with less then 36 hours, and 11 per cent of women from western Germany in comparison to 36 per cent from eastern Germany are working more than 36 hours (Engstler and Menning, 2003: 111). For the children’s day-to-day life, it is not only the mother’s gainful employment which is of importance but, more generally, parental employment as a whole, distinguished by full-time, part-time and family work. Family households increasingly depend on two incomes. Yet in Germany as a whole, the model of the (male) bread-winner is still the dominant pattern among couples with children under the age of six. Internationally, Germany has one of the highest shares of households where the wife is not gainfully employed: 30 Actively employed are gainfully employed persons excluding those on temporary leave, e.g. parental-leave, per 100 of the relevant population group (Engstler and Menning, 2003). 727 Children’s Welfare in Ageing Europe Table 4. Gainful employment among couples with children below the age of six (in per cent, 1998). Man works full-time; woman works full-time Man works full-time; woman works part-time Man works full-time; woman has no gainful employment Other situations Source: Bertelsmann Stiftung, 2002: 25. Employment pattern 15.7 23.1 52.3 8.9 For children this means that their fathers are usually gainfully employed (fulltime). Fatherhood does not impinge on the men’s gainful employment – quite on the contrary: the more children a family has the more and harder will the father work. On this aspect there are hardly any differences between East and West. Children up to the age of three similarly find themselves in an absent-father situation. The new parental timeout has had little effect in this respect. Fewer than one in ten fathers will reduce his working hours, and just five per cent of the fathers take parental leave (Bertelsmann Stiftung, 2002: 33), demotivated by the high loss of income when a father takes time out: the parental leave benefit is no substitute for wages and salaries, and men typically earn more than women. Instead, fathers tend to compensate, through increasing their job input, the income loss produced when the mother goes on parental leave. The situation is further compounded by the fact that career patterns demand high commitment especially in the decade between 30 and 40, exactly when the need to care for a small child occurs most frequently. A man’s identity is traditionally closely tied to his work, and in spite of assurances of equality at the start of a partnership, employment patterns and their consequences will ensure that care work remains the domain of women. The return to the traditional division of work between parents that occurs upon the birth of a child tends to have a serious impact on the quality and stability of a partnership and thus on the child’s family environment (Fthenakis et al., 2002). The incidence of jobs among single mothers (about two thirds) is markedly higher than among women who live with a partner, and the former tend to work full-time more often. But among the single mothers of children below the age of six, 52 per cent are not gainfully employed; 24 per cent are full-time workers and about the same number work part-time (Bertelsmann Stiftung, 2002: 26). Once again we find the typical gap between East and West, with Eastern mothers showing a higher rate of employment. 728 COST A19: Germany For children, the factual absence of their fathers in couple households and in single mother households means that their everyday life and thus their utilisation of space and time focuses strongly on the mother and thus on the female sex, because after all it is women who are charged with raising small children, whether in a personal or professional capacity (see below). However, we must not confuse the as-is situation with what parents actually want. The following table highlights the substantial divergence between theory and practice: Table 5. Employment pattern desired by couple households with children below the age of six (in per cent, 1998). Man works full-time; woman works full-time Man works full-time; woman works part-time Man works full-time; woman has no gainful employment Other situations Source: Bertelsmann Stiftung, 2002: 25. Desired employment pattern 32.0 42.9 5.7 19.4 In both parts of Germany, people clearly prefer the ‘additional earner’ model. This preference, combined with the declining size of family households and growing labour market participation rate among women (a trend that will continue in the future), accelerates the pressure to provide more community care slots. Already now, the discrepancy between actual rates of gainful employment among parents on the one hand and inadequate institutional child care on the other hand has been producing a typically German ‘mix’ of greatly varying care types. Care mixes in the daily life of small children The ‘care gap’, i.e. the discrepancy between supply of and demand for institutional care and a fact of life particularly in West Germany, has yielded a wide range of care mixes available to children aged 0-3, 3-6 and 6-10 respectively. Places and times available for children below the age of three The use of space and time by children up to the age of three is essentially governed by their life in the family – the result, chiefly, of the state-regulated parental timeout scheme (cf. the section on The social situation of children and 729 Children’s Welfare in Ageing Europe families) which grants parents a ‘leave’ of up to three years to care for their children. In 2000, fully 93 per cent of eligible parents (92 per cent in western and 100 per cent in eastern Germany) took advantage of this scheme immediately upon giving birth to a child: at least one parent (the mother in 95 per cent of cases) stayed at home with the child either all day or part-time (Engstler and Menning, 2003: 115).31 After the first six months, parental timeout is paid only up to a defined income threshold, with the result that the number of parents who stay with their child(ren) will successively decline. In East Germany mothers tend to return to work more quickly and more frequently. Once the child has reached his/her first birthday, about one half of the mothers in West Germany and just about a third of those in East Germany are on parental timeout (ibid: 117). Overall, during the first three years of a child, 19 per cent of mothers in West Germany and 12 per cent of mothers in East Germany with the youngest child under three years of age are on timeout (ibid: 111). In actual fact, a much greater proportion of mothers with children below the age of three stay at home with the child(ren): they are either outside the labour force (50 per cent in the West and 35 per cent in the East) or jobless (three per cent in the West and 13 per cent in the East) (ibid). Yet a care gap still persists for children up to three years old, since 29 per cent of West German mothers and 40 per cent of those in East Germany are actively employed (Table 3). Supplementary resources of institutional care, daycare centres and crèches fail to bridge the gap, especially in West Germany. In 2000, just 5.5 per cent of the children in the West spent any significant part of the day in such facilities;32 the corresponding figure for the East is 35.1 per cent (ibid: 121). Children of gainfully employed single parents have above-average attendance rates because they have a priority claim to such a facility. Added to this is the fact that in West Germany most day-care facilities for children provide no full-day care including lunch. Only 17 per cent of the children who actually attend a crèche spend more than half the day there, versus 71 per cent in East Germany (Veil, 2003: 22). This fails to compensate even for the share of mothers employed full-time, much less for gainfully employed mothers in general. Moreover, most day-care institutions in the West operate on 31 The scheme permits parallel part-time employment for up to 30 hours a week, an option that is taken up by just 5.8 per cent of the parents while they are paid a childraising allowance, i.e. during the first two years of the child’s life (Engstler and Menning, 2003: 116). 32 We need to distinguish between the rate of coverage and the rate of actual usage (‘attending rate’), because slots are occasionally underused or, alternatively, ‘doublebooked’. For this reason, the Deutsches Jugendinstitut – DJI-figures indicate a coverage of just 2.8 per cent (DJI, 2002: 151), which is, furthermore, subject to extreme regional variations. The usual statistics thus provide only limited information on the factual behaviour of children. 730 COST A19: Germany standardised opening hours of 8 am to 12 noon or 4 pm which fail to cover maternal absences resulting from gainful employment and transport.33 Another – albeit very rare – care option is child care organised at company level which does consider maternal working hours (Hagemann et al., 1999). It is typically available only in major corporations, but in those instances where it is offered, mothers may, at least in some places, get care between 6 am and 10 pm on a year-round basis. In a further attempt to bridge the care gap for the under-three-year-olds, another semi-institutional facility is used: Tagespflege (family day care) offers care in a ‘substitute’ family, organised on a public/private basis at a ratio of around 1:4 (Deutsches Jugendinstitut – DJI, 2002: 151).34 It involves a childminder (usually female) providing regular care for a child not her own, often together with the care for her own child(ren), either at the outside child’s own place or at the minder’s place.35 Child-minders are paid very little for their work and, at most, get an abbreviated training for their job. Just 3.5 per cent of the children below three years of age are in the care of child-minders; the practice is more common in urban communities, and relatively rare in East Germany due to the denser network of crèches available to mothers. At 14 hours per week, the average time that a child spends with his/her minder is much shorter than the time spent in a crèche (27 hours) (ibid: 159), but hours frequently differ from crèche opening hours (8 am to 12 noon or 4 pm). There are three reasons to explain the fact that child-minding is at least as common in West Germany as are day-care facilities: firstly, it is a better reflection of family ideology in West Germany; secondly it compensates for the shortage of crèche slots; and thirdly it offers greater flexibility in time, so that it is better in covering marginal and additional hours put in by working mothers. Children in the care of child-minders more often than other children (15 per cent vs. five per cent) also spend time in a crèche (ibid: 160); child-minding frequently serves complementary to crèche care. It may be assumed that such combined care is utilised particularly by families of mothers working full-time because they need substantially more child care than is available on a publicly organised basis. Care gaps are also bridged by informal care, usually provided by relatives. One out of three children below the age of three is cared for by relatives 33 Nevertheless there is a considerable regional bandwidth in standard offers as well as the occasional innovative model (DJI, 2002a). 34 Its public organisation is through the Youth Offices; the legal basis is provided in the Child and Youth Services Act KJHG. 35 Data on family-day-care are inadequate, so that the discussion is limited to estimates and qualitative single studies. 731 Children’s Welfare in Ageing Europe (Büchel and Spieß, 2002), typically grandparents, who live in the near vicinity (Table 6). However, no data are available whether such children stay at the grandparents’ or parental household and whether the situation for children under three is different. Table 6. Spatial distance between 10-14 year old children and their grandparents (in per cent).36 Same house/household Neighbourhood Same community Another community More than one hour’s drive Maternal grandparents Paternal grandparents Grandfather Grandmother Grandfather Grandmother 5.0 8.8 9.6 13.4 11.1 12.3 20.9 17.9 18.1 17.2 20.0 19.5 43.3 40.8 28.3 31.9 22.4 20.9 21.2 17.3 Source: Lange and Lauterbach, 1998. Figures nevertheless confirm the assumption that the strength of family ties between members not living in the same household is relevant for a child’s everyday life, and that therefore any definition of family that focuses on a shared household is simply inadequate. A family network study summarizes that • two related family households live under the same roof in seven per cent of cases; • 20 per cent of related family households live at a neighbourhood distance, and • a large number of relatives (30-40 per cent) live about an hour’s drive away (Fuchs, 2003). In its density, the network of relatives depends on the size of the community in which they reside (ibid: 93). Older siblings, if any, and other relatives chip in when it comes to child care, albeit with a lesser time input. Such support apart, there is a grey area of privately and informally organised child care which is difficult to assess quantitatively in scope and location, but tends to be of a short-term nature and cover ‘marginal’ times. Care for small children comes from family self-help initiatives, neighbourhood help groups, au-pair workers and ‘nannies’, the latter typically immigrants moonlighting in a family (approximately three per cent, Fthenakis, 2003). 36 No data currently exist for younger children, but figures appear to be even higher. 732 COST A19: Germany Table 7. Care-givers for children in the age of 0-3 years (in brackets for children of 3-6 years). Care rate, per cent Average care per week, hours Care provided by: elder sister 1.1 (2.5) elder brother 1.0 (2.1) grandmother 24.4 (26.3) grandfather 9.7 (12.3) other relative 4.6 (3.7) Family Day Care Day-carer 3.0 (1.3) other non-relative 2.5 (3.7) No other care giver 67.7 (65.6) Source: DJI, 2002: 159, survey 62. Proportion of children receiving additional institutional care, per cent 16 (15.4) 8.8 (14.4) 10.3 (9.4) 9.9 ( 8.5) 14.5 (8.3) 0 (71) 0 (61) 10 (85) 13 (83) 10 (85) 14.2 (14.9) 18 (10) 15 (87) 5 (68) 5 (75) The projection of a typical child’s everyday life up to the age of three shows that they spend most of their day in the parental home together with the mother or, as a second line, with their grandparents.37 They get up at around 7 am and leave home only to visit the playground or are taken by their mother on a round of shopping or visiting. A small number of children stays at a crèche for about 5.5 hours a day on average: the crèche normally opens at 8 am and closes at 4 pm. Both groups may have other institutional and informal care arrangements set up for them. Crèche time is the longest period of external care. If we add the typically shorter care periods in a private situation (altogether 11.5 hours per week, DJI, 2002: 158), we get a ‘relay’ of care-givers changing several times a day. One in four children alternates between two care facilities outside the family (Tietze, 1990: 182). Children of that age at most spent an hour with their father, during weekdays typically in the evening, between 7 and 8 pm, just before they are sent to bed (Statistisches Bundesamt, 2004). The weekends are mostly ‘pure’ family time. 37 Such a projection (as well as similar projections involving older children) demonstrates the serious shortage of studies that survey the day course of children. Data are restricted to care segments, and do not extend to the overall care mix. A single exception is provided by the ‘Münster care study’ (Tietze, 1990) which, however, was carried out already in the second half of the 1980s. In a similar vein, the new time budget study of the Federal Statistical Office starts with 10 year old children. The DJI ‘Longitudinal Study of Children’ commences at the age of five. 733 Children’s Welfare in Ageing Europe Places and times available to children of age three to six Three- to six-year-old children spend their time along entirely different lines, both in terms of institutional and informal care. Most enjoy a more balanced care situation, divided between parental, institutional and informal care, than is available to their younger peers. By far the most have their life filled by a combination of kindergarten and family time, with game time with friends and sports or arts activities thrown in.38 Consequently, transport (usually by parents) begins to take up more time (Kramer, 2004), and many children find their sphere of activities extending beyond the family home. In West Germany, the supply of kindergarten slots covers 87 per cent of demand; East Germany, in contrast, has an overcapacity of 112 per cent (Hank et al., 2003: 26 – see also Table 2).39 Attendance rates indicate that the gap between East and West Germany has virtually closed once the children reach an age of four to five years (Alt, 2004: 8). Nevertheless, the offer of whole-day kindergarten slots in western Germany is still inadequate: just 19 per cent of the demand can be met, compared to 98 per cent in eastern Germany (ibid: 7). Most of the Western children attend kindergarten in the morning and go home for lunch, whereas those in eastern Germany usually stay the whole day long (cf. Figure 4): Figure 4. Kindergarten opening hours, eastern and western Germany. other 1 1 morning and afternoon, no lunch 0 5 18 whole-day, lunch 76 1 0 afternoon, no lunch 11 morning, lunch morning, no lunch 16 64 7 0 East Germany 20 40 60 80 100 West Germany Number of cases: n=999; East Germany: n=147; West Germany: N=852; level of significance: 0.0001 Source: DJI, children panel, 1th wave, own calculations. 38 No study is available on this age group, with the exception of the DJI ‘Longitudinal Study of Children’, which has not yet furnished its final results. The following data are taken from first-wave preliminary results from an unpublished manuscript (Alt, 2004). 39 Once again, regional differences are important: both East and West still have areas of insufficient coverage. Alt’s latest results (2004) find that urban locations no longer are sure pointers of high coverage rates but that the issue is decided by the economic and social situation of a given region. 734 COST A19: Germany In their everyday life, children in Germany are subject to considerable differences in their lifestyles: some (mostly in eastern Germany) spend much of their time in an institutionalised environment; others (mostly in western Germany) tend to pass more of their time in a family surrounding.40 When we consider maternal full-time employment (as outlined above: 10 per cent of mothers of children aged three to five in the West; more than a third in the East), the above figures do not point at a direct bottleneck because kindergartens provide sufficient care-places for this age group of children. Furthermore, the fact that kindergartens close down completely only for some four or five weeks of the holiday periods provides some relatively suitable help for gainfully employed parents to reconcile such periods with their own paid leave. But a care gap will still arise in many cases because part-time work, an advancing work style both in western and eastern Germany, is no longer typically a morning job: the parent will not necessarily be able to knock off from work at the time when the child has to be fetched from the kindergarten. If we also consider the travelling time required by the parent there will always be time gaps when the child is waiting and the mother is in a breathless hurry. Consequently, there is considerable need for adjustment of the marginal opening hours of kindergartens. Although lately the occasional kindergarten has begun to vary its hours – some facilities allow children to arrive before 8 am and stay after 6 pm or even (in extremely rare cases) during the weekend (DJI, 2002a) – such long and flexible opening hours are the rare exception rather than anything like a rule and – at least in the West – not reliable, and they certainly do not cover the factual care need. Accordingly, children of this age, in addition to attending kindergarten, obtain extra regular care from persons external to their household, especially when the mother is gainfully employed. For the three- to six-year-olds, such additional care on an informal and regular basis is almost identical in eastern and western Germany (Hank et al., 2003: 26). Children of single parents and non-marital couples on average experience more additional care arrangements than those with parents in a traditional marriage situation (Alt, 2004: 24). Within the range of informal care options, family-day-care is less used by children from 3-6 years in comparison to those from 0-3 years, but hours themselves are slightly increased (Table 7). There is a widespread care-mix by using additional care. This fact once again points at care gaps suffered by the group of children of gainfully employed mothers. 40 Use of the kindergarten is to a significant extent decided by the social status: more than half of the parents whose children do not attend kindergarten are in a very low social stratum (Alt, 2004: 11). Similarly, the care mix clearly depends on the social level, as well as on regional factors (ibid: 26 f). 735 Children’s Welfare in Ageing Europe The typical everyday life of most children in West Germany involves attendance of the kindergarten between 8 am and 12 noon. At noon, the child is fetched and returns home, where the mother has cooked and serves lunch. The child spends afternoon at home or plays with friends in the near surrounding or makes use of some leisure-time activity. A smaller number of children spend their whole day (i.e. up to 4 pm) at the kindergarten, which is the normal situation in East Germany. For some of the children, a variety of informal care schemes follows morning care at the kindergarten, the former provided chiefly by grandparents or child-minders. If activities take place at different venues, it is usually the mother who does the afternoon chauffeuring, whereas fathers deliver and fetch their children of this age group in the morning and evening (Kramer, 2004). Relay care (‘Staffettenbetreuung’) is on the increase. The number of care types per day rises with the child’s age: every second child in the 3-6 age group commutes between family care and at least two other care types (Tietze, 1990). By 6 pm, most fathers are back home in time for the family supper, followed by playtime with father. By 8 pm at the latest it is bedtime for the child. Once again, the weekend is dedicated to the family: this is when fathers in particular have time for their children, which they spend on games and sports (Statistisches Bundesamt, 2004: 22). Children aged six to ten in after-school day-care centres The care situation of elementary school children once again constitutes a problem in Germany, similarly characterised by an East/West gap. All-day schools are still very much the exception in both parts of Germany. But whereas in eastern Germany at least 16.4 per cent of elementary school children (6-10 year-olds) make use of an after-school day-care centre and 13.3 per cent attend an all-day school, the respective figures for West Germany were just four per cent (after-school day-care) and 3.7 per cent (all-day school) in 1998 (Bertelsmann Stiftung, 2002: 31). In view of the growing inclusion of mothers in the active labour force, also in full-time employment, a supply gap is opening in this age group. It widens considerably during holidays, since school holidays (approximately 12 weeks) are substantially longer than the typical holiday leave granted to workers (max. 5 weeks). Such care gaps are again bridged by a mix of care types, where relatives continue to play a major role, and child-minders are an additional option for at least one in five school children (Tietze, 1990). Nevertheless, the children are increasingly left to their own devices, a situation which they face with ambivalent feelings (cf. the section on Schoolchildren’s activities in time and space). 736 COST A19: Germany Blurring boundaries: solving or deepening the care crisis? For the past years the relationship between childhood, family and working life has been changing, driven by increasingly flexible working hours and work places. Will this ease or perhaps even solve the care crisis? All studies on the future of work agree that the process of blurring boundaries will continue and even accelerate. The fordistic division of labour – with a woman-centred family and a clearly distinct working life – works for ever fewer parents. The newly evolving type of the ‘entreployee’ (Voß and Pongratz, 1998) can no longer take for granted fixed and stable time schedules and work places, a continuous work biography, clear and stable job status. Flexible working hours are growing to be the norm. By 1999, just 15 per cent of the dependently employed in the FRG were still subject to a regime of so-called ‘standard working hours’ (Groß and Munz, 2000),41 compared to 27 per cent some ten years ago (Groß et al., 1987). The remaining 85 per cent put in: • • • • • • regular shift and night work (18 per cent), weekend work (16 per cent on Sundays, 35 per cent on Saturdays), regular overtime (56 per cent), part-time work (20 per cent, of which 87 per cent are women), flexitime (83 per cent), working time account schemes (37 per cent), e.g. block leisure time and sabbaticals. Such processes indicate that the strict separation between paid work and holiday, between working hours and leisure time, is being abandoned. Working hours increasingly fail to define clear structures for organising the segments of occupational and family life. The length and rhythm of work to which working parents submit are being renegotiated – not just the beginning and end of the daily work but also the rhythm of weekly and annual work. Ancient temporal institutions, such as knocking-off time, weekend or annual leave, are about to lose their compulsive nature as timers for parents in gainful employment. Temporal flexibilisation goes hand in hand with locational flexibilisation. When it comes to space, the work place is no longer restricted to the company premises. Work may be brought home (a new type of cottage industry, typically teleworking), made possible by novel information and communications technologies. Another spatial change is being effected by travelling becoming normal. Field work (e.g. consulting) is intensified, as is commuting (Kramer, 41 I.e. full-time employment of 35–40 hours per week, distributed over five days (Mondays to Fridays), at a single work place. 737 Children’s Welfare in Ageing Europe 2004; Bonß and Kesselring, 1999). Mobility is on the rise, and distances between different work places as well as between work place(s) and home are growing. Commuting has given rise to weekend relationships as a form of living apart together. Parents need to re-organise the spatial structure of their work between workplace, home and travel. Where gainful employment takes place at home, the previous spatial separation needs to be replaced by a factual separation between paid work and family work. This leads to new challenges for children’s everyday lives and in caring for children from the parents’ view. In order to decide whether greater flexibility makes family life easier or more difficult, we need to remember the specific demands of family care. Caring for a child or an elderly relative is not something that you can decide anew every day. The care-giver is committed to submit to reliable and stable arrangements because such a relationship is based on another person being in a dependent position. Care work needs predictable times in order to enable both parties to be together at all. Family life requires fixed schedules, rituals and rules. On the other hand, care demands may well change every day because they are flexible by nature and subject to changes in intensity, which may call for quick responses. Child care does not follow a logical path, or comply with a time schedule or programme that is amenable to improvements in efficiency. In summary, a family needs working conditions which allow both: stability as well as flexibility. Immediate care needs apart, it requires shared time and time for the family in order to experience the ‘family’ as a quality-of-life aspect, as living together as a family rather than side by side as individuals. The crucial point of blurring boundaries with regard to care for children up to the age of six is the ongoing erosion of when, how long and where parents put in their paid working hours. Four consequences are conceivable: parents have more time to spend with their children at home; parents are physically more present at home but are occupied with their bring-home work; parents have less time to spend with their children; or children obtain their care from more and more flexibly arranged complementary institutional or informal care services. The first three of this list are well in place, whereas the last one is just emerging. So far, little empirical research is available on this issue, and a little more on the specific perspective of children’s everyday lives. • What we do know is that blurring boundaries result in stricter time management in families (Jurczyk and Rerrich, 1993). A general feeling of time shortage and time acceleration apart, it is the erosion of external time and predetermined spatial structures which reinforces the need for individuals to define their working time and working space themselves. This need is forced on us rather than self-chosen and it may well translate into overburdening the families. Family life generally means that the time structures and 738 COST A19: Germany activities of several people will necessarily clash, and the current trend towards more flexibility makes synchronisation even more necessary. Obviously, synchronisation problems get worse when both parents are on flexible time schedules. Such a situation requires them to constantly (re)organise their time and energy (Behringer and Jurczyk, 1995). The result is a daily round of negotiation, which spans all the people who are included in the family’s care network. Knocking-off time, leisure time, holiday time, time for children – they have to be defended against the employer in a new way. When people work at home (e.g. at the computer), work will make ever greater inroads on the private life sphere. The new everyday life situation means that people juggle precariously at the edge rather than gain a successful balance. With the new flexibility, shared time frequently needs to be identified and planned. A multi-headed family will run into ever greater problems finding time to share. The trend is clearly moving towards weekend families (Kleine, 2003), while the time in between is arranged by pinboard and cellphone messages – but such strategies work only with older children. • Secondly, we find an optimistic view of flexibilisation. Parents (and again especially mothers) actually can combine work and family, and fathers have an opportunity to spend time with their children. Recent studies by Klenner et al. (2003) of the effect of sabbaticals and working time accounts show that some parents are highly satisfied with the new opportunities of reconciling work and the family and the father’s co-parenting contribution. They are enthusiastic about the potential offered by such time regimes to respond flexibly to the changing demands of the children. In these modern families, where each member has his/her own rhythm, a new process is emerging where specific rituals and routines are created and new traditions are built to facilitate the organisation of everyday life. • The result of the new flexibility depends on the details: the work regime, the age of the children who need care and the interaction with other care systems. Thus when it comes to the rapidly spreading system of working time accounts, their success depends on the time span required before any long time blocks have been collected to be consumed with children (Eberling et al., 2004). But this does not help parents in their day-to-day care work for small children and still requires them to make use of supplementary day care systems. The benefit to be derived from working time accounts also depends on the scope at which workers can ‘draw’ time from their account, which varies greatly between companies. • Greater mobility by way of longer travelling periods obviously poses problems for families with children. More than half of the women working in jobs that require high mobility have no children (Schneider et al., 2002) – double the average rate of all women without children and still substantially 739 Children’s Welfare in Ageing Europe higher than the 44 per cent of academically qualified women without children (Engstler and Menning, 2003). Work-caused mobility outside the home, typified by the new ‘job nomads’, thus is difficult to handle for parents. Where spatial boundaries are blurred, new and flexible care arrangements are required to compensate for overnight and weekend absences of mobile parents. Nevertheless, mobility is tied to gender: more fathers commute between greater distances, whereas a majority of mothers is still stationary. The other, more ‘internal’ type of blurring boundaries, i.e. working at home, which is prevalent among the self-employed and teleworkers, does not automatically facilitate everyday life in a family. Whereas fathers manage to distance themselves from care requirements, mothers try to balance them by constantly switching between the job and children. They accept interruptions, do their work in bits and pieces, and by this method are accessible for the concerns and problems of their children (Jurczyk, 2002). Shifting gainful employment into the family, and thus ensuring the presence of a care-giver, may perhaps resolve problems of reconciliation but may at the same time generate new problems. Certainly the new type of ‘home work’ is no equivalent to the supposed idyll of the pre-modern pastoral cottage industry where the whole extended family lived and worked under a single roof. • Summarising the effects of flexible working time and space in their different facets, they appear to be highly ambivalent in their impact on child care (Jürgens, 2003). Some instances of flexible working time and space do offer some leeway (such as flexitime, part-time and teleworking), but on the other hand, parents are expected to become compatible with the economic logic of their company. Mothers have been demanding flexible working hours for several decades in order to better handle the changing demands of children, respond to illnesses, etc., but also in order to compensate for the rigid opening hours of care institutions. However, considering that companies increasingly tend to expect their employees to be available at all times, flexibility threatens to turn negative. At present, much evidence points to the assumption that flexible working hours exacerbate rather than solve the care crisis because the care institutions have failed to adjust their own opening hours accordingly. The care crisis in the form of a shortage of care slots is further aggravated by the greater need for flexible opening hours in crèches and kindergartens, for further care networks and for new services for families. Currently, new commercial service providers are mushrooming which offer care and operate as flexible backup systems, occasionally late into the night, overnight and during the weekend. Faced with an ever more flexible working world, child-minding services will similarly be in ever greater demand, because they offer flexibility 740 COST A19: Germany due to their semi-private nature. Blurring boundaries will solve the care crisis only when parents themselves determine (or at least have some say in) the place and time of work, when such factors apply reliably and are not subject to constant change due to company processes. Is there a care crisis? Experiences and values of children and parents How do children and parents experience the care situation? Do they realise that there actually is a care crisis? What do they want? What does increasing flexibility mean to them? Parental views of child care The care situation of small children is recognised as a problem in Germany, as is evidenced by the Federal Government’s plan to provide institutional care for about 20 per cent of the under-three-year-olds. Nevertheless this does not cover the demand, neither from the children’s nor from the parents’ point of view. Fathers and mothers want different working time arrangements, one out of three fathers wants more time for his family (Statistisches Bundesamt, 2004), some parents want better institutional care. On the latter point, opinions are divided: women both in western and eastern Germany perceive their gainful employment as less negative for their children than do men, although the difference is greater in the West. This gap may be explained by the fact that East German men realised in the past that women’s gainful employment did not produce any negative consequences. Fully 62 per cent of the west Germans, as against only 40 per cent of the east Germans, think that external child care negatively affects the children. Attendance of three- to six-year-old children of whole-day kindergarten is seen by West German mothers as mostly negative, whereas East German mothers clearly favour it (Codebuch Allbus, 1980-98: 162). For two out of three women with children up to elementary school age, regardless of whether living in the East or West, the preferred choice is one family partner working full-time and the other part-time (20 to 25 hours; Engstler and Menning, 2003: 113). Although a greater number of the couples (one third) wants full-time working for both than is the case today (see the section on Small children’s time and space), the majority are in favour of reduced working hours. Among men in family households the desire to cut job working hours (substantially: by up to nine hours) is more widespread (30 per cent) than among women (22 per cent; Bauer, 2004) – an expression of the difference in burdens that stem from working hours. For mothers, the desire depends i.a. on their actual job working hours: full-time employed women in all 741 Children’s Welfare in Ageing Europe of Germany wish to have their time on the job reduced to 30 hours (Bertelsmann Stiftung, 2002: 26), whereas mothers with part-time employment, especially in East Germany, would frequently like to spend more time on the job than is the case today. For mothers in West Germany, involuntary part-time work is significantly linked to the problem of insufficient and usually part-time child care (Büchel and Spieß, 2002); for their East German peers, it is due to a shortage of full-time jobs. Flexible job working hours, which have the greatest impact on the sharing of family life, are viewed critically: 46 per cent of the shiftworkers living in a family wish to reduce or give up shift work; as do 69 per cent of those working on Saturdays, 68 per cent of those working on Sundays and 54 per cent of workers putting in regular overtime (Bauer, 2004). Children’s views of care and the care crisis First of all we need to counter a widespread assumption: recent research has not found any evidence that parents and children spend less time together while mothers’ employment rates are rising. The new time budget study (Statistisches Bundesamt 2004: 22) finds that, in 2001, parents spent more time with their children below the age of six than was the case in 1991 – altogether 6.75 hours vs. 6 hours. This figure includes child care as a main activity as well as parallel activity carried out jointly with shopping and household work.42 Even single parents still spend a total of 4.5 hours with their children. The situation shows potential for polarisation between families with and without time welfare, between traditionally organised families where the mother stays at home or jobless parents who have plenty of time on the one hand, and parents who are both gainfully employed (especially those in full-time jobs) who have little time, on the other hand. Working mothers compensate for the lack of time by reducing their own time spent on sleeping and leisure. If we shift the focus from the quantity to the quality of together-time, such a sleep-reducing strategy deepens the impression of hurried and overworked parents which in turn takes us to the quality of life issue from the child’s point of view. Qualitative studies have shown that the extent of parental work is a decisive factor for the children’s well-being – and it works in both directions (Klenner et 42 It should, however, be noted that these aggregated data do not distinguish by groups of gainfully employed and jobless. In view of the high unemployment rate, especially in East Germany, it is only to be expected that time spent on gainful employment declines so that more time is left for the children. A more detailed evaluation is currently underway. 742 COST A19: Germany al., 2003; Roppelt, 2003).43 Both sides – children whose parents work long hours and children whose parents put in only a few hours of gainful employment – find their family situation to be rather stressful. Many of the girls and boys questioned expressed their contentment with the individual care solution found by their parents. Children have developed basic criteria for wellbeing and contentment: ‘For as long as I don’t feel alone,’ says a nine-year-old girl, addressing the balance that working parents have to achieve in managing care for their children. The point is not so much ensuring the parents’ constant presence but rather finding a balance between proximity and distance, i.e. between work and family that will generate satisfaction and well-being in the child. ‘It is important that somebody is at home or can be phoned – we arrange that. After all, I do need help with my homework. My parents needn’t be there all the time, only when I need them.’ (a nine-year-old boy) We cannot always assume a linear connection between the parents’ job burden and a higher burden to be carried by the affected children. Satisfaction is typically found in children whose parents bear a medium-scale work load (Roppelt, 2003). Fully 70 per cent of these children were satisfied with a care situation which enables them to enjoy a balance between easy-going and social environments, between boundaries and freedom. Children are also dissatisfied when the mother is not gainfully employed and they feel eternally observed and monitored because of her constant presence which robs them of an opportunity to escape the family regime: ‘It gets on my nerves when there’s always somebody around. No matter what I do, my mother will always notice. I can’t watch TV or eat when I want to. I told her to go to work for a few hours but she doesn’t want to.’ (an eleven-year-old girl) The children questioned by the study have pinpointed four desirable types of parental presence and absence: they wish for affection, proximity and activities shared with their parents, but also for autonomously enjoyable periods of time. Dissatisfaction with their parents’ time management is expressed in particular situations: when they feel ill or emotionally distressed or when there is a special 43 Questioning children on the job working hours of their parents is a methodological problem, affected, i.a., by the child’s age. Children up to the age of six are difficult to question and are unable to keep a diary. Among the older children, many have never reflected on the issue, others take things as given, and only a very few think consciously of the problem (Näsman, 2003). Another key factor for the children’s welfare is the quality of their sphere of activities (Blinkert, 1997). 743 Children’s Welfare in Ageing Europe occasion, children demand much more time from their parent(s) and perceive their presence to be indispensable and a matter of course. With regard to flexible and irregular working hours of their parents, children suffer from not knowing when their parents will be at home. The problem is not so much being alone but being forced to wait and not able to plan anything. For the eight- to ten-year-olds polled, the problem is in the uncertainty of working hours and, consequently, care hours which do not lend itself to advance planning: ‘I never know when she comes home. When she has a business meeting and does not know in advance, she will come later. And I need to wait and can’t arrange anything with my friends. I never can tell them to come, because my mother may not be at home. That’s really vexing me.’ (a nine-year-old boy) ‘I may come home and mum’s there, and another time I come home and mum’s not there. Some time it’s this way and some time that – I can’t rely on anything. Then I look in on granny whether she is at home, but it would be best if I were at home. It bothers me that I don’t know in advance and I get furious when things don’t work out.’ (a ten-year-old boy) Another restriction noted by children is the long periods of waiting and stop-gap measures until the parents will at last come home after work. They experience this as particularly aggravating, mainly because children are usually allowed to play outside only when their parents are at home. Stop-gap measures may result from demands on the parents’ part that derive from their working hours and are perceived as too difficult by the child: ‘Mummy cuts me a slice of bread and prepares something for me to heat. But doing all that on my own is difficult because after all I am only eight years old. I am also afraid that I might forget to switch off the stove and sometimes there are these funny noises. Then I am always glad when mummy gets back and I am no longer alone.’ (an eight-year-old girl) The subject of autonomy as an opportunity or unreasonable expectation clearly arises as a result of specific working hour arrangements. It is noticeable how much expectations are first directed at the mother. From the children’s point of view, a desirable care situation is constituted of the following elements: good oral arrangements, reliability, certainty that the parents can be reached, parents who are relaxed and not always in a hurry, no waiting periods, more shared quality time with the parents, especially with the father,44 and some time that can be spent alone. 44 A wish chiefly expressed by the children in eastern Germany (Mayr, 2002). 744 COST A19: Germany Children greatly appreciate family arrangements that comprise both parents: ‘In our family, mummy works at school. So daddy is often here and on weekdays I take my meals with him. I am never alone, either daddy or mummy is at home. They also take turns in the mornings. I like that because in this way I have both of them.’ (a nine-year-old girl) Children also greatly appreciate it when their parents manage to skilfully reconcile job and family. A clever solution that produces a harmonious link between the family and parental job(s) will be facilitated by working conditions that accommodate the need to co-ordinate the partners’ work schedules. With this, the ‘care crisis’ has so far had only conditional impact on the children themselves, chiefly on those children whose parents have irregular working hours or both work full-time. Most children voice their satisfaction with the presence and absence of their parents (Mayr and Ulich, 2002). This is due to the fact that the family still operates as a ‘safety net’ because it (chiefly through mothers and relatives) compensates in time what institutions fail to deliver. It still works – but frequently at the cost of overburdened and dissatisfied parents. Schoolchildren’s activities in time and space This section focuses on the impact of recent changes in the economy as well as in spatial developments on the times and places where children learn and play, and on the ways children use space and handle their time. It will show, firstly, how the impact of recent changes in the economy on the temporal organisation of children’s learning is mediated by adults’ ambivalence between the images of the playing child and the learning child. Secondly, it will illustrate how the structural power of spatial specialisation and separation processes is translated to children’s daily life world by adults who struggle with an ambivalence between their images of the autonomous child and the child that has to be controlled. Last but not least, children’s ways of meeting adult-made opportunities and constraints shall be reported. The power of school on children’s time Increase and reduction of years in school Nine or ten years (depending on the Länder) of school are compulsory; as a rule from the age of six. Although compulsory schooling begins at age six, half of children enter school after their 7th birthday. For the first four or six years all 745 Children’s Welfare in Ageing Europe children attend primary school, and then continue in one of the different types of secondary I level. One type is the grammar school that then goes on for a further three or two years (secondary II level) and is finished by an exam (Abitur) which enables university study. Prolongation of regular time in school is rather frequent because of class repetition. Every year, 1.9 per cent of all pupils in primary school have to repeat a year and in secondary I schools this figure is 4.2 per cent. Of 15 year-olds in 2000, between 11.2 per cent and 35.7 per cent (varying between the Länder) had one or more delays in their school career (Avenarius et al., 2003: 74 and 473). Table 8. Pupils in general schools 1999, percentage of the age group population (in per cent), 1999. age 5 age 6 age 7 age 8 2.2 5.5 99.4 100.0 age 16 age 17 age 18 age 19 age 20 Source: FMER, 2001: 24-25. 100.0 37.8 26.9 14.0 3.2 Until recently, the secular process of continual increase of the time the young generation spends in school was valued as a form of progress in children’s welfare, because more children are relieved for more time from the working world and instead enjoy the value of education for their personal development. Now the expansion of time for institutionalised learning is questioned by both the politicians who are responsible for the development of the educational system, and the children themselves. Policy concerns relate to the ageing of the population that will soon be unlikely to allow for a high amount of possible labour power being absorbed by a very long duration of life time spent exclusively on education. One measure is a one year abridgement of school duration until the final grammar school exam, from 13 to 12 years (only two years in secondary II level) that has now been started to be implemented in all Länder. Because the overall number of lessons will not be reduced, more lessons will be held within each year. Concerning the beginning of the school career, a campaign has been started against parents’ tendency to prolong children’s time before entering school. The tendency to put off starting school is partly due to a low standard of skills at age six, caused by a lack of learning promotion on the part of kindergartens (as politicians argue), partly by parents who want to save their child from being reached by the power of school at a time they judge as too early; they want their 746 COST A19: Germany child to play for as long as possible in early childhood. On the part of the parents, concepts of the playing child and the learning child are conflicting. However an extension of learning time into early childhood has to be taken in account: Reacting to the shocking German results of the international school achievement study ‘PISA’, recently new efforts have been made to empower early learning within the pre-school care system. Prolongation of daily time in school In classes 1 to 6 children spend on average 27 hours a week in school. Including time for homework and for the way to school, the amount of their time spent on school is 31 hours, while older pupils spend 39 hours in secondary II level schools, and 46 hours in secondary II level grammar school. Per year, 9 to 14 year-olds spend 850 hours in school, while the average in OECD countries is 889 hours (Avenarius et al., 2003: 75 and 143). As a rule, school takes place in the mornings only. Since more mothers are in the working world, severe care problems arise caused by several time gaps between children’s school hours and parents’ working hours: • In the children’s first years at school the daily number of lessons is small, and school begins and ends at different times each day, some days earlier, others later. Additionally, when a teacher is unable to work, school lessons are often suddenly cancelled because of a lack of teachers for financial reasons. • At midday, schools send children home hungry. • On Saturdays there is no school (few exceptions); the placing of lessons in the week had been adjusted to most parents’ five-day working week in the 1980s. However, working on Saturdays is now becoming more frequent again. • Children have more than twice as many free days in the year as their parents. They have twelve weeks of school holidays in summer, autumn, late winter, and at Christmas and Easter. There are not enough institutional programmes to care for school children in their holidays, neither enough afternoon care institutions which open during holiday time nor special holiday arrangements. Therefore some families cannot go on holiday altogether, some children stay at home alone, and others enjoy several journeys, one with the mother, one with the father, others with grandparents who help in many families (see the section on Small children’s time and space). Until recently, schools never regarded care as their obligation. The patterns of school time have been oriented only to the hourly requirements resulting from the curricula and from teachers’ working times and carried through by the 747 Children’s Welfare in Ageing Europe power of the state; the school system has always taken the non-working mother for granted who in principle can look after her child at home at any time. The efforts of reform-oriented teachers and educational scientists towards the implementation of more all-day schools was doomed to failure because of the widespread opinion that more hours at school would demand too much from children, and moreover it did not fit in with teachers’ understanding of their role and time-space organisation of work. The increasing participation of mothers in the working world suffering from a lack of time for their children plays an important role in the fact that parents’ demands for more institutional time for their children is now taken seriously by policy makers. • More and more primary schools are expanding young children’s daily times in school in order to cover the whole morning. Some of those realise an additional model where ordinary lessons are followed by caring time (‘verlässliche Grundschule’), others realise an integrated model (‘volle Halbtagsgrundschule’), where the increased amount of time is organised in a new way in order to help the children learn in a less stressed and more cooperative way. However not many of these provide a midday meal. At least some primary schools open the building very early in the morning in order to prevent pupils whose parents start work early from waiting in the streets. • Since very recently, all political parties have been demanding more all-day schools (Ganztagsschulen). In spite of a difficult financial situation, in summer 2003 the government agreed to spend money on establishing 10,000 additional all-day schools. Statistics on the number of children already attending all-day schools are not available because of different forms of such schools. ‘All-day schools’ which receive the proposed state funding must offer a midday meal and an afternoon programme – mostly voluntary activities – at least at three days per week, which must be in the responsibility of the school even if it is run by social workers or caring personal. In 2002/2003, less than 10 per cent of all pupils at primary and secondary I school level attended a school defined in this way. There is a surplus demand for places (Sekretariat KMK, 2004: 7). Doubtlessly the most powerful arguments are the economic need for women’s labour as well as better qualification of the nation’s human capital, since the relatively poor school achievement compared to pupils in other OECD nations (PISA study: Baumert et al., 2001) caused fear of a future lack of qualified labour. More daily time at school is a serious intervention into children’s access to use of time, and it has to be questioned if and in what respects it benefits children. Recent educational discourses on that question mirror the traditional ambivalence between the images of the playing and the learning child; the concept of childhood as a period of playing is placed in conflict with the further 748 COST A19: Germany expansion of scholarisation. Discourses point out children’s need for a quiet period after a long morning period of lessons and of being together with many others, and warn not to remove children’s possibility to shape the afternoon time on their own (see below). From the children’s perspective we must take into account that discourses on the concept of the child have always followed the prevailing adults’ concept of the family; the concept of the highly sensitive child depending on motherly care for a long period was related to the mother-at-home pattern, and has been followed in recent times by the concept of the more robust child, related to the pattern of a family where mothers are in the working world. Therefore discourses which aim at respecting children’s interests will have to reflect on the impact of traditional structures and thinking on children’s position between the family, other care arrangements and school. Children’s resistance to their role as pupil From older children’s perspective, many years in school mean a long duration of being positioned as a child: being dependent on the parent’s economy and say as well as on the school’s regulation and control of time and activities. Moreover, school learning is meant to provide young people with knowledge they will need in future life, a precondition that seems being weakened, since relevant knowledge changes very quickly. Two ways of resistance are increasingly used by children. A small number, mostly children from disadvantaged families, plays truant from school. In recent times, teachers and educational policy makers have been concerned about the growing of the number of children who seldom attend lessons. These pupils start their ‘no-school career’ between the age of 12 and 14 (Schreiber-Kittl and Schröpfer, 2002). In some secondary I schools these children make up four to 10 per cent of pupils. Parents are no longer blamed for their children’s behaviour in the debates on causes and measures, as was formerly the case. Rather, truancy is discussed as children’s reaction to a negatively experienced school practice, and as a sign that the world of school and the world of life outside school are drifting apart. A different way to escape from the long-lasting childhood situation of dependency is entering the adults’ working world besides going to school. Pupils’ access to the working world is restricted by law. With some exceptions, from the age of 14 children are permitted to work up to two hours per day, but only on working days and between 8 am and 6 pm. During holidays, work is allowed for four weeks from the age of 15. The law is often ignored. In recent years, school-age children’s interest in transgressing the border between schoolwork and adults’ working worlds has increased very considerably, due to their need of money for consumer goods and for using mobile phone 749 Children’s Welfare in Ageing Europe communication, as well as to their wish for transformation into a more autonomous adult-like position. According to recent small sample studies, about half of 14 to 16 year-olds seem to be involved, half of whom work only in the holidays, the other half in both holidays and school term-time. Representative statistics are rather old. The expansion of pedagogisation and scholarisation in children’s private lives While the school system is only very hesitantly preparing to adjust to temporal constraints in the children’s out-of-school lives, it traditionally intrudes on pupil’s private time by demanding homework. The maximum amount of time is regulated by education authorities or schools. Zinnecker and Silbereisen (1996: 27ff) account for about an hour per day needed by ten year olds, and one hour and a quarter needed by eleven to thirteen year olds (pupils of grammar schools needed more). Parents are supposed to check whether and how children do their homework, and if necessary to look for and pay for private coaching. Thus some school-related work which the school does not manage to do is loaded onto parents – a practice that has always been problematic because it underlines social inequality. Helping with homework often overburdens the time of parents who are already stressed from their working times. A fifth of younger pupils get non-parental private coaching (Avenarius et al., 2003: 91). In some socially disadvantaged local environments, welfare organisations offer help with homework. Adults’ wishes to keep young children in a world of play for as long and as much as possible contradicts with adults’ efforts to provide children with as many as possible opportunities to learn at the same time. In modern society, which awards a high priority to work and defines the life of adults to a high degree by their participation in the working world, children’s life has also been included into this understanding; childhood is seen more and more comprehensively as a period of preparation for later participation in the world of work. During the last decades educators, developmental psychologists and social scientists have devoted attention to the learning and development potential of children’s non-school activities, and pedagogisation has spread into children’s whole daily life. Everything children do in the course of the day has since been regarded as socialisation or informal learning: playing, media use, working in the household (practising how to do one’s duty), playing with peers (social learning) or doing paid work. Nearly all parents (97 per cent; LEGO Learning Study, 2003: 9) say that time spent playing is also time spent learning. The pattern of the learning child and the pattern of the playing child overlap, and the borderlines between school and the everyday world outside school are 750 COST A19: Germany blurred. On one hand, learning has been expanded into non-school everyday life by transforming children’s free play time into a time perceived by adults as a learning time. On the other hand, claiming the learning outcome of all children’s activities has allowed for introducing forms of playing into school learning. Forms of playing have especially expanded into the methods of primary schools. However, such a ‘de-scholarisation of school’ (Fölling-Albers, 2000) is accompanied by a much stronger tendency towards expansion of organised learning and scholarisation within children’s lives. This happens inside (see above) and outside the educational system. Outside school, scholarisation of leisure time activities has been increasing over a long period. Here, the tendency towards pedagogisation of children’s activities is connected with parents’ wishes to provide their child with education in addition to school, as well as with parents’ concerns about the lack of opportunities for their child to play among children in the neighbourhood environment and also about a lack of physical exercise. Middle class parents in particular want their children to join in formally organised educational activities besides school, hoping for an improvement of their career in the education system (Zinnecker and Silbereisen, 1996; Büchner and Krüger 1996). Since the 1970s, a multitude of such offers to practise music, theatre, ballet, arts, handicrafts, sports, language learning and computer use has arisen. Nowadays school seems ‘to be accepted by children and by parents less in relation to aspects of interesting or at least relevant knowledge and competence rather than in relation to access to certificates of education, and besides that also as a more or less interesting world of life – especially outside the achievement-oriented lessons. Learning material that is valued as important seems to be preferred to be gained outside of school.’ (Fölling-Albers, 2000: 123). Such facilities are organised by a large number of institutions including sport and other clubs, local communities, welfare organisations, churches, schools and in recent time more and more by private companies. The largest group of activities is for sports (see below). Since the 1990s, the number of voluntary afternoon working groups in schools has increased, not least because schools are in competition with each other to find enough pupils, and try to develop particular profiles. Orchestras, choirs, theatre groups, language learning groups and more are offered in 85 per cent of the schools at secondary I level and nearly all at secondary II. In 2000, about 30 per cent of fifteen year-olds participated in school-organised leisure time programmes (Baumert et al., 2003). The only data available for examining children’s use of such provisions is from different interview studies, each of them having investigated particular age groups in particular regions with particular questions: 751 Children’s Welfare in Ageing Europe • 9 to 12 year-olds: 76 per cent participated in institutionalised activities, half of these in one and the other half in several programmes (FurtnerKallmünzer et al., 2002: 40-41). • 10 to 13 year-olds: 80 per cent had at least one weekly activity. These children spent an average 10.2 hours per week on such activities (Zinnecker and Silbereisen, 1996: 66). • 10 to 15 year-olds reported more dense weekly schedules. Only six per cent said that they had no weekly institutionalised fixture, while about 42 per cent had one or two and about 53 per cent had three or more fixtures (Fuhs, 1996: 133). According to all these studies, middle class children more frequently join many club or course fixtures and at the same time meet friends more often. While 60 per cent of parents of children up to age 12 think that school time needs to be supplemented with other planned activities to complete a child’s education, at the same time 61 per cent of parents (much more than in the UK, USA and France) would encourage their child to spend more time choosing what to do freely (LEGO Learning Institute, 2003: 9-14). These data mirror parents’ ambivalence between contradictory images of the child. Children’s places: domestication and insularisation Ambivalences in the domestication trend Together with scholarisation processes, urban space development has led to a high degree of spatial separation between children’s daily lives out of school and adults’ daily lives. Young children are endangered by motorised traffic and the anonymous life of urban shopping areas, they are regarded as endangering, and many places are boring for them. Local policy for children aims at the ‘child-friendly town’. A variety of specialised playgrounds for children has been built including areas for toddlers and children, forest playgrounds and adventure playgrounds, areas for cross cycling and football pitches, areas in parks and in gaps between buildings. Thus children’s daily life has been bound more and more to sheltered places specialised for children’s purposes: to the school buildings, care and leisure time institutions, and to playing and sports grounds. The childhood historian Ariès (1962) referred to the increasing confinement of children in modernity that began with sending them to school. Zinnecker (1990), following Norbert Elias, described the same trend as domestication (Verhäuslichung) of childhood in the dual sense of the word; most children’s activities are located in houses or areas fenced in by walls and hedges and children’s agency is controlled by the structural power of spatial borderlines and the size of areas. 752 COST A19: Germany This spatial development is a symptom of the rise of childhood as an adultcontrolled societal structure in a differentiated modern society. This differentiation of childhood structures has been accompanied by the ideology of children being different from adults and not yet fully belonging to the societal world but rather to a world of free play. The discourses and policies on children’s space are characterised by that ambivalence between control and freedom. On one hand, pedagogists and urban developers value streets negatively as a counterspace beyond educational control and further domestication by protective and educational measures. However on the other hand, excluding children from public space is accompanied by complaints about the disappearance of children’s freedom, and adults wish to concede children a pre-modern free use of time and space in a non-educationally controlled space. This ambivalence supports a tendency to award high value to children’s free and wild activities. Sheltered places and arrangements are built and specialised for such activities, thus domesticating them, for instance by providing adventure playgrounds. But steps to de-specialise and reorganise urban space are also made in order to adapt it to children’s motion needs, including allowing children to play on park meadows and opening school grounds for playing in the afternoons. Trafficcalmed areas and play streets were established, and traffic education gained high importance (see below). The insularisation trend From the perspective of the individual course of a day, the places which an individual child uses in the course of a day and a week form a pattern that reflects the centralisation and spatial fragmentation of domesticated activity opportunities. In functionally differentiated landscapes, a child’s places of daily life such as home, school, day care and recreation centre buildings, playgrounds, sports fields and friends’ homes are islands within space that is geared to adults’ needs and has to be crossed by children but not used for staying there. The archipelago of islands where an individual child can stay may consist of a more or less large number of places, and the distances between home and other islands may be more or less large. The degree and shape of insularisation of children’s individual life spaces differ depending on the local infrastructure for different age groups as well as on how the children use their opportunities, which depends on age, gender (Nissen, 1998) and particular interests of a child as well as on – social class-dependent – help or constraints provided by parents (Zeiher and Zeiher, 1994; Zeiher, 2001). Case studies show huge differences between local regions (Hössl, 2002). Differences exist not simply between rural, suburban and inner city areas, or between areas with a more wealthy or poorer population. Suburban and urban regions differ to a high extent in relation to the wealth of the community and in 753 Children’s Welfare in Ageing Europe relation to the local culture and the commitment of the personnel in particular leisure facilities and in schools. There are wealthy villa areas lacking nearby provisions for children, residential areas where even hanging around would be boring, and old people’s areas where children’s noisy and fast-moving games are disliked. In some inner city areas the only option may be to look for access to institutional offers, but even there children find opportunities to meet outdoors. Children in rural regions who live outside a village have to take into account long travel routes and often parents’ help for transport when they take part in a course or want to meet a friend. There are villages and small towns where children find both natural playing areas such as woods and lakes nearby and different kinds of sports grounds and clubs with a local tradition, and there are suburbs and villages where middle class parents who themselves travel long distances to work tend to support their children’s long-distance commitments. The domestication and insularisation trends impact on children’s social life among their peers. For most children, possibilities to play outdoors with neighbours depend on a playground nearby, and smaller children are accompanied by an adult. Of children aged 8 to 10, only 16 per cent got to know their playmates in the neighbourhood, but 61 per cent in school or day care; 70 per cent had good friends whose home was in walking distance within less than 15 minutes, but 15 per cent of them were not allowed to go there alone; 20 per cent met friends only at school or day care (Traub, 2004). In order to meet their playmates many children tend to make appointments for the afternoon when they are at school together in the morning. Typically, networks of friends, almost all of them being classmates, never meet up all together in the afternoon – except at birthday parties – but prefer to spend their afternoons in pairs because they feel that making appointments in a larger group would be too complicated. Thus every afternoon throughout the urban area, a series of pairs of children meet in separate locations, perhaps at a playground, at a swimming pool or in one of the children’s homes. In schools and day care institutions children spend much more time together. And – not less important – here they enjoy meeting and playing in a larger group which many of them miss in other parts of their daily life (Zeiher and Zeiher, 1994). Asked what they like at school, two thirds of 10 to 18 year olds firstly mentioned ‘friends’ (Zinnecker et al., 2003: 43). In contrast, courses are seldom used as an occasion to make friends (Herzberg, 2001: 80). Most courses are temporally limited to one two-hour meeting a week, and a child meets different participants in each course he or she attends. Thus the trend of institutionalisation of leisure facilities causes a fragmentation not only of places but also of social relationships. At school, peers are together in time and space day by day for several hours. Breaks between lessons and the way to and from school are occasions for open and self-determined social life, while teachers control what happens during the 754 COST A19: Germany lessons, and social life among peers is more or less reduced to ‘back stages’. In breaks all pupils are together in a small fenced area. Especially in the ‘long break’ spent in the school yard, children enjoy moving around together after having been forced to sit for a long time, they talk about their own issues, and handle their personal conflicts (Krappmann and Oswald, 1995; Zinnecker, 2001). Some children prolong the time of being together in school. They arrive earlier in the morning in order to talk and play with peers, or they stay together for a while after school and play in the school yard or in a playground nearby. The routes which connect the domains of the family and school are an inbetween space and time where and when children are reached neither by the parents’ nor the teacher’s control. Children use this for their own social activities. They like to expand the duration, dawdle, stay for a while in a play area. In rural regions, school busses collect children to transport them together in the morning and at midday. During the waiting times for the bus, temporally and spatially located social worlds with particular rules and relations are created (Schick, 1992). Children whose parents transport them to and from school lack such social possibility. The importance of school for peer relations corresponds to a growing importance of the workplace for adults’ social life, the more social life becomes less frequent in family and neighbourhood contexts. Losing and reconquering urban space Dependency on transport Where small children live near to major roads, they are not allowed to go outdoors without the company of an adult. Older children walk and cycle, they depend on public transport and on parental ‘taxi service’. For both children and teenagers, fear of crime – increasingly also committed by other young people – is a reason, too. Children are usually not allowed to go to school alone before the age of eight or even nine. In 1988 only a third of 8 to 12 year-olds living in three West German regions was allowed to play outdoors wherever they liked (Deutsches Jugendinstitut, 1992). These children also reported about their modes of transport to afternoon clubs and courses: Table 9. Eight to ten year olds’ ways to afternoon clubs and courses (in per cent, 1988). By car By public transport In a city region 10 18 In a rural area 29 1 Source: Deutsches Jugendinstitut, 1992: 156. 755 Cycling 14 27 Walking 59 43 Children’s Welfare in Ageing Europe Adults wish that children could move around on their own outdoors. Local authorities try to make that possible through measures which diminish the traffic danger for children. These include speed reduction in 30 km/h zones, ‘play streets’ (Spielstraßen) and cycling lanes as well as by traffic behaviour education including instructing toddler’s parents, organising traffic security campaigns for school beginners, older pupils helping younger ones to cross the roads (Schülerlotsen), traffic behaviour lessons in all schools, examining all tenyear olds’ cycling behaviour, and obliging cyclists aged under eight to use footpaths and helmets. The risk of accidents when walking or cycling is highest in the age group of six to nine (Hautzinger et al., 1996). The rate of children killed in road accidents has diminished continuously since 1960. Long distances to day care and leisure facilities and to school cause need for transport. To build large schools which gather up children from a wide area is criticised for pedagogical reasons when younger children are involved, and for reasons of social inequality among older children since in lower class families transport need impacts on the decision to attend grammar school (Avenarius et al., 2003). However in eastern German rural regions, the demographic development forces school closures and children must be transported over longer distances. Most children’s family life also extends over a rather large space. At weekends, many families like to take trips together, often by car and/or bicycle. On Saturdays and Sundays, only 14 per cent of 5 to 12 year-old children in Cologne stayed at home, half of the others travelled a long way (Kleine, 1999: 112). Due to the length of school holidays, children presumably spend more holiday time away from home than their parents (see above). Separated parents living in different places also make children more mobile; some move more or less regularly between two homes, in each of which they have their own room. Only very seldomly do these children spend an equal amount of time at both places. About half at age 5 to 10 and fewer older children spend every second weekend with the parent with whom they do not live together permanently (Hater, 2004). These arrangements and their impact on children’s lives have not yet been investigated. Places and motion indoors Indoor activities are more immobile than outdoor activities. At school, children sit in the classroom most of the time (except in sports lessons). Afternoon leisure facilities also constrain the range of movement by fenced areas and equipment, compared to play in open urban space. In contrast, moving possibilities at home have increased. Parents like to give the child a rather large room furnished with slides and swings, thus making it a playground for kinds of motion formerly executed outdoors. Moreover, due to more child-oriented 756 COST A19: Germany views, in most families children are allowed to use most places in the house or flat for games and rough play. Since playing outdoors in the neighbourhood streets has become impossible for many children, playmates often meet at home and sometimes like overnight visits. Almost all children have a room of their own or shared with a sibling, and most own lots of toys, yet children often ignore spatial separation inside the home and bring their toys into the sitting room or do their homework at the kitchen table. However, the trend to allow for more free movement indoors contrasts with the fact that the home is the place of media use which makes persons sit in front of the TV frequently. 28 per cent of 10 to 13 year-olds have their own television set in their room (Kuchenbuch, 2003). In 2000, 3 to 13 year-olds watched television for 97 minutes on average on weekdays and 124 on Saturdays (Feierabend and Simon, 2001: 176-188). Time spent watching TV increases slightly with age and then decreases among teenagers. TV programmes structure the course of many small children’s evenings, and children are keen on particular series. 3 to 13 year-olds watch TV mainly in the early evening; between 18.45 and 20.00 every fifth child sits in front of the TV. When parents spend much time watching TV, children do the same (Kuchenbuch, 2003). Many children spend evening time in front of the TV because they want to be together with their parents (Jörg, 2000). Virtual space By reading, listening to music, playing computer games and watching TV, children travel into virtual worlds despite being at home physically. What happens there is thrilling, and usually moves much faster than real life. By a trip into virtual worlds, a child can separate her or himself from the real family space and from what happens or does not happen there. Contrary to common opinion, children’s reading activities (measured by the distribution of print products) are increasing. Three quarters tend to read magazines and books, preferring comics thereby (KidsVerbraucherAnalysen, 2002). In 2001, nearly half of 6 to 13 year-olds possessed a Gameboy, a quarter computer games, a quarter a video game console, a fifth their own computer, and many more wished to get this equipment. Half of the 7 to 14 year-olds had access to the Internet (Eckhardt et al., 2002). Moving around in the open air Doctors, sport educators and parents are greatly concerned about a lack of physical exercise. In public discourses this is judged to be alarming and related to increasing numbers of children suffering from obesity and lack of bodily 757 Children’s Welfare in Ageing Europe agility, strength and persistence. However, investigations show that three quarters of the children like and practise motion outdoors, and this is not lessened by media use as many adults believe (Baur, et al. 2004): • at age 4-10: 80 per cent like to play outdoors (according to their mothers) (Noelle-Neumann and Köcher, 2002: 126), • at age 7-13: 70 per cent enjoy moving around on bikes and 50 per cent by inline skates and skateboards (Noelle-Neumann and Köcher, 2002: 126), • at age 10-13: 80 per cent said that they take part in sports (Furtner-Kallmünzer et al., 2002: 54). Traditionally, sports training is done in clubs, but children also use more and more commercial and school programmes. In 2002, almost half of boys and 40 per cent of girls aged under 15 were sports club members (Statistisches Bundesamt 2003a: 59, 428). The gender difference depends mainly on many boys’ preference for football and many girls’ for horse riding. These most frequent types of sport demand much time; football, like other team sports, demands time for training on weekdays as well as for competitions at the weekend, and many girls who ride also care for the horses. In recent years, participation in organised sports has shifted to a younger age group. Now it is highest in the age group of 10 to 13, and then decreases. Sports clubs are changing their feature of being related to local and family traditions towards being service agencies who offer a wide range of programmes. One symptom is children’s increasing fluctuation between clubs and a trend to multiple memberships (Zinnecker and Silbereisen, 1996). Children’s sportive movement is not at all limited to training in clubs. Children love to use child-specific vehicles for moving quickly, and use a multitude of these including several types of bikes, skates and scooters. Children already ride a bicycle at the age of three, and growing older they change the bike for bigger and specialised ones such as mountain and racing bikes. Girls use bicycles more for transport while boys also use them as sports equipment. Hengst (1999: 27) refers to the town as ‘the most multi-faceted sports ground’: Looked at through the eyes of a skater, this sports ground is an accumulation of artificial spots, streets, curbs, banks, ditches, street obstacles, half pipes, mini ramps and more. Moreover there are sport islands such as skateboard parks or pools. Even now, since inline skating has become very popular, you seldom meet children who do not report about confrontations with adults. Some of them actively seek thrill and talk about such adventures. Yet more characteristic seem to be children’s efforts to reduce such adventures. 758 COST A19: Germany Since the 1980s and progressing into the 1990s, a shift has taken place in adults’ way of looking at children’s use of urban space. A need for urban space which in fits with children’s particular movement activities is recognised without trying to domesticate such activities at special places. Local authorities want young people to participate in the processes of developing measures in order to improve the urban infrastructure; local youth parliaments are the forum for such participation. As Hengst (1999: 28) states, the children tend to be less committed to more rights to use the ‘sports ground town’, rather they wish to get new places specialised for activities they prefer at the time. Thus they prefer more functional separation in space and more domestication. Resignation might be a reason, but the children also recognise the advantages of specialised places, ‘the high quality of the equipment, the stimulating atmosphere and the variety of possible sport activities’. Temporal autonomy and control After reporting what children do in their time let us now shift the perspective to the ways of deciding on time use. Children’s time use – like all people’s time use –are shaped in different ways including letting processes evolve their own intrinsic time, rational timing of one’s own activities by co-ordination and planning in a more or less long time horizon, acting in a temporally spontaneous way when a new possibility arises, adapting actions to an already existing time regime or particular date set by others or by oneself. Children’s ways of handling time – their temporal agency – are connected to the time structures and to the time use that they experience and are supposed to adapt to in their various environments. Shaping leisure time autonomously Playing time develops in the process of doing without being regulated by an external time regime – that is the meaning of playing, and doubtless that is one main way a child behaves when he or she plays. However before play with peers begins, a particular way of time use is often suitable in order to meet each other at a place and time which depends on environmental features. Children who often meet in the afternoon produce a collective way of organising their meetings temporally, thereby reacting to activity possibilities and constraints in the area and in their families (Zeiher and Zeiher, 1994). If the neighbourhood is appropriate, a child just goes outdoors and looks if anybody is already there. In such case no time organisation is necessary, and time is shaped by spatial movement, by visual perception and by walking to places; all of these activities are temporally spontaneous. One precondition for 759 Children’s Welfare in Ageing Europe such a way of handling time is attractive places which are located nearby and immediately available. Until the 1960s most neighbourhoods were appropriate for that kind of time and space use, while nowadays many children have to meet at special places including play and sports grounds or recreation centres where no need to plan curbs the users’ temporal spontaneity. Yet not many children live in close vicinity to such possibilities. Meeting at a more distant place demands an appointment. Thus, in order not to be alone in the afternoon, many children have to engage in planning time each on their own, and anticipate, initiate and co-ordinate meetings with peers. Their social life is organised more in the medium of time than by looking around in space. Young children practise this way of shaping time from a rather early age in kindergarten. These children handle their time rather autonomously, however that makes them rather dependent on their parents who help to manage the time schedule and on being transported to the appointed place. Since nearly all households are on the telephone (in western Germany since the late 1960s, in eastern Germany since 1991), appointments with peers made in the morning at school are usually confirmed later by phone, and usually a phone call is made before going to a friend’s house. The mobile phone has relieved phone communication from spatial fixation. Peers may be reached at any time wherever they are, and appointments can be made or changed at any time when a new situation, a need or an idea occurs. Whether and how children’s ways of organising their peer relations are going to be changed by use of mobile phone calls and SMS, and whether the time horizon of leisure management has been shortened, has not yet been investigated. It may be that long term planning becomes supplemented or even replaced by more ‘just in time’ production of daily life. From the start of the new technology, children and teenagers have been keen on owning a mobile phone in order to manage their peer relations by call or SMS. The number of owners increases so quickly that statistics soon become outdated. Many leisure time courses are temporally restricted by the need for booking in advance and fixed dates, and the activities are temporally structured by trainers and teachers more or less as they are in schools. Here, children also experience given time structures for their activities. However, leisure time arrangements are offers made to children. Children are not forced to go there but rather enticed by the arrangement specialising in activities they like to do. They decide on their own whether to participate. Case study research points to children who, despite being keen on a particular activity, did not join a course in order not to lose their temporal freedom. For them a prerequisite for using leisure facilities was that time is left open to their own decision. Others defended their temporal autonomy against institutional attempts to restrict it by attending too early or too late, irregularly or not at all (Zeiher, 2003; Zeiher and Zeiher, 1994). Children’s inclination to open time has been noted in the realm 760 COST A19: Germany of sport, too. Research into young people’s sport preferences shows a trend away from traditional athletic training that is strictly time-regulated along a given scheme towards a growing preference for individual performance of sporting skills. The latter is practised in streets and areas using skates or special bikes (Alkemeyer, 2003; Rusch and Thiemann, 1998). At home: handling time in many ways In family life, children experience a mixture of different ways of handling time, each depending on the activity and the sphere of life which is involved at the particular moment. On one hand, families react to the increasing temporal complexity by relieving daily life from traditional time structures. Instead of the traditional regular common midday meal, some children eat lunch at their afterschool day care centre or their grandmother’s home. Coming home from school, older children warm up a ready-made meal or wait for a parent’s return. And instead of the traditional time schedule for household work, families find their own rhythms which are easily changed according to occurring situations. On the other hand many families react by establishing one certain fixed-time common meal per day or at least at the weekend, in order to make sure they have a common communication time. Children usually persist in such rituals (Klenner et al., 2003). Thus at home children experience the strong power of time regimes and of occasional time restrictions that are set in the outer world and reign over their parents as well as over themselves. But they also experience that many things are done just in time and at any time around the clock, and that family time fixations are self-made and changeable and not mighty, externally set rules. Such contradictory experiences may help them to be able to handle time more autonomously. Yet children’s – especially younger children’s – need for reliable times is often not fulfilled; children say that they sometimes suffer from this (Roppelt, 2003, Klenner et al., 2003). As far as possible most parents tend to respect children’s interests, and children participate in negotiations on family times. The habit of negotiating instead of giving orders to children is widely spread, and embedded in a trend towards de-hierarchising child-adult relations. However, parents tend to stick strictly to certain time regulations. Making children go to bed earlier than adults (depending on their age) is part of the educational culture which seems not to have been changed by the trend to temporal de-regulation. During the week, ten year-olds tend to go to bed on average at about nine and tend to sleep nine to ten hours. Arguments about bedtime regulation are frequent, since children do not accept being excluded from their parents’ activities in the later evening. Prolonged evening time is a sign of growing up children fight for. About three quarters of 10 to 13 year-olds 761 Children’s Welfare in Ageing Europe report discussions with parents on the set bedtime, and about two thirds of them said that the conflicts are serious (Zinnecker and Silbereisen, 1996: 32 ff.). The time for coming home in the evening is also seen by children as an important sign of growing up. Here, arguments are fewer and negotiations are more common. In order to reach their child at any time and place, parents buy them a mobile phone. Set appointments for coming home can be changed, and both parents and child feel more secure when they can always reach each other. According to a study on the impact of the mobile phone on parent-child relations, 12 to 16 year-olds prefer to give information on coming home later in the evening by SMS rather than by call, as they like to avoid parents controlling and constraining them (Logemann and Feldhaus, 2002). Conflicts are frequently evoked when children do not tidy their own room, an activity of which children may determine the temporal placing more or less on their own, yet in a given time interval. More than 80 per cent of 10 to 13 year-olds reported discussions with parents and more than half of these serious arguments (Zinnecker and Silbereisen, 1996: 25; 419). Most parents stick to that task although they do not include children in much housework (Zeiher, 2000a). Changing features of household work and its timing have diminished the need and the occasions for children’s help. However, in line with the pedagogisation trend, parents like to give their children some duties in their own responsibility so that they can practise how to be conscious of fulfilling them. Usually an important duty is tidying their own room, besides emptying the dishwasher or the rubbish bin. In school: being forced into an obsolete time regime The usual organisation of time in school contradicts rather sharply with children’s many experiences of handling time more autonomously, individually and according to the respective situation. At all times, the school time regime has corresponded to the form of temporal organisation of industrial and bureaucratic work. The Taylorist method of fragmenting working time and forcing workers to adapt to the set structure and speed was also used for the temporal organisation of learning in school. Even nowadays, 45-minute intervals and detailed sequences of fragmented learning materials and steps of learning prescribe the temporal processes of learning in the same way for all pupils of a class. In the working world such types of time regime are becoming increasingly obsolete. For as much as three decades, individual workers’ ‘time sovereignty’ has been debated, and in recent times set working time structures are being transformed to flexible ones and replaced by individual control of one’s own time. However, the method of structuring learning time at school has not changed much until now, although this has been much criticised in reform discourses. Working in ‘epochs’ and on projects rather than in temporally 762 COST A19: Germany fragmented forms is practised in many schools at all levels, however not very frequently (Avenarius et al., 2003: 150). Most reform of teaching methods has taken place in primary schools (Heinzel, 2002), but even here traditional time structures are still usual. According to qualitative research, children become aware of the many ways time can be used and are thus able to reflect the power of given time structures and to resist it. Choosing ways of handling time which are suitable to the respective goal or situation, and being aware of that practice, many children take exception to time regimes which they feel to be arbitrary or counterproductive to their aimed activities. What children desire has been formulated by a ten-year old girl (Zeiher, 2000b). She compared the strict time structure of her primary school to the temporal conditions of her parents’ work: ‘To leave parts of time free for yourself, to allow yourself a break from time to time,... to choose on your own what issue you start on’. The initiated implementation of more all-day schools offers an opportunity to adapt the time organisation of school learning to the ways time is increasingly handled in contemporary society. In a prolonged school day, new ways of time organisation become possible. An alternative to the Tayloristic organisation could be to offer more possibilities than before for pupils to follow their own rhythms of learning and to dispose of more learning time on their own. Many teachers may be ready to try alternative forms of work organisation but it also needs money for more teachers and buildings. A need for more flexible and more individualised ways of shaping learning time in school presumably may grow from two sides. On the side of the children, reforms might more and more become necessary in order to improve pupils’ motivation for school learning. On the side of economy, such reforms are important in order to produce human capital which is adequate to the spreading new temporal forms of work in the working world. A short conclusion The central thesis of this study is that the welfare of children in Germany is influenced to a high extend by a clear discrepancy between children’s real forms of living on one hand, and the institutional framework of children’s lives on the other. German society and the German welfare state are considered ‘structurally indifferent’ towards children and families. Up to the early eighties of the 20th century the German welfare state was a ‘social insurance state’ centred on gainful employment; it was transfer-intensive and showed a weak children and family policy component. Since then there has been a far reaching change of the patterns of everyday life. Changed gender roles, changed patterns of distribution of labour and 763 Children’s Welfare in Ageing Europe increasing labour market participation of mothers are causing a care crisis. The traditional mix of joint responsibility of society and family, and of the mother and father for education, care and raising of children comes to a clash with the changed reality of family life and gender roles. Additionally, the western German model of family-based care combined with part-time work on the mother’s side has clashed with the eastern German model of public child care with a high rate of full-time employment by the mother. What do these social trends mean for the welfare and everyday lives of children? The study analyses children’s views of care and the care crisis and the societal trends which have an impact on the spatial and temporal dimensions of children’s lives – i.e. the blurring boundaries of family and work, the expansion of pedagogisation and scholarisation in children’s private lives and the domestication and insularisation trends. It is pointed out that the political-institutional framework is in a transformation process but institutions will change at a snail’s pace only. The consequences of the resulting lag have to be mastered by children and their parents in their private arrangements of everyday live. References Alkemeyer, T. (2003): ‘Zwischen Verein und Straßenspiel’, in Hengst, H. and H. Kelle (eds): Kinder, Körper, Identitäten. Weinheim, München: Juventa: 293-318. Alt, C. (2002): ‘Die Vielfalt familialer Lebensformen aus der Sicht von Kindern’, in Leu H.-R. (ed): Sozialberichterstattung zu Lebenslagen von Kindern. Opladen: Leske+Budrich: 139-170. Alt, C. (2003): ‘Wandel familialer Lebensverhältnisse minderjähriger Kinder in Zeiten der Pluralisierung’, in Bien, W. and J.H. Marbach (eds): Partnerschaft und Familiengründung. Ergebnisse der dritten Welle des Familien-Survey. DJI: Familien-Survey 11. Opladen: Leske+Budrich: 219-244. Alt, C. (2004): Institutionelle und familiale Betreuungsarrangements von Kindern. Unveröffentlichtes Manuskript. München: Deutsches Jugendinstitut e.V. Avenarius, H., H. Ditton, H. Döbert, K. Klemm, E. Klieme, M. Rürup, H.-E. Tenorth, H. Weishaupt and M. Weiß (2003): Bildungsbericht für Deutschland. Opladen: Leske+Budrich. Bacher, J. and C. Wenzig (2002): ‘Sozialberichterstattung über die Armutsgefährdung von Kindern’, in Leu, H.R. (ed): Sozialberichterstattung zu Lebenslagen von Kindern. Opladen: Leske+Budrich: 111-137. Bast, K. and I. Ostner (1992): ‘Ehe und Familie in der Sozialpolitik der DDR und BRD – ein Vergleich’, in Schmähl, W. (ed): Sozialpolitik im Prozeß der deutschen Vereinigung. Frankfurt A. M., New York: Campus: 228-270. Bauer, F. (2004): Familiale Zeitbewirtschaftung: Probleme der Zeitverwendung bei abhängig Beschäftigten und Selbständigen in Familienhaushalten. Vortrag zum Workshop ‘Zeit(organisation) und Familien’ am 15. Und 16. Januar 2004 in Gießen. 764 COST A19: Germany Baumert, J., E. Klieme, M. Neubrand, M. Prenzel, U. Schiefele, W. Schneider, P. Stanat, K.-T. Tillmann and M. Weiß (eds) (2001): PISA 2000: Basiskompetenzen von Schülerinnen und Schülern im internationalen Vergleich. Opladen: Leske+ Budrich. Baumert, J., K.S. Cortina and A. Leschinsky (2003): ‘Grundlegende Entwicklungen und Strukturprobleme im allgemeinbildenden Schulwesen’, in Cortina, K.S., J. Baumert, A. Leschinsky, K.U. Mayer and L. Trommer (eds): Das Bildungswesen in der Bundesrepublik Deutschland. Reinbek: Rowohlt: 52-147. Baur, J., U. Burrmann and K. Maaz (2004): ‘Verbreitet sich das ‘StubenhockerPhänomen’?’, Zeitschrift für Soziologie der Erziehung und Sozialisation 24: 73-89. Bayer, H. and R. Bauereiss (2002): ‘Amtliche Statistik als Basis für die Darstellung regionaler Unterschiede in den Ressourcen für den Kinderalltag’, in Leu H.-R. (ed): Sozialberichterstattung zu Lebenslagen von Kindern. Opladen: Leske+Budrich: 205255. Becker, I. and R. Hauser (2003): ‘Zur Entwicklung von Armut und Wohlstand in der Bundesrepublik Deutschland – eine Bestandsaufnahme’, in Butterwegge, C. and M. Klundt (eds): Kinderarmut und Generationengerechtigkeit. 2. Aufl., Opladen: Leske+Budrich: 25-41. Beher, K. (2001): ‘Kindertageseinrichtungen im Zwiespalt’, in Rauschenbach, Th. and M. Schilling (eds): Kinder- und Jugendhilfereport. Bd. 1, Münster: Votum: 53-72. Behringer, L. and K. Jurczyk (1995): ‘Umgang mit Offenheit. Methoden und Orientierungen in der Lebensführung von JournalistInnen’, in Projektgruppe Alltägliche Lebensführung (ed): Alltägliche Lebensführung. Arrangements zwischen Traditionalität und Modernisierung. Opladen: Leske+Budrich: 71-120. Bellenberg, G. (2001): ‘Wie Kinder aufwachsen’, in Böttcher, W., K. Klemm and Th. Rauschenbach (eds): Bildung und Soziales in Zahlen. Weinheim, München: Juventa: 21-37. Bertelsmann Stiftung (ed) (2002): Vereinbarkeit von Familie und Beruf: Benchmarking Deutschland Aktuell. Gütersloh: Verlag Bertelsmann Stiftung. Bertram, H. (1998): ‘Familie, Ökonomie und Fürsorge’, Aus Politik und Zeitgeschichte B53: 27-37. Bien, W. (1994): Eigeninteresse und Solidarität: Beziehungen in modernen Mehrgenerationenfamilien. Opladen: Leske + Budrich. Birg, H. and E.-J. Flöthmann (1993): Analyse und Prognose der Fertilitätsentwicklung in den alten und neuen Bundesländern. Bielefeld: Institut für Bevölkerungsforschung und Sozialpolitik der Universität Bielefeld. Bleses, P. (2003): ‘Wenig Neues in der Familienpolitik’, in Gohr, A. and M. SeeleibKaiser (eds): Sozial- und Wirtschaftspolitik unter Rot-Grün. Wiesbaden: Westdeutscher Verlag: 189-210. Blinkert, B. (1997): Aktionsräume von Kindern auf dem Land. Eine Untersuchung im Auftrag des Minsiteriums für Umwelt und Forsten Rheinland Pfalz. Pfaffenweiler: Centaurus. Bonß, W. and S. Kesselring (1999): ‘Mobilität und Moderne. Zur gesellschaftstheoretischen Verortung des Mobilitätsbegriffs’, in Tully, C.J. (ed): Erziehung und Mobilität: Jugendliche in der automobilen Gesellschaft. Frankfurt a. M.: Campus: 39-66. 765 Children’s Welfare in Ageing Europe Braches-Chyrek, R. (2002): Zur Lebenslage von Kindern in Ein-Eltern-Familien. Opladen: Leske+Budrich. Brückner, M. (2003): ‘Care. Der gesellschaftliche Umgang mit zwischenmenschlicher Abhängigkeit und Sorgetätigkeiten’, Neue Praxis 33: 162-171. Büchel, F. and K. Spieß (2002): Form der Kinderbetreuung und Arbeitsmarktverhalten von Müttern in Ost- und Westdeutschland. Stuttgart: Kohlhammer. Büchner, P. and H.-H. Krüger (1996): ‘Schule als Lebensort von Kindern und Jugendlichen’, in Büchner, P., B. Fuhs and Krüger, H.-H.: Vom Teddybär zum ersten Kuß. Opladen: Leske+Budrich: 201-224. Bundesministerium für Arbeit und Sozialordnung (BMAuS) (ed) (2001): Lebenslagen in Deutschland. Bonn. Bundesministerium für Familie und Senioren (BMFuS) (ed) (1994): Fünfter Familienbericht. Bonn. Bundesministerium für Familie, Senioren, Frauen und Jugend (BMFSFJ) (ed) (1998): Kinder und ihre Kindheit in Deutschland. Stuttgart, Berlin, Köln: Kohlhammer. Codebuch des kumulierten ALLBUS 1980-1998. Deutsches Jugendinstitut (ed) (1992): Was tun Kinder am Nachmittag? München: DJI Verlag. Deutsches Jugendinstitut (2002): Zahlenspiegel: Daten zu Tageseinrichtungen für Kinder. München: Deutsches Jugendinstitut e.V. Dingeldey, I. (2002): ‘Das deutsche System der Ehegattenbesteuerung im europäischen Vergleich’, WSI Mitteilungen 55: 154-160. Eckhardt, J., I. Mohr and T. Windgassen (2002): ‘Mediennutzung bei Kindern: Radio im Abseits’, Media Perspektiven 2: 88-102. Eberling, M., V. Hielscher, E. Hildebrandt and K. Jürgens (2004): Prekäre Balancen: Flexible Arbeitszeiten zwischen betrieblicher Regulierung und individuellen Ansprüchen. Berlin. Engstler, H. and S. Menning (2003): Die Familie im Spiegel der amtlichen Statistik: Lebensformen, Familienstrukturen, wirtschaftliche Situation der Familien und familiendemographische Entwicklung in Deutschland. Ed. by Bundesministerium für Familie, Senioren, Frauen und Jugend. Erweit. Neuauflage, Berlin. Esping-Andersen, G. (1990): The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism. Cambridge: Polity Press. Faik, J. (1997): ‘Institutionelle Äquivalenzskalen als Basis von Verteilungsanalysen – Eine Modifizierung der Sozialhilfeskala’, in Becker, I. and R. Hauser (eds): Einkommensverteilung und Armut. Frankfurt a. M., New York: Campus: 13-42. Feierabend, S. and E. Simon (2001): ‘Was Kinder sehen. Eine Analyse der Fernsehnutzung’, Media Perspektiven 4: 176-178. Feil, Chr. (2003): Kinder, Geld und Konsum. Weinheim, München. FMER (Federal Ministry of Education and Research) (2001): Basic and Structural Data 2000/2001. Bonn: FMER. Fölling-Albers, M. (2000): ‘Entscholarisierung von Schule und Scholarisierung von Freizeit?’, Zeitschrift für Soziologie der Erziehung und Sozialisation 20: 118-131. Fthenakis, W.E., B. Kalicki and G. Peitz (2002): Paare werden Eltern: Die Ergebnisse der LBS-Familienstudie. Opladen: Leske+Budrich. 766 COST A19: Germany Fthenakis, W.E. (2003): Auf den Anfang kommt es an! Weinheim, Basel, Berlin: Beltz. Bundesministerium für Familie, Senioren, Frauen und Jugend. Fuchs, M. (2003): Hausfamilien: Nähe und Distanz in unilokalen Mehrgenerationenkontexten. Opladen: Leske+Budrich. Fuhs, B. (1996): ‘Das außerschulische Kinderleben in Ost- und Westdeutschland’, in Büchner, P., B. Fuhs, and H.-H. Krüger: Vom Teddybär zum ersten Kuß. Opladen: Leske+Budrich: 129-158. Furtner-Kallmünzer, M., A. Hössl, D. Janke, D. Kellermann and J. Lipski (2002): In der Freizeit für das Leben lernen. München: Deutsches Jugendinstitut. Gerlach, I. (2000): ‘Politikgestaltung durch das Bundesverfassungsgericht am Beispiel der Familienpolitik’, Aus Politik und Zeitgeschichte B3-4: 21-31. Groß, H., U. Prekuhl and C. Thoben (1987): ‘Arbeitszeitstrukturen im Wandel’, in Minister für Arbeit, Gesundheit und Soziales des Landes NRW (ed): Arbeitszeit ‘87. Neuss: Ministerium für Arbeit, Gesundheit und Soziales des Landes NRW. Düsseldorf. Groß, P. and E. Munz (2000): Arbeitszeit ‘99: Arbeitszeitformen und -wünsche der Beschäftigten mit Spezialteil zu Arbeitszeitkonten. Ministerium für Arbeit, Soziales und Stadtentwicklung, Kultur und Sport des Landes NRW. Köln: ISO-Institut. Grünheid, E. (2003): Junge Frauen in Deutschland – Hohe Ausbildung contra Kinder? Ed. by Bundesinstitut für Bevölkerungsforschung (BiB) 1/2003: 9-15. Hagemann, U., B. Kreß and H. Seehausen (1999): Betrieb und Kinderbetreuung: Kooperation zwischen Jugendhilfe und Wirtschaft. Opladen: Leske+Budrich. Hank, K., M. Kreyenfeld and C.K. Spieß (2003): Kinderbetreuung und Fertilität in Deutschland. Diskussionspapier 331. Berlin: Deutsches Institut für Wirtschaftsforschung. Hater, K. (2004): Heute hier, morgen dort? Aspekte der räumlichen Neuordnung familiärer Beziehungen nach einer Trennung. (unpublished) Hauser, R., W. Glatzer, St. Hradil, G. Kleinhenz, Th. Olk and E. Pankoke (1996): Ungleichheit und Sozialpolitik. Opladen: Leske+Budrich. Hauser, R. and W. Voges (1999): ‘Armut und Armutspolitik in Deutschland’, Zeitschrift für Sozialreform 2: 308-338. Hautzinger, H., B. Tassaux-Becker and R. Hamacher (1996): Verkehrsunfallrisiko in Deutschland. Bergisch-Gladbach: Bundesanstalt für Straßenwesen. Heinzel, F. (2002): ‘Kindheit und Grundschule’, in Krüger, H.-H., and C. Grunert (eds): Handbuch Kindheits-und Jugendforschung. Opladen: Leske+Budrich: 541-566. Hengst, H. (1999): ‘Objekte zu Subjekten – zum Wandel von Kindheitsbildern und Kinderwelten’, in Kleine, W. and N. Schulz (eds): Modernisierte Kindheit – sportliche Kindheit? Sankt Augustin: Academia: 10-37. Herzberg, I. (2001): Kleine Singles. Weinheim and München: Juventa. Hössl, A. (2002): ‘Freizeitaktivitäten und Freizeitlernen’, in Furtner-Kallmünzer, M., A. Hössl, D. Janke, D. Kellermann and J. Lipski (eds): In der Freizeit für das Leben lernen. München: Deutsches Jugendinstitut: 37-76. Huinink, J. (1995): Warum noch Familie? Frankfurt a. M., New York: Campus. Joos, M. (2001): Die soziale Lage der Kinder. Weinheim, München: Juventa. Jörg, S. (2000): ‘Verantwortung in audiovisuellen Medien’, tv diskurs 12: 72-75. 767 Children’s Welfare in Ageing Europe Jurczyk, K. (2002): Zwischen Selbstbestimmung und Bedrängnis. Zeit im Alltag von Frauen’, in Kudera, W. and G.G. Voß (eds): Lebensführung und Gesellschaft. Beiträge zu Konzept und Empirie alltäglicher Lebensführung. Opladen: Leske+ Budrich: 219-246. Jurczyk, K. and M.S. Rerrich (eds) (1993): Die Arbeit des Alltags. Beiträge zu einer Soziologie der alltäglichen Lebensführung. Freiburg i. Br.: Lambertus. Jürgens, K. (2003): ‘Die Schimäre der Vereinbarkeit. Familienleben und flexibilisierte Arbeitszeiten’, Zeitschrift für Soziologie der Erziehung und Sozialisation 23: 251267. KidsVerbraucherAnalyse 2002 (2002). Wien and Leipzig: Bastei-Verlag. Kleine, W. (1999): ‘Kinder unterwegs – Wegstrecken als Räume kindlicher Bewegungssozialisation’, in Kleine, W. and Schulz, N. (eds) (1999): Modernisierte Kindheit – sportliche Kindheit? Sankt Augustin: Academia. Kleine, W. (2003): Tausend gelebte Kindertage: Sport und Bewegung im Alltag der Kinder. Weinheim: Juventa. Klenner, C., S. Pfahl and S. Reuyß (2003): ‘Flexible Arbeitszeiten aus Sicht von Eltern und Kindern’, Zeitschrift für Soziologie der Erziehung und Sozialisation 37: 268285. Klenner, C., S. Pfahl and S. Reuyß (2003): Arbeitszeiten – Familienzeiten – Kinderzeiten: Bessere Vereinbarkeit durch Sabbaticals und Blockfreizeiten? Düsseldorf: Wirtschafts- und Sozialwissenschaftliches Institut. Kramer, C. (2004): Verkehrsverhalten, Wegezeiten und Mobilität. Vortrag zum Workshop ‘Zeit(organisation) und Familien’ am 15. Und 16. Januar 2004 in Gießen. Krämer, W. (2000): Armut in der Bundesrepublik. Frankfurt a. M., New York: Campus. Krappmann, L. and H. Oswald (1995): Alltag der Schulkinder. Weinheim and München. Kreyenfeld, M., C.K. Spieß and G.G. Wagner (2001): Finanzierungs- und Organisationsmodelle institutioneller Kinderbetreuung. Neuwied, Berlin: Luchterhand. Kreyenfeld, M., C.K. Spieß and G.G. Wagner (2002): ‘Kinderbetreuungspolitik in Deutschland’, Zeitschrift für Erziehungswissenschaft 5: 201-221. Kuchenbuch, K. (2003): ‘Die Fernsehnutzung von Kindern aus verschiedenen Herkunftsmilieus’, Media Perspektiven, No.1: 2-11. Lampert, H. (1996): Priorität für die Familie. Berlin: Duncker & Humblot. Lange, A. and W. Lauterbach (1998): ‘Die gesellschaftliche Relevanz multilokaler Mehrgenerationenfamilien’, Zeitschrift für Soziologie der Erziehung und Sozialisation 18: 227-249. LEGO Learning Institute (2003): Executive summary: Time for playful learning? Learning, play & time conference 30.1.2003, Copenhagen University of Education. Logemann, N. and M. Feldhaus (2002): ‘Die Bedeutung von Internet und Mobiltelefon im familialen Alltag’, in Nave-Herz, R. (ed): Kontinuität und Wandel der Familie in Deutschland. Stuttgart: Lucius & Lucius: 217-225. Löhr, H. (1991): ‘Kinderwunsch und Kinderzahl’, in Bertram, H. (ed): Die Familie in Westdeutschland. DJI-Familien-Survey 1, Opladen: Leske+Budrich: 461-496. Mayr, T. and M. Ulich (2002): ‘Wohlbefinden im späten Kindes- und frühen Jugendalter – wie erleben Kinder/Jugendliche Familie, Freunde und Schule?’ in LBSInitiative Junge Familie (ed): Kindheit 2001: Das LBS-Kinderbarometer: Was 768 COST A19: Germany Kinder wünschen, hoffen und Befürchten. Opladen: Leske+Budrich sowie Institut für Demoskopie: 45-69. Meulemann, H. (1998): ‘Geht immer noch “Privat vor Katastrophe“? Familie und Selbstbestimmung in West- und Ostdeutschland 1991-1996’, Soziale Welt 49: 253274. Mierendorff, J. and Th. Olk (2003): ‘Kinderwohlfahrtspolitik in Deutschland’, in Kränzl-Nagl, R., J. MierendorffJ and Th. Olk (eds): Kindheit im Wohlfahrtsstaat. Frankfurt a. M., New York: Campus: 419-464. Münch, U. (1990): Familienpolitik in der Bundesrepublik Deutschland. Freiburg i. Br.: Lambertus. Näsmann, E. (2003): ‘Employed or Unemployed Parents. A Child Perspective’, in Jensen, A.-M. and L. McKee (eds): Children and the Changing Familiy: Between Transformation and Negotiation. London, New York: Routledge Falmer: 46-60. Neumann, U. and M. Hertz (1998): Verdeckte Armut in Deutschland. Forschungsbericht im Auftrag der Friedrich Ebert-Stiftung. Frankfurt a. M.: Institut für Sozialberichterstattung und Lebenslagenforschung. Nissen, U. (1998): Kindheit, Geschlecht und Raum. Weinheim and München: Juventa. Noelle-Neumann, E. and R. Köcher (2002): Allensbacher Jahrbuch für Demoskopie 1998-2002, Vol. 11. München: K. G. Saur. Olk, Th. and J. Mierendorff (1998): ‘Existenzsicherung für Kinder – Zur sozialwissenschaftlichen Regulierung von Kindheit im bundesdeutschen Sozialstaat’, Zeitschrift für Soziologie der Erziehung und Sozialisation 18: 38-52. Roppelt, U. (2003): Kinder – Experten ihres Alltags? Frankfurt a. M.: Peter Lang. Rosendorfer, T. (2000): Kinder und Geld. Frankfurt a. M., New York: Campus. Rusch, H. and F. Thiemann (1998): ‘Straßenszenen’, Zeitschrift für Soziologie der Erziehung und Sozialisation 18: 423-434. Schick, M. (1992): Kindheit in einem Dorf. Berlin: MPI für Bildungsforschung. Schmidt, M. G. (1998): Sozialpolitik in Deutschland. 2. Aufl., Opladen: Leske+Budrich. Schneider, N., R. Limmer and K. Ruckdeschel (2002): Berufsmobilität und Lebensform: Sind berufliche Mobilitätserfordernisse in Zeiten der Globalisierung noch mit der Familie vereinbar? Stuttgart: Kohlhammer. Schreiber-Kittl, M. and H. Schröpfer (2002): Abgeschrieben? München: DJI Verlag. Schwarz, K. (2002): Aspekte der Geburtenentwicklung in Deutschland gestern, heute und bis zum Jahr 2050. BiB-Mitteilungen: Informationen aus dem Bundesinstitut für Bevölkerungsforschung beim Statistischen Bundesamt: 16-18. Sekretariat der KMK (Ständige Konferenz der Kultusminister der Länder der BRD) (07.01.2004): Bericht über die Allgemeinbildenden Schulen in Ganztagsform. Bonn: IVD-DST 1933-4 (20). Statistisches Bundesamt (2003a): Statistisches Jahrbuch der BRD 2003. Wiesbaden. Statistisches Bundesamt (2003b): Bevölkerung Deutschlands von 2002 bis 2050. CDRom, Wiesbaden. Statistisches Bundesamt (2004): Pressemitteilung vom 21. Januar 2004. http://www.destatis.de/presse/deutsch/pm2004/p0330031.htm vom 09.02.2004. Statistisches Bundesamt (2004): Statistik der Sozialhilfe: Kinder in der Sozialhilfe 2002. Wiesbaden. 769 Children’s Welfare in Ageing Europe The World Bank (2001): World Development Indicators. Washington, DC: World Bank. Tietze, W. (1990): Betreuungsalltag: Welt des Kindes. München: Kösel-Verlag. Traub, A. (2004): Ein Freund, ein guter Freund – Gleichaltrigenbeziehungen von 8 bis 9 Jährigen. (unpublished) UNICEF (2000): A League Table of Child Poverty in Rich Nations. New York. Veil, M. (2003): ‘Kinderbetreuungskulturen in Europa: Schweden, Frankreich, Deutschland’, Aus Politik und Zeitgeschichte B-44, 53: 12-22. Voß, G. G. and H.J. Pongratz (1998): ‘Der Arbeitskraftunternehmer. Eine Grundform der ‘Ware Arbeitskraft’?’, Kölner Zeitschrift für Soziologie und Sozialpsychologie 50: 131-159. Walper, S. (1999): ‘Auswirkungen von Armut auf die Entwicklung von Kindern’. Jugendbericht, Sachverständigenkommission Zehnter Kinder- und Jugendbericht (ed): Materialien zum Zehnten Kinder- und Jugendbericht. Band 1: Kindliche Entwicklungspotentiale. Normalität, Abweichung und ihre Ursachen. München: Verlag Deutsches Jugendinstitut: 291-360. Zeiher, H. (2001): ‘Children’s islands in space and time’, in du Bois-Reymond, M., H. Sünker and H.-H. Krüger (eds): Childhood in Europe. New York: Peter Lang: 139159. Zeiher, H. (2000a): ‘Hausarbeit: Zur Integration der Kinder in die häusliche Arbeitsteilung’, in Hengst, H. and H. Zeiher (eds): Die Arbeit der Kinder. Weinheim and München: Juventa: 45-69. Zeiher, H. (2000b): Fallstudien zur alltäglichen Lebensführung Zehnjähriger. (unpublished) Zeiher, H. (2003): ‘Shaping daily life in urban environments’, in Christensen, P. and M. O’Brien (eds): Children in the City. London and New York: RoutledgeFalmer: 6681. Zeiher, H.J. and H. Zeiher (1994): Orte und Zeiten der Kinder. Weinheim and München: Juventa. Zinnecker, J. (1990): ‘Vom Straßenkind zum verhäuslichten Kind’, in Behnken, I. (ed): Stadtgesellschaft und Kindheit im Prozeß der Zivilisation. Opladen: Leske+Budrich: 142-162. Zinnecker, J. (2001): Stadtkids. Weilheim and München: Juventa. Zinnecker, J., I. Behnken, S. Maschke and L. Stecher (2003): null zoff & voll busy. Opladen: Leske+Budrich. Zinnecker, J. and R.K. Silbereisen (1996): Kindheit in Deutschland. Weinheim and München: Juventa. 770
© Copyright 2024