Offshoring, Hicks-Neutral Productivity and Skill-Biased Technological Change Zhanar Akhmetova∗ Department of Economics, UNSW Business School, University of New South Wales Sydney, NSW 2052, Australia Shon Ferguson Research Institute of Industrial Economics (IFN) Grevgatan 34, SE-102 15 Stockholm, Sweden April 9, 2015 Abstract. The paper answers two questions simultaneously. What is the effect of offshoring on firms’ Hicks-neutral productivity? What is the effect of offshoring on skill-biased technological change? We estimate a model of firm production that allows for the effect of offshoring on both Hicks-neutral productivity and skill-biased productivity, and for spillovers between the two. The model is fitted to Swedish firmlevel data between 2001-2011. We find significant positive effects of offshoring on Hicks-neutral productivity in several manufacturing industries, and significant effects (positive and negative) of offshoring on skill-biased productivity in production and non-production activities in some industries. Strong support for the interdependency between Hicks-neutral productivity, skill-biased productivity in production activities ∗ Corresponding author. School of Economics, UNSW Business School, University of New South Wales, Sydney 2052 Australia. Email: [email protected]. 1 and skill-biased productivity in non-production activities emerges. Keywords: Offshoring, intermediate inputs, Hicks-neutral productivity, skill-biased technological change, relative skilled labor demand. JEL classification: D24, F14, F16. 1 Introduction Offshoring, that is subcontracting the production of some tasks and inputs by firms to overseas companies or subsidiaries, has intensified since the late 1980s. It has attracted considerable attention both in the media and in the academic literature, due to the observed or perceived effects of offshoring on wages and employment in both the origin and destination countries. In the media, offshoring has been blamed for the loss of jobs in developed countries and rising wage inequality, measured as the ratio of skilled to unskilled labor wages. In the academic literature, no consensus on the effects of offshoring has been reached so far (Gorg, 2011). Some theoretical models suggest that offshoring leads to lower employment of unskilled labor and rising wage inequality in developed countries (Feenstra and Hanson, 1995). Still others point to the possibility of enhanced firm productivity as a result of offshoring, and hence expansion in output and higher employment of all factors, as well as declining wage inequality in developed countries (Grossman and Rossi-Hansberg, 2008). To be more precise, there are at least two potential effects of offshoring. Industrialised countries offshore unskilled-labor-intensive parts of production, while skilled-labor- and capital-intensive tasks are kept at home. As a direct effect of this movement, demand for unskilled labor goes down, while the demand for skilled labor and capital increases. This can be called the relocation effect. It 2 also creates an upward pressure on the wages of skilled labor relative to unskilled labor. There is another possible consequence of offshoring, however, which is the rise in the productivity of offshoring firms, due to access to higher quality inputs and the reorganisation of their production process. As a result, total output of these firms may expand, leading to higher employment of both skilled and unskilled labor. This is the so-called scale effect. Moreover, if unskilled labor productivity increases the most due to offshoring, the wage of skilled labor relative to unskilled labor may fall, i.e. wage inequality may decrease. In this paper we will concern ourselves with a very specific definition of offshoring, namely, importing intermediate inputs from abroad. This measure is convenient as it is easily computed from firm-level production and trade data, and it has been widely used in the literature (Gorg et al. (2008), Yasar and Morison Paul (2006), Andersson et al. (2008), among others). The questions that we tackle are two-fold. First, we would like to study the effect of offshoring on firms’ Hicks-neutral productivity. Higher Hicks-neutral productivity will translate into higher production and total employment levels, and is beneficial for everyone’s welfare. Second, we are interested in the effect of offshoring on skill-biased technological change. If offshoring leads to improvements in (relative) skill-specific productivity, then it also implies an increase in relative skilled labour demand, which contributes to higher wage inequality. Many papers have addressed either of these issues individually. Particularly, Kasahara and Rodrigue (2008) study the effect of offshoring on Hicks-neutral productivity using Chilean data, and Kasahara et al. (2013) investigate the effect of offshoring on relative skilled labour demand using Indonesian data. To the best of our knowledge, we are the first to consider these two issues in a single framework. Estimating one of the two types of productivity (Hicks-neutral and skilled-labor-specific) is impossible without estimating the other. At the same time, correctly estimating either in the presence of potential effects of offshoring requires incorporating this hypothetical link into the estimation procedure. Moreover, we claim that changes in one can lead to 3 changes in another, and this should be taken into account when estimating these productivities, as well. In what follows, we consider a model that allows for all of the above interdependencies, and fit it to Swedish firm-level data between 2001-2011. We find significant positive effects of offshoring on Hicks-neutral productivity in three out of 16 manufacturing industries (Basic Metals, Machinery and equipment n.e.c., and Other transport equipment (transport equipment other than motor vehicles, trailers and semi-trailers)). Offshoring leads to unskilled labour biased technological change in production activities in one sector (Food products, beverages & tobacco), and to skilled labour biased technological change in production activities in one industry (Printing and reproduction of recorded media). Offshoring leads to skill-biased technological improvements in non-production activities in three sectors (Wood and products of wood and cork, Rubber and plastics products, and Motor vehicles, trailers and semi-trailers). Moreover, we find significant spillovers between Hicks-neutral productivity, skillbiased productivity in production activities and skill-biased productivity in nonproduction activities. This emphasises the importance of estimating these jointly and allowing for these links in the estimation procedure. The rest of the paper is organised as follows. Section 2 lays out the theoretical model, Section 3 discusses the data, and Section 4 presents the results. Section 5 concludes. 2 Theoretical Framework We carry out TFP estimation for each industry separately. We extend the theoretical framework of Kasahara et al. (2013), who consider the following Cobb-Douglas production function with embedded CES aggregator functions: Yit = Qit euit , 4 α p n Qit = Lp,it Lαn,it Kitαk eωit , where i indexes firms in a given industry, and t indexes time (years in our case), Y is the value added, that is, gross output net of intermediate components and raw materials, Lp , Ln , K are inputs - production labor, non-production labor, and capital, respectively, ωit is an unobserved Hicks-neutral productivity coefficient, uit is an error term, representing shocks to production or productivity that are not observable (or predictable) by firms before making their input decisions at t. We deal with a value added production function, which requires an implicit assumption that the intermediate inputs are a fixed proportion of the gross physical output (M = mY , where M is the intermediate inputs quantity, Y is gross physical output, and m is a positive real number). Moreover, production and non-production labor are composites of skilled and unskilled labor units: Lp,it = ((Ap,it Lsp,it ) Ln,it = ((An,it Lsn,it ) σp −1 σp + (Lup,it ) σn −1 σn σp −1 σp + (Lun,it ) σp ) σp −1 , σn −1 σn σn ) σn −1 , where Lsp and Lup is the number of units of skilled and unskilled labor employed in production, respectively, and Lsn and Lun is the number of units of skilled and unskilled labor employed in non-production activities, respectively. The constants Ap,it ∈ R+ and An,it ∈ R+ are the skilled-labor-biased productivity coefficients in production and non-production activities of firm i in year t, respectively, and an increase in Ap (An ) reflects skill-biased technological progress in production (non-production) activities. The first-order conditions of the firm’s profit maximisation problem with respect to Lsj,it , Luj,it , j = p, n, are given by u u Wj,t Lj,it = αj Qit s s Wj,t Lj,it = αj Qit (Luj,it ) (Aj,it Lsj,it ) σj −1 σj σj −1 σj + (Aj,it Lsj,it ) (Aj,it Lsj,it ) 5 σj −1 σj + (Luj,it ) σj −1 σj , σj −1 σj (Luj,it ) σj −1 σj , which gives us σ −1 j s Luj,it 1 Wj,t σ ( s ) σj Aj,itj = u , Lj,it Wj,t for j = p, n, (1) s u where Wp,t and Wp,t are the wages of skilled and unskilled labor in year t in production, u s are the wages of skilled and unskilled labor in year t and Wn,t respectively, and Wn,t in non-production activities, respectively. Substituting (1) into the expressions for Lp,it and Ln,it , we obtain −σ Lj,it = Xj,it σj j −1 Luj,it , where Xj,it ≡ u u Wj,t Lj,it , s s u u Wj,t Lj,it + Wj,t Lj,it for j = p, n. Substituting these equations into the production function and taking the logarithm results in u u yit = αk kit + αp lp,it + βp xp,it + αn ln,it + βn xn,it + ωit + uit , (2) where the lower case letters denote the logarithms of the upper case variables (e.g. σ α yit ≡ ln Yit ), and βj ≡ − σjj−1j , for j = p, n. Taking the logarithm of equation (1), we can also get rj,it = σj sj,t − (σj − 1) ln Aj,it , Lu (3) Ws where rj,it ≡ ln( Lsj,it ), and sj,t ≡ ln Wjtu . j,it jt We propose the following dynamics for the Hicks-neutral productivity term ω: 2 3 ωit = ξt + γ1 ωi(t−1) + γ2 ωi(t−1) + γ3 ωi(t−1) + γ4 of fi(t−1) + γ5 expi(t−1) + γ6 ln Ap,i(t−1) + γ7 ln An,i(t−1) + νit , (4) Mf where ξt is an industry-specific Hicks-neutral productivity shock, of fit ≡ ln(1 + Mitit ), offshoring intensity of firm i in year t, where Mitf is the quantity of intermediate inputs imported from abroad, and Mit is the total quantity of intermediate inputs used in production, expit is a dummy equal to 1 if firm i exports in year t, and 0 otherwise, and νit is a firm-specific zero-mean shock to ω in year t, which is unforeseen before year t and is independent of ξt . 6 We also propose the following dynamics for the skill-biased technological terms Ap,it and An,it : ln Ap,it = ζp,t + θp,1 ln Ap,i(t−1) + θp,2 ln A2p,i(t−1) + θp,3 ln A3p,i(t−1) + θp,4 of fi(t−1) + θp,5 expi(t−1) + θp,6 ωi(t−1) + θp,7 ln An,i(t−1) + ηp,it , (5) ln An,it = ζn,t + θn,1 ln An,i(t−1) + θn,2 ln A2n,i(t−1) + θn,3 ln A3n,i(t−1) + θn,4 of fi(t−1) + θn,5 expi(t−1) + θn,6 ωi(t−1) + θn,7 ln Ap,i(t−1) + ηn,it , (6) where ζp,t and ζn,t are industry-specific skill-biased productivity shocks, ηp,it and ηn,it are firm-specific zero-mean shocks to ln Ap,it and ln An,it , respectively, which are unforeseen before year t and are independent of ζp,t and ζn,t , respectively. We assume therefore that changes in Hicks-neutral productivity can affect future direction of skill-biased technological progress in production and non-production activities, and that skill-biased technological progress in production and non-production activities can affect future values of Hicks-neutral productivity of the firm. This dynamic interaction necessitates joint estimation of ω and ln Ap , ln An . We do this by jointly fitting equations (2) and (3), as well as (4) and (5), (6) to the data. We incorporate the ACF (Ackerberg, Caves and Frazer (2006)) critique of the Levinsohn and Petrin (2003) and Olley and Pakes (1996) estimation approaches, and estimate all production coefficients in the second stage of our estimation. The first stage consists of relying on the equation for the optimal choice of intermediate inputs (in logs) mit = mt (ωit , kit ), to invert: ωit ≡ ψt (mit , kit ), assuming monotonicity in the function mt (.). Current capital input kit is set at t − 1, as it depends on past capital ki(t−1) and investment at time t − 1. Inserting this into 7 the expression for value added: u u yit = αk kit + αp lp,it + βp xp,it + αn ln,it + βn xn,it + ψt (mit , kit ) + uit , It is evident from the above that the coefficient αk is not identified, since kit appears in ψ(mit , kit ), and the coefficients αp , αn are not identified, since the optimal u u choice of lp,it and ln,it likely depends on ωit ≡ ψt (mit , kit ). We can however estimate the residual uit by fitting the regression equation u u yit ≡ αp lp,it + βp xp,it + αn ln,it + βn xn,it + Ψt (mit , kit ) + uit , where Ψt (mit , kit ) is a polynomial in capital and intermediate inputs, one for each year: Ψt (mit , kit ) ≡ T X b0t Dt + t=1 + + + T X t=1 T X t=1 T X T X b1mt Dt mit + t=1 T X b1kt Dt kit t=1 b2mkt Dt kit mit + T X b2mmt Dt m2it + t=1 T X b3kkmt Dt kit2 mit + T X b2kkt Dt kit2 t=1 b3kmmt Dt kit m2it t=1 b3kkkt Dt kit3 + t=1 T X b3mmmt Dt m3it , t=1 where Dt are year dummies. Using the obtained estimates, we can purge yit of the error term uit : yˆit ≡ yit − uˆit . In the second stage we apply GMM to estimate αk , αp , αn , σp , σn . For given values σ α of αk , αp , αn , σp , σn , one can calculate βj ≡ − σjj−1j , for j = p, n. Next, calculate ωit from u u ωit = yˆit − αk kit − αp lp,it − βp xp,it − αn ln,it − βn xn,it , and ln Aj,it = σj 1 sj,t − rj,it , σj − 1 σj − 1 8 from (3). We would like to estimate the residual νit by running the regression (4). However, this equation is subject to a selection bias, since we only observe firms with high enough productivity to stay active. That is, a firm i produces in year t if and only if ωit ≥ ω t (kt ), where ω t (kt ) is a threshold below which firms exit in year t, which depends on the (log-)capital stock of the firm in year t and industry-level demand and cost considerations (hence the subscript t). We rely on the Heckman correction to tackle this issue. Since ωit can be predicted using ωi(t−1) (from (4)), which we expressed as ω(i−1)t ≡ ψt−1 (mi(t−1) , ki(t−1) ), and kt is predetermined by ki(t−1) and investment in year t, it(i−1) , we can employ these variables to predict firm survival probabilities. We also use lagged offshoring intensity of fi(t−1) , since we assume that it affects the firm’s current productivity ωit : P rob(Sit = 1) = T X 2 δt Dt + δk ki(t−1) + δm mi(t−1) + δi ii(t−1) + δkk ki(t−1) + δmm m2i(t−1) t=1 + δii i2i(t−1) + δmk mi(t−1) ki(t−1) + δik ii(t−1) ki(t−1) + δof f of fi(t−1) ≡ Xδ, (7) where Sit is a dummy variable equal to 1 if the firm survives in year t and 0 otherwise, and Dt are year dummies. In the data we treat all the years between the first time and the last time the firm is observed producing as the years when it survives, and the year after the last year the firm is observed producing as the year it exits production. X ≡ 2 [D1 , ..., DT , ki(t−1) , mi(t−1) , ii(t−1) , ki(t−1) , m2i(t−1) , i2i(t−1) , mi(t−1) ki(t−1) , ii(t−1) ki(t−1) , of fi(t−1) ], and δ ≡ [δ1 , ..., δT , δk , δm , δi , δkk , δmm , δii , δmk , δik , δof f ]0 . Once we fit equation (7), we can calculate the non-selection hazard ratio, or the inverse Mills ratio, for each observation point, as ˆ = nsh(X δ) 9 ˆ φ(X δ) , ˆ Φ(X δ) where φ denotes the probability density function of the standard normal distribution, and Φ - its cumulative distribution function. We then include the non-selection hazard ratio as an additional explanatory variable in the regression for ω: 2 3 ωit = ξt + γ1 ωi(t−1) + γ2 ωi(t−1) + γ3 ωi(t−1) ˆ + νit , + γ4 of fi(t−1) + γ5 expi(t−1) + γ6 ln Ap,i(t−1) + γ7 ln An,i(t−1) + γ8 nsh(X δ) (8) Estimate the residual νit by running the regression (8) and setting 2 3 νit = ωit − ξˆt − γˆ1 ωi(t−1) − γˆ2 ωi(t−1) − γˆ3 ωi(t−1) ˆ − γˆ4 of fi(t−1) − γˆ5 expi(t−1) − γˆ6 ln Ap,i(t−1) − γˆ7 ln An,i(t−1) − γˆ8 nsh(X δ), and estimate the residuals ηp,it , ηn,it by running the regressions (5), (6) and setting ηp,it = ln Ap,it − ζˆp,t − θˆp,1 ln Ap,i(t−1) − θˆp,2 ln A2p,i(t−1) − θˆp,3 ln A3p,i(t−1) − θˆp,4 of fi(t−1) − θˆp,5 expi(t−1) − θˆp,6 ωi(t−1) − θˆp,7 ln An,i(t−1) , ηn,it = ln An,it − ζˆn,t − θˆn,1 ln An,i(t−1) − θˆn,2 ln A2n,i(t−1) − θˆn,3 ln A3n,i(t−1) − θˆn,4 of fi(t−1) − θˆn,5 expi(t−1) − θˆn,6 ωi(t−1) − θˆn,7 ln Ap,i(t−1) . Use the moments E[νit (αk , αp , αn , σp , σn )kit ] = 0, u E[νit (αk , αp , αn , σp , σn )lp,i(t−1) ] = 0, E[νit (αk , αp , αn , σp , σn )xp,i(t−1) ] = 0, u E[νit (αk , αp , αn , σp , σn )ln,i(t−1) ] = 0, E[νit (αk , αp , αn , σp , σn )xn,i(t−1) ] = 0, E[ηp,it (αk , αp , αn , σp , σn )rp,i(t−1) ] = 0, E[ηn,it (αk , αp , αn , σp , σn )rn,i(t−1) ] = 0, 10 to identify the parameters αk , αp , αn , σp , σn . Since we have 7 moments to estimate 5 parameters, we conduct the test for over-identifying restrictions, which allows us to check whether the moment conditions match the data well or not. α ˆp ˆ α ˆn Given estimates α ˆk , α ˆp, α ˆn, σ ˆp , σ ˆn , and βˆp ≡ − σˆσˆpp−1 , βn ≡ − σσˆˆnn−1 , the estimate of Hicks-neutral productivity ω, is given by u u ω cit = yˆit − α ˆ k kit − α ˆ p lp,it − βˆp xp,it − α ˆ n ln,it − βˆn xn,it , and the estimates of skill-biased productivity terms ln Ap and ln An are given by lnd Aj,it = σ ˆj 1 sj,t − rj,it . σ ˆj − 1 σ ˆj − 1 We can then investigate the relationship between offshoring and firm productivity through the regressions 2 3 ω cit = ξt + γ1 ωd i(t−1) + γ2 ωd i(t−1) + γ3 ωd i(t−1) d ˆ + γ4 of fi(t−1) + γ5 expi(t−1) + γ6 ln Ad p,i(t−1) + γ7 ln An,i(t−1) + γ8 nsh(X δ) + νit , (9) and d 2 d 3 lnd Ap,it = ζp,t + θp,1 ln Ad p,i(t−1) + θp,2 ln Ap,i(t−1) + θp,3 ln Ap,i(t−1) d + θp,4 of fi(t−1) + θp,5 expi(t−1) + θp,6 ωd i(t−1) + θp,7 ln An,i(t−1) + ηp,it , (10) d 2 d 3 lnd An,it = ζn,t + θn,1 ln Ad n,i(t−1) + θn,2 ln An,i(t−1) + θn,3 ln An,i(t−1) d + θn,4 of fi(t−1) + θn,5 expi(t−1) + θn,6 ωd i(t−1) + θn,7 ln Ap,i(t−1) + ηn,it . (11) Studying the effect of offshoring on the skill-biased productivity terms ln Ap and ln An directly gives us the effect of offshoring on relative skilled-labor demand, since rp,it Lup,it ≡ ln( s ) = σp sp,t − (σp − 1) ln Ap,it , Lp,it rn,it Lun,it ≡ ln( s ) = σn sn,t − (σn − 1) ln An,it , Ln,it 11 from (3). Hence, if offshoring has a positive effect on ln Ap (ln An ), this implies that it has a negative effect on relative unskilled-labor demand, and a positive effect on relative skilled-labor demand in production (non-production) activities, ceteris paribus. 3 Data and Descriptive Statistics The data is obtained from the Swedish Survey of Manufacturers conducted by Statistics Sweden, the Swedish government’s statistical agency. The survey covers all firms within manufacturing (2-digit NACE Rev.2 codes 15-32) with 10 or more employees. We use data for the period 2001-2011, which is when data on the occupation of workers employed by Swedish firms is available. The survey contains information on value-added, intermediate inputs, capital stock, investment and the number of employees at the firm level. We merge the firm-level data with the employee data. The employee data contains information on their level of education and their occupation. We define workers as ‘high-skilled’ if they have some high-school education, and ‘low-skilled’ otherwise. Occupation is defined according to the Swedish Standard Classification of Occupations (SSYK). We define ‘non-production’ workers as workers with occupation codes 1-5 (managers, professionals, technicians, clerks and service workers). We define ‘production’ workers as workers with occupation codes 6-9 (agricultural and fishery workers, craft and related trades workers, plant and machine operators and assemblers and elementary occupations). We define intermediate inputs as inputs that are transformed by the firm. These include raw materials1 . Our measure of intermediate inputs thus does not include goods that are sold onward without any modification. We define capital as tangible assets, which includes buildings, land and equipment. We calculate capital using 1 In the dataset, we observe a variable that incorporates both intermediate components and raw materials, and we do not observe these separately. 12 the perpetual inventory method. Capital for year t equals the capital in year t − 1 plus investment in year t, depreciating capital using Hulten and Wykoff’s (1981) depreciation rates for buildings (0.0361) and equipment (0.1179). We deflate value-added, capital and intermediate inputs using data available from Statistics Sweden and follow the EUKLEMS methodology to construct the deflators. 2 . The level of industry aggregation for the deflators appears in Table 1. The deflators are available at the 2-digit industry level for most industries, but in some cases 2-digit industries are aggregated due to a lack of observations. We calculate TFP using the level of industry aggregation given in Table 1.3 We merge the firm-level data with customs data on imports. Our measure of offshoring is offshoring intensity - the ratio of the quantity of imported intermediate Mf inputs to total intermediate inputs, or more precisely, ln of fit ≡ ln(1 + Mitit ).4 We define imports as intermediate inputs if they correspond to ‘Industrial supplies not elsewhere specified’ or ‘Fuels and lubricants’, using the Classification by Broad Economic Categories (BEC), revision 4. We match our trade data (Combined Nomenclature) to the BEC classification using a concordance provided by Eurostat. The descriptive statistics in Table 2 indicate a large degree of heterogeneity among Swedish firms in terms of value-added, capital, employment and materials. 2 3 EUKLEMS does not report Swedish NACE rev.2 deflators for materials and capital. We omit ‘Coke and refined petroleum products’ (NACE rev.2 19) from the analysis due to a lack of observations. 4 We introduce the 1 in the definition to allow firms with no offshoring to enter our dataset. 13 Table 1: Industry classification Industry NACE Revision 2 Description 10-12 Food products, beverages and tobacco 13-15 Textiles, wearing apparel, leather and related products 16 Wood and products of wood and cork 17 Paper and paper products 18 Printing and reproduction of recorded media 20-21 Chemicals and chemical products 22 Rubber and plastics products 23 Other non-metallic mineral products 24 Basic metals 25 Fabricated metal products, except machinery and equip. 26 Computer, electronic and optical equip. 27 Electrical equip. 28 Machinery and equip. n.e.c. 29 Motor vehicles, trailers and semi-trailers 30 Other transport equip. 31-32 Furniture, other manufacturing Table 2: Descriptive statistics Variable N mean std. dev. min max Value-added (SEK thousands) 52,141 3.579e+07 2.324e+08 707.4 2.549e+10 Capital (SEK thousands) 52,141 306,404 1.557e+06 0.497 5.645e+07 Low-skilled labour (employees) 52,141 48.16 204.0 0.00145 18,611 High-skilled labour (employees) 52,141 11.12 78.75 7.64e-05 6,595 Materials (SEK thousands) 52,141 5.656e+07 3.054e+08 1,994 1.722e+10 Non-production labour (employees) 39,156 19.79 112.6 0 7,928 Production labour (employees) 39,156 37.93 201.0 0 18,200 14 4 Results In Table (3) we present the estimates of the parameters αk , αp , αn , σp , σn . All sectors, other than ‘Furniture, other manufacturing’ satisfy the test for over-identifying restrictions at 5% confidence level, while the sector ‘Furniture, other manufacturing’ satisfies this test at 10% confidence level. In Table (4) we test the crucial assumption that intermediate inputs are a monotonic function of firm Hicks-neutral productivity by regressing mit on ωit and kit , over all firms and all years. Since we are dealing with estimates of ωit , we rely on bootstrapped standard errors for significance tests. We include industry-year fixed effects in the regression to control for industry-level time-varying variables. Both ωit and kit have significant positive coefficients, and a 1% increase in ωit is associated with a 1.72% increase in intermediate inputs use. We also regress offshoring intensity on ωit , kit , ln Ap,it and ln An,it , over all firms and all years, in Table (5). Both ωit and kit have significant positive coefficients, while ln Ap,it has a statistically significant, but economically insignificant, negative coefficient. The R2 of this regression is also quite small, at only 0.171, which suggests some explanatory variables are missing. In what follows we present the results of regressions (9), (10), and (11). We normalise ωit , ln Ap,it and ln An,it by subtracting the log of the industry-wide mean of the firm-averages of ωit , ln Ap,it and ln An,it , respectively. For each of these three regressions, we first present the results for a pooled regression over all industries, with industry-year fixed effects. Next, results for industry-specific regressions, with year-fixed effects, are shown. All standard errors are bootstrapped. 15 Table 3: Estimated parameters. Industry αk αp αn σp σn Food products, beverages & tobacco .2609581 .4911126 .391406 1.128439 1.67804 Textiles, wearing apparel, leather & r.p. .3260372 .3791375 .1519337 1.165775 2.259352 Wood & products of wood and cork .2366288 .3939885 .3372445 1.08367 1.359775 Paper and paper products .3244185 .24625 .470887 1.159046 2.346776 Printing and reprod. of recorded media .1203349 .4893677 .6032252 1.076156 1.373085 Chemicals and chemical products .3495868 .2032533 .5338477 2.277436 6.447295 Rubber and plastics products .2385715 .3752728 .337668 1.206993 2.019283 Other non-metallic mineral products .3438172 .2690409 .4669266 1.104144 1.902186 Basic metals .2469986 .3840903 .3812921 1.153433 2.358303 Fab. metal products, exc. mach. & equip. .14636 .3903397 .3625153 1.153083 1.515414 Computer, electronic and optical equip. .1084342 .2893059 .6455436 1.764767 4.783109 Electrical equip. .1938643 .272957 .5750953 1.218866 4.2536 Machinery and equip. n.e.c. .1977321 .4608776 .4556512 1.12464 2.229365 Motor vehicles, trailers & semi-trailers .1055057 .3356779 .5791256 1.062893 3.656644 Other transport equip. .0431014 .6570168 .4448475 3.743433 2.935108 Furniture, other manufacturing .2605653 .3520406 .4561782 1.126869 1.799166 16 Table 4: The regression for intermediate inputs Dependent variable: firm-level intermediate inputs mit ωit 1.720 (0.039)*** kit 0.839 (0.004)*** Constant 3.246 (0.071)*** Observations 24896 R2 0.716 Industry-year fixed effects are included Bootstrapped standard errors in parentheses * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01 17 Table 5: The regression for offshoring intensity Dependent variable: firm-level offshoring intensity ln of fit ωit 0.009 (0.001)*** kit 0.005 (0.000)*** ln Ap,it -0.000 (0.000)*** ln An,it 0.000 (0.000) Constant -0.078 (0.004)*** Observations 24321 R2 0.171 Industry-year fixed effects are included Bootstrapped standard errors in parentheses * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01 18 4.1 The effect of offshoring on Hicks-neutral productivity In Table (6), we investigate the relationship between offshoring and firms’ Hicksneutral productivity, by estimating equation (9) over all industries jointly. Neither lagged offshoring intensity nor the lagged exporting dummy have significant coefficients. The lagged linear, quadratic and cubic ω terms have significant coefficients, supporting the hypothesised AR(1) structure of the dynamics of ω. None of the lagged skill-biased productivity terms in production and non-production activities have significant coefficients. Next, we estimate equation (9) for each industry individually, and show the results in Table (7). Lagged offshoring intensity has a positive effect in three industries: Basic Metals, Machinery and equipment n.e.c., and Other transport equipment (transport equipment other than motor vehicles, trailers and semi-trailers). It has the largest effect in the Other transport equip industry, where a 5% increase in the measure of offshoring intensity we introduced (1 + f Mit ) Mit results in a nearly 7% increase in the Hicks-neutral productivity. The lagged exporting dummy has a positive significant coefficient in three industries, confirming the hypothesis in the international trade literature that exporting has a favourable effect on firms’ productivity. The lagged skill-biased productivity terms in production and non-production activities, ln Ap,i(t−1) and ln An,i(t−1) have significant positive coefficients in some industries, and significant negative coefficients in some others. Notably, they both have negative coefficients in two sectors, Food products, beverages & tobacco and Machinery and equip. n.e.c., and positive or insignificant coefficients in all other sectors. This finding (a negative effect of lagged skill-biased technological change on Hicksneutral productivity) has to be explained. It could be the case that resources are diverted from innovation that contributes to Hicks-neutral efficiency to innovation that contributes to skill-biased technological advances. The positive effect of lagged skill-biased progress is probably explained by spillovers between the innovation pro19 cesses within the firm, and by higher productivity of engineers and innovators within the firm as a result of skill-biased technological improvement, which in turn translates into higher Hicks-neutral productivity. 4.2 The effect of offshoring on skill-biased productivity in production activities In Table (8), the results of estimating equation (10) over all industries jointly are presented. Neither lagged offshoring intensity nor exporting seem to have a significant effect on skill-biased productivity in production activities. The lagged linear, quadratic and cubic ln Ap terms have significant coefficients. Both lagged Hicksneutral productivity and lagged skill-biased productivity in non-production activities have positive significant coefficients. A 1% increase in Hicks-neutral productivity is associated with a 0.189% percent increase in skill-biased productivity in production, while a 1% increase in skill-biased productivity in non-production activities - with a 0.101% increase. Next, we study equation (10) for each industry individually. In Food products, beverages & tobacco, lagged offshoring intensity has a negative significant coefficient. This suggests that offshoring induces unskilled-labour-biased technological improvements in this industry, which translates into rising relative unskilled labor demand.5 5 Note that the model can be seen as isomorphic to the following model. α ˜ pL ˜ αn αk ω˜ it , Qit = L p,it n,it Kit e Yit = Qit euit , s ˜ p,it = ((Bp,it L Lsp,it ) σp −1 σp u +(Bp,it Lup,it ) σp −1 σp σp s ˜ n,it = ((Bn,it L Lsn,it ) ) σp −1 , σn −1 σn u +(Bn,it Lun,it ) σn −1 σn σn ) σn −1 , s s where the constants Bp,it ∈ R+ and Bn,it ∈ R+ are the skilled-labor-specific productivity coefficients in production and non-production activities of firm i in year t, respectively, and the constants u u Bp,it ∈ R+ and Bn,it ∈ R+ are the unskilled-labor-specific productivity coefficients in production and non-production activities of firm i in year t, respectively. Transform the above two equations: u ˜ p,it = Bp,it L ((Ap,it Lsp,it ) σp −1 σp +(Lup,it ) σp −1 σp σp u ˜ n,it = Bn,it L ((An,it Lsn,it ) ) σp −1 , 20 σn −1 σn +(Lun,it ) σn −1 σn σn ) σn −1 , In the ‘Printing and reproduction of recorded media’ industry, offshoring has a significant positive coefficient, and a 1% increase in lagged offshoring intensity there is associated with a 17.332% percent increase in skill-biased productivity in production. This translates into rising skilled-labor demand in production activities. Lagged exporting dummy has a significant coefficient in only one industry. In Motor vehicles, trailers and semi-trailers exporting seems to have a positive effect on unskilled-labour-biased productivity. Lagged Hicks-neutral productivity has a positive significant coefficient in Textiles, wearing apparel, leather and related products. Lagged skill-biased productivity in non-production activities has positive significant coefficients in Food products, beverages and tobacco, Wood and products of wood and cork, Paper and paper products, Chemicals and chemical products, Rubber and plastics products, Fabricated metal products, except machinery and equipment, Computer, electronic and optical equipment, Machinery and equip. n.e.c., and Furniture and other manufacturing. This suggests spillovers in skill-biased innovation processes from non-production to production activities in these sectors. 4.3 The effect of offshoring on skill-biased productivity in non-production activities In Table (10), the results of estimating equation (11) over all industries jointly are presented. Lagged offshoring intensity has a strongly significant positive coefficient, where a 1% increase in offshoring intensity results in a 0.094% percent increase in where Ap,it ≡ s Bp,it , u Bp,it An,it ≡ s Bn,it u Bn,it are the skill-biased productivity terms. Then α αk ωit p n Qit = Lp,it Lα , n,it Kit e where Lp,it ≡ ˜ p,it L , u Bp,it Ln,it ≡ ˜ n,it L u Bn,it u u and eωit ≡ eω˜ it (Bp,it )αp (Bn,it )αn . We cannot identify separately u u ω ˜ it , Bp,it or Bn,it , and can only identify ωit , and Ap,it , An,it . Increases in Ap,it , An,it signal increases in (relative) skill-biased productivity terms s Bp,it Bs , Bn,it , u u Bp,it n,it 21 that is, skill-biased technological change. skill-biased productivity in non-production activities. Lagged exporting dummy also has a positive significant coefficient. The lagged linear and quadratic ln An terms have significant coefficients. Both lagged Hicks-neutral productivity and lagged skillbiased productivity in production activities have positive significant coefficients. A 1% increase in Hicks-neutral productivity is associated with a 0.107% percent increase in skill-biased productivity in production, while a 1% increase in skill-biased productivity in production activities - with a 0.008% increase. Next, we investigate equation (11) for each industry individually. Lagged offshoring intensity has significant positive coefficients in Wood and products of wood and cork, Rubber and plastics products, and Motor vehicles, trailers and semi-trailers. These coefficients are also economically significant, with the percentage effects of a 1% increase in offshoring intensity ranging from 0.330 to 0.815. Lagged exporting dummy has a significant positive coefficient in 12 out of 14 industries, suggesting a statistically significant effect of exporting on relative skilled labour demand in non-production activities in these sectors. Lagged Hicks-neutral productivity seems to have a significant effect on current skill-biased productivity in non-production occupations in three industries: Wood and products of wood and cork, Fabricated metal products, except machinery and equipment, and Computer, electronic and optical equipment. Lagged skill-biased productivity in production has a positive effect on skill-biased productivity in non-production activities in 13 out of 16 sectors. This confirms the strong spillovers in skill-biased technological progress between production and nonproduction activities. 22 Table 6: Estimating equation (9) Dependent variable: firm-level Hicks-neutral productivity ωit ln of fi(t−1) 0.024 (0.019) expi(t−1) -0.003 (0.003) ωi(t−1) 0.800 (0.009)*** ωi(t−1) 2 0.036 (0.020)* ωi(t−1) 3 -0.092 (0.018)*** ln Ap,i(t−1) -0.000 (0.000) ln An,i(t−1) -0.000 (0.001) nshit 0.053 (0.035) Constant 0.025 (0.004)*** Observations 17577 R2 0.757 Industry-year fixed effects are included Bootstrapped standard errors in parentheses * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01 23 Table 7: The effect of offshoring on Hicks-neutral productivity, 2001-2011 Panel A Industry ln of fi(t−1) expi(t−1) ωi(t−1) 2 ωi(t−1) 3 ωi(t−1) ln Ap,i(t−1) ln An,i(t−1) nsh Constant 10-12 13-15 16 17 18 20-21 22 23 Food Textiles Wood Paper Print. Chem. Rubber Nonmet. 0.177 -0.096 0.033 -0.015 0.329 0.007 0.045 -0.066 (0.395) (0.654) (0.068) (0.091) (0.810) (0.027) (0.156) (0.041) -0.012 0.069 0.025 0.003 -0.006 0.106 -0.002 -0.033 (0.008) (0.038)* (0.011)** (0.044) (0.020) (0.045)** (0.021) (0.023) 0.819 0.896 0.601 0.801 0.803 0.696 0.667 0.732 (0.026)*** (0.059)*** (0.051)*** (0.067)*** (0.050)*** (0.043)*** (0.049)*** (0.069)*** -0.066 -0.148 0.199 -0.122 -0.033 -0.103 0.151 -0.153 (0.052) (0.069)** (0.118)* (0.072)* (0.059) (0.133) (0.064)** (0.147) -0.198 -0.078 -0.661 -0.393 0.039 -0.273 -0.052 -0.087 (0.050)*** (0.195) (0.336)** (0.173)** (0.055) (0.237) (0.068) (0.297) -0.004 -0.000 0.001 -0.001 0.003 0.003 0.002 -0.001 (0.001)*** (0.002) (0.001)* (0.002) (0.001)*** (0.012) (0.001) (0.002) -0.008 -0.002 0.001 0.005 0.003 0.070 -0.005 0.018 (0.004)** (0.016) (0.002) (0.010) (0.004) (0.035)** (0.005) (0.011) 0.229 -0.097 -0.173 0.654 0.023 0.031 -0.960 -0.053 (0.139)* (0.182) (0.182) (0.141)*** (0.117) (0.092) (0.237)*** (0.189) -0.087 0.009 -0.004 0.016 0.234 -0.087 0.088 0.015 (0.021)*** (0.049) (0.024) (0.048) (0.040)*** (0.047)* (0.033)*** (0.043) Observations 1709 295 1139 732 406 714 1294 398 R2 0.744 0.756 0.358 0.718 0.863 0.617 0.667 0.644 Panel B Industry ln of fi(t−1) expi(t−1) ωi(t−1) 2 ωi(t−1) 3 ωi(t−1) ln Ap,i(t−1) ln An,i(t−1) nsh Constant Observations R2 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31-32 BasicMet. FabMet. Comp. Electrical Machines Vehicles Transport Furniture 0.232 0.120 4.333 0.338 0.354 0.108 6.986 0.032 (0.074)*** (0.141) (7.832) (0.743) (0.148)** (0.203) (4.115)* (0.087) 0.010 -0.001 -0.037 -0.005 -0.004 -0.011 0.072 0.008 (0.046) (0.003) (0.044) (0.016) (0.008) (0.021) (0.079) (0.011) 0.776 0.845 0.483 0.652 0.722 0.698 0.711 0.856 (0.055)*** (0.019)*** (0.109)*** (0.060)*** (0.025)*** (0.043)*** (0.202)*** (0.050)*** 0.111 0.214 0.033 0.028 0.011 -0.005 0.064 0.149 (0.113) (0.079)*** (0.045) (0.136) (0.060) (0.068) (0.151) (0.079)* -0.126 -0.289 0.038 -0.124 -0.065 0.001 -0.208 -0.548 (0.135) (0.131)** (0.056) (0.296) (0.133) (0.072) (0.292) (0.287)* 0.003 0.001 0.035 -0.001 -0.003 -0.000 0.198 0.001 (0.002) (0.000)* (0.010)*** (0.001) (0.000)*** (0.001) (0.170) (0.001)*** -0.012 -0.000 0.055 -0.021 -0.016 -0.003 0.135 -0.004 (0.011) (0.001) (0.043) (0.021) (0.003)*** (0.016) (0.056)** (0.003) -0.008 -0.326 -0.111 -0.125 0.630 0.308 0.705 -0.126 (0.104) (0.076)*** (0.168) (0.190) (0.121)*** (0.153)** (0.487) (0.118) 0.013 0.042 0.144 0.039 (0.050) (0.007)*** (0.049)*** (0.022)* 24 -0.082 0.028 -0.125 0.048 (0.015)*** (0.030) (0.088) (0.015)*** 438 3982 462 747 2778 958 79 1446 0.608 0.831 0.907 0.688 0.745 0.750 0.765 0.793 Dependent variable: firm-level Hicks-neutral productivity at time t. Year fixed effects included in all specifications. Bootstrapped standard errors in parentheses. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 Table 8: Estimating equation (10) Dependent variable: firm-level skill-biased productivity in production activities, ln Ap,it ln of fi(t−1) -0.103 (0.184) expi(t−1) -0.083 (0.061) ln Ap,i(t−1) 0.917 (0.006)*** ln Ap,i(t−1) 2 -0.001 (0.001)** ln Ap,i(t−1) 3 -0.000 (0.000)** ωi(t−1) 0.189 (0.091)** ln An,i(t−1) 0.101 (0.015)*** Constant 0.283 (0.056)*** Observations 21652 R2 0.832 Industry-year fixed effects are included Bootstrapped standard errors in parentheses * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01 25 Table 9: The effect of offshoring on skill-biased productivity in production activities Panel A Industry ln of fi(t−1) expi(t−1) ln Ap,i(t−1) ln A2 p,i(t−1) ln A3 p,i(t−1) ωi(t−1) ln An,i(t−1) Constant 10-12 13-15 16 17 18 20-21 22 23 Food Textiles Wood Paper Print. Chem. Rubber Nonmet. -8.346 11.754 -0.814 -0.802 17.332 0.023 -0.556 0.256 (4.718)* (7.967) (1.060) (0.607) (6.250)*** (0.039) (0.911) (0.403) -0.215 -0.140 -0.137 -0.182 -0.300 0.025 -0.016 0.270 (0.133) (0.576) (0.270) (0.374) (0.331) (0.166) (0.271) (0.489) 0.705 0.579 0.668 0.731 1.171 0.920 0.786 0.546 (0.111)*** (0.087)*** (0.138)*** (0.085)*** (0.168)*** (0.026)*** (0.054)*** (0.265)** -0.015 -0.037 -0.009 -0.022 0.012 -0.002 -0.027 -0.019 (0.008)* (0.011)*** (0.006) (0.011)** (0.006)* (0.025) (0.008)*** (0.014) -0.000 -0.001 -0.000 -0.001 0.000 -0.026 -0.001 -0.000 (0.000)** (0.000)*** (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)** (0.020) (0.000)*** (0.000) 0.328 1.050 0.316 0.068 0.268 0.094 0.016 0.685 (0.352) (0.586)* (0.428) (0.250) (0.455) (0.062) (0.194) (0.748) 0.286 0.189 0.074 0.385 0.088 0.168 0.118 0.171 (0.070)*** (0.212) (0.034)** (0.136)*** (0.057) (0.063)*** (0.051)** (0.169) -1.695 -1.454 -3.691 -0.507 -0.267 -0.018 -0.479 -3.691 (0.567)*** (0.588)** (1.146)*** (0.412) (1.482) (0.165) (0.281)* (1.645)** Observations 1981 428 1592 911 836 900 1504 539 R2 0.723 0.794 0.849 0.883 0.853 0.835 0.799 0.807 Panel B Industry ln of fi(t−1) expi(t−1) ln Ap,i(t−1) ln A2 p,i(t−1) ln A3 p,i(t−1) ωi(t−1) ln An,i(t−1) Constant Observations R2 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31-32 BasicMet. FabMet. Comp. Electrical Machines Vehicles Transport Furniture -0.239 0.139 2.425 1.920 -2.016 -2.906 0.647 -1.117 (0.630) (0.818) (7.700) (4.949) (4.995) (4.703) (0.945) (1.165) -0.114 -0.136 0.084 -0.029 0.119 -1.028 0.016 0.117 (0.378) (0.089) (0.080) (0.202) (0.154) (0.597)* (0.030) (0.257) 0.899 0.729 0.870 0.903 0.821 0.522 0.909 0.717 (0.062)*** (0.041)*** (0.034)*** (0.050)*** (0.053)*** (0.159)*** (0.060)*** (0.065)*** -0.008 -0.013 -0.043 -0.004 -0.007 -0.013 -0.102 -0.016 (0.013) (0.004)*** (0.027) (0.008) (0.004)* (0.006)** (0.205) (0.005)*** -0.001 -0.000 -0.011 -0.000 -0.000 -0.000 -0.191 -0.000 (0.001) (0.000)** (0.008) (0.000) (0.000)* (0.000)* (0.288) (0.000)*** 0.073 -0.049 0.085 0.108 0.141 -0.387 0.000 0.397 (0.242) (0.192) (0.083) (0.284) (0.256) (0.836) (0.028) (0.379) 0.033 0.059 0.162 0.238 0.262 0.870 0.018 0.179 (0.097) (0.020)*** (0.066)** (0.226) (0.065)*** (0.537) (0.017) (0.065)*** -0.029 -1.289 -0.092 -0.374 -1.197 -4.684 -0.009 -1.476 (0.408) (0.167)*** (0.080) (0.234) (0.264)*** (1.538)*** (0.029) (0.385)*** 548 4646 620 855 3196 1196 221 1679 0.869 0.831 0.841 0.869 0.834 0.842 0.838 0.853 Dependent variable: firm-level skill-biased productivity in non-production activities at time t. Year fixed effects included in all specifications. 26 Bootstrapped standard errors in parentheses. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 Table 10: Estimating equation (11) Dependent variable: firm-level skill-biased productivity in non-production activities, ln An,it ln of fi(t−1) 0.094 (0.036)*** expi(t−1) 0.108 (0.016)*** ln An,i(t−1) 0.893 (0.007)*** ln A2n,i(t−1) 0.005 (0.002)** ln A3n,i(t−1) 0.000 (0.001) ωi(t−1) 0.107 (0.020)*** ln Ap,i(t−1) 0.008 (0.001)*** Constant -0.045 (0.015)*** Observations 20732 R2 0.822 Industry-year fixed effects are included Bootstrapped standard errors in parentheses * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01 27 Table 11: The effect of offshoring on skill-biased productivity in non-production activities Panel A Industry ln of fi(t−1) expi(t−1) ln An,i(t−1) ln A2 n,i(t−1) ln A3 n,i(t−1) ωi(t−1) ln Ap,i(t−1) Constant 10-12 13-15 16 17 18 20-21 22 23 Food Textiles Wood Paper Print. Chem. Rubber Nonmet. 2.430 0.910 0.815 0.039 3.425 0.014 0.583 -0.035 (1.743) (0.565) (0.297)*** (0.078) (3.621) (0.013) (0.273)** (0.054) 0.195 0.073 -0.042 0.087 0.190 0.031 0.140 0.125 (0.037)*** (0.060) (0.086) (0.056) (0.110)* (0.030) (0.062)** (0.055)** 0.837 0.850 0.939 0.896 0.853 0.931 0.877 0.872 (0.021)*** (0.041)*** (0.020)*** (0.025)*** (0.081)*** (0.030)*** (0.021)*** (0.036)*** -0.018 -0.007 0.008 0.007 -0.006 0.036 -0.022 -0.023 (0.012) (0.034) (0.008) (0.028) (0.026) (0.065) (0.018) (0.018) -0.007 0.000 0.000 -0.011 -0.000 -0.521 -0.007 -0.000 (0.004)* (0.034) (0.001) (0.021) (0.002) (0.369) (0.009) (0.010) -0.023 0.057 0.450 0.041 -0.030 -0.002 0.063 0.035 (0.075) (0.064) (0.145)*** (0.035) (0.134) (0.011) (0.061) (0.101) 0.015 0.001 0.009 0.010 0.009 0.013 0.014 0.011 (0.004)*** (0.003) (0.004)** (0.003)*** (0.005)* (0.004)*** (0.004)*** (0.004)*** 0.075 -0.068 0.084 0.018 -0.296 -0.031 -0.051 0.114 (0.061) (0.063) (0.124) (0.058) (0.172)* (0.030) (0.067) (0.089) Observations 1897 417 1478 886 792 884 1438 508 R2 0.762 0.780 0.833 0.847 0.782 0.850 0.806 0.862 Panel B Industry ln of fi(t−1) expi(t−1) ln An,i(t−1) ln A2 n,i(t−1) ln A3 n,i(t−1) ωi(t−1) ln Ap,i(t−1) Constant Observations R2 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31-32 BasicMet. FabMet. Comp. Electrical Machines Vehicles Transport Furniture 0.109 0.037 3.017 -0.353 0.115 0.330 1.233 0.185 (0.137) (0.166) (1.914) (0.594) (0.263) (0.177)* (1.245) (0.448) 0.123 0.095 0.042 0.040 0.077 0.043 0.137 0.089 (0.071)* (0.033)*** (0.020)** (0.015)*** (0.022)*** (0.021)** (0.044)*** (0.044)** 0.971 0.922 0.933 0.941 0.948 0.853 0.972 0.940 (0.028)*** (0.010)*** (0.026)*** (0.030)*** (0.012)*** (0.022)*** (0.047)*** (0.017)*** 0.005 0.008 0.087 -0.097 -0.020 0.009 0.055 0.003 (0.016) (0.004)** (0.047)* (0.061) (0.010)** (0.041) (0.032)* (0.008) -0.028 -0.000 -0.130 -0.274 -0.019 0.073 -0.043 -0.005 (0.014)** (0.001) (0.114) (0.144)* (0.006)*** (0.060) (0.036) (0.003)* 0.030 0.488 0.031 -0.004 0.001 -0.035 -0.024 0.095 (0.037) (0.074)*** (0.015)** (0.024) (0.031) (0.024) (0.037) (0.071) 0.005 0.008 0.015 0.003 0.004 0.001 0.037 0.006 (0.004) (0.002)*** (0.004)*** (0.001)*** (0.001)*** (0.000)** (0.058) (0.002)*** -0.082 -0.061 -0.032 -0.005 0.005 -0.009 -0.134 -0.030 (0.077) (0.038) (0.021) (0.017) (0.025) (0.024) (0.042)*** (0.054) 531 4395 616 844 3080 1163 207 1596 0.904 0.821 0.895 0.825 0.877 0.799 0.901 0.859 Dependent variable: firm-level skill-biased productivity in non-production activities at time t. Year fixed effects included in all specifications. 28 Bootstrapped standard errors in parentheses. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 5 Conclusion TO BE COMPLETED REFERENCES • Ackerberg, D., K. Caves, K. and G. Frazer (2006), Structural Identification of Production Functions, working paper. • Andersson, L., P. Karpaty and R. Kneller (2008), ‘Offshoring and Productivity: Evidence Using Swedish Firm Level Data’. Orebro University School of Business Working Paper. • Feenstra, R. C. and G. H. Hanson (1995), ‘Foreign Investment, Outsourcing and Relative Wages’, NBER Working Paper No. 5121. • Grossman, G. M. and E. Rossi-Hansberg (2008), ‘Trading Tasks: A Simple Theory of Offshoring’. American Economic Review, vol. 98(5), pp. 1978-97. • Gorg, H. (2011), ‘Globalization, offshoring and jobs’, in Making Globalization Socially Sustainable, Eds. M. Bacchetta and M. Jansen, International Labor Office publications. • Gorg, H., A. Hanley and E. Strobl (2008), ‘Productivity Effects of International Outsourcing: Evidence from Plant Level Data’. Canadian Journal of Economics, vol. 41, pp. 670-688. • Kasahara, H. and J. Rodrigue (2008), ‘Does the Use of Imported Intermediates Increase Productivity? Plant-Level Evidence’. Journal of Development Economics, vol. 87(1), pp. 106-118. • Kasahara, H., Y. Liang, and J. Rodrigue (2013), ‘Does Importing Intermediates Increase the Demand for Skilled Workers? Plant-level Evidence from Indonesia’. 29 CESIFO Working Paper No. 4463. • Levinsohn, J., Petrin, A., (2003), Estimating Production Functions Using Inputs to Control for Unobservables. Review of Economic Studies 70 (2): 317-342. • Olley, S., Pakes, A., (1996), The Dynamics of Productivity in the Telecommunications Equipment Industry. Econometrica 64(6): 1263-1295. • Yasar, M. and C. J. Morrison Paul (2007), ‘International Linkages and Productivity at the Plant Level: Foreign Direct Investment, Exports, Imports and Licensing’. Journal of International Economics, vol. 71(2), pp. 373-388. 30
© Copyright 2024