Identity, Overconfidence, and Investment Decisions

Identity, Overconfidence, and
Investment Decisions
Francesco D’Acunto
∗
June 2015
Abstract
Why are men more risk tolerant than women, and why do they invest more
than women? I test whether identity stereotypes help explain this heterogeneity. I
manipulate identity in a controlled environment by priming its salience to subjects.
Men whose identity is primed take on more risk, and invest more often and more
money than controls. The salience of male identity increases men's beliefs of
experiencing good outcomes in a game of chance. Inducing overconfidence similarly
makes men take on more risk and invest more. The effects are stronger for older
cohorts of men, consistent with the notion that gender identity stereotypes have
become less stark over the last decades.
JEL: D81, G01, G11, J16
Keywords: Stereotypes, Experimental Economics, Heterogeneous Beliefs,
Individual Investors.
∗
Haas School of Business, UC Berkeley (francesco [email protected]). UC Berkeley CPHS
Approval Protocol number 2013-11-5805. For their invaluable help and guidance, I thank Stefano
DellaVigna, Ulrike Malmendier, Gustavo Manso, Terrance Odean, and Ross Levine. For very helpful
comments and discussions, I thank Nick Barberis, Dan Benjamin, James Choi, Xavier Gabaix, Luigi
Guiso, George Korniotis (discussant), Samuli Kn¨
upfer, Rachel Kranton, Ross Levine, Don Moore, Adair
Morse, Muriel Niederle, Christine Parlour, Matthew Rabin, Andrei Shleifer, Stephan Siegel (discussant),
Michael Weber, and seminar participants at the 2014 Miami Behavioral Finance Conference, the 2013
NBER Behavioral Economics Fall meeting, the 2014 Whitebox Advisors Graduate Conference, and UC
Berkeley. Financial support from the White Foundation is gratefully acknowledged. All errors are my
own..
1
Introduction
Men are more risk tolerant than women (Croson and Gneezy, 2009). They are more
competitive (Niederle and Vesterlund, 2007), and they invest more often and more
aggressively than women in financial opportunities (Barber and Odean, 2001). Several
explanations for the different risk attitudes across genders have been proposed. First,
these differences have biological roots (Kuhnen and Chiao, 2009; Coates and Herbert,
2008; Mastripieri, Sapienza, and Zingales, 2009; Cesarini et al., 2010; Cronqvist and
Siegel, 2014; Cronqvist et al., 2014). Second, social identity may additionally help to
explain these differences, because identity stereotypes prescribe normative behaviors to
men and women (Mischel, 1966; Akerlof and Kranton, 2000).1 Third, the differences may
stem from other characteristics that correlate with gender.
In this paper, I aim to provide a causal test for the effect of social identity on the risk
attitudes and investment behavior across genders, and to study the economic channels
that may mediate this effect. Running causal tests in the field would be hard (Camerer
and Lovallo, 1999; Biais et al., 2005), thus I randomly manipulate the salience of identity
stereotypes in a controlled environment (e.g., Steele, 1997; Shih et al., 1999), and I
compare the risk tolerance and investment behavior of treated and control subjects.
Similar priming techniques have been employed to address economic questions for which
exogenous variation in the field is hard to detect (Benjamin, Choi, and Fisher, 2013;
Cohn et al., 2015; Coffman, 2015).
Results in social psychology show that priming and threatening male identity both induce
risky behaviors in men due to salience and overcompensation (Maas et al., 2003; Willer et
al., 2013). Salience means individuals tend to conform to the trait of their own identity
that is primed. Overcompensation means individuals behave more in line with their own
identity to reaffirm it when it is threatened.2
I find that men whose identity stereotypes are primed or threatened become more risk
tolerant after the manipulations, and invest more often and more money in simple
1
See Table 1 for a list of identity stereotypes attributed to men and women by 200 online respondents.
The identity channel is not necessarily uncorrelated with biology or genetics. In Willer et al. (2013), men
with higher levels of basal testosterone are more responsive to identity threats.
2
Note that this notion of identity threat is unrelated to the stereotype threat of Carr and Steele, 2010.
1
investment decisions compared to control men and to women. I detect no effect of
identity manipulation on women’s risk attitudes and investment behavior.
Previous literature in Economics and in Psychology found conflicting results on the
effect of gender identity on risk attitudes.
In Meier-Pesti and Penz (2008), male
gender salience increases the willingness to take risks in both men and women, but in
a non-incentive-compatible setting, and in a subject pool in which men and women
reported the same masculine attributes. To the contrary, in Benjamin, Choi, and Fisher
(2010), there is no effect of gender salience on risk preferences in an incentive-compatible,
between-subjects experimental design.
Compared with previous literature, this paper proposes five innovations.
First, I construct a within-subject experimental design, which controls for the
heterogeneity of subjects’ preferences before the experimental manipulations.
This
design allows testing for the effect of identity on risk attitudes more precisely than
between-subjects designs. If I only use the between-subjects variation in risk attitudes
after the manipulations, I estimate effects of similar size but statistically indifferent from
zero, which is consistent with the non-result of Benjamin, Choi, and Fisher (2010).3 The
within-subject design raises concerns of demand effects. This is why I run artefactual
field experiments with varied non-student subjects that are not aware of being part of
an experiment throughout the paper. I also recruit additional subjects who perform the
same experimental tasks as others, but guess the motivations of the tasks at the end of
the experiment.4 Less than 10% of these subjects give answers that could be compatible
with the true scope of the study, whereas I show that virtually all subjects exposed to
the treatment conditions become more risk tolerant after the manipulations.
Second, I test for the first time for the economic channels that transmit the effect of
gender identity on risk attitudes. I find that beliefs are a channel of transmission, because
men whose identity is manipulated become overconfident in a pure game of chance,
3
I report the between-subjects results for this paper in Table 5 of Appendix B. The priming procedure
in this paper is also purposefully more aggressive than in Benjamin, Choi, and Fisher (2010): subjects
read a text full of stereotypes related to male or female identity, and they recall and describe in detail
a situation when they behaved in line with the stereotypes (see Appendix A). The more aggressive
procedure possibly explains the larger estimated magnitudes of the effects compared to their test.
4
I thank Dan Benjamin for suggesting this test.
2
consistent with the illusion of controlling a random process. The effect of gender identity
on men’s beliefs in a pure game of chance is a novel result that deepens our understanding
of the sources of overconfidence, which is one of the most studied behavioral biases in
Economics.5 Parallel to the lack of an effect of identity on women’s risk attitudes, the
manipulations do not affect the beliefs of women.
Third, I show that the effect of identity on men’s risk attitudes also obtains if subjects
make investment decisions under risk, both on the extensive margin (the decision to
invest or not), and the intensive margin (the decision of how much money to invest
conditional on investing). The results are similar if the decisions are framed as delegated
investments, that is, if subjects invest money on behalf of a principal. The delegated
setting aims to mimic the decisions of asset managers and corporate executives in the
field. These results could therefore be interpreted as a causal test for the large body
of correlational evidence in Economics and Finance on overconfidence and investment
decisions by individual investors and corporate executives.6
Fourth, I exploit the varied pool of subjects in terms of demographics to disentangle the
effect of gender identity from the effects of biological and genetic characteristics on risk
attitudes and investment decisions. I find that older men are the most affected by the
identity manipulations, and the effect decreases monotonically the younger the subjects.
This result is consistent with the notion that gender identity stereotypes have become less
stark over the last four decades, and hence their manipulation should have lower effects
on the behavior of younger cohorts of men. The biological and genetic characteristics
of human beings, instead, cannot have changed significantly in such a short period of time.
Fifth, I propose a coherent economic framework based on Bordalo, Gennaioli, and Shleifer
(2014) to interpret the results in the paper. To the best of my knowledge, this is the
first paper that proposes a theoretical foundation in Economics for the act of priming in
a controlled environment. This framework could inspire the uprising economic research
that uses priming techniques to discipline the predictions of their tests. In this paper,
5
Note that this test may have been run in the past with no results, and may have not been disclosed
due to publication bias.
6
e.g., Barber and Odean, 2001; Malmendier and Tate, 2005; Malmendier and Tate, 2008; Gervais et
al., 2011; Hirshleifer and Han, 2012; Ben-David et al., 2013.
3
the framework requires an effect of identity salience on men’s beliefs, which is exactly
what I find.
There are caveats to the interpretation of the evidence in the paper. By construction
the analysis isolates reduced-form effects: a drawback is the causal tests do not inform
on the expected size of the effects in the field. The experiments change the salience of
identity stereotypes to gauge their causal effect on decision making, but the level of the
perception of stereotypes should affect decisions in the field. Moreover, the subjects
do not necessarily represent the average investor or the average CEO, and there is no
uncertainty in the lottery choices and the investment decisions that the subjects perform.
It is also important to stress what this paper does not show. The paper does not show
that gender identity is more important than biology and genetics as a determinant of risk
attitudes. Future research should be devoted to understanding how biology, genetics, and
identity may interact to affect risk attitudes and investment decisions. Moreover, in this
paper men and women react differently to the same identity stereotype manipulations.
My results are therefore inconsistent with the claim that the differences between the
sexes could be eliminated by manipulating men and women’s gender stereotypes, or that
the only difference between the sexes is their gender identity.
2
Laboratory Environment
The experiments are run on an online platform, Amazon Mechanical Turk (mTurk).
Kuziemko et al. (2015) are among the first who use mTurk in Economics research.
On mTurk Requesters post tasks, and a large pool of Workers can accept to perform
them. Requesters are often private companies and Workers are registered users. Workers
provide their fiscal address and social security number for tax purposes. Tasks are short,
and the average pay is low ($1.39 per hour).
Workers based in the United States,
who are exclusively recruited in this paper, access mTurk mainly to spend their spare
time constructively (Paolacci et al., 2010). The quality of answers is not lower than
in human-subjects laboratories despite the lower pay (Casler et al., 2013).7 Recently,
7
Mason and Suri (2011) and Paolacci et al. (2010) describe mTurk and Workers. Berinsky et al.
(2011) replicate laboratory results in political science on mTurk.
4
mTurk has gained interest as a means to recruit diversified subjects for artefactual field
experiments, but a concern is Workers may not properly complete the tasks. To address
the concern, (i) I restrict the subject pool to Workers with at least 95% positive rates on
all the tasks accepted in the past; (ii) I track the time they take to complete each task;
(iii) I read all essays to verify that subjects produce coherent statements; and (iv) I add
implausible options to the lotteries and I verify that they are not picked.8
Advantages over laboratory. mTurk has a set of advantages compared to humansubject laboratories (Horton et al., 2011), especially for a study on identity priming and
for within-subject designs:
• Subjects come from the whole United States. Figure 1 plots their IP addresses.
If subjects came from the same college town, they would live in a peculiar social
environment that is likely dissimilar from the one average Americans face. Also,
college and MBA students may sort into communities whose values they share.
• As an online, double-blind platform, mTurk allows to run artefactual field
experiments in which recruiting is simple (List, 2011). Subjects perform tasks in
their environment and are not aware they are part of an experiment. This procedure
helps to address the concerns of demand effects raised by within-subject designs.
• Subjects’ demographics are well varied, whereas a sample of college students would
only include individuals between 18 and 22 years of age with some college education.
• Replicability of results is easy: any Requester accesses the same subject pool. Easy
replicability allows for a transparent comparison of results across studies.9
• Workers’ anonymity makes the priming procedure most effective. Subjects may
describe unconventional experiences with no fear of being identified.
3
Effect of Identity on Risk Tolerance
In Experiment 1, I test whether gender identity stereotypes have a causal effect on
risk attitudes in a within-subject experimental design, where subjects’ risk tolerance is
elicited before and after being exposed to the manipulation of their gender identity. The
manipulations include identity salience and threat, both of which have been shown to
8
For instance, I add a choice between $0 for sure and a lottery that pays $0 or a positive amount.
On September 26, 2012, Daniel Kahnemann proposed a protocol for improving the credibility of
research on priming, which is easy to implement on mTurk.
9
5
induce risky behaviors in men due to salience and overcompensation (Maas et al., 2003;
Willer et al., 2013).
Experimental Design.
340 subjects were recruited on Amazon Mechanical Turk
(mTurk) in April 2012 (first session) and September 2012 (second session). Subjects
were proposed a creative writing task to earn $0.5, plus a chance to earn a bonus by
picking lotteries. The nature or objectives of the study were not disclosed to ensure
that (i) subjects were not primed with their identity before the experiment; (ii) subjects
would not search for previous research on identity priming, which would raise concerns
of demand effects; and (iii) the results could be replicated in subsequent sessions and by
other researchers. The subject pool was restricted to users with a US tax identification,
and with more than 95% of lifetime tasks approved in the past.
Table 2 describes the experimental designs and samples for all the experiments in the
paper. The design of Experiment 1 was a 2 (male, female) by 3 (control, male prime,
female prime) factorial design. I excluded 20 subjects (5.8% of the full sample) because of
inconsistencies in lottery choices, leading to a final sample of 320 subjects. Subjects were
assigned in proportions of 2:2:1 to the control, male-prime, and female-prime conditions.10
The aim was to maximize the power for the male identity salience test, because my
cheating-free threat had not been tested in previous research, and it was a weaker prime
than the one used by Maas et al. (2003) and Willer et al. (2013).11
Procedure. The experimental procedure was as follows. In the first stage, subjects
answered four background questions including the country of residence, gender, age group
(18-22, 23-35, 36-45, 46-60, 60+), and education (high school or lower, some college,
college degree, postgraduate degree). Then subjects faced two screens of lottery choices
(Holt and Laury, 2002). Each choice included a degenerate lottery paying a positive
outcome for sure (certainty equivalent), and a lottery paying a positive outcome with
probability 1/2, and zero otherwise. In the second session, subjects faced three sets of
lottery choices to make sure the results did not vary with effort, which indeed was not the
case. Subjects had to complete the lottery task in full before proceeding, but they could
10
It is important to stress that on mTurk one cannot discriminate Workers at the recruitment stage by
gender, that is, one cannot limit the sample to men only, or target the same number of male and female
subjects. About 60% of U.S. mTurk workers are women (Mason and Suri, 2011).
11
They gave random feedback on a gender-identity survey suggesting that subjects are masculine or
feminine, which implies an act of deception on the part of the experimenter.
6
leave the experiment at any time.12
The second stage consisted of the experimental treatments. Subjects read a short text
(see Appendix A) and recalled and described an experience in line with the text. Subjects
were asked to describe the situation and their feelings in detail in a short essay of 5 to
10 sentences. The texts were taken from online blogs, so as to be similar to the gender
identity manipulations to which the subject pool, which is made of internet users, may
be regularly exposed in their daily life. Note that this test does not aim to give subjects
a scientific definition of identity stereotypes, but to activate their own interpretation of
identity stereotypes once they face them explicitly.
Control subjects read a text on ayurveda principles for a healthy lifestyle. Subjects in the
male-identity-prime condition read a text full of stereotypes about how a masculine person
behaves.13 Subjects in the female-identity-prime condition read a text full of stereotypes
about how a feminine person behaves.
The third stage consisted of two additional screens of lottery choices. The lottery choices
changed to ensure subjects did not merely repeat their first-stage choices. All choices
were incentive-compatible: subjects knew their bonus would be calculated by picking one
screen and one line at random, running their choice (certainty equivalent or lottery), and
dividing the final amount by 100.
Manipulation Check. Across all experiments, the content of the essays produced by
the subjects served for the manipulation checks. I verified that each essay reported words
related to the identity stereotypes enlisted in Table 1 in the corresponding experimental
condition (see Appendix A for essay samples). Ad hoc manipulation check tasks would
have made subjects aware they were part of an experiment, and hence would have
worsened the risk of demand effects. In Figure 7, I formalize this manipulation check
for Experiment 1.14 In Panel (a) of Figure 7, I report the average number of times
subjects wrote a stereotype associated with male individuals from Table 1 in their essays,
12
No one left the experiment before completing it in full.
Consistent with Table 1, confidence entered the text. A concern is the treatment directly induces
overconfidence instead of priming a generic set of manly characteristics. But the male-identity priming
text explicitly states that ”the masculine side [...] includes [...] how to accurately weigh probabilities
so that you know the most likely outcome to expect in situations you come across” (see Appendix A).
Specifying the importance of a correct assessment of probabilities also speaks to the issue of demand
effects in a within-subject design: if the subjects wanted to please the experimenter, they would pay
attention to the objective probabilities in the lottery choices.
14
The (unreported) results are similar across all other experiments.
13
7
across experimental conditions. Subjects in the male identity prime condition reported on
average 2.41 male identity stereotypes.15 Instead, subjects in the control or female identity
prime condition do not write masculine identity stereotypes. In Panel (b) of Figure 7, I
report the average number of times subjects wrote a stereotype associated with female
individuals from Table 1 in their essays, across experimental conditions. Subjects in the
female identity prime condition are likely to report stereotypes associated with female
individuals, whereas others are not.
Measuring Risk Tolerance and Non-parametric Analysis.
I compute a
non-parametric measure of risk tolerance at the subject level, described in Figure 2. I
subtract the times the subject chose the certainty equivalent over the lottery from the
times a risk-neutral agent would make this decision. I average the difference across the
choices of the first stage to obtain a pre-treatment measure of risk tolerance:
RiskT olerancepre,i =
1 X
×
(RN choicespre,l − choicespre,l,i ),
L
l
where l ∈ (1, L) are the screens of lottery choices the subject faces, RN choicespre, l are
the times a risk-neutral agent would choose the certainty equivalent over the lottery in
screen l, and choicespre, l, i are the times agent i chose the certainty equivalent over the
lottery in screen l. RiskT olerancepre,i is positive when the subject, on average, chose the
lottery more often than a risk-neutral agent would do. I compute the analogous measure
for choices made after the experimental treatments:
RiskT olerancepost,i =
1 X
(RN choicespost,l − choicespost,l,i ),
×
L
l
The within-subject change in risk tolerance after the treatment compared to before the
treatment is ∆RiskT olerancei = RiskT olerancepost,i − RiskT olerancepre,i .
Figure 3 plots the estimated densities and the cumulative distributions of
RiskT olerancepre and of ∆RiskT olerance for the subsample of men, who are affected
by the manipulations. Results for women are in Appendix B. Panel A of Figure 3 plots
the estimated distributions of the level of risk tolerance of men across treatment conditions
before the manipulations. The vast majority of subjects are risk averse: the mean of all
15
The figure only refers to the most common stereotypes, in Table 1. Subjects often reported other
masculine stereotypes that do not enter the computation.
8
distributions and the largest part of their mass lie in the negative domain. Reassuringly,
the distributions for men that will be exposed to the control and to the male prime
conditions (green dot-dash and blue solid lines) are similar in terms of mean and standard
deviation. The distribution of the risk tolerance of men in the female prime group spikes
to a negative value and lies in the negative domain, but the standard deviation is lower
than the one for the other experimental groups.
Panel B of Figure 3 depicts the main result of Experiment 1. The plots report the
density and cumulative distribution of ∆RiskT olerance for the male subsample across
experimental conditions. The risk tolerance of control subjects (green, dot-dash line) does
not change, on average, after exposure to the control condition. This evidence suggests
that the control condition does not drive the results, and that the act of priming does
not cause any change in behavior by itself. If the male prime and the female prime were
increasing the risk tolerance of subjects, we would expect the distributions of the change
in risk tolerance to shift to the right compared to the distribution for controls. Indeed,
the change in the risk tolerance of the male prime group (blue, solid line) is on average
positive (0.5).16 The distributions of the change in risk tolerance for the identity threat
group (dashed, red line) also peak to a positive value (0.45).
OLS Results. To assess the statistical significance of the effects, I estimate the following
OLS equation on the subsample of men:
∆RiskT oleranceiae = α + γ1 × M aleP rimeiae + γ2 × F emaleP rimeiae + ηa + ηe + iae (1)
where ∆RiskT oleranceiae is the within-subject change in risk tolerance for subject i, in
age group a, and education group e; M aleP rime and F emaleP rime are dummies that
equal 1 if the man is exposed to the male identity (salience) or female identity (threat)
prime; ηa and ηe capture subjects’ age and education groups. The identification strategy
is a difference-in-differences design: I look at subjects’ decisions before and after the
manipulations, and across subjects in the treatment and control groups. In column (1)
of Panel A of Table 3, men primed with male identity choose lotteries over certainty
16
The male group displays a fat right tail. In Table 7 of Appendix B, I show the results are not driven
by the subjects in this right tail.
9
equivalents 0.51 times more often (s.e. 0.25) than controls after the prime.17 The result
is robust to averaging out age- and education-group effects in column (2) of Panel A of
Table 3. Men primed with female identity choose lotteries over certainty equivalents 0.43
times more often (s.e.0.21) after the prime compared to before it.
In Panel B of Table 3, I add the subsample of women to the analysis, and hence I use a
triple-differences estimator. I test if the results on men are robust to adding this additional
layer of subjects by estimating the following:
∆RiskT oleranceiae = α + βM aniae + γ1 × M aleP rimeiae + γ2 × F emaleP rimeiae
γ3 × (M aleP rime × M an)iae + γ4 × (F emaleP rime × M an)iae + ηa + ηe + iae
(2)
where ∆RiskT olerance is the same measure as in Equation 1, and M an equals 1 if the
subject is a man. In Equation 2, β does not capture the difference in average risk tolerance
between men and women ex ante, but the difference in the change in risk tolerance due to
the exposure to the control condition. Hence, βˆ should be zero, unless being exposed to
the control condition affects men and women’s risk tolerance differently. I cannot reject
the null that βˆ is zero at any meaningful level of significance.
The increase in risk-tolerant choices by men in the male-identity-prime condition is
significantly more positive (0.84, s.e. 0.37) than that of women, and with respect to the
control group. The result is robust to averaging out age- and education- group effects.
Men also become more risk tolerant after the identity threat, but I can only reject the
null of no effect at the 10% level of significance (0.59, s.e. 0.33).
Demand Effects?
The within-subject design raises concerns of demand effects:
subjects may be willing to conform their behavior to what they believe is the aim of
the experimenter. Demand concerns are the main reason why I run artefactual field
experiments, in which subjects are not aware of the scope of the experimenter, or that
they are part of an experiment, but they perform tasks on mTurk for which they have
signed up for pay.18 I also test for the scope of demand effects more directly. In June and
July 2014, I recruited 100 new subjects to perform the same tasks as in Experiment 1, but
17
Because individual-level choices are collapsed into their average before and after the treatment, robust
standard errors are only corrected for White heteroskedasticity.
18
Note that mTurk’s primary function is for private companies to outsource simple tasks or to test the
effectiveness of advertising campaigns. mTurk was not created as a tool for conducting scientific research.
10
also to guess the motivations of the tasks at the end of the experiment.19 Figure 8 plots the
reported motivations for the lottery tasks and the writing task across six categories. Less
than 10% of subjects gave answers that could be compatible with the true scope of the
study, whereas in Figure 3 virtually all subjects exposed to the treatment conditions
become more risk tolerant after the manipulations. Even if this test is run on a different
pool of subjects that those in Experiment 1, the results provide direct evidence that
demand effects are unlikely to be a relevant concern in this setting.
Evidence against fabricated data. I run the test proposed by Simonsohn (2013)
against fabricated data in experimental research. This test is important in light of the
recent research misconduct scandals commented on by Kahneman (2012). In Table 8 of
Appendix B, I verify for all the experiments in the paper that the standard deviations
of the sample averages across experimental conditions do not differ from those one would
obtain in random samples across conditions. In Experiment 1, the null that the observed
distributions come from independently drawn random samples can only be rejected above
the 99.99% significance level (99.98% in the male subsamples).
4
Channels that Mediate the Effect of Identity on Risk
Tolerance: Beliefs
After having established that priming or threatening male identity increases men’s
willingness to take risk in a within-subject, incentive-compatible research design, I move
on to test for the economic channels that may explain this effect.
The primes may act through two channels: (i) preferences: priming identity could be a
positive shock to men’s risk tolerance. This shock would reduce the certainty equivalent
men require to give up a chance to take part in a lottery; (ii) beliefs: priming identity
could be a positive shock to men’s subjective probability of experiencing good outcomes
if they take part in a lottery. They could believe they are more likely to obtain the good
outcome conditional on participating than what the objective probabilities suggest.
If individuals held subjective beliefs of experiencing good outcomes in risky settings, which
might differ from the objective probabilities they are told, the identity manipulations could
affect their subjective beliefs. Subjects would become overconfident, that is, believe they
19
I thank Dan Benjamin for suggesting this test.
11
are more likely than what the objective probabilities suggest to obtain the good outcome
if they participate in the lottery. This form of overconfidence involves the illusion of
controlling random processes, as opposed to overplacement or overprecision in interpreting
signals (see Moore and Healy, 2008) In this section, I propose two novel tests to assess
the possibility that a beliefs channel helps explain the effect of identity manipulations on
men’s attitudes under risk.20
A
Identity and Subjective Beliefs under Risk
The first challenge to testing for an effect of identity manipulations on beliefs is to design
a test that does not elicit at the same time the preferences for risk and the subjective
beliefs of experiencing good outcomes under risk. I propose such a test in Experiment 2.
Design and Procedure. I recruited 325 subjects on Amazon Mechanical Turk in May
2015, and invited them to work on a survey to earn $0.4.21 I excluded two subjects (1%
of sample), because they did not write meaningful words or sentences in the priming task,
leading to a final sample of 323 subjects. After answering four background questions,
subjects were exposed to the experimental conditions of Experiment 1 (control, male
identity prime, female identity prime). I assigned subjects in equal proportions to the
three experimental conditions (see Table 2). I elicited subjective beliefs in two steps.
First, subjects faced a lottery that won on average 5 out of 10 times. No additional
details were disclosed, including the ”winning” or ”losing” payoffs. Subjects predicted
the number of times they would win if the lottery was played 10 times. The number
they reported was a direct measure of the subjective probability of experiencing a good
outcome in a risky setting. To make the elicitation incentive-compatible, subjects knew
that the lotteries would be played 10 times using a random number generator after the
experiment, and they would receive a bonus based on the difference between the predicted
number of wins and the actual number of wins.22 This design ensured that (i) subjects
were told explicitly that the outcomes of the lotteries would be completely determined by
20
Assessing the relative contribution of the preferences and beliefs channels is beyond the scope of this
paper.
21
A previous version of this experiment elicited beliefs in a non-incentive-compatible setting. I report
the similar results for the previous experiment in the Online Appendix.
22
The bonus was 10 cents if the subject predicted the actual number of wins, 5 cents if the subject
was one time long or short the actual number of wins, 2 cents for two times long or short, and 1 cent for
three times long or short.
12
chance, and (ii) risk tolerance had no role in the predictions.
In a second step, subjects imagined a person taken at random from their neighborhood
participated 10 times in the same lottery. They predicted the number of times they
thought this neighbor would win, and were paid a second bonus based on the accuracy
of their predictions. The number was interpreted as a direct measure of the subjective
probability that a peer would win the lottery. The comparison to peers is relevant,
because if the primes were simply inducing a state of elation in subjects, they would reply
that both they and the peers were likely to win more than 5 times. Instead, if subjects
believed they could control a random process, and the primes made them confident they
were better than average at the lottery, then primed subjects should have thought their
peers were as likely to win the lottery as the objective probability suggested.
Results. Panel A of Figure 4 plots the subjective beliefs of winning the lottery for men,
across the control and primed conditions, where the primed condition pools together
identity salience and threat.23 Primed men think they will succeed more than five times
on average, whereas control men do not. A double-sided t-test for whether the average
predicted number of wins by primed men (5.25) equals 5 rejects the null at the 1% level
of significance, whereas a similar test for whether the average number of wins by control
men (4.96) equals 5 cannot reject the null at any plausible level.24
Panel B of Figure 4 plots the average difference between men’s predicted wins by
themselves and by peers across experimental conditions.
The difference (0.04) is
statistically and economically indistinguishable from zero for controls. It is significantly
positive for primed men (0.25).
Manipulating identity therefore does increase the
subjective probability of experiencing a winning lottery outcome for men, even if they
play a pure game of chance. This novel result can only be justified if subjects have the
illusion of controlling a game of chance, and if priming makes subjects overconfident on
their ability at this game. In Appendix B, I show that the manipulations have no effect
on the beliefs of women: both control and treated women think on average that they will
succeed five times if playing the lottery 10 times, in line with the objective probabilities
they are told. The different results on the effect of the manipulations on beliefs across men
23
I merge the identity salience and threat groups to increase the power of the test, because the two
primes have very similar effects on the willingness to take on risks in Experiment 1.
24
Note that a test for whether the averages across groups are equal only rejects the null at the 10%
level of significance.
13
and women pair up with the asymmetric effect of identity manipulation on risk attitudes
by gender in Experiment 1.
Incidentally, the effect of identity on men’s beliefs may help to shed light on the sources of
overconfidence, which is one of the most studied behavioral biases in Economics. Gender
identity appears to causally affect beliefs in risky settings.
B
Inducing Overconfidence and Risk Tolerance
The results of Experiment 2 suggest that indeed the beliefs channel could in part explain
the effect of gender identity manipulations on the willingness to take risks by men. I
therefore propose a further test for whether manipulating men’s beliefs about experiencing
good outcomes in choices under risk may provide a similar effect on risk attitudes as the
effect of the identity manipulation, and in an incentive-compatible setting.
The methodological challenge for such test is to provide an experimental manipulation
that plausibly affects men’s confidence in a pure game of chance, hence gives them the
illusion of controlling the outcomes. To this aim, in Experiment 3 I build on the social
psychology literature, and I induce overconfidence in the form of illusion of control asking
subjects to recall a situation in which they had power over one or more individuals (e.g.,
Anderson and Galinsky, 2009; Fast et al., 2009; Fast et al., 2012). Table 1 shows that the
stereotypes attached to powerful individuals by a pool of 200 respondents on mTurk are
strikingly similar to those attached to men.
Recalling a situation of power over others may also induce a state of elation in subjects,
which would affect their risk attitudes for reasons unrelated to overconfidence or identity
(Kuhnen and Knutson, 2011).
I propose to prime the sense of success of subjects
as a placebo manipulation. Recalling a situation when subjects were successful and
describing it in detail plausibly induces a state of elation in subjects. But whereas
powerful individuals are described with similar stereotypes as men, successful individuals
are associated with a mix of male and female identity stereotypes (see Table 1).
A concern with this test for elation states is that success itself may be expected to induce
overconfidence in subjects, because confidence is a stereotype attached to successful
individuals.
But (i) there is no evidence in the social psychology literature that a
14
success prime induces overconfidence in subjects;25 and (ii) if the prime was inducing
overconfidence, it would induce it in the form of overplacement as opposed to the
illusion of control of outcomes. Contrary to the illusion of control of random outcomes,
overplacement should not affect decisions under risk in a pure game of chance, because
individual ability or effort cannot affect the outcomes. Hence, Experiment 3 could also
be interpreted as a placebo test to show that overconfidence in the form of overplacement
does not affect the risk attitudes of men in a pure game of chance.
Design and Procedure. I recruited 340 subjects on Amazon Mechanical Turk (mTurk)
in May 2012 (first session) and October 2012 (second session), and invited them to
work on a survey on creative writing to earn $0.5, and a bonus by picking lotteries.
I restricted the subject pool to mTurk Workers in the United States and with more
than 95% of lifetime tasks approved by requesters. Table 2 describes the experimental
design, which was a 2 (male, female) by 3 (control, overconfidence prime, success prime)
factorial design. I excluded 17 subjects (5% of sample) because of inconsistencies in
the lottery choices, leading to a final sample of 323 subjects. I assigned subjects in
equal proportions to the three experimental conditions. The first and third stages of
the experimental procedure were the same as in Experiment 1. In the second stage,
subjects in the control condition recalled an event in which they felt relaxed. Subjects
in the overconfidence-prime condition recalled an event in which they had power over an
individual or individuals. Subjects in the success-prime condition recalled an event in
which they felt successful. All subjects described the events in 5-10 sentences.
Results. I measure subjects’ tolerance to risk before and after the treatment, as well as
its change, as in Experiment 1. Panel A of Table 3 reports the estimated coefficients for
the following OLS equation:
∆RiskT oleranceiae = α+γ1 ×Overconf idenceP rimeiae +γ2 ×SuccessP rimeiae +ηa +ηe +iae
(3)
Column (3) of Panel A of Table 3 shows that men induced with overconfidence choose
lotteries over certainty equivalents 0.52 (s.e. 0.26) times more after the prime than before,
compared to controls. The effect is robust to adding age- and education-group fixed
25
Clearly the missing evidence may be merely due to publication bias.
15
effects.26
The size of the effect of the overconfidence prime on men’s risk tolerance
is similar to the size of the effect of the identity manipulations on risk tolerance in
Experiment 1. This similarity is consistent with the similar characterizations of male
and powerful individuals in Table 1. Once I add women in Panel B of Table 3, the effect
of power on men is still positive (0.44), but I cannot reject the null that the coefficient is
zero at plausible levels (s.e. 0.42).
The estimated coefficient on the elation-state treatment, SuccessP rime, is always close
to zero in magnitude and statistically indifferent from zero. This result suggests that
inducing a state of elation in men, or inducing overconfidence in the form of overplacement,
hardly drives the increase in risk tolerance after the identity or overconfidence primes.
Contrary to Experiment 1, the effect of the control condition on the omitted categories
is on average negative. A t-test for whether the mean is different from zero within the
omitted categories cannot reject the null at any conventional level of significance. But
this non-result may be driven by the low power of a test with few observations. This is
why, in the next section that looks at risky decisions framed as investment opportunities,
I ask all subjects to recall and describe a situation when they felt relaxed, which primes
the same state as the control manipulation in Experiment 1 and Experiment 3.27
5
Identity, Overconfidence, and Investment Decisions
In the previous sections, I found a positive effect of gender identity salience and threat
on men’s willingness to take risk. I tested for whether a beliefs channel may help explain
this effect, and I found evidence consistent with an effect of identity stereotypes on men’s
subjective beliefs of experiencing good outcomes in a pure game of chance, and a positive
effect of inducing overconfidence on their willingness to take risks.
I move on to test whether the manipulations I have studied so far – identity and
overconfidence – may also explain men’s choices in risky settings that are framed as
investment decisions, instead of lotteries. Looking at investment decisions is relevant,
because it can provide a causal test for the correlational evidence on the effects of
26
One subject did not report his education level.
Moreover, Experiment 3 differs from all other experiments on the gender composition of the sample.
Recruitment on mTurk cannot discriminate by gender, and about 60% of U.S. Workers are women (Mason
and Suri, 2011). Contrary to all other experiments, in Experiment 3 there are more subjects who declare
to be men than women (see Table 2)
27
16
gender and overconfidence on men’s investment decisions in the field, which have been
documented in a large literature in Economics and Finance, both for individual investors
(e.g., Barber and Odean, 2001), and for corporate executives (e.g., Malmendier and
Tate, 2008; Malmendier and Tate, 2005; Gervais et al., 2011; Hirshleifer and Han, 2012;
Ben-David et al., 2013).
A
Identity, Overconfidence, and Individual Investments
In Experiment 4, I test if identity and overconfidence affect the behavior of men when
facing simple investment decisions.
Design and Procedure. I recruited 240 subjects on Amazon Mechanical Turk (mTurk)
in September 2012, and invited them to work on a survey on creative writing for $0.5,
plus a bonus by performing simple investment decisions. I restricted the subject pool
to mTurk workers in the United States, and with more than 95% of lifetime tasks
approved by requesters. The experimental design was a 2 (male, female) by 3 (control,
male identity prime, overconfidence prime) factorial design. I excluded six subjects (3%
of whole sample) who did not write meaningful words in the priming task, leading to
a final sample of 234 subjects. I assigned subjects in equal proportions to the three
experimental conditions. The experimental procedure was as follows. In the first stage,
subjects answered four background questions. To address the concern that a change in
the behavior of control subjects could drive the results, all subjects recalled a situation
in which they felt relaxed, which is the condition that the control manipulation aims to
induce. In the second stage, the control and male prime conditions were the same as
in Experiment 1. The overconfidence prime was the induction of a sense of power in
Experiment 3.
The third stage consisted of the investment decisions. I gave subjects a virtual endowment
of $100 at the beginning of each of three periods.
Each period, subjects faced an
opportunity, and decided how much of their per-period endowment to invest, if any
(Gneezy and Potters, 1997). The first opportunity succeeded with probability 1/2 and
paid off three times the invested amount in case of success. The second and third
opportunities succeeded with probability 1/6 and paid off seven times the invested
amount. I presented the three opportunities to subjects in random order. They could not
17
invest less than zero, that is, pay to avoid a choice. A random-number generator calibrated
to the objective probabilities of each opportunity determined good or bad outcomes.
Subjects received feedback about the outcomes immediately after their choices. The aim
was to verify the effects of identity and overconfidence were not confined to experiences
of good outcomes, but they survived even after experiencing negative outcomes, which is
what I find.28 Subjects were paid a scaled amount of what they were left with at the end
of the experiment in the form of a bonus payment on top of the show-up fee.
Results.
Panel A of Figure 5 shows the average take-up rate across experimental
conditions. Subjects in the male identity and power prime conditions were more likely to
invest than controls. I estimate the following probit model to make statistical inference
on the effects of primes on the extensive margin of investment:
Pr(Invest = 1)iae = Φ(α + γ1 × M aleP rimeiae + γ2 × Overconf idenceP rimeiae + ηa + ηe )
(4)
where Investiae equals 1 if subject i in age group a and education-level group e accepted to
invest any positive amount, and zero otherwise. Φ(.) is the normal cdf, and covariates are
defined as in Equation 1. Panel A of Table 4 reports the average marginal effects derived
from the estimated coefficients. Standard errors are clustered at the subject level, because
subjects made three investment decisions. Column (1) shows that men primed with male
identity are 12 percentage points (s.e. 6.5 p.p.) more likely to invest than controls, who
invest on average 65% of the times. The effect is robust to averaging out fixed age and
education effects. Men primed with power invest 17 percentage points (s.e. 6.8 p.p.) more
often than controls. Unreported results are similar if I estimate the marginal effects in a
linear probability model.
Panel B of Table 4 refers to the intensive margin of investment. The invested amount is
censored to the right ($100) and to the left ($0), hence I estimate a tobit specification.
Covariates are as in Equation 1. Standard errors are clustered at the subject level. Because
estimated coefficients are within the censoring interval, I interpret them similarly to OLS
coefficients. In column (1), subjects primed with male identity invest on average $16
28
The immediate feedback after the investments is also the reason why Experiment 4 and Experiment
5 have a between-subjects design: differentiating between treatment conditions across subjects that had
experienced positive or negative outcomes in first stage investments would have increased the number of
experimental cells, and eliminated the statistical power advantage of the within-subject design.
18
dollars more in each opportunity than controls, but the effect is not statistically significant.
Averaging out age and education effects (column (2)) increases the size of the estimated
coefficient to about $21 (s.e. $10), which is an economically and statistically significant
effect. Subjects primed with power invest about $17 (s.e. $9) more than control subjects
in the baseline specification of column (1). The size of the effect increases to about $23
(s.e. $10) once age and education fixed effects are averaged out.
B
Identity, Overconfidence, and Delegated Investments
In Experiment 5, I test for the effects of identity on delegated investments in a setting
where the conflict of interest between the principal and the agent is minimal. This setting
is important to ensure that the overconfidence of agents predicts overinvestment, but there
is only a minor scope for agency-based explanations of overinvestment. To reproduce this
setting, I change the framing of the investment tasks to include a principal on whose
behalf the subjects invest, which aims to mimic the investment choices of mutual fund
managers or corporate executives in the field. If the subjects’ preferences are the same as
those of the fictitious principal,29 the interests of the principal and agent are aligned in
this setting, because the compensation of the agent is a fixed proportion of the principal’s
revenues. Because of this feature, the experiment can be interpreted as a causal test of
Malmendier and Tate (2005), where overconfident CEOs overinvest when they have access
to cheap funds because they believe they act in the best interest of shareholders.
I also allow for money-burning investment opportunities, because the field evidence on
overconfidence and investment behavior by individual investors and executives has shown
that the negative effects of overconfidence are mainly concentrated in money-burning
investment projects, such as diversifying mergers (e.g., Malmendier and Tate, 2008)
Design and Procedure. I recruited 220 subjects on Amazon Mechanical Turk (mTurk)
in October 2012, and invited them to work on a survey on creative writing for $0.5, plus
a chance to earn a bonus by performing simple investment decisions. I restricted the
subject pool to Workers in the United States who had more than 95% of tasks approved
by requesters. The experimental design was a 2 (male, female) by 2 (control, male prime)
29
The instructions for this experiment are in Appendix A. Importantly, the subjects were asked to
imagine they were managing the money of Sally, a lady in their neighborhood who was unable to invest
her own savings by herself, hence there was no deception on the nature of the principal in these investment
games.
19
factorial design. Given the strikingly similar effects of overconfidence and identity primes
on investment decisions in Experiment 4, and the similar categorization of stereotypes
attached to a male individual and a powerful individual in Table 1, I increased the power
of this test by only using one of the two treatment conditions, the male identity prime.
I excluded seven subjects (3% of whole sample) who did not write meaningful words in
the priming task, leading to a final sample of 213 subjects. I assigned subjects in equal
proportions to the experimental conditions.
The procedure was the same as in Experiment 4, except for the third stage. Investments
were framed as delegated decisions: in each of two periods, subjects had to imagine they
were given money by Sally, a lady in their neighborhood who wanted to invest her money
instead of keeping it in her checking account, but was unable to do so. Each period,
subjects faced an investment opportunity. They decided if and how much of Sally’s
endowment they wanted to invest. Their compensation would be a performance-based
fee, calculated as a fraction of the amount Sally ended up with after all the investment
decisions. One opportunity succeeded with probability 1/2 and paid off 2.2 times the
invested amount (sound investment). The other opportunity succeeded with probability
1/2 and paid off 1.8 times the invested amount (money-burning investment). A riskneutral agent would have invested her whole endowment in the first case, and nothing in
the second case. The opportunities were presented in random order to subjects. Each
period, subjects could not invest more than their endowment or less than zero.
Results. Columns (3) and (4) of Panel A of Table 4 report the marginal effects implied
by the estimated coefficients of the specification in Equation 4, but with the male-identityprime category only. Men whose identity is primed are 10.7 percentage points more likely
than control men to invest (s.e. 5.0 p.p.). The effect is robust to controlling for age and
education effects, and to computing the marginal effects with a linear probability model
(untabulated). Panel B of Table 4 shows results for estimating a tobit model whose
dependent variable is the invested amount in the two opportunities, censored at $0 at
$100. Men whose identity is primed invest on average $27.4 more (s.e. $9.8) than controls.
The effect on the intensive margin of investment is robust to controlling for age and
education effects. In Panel B of Figure 4, I report the average invested amounts separately
for the sound and the money-burning investments across experimental conditions. The
20
difference on the intensive margin is larger for the money-burning opportunity than for
the sound opportunity, in line with the correlational evidence of Malmendier and Tate
(2008). Note that this difference between opportunities is driven by the mistakes of primed
men: whereas controls on average shy away from the money-burning opportunity, as they
should, primed subjects invest similar amounts in the sound and the money-burning
opportunities.
6
Identity vs. Biology: Effect Across Cohorts
To better understand why identity affects risk attitudes and investment decisions, I move
on to test if the effects change as the perception of gender stereotypes evolves. Alesina
et al. (2013) show the perception of gender roles varies across countries. Fernandez and
Fogli (2009) exploit the variation in cultural stereotypes across native and immigrant
U.S. individuals. In my setting, all subjects are from the U.S., and I do not observe the
immigration status of the subjects. I cannot exploit cross-regional variation in stereotypes
within the U.S. because the IRB-approved protocol does not allow me to use the IP
addresses of the subjects in the analysis. I therefore exploit the variation in gender
identity stereotypes over time: with the gradual expansion of women’s rights, the roles
of the two genders in society, and hence gender identity stereotypes, have become closer
(Goldin et al., 2006: Doepke and Tertilt, 2009; and Glaeser and Ma, 2013).
The genetic characteristics of individuals have not changed significantly over the last
four decades. Instead, biological characteristics change as individuals age in the opposite
direction of the perception of stereotypes. Since Williams (1966), evolutionary biology has
argued that the risky behavior of male subjects of various species, including Homo Sapiens,
is fueled by competition to access more mating opportunities. This fact is particularly true
for young individuals, who have no established reputations within communities. A large
body of neurological evidence (e.g., surveyed by Casey et al., 2008) finds that risk taking
increases at puberty and decreases with age. Steinberg (2008) connects these results to
the remodeling of the dopaminergic system at the time of puberty. Psychologists show
the gender gap in risk taking is larger around puberty and decreases over time (e.g., see
Byrnes et al., 1999).
If the effect of identity salience is higher the higher the difference in male and female
21
stereotypes, the effects of male identity on subjects’ risk tolerance and investments should
be larger for older cohorts of men. In Figure 6, I run the analyses of Experiment 1 and
Experiment 4 separately for four cohorts of men. I look at subjects born before 1975,
between 1976 and 1983, between 1984 and 1989, and between 1990 and 1994.30 Panel A
of Figure 6 shows the effect of identity salience on the change in risk tolerance is highest
for subjects born before 1975, and it fades away monotonically to become insignificantly
negative for men born after 1990. A similar pattern exists for the effect of male identity
on the probability to invest (Panel B of Figure 6). Panel C of Figure 6 shows the effect
of male identity on the amount invested in Experiment 4 is also higher for those born
earlier, although the decreasing pattern is not monotonic. These results also speak to
the external validity of the effects, because older individuals are on average wealthier and
are more likely to invest than the youngsters.
The results across cohorts warrant two comments.
First, I cannot disentangle the
mediating effect of cohorts (change in the societal perception of identity stereotypes over
time) from an effect of age (individual-level change in the perception of identity stereotypes
from youth to adulthood). This caveat does not affect the interpretations of the results
as long as individuals, if anything, become more conservative over time.31
But the two mechanisms have different implications for the identity effect over time. If the
results are driven by cohort effects, the aggregate effect of identity on risk tolerance and
investment decisions should fade away over time as more individuals with less stark views
on gender roles replace the older cohorts (e.g., see Guiso et al. (2008) for a cross-country
argument). If the results are partly driven by aging, the aggregate effects would fade away
more slowly over time. Second, one may be concerned the results capture some form of
regression to the mean. Young men are more likely to engage in risky behaviors than older
men. Youngsters may be so risk tolerant that the manipulations have no effect on them.
But the average risk tolerance of men before the manipulations, the average likelihood to
invest, and the average invested amounts by controls do not decrease monotonically with
age, which the regression-to-the-mean explanation requires.
30
The cohort-level analysis was designed after running the experiments, so that cohort boundaries are
effectively exogenous for the purposes of the cross-cohort test. But I cannot perform robustness checks
by varying the cohort boundaries, except from aggregating existing groups in alternative ways.
31
Biology may mediate the sensitivity to the priming: Samanez-Larkin et al. (2010) find nucleus
accumbens activity explains the varying quality of financial choices by age.
22
7
Economic Interpretation of Priming and Threatening
Identity Stereotypes
In this section, I sketch an economic interpretation of the effects of priming identity on
men based on Gennaioli, Bordalo, and Shleifer (2014), which helps to organize the results
in the paper in a coherent setting.
Table 1 reports the most common types a pool of 200 anonymous respondents associate
with four identities: male, powerful, successful, and female individuals. The lists for
male and female individuals are similar to those in the pioneering work of Williams and
Bennett (1975). I interpret the enlisted characteristics as the most likely types associated
with each identity. Because the most likely types for the male and female identities do
not overlap, we can interpret them as the most representative types of each gender. In
Bordalo, Gennaioli, and Shleifer (2014), a type is representative of a group if a Bayesian
decision maker that observes the type thinks it was more likely drawn from the group
than from its complement.32
I call M the set of representative types for men, and −M the set of representative types
for women, where −M = Ω\M , and Ω, the union of male and female representative types,
covers the universe of gender-related representative types.33 Note that the set of types in
M needs not include the opposite of the types in −M .
I follow Bordalo, Gennaioli, and Shleifer (2014) and define the stereotype for a group as
a truncated probability distribution over types, where the most representative types are
assigned a positive probability weight, and the decision maker neglects all other possible
types. Thus, the stereotype is a set of beliefs decision makers hold about the probability
distribution of types associated with the assessed group.
The novelty of this paper is interpreting the act of priming as an exogenous shock to the
probability distribution over the types the subjects associate with their identity. Before
the act of priming, subjects assess their type based on all the social groups to which
they belong, such as gender, social class, or religious affiliation. Because in general male
subjects belong to different social groups, except for their gender group, we should observe
that absent any intervention men have heterogeneous risk attitudes and beliefs. But after
32
33
This definition of representativeness builds on Kahneman and Tversky (1972.)
There is no scope for gender-related types different from those associated with men or women.
23
the gender identity prime, subjects’ beliefs about their own types are determined by the
most representative types of their gender identity, and the non-gender-related types for
the other social groups to which the subject belongs are neglected.
Importantly, I also interpret the act of threatening subjects’ gender identity as an
exogenous shock to the probability distribution over the types the subjects associate
with their own gender identity. This interpretation follows from the fact that the threats
in the experiments consist of priming the other gender’s most representative types, hence
for the case of men, −M . Making −M salient to men cannot have them relate to the
types in −M , because those types are not part of men’s gender identity. Instead, priming
−M makes it salient to subjects that they should assess their type based on the social
group ”gender,” which, for the case of men, includes the representative types in M , and
not in −M . This interpretation of gender identity threats is crucial to rationalize the
same directional results of priming and threatening male identity on men’s willingness to
engage in risky behaviors, which is documented in the social psychology literature (Maas
et al., 2003; Willer et al., 2013), and is documented in this paper for the case of risk
attitudes and investment decisions.
Akerlof and Kranton (2000) argue that stereotypes prescribe normative behaviors to
individuals. Hence, a link exists between gender-related types and the behaviors to which
individuals conform. Suppose that any possible types associated with gender identities
could be classified in a type associated with a ”winning behavior” or with a ”losing
behavior.” Subjects will then form beliefs about the likelihood of winning as follows:
P r(win) = p = f (πt )
where πt = πt(n) /
P
πt(n) for n ∈ {1, ..., N } and N are all possible types associated with
the subject’s identity, across all the social groups to which he belongs. If a man faces
a lottery with two possible outcomes, the definition above could be interpreted as his
subjective probability of winning the higher payoff when entering the lottery. If the
types associated with winning and losing have a similar weight in a man’s identity, this
subjective probability would coincide with the objective probability of winning the higher
payoff when entering the lottery. Based on the interpretation of priming described above,
if a man is primed with male or female identity, he will assess his probability of winning
24
as follows:
P r(win|M ) = pˆ = f (ˆ
πt )
where π
ˆt is now the male identity stereotype, that is, the probability distribution of
P
the most representative types that belong to the male identity: π
ˆt = π
ˆt(m) / π
ˆt(m) for
m ∈ {1, ..., M } ⊂ {1, ..., N }, and 0 otherwise. The set {1, ..., M } only includes the
most representative types associated with the male identity group. The two subjective
probabilities differ in general: P r(winner|M ) will be higher or lower than P r(winner),
based on whether the most representative types for the male identity are associated with
winning or losing. I propose the following hypothesis:
Hypothesis 1. If the set of most representative male types {1, ..., M } includes more
types associated with winning behaviors than with losing behaviors compared to the full
set of possible types {1, ..., N }, then pˆ > p.
If the subset of types {1, ..., M } is more likely to include types associated with winning
than with losing, primed men become overconfident about their performance even in a
pure game of chance, because they are more likely to believe they will experience high
outcomes than what the objective probabilities for each state of the world suggest. This
distortion of beliefs due to the priming is the crucial and novel hypothesis to interpret
the results in this paper. I test directly for this hypothesis in Experiment 2, where I find
that men whose identity is primed believe they are more likely than a group of peers
to experience the winning outcome of a lottery, even if the objective probability of each
future state of the world is known.
Moreover, if men primed with their identity stereotypes become overconfident in a game of
chance, they will choose lotteries over certainty equivalents more often after being primed
than before. Intuitively, every time a subject decides whether to choose a lottery over a
certainty equivalent, she will compare the expected utility from entering the lottery with
the utility from the certain amount. Because pˆ > p, the subjective expected utility from
entering the lottery after the prime is higher than the expected utility implied by the
objective probabilities, as long as the subjects’ expected utility is strictly monotone:
Hypothesis 2. If {1, ..., M } includes more types associated with winning than {1, ..., N },
25
a primed man will require a higher certainty equivalent to give up the chance to take part
in the same lottery compared to a non-primed man.
I test Hypothesis 2 with a within-subject incentive-compatible design in Experiment 1,
where I find that men primed either with salience or threat of their identity are more
likely to choose lotteries over certainty equivalents after the manipulations compared to
before them.
Moreover, if priming male identity increases men’s subjective beliefs of experiencing higher
outcomes, primed men should be more likely to invest in risky opportunities whose
objective probabilities are known than non-primed men, because their expected utility
from investing is higher than the one implied by the objective probabilities:
Hypothesis 3. If {1, ..., M } includes more types associated with winning than {1, ..., N },
a primed man will be more likely to invest in a risky opportunity whose objective
probability of success is known than a non-primed man.
I test Hypothesis 3 in Experiment 4 for individual investment decisions, and in Experiment
5 for delegated investment decisions. In both cases, primed men invest more often and
more money than controls.
So far, the set of types associated with male identity, {1, ..., M }, was the same across men.
Bordalo, Gennaioli, and Shleifer (2014) show how the change in the representativeness of
types for each identity over time modifies the stereotypes associated with genders. I exploit
the fact that identity stereotypes have become less stark over the last decades (Goldin et
al., 2006; Doepke and Tertilt, 2009; Glaeser and Ma, 2013), to develop a hypothesis on
the predicted magnitude of the effects of priming across cohorts with different perceptions
of stereotypes:
Hypothesis 4.
If {1, ..., MOLD } includes more types associated with winning than
{1, ..., MY OU N G }, the effects of priming identity on the behavior of men should be larger
for older cohorts of men than younger cohorts of men.
In Figure 6, I show evidence in line with Hypothesis 4 for the risk attitudes and investment
decisions of men.
26
In the paper, I find no effect of priming or threatening gender identity on women. The
non-result for women can be consistent with the setup above if the most representative
types for female identity do not include more types associated with losing than with
winning. The types enlisted in Table 1, as well as the more comprehensive lists of Williams
and Bennett (1975), seem to include characteristics of both winners (smart, flirty, happy)
and losers (passive, emotional, kind). But it is surely impossible to categorize the types,
and there is no guidance on how to associate types to winning or losing behaviors in the
theoretical framework.
8
Discussion and Conclusions
I test whether social identity contributes to an explanation of the systematic heterogeneity
in risk attitudes and investment behavior across genders, because gender identity
prescribes opposite behaviors to men and women. Previous literature found conflictive
answers to this question.
In a set of artefactual field experiments, priming or threatening the identity of men
increases their risk tolerance.
Primed men invest more often and more money in
risky opportunities, even when they act as agents of a principal, and especially in
money-burning investments. The primes have no effect on the behavior of women.
To the best of my knowledge, this is the first paper that tests for the economic channels
that drive the effect of identity on risk attitudes. Manipulating identity salience affects
men’s beliefs of experiencing positive outcomes in a game of chance. Moreover, the causal
effects of identity on risk tolerance and investments decrease monotonically from older
to younger cohorts of men, consistent with the attenuation of gender-related stereotypes
over time. This result suggests different implications on the persistence of heterogeneous
behaviors across genders than biology and genetics, which is effectively stable over time.
I also analyze the interplay between identity and overconfidence, which I induce in subjects
by priming their sense of power over others. Stereotypical behaviors attached to powerful
individuals and to men are similar (Table 1). The investment behavior of men induced
with overconfidence is qualitatively and quantitatively similar to that of men primed with
male identity.
27
The results can be interpreted as a causal test of Barber and Odean (2001), who use
male gender as a proxy for overconfidence. Results on delegated investments when the
interests of principal and agent are perfectly aligned may be interpreted as a causal test
of Malmendier and Tate (2005). At the same time, the results can be seen as an empirical
test of Gervais, Heaton, and Odean (2011), who show that overconfident agents are less
conservative than other agents when investing in sound opportunities. This finding is
consistent with Hirshleifer, Low, and Teoh (2012).
Consistent with the trade-off between the positive effects of self-serving beliefs and the
risks of overconfidence of Benabou and Tirole (2002), the welfare implications of the results
are driven by the quality of the opportunities individual investors and CEOs face.34 If
the opportunities have a positive net present value, male identity and overconfidence
benefit men by increasing their willingness to invest. But they cause men to overinvest
in money-burning opportunities if not tied by liquidity constraints.
These results can be the basis for research efforts that better characterize the sources
of biased beliefs. Understanding the roots of biased beliefs has relevant implications for
hiring firms who need to screen potential managers and employees, as well as to design
policies that reduce the emergence of distorted beliefs if they hurt the decision makers.
A fruitful avenue for future research is also to study the interactions between identity and
biology to better understand financial decisions. mTurk does not allow to reliably collect
information on the biological characteristics of subjects, but laboratories or field settings
that the experimenter can physically reach may allow for such analysis.
The priming techniques employed in the paper show that identity and overconfidence can
be manipulated. Male identity and overconfidence cues may be used to design policies
or compensation contracts that foster individual investors’ and executives’ willingness to
take on financial risks. Figure 13 of Appendix B shows that financial firms seem to believe
in the effects of priming the identity and overconfidence of potential clients to boost the
take-up rates of their risky products. Future research should be devoted to testing for the
causal effects of cues and priming on financial decisions in the field.
34
All claims of external validity are subject to the caveat that there is no uncertainty in the experiments
in the paper
28
References
G. Akerlof and R. Kranton. Economics and Identity. Quarterly Journal of Economics,
115(3):715–753, 2000.
A. Alesina, P. Giuliano, and N. Nunn. On the Origins of Gender Roles: Women and the
Plough. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 128(2):469–530, 2013.
B. Barber and T. Odean. Boys will be Boys: Gender, Overconfidence and Common Stock
Trading. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116(1):261–292, 2001.
I. Ben David, J. Graham, and C. Harvey. Managerial Miscalibration. Quarterly Journal
of Economics, 128(4):1547–1584, 2013.
R. Benabou and J. Tirole. Self-Confidence and Personal Motivation. Quarterly Journal
of Economics, 117(3):871–915, 2002.
D. Benjamin, J. Choi, and J. Strickland. Social Identity and Preferences. American
Economic Review, 100(3):1913–1928, 2010.
D. Benjamin, J. Choi, and G. Fisher. Religious Identity and Economic Behavior. Working
Paper, 2013.
A. Berinsky, G. Huber, and G. Lenz. Evaluating Online Labor Markets for Experimental
Research: Amazon.com’s Mechanical Turk. Political Analysis, 20(3):351–368, 2012.
B. Biais, D. Hilton, K. Mazurier, and S. Pouget. Judgemental Overconfidence, SelfMonitoring and Trading Performance in an Experimental Financial Market. Review of
Economic Studies, 72(2):287–312, 2005.
P. Bordalo, N. Gennaioli, and A. Shleifer. Stereotypes. NBER Working paper No. w20106,
2014.
A. Boschini, A. Muren, and M. Persson. Constructing Gender Differences in the
Economics Lab. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, pages 741–752, 2012.
A. Boschini, A. Dreber, E. von Essen, A. Muren, and E. Ranehill. Gender and Economic
Preferences in a Large Random and Representative Sample. Working Paper, 2014.
T. Breda and S. Ly. Stereotypes, Discrimination, and the Gender Gap in Science. Working
Paper, 2014.
J.P. Byrnes, D.C. Miller, and W.D. Schafer. Gender Differences in Risk Taking: A
Meta-Analysis. Psychological Bulletin, pages 367–383, 1999.
C. Camerer and D. Lovallo. Overconfidence and Excess Entry: An Experimental
Approach. American Economic Review, 89(1):306–318, 1999.
P. Carr and C. Steele. Stereotype Threat Affects Financial Decision Making. Psychological
Science, 21(10):1411–1416, 2010.
29
B.J. Casey, R.M. Jones, and T. Hare. The Adolescent Brain. Annals of the New York
Academy of Sciences, pages 111–126, 2008.
K. Casler, L. Bickel, and E. Hackett. Separate but Equal? A Comparison of Participants
and Data Gathered via Amazon’s mTurk, Social Media, and Face-to-Face Behavioral
Testing. Computers in Human Behavior, 29(6):2156–2160, 2013.
D. Cesarini et al. Genetic Variation in Financial Decision Making. Journal of Finance,
65:1725–1754, 2010.
J. Coates and J. Herbert. Endogenous Steroids and Financial Risk Taking on a London
Trading Floor. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 105:623–628, 2008.
K. Coffman. Evidence onl Self-Stereotyping and the Contribution of Ideas. Quarterly
Journal of Economics, forthcoming.
A. Cohn, M. Mar´echal, and T. Noll. Bad Boys: the Effect of Criminal Identity on
Dishonesty. Working Paper, 2014.
A. Cohn, J. Engelmann, E. Fehr, and M. Marechal. Evidence for Countercyclical Risk
Aversion: An Experiment with Financial Professionals. American Economic Review,
forthcoming.
H. Cronqvist, A. Previtero, S. Siegel, and R. White. The Fetal Origin Hypothesis in
Finance: Prenatal Environment and Financial Risk Taking. Working Paper, 2014.
R. Croson and U. Gneezy. Gender Differences in Preferences. Journal of Economic
Literature, 47(2):1–17, 2009.
M. Doepke and M. Tertilt. Women’s Liberation: What’s in it for Men? Quarterly Journal
of Economics, 124(4):1541–1591, 2009.
T. Dohmen, A. Falk, D. Huffman, U. Sunde, J. Schupp, and G. Wagner. Individual Risk
Attitudes: Measurement, Determinants, and Behavioral Consequences. Journal of the
European Economic Association, 9(3), 2011.
N. Fast, N. Sivanathan, N. Mayer, and A. Galinsky. Power and Overconfident Decision
Making. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 117(2):249–260,
2012.
R. Fernandez and A. Fogli. Culture: An Empirical Investigation of Beliefs, Work, and
Fertility. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 1(1):146–177, 2009.
A. Gandhi and R. Serrano-Padial. Does Belief Heterogeneity Explain Asset Prices: The
Case of the Longshot Bias. Review of Economic Studies, forthcoming.
N. Garleanu and S. Panageas. Young, Old, Conservative, and Bold: Implications
of Heterogeneity and Finite Lives for Asset Pricing. Journal of Political Economy,
forthcoming.
30
S. Gervais and T. Odean. Learning to be Overconfident. Review of Financial Studies,
14(1):1–27, 2001.
S. Gervais, J.B. Heaton, and T. Odean. Overconfidence, Compensation Contracts, and
Capital Budgeting. Journal of Finance, 66(5):1735–1777, 2011.
E. Glaeser and Y. Ma. The Supply of Gender Stereotypes and Discriminatory Beliefs.
NBER Working Paper No. 19109, 2013.
U. Gneezy and Potters. An Experiment on Risk Taking and Evaluation Periods. Quarterly
Journal of Economics, 112:631–645, 1997.
C. Goldin, L. Katz, and I. Kuziemko. The Homecoming of American College Women. The
Reversal of the College Gender Gap. Journal of Economic Persectives, 20(4):133–156,
2006.
M. Grinblatt and M. Keloharju. Sensation Seeking, Overconfidence, and Trading Activity.
Journal of Finance, 64(2):549–578, 2009.
L. Guiso and M. Paiella. Risk Aversion, Wealth, and Background Risk. Journal of the
European Economic Association, 6(6):1109–1150, 2008.
L. Guiso, F. Monte, P. Sapienza, and L. Zingales. Culture, Gender, and Math. Science,
320:1164–1165, 2008.
D. Hirshleifer, A. Low, and S. H. Teoh. Are Overconfident CEOs Better Innovators?
Journal of Finance, 67(4):1457–1498, 2012.
C. Holt and S. Laury. Risk Aversion and Incentive Effects in Lottery Choices. American
Economic Review, 92:1644–1655, 2002.
J. Horton, D. Rand, and R. Zeckhauser. The Online Laboratory: Conducting Experiments
in a Real Labor Market. Experimental Economics, 14:399–425, 2011.
D. Kahneman and A. Tversky. Subjective Probability: a Judgement of Representativeness. Cognitive Psychology, 3(3):430–454, 1972.
C. Kuhnen and J. Chiao. Genetic Determinants of Financial Risk-Taking. PLosONE,
4(2), 2009.
C. Kuhnen and B. Knutson. The Influence of Affect on Beliefs, Preferences and Financial
Decisions. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 46(3):605–626, 2011.
I. Kuziemko, M. Norton, E. Saez, and S. Stantcheva. How Elastic are Preferences for
Redistribution? Evidence from Randomized Survey Experiments. NBER Working
Paper 18865, 2013.
J. List. Why Economist Should Conduct Field Experiments and 14 Tips for Pulling One
Off. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 25(3):3–16, 2011.
31
A. Maas, M. Cadinu, G. Guarnieri, and A. Grasselli. Sexual Harassment under Social
Idetity Threat: the Computer Harassment Paradigm. Journal of Personality and Social
Psychology, 85(5):853–870, 2003.
U. Malmendier and G. Tate. CEO Overconfidence and Corporate Investments. Journal
of Finance, 60(6):2661–2700, 2005.
W. Mason and S. Suri. Conducting Behavioral Research on Mechanical Turk. Behavioral
Research Methods, 44(1):1–23, 2012.
D. Mastripieri, P. Sapienza, and L. Zingales. Gender Differences in Financial Risk
Aversion and Career Choices are Affected by Testosterone. Proceedings of the National
Academy of Sciences, pages 526–556, 2009.
K. Meier-Pesti and E. Penz. Sex or Gender? Expanding the sex-based view by introducing
masculinity and femininity as predictors of financial risk-taking. Journal of Economic
Psychology, 29:180–196, 2008.
W. Mischel. A Social Learning View of Sex Differences in Behavior. The Development of
Sex Differences, E.E. Maccoby (Ed.) - Stanford University Press:56–81, 1966.
M. Niederle and L. Vesterlund. Do Women Shy away from Competition? Do Men
Compete too Much? Quarterly Journal of Economics, 122(3):1067–1101, 2007.
G. Paolacci, J. Chandler, and P. Ipeirotis. Running Experiments on Amazon Mechanical
Turk. Judgment and Decision Making, 5(5):411–419, 2010.
E. Reuben, P. Sapienza, and L. Zingales. How Stereotypes Impair Women’s Careers in
Science. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 111(12):4403–4408, 2014.
G. Samanez-Larkin, C. Kuhnen, D. Yoo, and B. Knutson. Variability in Nucleus
Accumbens Activity Mediates Age-Related Suboptimal Financial Risk Taking. Journal
of Neuroscience, 30(4):1426–1434, 2010.
M. Shih, T. Pittinsky, and N. Ambady. Stereotype Susceptibility: Identity Salience and
Shifts in Quantitative Performance. Psychological Science, 10(1):80–83, 1999.
U. Simonsohn. Just Post It: The Lesson From Two Cases of Fabricated Data Detected
by Statistics Alone. Psychological Science, 24(10):1875–1888, 2013.
C. Steele. A Threat in the Air: How stereotypes shape intellectual identity and
performance. American Psychologist, 52:613–629, 1997.
L. Steinberg. A Social Neuroscience Perspective on Adolescent Risk-Taking. Developmental Review, pages 78–106, 2008.
R. Willer, C. Rogalin, B. Conlon, and M. Wojnowicz. Overdoing Gender: a Test of the
Masculine Overcompensation Thesis. American Journal of Sociology, 118:980–1022,
2013.
G.C. Williams. Adaptation and Natural Selection. Princeton University Press, 1966.
32
25
30
Latitude
35
40
45
50
Figure 1: Location of Subjects
-120
-110
-100
Longitude
Experiment 2
-90
-80
-70
Experiment 3
Figure 1 depicts the location of the subjects in Experiment 2 and Experiment 3
based on their IP address.
33
Figure 2: Risk Tolerance Elicitation and Measure
Risk Neutral Agent choice:
RN choices = 10
Subject’s choice:
# choices = 13
Risk Tolerancei =
10-13 = -3
Figure 2 describes the construction of the Risk Tolerance measure based on the
subject’s choices. Subjects face a set of screens, each including a variable number
of choices between a decreasing certainty equivalent and a fixed lottery. The Risk
Tolerance measure is the difference between the number of times a risk neutral agent
would choose the certainty equivalent in the screen, and the number of times the
subjects chooses the certainty equivalent in the screen.
34
Figure 3: Changes in Risk Tolerance induced by the Identity Manipulations
Density Risk Tolerance before manipulations
0
.05
.1
.15
.2
Cumulative Distribution Risk Tolerance before manipulations
0
.2
.4
.6
.8
1
(a) Distribution of Risk Tolerance before the manipulations (male subsample)
-10
-5
0
Control
Female Prime
5
Male Prime
-10
-5
0
5
risklevpre
Control
Female Prime
Male Prime
Cumulative Change in Risk Tolerance
.2
.4
.6
.8
.4
.3
.2
0
.1
-4
0
Estimated Density Change in Risk Tolerance
1
(b) Distribution of ∆ Risk Tolerance induced by the manipulations (male subsample)
-4
-2
0
2
4
6
-2
0
Control
Female Prime
2
4
6
Male Prime
Figure 3 plots the estimated densities and cumulative distributions for the risk tolerance
before the manipulations (panel A) and the subject-level change in risk tolerance before and
after exposure to the experimental conditions (panel B) in Experiment 1 for male subjects.
The subject-level change in risk tolerance is measured as follows: ∆RiskT olerancei =
RiskT olerancepost,i − RiskT olerancepre,i , where RiskT olerancepre,i and RiskT olerancepost,i
are elicited via lottery choices a la Holt and Laury (2002). The smooth density plots use
an Epanechnikov kernel with bandwidth of 0.7. The cumulative distribution plots interpolate
the medians of 10 vertical bands with cubic splines. The plots of the distributions for the female
subsample are in Appendix B.
35
Figure 4: Identity Manipulations and Beliefs under Risk
4.6
Predicted Wins if Lottery played 10 times (p=0.5)
4.8
5
5.2
5.4
5.6
(a) Subjective beliefs of experiencing the good outcome in a lottery that succeeds on average
5 out of 10 times
Control Men
Primed Men
-.4
Own minus Neighbor Predicted Wins (p=0.5)
-.2
0
.2
.4
.6
(b) Better-than-average beliefs across experimental conditions (men only)
Control Men
Primed Men
Panel (a) of Figure 4 plots the subjective beliefs of experiencing the good outcome by gender
for subjects who imagine to play 10 times a lottery whose good outcome obtains on average 5
out of 10 times. Bandwidths are 95% confidence intervals for estimated means. Panel (b) of
Figure 4 plots the average subjective better-than-average beliefs for men in the control group
and in the primed group, which collects the male identity (salience) and female identity (threat)
primes.
36
Figure 5: Identity, Extensive and Intensive Margins of Investment
1
Number of Times Invested (out of 3)
2
3
(a) Times invested out of 3 opportunities (men only)
Control
Male Prime
Power Prime
30
Amount Invested (out of $100)
40
50
60
70
(b) Dollars Invested in Delegated Opportunities (men only)
Control Sound
Male Prime Sound Control Bad Inv. Male Prime Bad Inv.
Panel (a) of Figure 5 reports the average number of times that male subjects invest out of three
potential opportunities in Experiment 3, where all the investment opportunities have a positive
NPV, across experimental conditions. Panel (b) of Figure 5 reports the average amount of
money (in experimental dollars) the subjects invest in Experiment 5 across the experimental
conditions, and separately for sound and money-burning investment opportunities.
37
Figure 6: Identity vs. Biology: Effects of Identity across Cohorts
-.2
Effect of Male prime on Change in Risk Tolerance
0
.2
.4
.6
.8
(a) Effect of Male Identity prime on Risk Tolerance by cohorts (men only)
Born before 1975 Born 1976-1983
Born 1984-1989
Born 1990-1994
Marginal Effect of Male Prime on Probability to Invest
-.1
0
.1
.2
.3
(b) Effect of Male Identity prime on Probability to Invest by cohorts (men only)
Born before 1975 Born 1976-1983
Born 1984-1989
Born 1990-1994
-20
Effect of Male Prime on Amount Invested
0
20
40
60
(c) Effect of Male Identity prime on Amount Invested by cohorts (men only)
Born before 1975 Born 1976-1983
Born 1984-1989
Born 1990-1994
Panel (a)-(c) of Figure 6 plot the effect of the male identity manipulations on the change in
risk tolerance in Experiment 1, the likelihood that subjects invest in Experiment 4, and the
average amount invested in Experiment 4, across four cohorts of subjects based on their year
of birth.
38
Figure 7: Manipulation Check for Experiment 1
0
Number of Male Types from Table 1 in Essay
1
2
3
(a) Average Number of Male Types from Table 1 reported in Experiment 1
Control
Male Prime
Female Prime
0
Number of Female Types from Table 1 in Essay
1
2
3
(b) Average Number of Female Types from Table 1 reported in Experiment 1
Control
Male Prime
Female Prime
Figure 7 reports the results for the manipulation check for Experiment 1. Panel (a) shows the
average number of times each subject reported any of the types related to male individuals
enlisted in Table 1 in their essays, by experimental conditions. Panel (b) shows the average
number of times each subject reported any of the types related to female individuals enlisted in
Table 1 in their essays, by experimental conditions. The bars represent 95% confidence intervals
for the arithmetic mean within each group of subjects.
39
Figure 8: Testing for the Scope of Demand Effects
(a) Reported Motives for the Reading and Essay Tasks (100 subjects)
35
28
21
14
7
0
No Idea
Distraction
Collect
Opinions
Check if
Human
Relate to Manipulation
Lotteries
(b) Reported Motives for the Lottery Tasks (100 subjects)
30
25
20
15
10
5
0
No Idea
For Bonus Won't Use Measure
Risk
Relate to Change in
text
Risk
Figure 8 reports results for 100 subjects recruited in June and July 2014 to perform the tasks
in Experiment 1 following the same recruitment procedures as described in the paper. These
subjects were also asked to guess the motivations of the tasks at the end of the study. Panel (a)
reports the distribution of answers for why subjects had to read a text and write a short essay,
split into six broad categories. The dark histogram to the right (8 subjects) shows the answers
compatible with the aim of the study. Panel (b) shows the distribution of answers for why
subjects had to make lottery choices before and after the writing task. The emphasis on before
and after aimed to instill the idea that the order of tasks was related to their motives. The
only category compatible with the true motives includes 9 subjects (dark, right), 8 of which
are those depicted in dark in Panel (a).
40
Table 1: Characterization of Stereotypes
MALE
POWERFUL
SUCCESSFUL
FEMALE
41
Strong
37
Strong
50
Confident
46
Caring
40
Loud
27
Confident
45
Smart
36
Emotional
34
Aggressive
26
Arrogant
19
Happy
26
Flirty
16
Confident
18
Aggressive
18
Proud
19
Passive
15
Arrogant
15
Assertive
15
Determined
15
Smart
13
Dumb
12
Dominant
13
Focused
12
Loving
13
Stubborn
11
Greedy
9
Motivated
11
Happy
12
Assertive
11
Cocky
8
Assertive
10
Gossipy
12
Proud
10
Proud
8
Ambitious
10
Helpful
10
Dominant
10
Smart
7
Strong
10
Kind
10
1 reports the words mentioned most frequently by 200 survey respondents recruited on mTurk to describe how
Table
they think a typical male individual, a powerful individual, a successful individual, or a female individual behave.
Respondents wrote 3 to 5 words for each type of individual. Types were presented in a random order. The numbers
next to each stereotypical semantic area are the number of times respondents reported a word in that area.
Table 2: Experimental Designs and Sample Descriptions
Treatment
Design
Sample
Experiment 1
Identity Salience,
2 (male-M, female-F)
Risk Attitudes
Threat
X 3 (control-C, male identity-MI, female identity-FI)
MC:55, FC:74, MMI-61,
FMI:64, MFI:32, FFI:34.
Total:320
Experiment 2
Identity Salience,
2 (male-M, female-F)
Threat
X 3 (control-C, male identity-MI, female identity-FI)
Experiment 3
Induction of
2 (male-M, female-F)
Risk Attitudes
Overconfidence
X 3 (control-C, overconfidence-O, success-S)
Experiment 4
Identity Salience,
2 (male-M, female-F)
Investments
Induction of Overconfidence
X 2 (control-C, male identity-MI, overconfidence-O)
Experiment 5
Identity Salience
2 (male-M, female-F)
Beliefs
Investments
42
X 3 (control-C, male identity-MI, overconfidence-O)
MC:50, FC:58, MMI:49,
FMI:53, MFI:53, FFI:60.
Total:323
MC:56, FC:51, MMI-54,
FMI:53, MO:59, FO:50.
Total:323
MC:35, FC:43, MMI:38,
FMI:41, MO:32, FO:45.
Total:234
MC:48, FC:60,
MMI:49, FMI:55.
Total:212
Table 2 describes the treatments, experimental designs, and sample compositions for all the experiments in the paper. On mTurk,
one cannot discriminate by gender at the recruitment stage, and about 60% of U.S. mTurk Workers are women (Mason and Suri
(2011)).
Table 3: Identity, Overconfidence, and Risk Taking
Experiment 1:
Identity
Experiment 3:
Overconfidence
(1)
(2)
Male Prime
0.507
(0.246)**
0.577
(0.264)**
Overconfidence Prime
Female Prime
0.431
(0.205)**
0.564
(0.258)**
Mean omitted
Median omitted
Session f.e.
Age group f.e.
Education f.e.
Observations
R2
-0.212
0
148
0.03
-0.212
0
X
X
X
148
0.09
(1)
(2)
Male Prime
-0.337
(0.280)
-0.286
(0.268)
Female Prime
-0.163
(0.262)
-0.089
(0.271)
Man*
Male Prime
0.844
(0.373)**
Man*
Female Prime
Man
Panel A. Men Only
Panel B. Full Sample
Mean omitted
Median omitted
Session f.e.
Age group f.e.
Education f.e.
Observations
R2
(3)
(4)
0.519
(0.259)**
0.595
(0.270)**
Success Prime
0.014
(0.260)
-0.005
(0.262)
Mean omitted
Median omitted
Session f.e.
Age group f.e.
Education f.e.
Observations
R2
-0.332
-0.167
169
0.03
-0.332
-0.167
X
X
X
168
0.12
(3)
(4)
Overconfidence Prime
0.077
(0.331)
0.122
(0.348)
Success Prime
0.263
(0.321)
0.274
(0.328)
0.836
(0.375)**
Man*
Overconfidence Prime
0.442
(0.420)
0.394
(0.444)
0.594
(0.333)*
0.659
(0.344)*
Man*
Success Prime
-0.249
(0.414)
-0.292
(0.417)
-0.257
(0.212)
-0.329
(0.223)
Man
0.048
(0.320)
0.103
(0.331)
0.045
0
0.045
0
X
X
X
320
0.10
Mean omitted
Median omitted
Session f.e.
Age group f.e.
Education f.e.
Observations
R2
-0.536
-0.333
-0.536
-0.333
X
X
X
322
0.08
320
0.02
323
0.02
Columns (1) and (2) of Table 3 report the estimated coefficients from:
∆RiskT oleranceiae = α + γ1 × M aleP rimeiae + γ2 × F emaleP rimeiae + ηa + ηe + iae
Columns (3) and (4) report the estimated coefficient from:
∆RiskT oleranceiae = α + γ1 × Overconf idenceP rimeiae + γ2 × SuccessP rimeiae + ηa + ηe + iae
where ∆RiskT oleranceiae is the within-subject change in risk tolerance for subject i, in age
group a and education group e, before and after being exposed to the treatments in Experiment
1 and Experiment 2. ηa and ηe are fixed effects for subjects’ age and education-level groups.
Hubert-White s.e. are reported in brackets. Statistical significance is reported as follows: **
5%, * 10%.
43
Table 4: Identity, Overconfidence, and Investment Decisions
Experiment 4:
Individual
Investments
Experiment 5:
Delegated
Investments
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
Male Prime
0.123
(0.065)*
0.136
(0.063)**
0.107
(0.050)**
0.105
(0.048)**
Overconfidence Prime
0.170
(0.068)**
0.173
(0.069)**
0.65
1
0.84
1
315
0.03
0.65
1
X
X
X
315
0.09
194
0.05
0.84
1
X
X
X
194
0.06
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
Male Prime
15.66
(9.92)
20.59
(9.72)**
Overconfidence Prime
16.97
(9.32)*
22.77
(9.77)**
41.7
29.0
41.7
29.0
X
X
X
315
0.03
Panel A. Probability
to Invest
Mean omitted
Median omitted
Success prob. f.e.
Age group f.e.
Education f.e.
Observations
pseudo-R2
Panel B. Amount
Invested
Mean omitted
Median omitted
Success prob. f.e.
Age group f.e.
Education f.e.
Observations
pseudo-R2
315
0.01
Male Prime
Mean omitted
Median omitted
Success prob. f.e.
Age group f.e.
Education f.e.
Observations
pseudo-R2
Male Prime
Mean omitted
Median omitted
Session f.e.
Age group f.e.
Education f.e.
Observations
pseudo/R2
27.35
(9.82)***
24.99
(9.57)**
53.3
50.0
53.3
50.0
X
X
X
194
0.02
194
0.01
Panel A of Table 4 reports the estimated coefficients from:
Pr(Invest = 1)iae = α + γ1 × M aleP rimeiae + γ2 × Overconf idenceP rimeiae + ηa + ηe )
where ηa and ηe are fixed effects for subjects’ age and education-level groups. Panel
B of Table 4 reports the estimated coefficients from a tobit regression of the amount
invested in each opportunity (censored at $0 and $100) on the Male identity prime and
Overconfidence prime indicators from Experiment 3 and Experiment 4. S.e. are clustered
at the subject level. Statistical significance is marked as follows: ** 5%, * 10%.
44
Appendix A - Experimental Materials
This Appendix provides part of the materials used in Experiments 1 through 4. Figure 8
shows the screenshot subjects faced any time they had to perform a risk aversion elicitation
lottery task a` la (Holt and Laury (2002)). For each line, subjects were asked to choose
between a lottery paying a strictly positive amount with probability 50%, zero otherwise,
and a certain amount. The certain amount decreases from one line to the other, while
the lottery is fixed. The number of times a subjects chooses the certainty equivalent is
subtracted from the number of times a risk neutral agent would pick the certain amount
over the lottery to obtain a measure for the subject’s risk tolerance (see Section 5.B). In
Experiments 1 and 2, subjects perform lottery tasks before and after being exposed to
the experimental condition, so as to obtain a within-subject measure of the change in risk
tolerance due to the experimental treatment.
Figure 9 shows the screenshot subjects faced if assigned to the male identity priming
condition. It is an excerpt from an internet blog, which makes the treatment as close
as possible to daily-life experiences by subjects, who are regular internet users. The
excerpt describes a series of characteristics attributed to the “masculine side” of life,
which are similar to the traits survey responders in Table 1 think best describe how a
typical male individual behaves. Figure 10 shows an analogous screenshot subjects faced
if assigned to the female identity priming condition. The excerpt describes a series of
characteristics attributed to the “feminine side” of life. Finally, Figure 11 shows the
screenshot subjects faced if assigned to the control condition. The excerpt, also from a
blog, describes lifestyle according to the “ayurveda principles”. In all three cases, after
reading the excerpt, subjects were asked to recall a situation when the behaved in line
with the principles presented in the text, and describe the situation, their thoughts and
feelings in detail in a short essay (5 to 10 sentences). Computing a within-subject measure
of change in risk tolerance helps to ensure results are not driven by individuals exposed
to the control condition. To further address this concern, all subjects were asked to recall
a situation when they felt relaxed, and describe it in detail before being exposed to any
experimental condition in Experiment 3 and Experiment 4.
44
Survey | Qualtrics Survey Software
Ignore Validation
Click Here to Start Over
Do Not Show Hidden Questions
Previewing Survey
Figure 8: Set of lottery pairs choice
This picture reports the screenshot of one of the sets of lottery pair choices subjects were faced with in Experiment 1 and
Experiment 2. Lottery pairs are a degenerate version of those introduced by Holt and Laury (2002).
For each line, please pick one choice by filling the corresponding circle:
$6 for sure 50% -- $7
$5.7 for sure 50% -- $7
$5.4 for sure 50% -- $7
$5.1 for sure 50% -- $7
$4.8 for sure 50% -- $7
$4.5 for sure 50% -- $7
$4.2 for sure 50% -- $7
$3.9 for sure 50% -- $7
$3.6 for sure 50% -- $7
$3.3 for sure 50% -- $7
$3 for sure 50% -- $7
$2.7 for sure 50% -- $7
$2.4 for sure 50% -- $7
$2.1 for sure 50% -- $7
$1.8 for sure 50% -- $7
$1.5 for sure 50% -- $7
$1.2 for sure 50% -- $7
$0.9 for sure 50% -- $7
$0.6 for sure 50% -- $7
$0.3 for sure 50% -- $7
$0 for sure 50% -- $7
Survey Powered By Qualtrics
https://dc-viawest.qualtrics.com/SE/?SID=SV_9H92b78shkIfoeV&Preview=Survey&BrandID=ucbpsych[10/7/2012 2:48:31 PM]
45
Previewing Survey
Ignore Validation
Do Not Show Hidden Questions
Click Here to Start Over
Figure 9: Male Identity Priming text
This picture reports the screenshot of the text subjects in the male identity prime treatment were asked to read. It is an
excerpt from a blog entry on the internet. After reading the excerpt, subjects were asked to recall a situation when the
behaved in line with the “masculine side” as presented in the text, and describe the situation, their thoughts and feelings
Please read the following short
textincarefully.
In (5
the
screens you will be asked three
in detail
a short essay
to next
10 sentences).
easy questions based on the text.
It should take you about 10 minutes to complete this section.
The Masculine Side
The Masculine Side deals with the strength of the self. It is what causes you to act either
timidly or self-confidently. The thing that is most important in determining the strength of
the masculine side, is the value that you, at a deep level, place on yourself. This is a value
you know within yourself that you have really and truly earned. It could be thought of as a
sort of self esteem. Placing a high value on yourself affects your whole being and helps you
feel strong and confident in operating your life. And, in the reverse direction, when you are
able to operate your life confidently, things can really turn around for you because you get
more out of life, and this automatically makes you place a higher value on yourself. You can
build the masculine side through progress and small wins, through positive reinforcement,
by practicing, and by doing things and generally taking an active part in operating your life.
If you have a strong masculine side, you are in charge of your own life because you are
internally controlled. You tend to look people in the eye. You stand straight, and you usually
command attention when you walk into a room, whether you say anything or not. This
happens because of the strength within. […] if you have a strong masculine side you are
self-confident, and don't feel it is necessary to show off.
The masculine side is full of things that you have to be strong and self-confident in order to
do. These include being able to claim your basic rights, such as the right to feel free to
operate independently of others, and the right to belong or fit into society in any way you
please. Claiming your rights also includes being able to stand up to people who try to take
away your rights, either by force or intimidation, or by manipulation, or by trying to hinder
you in choosing your own direction in life. The masculine side also includes the ability to
take risks when appropriate, to be decisive when necessary, and to focus or concentrate in
order to get something done. In addition, it includes being able to figure out how to
accomplish things so you can get more of what you want out of life. Part of this is being
able to figure out how to operate your life in a responsible manner, how to reason without
distorting reality and without fooling yourself, and how to accurately weigh probabilities so
that you know the most likely outcome to expect in situations you come across.
Extract from http://www.lovesedona.com/02.htm.
https://new.qualtrics.com/SE/?SID=SV_9LlRDmIFHq6VSqU&Preview=Survey&BrandID=ucbpsych[5/4/2012 8:02:25 PM]
46
Previewing Survey
Do Not Show Hidden Questions
Click Here to Start Over
Figure 10: Female Identity Priming text
This picture reports the screenshot of the text subjects in the female identity prime treatment were asked to read. It is an
excerpt from a blog entry on the internet. After reading the excerpt, subjects were asked to recall a situation when the
Please
thethe
following
text
carefully.
In the
screens
you will
asked three
behaved
in read
line with
“feminine short
side” as
presented
in the text,
andnext
describe
the situation,
theirbe
thoughts
and feelings in
easy questions based on the text.
detail in a short essay (5 to 10 sentences).
It should take you about 10 minutes to complete this section.
The Feminine Side
[…] the Feminine Side is based, […] on a value that you place on others. It could be thought
of as a sort of other esteem. The value you place on others affects your whole being. If you
have a strong feminine side and place a high value on others, you are often giving and
unselfish. You usually know what is good for people, and you tend to operate in ways that
help others get what they want out of life. You happily let people operate their own life
without interference from you, but when asked, you are also willing to help by supporting,
cooperating, and giving advice. People feel comfortable with you because you
give them who you are without pushing yourself on others.
If you have a strong feminine side, people also feel comfortable being around you because
there is no selfishness for them to detect. [… ]
If you have a strong feminine side, you often behave in ways that are considered feminine in
nature. You do things you have to be giving and unselfish in order to do. These include
recognizing the basic right of all people to use their own will to operate their own life, for
example, by allowing them freedom to operate independently, freedom to fit in where and
how they want, and freedom to choose what things to confront or face up to in life. Allowing
people their basic rights also includes allowing them to control their own life without
interference from you, to choose their own obligations in life without being manipulated by
you, and to choose their own path or direction in life without hindrance from you. The
feminine side also includes having enthusiasm and zest for life, and recognizing what things
are worth getting enthusiastic about. And it includes having the persistence and tenacity to
stay with things to the end, while still knowing when to give up on something if your energy
is better used elsewhere.
In addition, the feminine side also includes being kind, compassionate, patient, responsive
to the needs of others, and it includes knowing how much energy you can put into each of
these without hurting yourself by draining your own energy.
Extract from http://www.lovesedona.com/02.htm.
https://new.qualtrics.com/...icsSurveyEngine/?SID=SV_9LlRDmIFHq6VSqU&SVID=&Preview=Block&ID=BL_0oG4krywq4d8CQQ[5/4/2012 8:19:51 PM]
47
Ignore Validation
Previewing Survey
Do Not Show Hidden Questions
Click Here to Start Over
Figure 11: Control Condition text
This picture reports the screenshot of the text subjects in the control condition were asked to read. It is an excerpt from a
blog entry on the internet. After reading the excerpt, subjects were asked to recall a situation when the behaved in line
with
the “ayurveda
principles”
as presented
in the
text, and describe
the situation,
their
thoughts
andasked four
feelings in detail in
Please
read the
following
short text
carefully.
In the next
screens
you
will be
a short essay (5 to 10 sentences).
easy questions based on the text.
It should take you about 10 minutes to complete this section.
Dincharya [Daily Routine] In Sanskrit, the word 'dincharya' means daily routine. According to Ayurveda, one should
follow the dincharya in order to lead a healthy and disease-free life. Everyday, two cycles of
change pass through the human body, each bringing a Vata, Pitta, or Kapha predominance.
Based on the cycles of vata, pitta and kapha, our daily routine should be divided into
morning, noon, evening/twilight, dinner and bedtime. In the Ayurvedic texts, it is written that
a person should wake up two hours prior to the sunrise, if he/she is not suffering from any
diseases such as fever or diarrhea. Very young, very old and sick people are some of the
exceptions.
According to dincharya, the day should be kick-started by eliminating the colon and the
bladder, followed by a through cleaning of the senses - ears, eyes, mouth etc. This should be
followed by an oil self massage. Exercise in the morning, just after the massage, helps
rejuvenate the body and soul. After bathing, one should head towards the dining table for
breakfast. The day follows by activities like studying, working or traveling. During the lunch,
one should consume nutritious meal […]. Dinner should consist of a light meal. Before going
to bed, one should sit back and relax. By following the dincharya of Ayurveda, one can
ensure a healthy life.
Though it is difficult to follow a stringent dinacharya in this fast moving life, it is highly
recommended by Ayurvedic physicians, because a number of health benefits are associated
with it. The dinacharya makes one to lead a healthy and disciplined life. According to the
latest studies in the field of medical science, people who stick to the daily routine are more
fit than those, who do not have a particular time to perform their everyday activities. It is
said that dinacharya reduces the stress level to a great extent. In addition to this, the
person's body is purified and detoxified. Therefore, barring a few exceptions like sickness,
very old and young age, Ayurvedic dinacharya is recommended for everyone.
Extract from http://ayurveda.iloveindia.com/dincharya/index.html
I am now ready to answer four questions based on the text above.
https://new.qualtrics.com/...ricsSurveyEngine/?SID=SV_9LlRDmIFHq6VSqU&SVID=&Preview=Block&ID=BL_b9HHSp9g5S0ZnFi[5/4/2012 8:14:48 PM]
48
This page reports sample essays written by subjects in the four conditions
across the experiments presented in the paper: priming relax, male identity,
female identity or power over other individuals (any typos as in the subjects’
entries.
Control condition:
I was at our lake house. The kids were reading and taking care of themselves. The lake
was calm and the bugs were scarce. All you could hear was the occasional boat, which to
me is relaxing. The sound of the tiny waves lapping at the shore in the twilight was music
to my ears. I had a book, but spent most time looking out at the mountains and clear water.
Priming male identity:
It was a typical weekend after work. [...] I was with a group of friends in a bar and in
walked the hottest group of girls that night. Every guy immediately turned their heads
to look, including me, and the girls knew it and loved it. However, everyone quickly
averted their glances thinking they were out of league. However, I remained calm and
kept my steady gaze until the one I was eyeing saw me in her sweep of the room. She
looked back, cocked her head slightly, and I saw a faint smile forming at the edge of her
lips. After about half an hour, I confidently walked up to the group of girls, straight
to the girl I picked out, and asked her to join me at the bar for a drink. The rest is history.
Priming female identity:
My best friend was recently laid off from his job and his lease to his apartment was set
to expire. Although I live with 3 other roomates, I allowed my friend to stay in my
apartment for 4 months until he got back on his feet with a full-time job. I felt a sense of
responsibility to be compassionate and help him in this situation.
Priming Power over other individuals:
When I became the executive director of my actual company, my attributions were many.
I was almost the most powerful person. I could do whatever I wanted, but I did only what
was fair for every employee. Everyone got what they deserved and they seemed satisfied
49
with me. I felt very capable and skillful. I did exactly what was right.
50
Appendix B - Additional Results
51
Table 5: Experiment 1 - Using Post-manipulation Risk Tolerance only (No
Within-subject Design)
The left panel shows results for the level of risk tolerance after the experimental
manipulations in the male subsample in Experiment 1. The right panel shows results for
the level of risk tolerance after the experimental manipulations for the all subjects in
Experiment 1. Statistical significance is marked as follows: *** 1%, ** 5%, * 10%.
(1)
Male Prime
Female Prime
(2)
Men only
(3)
(4)
(6)
0.803
0.821
0.918
-0.134
-0.138
-0.008
(0.488)
(0.501)
(0.526)*
(0.474)
(0.474)
(0.462)
0.937
0.907
0.934
-0.337
-0.407
-0.371
(0.431)**
(0.491)*
(0.500)*
(0.399)
(0.396)
(0.400)
Man*M. Prime
Man*F. Prime
Man
0.894
0.866
0.733
(0.681)
(0.689)
(0.689)
1.034
1.039
1.040
(0.596)*
(0.587)*
(0.594)*
0.087
(0.483)
Mean omitted
Median omitted
Session f.e.
Age group f.e.
Education f.e.
Observations
R2
(5)
Full Sample
X
148
0.08
-2.01
-1.67
X
X
148
0.08
X
X
X
148
0.09
52
X
320
0.06
0.080
(0.482)
-2.25
-2.5
X
X
320
0.07
0.074
(0.484)
X
X
X
320
0.11
Experiment 2
20 40 60 80 100 120
Experiment 1
61+
18-22 23-28 29-35 36-45 46-60
61+
Experiment 4
0
20 40 60 80 100 120
Experiment 3
0
20 40 60 80 100 120
18-22 23-28 29-35 36-45 46-60
0
0
20 40 60 80 100 120
Figure 12: Age Distribution of Subjects across the Experiments
18-22 23-28 29-35 36-45 46-60
61+
18-22 23-28 29-35 36-45 46-60
53
61+
Figure 13: Identity and Overconfidence cues in financial products ads
The set of pictures below are examples of financial products ads across countries and for different types of products with male identity
and overconfidence cues.
54
Figure 14: Risk Tolerance Change and Beliefs in the Female Subsamples
Panel A depicts estimated densities for the change in risk tolerance measured
at the subject level across experimental conditions in Experiment 1 (Identity
prime) for female subjects. The change in risk tolerance is measured as follows:
∆RiskT olerancei = RiskT olerancepost,i − RiskT olerancepre,i , where RiskT olerancepre,i
and RiskT olerancepost,i are elicited via lottery choices a la Holt and Laury (2002) before
and after exposure to the experimental conditions, respectively. Panel B depicts the
average measure of “better-than-average” beliefs constructed in Experiment 4 for the
female subsample across experimental conditions.
Estimated Density Change in Risk Tolerance - Women
0
.1
.2
.3
.4
A. Distribution of ∆Risk Tolerance (female subsample)
-6
-4
-2
0
2
4
x
Control
Female Prime
Male Prime
-.6
-.4
-.2
0
.2
.4
.6
B. Better-than-Average Beliefs (female subsample)
Control
55
Male and Power Prime
Table 6: Investment Decisions by the Female Subsamples
Panel A shows results for the investment decisions made by women in Experiment 3. The
left panel reports marginal effects computed from the following probit model:
P r(Invest = 1)iae = Φ(α + β × M aleP rime + γ × Overconf idenceP rime + ηa + ηe )
where Invest is 1 if subject i in age group a and education level group e invests
any positive amount, zero otherwise. Φ(.) is the normal cdf. M aleP rime and
Overconf idenceP rime equal one for subjects exposed to the male identity or power
prime; ηa and ηe are fixed effects for subjects’ age and education level groups for
female subjects. The right panel reports results for a tobit model whose dependent
variable is the amount of money a subject invests in each opportunity, which is
censored at $0 and $100. Standard errors are clustered at the subject level, and computed
with the delta method. Statistical significance is marked as follows: *** 1%, ** 5%, * 10%.
A. Experiment 3: Investment Decisions (female subsample)
Female
subsample
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
Probability of Investing
Male Prime
0.113
Overconfidence
Prime
0.137
0.135
(7)
(8)
Amount Invested
0.136
3.554
5.638
5.961
5.763
(0.076)
(0.074)*
(0.074)*
(0.073)*
(5.667)
(5.321)
(5.384)
(5.359)
-0.026
-0.017
-0.004
-0.003
-7.751
-6.813
-6.616
-6.778
11.94
14.87
-13.54
2.803
(4.48)***
(5.64)***
(15.82)
(15.32)
X
X
X
X
X
X
387
0.01
384
0.01
384
0.03
(0.073)
(0.073)
(0.074)
(0.073)
Constant
Age group f.e.
Education f.e.
Success prob. f.e
Observations
(pseudo-)R2
(6)
387
0.01
X
X
X
X
X
X
387
0.02
384
0.02
384
0.09
(6.060)
387
0.01
(5.851)
(5.864)
(5.848)
B. Experiment 4: Investment Decisions (female subsample)
Female
Subsample
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
Probability of Investing
Male Prime
0.005
(0.055)
0.001
(0.053)
(6)
Amount Invested
0.004
(0.052)
Constant
0.54
(5.37)
0.50
(5.22)
0.84
(2.18)
X
X
X
230
0.01
228
0.01
38.26
(3.92)***
Age group f.e.
Education f.e.
Observations
(pseudo-)R2
(5)
230
0.00
X
X
X
230
0.03
228
0.06
56
230
0.00
Table 7: Experiment 1 - Contribution of right tail and average to results
Panel A shows results for the change in risk tolerance in the male subsample in Experiment
1. Panel B shows results for the change in risk tolerance for the full sample of subjects
in Experiment 1. The outcome variable (∆RiskT olerance) is winsorized at the 5-95
percentiles in the left Panels, at the 10-90 percentiles in the right panels. Hubert-White
s.e. are reported in brackets. Statistical significance is marked as follows: ** 5%, * 10%.
A. Experiment 1: Winsorizing outliers (male subsample)
Male Only
(1)
M. Prime
F. Prime
(4)
(5)
(6)
Winsorize 10-90 perc.
0.319
0.336
0.335
0.293
0.306
0.304
(0.197)
(0.195)*
(0.195)*
(0.165)*
(0.161)*
(0.163)*
0.481
0.447
0.450
0.419
0.377
0.373
(0.208)**
(0.215)**
(0.221)**
(0.189)**
(0.194)*
(0.199)*
Mean omitted
Median omitted
Session f.e.
Age group f.e.
Education f.e.
Observations
R2
(2)
(3)
Winsorize 5-95 perc.
-0.170
0
X
X
X
148
0.03
148
0.09
X
X
X
X
148
0.09
148
0.04
-0.133
0
X
X
148
0.09
X
X
X
148
0.09
B. Experiment 4: Winsorizing outliers (full sample)
Full Sample
M. Prime
F. Prime
Male*M. Prime
Male*F. Prime
Male
(1)
(2)
(3)
Winsorize 5-95 perc.
Observations
R2
(5)
(6)
Winsorize 10-90 perc
-0.265
-0.269
-0.237
-0.189
-0.188
-0.169
(0.194)
(0.196)
(0.196)
(0.154)
(0.155)
(0.156)
-0.117
-0.162
-0.153
-0.088
-0.127
-0.122
(0.202)
(0.209)
(0.209)
(0.162)
(0.167)
(0.167)
0.590
0.588
0.566
0.489
0.484
0.469
(0.276)**
(0.277)**
(0.278)**
(0.225)**
(0.225)**
(0.227)**
0.628
0.650
0.643
0.543
0.557
0.553
(0.276)**
(0.280)**
(0.281)**
(0.235)**
(0.239)**
(0.241)**
-0.253
-0.262
-0.271
-0.244
-0.248
-0.252
(0.179)
Mean omitted
Median omitted
Session f.e.
Age group f.e.
Education f.e.
(4)
X
320
0.03
(0.179)
0.050
0
X
X
320
0.04
(0.182)
(0.151)
X
X
X
X
320
0.06
320
0.03
57
(0.151)
0.072
0
X
X
320
0.05
(0.154)
X
X
X
320
0.10
Table 8: Just Post It - Evidence vs. Fabricated Data
Panel A refers to the full sample, Panel B to the male subsample. For each cell the
sample mean is reported, the standard deviation is reported in round parentheses, and
the number of subjects in curly parentheses. Panel C shows results for running the test
of Simonsohn (2013) for each experiment and sample. The test consist of: (i) estimating
100,000 samples randomly drawn from a normal distribution with mean equal to the one
in the condition, and standard deviation equal to the average across conditions in each
experiment (samples are drawn from a binomial distribution with probability equal to
the mean of the extensive margins in Experiment 3 and Experiment 4); (ii) Computing
the standard deviation of the standard deviations in each drawn sample; (iii) reporting
the ratio of times that the simulated standard deviation of standard deviations are lower
than the actual one in the data.
A. Summary Statistics (full samples)
Experiment 1
Experiment 2
Experiment 3
(extensive)
Experiment 3
(intensive)
Experiment 4
(extensive)
Experiment 4
(intensive)
Experiment 5
Male Identity
Prime
Female Identity
Prime
-0.01
(1.74) {125}
0.05
(1.07) {66}
Overconfidence
Prime
-0.21
(1.43) {107}
0.680
(0.468) {231}
23.34
(28.55) {231}
0.747
(0.436) {237}
27.95
(29.81) {237}
0.904
(0.296) {208}
49.93
(32.17) {208}
0.079
(1.711) {214}
Success
Prime
-0.38
(1.37) {109}
Control
-0.06
(1.22) {129}
-0.51
(1.62) {107}
0.624
(0.485) {234}
23.41
(29.40) {234}
0.852
(0.356) {216}
42.04
(30.07) {216}
-0.090
(1.743) {110}
B. Summary Statistics (male subsamples)
Experiment 1
Male Identity
Prime
Female Identity
Prime
0.30
(1.54) {61}
0.22
(0.81) {32}
Experiment 2
Experiment 3
(extensive)
Experiment 3
(intensive)
Experiment 4
(extensive)
Experiment 4
(intensive)
Experiment 5
0.781
(0.416) {114}
34.92
(35.42) {114}
0.949
(0.221) {98}
60.88
(35.03) {98}
0.405
(1.407) {84}
Overconfidence
Prime
0.03
(1.32) {54}
0.823
(0.384) {96}
35.47
(33.97) {96}
Success
Prime
-0.47
(1.39) {59}
Control
-0.21
(1.09) {55}
-0.49
(1.40) {56}
0.648
(0.480) {105}
26.99
(33.41) {105}
0.844
(0.365) {96}
44.96
(32.75) {96}
-0.024
(1.968) {41}
C. P-values for random draw of samples across conditions
Full
Sample
Male
Subsample
Experiment 1
0.99991
0.99982
Experiment 2
0.82831
0.10523
Experiment 3 (ext. margin)
0.45736
0.41635
Experiment 3 (int margin)
0.20449
0.17365
0.50212
0.47808
Experiment 4 (int. margin)
0.67175
0.49040
Experiment 5
0.17617
0.98543
Experiment 4 (ext. margin)
58