1 Tell me a good story and I may lend you my money: The role of narratives in peer-to-peer lending decisions Michal Herzenstein Assistant professor of marketing Lerner College of Business and Economics University of Delaware Newark, DE 19716 Tel: (302) 831-1775 Email: [email protected] Scott Sonenshein Assistant professor of management Jones Graduate School of Business Rice University 6100 Main Street Houston, TX 77005 Tel: (713) 348-3182 Email: [email protected] Utpal M. Dholakia Professor of management Jones Graduate School of Business Rice University 6100 Main Street Houston, TX 77005 Tel: (713) 348-5376 Email: [email protected] We thank Rick Andrews, Richard Schwarz, and Greg Hancock for their statistical assistance. We further thank Editor John Lynch, the AE and two reviewers for their insightful comments. Financial support from the Lerner College of business and economics at the University of Delaware and the Jones graduate school of business at Rice University is greatly appreciated. Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1840668 2 Tell me a good story and I may lend you my money: The role of narratives in peer-to-peer lending decisions Abstract We examine the role of identity claims constructed in narratives by borrowers in influencing lender decision making regarding unsecured personal loans. We study whether the number of identity claims and their content influence decisions of lenders and whether they predict longerterm performance of funded loans. Using data from the peer-to-peer lending website Prosper.com, we find that unverifiable information affects lending decisions above and beyond objective, verifiable information. Specifically, as the number of identity claims in narratives increases, so does loan funding but loan performance suffers, because these borrowers are less likely to pay back. In addition, identity content plays an important role. Identities about being trustworthy or successful are associated with increased loan funding but ironically they are less predictive of loan performance compared with other identities (moral and hardworking). Thus, some identity claims are meant to mislead lenders while others are true representations of borrowers. Key Words Identities, narratives, peer-to-peer lending, decision making under uncertainty, consumer financial decision making. Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1840668 3 The last decade has seen a growing number of business models that facilitate economic exchanges between individuals with limited institutional mediation. Consumers can buy products on eBay, lend money on peer-to-peer (P2P) loan auction sites such as Prosper.com, and provide zero-interest ―social loans‖ to entrepreneurs via Kiva.org. In all these cases, strangers must decide whether to engage in an economic exchange and on what terms using only the provided information. Objective quantitative data about exchange partners is often difficult to obtain, insufficient, or unreliable in these contexts. As a result, decision makers may turn to subjective, unverifiable, but potentially diagnostic qualitative data (Michels 2011). One form of qualitative data useful to decision makers in such economic exchanges is narratives constructed by potential exchange partners. A narrative is a sequentially structured discourse that gives meaning to events unfolding around the narrator (Riessman 1993). For example, a narrative might explain an individual’s past experiences, current situation or future hopes (e.g., Thompson 1996; Wong and King 2008). By providing an autobiographical sketch explaining the vicissitudes of their life, narratives often provide a window into how individuals conceptualize themselves (Gergen and Gergen 1997) and a portrait of how they construct their identity. As a result of either ambiguity or the strategic use of the medium to influence others (e.g., Schau and Gilly 2003), one characteristic of narratives is that they offer only one of several possible interpretations of self-relevant events (Sonenshein 2010). As a result, narrators can relay interpretations of their circumstances that convey favorable identities (Goffman 1959). RESEARCH MOTIVATIONS AND CONTRIBUTIONS The idea that narratives may involve the construction of a favorable identity poses two key questions for research. First, while narratives can provide diagnostic information to a decision maker considering an economic exchange, the veracity of the narrator’s story is difficult to 4 determine. Because a narrative offers the possibility of either describing an authentic, full or true self, or a partial, inauthentic or misleading self, potential exchange partners are left to intuit the truth of what is presented. Accordingly, a key question to consider is, given their potential for diagnostic and misleading information, to what extent do narratives influence economic exchange transactions? While previous consumer research has largely focused on narratives regarding consumption experiences (Thompson 1996) or consumption stories (Levy 1981), scholars have not examined the role of narratives in economic exchanges. Yet, we believe that narratives may be a particularly powerful lens as they allow the consumer to attempt to better control an exchange and thus can provide an edge in helping consummate an exchange. A second key question is to what extent do narratives affect the performance and outcome of an economic exchange? Narrative scholars claim the construction and presentation of a narrative can shape its creator’s future behavior (Bruner 1990) but rarely empirically examine the nature of this influence. Such an examination is critical to understand how a mixture of quantitative and qualitative factors shapes outcome quality (e.g., Hoffman and Yates 2005). We examine these two questions using online P2P loan auctions on Prosper.com by studying borrower-constructed narratives (particularly the identities embedded in them), the subsequent decisions of lenders and transaction performance two years later. We define identity claims as the ways that individuals describe themselves for others (Pratt, Rockman, and Kaufman 2006). Borrowers can construct an identity based on a range of items, such as about religion or success. This becomes an identity claim when it is public discourse as opposed to a private cognition. In this framework, we intend to make the following contributions. First, by developing and testing theory around how narratives supplement more objective sources of information decision makers use when considering a financial transaction, we draw 5 attention to how narrators can intentionally exploit uncertainty and favorably shape circumstantial facts to obtain resources such as access to money in unmediated environments. The narrative, as a supplementary, yet sometimes deal-making or deal-breaking, information source to decision makers, is predicated on compelling stories versus objective facts. It thus offers a means for individuals to reconstruct their pasts and present their futures in positive ways. Second, by linking narratives to objective performance measures, we show how narratives may predict the longer-term performance of lending decisions. Because the decision stakes are high in this unmediated and unsecured financial arena, lenders engage in highly cognitive processing (Petty and Wegener 1998). The strong incentive of potential financial loss leads to cognitive processing that tends to produce accurate attributions about a person and probabilities about future events (Osborne and Gilbert 1992). Given this motivation for accuracy, we suspect lenders use narratives to make investment decisions. Third, from a practice perspective, the recent financial crisis has exposed flaws in criteria used to make lending decisions. Quantitative financial metrics, such as credit scores, have proven unreliable in accurately predicting the ability or likelihood of consumers to repay unsecured loans (e.g., Feldman 2009). A narrative perspective on the consummation and performance of financial transactions offers the promise of improving our systems of assessing borrowers. RESEARCH SETTING Our research was conducted on Prosper.com (hereafter, Prosper), which is the largest P2P loan auction site in the U.S. with over a million members and $228 million in personal loans originated since its inception in March 2006 through April 2011. We selected Prosper because borrowers and lenders never meet in person, thereby allowing us to assess the role of narratives in overcoming uncertainty that arises during financial transactions between unacquainted actors. 6 The process of borrowing and lending money through a loan auction on Prosper is as follows. Before posting their loan request, borrowers give Prosper permission to verify relevant personal information (household income, home ownership, bank accounts, etc.) and access to their credit score from Experian, one of the major credit-reporting agencies. Using this and other information, such as pay-stubs and income tax returns, Prosper assigns each borrower a credit grade reflecting the risk to lenders. Credit grades can range from AA, indicating the borrower is extremely low in risk (a high probability of paying back the loan), to A, B, C, D, E, to HR, signifying the highest risk of default. Borrowers can now post loan requests for auction. When posting their loan auction, borrowers choose the amount to ask (up to $25,000) and the highest interest rate they will pay. They may also use an open-text area with unlimited space to write anything they want—the borrower’s narrative—which is voluntary (see also Michels 2011). After the listing becomes active, lenders decide whether to bid and, if relevant, how much money to offer and at what interest rate. A $1,000 loan can be financed by one lender who lends $1,000 or, at the other extreme, by 40 lenders each lending $25. Most lenders bid the minimum amount ($25) on individual loans to diversify their portfolios (Herzenstein et al., 2011). After the auction closes, listings with bids covering the requested amount are funded. If it receives bids covering more than this amount, the bids with the lowest interest rates win. If the auction does not receive enough bids, the request remains unfunded. Prosper administers the loan, collects payments, and receives fees of .5 to 3.0% from borrowers and a 1% annual fee from lenders. We employed three dependent variables in our study. First, loan funding is the percentage of the loan request to receive commitment of funding from lenders. For example, if a loan request for $1,000 receives bids worth $500, then loan funding is 50%. If it receives bids worth $2,000, loan funding is 200%. A higher value of loan funding signifies greater lender interest. Second, 7 percent reduction in final interest rate captures the decrease in interest rate between the borrower’s maximum specified rate and the final rate. For example, if a borrower’s maximum interest rate is 18% and the final rate is 17%, then the percent reduction in interest rate is (1817)/18 = 5.56%. The rate is reduced only if the loan request receives full funding; greater lender interest results in greater reduction of interest rate. Third, loan performance is the payment status of the loan two years after its origination. It is also important to explain the types of identity claims made by prospective borrowers. Borrowers in our sample employed six identity claims in their narratives: trustworthy, economic hardship, hardworking, successful, moral, and religious. Table 1A provides definitions and illustrative examples of these identity claims. Borrowers constructed an average of 1.53 (SD = 1.14) identity claims in their narratives. RESEARCH HYPOTHESES Who Is Likely to Provide More Identity Claims in Their Narratives? Narratives, when viewed as vehicles for identity work, provide opportunities for individuals to manage the impressions others hold of them. Impression management theory posits that individuals have a goal to create and maintain a specific identity (Leary and Kowalski 1990). Narratives provide one avenue of impression management as, through discourse, individuals can shape situations and construct identities designed specifically to obtain a desired outcome (Schlenker and Weigold 1992). Some scholars argue that individuals strategically use narratives to establish, maintain, or protect desired identities (Rosenfeld, Giacalone, and Riordan 1995). However, the use of impression management need not automatically signal outright lying— individuals may select from a repertoire of self-images they genuinely believe to be true (Leary and Kowalski 1990). Nevertheless, strategic use means that, at a minimum, individuals offer those select representations of their self-image most likely to garner support. 8 In economic exchanges involving repeated transactions, individuals receive feedback from exchange partners that either validate or dispute the credibility of their self-constructions (Leary and Kowalski 1990) and thus, are able to determine if an identity claim has been granted. Prior transactions also offer useful information through feedback ratings and other mechanisms that convey and archive reputations (Weiss, Lurie, and MacInnis 2008). However, in one-time economic exchanges, this type of feedback is not available. Instead, individuals have a single opportunity to present a convincing public view of the self. Similarly, receivers of this information have only this one presentation to deem the presenter as either credible—or not. We hypothesize that in these conditions, borrowers will be strategic in their identity claims. Borrowers with satisfactory objective characteristics will be less likely to construct identity claims to receive funding: they may feel their case stands firmly based on its objective merits alone. In contrast, borrowers with unsatisfactory objective characteristics may view narratives as an opportunity to influence the attributions lenders may make by countering past mistakes and difficult circumstances. In this scenario, borrowers make identity claims that offset the attributions made by lenders about the borrower being fundamentally not a creditworthy person. These dispositional attributions are often based on visible characteristics (Gilbert and Malone 1995). The most relevant objective characteristic of borrowers is the credit grade assigned by Prosper and derived from personal credit history (Herzenstein et al. 2011). More than one identity claim allows borrowers to present a more complex, positive self to counteract negative objective information from a low credit grade. Thus: H1: The lower the borrower’s credit grade, the greater will be the number of identities claimed by the borrower in the narrative. The Impact of the Number of Identity Claims on Lenders’ Decision Although economists often expect that unverifiable information should not matter (e.g., 9 Farrell and Rabin 1996), we suggest that the number of identity claims constructed in a borrower’s narrative will play a role in lenders’ decision making for at least two reasons. First, borrower narratives with too few identities may fail to resolve questions about the borrower’s disposition. If a borrower fails to provide sufficient diagnostic information for lenders to make attributions about the borrower (Cramton 2001), lenders may suspect the borrower lacks sufficient positive or distinctive information or is withholding or hiding germane information. Second, the limited diagnostic information provided by fewer identity claims limits a decision maker’s resolution of outcome uncertainties. Research on perceived risk supports this reasoning showing that decision makers gather information as a risk-reduction strategy and tend to be risk averse in the absence of sufficient information regarding the decision at hand (e.g., Cox and Rich 1964). In the P2P lending arena, the loan request and evaluation process unfold online without any physical interaction between the parties. Furthermore, on Prosper, borrowers are anonymous to lenders (real names and addresses are never revealed). This lack of seemingly relevant information is especially salient because many decision makers view unmediated online environments as ripe for deception (e.g., Caspi and Gorsky 2006). To the extent that the identity claims presented in a narrative reduce uncertainty regarding a borrower, lenders should be more likely to view the listing favorably, increase loan funding and decrease the final interest rate paid. Therefore, the number of identity claims in a borrower’s narrative may serve as a heuristic for assessing the borrower’s loan application and likely lead to greater interest in the listing. While we suggest that the number of identities borrowers claim will result in favorable lending decisions, we further suggest that these identity claims may persuade lenders erroneously and thus, lenders may fund loans with a lower likelihood of repayment. Borrowers can use elaborate multiple-identity narratives to craft ―not-quite-true‖ stories and make promises they 10 might find difficult to keep later on. More generally, a greater number of identity claims may suggest that borrowers are being more strategic and positioning themselves in a manner they believe is likely to resonate with lenders as opposed to presenting a true self. Therefore, we posit that, whether consciously or not, borrowers that construct several identities may have more difficulty fulfilling their obligations, and be more likely to fall behind or stop loan repayments altogether. Thus, despite the high stakes of the decision, we believe lenders swayed by multiple identities are more likely to fall prey to borrowers that underperform or fail (Goffman 1959). H2: Controlling for objective, verifiable information, the more identities borrowers claim in their loan requests, the more likely lenders will be to: (a) fund the loan, and (b) reduce its interest rate, but (c) the poorer will be the likelihood of repayment. The Role of the Content of Identity Claims on Lender Decision Making and Loan Performance We also examine the extent to which select identities affect lenders’ decision making and the longer-term performance of loans. Due to a limited theoretical basis for determining the types of identities most likely to influence lenders’ decision making, we pose this part as exploratory. Research on trust offers a promising starting point (Mayer, Davis, and Schoorman 1995), as it suggests that identities may reduce dispositional uncertainty and favorably influence lenders. Trust is a crucial element for consummation of an economic exchange (Arrow 1974). Scholars theorize trust as involving three components: integrity (borrowers adhere to principles lenders accepts), ability (borrowers possess skills necessary to meet obligations) and benevolence (borrowers have some attachment to lenders and are inclined to do good) (Mayer et al.1995). We theorize that trustworthy, religious, and moral identities will increase the perception of integrity by leading lenders to believe that borrowers ascribe to the likely lender-endorsed principle of fulfilling obligations, either directly (trustworthy) or indirectly by adhering to a philosophy (religious or moral). More specifically, the moral identity tells potential lenders that an individual has ―a self-conception organized around a set of moral traits‖ (Aquino et al. 2009, 11 p. 1424), thereby increasing perceptions of integrity. The religious identity signals a set of roleexpectations a person is likely to adhere to, and while religions vary in the content of these role expectations (Weaver and Agle 2002), many include principles around not lying or stealing, and generally honoring a contractual agreement. We further suggest that the hardworking identity will increase the perception of integrity, because hardworking individuals are determined and dependable, and as such they are often problem solvers (Witt et al. 2002), meaning that they will do their best to meet their obligations, a disposition likely to resonate with lenders. Additionally, we reason that the religious and moral identities will invoke in lenders a sense of benevolence, a foundational principle of many religions and moral philosophies. Similarly, the economic hardship identity may also invoke benevolence as the borrower exhibits forthrightness about past mistakes, which may suggest to lenders that the borrower is trying to create a meaningful relationship based on transparency. We theorize that an identity claim of success can increase the perception of ability and the belief that the narrator is capable of fulfilling promises (Butler 1991). Lenders are more likely to lend money to a borrower if they perceive the individual as capable of on-time repayment (Newall and Swan 2000). While the successful identity is likely to describe the past or present, it can also serve as an indication of a probable future (i.e., that the borrower will continue to be successful), thereby helping ―fill in the blanks‖ about the borrower in a positive way. On the other hand, economic hardship is likely to construct the borrower as someone who has had a setback and ultimately undermine perceived ability, thus negatively affecting lenders’ decisions. While we have offered some preliminary theory in support of specific relationships between identity content and loan funding/interest rate reductions, we acknowledge that this is exploratory and therefore pose these relationships as an exploratory research question (ERQ): 12 ERQ1: Which types of identity claims influence lending decisions as indicated through (a) an increase in loan funding, and (b) a decrease in the final interest rate? We also examine in an exploratory way the impact of the content of identity claims on loan performance. We envision two potential scenarios. Under the first scenario, we assume identities are diagnostic of the borrower or serve as self-fulfilling prophecies. Examining the ability aspect of trustworthiness, we anticipate a negative relation between the economic hardship identity and loan performance (as individuals further validate their claim of setbacks), and a positive relation between the successful identity and loan performance (as individuals prove their claim of past success). Moreover, we expect the four identities used to construct the borrower as having integrity—trustworthy, hardworking, moral, and religious—to be related to increased loan performance. After presenting oneself as having integrity, the borrower will probably have a strong psychological desire for consistency between what s/he says and what s/he does (Cialdini and Trost 1998). That is, borrowers may be making an active, voluntary, and public commitment that past literature has shown to psychologically bind narrators to a particular set of beliefs and subsequent behaviors (Berger and Heath 2007). As these four identities speak to fundamental self-beliefs versus predicted outcomes (e.g., success or hardship), they may greatly motivate individuals to live up to their claims. This may explain why these identities, regardless of their accuracy, can nevertheless become true and predict the performance of the lending decision. However, under another scenario, identities can improve the lender’s impression of the borrower, thereby allowing borrowers to exert control over the impressions given (Goffman 1959). Borrowers (or narrators more generally) construct positive impressions of themselves, and therefore may misrepresent themselves and send off signals that may not be objectively warranted. As such, despite believing that self-constructing identities are helpful for a lending decision, they may have no impact or may even be harmful to lenders. 13 Given the mixed possibilities, we pose the following exploratory research question: ERQ2: How are the content of identity claims and loan performance related? STUDY Data Our dataset consists of 1,493 loan listings posted by borrowers on Prosper in June 2006 and June 2007. We extracted the dataset using a stratified random sampling strategy. First, using a web crawler we extracted all loan listings posted in June 2006 and June 2007 (approximately 5,400 and 12,500 listings, respectively). A significant percentage of borrowers on Prosper have very poor credit histories and most loan requests listed on the site do not receive funding. To avoid overweighting high-risk borrowers and unfunded loans, we sampled an equal number of loan requests from each credit grade. To do so, we first separated funded loan requests from unfunded ones. We then divided each group by the seven credit grades assigned by Prosper. Finally, we eliminated all loan requests without text for three reasons. First, including loan requests without a narrative could confound the borrower’s choice to write something in the open text box but not utilize narratives with the choice to write nothing at all. Second, the vast majority of listings lacking a narrative are not funded. Third, loan requests without text represented only 9% of all loans posted in June 2006, and 4% of the loans posted in June 2007. We nevertheless used the ―no text‖ loans in a robustness check for our results. Next, we randomly sampled from the 14 sub-groups (2 funding status × 7 credit grades). In 2006, we sampled 40 listings from each sub-group (until data was exhausted) to obtain 513 listings and in 2007, we sampled 70 listings from each sub-group to obtain 980 listings—a total of 1,493 listings. Each listing in our dataset includes the borrower’s credit grade, requested loan amount, the maximum interest rate, loan funding, the final interest rate of funded loans, the 14 payback status of funded loans after two years, and open-ended text data. Before combining data from 2006 and 2006 we tested for an effect of ―year‖ on how our independent variables affect the dependent variables and found none, thus the data were combined. Dependent Variables The first dependent variable, loan funding, ranges from zero to 905% in our dataset, but the equal inclusion of all credit ratings skews these statistics. The mean percent funded in our dataset (including all listings) is 105.74% (SD = 129.2) and for funded listings is 205.45% (SD = 119.6). Because it was skewed, we log-transformed loan funding as follows, Ln(percent funded + 1). The second dependent variable, percent reduction in the final interest rate, ranges from zero to 56% in our dataset. The mean percent reduction in interest rate in our dataset (including all listings) is 6.4% (SD = 10.7) and for funded listings is 11.88% (SD = 12.75). Since the distribution is skewed, it was log-transformed (see distribution figures in web appendix). The third dependent variable is loan performance measured two years after loan funding. For each funded loan in our dataset, we obtained data about whether the loan was paid ahead of schedule and in full (31.1% of the funded listings in our dataset were paid ahead), was current (i.e., paid as scheduled; 40.5%), late (i.e., payments were between one to four months late; 7.1%), or had defaulted (21.3%). While it may seem that this dependent variable is ordered, likelihood ratio tests reveal that a multinomial logit model fares better than an ordered logit model when analyzing these data (for both independent variables, the number and content of identities). Thus, in the analysis reported below we employ a multinomial logit model. Independent Variables We read approximately one third of all narratives and developed an inductively derived list of six identity claims found in the data (Miles and Huberman 1994): trustworthy, economic 15 hardship, hardworking, successful, moral and religious. Next, two research assistants examined the same data and determined these six identities were exhaustive. Table 1A provides definitions of the identity claims and examples from our data. Then we employed five other pairs of research assistants (10 total) to code the entire dataset. Each identity was coded as a dichotomous variable that receives the value ―1‖ if the identity claim was present in a borrower’s narrative and ―0‖ otherwise. Each listing in our dataset was read by a pair of research assistants who first read the listings independently and then discussed them to provide a unifying code for each listing. Further, all research assistants coded 20 randomly sampled listings from our dataset to measure their agreement. The Fleiss Kappas range from .66 to .96 (see Table 1B) indicating a substantial agreement rate according to the Kappa interpretation guide offered by Landis and Koch (1977). Table 1B also presents the correlation between each pair of identities and the correlation of the presence of each identity with the total number of identities claimed. **** INSERT TABLES 1A AND 1B ABOUT HERE**** To test H1 and H2, the independent variable is the number of identities constructed by the borrower. That is, we counted how many different identities the loan request narrative included, with 0 representing no constructed identities and 6 representing the maximum number of identities. Most of the listings in our dataset (81.4%) included at least one identity. Since only 17 listings include five or six identities, we grouped them with listings that created four identities to smooth this variable and create more even groups (we note that this grouping affects neither our theory nor the substantive results obtained). Consequently, the variable representing the number of identities has the following distribution: zero identities = 18.6%; one identity = 35.6%; two identities = 26.7%; three identities = 13.7%; four or more identities = 5.4%. Control Variables 16 Prior research shows that borrowers on Prosper with better credit grades, those requesting smaller loan amounts, and offering higher initial interest rates are substantially more likely to receive funding (Ryan, Reuk, and Wang 2007). Therefore, we control for these in our analyses. We treat the credit grade as categorical because, although this variable is ordinal, we do not believe it is interval (i.e., the difference between HR and E may not be the same as the difference between A and AA). We created seven dummy variables, one for each credit grade. In our analyses, we use dummy variables for credit grades AA-E and leave HR as the base comparison. Additionally, we controlled for borrowers’ demographics. Our ten research assistants coded the demographic characteristics of borrowers from their narratives and pictures (specifically their gender, race, marital status and whether their family includes children). Two research assistants coded each listing for demographics and the results of the two coders were virtually identical. Disclosure of demographic information is voluntary on Prosper, and in our dataset, 66% of borrowers included at least some demographic information in their loan requests, either in their narrative or through pictures. We coded these demographic variables as categorical and note that, because disclosure is voluntary, the interpretation of these variables is, for example, not ―female‖ but ―disclosing that the borrower is a female‖. For this reason, our models include dummies for both female and male and the reference category is ―the borrower did not disclose gender‖. Results and Discussion H1 posited that a lower credit grade would result in a higher number of identities claimed in a borrower’s narrative. We employed a trend analysis to test this hypothesis because, as Dawes and Corrigan (1974) suggest, a linear function can account for almost all of the variance in any conditionally monotonic relationship. For this purpose, we coded the credit grade information as one variable that receives the following values: 1 if the credit grade is HR, 2=E, 3=D, 4=C, 5=B, 17 6=A, and 7=AA (we employed an ANCOVA that treats this variable as categorical). Controlling for demographic and loan characteristic variables, the trend analysis showed, as expected, a significant linear relation between borrowers’ credit grade and the number of identities borrowers constructed in their narratives (t(1472) = 2.63, p < .01). Higher order polynomial trends did not account for a significant proportion of the variance in the number of identities (pquadratic = .17, pcubic = .81, porder4 = .16). Figure 1 provides the estimated marginal means of the number of identities as a function of credit grade, controlling for the demographics and loan characteristics. **** INSERT FIGURE 1 ABOUT HERE**** In H2a, we posited that an increased number of identities claimed in a narrative would have a positive effect on loan funding. To test this hypothesis, we regressed the number of identities as the main predictor and credit grade, requested amount, gender, marital status, race, and having children as covariates on the natural log of loan funding. We present results in Table 2 and show that, controlling for borrowers’ demographics and loan characteristics, the number of identities borrowers claim in their narratives positively affects loan funding (β = .11, SE = .04, t = 2.81, p < .001). The model including the number of identities as the main predictor fits the data better than a model including only the controls (R2 = .46 versus .44, F(1, 1472) = 7.91, p < .01). Furthermore, and in support of H2a, the relation between the number of identities and loan funding is monotonic and increasing (the linear trend is significant (t(1472) = 2.71, p < .01), but not the quadratic: pquadratic = .99; and the cubic is marginal: pcubic = .08). Figure 2 presents the average loan funding as a function of the number of identities. H2b stated that the percent reduction in the final interest rate would be positively affected by the number of identity claims of the borrower. We employed the same regression analysis as in H2a but with the natural log of percent reduction in the final interest rate as the dependent 18 variable. Results are presented in Table 2 and show that the number of identities borrowers claim positively affects the reduction of interest rate (β = .12, SE = .03, t = 4.04, p < .001). The model including the number of identities as the main predictor fits the data better than a model including only the controls (R2 = .17 versus .15, F(1, 1472) = 16.33, p < .001). As before, and in support of H2b, the relation between the number of identities and the reduction in interest rate is monotonic and increasing (the linear trend is significant (t(1472) = 3.98, p < .001), but not the quadratic, pquadratic = .52 or cubic, pcubic = .15). Figure 2 presents more detail about this analysis. Additionally, to test the robustness of our specifications, we examined the effect of the presence of text on loan funding. Our dataset for this analysis included all loans posted on Prosper on June 2006 (n = 4,959 with no repeat listings). We created a dichotomous variable that takes the value 1 if the borrower included text in the loan request and 0 if not. Controlling for the financial characteristics, results show that loan funding increases when the listing includes text (β = .32, t = 5.64, p < .001). Indeed, only 3.5% of the listings that have no text were fully funded, compared with 8.0% of the loans with text during that month (χ2(1)= 12.63, p < .001). **** INSERT TABLE 2 AND FIGURE 2 ABOUT HERE**** To test H2c, which posited a negative effect of number of identities on loan performance, we employed a multinomial logistic model. The main predictor was the number of identities and we controlled for borrower demographic and financial characteristics. Results reveal that as the number of identity claims provided in the loan request increase, borrowers are more likely to default than to pay late (β = .29, χ2(1) = 2.98, p < .1), and are more likely to pay late than to pay on time (β = -.31, χ2(1) = 3.73, p = .053) or ahead of time (β = -.32, χ2(1) = 3.67, p = .054). The number of identities does not affect inclusion in any other categories of loan performance (see Table WA-1 in the web appendix). Figure 2 presents the percentage of borrowers that repay 19 (current and paid combined) by the number of identities constructed in their narrative. Table 3 presents the distribution of loan performance as a function of the number of identities borrowers claim in their narratives. From this table it is clear that as the number of identities increases, the default rate increases and the paid rate decreases. **** INSERT TABLES 3 AND 4 ABOUT HERE**** ERQ1 concerned the roles played by the content of the identities claimed by borrowers on lender decision making. We examined this exploratory research question using regression analyses with the six identities as main predictors. As before, we controlled for demographic variables and other financial characteristics to account for the data available to lenders when they make decisions. We present our results in Table 4. After controlling for borrowers’ demographics and loan characteristics, lenders are affected by the trustworthy identity (β = .33, SE = .09, t = 3.79, p < .001) and the successful identity (β = .23, SE = .11, t = 2.11, p < .05) such that loan funding increases. Lenders are also marginally affected by the religious identity (β = -.33, SE = .18, t = -1.82, p = .07), but this identity reduces loan funding. Borrowers claiming the trustworthy or successful identities received significantly higher loan funding than those who did not claim these identities (120.74% versus 81.51%, t(1491) = 5.76, p < .001; 124.89% versus 101.06%, t(1491) = 2.84, p < .01, respectively). Are the above effects of the identities due to an omitted variable in the regression (the total number of identities) rather than the content of these identities? That is, do the successful and trustworthy identities always appear in narratives that have many identities and the religious identity always appear in narratives that have fewer identities? Examining the correlations of the appearance of the six identities with the total number of identities (see Table 1B) shows this is not the case. For example, the low correlation of the successful identity with the overall number 20 of identities shows that this identity’s positive effect on lenders’ decisions is because of its content rather than the number of identities in narratives that include successful claims. Claiming any other identity neither helped nor hurt borrowers attempting to secure funding. The model including the six identities predicts loan funding significantly better than a model including only the controls (R2 = .46 versus .44, F(6, 1467) = 3.84, p < .001). We found similar results for the final interest rate with the trustworthy (β = .24, SE = .07, t = 3.55, p < .001) and successful identities (β = .27, SE = .08, t = 3.26, p < .001) helping to reduce final interest rates. Borrowers claiming trustworthy or successful identities enjoy greater reduction in interest rate compared with those who did not claim these identities (7.60% versus 4.54%, t(1491) = 5.41, p < .001; 8.86% versus 5.83%, t(1491) = 4.38, p < .001, respectively). None of the other identities had an effect on reduction in interest rate. Also, the model including the six identities predicts the percent reduction in interest rate better than the model including only the controls (R2 = .17 versus .15, F(6, 1467) = 4.75, p < .001). One interesting question is what affects lenders more, the number of identities or their content. We compared the unrestricted model (the one with the six different identities) with the restricted model (the one in which we count the identities and ignore their content) and using the F-test for nested models we find that the unrestricted model fits the data better (F(5, 1472) = 3.02, p = .01). Next, we tested whether there is a partial effect of the number of identities after controlling for their content. To the regressions presented in Table 4 we added a dichotomous variable for listings by borrowers who claim many identities (4 or more). This variable has a marginal positive effect on loan funding above and beyond the content of the identities (β = .35, SE = .21, t = 1.67, p < .1). Moreover, the trustworthy identity remains significant in this analysis (β = .32, SE = .09, t = 3.63, p < .001), the successful identity becomes less significant (β = .19, 21 SE = .11, t = 1.73, p < .1), and the religious identity becomes more significant (β = -.43, SE = .19, t = -2.23, p < .05). Taken together, these analyses show that the effect of the number of identities is weaker than the effect of the specific identities. To examine ERQ2, we subjected the loan performance measure to a multinomial logit with the identities as the main predictors along with other borrower and loan characteristics as controls (see results in WA-2 in the web appendix). We find that while the successful identity helps borrowers fund their loans and reduce their final interest rate, this identity is unrelated to loan performance. The trustworthy identity predicts loan performance such that borrowers who claim this identity are more likely to pay ahead of time than to pay on time (β = -.51, χ2(1) = 5.51, p < .05). More interestingly, two other identities were found to be related to loan performance, moral (positive) and economic hardship (negative). Specifically, borrowers claiming a moral identity are more likely to pay on time than pay late (β = .81, χ2(1) = 3.00, p < .1) or default (β = .73, χ2(1) = 5.77, p < .05). Additionally, borrowers claiming the economic hardship identity are more likely to default (β = .90, χ2(1) = 9.15, p < .001), pay late (β = .69, χ2(1) = 3.10, p < .1), or on time (β = .66, χ2(1) = 6.54, p < .01) than pay their loans ahead of time. The model including the six identities predicts loan performance better than the model including the controls only (-2LL = 1547 versus 1575, χ2(6) = 27.88, p < .001). In sum, our findings suggest that while the trustworthy and successful identity claims are more likely to result in funded loans, lenders should only consider the trustworthy identity. Lenders should also consider the moral identity and put negative weight on the economic hardship identity as it is negatively related to loan performance. GENERAL DISCUSSION In this research, we examined the roles narratives play in influencing decision making in 22 economic exchanges between previously unknown transaction partners—borrowers who serve as narrators and lenders who serve as decision makers. We reasoned and found support for the hypothesis that narratives influence decision makers beyond objective information. Narrators appear to strategically provide identities and favor multiple identities when their credit grades are poor. From the lender’s perspective, claiming more identities predicts an increased likelihood of loan funding and a reduction of the final interest rate. Yet, more identities can have a negative impact on loan performance. Thus, talk (i.e., claiming identities) is ―cheap‖, but given that lenders respond to it, talk affects important outcomes. Further, claiming trustworthy and successful identities influence lenders to engage in economic exchanges, but ironically the successful identity is not predictive of a positive outcome, and the trustworthy identity explains the difference between borrowers who pay on time and those who pay ahead of time, both positive outcomes. Instead, more predictive of long-term performance are the moral and economic hardship identities (positively and negatively respectively). To the extent that lenders’ and borrowers’ interests are sufficiently aligned (e.g., negative loan performance affects the ability to borrow again on Prosper), a misrepresentation that increases loan funding but does not positively affect loan performance may be detrimental to borrowers and lenders. Theoretical Implications The narrative approach to identity that we apply to decision making builds on recent scholarly interest around the use of narratives in facilitating economic transactions. For example, Martens, Jennings, and Jennings (2007) found narratives help entrepreneurs secure resources for their endeavors by providing a compelling story about the organization’s identity. Chen, Yao, and Kotha (2009) examined business plans of entrepreneurs that, as a type of narrative, serve as a vehicle providing vital information during financial exchanges involving uncertainty. We extend 23 the study of narratives to financial transactions involving unsecured personal loans between individuals. We explain our findings using the idea that information embedded in identity claims reduces dispositional uncertainty and provides contextual information that influences decision makers. By extending our findings to include longer-term performance, we show that narratives not only influence decision makers but also can predict the outcome of their decisions. This demonstration expands the scope of narrative research from an exercise in persuasion to a key factor in predicting outcomes, a point narrative scholars have frequently made (e.g., Bruner 1990), but one that has gone largely undeveloped and thus far, unproven. In explaining our exploratory findings around the content of identity claims and lending decision making, we found the trustworthy identity may invoke attributions of integrity and the perception that the borrower adheres to a set of principles the lender finds acceptable. The successful identity may invoke attributions of ability and the perception that the borrower is competent and has the skills necessary to meet obligations. Future research may seek to explain why the moral and religious identities did not increase attributions of integrity. It could be that lenders discount or ignore these particular identities based on their persuasion knowledge regarding such identity claims (Friestad and Wright 1994) or because of attributions based on these identities regarding the borrower (Gilbert and Malone 1995). We also posed as exploratory research the relationship between the content of identity claims and loan performance, proposing two scenarios. In the first, we posited that constructed identities are transparent and true indicators of the self and, as theorized, an economic hardship identity negatively affects loan performance. However, the presentation of a successful identity did not relate to loan performance. While future research is needed to unpack this mixed finding, one explanation may be that negative constructs (such as economic hardship) tend to be more 24 powerful than positive ones (Baumeister et al. 2001). We also suggested that the four identities around integrity would psychologically bind individuals to engage in behaviors to uphold their sense of integrity. In fact, the moral and trustworthy identities exhibited this effect. One explanation for the strong effect of the moral identity may be that this identity serves as a selfregulatory mechanism (Aquino et al., 2009). On the other hand, a second scenario suggests that there is either no or even a negative relationship between the content of the identity claims and loan performance. Indeed, the successful, hardworking, and religious identities are not related to loan performance, and economic hardship is negatively related to loan performance. More generally, our findings largely support the interpretation that individuals use narratives strategically to manage favorable impressions, something which contributes to research on impression management and its role in decision making. A wide body of research indicates individuals are adept in crafting favorable self-views for themselves and others (Leary and Kowalski 1990). What is less clear is the relationship between these impressions and reality. Our study addresses this question by assessing whether impressions individuals construct bear out in the future. We find that, even for a process as complex and prone to unforeseen environmental contingencies (job loss, medical emergency, etc.) as a loan (Warren and Warren Tyagi 2003), when individuals claim a moral identity, they strive to fulfill that presentation. However, the economic hardship identity is negatively related to loan performance suggesting that, despite being authentic about their difficulties, it is not always reasonable to expect these borrowers to create a new reality. Additionally, the pattern of results suggests that individuals use an economic hardship identity strategically to gain empathy, a tactic lenders should view as a warning sign as, ultimately, these borrowers lack either the ability or willingness to fulfill their loan obligations. Practical Implications 25 Our findings suggest how both borrowers (narrators) and lenders (decision makers) can be more effective. For borrowers, our findings show the power of constructing a viable narrative when attempting to influence a decision maker. An effective narrative should contain several identity claims and emphasize a trustworthy or successful identity. For lenders, our findings show the importance of analyzing narratives when making economic exchange decisions under uncertain conditions. The analysis of narratives can provide a competitive advantage to lenders that goes beyond traditional credit-based risk scoring models. While credit scores and other objective economic information will continue to play an important role in lending decisions, our findings suggest the benefits of supplementing this approach with an informed assessment of narrative data. Specifically, lenders should favor borrowers who claim to be moral or trustworthy and avoid borrowers claiming economic hardship. In this sense, our research offers an important method to assess financial transactions beyond traditional credit-based models. Limitations and Future Research Directions Our research has several limitations and, as a result, suggests promising directions for future research. First, while our data includes important information about borrowers, lenders’ decisions, and outcomes, we were unable to get any additional information about lenders. Based on theory, we inferred how lenders make decisions. As such, there is an opportunity for future research to capture the mental maps of decision makers when evaluating narratives. For example, are lenders cognizant of the number and content of identities, or are their responses heuristically based? Do key factors, such as lending experience, explain why some decision makers are more adept at consummating transactions with favorable outcomes? Is it possible that narratives that are familiar to and resonate with particular decision makers have an increased likelihood of funding? Knowing the background and personal characteristics of lenders would be useful in this 26 regard. Second, given the novelty of this research area, we centered our hypotheses around single identities. To build on our findings, future research should develop and test hypotheses about interactions between identities. Third, we focused on one aspect of narratives—identities, both their number and content. Yet, as rich mediums of communication, narratives contain more complexity than we explored. For example, narratives convey emotions (e.g., sympathy, anger) or attributions (internal or external) that may influence decision makers, and temporal structures that reveal how individuals reconstruct the unfolding of events (Gergen and Gergen 1997). Studying these aspects and their effects on consummation and performance of economic exchanges can add further depth to our approach. Additionally, we acknowledge that the size of the effects of narratives on loan funding is generally small (around 2%), even if it is in line with effect sizes reported by other narrative researchers (for example, Martens et al. (2007) show that identity claims affect underpricing in IPOs above and beyond objective information by 3%). Our findings present both opportunities and challenges for research. Economic exchanges at arm’s length provide little diagnostic information for exchange partners. What is especially attractive about our approach is that the alternative source of information provided in a narrative can reduce uncertainty and lead to more frequent successful exchanges. This information can also enhance predictions of performance. As evidenced by the recent financial crisis, lenders often make poor decisions that lead to sub-optimal outcomes (Feldman 2009). Our findings suggest that decision makers might be relying on the wrong type of data or not adequately supplementing their analyses with alternative data. A narrative, as a rich source of qualitative data about who an individual is, offers the promise to expand current decision making models of lending (and other economic transactions), reduce uncertainty transaction partners usually face and limit future challenges similar to those recently experienced in the financial markets. 27 REFERENCES Aquino, Karl F., Dan Freeman, Americus Reed II, Vivien K. G. Lim and Will Felps (2009), ―Testing a Social-Cognitive Model of Moral Behavior: The Interactive Influence of Situations and Moral Identity Centrality,‖ Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 97(1), 123-141. Arrow, Kenneth (1974), The Limits of Organization. New York: Norton, York. Baumeister, Roy F., Ellen Bratslavsky, Cartin Finkenauer, and Kathleen D. Vohs (2001), ―Bad Is Stronger Than Good,‖ Review of General Psychology, 5(4), 323-370. Berger, Jonah and Chip Heath (2007), ―When Consumers Diverge from Others: Identity Signaling and Product Domains,‖ Journal of Consumer Research, 34(2), 121-134. Bruner, Jerome S. (1990), Acts of Meaning. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Butler, John K. (1991), ―Toward Understanding and Measuring Conditions of Trust: Evolution of a Conditions of Trust Inventory,‖ Journal of Management, 17(3), 643-663. Caspi, Amer and Paul Gorsky (2006), ―Online Deception: Prevalence, Motivation, and Emotion,‖ CyberPsychology and Behavior, 9(1), 54-59. Chen, Xiao-Ping, Xin Yao, and Suresh Kotha (2009), ―Passion and Preparedness in Entrepreneurs’ Business Plan Presentations: A Persuasion Analysis of Venture Capitalists’ Funding Decisions,‖ Academy of Management Journal, 52(1), 199-214. Cialdini, Robert B. and Melanie R. Trost (1998), ―Social Influence: Social Norms, Conformity, and Compliance,‖ in The Handbook of Social Psychology, 4th ed. Daniel T. Gilbert, Susan T. Fiske and Gardner Lindzey, eds. Boston: McGraw-Hill, 151-192. Cox, Donald F. and Stuart U. Rich (1964), ―Perceived Risk and Consumer Decision-Making: The Case of Telephone Shopping,‖ Journal of Marketing Research, 1(4), 32-39. Cramton, Catherine Durnell (2001), ―The Mutual Knowledge Problem and Its Consequences for Dispersed Collaboration,‖ Organization Science, 12 (3), 346-371. Dawes, Robyn M. and Bernard Corrigan (1974), ―Linear Models in Decision Making,‖ Psychological Bulletin, 81(2), 95-106 Duarte, Jefferson, Stephen Siegel, and Lance Young (2009), ―Trust and Credit,‖ Working paper, Rice University. Farrell, Joseph, and Matthew Rabin (1996), ―Cheap Talk,‖ Journal of Economic Perspectives, 10(3), 103-118. Feldman, Amy (2009), ―Peer-to-Peer Lending for Nanks, Too?‖ BusinessWeek, April 27. Friestad, Marian and Peter Wright (1994), ―The Persuasion Knowledge Model: How People 28 Cope with Persuasion Attempts,‖ Journal of Consumer Research, 21(1), 1-31. Gergen, Kenneth J. and Mary K. Gergen (1997), ―Narratives of the Self,‖ in Memory, Identity, Community: The Idea of Narrative in the Human Sciences, Lewis P. Hinchman and Sandra Hinchman, eds. Albany, NY: State University of New York, 161-184. Gilbert, Daniel T., Patrick S. Malone (1995), ―The Correspondence Bias,‖ Psychological Bulletin, 117(1), 21-38. Goffman, Erving (1959), The Presentation of Self in Everyday Life. New York: Doubleday. Herzenstein, Michal, Utpal M. Dholakia, and Rick L. Andrews (2011), ―Strategic Herding Behavior in Peer-to-Peer Online Loan Auctions,‖Journal of Interactive Marketing,25(1),27-36. Hoffman, Robert R. and J. Frank Yates (2005), ―Decision(?) Making(?),‖ IEEE Intelligent Systems, 20(4), 76-83. Landis, J. Richard and Gary G. Koch (1977), ―The Measurement of Observer Agreement for Categorical Data,‖ Biometrics, 33(1), 159-174. Leary, M., R. Kowalski. 1990. Impression Management: A Literature Review and a TwoComponent Model. Psychological Bulletin 107(1) 34-47. Levy, Sidney J. (1981), ―Interpreting Consumer Mythology: A Structural Approach to Consumer Behavior,‖ Journal of Marketing, 45, 49-62. Martens, Martin L., Jennifer E. Jennings, and P. Devereaux Jennings (2007), ―Do the Stories They Tell Get Them the Money They Need? The Role of Entrepreneurial Narratives in Resource Acquisition,‖ Academy of Management Journal, 50(5), 1107-1132. Mayer, Roger C., James H. Davis, and F. David Schoorman (1995), ―An Integrative Model of Organizational Trust,‖ Academy of Management Review, 20, 709-734. Michels, Jeremy (2011), ―Do Unverifiable Disclosures Matter? Evidence from Peer-to-Peer Lending,‖ Working Paper, University of Colorado. Miles, Matthew B. and A. Michael Huberman (1994), Qualitative Data Analysis: An Expanded Sourcebook, 2nd ed. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage. Newall, Susan and Jacky Swan (2000), ―Trust and Inter-organizational Networking,‖ Human Relations, 53(10), 1287-1328. Osborne, Randall E. and Daniel T. Gilbert (1992), ―The Preoccupational Hazards of Social Life,‖ Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 62(2), 219-228. Petty, Richard and Duane T. Wegener (1998), ―Matching Versus Mismatching Attitude Functions: Implications for Scrutiny of Persuasive Messages,‖ Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 24(3), 227-240. 29 Pratt, Michael G., Kevin W. Rockmann, and Jeffrey B. Kaufmann (2006), ―Constructing Professional Identity: The Role of Work and Identity Learning Cycles in the Customization of Identity among Medical Residents,‖ Academy of Management Journal, 49(2), 235-262. Riessman, Catherine Kohler (1993), Narrative Analysis. Newbury Park, CA: Sage Publications. Rosenfeld, Paul, Robert A. Giacalone, and Catherine A. Riordan (1995), Impression Management in Organizations. London: Routledge. Ryan, Joe, Katya Reuk, and Charles Wang (2007), ―To Fund or Not to Fund: Determinants of Loan Fundability in the Prosper.com Marketplace,‖ working paper, Stanford University. Schau, Hope Jensen and Mary C. Gilly (2003), ―We Are What We Post? Self-presentation in Personal Web Space,‖ Journal of Consumer Research, 30(3), 385-404. Schlenker, Barru R. and Michael F. Weigold (1992), ―Interpersonal Processes Involving Impression Regulation and Management,‖ Annual Review of Psychology, 43, 133-168. Shafir, Eldar, Itamar Simonson, and Amos Tversky (1993), ―Reason-based Choice,‖ Cognition, 49, 11-36. Sonenshein, Scott (2010), ―We’re Changing or Are We? Untangling the Role of Progressive, Regressive and Stability Narratives during Strategic Change Implementation,‖ Academy of Management Journal, 53(3), 477-512. Thompson, Craig J. (1996), ―Caring Consumers: Gendered Consumption, Meanings and the Juggling Lifestyle,‖ Journal of Consumer Research, 22(4), 388-407. Warren, Elizabeth and Amelia Warren Tyagi (2003), The Two Income Trap: Why Middle-Class Mothers and Fathers are Going Broke. New York: Basic Books. Weaver, Gary R. and Bradley R. Agle (2002), ―Religiosity and Ethical Behavior in Organizations: A Symbolic Interactionist Perspective,‖ Academy of Management Review, 27(1), 77-97. Weiss, Allen M., Nicholas H. Lurie, and Deborah J. MacInnis (2008), ―Listening to Strangers: Where Responses are Valuable, How Valuable Are They and Why?‖ Journal of Marketing Research, 45(4), 425-436. Witt, L. A., K. Michele Kacmar, Dawn S. Carlson, and Suzanne Zivnuska (2002), ―Interactive effects of personality and organizational politics on contextual performance,‖ Journal of Organizational Behavior, 23(8), 911–926. Wong, Nancy and Tracey King (2008), ―The Cultural Construction of Risk Understanding through Illness Narratives,‖ Journal of Consumer Research, 34(5), 579-594. Woolcock, Michael J. V. (1999), ―Learning From Failures in Microfinance: What Unsuccessful Cases Tell Us About How Group-Based Programs Work,‖ American Journal of Economics and Sociology, 58(1), 17-42. 30 Table 1A. Definitions of identities and examples for data coding Identity Definition Trustworthy Lenders can trust the borrower to ―I am responsible at paying my bills and pay back the money on time lending me funds would be a good investment.‖ (Listing #17118) (i.e., Duarte, Siegel, and Young 2009) Successful (i.e., Shafir, Simonson, and Tversky 1993) Hardworking (i.e., Woolcock 1999) Examples The borrower is someone with a successful business or job/career ―I have (had) a very solid and successful career with an Aviation company for the last 13 years.‖ (Listing #18608) The borrower will work very hard to pay the loan back ―I work two jobs. I work too much really. I work 26 days a month with both jobs.‖ (Listing #18943) The borrower is someone of need because of hardship as a (i.e., Woolcock 1999) result of difficult circumstances, bad luck or other misfortunes that were, or were not, in the borrower’s control ―Unfortunately, a messy divorce and an irresponsible ex have left me with awful credit.‖ (Listing #20525) The borrower is honest or moral person ―On paper I appear to be an extremely poor financial risk. In reality, I am an honest, decent person.‖ (Listing #17237) The borrower is a religious person ―One night, the Lord awaken me and my spouse… our business has been an enormous success with G-d on our side.‖ (Listing #21308) Economic Hardship Moral (i.e., Aquino et al. 2009) Religious (i.e., Weaver and Agle 2002) 31 Table 1B. Frequencies and coders’ agreement measures for identity claims, correlations of each identity claim with the total number of identities, and co-occurrence of each two identities (out of all listings) Frequency a Agreement rate b Fleiss Kappa Interpretation of Kappa c Number of identities Trustworthy Trustworthy 61.8% 83% 0.66 Substantial .57** 1 Successful 19.6% 79% 0.75 Substantial .38** .07** 1 Economic Hardship 25.0% 90% 0.80 Substantial .49** .03 -.07** 1 Hardworking 25.7% 81% 0.71 Substantial .56** .09** .07* .14** 1 Moral 15.4% 78% 0.78 Substantial .51** .15** -0.02 .14** .16** 1 Religious 5.7% 98% 0.96 Almost perfect .35** .12** -0.01 .11** .05* .12** Successful a. This frequency represents all listings of borrowers that claimed the identity, with or without claiming other identities. b. Agreement rate between five sets of two coders for the twenty listings that everyone coded. c. The interpretation of the Kappa size is based on the one suggested by Landis and Koch (1977). *. ** represent significance levels at .05, and .01 respectively. Economic hardship Hardworking Moral 32 Table 2. Loan funding (H2a) and percent reduction in interest rate (H2b) as a function of number of identities β Log of Loan funding SE t p Log of % reduction in interest rate β SE t p Constant -6.60 0.20 -32.52 0.00 -5.64 0.16 -36.00 0.00 Number of identities 0.11 0.04 2.81 0.01 0.12 0.03 4.04 0.00 Requested loan amount (thousands) -0.10 0.01 -16.16 0.00 -0.03 0.01 -6.78 0.00 Initial interest rate 21.72 0.77 28.15 0.00 7.26 0.60 12.19 0.00 AA 4.23 0.18 23.16 0.00 1.59 0.14 11.29 0.00 A 3.65 0.18 20.43 0.00 1.38 0.14 9.98 0.00 B 2.85 0.17 16.85 0.00 1.08 0.13 8.28 0.00 C 1.91 0.16 11.94 0.00 0.63 0.12 5.14 0.00 D 1.30 0.16 8.27 0.00 0.46 0.12 3.81 0.00 E 0.27 0.15 1.78 0.08 0.18 0.12 1.54 0.12 Male 0.51 0.13 4.00 0.00 0.16 0.10 1.63 0.10 Female 0.38 0.14 2.83 0.00 0.13 0.10 1.21 0.23 Married 0.25 0.12 2.07 0.04 0.20 0.09 2.16 0.03 Divorced -0.19 0.21 -0.92 0.36 0.04 0.16 0.24 0.81 Single 0.49 0.20 2.42 0.02 0.29 0.16 1.85 0.07 Engaged -0.10 0.24 -0.43 0.67 0.21 0.19 1.13 0.26 Caucasian -0.11 0.11 -1.04 0.30 0.12 0.08 1.44 0.15 African American -0.37 0.18 -1.98 0.05 -0.04 0.14 -0.29 0.77 Hispanic 0.03 0.35 0.07 0.94 0.05 0.27 0.20 0.84 Children -0.06 0.11 -0.60 0.55 -0.04 0.08 -0.53 0.59 Reference categories for the predictors: for gender it is ―no gender‖ (borrowers who did not disclose their gender), for marital status it is ―no marital status or widow‖ (we have only two widows in our sample), for race it is ―no race or race other than Caucasian, African American, or Hispanic‖ (there were a few Asian and Indian in our sample), for credit grade it is HR (high risk). 33 Table 3. Distribution of loan performance as a function of the number of identities borrowers claim No identities One identity Two identities Three identities Four identities Total Default 12.2% 18.4% 24.2% 26.4% 28.8% 21.3% Late 8.9% 6.5% 7.4% 6.4% 7.7% 7.1% Current 40.0% 42.1% 37.2% 41.8% 44.2% 40.5% Paid 38.9% 33.0% 31.2% 25.5% 19.2% 31.0% Total 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 90 261 215 110 52 728 n 34 Table 4. Loan funding and percent reduction in interest rate as a function of the identities (ERQ1) Log of Loan funding Log of % reduction in interest rate β SE t p β SE t p Constant -6.59 0.20 -32.27 0.00 -5.62 0.16 -35.59 0.00 Trustworthy 0.33 0.09 3.79 0.00 0.24 0.07 3.55 0.00 Successful 0.23 0.11 2.11 0.03 0.27 0.08 3.26 0.00 Economic Hardship 0.00 0.10 0.01 0.99 0.01 0.08 0.14 0.89 Hardworking 0.05 0.10 0.54 0.59 0.07 0.08 0.98 0.33 Moral 0.01 0.12 0.08 0.94 -0.04 0.09 -0.46 0.65 Religious -0.33 0.18 -1.82 0.07 0.13 0.14 0.91 0.36 Requested loan amount (thousands) -0.10 0.01 -16.13 0.00 -0.03 0.01 -6.84 0.00 Initial interest rate 21.48 0.77 27.80 0.00 7.08 0.60 11.85 0.00 AA 4.10 0.19 22.03 0.00 1.50 0.14 10.42 0.00 A 3.54 0.18 19.61 0.00 1.30 0.14 9.29 0.00 B 2.76 0.17 16.22 0.00 1.03 0.13 7.79 0.00 C 1.85 0.16 11.57 0.00 0.60 0.12 4.85 0.00 D 1.28 0.16 8.17 0.00 0.45 0.12 3.69 0.00 E 0.28 0.15 1.84 0.07 0.19 0.12 1.64 0.10 Male 0.48 0.13 3.83 0.00 0.16 0.10 1.63 0.10 Female 0.40 0.14 2.91 0.00 0.16 0.10 1.56 0.12 Married 0.27 0.12 2.25 0.02 0.21 0.09 2.22 0.03 Divorced -0.18 0.21 -0.83 0.41 0.05 0.17 0.33 0.74 Single 0.53 0.20 2.60 0.01 0.32 0.16 2.02 0.04 Engaged -0.08 0.24 -0.31 0.75 0.23 0.19 1.21 0.23 Caucasian -0.10 0.11 -0.89 0.38 0.12 0.08 1.46 0.14 African American -0.36 0.18 -1.94 0.05 -0.05 0.14 -0.34 0.73 Hispanic 0.01 0.35 0.02 0.98 0.03 0.27 0.10 0.92 Children -0.05 0.11 -0.42 0.67 -0.03 0.08 -0.37 0.71 Reference categories for the predictors: for identities it is ―no identities‖ (borrowers who did not claim any of the six identities), for gender it is ―no gender‖, for marital status it is ―no marital status or widow‖, for race it is ―no race or race other than Caucasian, African American, or Hispanic‖, for credit grade it is HR. 35 Figure 1. Estimated marginal means of the number of identities constructed by borrowers as a function of borrowers’ credit grade, controlling for demographics and loan financial characteristics 1.75 Estimated marginal means of the number of Identities 1.71 1.70 1.68 1.65 1.60 1.55 1.50 1.48 1.45 1.46 1.44 1.45 1.40 1.40 HR E D C B A AA Credit Grade Covariates appearing in the model are evaluated at the following values: requested loan amount = 8310.24, initial interest rate = .169081, male = .32, female = .24, married = .23, divorced = .04, single = .05, engaged = .03, Caucasian = .35, African American = .07, Hispanic = .01, children = .27. 36 Figure 2. Number of identities predicts loan funding, reduction in interest rate, and loan performance* Loan funding Loan performance Reduction in interest rate 1.4 0.1 1.3 0.08 1.1 1 0.07 0.9 0.06 0.8 0.7 0.05 Percent reduction in interest rate Loan funding / Loan performance 0.09 1.2 0.6 0.04 0.5 0.4 0.03 No identities One identity Two identities Three identities Four or more identities Number of identities * For the purposes of plotting this figure, we grouped the four loan performance levels into two levels (pay/no pay) and present the percentage of listings by borrowers who pay. 37 Web appendix Table WA-1 Loan performance as a function of the number of identities (H2c). Late is the reference category Default Paid Current β 0.60 SE 1.33 χ2(1) 0.20 p 0.65 β 3.86 SE 1.23 χ2(1) 9.81 p 0.00 β 3.83 SE 1.29 χ2(1) 8.85 p 0.00 0.29 0.17 2.98 0.08 -0.31 0.16 3.73 0.053 -0.32 0.17 3.67 0.054 0.05 0.04 1.61 0.20 -0.04 0.04 1.43 0.23 -0.08 0.04 5.23 0.02 2.52 4.77 0.28 0.60 -9.50 4.43 4.59 0.03 -12.63 4.66 7.35 0.01 0.68 1.38 0.24 0.62 1.77 1.28 1.90 0.17 3.02 1.31 5.32 0.02 A -0.60 0.97 0.39 0.53 0.31 0.87 0.13 0.72 0.81 0.91 0.79 0.37 B -0.20 0.79 0.06 0.80 0.17 0.73 0.05 0.82 0.54 0.77 0.48 0.49 C -0.36 0.63 0.33 0.57 0.24 0.60 0.16 0.69 0.62 0.64 0.92 0.34 D 0.37 0.61 0.37 0.54 0.70 0.59 1.41 0.24 1.20 0.63 3.59 0.06 E 0.22 0.51 0.18 0.67 0.69 0.50 1.90 0.17 0.66 0.57 1.34 0.25 Male -0.98 0.57 2.92 0.09 -0.72 0.54 1.74 0.19 -0.38 0.56 0.45 0.50 Female -1.69 0.57 8.77 0.00 -0.96 0.54 3.17 0.08 -1.38 0.57 5.88 0.02 Married 0.22 0.47 0.22 0.64 -0.37 0.43 0.72 0.40 -0.35 0.46 0.58 0.44 Divorced -0.27 0.61 0.20 0.66 -0.95 0.59 2.61 0.11 -1.53 0.71 4.64 0.03 Single 0.95 0.72 1.74 0.19 0.34 0.71 0.24 0.63 0.47 0.74 0.40 0.53 Engaged 0.24 0.89 0.07 0.79 0.14 0.82 0.03 0.86 -1.08 0.93 1.33 0.25 Caucasian -0.03 0.41 0.01 0.94 0.27 0.38 0.50 0.48 0.56 0.40 1.94 0.16 -0.07 0.57 0.02 0.90 -0.94 0.60 2.46 0.12 0.30 0.62 0.23 0.63 -1.98 1.22 2.66 0.10 -1.12 0.87 1.67 0.20 -1.73 1.09 2.54 0.11 0.07 0.38 0.03 0.86 -0.03 0.36 0.01 0.93 -0.35 0.39 0.79 0.37 Intercept Number of identities Requested loan amount (thousands) Initial interest rate AA African American Hispanic Children Reference categories for the predictors: for gender it is ―no gender‖, for marital status it is ―no marital status or widow‖, for race it is ―no race or race other than Caucasian, African American, or Hispanic‖, for credit grade it is HR. 38 Table WA-2. Loan performance as a function of identities (ERQ2). Paid is the reference category 2 Current Late Default 2 β SE χ (1) p β SE χ (1) P β SE χ2(1) p Intercept -3.29 0.91 12.92 0.00 -3.93 1.30 9.15 0.00 0.04 0.68 0.00 0.96 Trustworthy -0.32 0.28 1.35 0.24 -0.55 0.37 2.16 0.14 -0.50 0.21 5.51 0.02 Successful -0.43 0.31 1.92 0.17 -0.10 0.43 0.06 0.81 -0.38 0.25 2.41 0.12 Economic Hardship 0.90 0.30 9.15 0.00 0.69 0.39 3.10 0.08 0.66 0.26 6.54 0.01 Hardworking 0.13 0.28 0.21 0.64 -0.45 0.41 1.16 0.28 0.18 0.23 0.60 0.44 Moral -0.53 0.35 2.37 0.12 -0.62 0.50 1.54 0.21 0.19 0.27 0.53 0.47 Religious 0.49 0.52 0.88 0.35 0.01 0.76 0.00 0.99 0.43 0.47 0.86 0.35 Requested loan amount (thousands) 0.14 0.03 26.75 0.00 0.08 0.04 4.65 0.03 0.05 0.02 4.86 0.03 Initial interest rate 15.77 3.34 22.34 0.00 12.79 4.70 7.40 0.01 3.83 2.56 2.24 0.13 AA -2.17 0.77 7.96 0.00 -2.89 1.32 4.79 0.03 -1.00 0.52 3.62 0.06 A -1.17 0.70 2.80 0.09 -0.60 0.92 0.43 0.51 -0.22 0.50 0.20 0.66 B -0.65 0.58 1.26 0.26 -0.45 0.78 0.33 0.56 -0.26 0.46 0.31 0.58 C -0.88 0.49 3.18 0.07 -0.54 0.65 0.70 0.40 -0.26 0.42 0.38 0.54 D -0.87 0.45 3.82 0.05 -1.23 0.64 3.74 0.05 -0.53 0.40 1.72 0.19 E -0.53 0.45 1.37 0.24 -0.73 0.58 1.59 0.21 -0.04 0.43 0.01 0.92 Male -0.68 0.37 3.40 0.07 0.31 0.56 0.30 0.59 -0.39 0.28 1.89 0.17 Female -0.48 0.41 1.42 0.23 1.29 0.58 4.93 0.03 0.23 0.32 0.54 0.46 Married 0.51 0.35 2.11 0.15 0.29 0.46 0.40 0.53 -0.05 0.27 0.03 0.86 Divorced 0.88 0.65 1.86 0.17 1.16 0.72 2.57 0.11 0.38 0.58 0.42 0.52 Engaged 0.38 0.48 0.61 0.43 -0.53 0.75 0.49 0.49 -0.23 0.43 0.28 0.60 Single 1.43 0.72 3.91 0.05 1.25 0.94 1.76 0.18 1.26 0.60 4.43 0.04 Caucasian -0.54 0.30 3.10 0.08 -0.51 0.41 1.57 0.21 -0.25 0.24 1.11 0.29 African American -0.31 0.51 0.37 0.54 -0.14 0.62 0.05 0.83 -1.28 0.52 6.13 0.01 Hispanic -0.06 1.37 0.00 0.96 1.97 1.10 3.22 0.07 0.84 0.88 0.91 0.34 Children 0.34 0.30 1.24 0.26 0.30 0.40 0.59 0.44 0.23 0.25 0.81 0.37 Reference categories for the predictors: for identities it is ―no identities‖, for gender it is ―no gender‖, for marital status it is ―no marital status or widow‖, for race it is ―no race or race other than Caucasian, African America, or Hispanic‖, for credit grade it is HR. Percent funded over 500% 450-499% 400-449% 350-399% 300-349% 250-299% 200-249% 150-199% 100-149% 50-99% 0-49% 0 Number of listings 39 Figure WA-1 Distribution of loan funding percent 500 450 400 350 300 250 200 150 100 50 0 40 Figure WA-2. Distribution of percent reduction in interest rate (funded listings only) 300 250 Number of listings 200 150 100 50 0-5% 5-10% 10-15% 15-20% 20-25% 25-30% 30-35% Percent reduction in the final interest rate 35-40% over 40%
© Copyright 2024