ECONOMICS ECONOMICS EUROPE ASIA Subscribe Subscribe to to the the Bloomberg Brief at BRIEF<GO> Bloomberg Brief at BRIEF<GO> or or www.bloombergbriefs.com www.bloombergbriefs.com Prasad, Pettis Lock Horns on China Growth Prospects MICHAEL PETTIS, PEKING UNIVERSITY, AND ESWAR PRASAD, CORNELL UNIVERSITY As China enters the year of the goat, opinions on the state of the economy have seldom been so divided. Bloomberg Brief asked Michael Pettis and Eswar Prasad to lock horns in debate. The question: can China maintain GDP growth of about 6 percent to 7 percent for the next three years or is a further pronounced slowdown assured? The opening round of arguments appears on pages 1 and 2. Replies from Pettis and Prasad appear on pages 3 and 4. Michael Pettis is a professor at Peking University’s Guanghua School of Management and a senior associate at the Carnegie Endowment for International Peace. He is the author of Avoiding the Fall: China’s Economic Restructuring (ceip.org/JWogj1). Previously, he taught at Tsinghua University and at Columbia University’s Graduate School of Business. Eswar Prasad is the Tolani Senior Professor of Trade Policy at Cornell University and the author of The Dollar Trap: How the U.S. Dollar Tightened Its Grip on Global Finance (TheDollarTrap.com). He was formerly chief of the Financial Studies Division in the International Monetary Fund’s Research Department and, before that, was the head of the IMF’s China Division. MICHAEL PETTIS’S OPENING ARGUMENT: ESWAR PRASAD’S OPENING ARGUMENT: Destined to Fall Hopes for Stability The fundamental misunderstanding among economists about China’s growth prospects in the last decade, and indeed that of every country that has experienced a similar growth miracle, has always hinged on the role of debt. Highly pro-cyclical balance sheets work both ways, and if they boost growth during the growth acceleration period, they necessarily constrain it as growth decelerates. We’ve seen how it works beginning in the early 1990s, when Beijing put into place a financial system designed both to expand domestic funding by forcing up the national savings rate and to allocate credit as rapidly as possible into productive investment. The result was many years in which rapid expansion in the banking system reinforced and was reinforced by spectacular and highly unbalanced economic growth. Nearly 50 years ago, Albert Hirschman told us not to fear imbalances. All rapid growth is unbalanced, he explained, and imbalances always eventually reverse. The difficulty, however, is that vested interests develop around the institutions on which growth is based and oppose reform, making it very hard in most cases for the imbalances to adjust before they seriously distort the underlying economy. This is why most growth miracles ultimately fail. With investment growing at among the fastest rates in history, China eventually reached the limit of its productive ability to absorb continued credit growth at least 10-15 years ago. But when Beijing tried, in the middle of the last decade, to rebalance the economy, opposition from vested interests prevented reform, and credit continued pouring into wasteful investment. During this time, in other words, reported GDP grew faster than continued on next page Over the past year, growth has slowed significantly, producer prices continue to fall and various other indicators of economic activity show a loss of momentum in the economy. In short, the headline data do not look good. On the other hand, there has been some progress on growth rebalancing – the consumption to GDP ratio is up a tad, and the services sector’s share in the economy has continued to rise. So what does all this portend for the future of the Chinese economy? Separating the trend from the cycle, especially in real time, is a challenge in any economy and especially for a developing economy that is still undergoing massive structural change in many dimensions. As the economy matures and becomes richer both in terms of absolute size and per capita income, traditional convergence effects alone would dictate a slowdown in China’s growth. The concern that you have rightly emphasized, the high level of debt, is emblematic of the tensions inherent in China’s unbalanced and unsustainable growth model. The key issue where our analyses seem to differ is whether the required reforms and underlying growth dynamics will necessarily lead to growth falling significantly below 7 percent a year in the short term. On the positive side, there is clearly commitment to deal with problems, including the rapid accumulation of debt. Whether policy makers can do so without severely crimping growth, given the significant economic and political constraints to reforms, is the key question. The actions of the People’s Bank of China (PBOC) over the last year highlight the difficult tension the government faces. The PBOC has mainly relied on a variety of indirect measures to support economic activity rather than unleashing a rapid expancontinued on next page © 2015 Bloomberg LP. All rights reserved. These commentaries were originally published in Bloomberg Brief: Economics Asia, a daily newsletter, on March 3 and March 17, 2014. For more analysis and data, run ECON <GO> on the Bloomberg Professional Service. Take a trial to the Briefs at www.bloombergbriefs.com or run BRIEF<GO> ECONOMICS ASIA Subscribe to the Bloomberg Brief at BRIEF<GO> or www.bloombergbriefs.com MICHAEL PETTIS’S OPENING ARGUMENT… ESWAR PRASAD’S OPENING ARGUMENT… economic value creation. This was largely due to a significant share of growth occurring in the form of wasted investment, which was not sustainable since it meant debt was growing faster than debt-servicing capacity. Only because they failed to understand this, as late as 2012, most analysts expected GDP growth rates to continue at 9-10 percent for many years. President Xi Jinxing’s administration fully recognizes the problem and has vowed to rebalance demand and eliminate China’s debt addiction before it reaches debt capacity limits. But while they now understand the problem Beijing faces, the same analysts still do not understand the implications. If the gap between economic value creation and the cost of investment has not been correctly recognized on the national balance sheet, GDP growth was and continues to be overstated, and this must show up in the form of unrecognized bad debt. Beijing knows what to do. As the 2013 Third Plenum reforms are implemented, China’s economic growth will become healthier, but reported growth will continue to drop for several important reasons. For one, once Beijing has stopped the continued accumulation of bad debt, the gap between value creation and reported growth will largely disappear. As this happens, however, acceleration in value creation will not be matched by an equivalent acceleration in reported growth. Only if the reforms cause an extraordinary surge in real productivity growth will the convergence imply rising rates of GDP growth. Another reason for reported growth to continue to drop is the deteriorating viability and creditworthiness of Chinese borrowers. When a borrower’s ability to repay debt comes into question, uncertainty rises as to how the associated losses will ultimately be distributed – will the lender lose, or will the government step in and directly or indirectly force the losses onto taxpayers, savers, workers, local governments, businesses or other stakeholders? This uncertainty changes how stakeholders behave in ways that always reduce economic value. As debt continues to rise faster than debt-servicing capacity, this loss in value – which may already be happening and which is referred to in finance theory as financial distress – will rise. GDP growth in China has not bottomed out and consensus forecasts of 6-7 percent growth over the medium term will be disappointed largely because analysts have failed to incorporate the impact of debt in their analyses. Beijing has already taken important steps to address China’s imbalances, but China still has a way to go before credit growth converges with growth in debt-servicing capacity. Just as the structure of the balance sheet exacerbated growth during the acceleration phase, so will it exacerbate the slowdown during the deceleration phase. This has always been the historical pattern, and history suggests that as Beijing continues its reforms, reported GDP growth rates will continue to drop even as the country’s real economic performance begins to improve. sion of credit that could add to the existing problems. The irony, of course, is that this vitiates the objective of financial market reforms as it involves a state-determined allocation of resources. But at least the PBOC is trying to limit the damage and not throw in the towel by rolling back reforms. The government has not unleashed one weapon that could support growth in the short term and facilitate longer-term rebalancing – fiscal policy. China’s government budget deficit and explicit public debt levels remain low by international standards. Rather than accumulating more implicit debt through an increase in nonperforming assets in the banking system, it would make more sense for the government to use fiscal policy directly to support growth and also promote longer-term growth rebalancing by strengthening the social safety net. For instance, funding a more comprehensive catastrophic health insurance program might help restrain the savings of elderly households. A better safety net would reduce precautionary savings. Financial market reforms that generate higher returns on savings and allow for portfolio diversification, both domestically and abroad, may also reduce savings. Concerns about China’s high rates of investment in physical capital are warranted. But China still has a much lower capital-output ratio than do advanced economies such as the U.S. and still has vast needs for infrastructure in its interior provinces. The question is whether the allocation of domestic savings into domestic investment is being intermediated in an efficient manner that allocates capital to its most productive uses. The level of gross debt in China is very high. The fact that much of this debt accumulation is financed by China’s domestic savings suggests not so much a source of financial risk as of major inefficiencies and waste because of a broken system of allocating capital. The fact that the state owns most of the key creditors and debtors makes it less likely that a financial shock could set off a cascade that results in a financial crisis or a collapse in growth. While the Chinese leadership might know what to do, slowing momentum on domestic growth and a weak external environment have eroded political support and tightened economic space for reforms. Yet my reading is that the government remains committed to its agenda, although the pace and scope are certainly not at the level I would wish for. Thus, I concur with your view that the level of debt and its continued rise pose major challenges for China. But I am more optimistic that, if the government remains committed to reforms and can implement them at a reasonable pace, China can maintain growth at around 7 percent per year over the next two to three years. What happens in the longer term will depend to a great deal on what is done in the next few years to set the economy on the right course. continued from previous page continued from previous page Michael Pettis’s Main Arguments: Eswar Prasad’s Main Arguments: A significant part of China’s growth has come from wasteful investment. That’s not sustainable as debt has grown faster than debt servicing capacity. Fights over who faces the cost of bad loans will add to downward pressure. Government remains committed to its reform agenda. Low debt means Beijing can unleash fiscal policy to support growth and rebalancing. High domestic savings and state ownership limit the chance of financial crisis. © 2015 Bloomberg LP. All rights reserved. 2 Subscribe to the Bloomberg Brief at BRIEF<GO> ECONOMICS ASIA or www.bloombergbriefs.com Prasad, Pettis Lock Horns on China Growth Prospects (Round 2) MICHAEL PETTIS, PEKING UNIVERSITY, AND ESWAR PRASAD, CORNELL UNIVERSITY As China’s National People’s Congress rumbled to a close, Bloomberg Brief asked Michael Pettis and Eswar Prasad to resume their debate on the state of the Chinese economy. The question: can China maintain GDP growth of about 6 percent to 7 percent for the next three years or is a further pronounced slowdown assured? This exchange is the second and final round of the debate. MICHAEL PETTIS’S REPLY: ESWAR PRASAD’S REPLY: Hard Constraints Limit High Growth Resource Reallocation May Be the Key Given our many agreements some readers might conclude that we differ mainly because you are more optimistic than I am about Beijing’s commitment to reforms and its ability to implement them. I would argue that our disagreement is more fundamental. I do not doubt Beijing’s determination to reform. After living in China for 13 years, I have seen first-hand how intent policy makers have been to modernize China. I have long argued the rebalancing process was going to be difficult, and yet I believe that Xi Jinping’s administration has done as well as possible. The problem, as I see it, is a very different one. In my reading of development history, it hasn’t been the lack of intelligent reforms and determination that explains why every country that has experienced many years of investment-driven “miraculous” growth has had a very difficult adjustment in which GDP growth has dropped significantly. The problem has been the balance sheet constraints. Because of these constraints, and the debt dynamics they imply, GDP growth must drop sharply even as Beijing manages a substantial transfer of wealth from local governments to ordinary households. If Beijing can manage it so that the income growth of ordinary households drops minimally, perhaps to a very healthy 5-7 percent, GDP growth must be at least 2-3 percentage points lower if China is going to rebalance its economy meaningfully, which it must. And Beijing must pull this off while eliminating the balance sheet impact of many years when the economic value of investment was overstated. To put it differently, I think you would argue that if China’s growth drops to 3-4 percent or less, this would indicate that Beijing was insufficiently committed to the necessary reforms or unable to implement them efficiently. I, on the other hand, would argue that President Xi will have pulled off an extraordinary feat that few leaders have managed. Much higher growth rates in consumption and GDP for the rest of this decade, I would argue, are only possible if Beijing allows debt to grow out of control, in which case the higher growth rates would almost certainly be followed by a terrible “lost decade,” or if Beijing is able to transfer the equivalent of 3-4 percent of GDP from the state to Chinese households every year, which strikes me as highly implausible. There is another area that might also represent a fundamental disagreement between us. In your letter you say: “But China still has a much lower capital-output ratio than advanced economies such as the U.S. and still has vast needs for infrastructure in its interior provinces. The question is whether the allocation of domestic savings into domestic investment is being intermediated in an efficient continued on next page © 2015 Bloomberg LP. All rights reserved. You have set out the dichotomy in our views clearly and sharply. The central question is the following – can China maintain high growth in the next few years without a further massive expansion of credit and while undertaking economic reforms? My view is that reforms and rebalancing are compatible with maintaining growth at its present level of around 6-7 percent. Yours, as I understand it, is that these two sets of goals cannot be achieved simultaneously. Of course, we agree that high growth built on a shaky foundation of rapid credit expansion without reforms and rebalancing would be undesirable and risky. At heart, my argument is simple. There is substantial misallocation of resources in China, so economic and financial sector reforms that result in improved resource allocation can help China maintain growth in the government’s target range while promoting rebalancing. How is this possible? There are a number of inter-related strands underlying my argument, with the proviso that I fully recognize each of these represents a difficult but not insurmountable challenge. I will sketch these points here, leaving a detailed numerical analysis for another time. First, labor reallocation. A large pool of unutilized or underutilized labor, especially in rural areas, remains to be tapped and drawn into productive employment. This is one objective of the government’s urbanization program, although there may be better ways – involving less disruption and fewer congestion costs – of moving labor from unproductive sectors to more productive ones. This reallocation effect by itself can give a short-term boost to both GDP growth and productivity growth. Second, an increase in private consumption growth can become a more important driver of GDP growth. This will require economic changes that generate more employment and diminish households’ precautionary savings motives. In my research, I have found that a weak financial system (lack of diversification opportunities, inability to borrow against future income) and precautionary savings driven by an inadequate safety net have contributed to rising household saving rates. The ownership structures of many firms and their financing sources also create incentives for higher corporate savings (retained earnings) that are plowed back into investment, some of marginal value at best. Third, directing more financial resources to parts of the economy that are better at generating employment, especially the services sector and small and medium sized enterprises, could add to employment growth. This would have the added benefit of reducing the capital intensity of growth. continued on next page 3 Subscribe to the Bloomberg Brief at BRIEF<GO> ECONOMICS ASIA or www.bloombergbriefs.com MICHAEL PETTIS’S REPLY… ESWAR PRASAD’S REPLY… manner that allocates capital to its most productive uses.” I would say that there is a prior question. Are poor countries poor because their capital-output ratios are low, or are they poor because they are unable to absorb very high levels of capital productively? The former model implies that development is largely due to rising investment, whereas the latter model implies that advanced countries have different social, legal, financial and economic institutions and incentives that permit individuals and businesses to exploit capital more productively, and that development has more to do with acquiring these institutions. Obviously there is no way to resolve this question here, although elsewhere I have written about how much investment is optimal according to each of these models. The former model has been used to justify the ever-increasing amount of investment spending, but I think the latter informs Beijing policy makers as they focus on reforming the financial system, the legal and regulatory framework, education, and so on. This matters not just in the case of comparing capital-output ratios between China and the advanced economies but also between the various provinces in China. Two years ago the chief China economist at Standard Chartered proposed that simply bringing the poorest provinces in China to the same GDP per capita level of the richest could guarantee at least five more years of growth above 7 percent. This may be arithmetically true, but if differences in provincial GDP per capita were so easily explained, it leaves unexplained why the IMF found that even though they had lower levels of investment per capita, the return on investment in these inland provinces was lower than in the more developed coastal provinces. These are major issues that cannot be resolved within the limits of a short exchange of letters, but they point to an important difference between our views. You argue that China can manage to keep very high growth rates for many more years if Beijing continues to manage the economy as well as it has in the past. I argue that there are hard constraints that will make it almost impossible for China’s GDP growth rates to remain high unless credit grows even faster. This leaves us with radically different ways of evaluating the success of Beijing’s policies. Fourth, in the short run, fiscal policy can play a more effective role at supporting growth, creating fewer risks for the financial sector and promoting growth rebalancing (for instance, by strengthening the social safety net). In a nod to this, last week the government set a modestly higher deficit target for the coming fiscal year, although I would have liked to see that accompanied by more substantive changes in the composition of expenditures and the tax structure. Fifth, the rate of investment growth can be maintained at a high level if some of it is financed through alternative channels such as corporate bond markets. Moreover, even if investment growth declines by 1-2 percentage points, other components can make up for this. I agree with you that a cross-country comparison of capital-output ratios by itself is overly simplistic. Improvements in corporate governance, the financial regulatory framework, and legal reforms that underpin a market-oriented system are all essential for productive investment. President Xi has indicated that his government will push forward with reforms in these dimensions. Of course, one should have no illusion that they presage sweeping institutional, legal, or political reforms – Xi has made it abundantly clear that those are not on the cards. What will it take to generate the shifts in the economy I have laid out? A broader, more efficient, and better-regulated financial system is crucial to accomplish the different aspects of rebalancing I have set out above. A more flexible monetary policy framework that is not hampered by a tightly managed exchange rate regime and a more supportive fiscal framework have to be part of the package. Institutional reforms and the freer play of market forces in the enterprise sector are necessary as well. These are all major transitions, time is short, political opposition is strong, and the risks of stumbling are great. But I remain optimistic (or, at least, hopeful). So long as the government keeps moving in the right direction at a reasonable pace, the reforms and rebalancing can take place without the economy necessarily facing the sharp growth slowdown you envisage. To round up this year’s debate on a more harmonious note, we seem to concur that the Chinese government is committed to reforms. That, at least, is something positive and encouraging that we can agree upon! continued from previous page continued from previous page Michael Pettis’s Main Arguments: Eswar Prasad’s Main Arguments: Arithmetic of rebalancing means even if household income growth can be maintained at 5 percent to 7 percent, GDP growth must necessarily be lower. China’s limited institutional development makes it difficult to absorb large volumes of capital productively. GDP growth of 3 percent to 4 percent, combined with progress on rebalancing, would be a significant achievement. Improved resource allocation can maintain growth in the 6 percent to 7 percent range while promoting rebalancing. Underutilized rural labor and inefficient allocation of capital both represent opportunities to use reform to unlock new sources of growth. Progress will be tough, and require new arrangements for monetary and fiscal policy, as well as freer play of market forces in the enterprise sector. CURRENCY MOVES & Central Bank Policy Read it here. © 2015 Bloomberg LP. All rights reserved. 4
© Copyright 2024