Credit Default Swaps, Debt Financing and Corporate Liquidity Management∗ Marti G. Subrahmanyam Stern School of Business, New York University E-mail : [email protected] Dragon Yongjun Tang Faculty of Business and Economics, University of Hong Kong E-mail : [email protected] Sarah Qian Wang Warwick Business School, University of Warwick E-mail : [email protected] May 19, 2015 ABSTRACT Creditors monitor their borrowers less vigilantly and become tougher bargaining parties in debt renegotiations when they can hedge their exposure using credit default swaps (CDS). Thus, the inception of CDS trading on the debt of a firm can affect its financing abilities and risk management policies. We find that CDS firms hold more cash after CDS trading is introduced – cash that might be partly financed by new debt issues. These increased cash holdings are more pronounced for CDS firms that do not pay dividends, own more intangible assets, and have higher marginal value of liquidity. For CDS firms with higher cash flow volatility, these increased cash holdings do not entail higher leverage. Overall, although trading in CDS facilitates debt financing, it also induces CDS-referenced firms to adopt more conservative liquidity policies. ∗ For helpful comments on previous drafts of this paper, we thank an anonymous referee, Lauren Cohen, Miguel Ferreira, Andrea Gamba, Robin Greenwood, Jarrad Harford, Victoria Ivashina, Andrew Karolyi, Beni Lauterbach, Kai Li, Chen Lin, Tse-chun Lin, Ron Masulis, Florian Nagler, Joshua Pollet, Henri Servaes, Laura Starks, Ren´e Stulz, Neng Wang, Toni Whited, Ashraf Al Zaman, and seminar and conference participants at the University of Hong Kong, the University of Warwick, the University of M¨ unster, University of Reading, University of Manchester, the 2012 NTU International Conference on Finance, the 2012 SFM Conference at the National Sun Yat-sen University, the 2013 European Finance Association Meetings, the 2014 Jerusalem Finance Conference, the 2014 Annual Global Finance Conference, the 4th International Conference of F.E.B.S. at the University of Surrey, the 2014 Risk Management Institute Annual Conference at National University of Singapore, and the 2014 Northern Finance Association Annual Meetings. Credit Default Swaps, Debt Financing and Corporate Liquidity Management ABSTRACT Creditors monitor their borrowers less vigilantly and become tougher bargaining parties in debt renegotiations when they can hedge their exposure using credit default swaps (CDS). Thus, the inception of CDS trading on the debt of a firm can affect its financing abilities and risk management policies. We find that CDS firms hold more cash after CDS trading is introduced – cash that might be partly financed by new debt issues. These increased cash holdings are more pronounced for CDS firms that do not pay dividends, own more intangible assets, and have higher marginal value of liquidity. For CDS firms with higher cash flow volatility, these increased cash holdings do not entail higher leverage. Overall, although trading in CDS facilitates debt financing, it also induces CDS-referenced firms to adopt more conservative liquidity policies. 1. Introduction Credit default swaps (CDS) are one of the major financial innovations in recent decades and are the main construct of the multi-trillion dollar credit derivatives market. CDS allow creditors to hedge credit risk without formal borrower approval. As a result, CDS can affect the creditor-borrower relationship and have implications for corporate financial management. Because corporate risk and liquidity management policies are better considered in an integrated framework, the inception of CDS trading on a firm’s debt offers an opportunity for researchers to observe the effects of some of these joint considerations. There is anecdotal evidence that corporate finance executives, such as CFOs and treasurers, take CDS market positions into account in practice. “Like it or not, CFOs will increasingly be forced to deal with the default-swap gamblers.”1 In this paper, we empirically examine how the introduction of CDS trading on individual firms’ debt affects corporate liquidity – particularly when it also affects corporate leverage. The theoretical foundation for our empirical analysis is developed in by Bolton and Oehmke (2011) and Bolton, Chen, and Wang (2011). In this formulation, there is a tension between the benefits and costs of CDS: On the one hand, CDS help increase the current credit supply, because creditors are able to transfer part of their credit risk into the CDS market; on the other hand, the existence of CDS may change the relationship between creditors and borrowers and may impose future financing constraints – or costs – on borrowers. Bolton and Oehmke (2011) show that lenders can use CDS to gain bargaining power with borrowers in renegotiations and become tougher creditors particularly when engaged with borrowers facing financial distress. As a consequence, borrowers may attempt to avoid such renegotiations under those circumstances. Bolton, Chen, and Wang (2011) present a framework in which firms consider liquidity and risk management jointly, and note that the marginal value of liquidity is a major determinant of corporate financial policies. The key state variable for corporate financial policies in their model is the cash-capital ratio of the firm. Moreover, cash can be a more effective risk management tool when other types of hedging are more costly because of margin requirements and other frictions. If CDS transform lenders into tough bargaining parties, the marginal value of liquidity will be higher because of the need to avoid the contingency of renegotiation, and we therefore expect that corporate cash holdings will be higher following the initiation of CDS trading on a firm’s debt. 1 “Too Big to Ignore: Debt derivatives markets are encroaching on corporate finance decisions.” CFO Magazine, September 26, 2007, available online at http://www.cfo.com/printable/article.cfm/9821507?origin=archive (retrieved on May 11, 2014). 1 Nevertheless, creditor monitoring may be less stringent after the introduction of CDS trading on a firms debt (Parlour and Winton (2013)). In this case, the firm may also engage in risk-shifting and hold less cash to maximize the value of equity. Moreover, conventional risk management analysis suggests that when lenders can hedge their risk efficiently, borrowers may not have to undertake costly hedging strategies, which means that they can hold less cash. In addition, considering the relaxed credit supply constraint after CDS trading begins on a firm, its precautionary demand for holding cash may decrease. The ultimate effect of CDS will reflect this tension between these conflicting effects, and the effect of CDS on corporate cash holdings is, thus, best determined empirically. We construct a comprehensive dataset of the introduction of CDS trading on firm debt to study the effects of CDS on both cash and leverage. We rely on multiple data sources to pin down the date of CDS introduction for particular firms. Over the 1997-2009 period, we identify 901 CDS introductions for U.S. corporations with data from CRSP and Compustat. Our first main finding is that introducing CDS trading on a firm leads to an increase in that firm’s cash holdings, after controlling for the existing determinants of corporate cash holdings. The effect is also quantitatively important: The level of cash holdings as a proportion of total assets is 2.6% higher following the introduction of CDS trading on a firm, while the average level of cash holdings for those firms before CDS introduction is approximately 9.5%. Our finding for cash holdings is robust to variations in model specifications and to the selection of firms for CDS trading. We employ both propensity score matching and instrumental variable (IV) methods to address the endogeneity concern that firms facing a potential increase in cash holdings may be the very ones selected for CDS trading. The CDS effect on cash holdings remains statistically significant even after matching firms based on CDS trading propensity and following such instrumentation. The findings are consistent with the “tough creditor” argument because the CDS effect is more pronounced for firms closer to financial distress or with stringent financial constraints, as measured by credit market access. However, the CDS effect on cash holdings is similar for well-monitored and unmonitored firms when we use analyst coverage as a proxy for monitoring, which suggests that monitoring does not negate the tough creditor problem. Moreover, the CDS effect is more pronounced when there are more CDS contracts outstanding and also when the firm’s directors and officers have greater financial expertise, which suggests that both the magnitude of the empty creditor problem and the sophistication of firm management play an important role. If cash is simply regarded as negative debt, then the increase in cash holdings may imply a decrease in leverage. However, Saretto and Tookes (2013) and Subrahmanyam, Tang, and Wang (2014) find that firm leverage and default risk are both higher after the introduction of 2 CDS trading. Indeed, we find that the high-cash phenomenon coexists with the high-leverage phenomenon after CDS trading is introduced. We reconcile these seemingly contradictory findings regarding cash holdings and leverage using the theoretical framework of Bolton, Chen, and Wang (2014) to further illuminate the joint effects of CDS on cash and leverage.2 Bolton, Chen, and Wang (2014) show that firms may simultaneously issue additional debt and hold the proceeds as cash to weather potential financial stress. Moreover, firms may simply raise capital when market conditions are favorable, even without an immediate financial need, as shown by Bolton, Chen, and Wang (2013). Their framework provides implication for the impact of financial constraints and cash flow volatility on corporate policies. When a firm’s credit risk increases, a high debt–high cash holdings strategy is more favorable from the shareholder’s perspective than a low debt–low cash holdings strategy, even for the same level of net debt, based on the increase in the marginal value of cash holdings that is associated with increases in leverage in this model. Therefore, CDS trading may lead to higher cash holdings and higher leverage. We find evidence that firms raise debt and hold some of the proceeds as cash. However, the parallel increase in leverage and cash holdings that is indicated by the correlation between these two changes is less than perfect (although it is substantial), which suggests that they do not always occur together. Firms do not always hold all the proceeds from debt issuance as cash; however, they also do not always source additional cash through debt issuance. Indeed, there are situations in which firms do not increase leverage but nonetheless increase their cash holdings. For example, when firms have high cash flow volatility, they increase their cash holdings but not their leverage after CDS trading. Alternatively, when a firm has substantial cash flows, pays dividends, and is far from financial distress, the threat from tough creditors is minimal. Indeed, we find that dividend-paying firms (i.e., firms that are generally healthier than other firms) do not increase their cash holdings after CDS trading, although they typically do increase their leverage. When a large amount of firm debt is coming due and when the firm faces refinancing risk or “rollover risk”, it holds more cash because the marginal value of liquidity is high in such situations. The Bolton, Chen, and Wang framework also considers other factors, including derivatives hedging, lines of credit, and asset sales. A holistic examination of their model yields predictions that are beyond the scope of our study. However, we find additional evidence consistent with their predictions. For example, because tangible assets are more liquid and saleable than intangible assets, firms may substitute asset liquidity for financial liquidity. When a firm has 2 As discussed above, in the Bolton, Chen, and Wang (2011) framework, the marginal value of cash holdings is a function of leverage, among other variables. Therefore, if leverage changes following the inception of CDS trading, we must jointly consider cash holdings and leverage. 3 more intangible assets, an asset sale is less feasible; thus, for those firms, we find a larger cash increase after CDS trading is introduced. Our study helps illuminate the dynamics of corporate liquidity, in general, and cash holdings in particular. Bates, Kahle, and Stulz (2009) document a dramatic increase in corporate cash holdings in recent years. We conjecture that the advent of the credit derivatives market may have contributed to this increase because CDS pose a potential threat to corporate decision makers. The creditor concern can also increase refinancing risk, which has been shown by Harford, Klasa, and Maxwell (2014) to be a determinant of corporate cash holdings. Overall, our empirical findings are consistent with the predictions of Bolton, Chen, and Wang (2011, 2013, and 2014). Importantly, we demonstrate the interactions between cash and leverage policies that arise from their model, although cash holdings and outstanding debt are both affected by CDS. If we focus on only one aspect at a time, we may find that the two effects seem to conflict with one another. However, under a unified framework with external financing costs, the combination of high leverage and high cash holdings is a natural outcome of prudent corporate risk management. Our paper provides new insights into the real effects of credit derivatives on corporate financial decisions. Whereas CDS have been labeled “financial weapons of mass destruction,” they remain robust and effective financial tools for hedging credit risk and for undertaking additional exposure and are widely utilized by financial institutions as a result.3 Indeed, banks’ use of CDS has even expanded since the 2007-2009 financial crisis as a result of the gradual implementation of the Basel III benchmarks and the capital relief that CDS provide to banks under the new regulations. Thus, increases in cash holdings and leverage remain a side-effect of the active participation of lenders such as banks in the CDS market. The paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 presents the related literature and the development of our hypotheses. In Section 3, we describe our sample and empirical methods. Section 4 presents our main empirical results regarding the effect of CDS on cash holdings. The joint effects of CDS trading on cash and leverage are presented in Section 5. Section 6 concludes. 3 Berkshire Hathaway annual report for 2002: http://www.berkshirehathaway.com/2002ar/2002ar.pdf 4 2. The Theoretical Framework and Its Testable Predictions We motivate our empirical analysis by sketching out the framework underlying the hypotheses that follow. Although we do not present a formal model in this study, we draw upon prior work in the field to present the economic intuition underlying the model. The following corporate financing and debt renegotiation scenario involving the contingency of financial distress sets the stage for our subsequent analysis: An entrepreneur must finance an investment project with a choice between debt and outside equity. The firm must pay creditors a pre-specified amount as part of the loan contract on an intermediate date. There is the possibility of renegotiation between the two counterparties if the reported cash flow on the intermediate date is insufficient to meet the obligations to the debt holders. This situation can result either when the cash flow is actually low and reported by the entrepreneur to be such or when the entrepreneur declares an artificially low cash flow although it is, in fact, sufficient to make the payment to the debt holders. In the latter instance, the borrower may strategically report an artificially low cash flow to divert part of the cash flow to himself. In either event, renegotiation of the debt ensues, and the firm could be liquidated if it fails or persist following a renegotiated agreement between the entrepreneur and the debt holders. In anticipation of such financial distress and the consequent uncertain renegotiation process, the firm can hoard enough cash to secure the intermediate payment and avoid renegotiation when the realized cash flow is low. This is the key insight developed by Hart and Moore (1998) and employed in the context of CDS by Bolton and Oehmke (2011) in a discrete-time setting.4 Bolton, Chen, and Wang (2011, 2013, and 2014) present a continuous-time variation of this setting in which the information and incentive problems are modeled in a reduced-form fashion and give rise to external financing costs. The focus of this study is to examine how firms’ corporate financial policies are related to the presence of CDS trading. In the classic sense pioneered by JPMorgan, banks buy CDS to hedge their credit exposures, freeing up their balance sheets to fund additional corporate loans.5 Bolton and Oehmke (2011) use this central insight to propose the first theory of corporate finance in the academic literature that considers the presence of CDS contracts, 4 Hart and Moore (1998) derive sufficient conditions for the debt contract to be optimal in this context, whereas other models focus on equity, debt or both. This same study was also the first to show that it is optimal for the borrower to simultaneously hold cash and take on leverage when renegotiation is costly. 5 The introduction of CDS contracts in the early 1990s was, to a large extent, motivated by corporate financing needs in the context of constrained bank balance sheets (see Tett (2009)). Some of the determinants of CDS trading are also discussed by Oehmke and Zawadowski (2014). 5 arguing that CDS raise the creditor’s bargaining power and simultaneously act as a device for borrowers to pay out more of their cash flow to debt holders. The former argument arises from the reduced credit exposure of creditors, who are thus able to extract more from these debtors in their renegotiations. Simultaneously, debtors are less incentivized to strategically negotiate down their debt commitments. Nevertheless, there is a greater likelihood of default in the context of recalcitrant creditors which can even result in bankruptcy rather than an efficient recapitalization – according to the latter argument. Employing similar reasoning, Arping (2014) argues that CDS may even discourage the use of debt in anticipation of such an eventuality. The increase in credit supply associated with CDS trading is empirically corroborated by Saretto and Tookes (2013). When creditors are tougher in their debt renegotiations, they may force more bankruptcies than are necessary from a welfare perspective; this is particularly true when creditors buy more CDS protection than their risk exposures necessitate purely for hedging purposes, leading them to become so-called “empty creditors.” This increase in bankruptcy risk following the initiation of CDS trading is documented by Subrahmanyam, Tang, and Wang (2014) and is shown to be robust to a variety of controls.6 It should be emphasized that the literature has, thus far, focused on the leverage dimension and the attendant consequences for bankruptcy risk, with each aspect being examined separately. By contrast, the consequences of CDS for corporate liquidity management have not yet received sufficient attention. In this paper, we remedy this research lacuna by jointly considering the liquidity, leverage and risk management decisions of the firm after CDS referencing the firms debt have been introduced.7 We conceptually superimpose the Bolton and Oehmke (2011) “empty creditor” model on the unified framework of Bolton, Chen, and Wang (2011) to motivate our empirical analysis. A central notion in this model is the marginal value of liquidity, which is determined endogenously. Bolton, Chen, and Wang (2011) study a firm’s investment and financing problems in a continuous-time model with adjustment costs and external financing costs.8 Intended as a model for mature firms, their baseline model only considers equity for external financing (with a credit line being added in an extended model and with the possibility of debt financing later being included in Bolton, Chen, and Wang (2014)). 6 Augustin, Subrahmanyam, Tang, and Wang (2014) provide an overview of the literature on CDS relating to corporate finance, placing this issue in context. Bolton and Oehmke (2013) also discuss the strategic conduct of CDS market participants in this setting. 7 Almeida, Campello, Cunha, and Weisbach (2014) survey the literature on liquidity management and call for further examination to distinguish the dramatic increase in cash holdings in recent years from the time series patterns of other forms of liquidity management, such as (bank) lines of credit. 8 They consider time-invariant financing opportunities. Bolton, Chen, and Wang (2013) extend this analysis to time-varying financing opportunities and also consider the market timing of the firms equity issuance. 6 The key state variable for decision makers in these various models is the cash-capital ratio of the firm. Their formulation shows that the firm may be in one of the three regions, depending on the state of its intermediate cash flow: payout, internal financing, and external financing or liquidation. The marginal value of liquidity is low in the payout region and high in the external financing region because of external financing frictions. The introduction of CDS may increase future external financing costs, particularly for high credit risk firms (Ashcraft and Santos (2009)). Therefore, CDS trading may shift the boundaries between the three regions such that the firm is more likely to be in the external financing or liquidation region because of the tougher creditors. Therefore, on average, the marginal value of liquidity will be higher following the introduction of CDS trading. Moreover, as firms become riskier after CDS trading has been initiated (Subrahmanyam, Tang, and Wang (2014)), they accumulate higher cash reserves due to their precautionary motives and rely on cash more than lines of credit for liquidity management (as argued by Acharya, Devydenko, and Strebulaev (2012), and Acharya, Almeida, and Campello (2013)). Therefore, this line of analysis predicts that firms will increase their cash holdings following the introduction of CDS trading when the marginal value of liquidity is high.9 Hypothesis 1 (CDS, Tough Creditors and Cash Holdings) The cash holdings of firms increase after the inception of CDS trading on their debt. In addition to the tougher creditor theory, other theories may also have implications for the relationship between CDS trading and cash holdings. A reasonable concern is that banks may reduce debtor monitoring when they can buy CDS on the debt (as in Morrison (2005), Parlour and Winton (2013)). In such a case, the borrower may engage in risk shifting (see, e.g., Campello and Matta (2013), Karolyi (2013)). Such moral hazard may result in less cash holding by the firm, as argued by the agency theories of cash, which are discussed by, among others, Harford, Mansi, and Maxwell (2008), particularly as a firm nears financial distress or bankruptcy. Therefore, the liquidity and monitoring arguments can yield contradictory predictions, particularly for firms close to financial distress. The central theme highlighted by Bolton, Chen, and Wang (2011) is that “cash management, financial hedging, and asset sales are integral parts of dynamic risk management.” 9 Alternative mechanisms might also lead to the positive relationship between CDS trading and cash holding. For example, CDS may increase the bargaining power of bank lenders as CDS-protected banks are in better negotiating positions. Pinkowitz and Williamson (2001) argue that bank power may affect corporate cash holdings. Strong banks persuade firms to hold large cash holdings as a cushion rather than to use such cash to pay down their debt. In this vein, these authors find that cash holdings are higher in Japan because of the greater negotiating power of large banks. 7 Gamba and Triantis (2014) also emphasize the value created by a dynamically integrated risk management strategy. Thus, the main objective of our study is to examine different ways of managing firm risk in a unified framework, particularly with respect to the joint effects of CDS trading on both cash and leverage.10 Cash is not simply regarded as negative debt when firms face heightened risk, as argued by Acharya, Almeida, and Campello (2007). Firms may raise external funds, e.g., issue new equity (Bolton, Chen, and Wang (2013)) or debt (Bolton, Chen, and Wang (2014)), hoarding the proceeds as cash even when there is no immediate use of the funds, particularly with benign market conditions at issuance. The notion that firms may issue long-term debt and save the proceeds as cash was first suggested by Hart and Moore (1998) in a context in which there is a possible renegotiation stage in the interim.11 Bolton, Chen, and Wang (2014) present a dynamic model of optimal capital structure and liquidity management. In their model, firms face external financing frictions and need to use liquidity reserves to service outstanding debt (i.e. debt servicing costs). The interactions of the two factors exacerbate the precautionary demand for cash. Therefore, financially constrained firms will exploit the increased credit supply to increase leverage, on the one hand, but hold more cash as a precaution, on the other. As discussed above, the Bolton, Chen, and Wang (2011, 2014) formulation shows that firms may be in one of three different regions in terms of their marginal value of cash holdings. In the first of these, following the introduction of CDS trading, the marginal value of cash is low when firms are in the payout region. In this region, the threat from empty creditors based on CDS is minimal, and firms are less likely to increase their cash holdings as a result. However, the firm can still enjoy the benefits of increased credit supply and their leverage will nonetheless increase. Therefore, we predict that cash and leverage increases are more likely for dividend nonpayers than payers following the introduction of CDS trading. For dividend payers, such increases result in increased leverage but not cash holdings. Hypothesis 2 (Dividend Payout) The effect of CDS trading on cash holdings is more pronounced for firms that do not pay dividends. In contrast, the effect of CDS trading on leverage is significant for both dividend payers and non-payers. One unique prediction of the Bolton, Chen, and Wang (2014) model is that firms increase their leverage when cash flow volatility increases (instead of decreasing leverage as other 10 We thank an anonymous referee for suggesting that we study the simultaneous effects of CDS on cash and leverage. 11 This insight is further explored by Acharya, Huang, Subrahmanyam and Sundaram (2006), and Anderson and Carverhill (2012), who show that cash increases with the level of long-term debt. Eisfeldt and Muir (2014) document a positive relationship between debt issuance and cash accumulation. 8 structural models would predict) and hold more cash because the high leverage–high cash strategy is better from the equity holders’ perspective than the low leverage–low cash strategy even for the same level of net debt. Bolton, Chen, and Wang (2014), Figure 3, Panel A and Panel B, show that when cash flow volatility is in the highest region, leverage decreases and cash holding increases with cash flow volatility. In this setting, the high marginal value of cash increases the demand for cash. But the concern about debt servicing costs, i.e., that debt payments drain the firms valuable liquidity reserves, decreases the demand for leverage. These divergent relationships between cash and leverage offer a good setting in which to test these theoretical predictions. Hypothesis 3 (Cash Flow Volatility) For firms with higher cash flow volatility, CDS trading has a stronger effect on cash holdings but a weaker effect on leverage. The unified framework of Bolton, Chen, and Wang (2011, 2013, and 2014) is so rich that it is difficult for a single empirical study to fully explore all its implications. Moreover, other studies have provided complementary evidence. For example, Bolton, Schaller, and Wang (2013) empirically examine the investment implications of the Bolton, Chen, and Wang (2011) model and find supporting evidence. In this spirit, we attempt a somewhat broader empirical analysis of their framework and consider alternative risk management tools in this unified framework, and one of these is raising cash through asset sales. Because tangible assets, including cash, are more liquid than intangible assets, they can be used as collateral for risk management or borrowing, as argued by Rampini and Viswanathan (2013) and Rampini, Sufi and Viswanathan (2014). They are also more difficult to be expropriated by managers for their private benefit, and firms with more tangible assets are, thus, likely to be more immune to debt-equity conflicts. Hypothesis 4 (Asset Tangibility) For firms with more intangible assets, CDS trading has a stronger effect on cash but a weaker effect on leverage. In the following sections on empirical analysis, we test the predictions made above, while bearing in mind the concern that CDS trading is endogenous. In particular, we address such concerns carefully by using IVs and following the prior literature, including Saretto and Tookes (2013) and Subrahmanyam, Tang, and Wang (2014). 9 3. Data and Empirical Specification 3.1. Data We use CDS transaction data to identify a sample of firms with CDS contracts referencing their debt. Our CDS transaction data are from CreditTrade and the GFI Group. In contrast to the CDS quote data employed in some of the previous studies, our data contain actual trading records with complete contractual information. Given the over-the-counter nature of CDS contracts, we use the first CDS trading date in our sample as the CDS introduction date and compare the changes in corporate cash holdings and leverage following the onset of CDS trading. We further cross-check this CDS sample against the Markit database, which provides end-of-day valuations based on a survey of broker-dealers. In an auxiliary analysis, we also utilize more detailed transaction information and construct continuous measures of CDS exposures. The combined sample covers the period from June 1997 to April 2009 and includes 901 North American corporations that have CDS initiated on their debt at some time during the sample period. The industry coverage of the firms on which CDS are traded (henceforth, CDS firms) in our sample is quite diversified. Most are in the manufacturing, transportation, communications, and utilities sectors.12 Our data on corporate cash holdings, leverage and other firm characteristics are from the Compustat database. Following Bates, Kahle, and Stulz (2009), we measure cash holdings by the ratio of cash and marketable securities to total assets.13 We obtain credit ratings data from Compustat and FISD, financial expertise data from RiskMetrics, and analyst coverage data from I/B/E/S. Panel A of Table 1 presents the year-wise summary of CDS trading and cash ratios for all firms in the Compustat database during the 1997-2009 period: the number of Compustat firms (column 2), the number of CDS firms (columns 3 and 4), and cash ratios for firms with and without CDS trading (columns 5 and 6). As the fourth column of the table shows, CDS trading was initiated on the largest number of new firms during the 2000-2003 period. As shown in the fifth and sixth columns, similar to the findings in Bates, Kahle, and Stulz (2009), there is an increasing trend over time in the cash ratios for both non-CDS and CDS firms in our sample, but the increase is relatively larger for CDS firms: The average cash ratio for 12 We use the entire sample, including financial firms, for our main analysis and report the estimation results. However, we have also conducted our analysis by excluding financial firms. The estimation results in the Internet Appendix Table A2 show that our findings are similar in all cases whether we include or exclude financial firms. 13 Although the ratio of cash and marketable securities to assets is the most conventional measure of cash holdings, we also analyzed alternative measures of the cash ratio and found similar results. The CDS effects are robust to different definitions of cash holdings. 10 non-CDS firms increases by 16% from 1997 to 2009, whereas the corresponding increase in the cash ratio is 43% for CDS firms, which have lower cash ratios to begin with. As shown in Subrahmanyam, Tang, and Wang (2014), CDS firms are relatively large firms compared with their non-CDS counterparts. Large firms generally hold less cash due to their economies of scale: They incur lower transaction costs per unit in converting fixed assets into liquid assets. In our sample, the average cash ratio for non-CDS firms (0.209) is more than twice that of CDS firms (0.082). Summary statistics for firm characteristics are provided in Table 1, Panel B. Most of our analysis is for CDS firms and their matching firms (we will discuss matching methods in Section 4.2 below). In the regression sample, the average cash ratio is 0.095 and the average leverage ratio is 0.274. On average, 57.2% of firms in the matching sample pay dividends. The Pearson correlation coefficient between Cash and Leverage is −0.318. In addition to cash flow volatility, the cash ratio has a high correlation with future investment opportunity measures, including the Market to Book and R&D/Sales ratios (0.311 and 0.509, respectively). 3.2. The Baseline Empirical Specification We employ the regression model in Opler, Pinkowitz, Stulz and Williamson (1999) and Bates, Kahle, and Stulz (2009) to investigate the effect of CDS on corporate cash holdings.The dependent variable is the ratio of cash and marketable securities to total assets, which is regression on a set of determinants of cash holdings and other controls including firm fixed effects. The determinants of cash holdings in our empirical specification of cash holdings models are motivated by the transaction and precautionary explanations for cash holdings. The set of independent variables include the industry cash flow risk (Industry Sigma), the ratio of cash flow to total assets (Cash Flow/Assets), a measure of the investment opportunities (Market to Book ), the logarithm of total assets (Size), the working capital ratio (Net Working Capital/Assets), capital expenditures (Capital Expenditure), the leverage (Leverage), the ratio of research and development to sales (R&D/Sales), dividend payments (Dividend Dummy), the ratio of acquisitions to total assets (Acquisition Activity), and the proportion of foreign pretax income(Foreign Pretax Income). We explain the variable construction and data source in the Appendix. We use an indicator variable in the model specification to estimate the impact of CDS trading on corporate cash holdings and leverage, following Ashcraft and Santos (2009), Saretto and Tookes (2013), and Subrahmanyam, Tang, and Wang (2014). Our key independent variable, CDS Trading, is a dummy variable that equals one for a CDS firm after the inception 11 of the firm’s CDS trading and zero before that time. The regression analysis is conducted on the sample that includes CDS firms and non-CDS firms. Given the unobservable differences between firms, we control for firm fixed effects in our panel data analysis. Therefore, the coefficient of CDS Trading captures the impact of the inception of CDS trading on cash holdings and leverage. A challenge in establishing causal effects of CDS trading on corporate cash holdings and leverage is the potential endogeneity of CDS trading as firms are selected into CDS trading. There is the possibility that a third factor is affecting the introduction of CDS trading, corporate cash holdings and leverage. In that case, the observed effects on cash holdings and leverage might not be caused by the CDS contracts but might instead be the result of the impact of this third factor. We use multiple methods to address this endogeneity concern, including propensity score matching analysis and an instrumental variable approach, which are discussed below. Firms may make their financing and risk management decisions simultaneously. We further investigate the CDS effect in a unified framework of corporate policies by jointly estimating debt and cash policies in a simultaneous equation system. Our analysis of leverage follows Saretto and Tookes (2013) and Subrahmanyam, Tang, and Wang (2014) but incorporates the liquidity decision into the analysis. 4. CDS Trading and Cash Holdings In this section, we establish the empirical relationship between CDS trading and corporate cash holdings to pave the way for a joint analysis of cash and leverage in the next section. (The effect of CDS trading on leverage itself is previously established by Saretto and Tookes (2013) and Subrahmanyam, Tang, and Wang (2014).) We consider the endogeneity of CDS trading by using propensity score matching and IVs. We aim to understand the source of the CDS effect by scrutinizing the ex ante precautionary effect and comparing it against the ex post monitoring effect of the empty creditor theory. 4.1. Changes in Corporate Cash Holdings around CDS Introduction The summary statistics in Panel A of Table I suggest that there is an increase in the cash ratio for both CDS and non-CDS firms. To demonstrate that CDS firms experience a more significant increase in this ratio, we focus on the changes in the cash ratio around the inception of CDS trading (defined as date 0). Figure 1 shows the changes in the cash ratios for CDS 12 and non-CDS firms, from one year before the inception of CDS trading to zero (-1,0), one (-1,1), two (-1,2) or three (-1,3) years following its inception. Non-CDS-matching firms are selected from a sample of firms that do not have CDS trading at any time during the entire sample period. For each CDS firm, we find a non-CDS matching firm that is in the same industry (measured by the 4-digit SIC code) that has the closest size to the CDS firm (as measured by total assets). It is evident that the average cash ratio increases for both CDS and non-CDS firms. However, the increase is more pronounced for the CDS firms. We observe a 0.6% increase in the cash ratio for both CDS firms and non-CDS matching firms from year −1 to year 0. However, from year −1 to year +3, the increase in cash holdings for CDS firms is 0.7% more than that of the non-CDS matching firms. Given the mean cash ratio of 8% across the CDS firms and their non-CDS industry and size matched firms, the 0.7% additional increase in the cash ratio for CDS firms is economically meaningful. Therefore, we obtain a preliminary indication from this figure that the increase in the cash ratio over the years is greater for CDS firms following the introduction of CDS trading than for their non-CDS counterparts. 4.2. Impact of CDS Trading on Cash Holdings 4.2.1. Propensity Score Matching The endogeneity of CDS trading complicates the interpretation of the impact of CDS trading on cash holdings. It is possible that investors may anticipate a firm’s increase in cash holdings, and initiate CDS trading on it as a result. Of course, we control for firm fixed effects in all model specifications, which accounts for the time-invariant differences in characteristics between CDS and non-CDS firms, and may partially address this issue. However, it is still necessary to address the endogeneity directly. To that end, we implement alternative econometric methodologies, suggested by Li and Prabhala (2007) and Roberts and Whited (2012), to control for endogeneity. We use propensity score matching and the instrumental variable approach, to estimate the CDS effect, after controlling for the selection of firms into the CDS sample. To implement these approaches, we first predict the presence of CDS trading for individual firms. Following Ashcraft and Santos (2009), Saretto and Tookes (2013), and Subrahmanyam, Tang, and Wang (2014), the prediction model for CDS trading is estimated utilizing a probit specification with a dependent variable that equals one after the introduction of CDS trading, and zero otherwise. The CDS prediction models are reported in Internet Appendix Table A1. Table A1 shows that CDS trading can be explained reasonably well by the explanatory 13 variables that have a pseudo-R2 of approximately 38.9%. We further construct a propensity score matching sample based on the CDS prediction model: for each CDS firm, we find one non-CDS matching firm with a similar propensity score for CDS trading. Next, we run the cash holdings analysis on this matched sample. In constructing our propensity score matching sample, we use four different propensity score matching criteria to choose matching firms: (1) the one non-CDS firm nearest the CDS firm in terms of propensity score; (2) the one firm with the propensity score nearest the CDS firm and within a difference of 1%; (3) the two non-CDS firms with the propensity scores nearest the CDS firm; and (4) the two non-CDS firms with the propensity scores nearest the CDS firm and within a difference of 1%. Roberts and Whited (2012) discuss the “parallel trends” assumption that requires “any trends in outcomes for the treatment and control groups prior to treatment to be the same.” Given the central importance of this assumption for the difference-in-differences estimator, we first compare the trends in the cash ratio during the pre-treatment era. The results are presented in Figure 2. We compare cash holdings for CDS firms and their propensity-scorematched firms from two years prior to the CDS treatment to two years following treatment. We find that CDS firms have slightly lower cash ratios than non-CDS firms before treatment. Afterwards, CDS firms catch up with their matching firms, and exhibit a greater increase in cash holdings. Importantly, there is no significant difference between the time series trends in the cash ratios during the pre-treatment era for CDS and non-CDS matched firms. Following Roberts and Whited (2012), we further conducted a t-test of the difference in the average growth rates of the cash ratio between CDS and control firms prior to the treatment. The t-test results indicate that the cash growth rate difference is not statistically significant (tstatistic=−1.288) before CDS introduction. Therefore, it seems that the propensity-scorematched sample satisfies the parallel trend assumption. We then conduct the propensity score matching analysis. Unlike the case when using all non-CDS firms in the Compustat sample as the control group, firms in the restricted propensity score matching sample are more comparable with one another. Table 2 presents the regression results.14 In all these specifications, the coefficient estimates for CDS Trading are significantly positive, which indicates that corporate cash holdings increase after CDS trading has been introduced. The economic magnitudes are also substantial: For example, compared with the sample mean cash ratio of 9.5% for this restricted sample, the 2.6% change in cash holdings following the introduction of CDS, in the results using “nearest one” 14 We use all four alternative propensity score matching criteria discussed above to assess the robustness of our propensity score matching results. Propensity scores are calculated based on Model 3 in Internet Appendix Table A1. We also use all three CDS prediction models as a robustness check. 14 matching, represents a 27.4% increase in the mean cash ratio.15 The coefficients of the control variables in this propensity-score-matched sample are consistent with prior findings. As predicted, firms with high cash flow risk, as measured by Industry Sigma, hold more precautionary cash. The negative sign of the coefficient of Size relates to economies of scale involved in holding cash: large firms hold proportionately less cash. The coefficient of Capital Expenditure is negative and significant because capital expenditures create assets that can be used as collateral for future borrowing, thus reducing the precautionary demand for cash holdings. As in the findings in the previous literature, the sign of the Leverage coefficient is negative.16 R&D/Sales is a measure of future growth opportunities. Firms with higher R&D expenditures incur greater costs of being financially constrained because they must plan for future investment opportunities and must hold more cash as a result. The coefficient of Acquisition Activity has the same sign as that of Capital Expenditure, which is expected because acquisitions and capital expenditures are likely to be substitutes for one another. Multinational firms with foreign income (Foreign Pretax Income) may seek to hold more cash due to taxes associated with repatriating foreign income, as documented in Foley, Hartzell, Titman, and Twite (2007). We note that the propensity score matching approach is only effective in controlling for the observable differences in firm characteristics between the treatment and control groups. It is possible that there is an unobservable variable that drives both the introduction of CDS trading and corporate cash holdings; if this supposition were true, then propensity score matching would not effectively address endogeneity in this setting. In the next section, we also use the IV approach to address the endogeneity issue directly to mitigate this concern. 4.2.2. The Instrumental Variable Approach To allow for the possibility of time-varying unobserved heterogeneity across firms, we estimate a two-stage least squares (2SLS) model with IVs in which the indicator variable, CDS Trading, is treated as endogenous. Specifically, the cash holdings and the CDS contract status of a firm can be modeled as follows: 15 We have conducted a placebo test in the propensity-score-matched sample in Internet Appendix Table A2 Panel C. We use data from the 1980s when there was no CDS trading, and perform the cash holding analysis using pseudo-CDS firms and their control groups. We find no effect for the artificial CDS introductions on cash holdings. 16 Leverage and cash policies might be jointly determined. Firms may use cash to reduce leverage, and leverage might be a source of cash. We address the simultaneous financing and liquidity management decisions in much greater detail in Section 5. 15 Cash = βX + γ1 CDS Trading + δY + ϵ, (1) ∗ CDS Trading = λZ + ω, CDS Trading = 1, if CDS Trading∗ > 0; CDS Trading = 0, otherwise. The dependent variable in the above specification is the cash ratio, which is measured by the ratio of cash and marketable securities to total assets. X is a vector of determinants of cash holdings, and Y is a vector of other controls, such as firm fixed effects. The coefficient of interest is γ1 , which captures the impact of CDS on corporate cash holdings. The instrumented variable CDS Trading∗ represents the latent propensity of a firm to have CDS trading introduced on its debt. In the above specification, CDS Trading is allowed to be endogenous because corr(ϵ, ω) ̸= 0. For identification, we include IVs that affect a firm’s propensity for CDS introduction but do not affect its cash holdings directly – other than through the impact of CDS introduction. Therefore, Z in equation (1) includes the IVs. Our choice of IVs is motivated by both econometric and economic considerations. We use both Lender FX Usage and Lender Tier 1 Capital as instruments (Saretto and Tookes (2013) and Subrahmanyam, Tang, and Wang (2014) provide more details on the construction of the IVs). Econometrically, the instruments must satisfy both the relevance and exclusion restrictions. The relevance condition is met based on the results in Internet Appendix Table A1 which show that CDS trading is significantly associated with Lender FX Usage and the Lender Tier 1 Capital ratio. The instruments we use are economically sound because they are associated with the overall hedging interest of the lenders or credit suppliers. Specifically, lenders with a larger hedging position are generally more likely to trade the CDS of their borrowers. Moreover, banks with lower capital ratios have a greater need to hedge the credit risk of their borrowers via CDS.17 The fitted value of CDS Trading is included in the second-stage analysis of the determinants of cash holdings. Table 3 presents the estimation results. To show the robustness of our results, we present the IV results for each IV separately and two IVs jointly. In Model 1 we only employ Lender FX Usage as the instrumental variable. In Model 2, Lender Tier 1 Capital is the instrumental variable. In Model 3, we use both Lender FX Usage and Lender Tier 1 Capital as instruments. We find that Instrumented CDS Trading have positive and significant coefficient estimates for all model specifications, suggesting that the presence of 17 It is notable that the instruments we use are not weak: We find that the Sargan F -test statistics are above 10 for both IVs, thus strongly rejecting the hypothesis of weak instruments. 16 CDS contracts leads to higher cash ratios even after ensuring that the key independent variable is identified. Therefore, the evidence supports a causal interpretation of CDS trading on corporate cash holdings. 4.3. Firms’ Precautionary Considerations Empty creditors may have a more disciplinary effect when the manager has more financial expertise and when the CDS market is more prevalent. We examine whether such auxiliary predictions of the empty creditor theory hold in the data. 4.3.1. The Financial Expertise of Top Management The background of senior corporate executives and board members can greatly influence a firm’s financial policies. For example, firms run by CEOs who have previously experienced financial difficulties save more cash (Dittmar and Duchin (2013)). Furthermore, banks take more risk when independent board directors have more financial expertise (Minton, Taillard, and Williamson (2014)). In addition, firms with CEOs who are financial experts may hold less cash and more debt (see Custodio and Metzger (2014)). In this spirit, firms with greater financial expertise among their board members and senior managers may have a better understanding of the potential effect of CDS on their firms’ creditor relationships. Therefore, they are more likely to take preemptive actions to protect themselves from the CDS-induced “tougher” creditors. If such tougher creditors are indeed a major concern for borrowers, we expect that the increase in cash holdings exhibited by CDS firms will be more pronounced for those firms with management that has more financial expertise. We measure the financial expertise of firms based on information from RiskMetrics. The Directors Data in Riskmetrics include a range of variables related to the individual board directors and the officers of firms, including their names, ages, whether they have financial expertise, etc. In our regression analysis, we define Number of Financial Experts as the log of the number of financial experts on the board. The interaction term of CDS Trading×Number of Financial Experts captures the effect of CDS trading on the cash holdings of firms with financial expertise. We conduct the cash holdings analysis on the sample of CDS firms after controlling for their financial expertise. The results in Model 1 Table 4 indicate that firms with more financial expertise hold less cash, a finding that resembles that of Custodio and Metzger (2014). Moreover, the positive and significant coefficient for the interaction variable implies that CDS firms with financial expertise hold more cash. 17 4.3.2. CDS Amount Outstanding Instead of using the regime variable, CDS Trading, which equals one after CDS trading is introduced, we utilize detailed information about the notional amount of CDS contracts outstanding to construct a continuous measure of CDS exposure. Continuous economic variables also help further address the self-selection concern in analyzing the effects of CDS trading. As noted by Li and Prabhala (2007), the magnitude of the selection variable (for CDS trading) both introduces an independent source of variation and aids the identification of the treatment effect, while simultaneously ameliorating self-selection concerns. In addition, the continuous CDS outstanding measure is a proxy for the severity of the CDS effect: The larger is the amount of CDS outstanding, the greater the benefits to the CDS-protected creditors and, as a result, the tougher the empty creditors are likely to be in the process of re-negotiation. Moreover, the amount of CDS outstanding is a proxy for CDS market liquidity; therefore, the CDS spread of a firm with more CDS contracts outstanding and with a more liquid CDS market as a result will be more sensitive to new information, such as the firm’s credit and liquidity status. Therefore, the feedback effect from the CDS market to the bond market will be more severe for firms with larger amounts of outstanding CDS. When corporate liquidity declines, the CDS market responds by increasing the CDS spread particularly for firms with a liquid CDS market. A sharp decline in cash holdings, which results in a spike in the CDS spread, could undermine market confidence in the firm and reinforce a negative view of it. As a result, it may be judicious for a firm to retain more cash on hand after the introduction of CDS trading on its debt, in particular. Thus, both the tougher creditor mechanism and the CDS feedback effect predict that firms will have a greater incentive to hold cash reserves when there are proportionately more CDS contracts outstanding on their debt. We measure the level of corporate CDS outstanding by the ratio of the notional dollar amount of CDS contracts outstanding to the total dollar amount of debt outstanding at the same time (CDS Outstanding/Total Debt). We use the maturity date of each contract in our CDS data to identify the outstanding amount of CDS at any given time.18 We scale the CDS position by total debt to relate the dollar amount of CDS outstanding to the potential total demand of creditors. We conjecture that firms with greater relative proportions of outstanding CDS are likely to be more vulnerable to the CDS effect. Our estimation results are presented in Model 2 in Table 4. The analysis is conducted in the CDS sample, and we again find a significant and positive coefficient. These findings suggest that greater CDS exposure leads to higher corporate cash holdings. 18 The Depository Trust & Clearing Corporation (DTCC) uses the same method but covers the entire CDS universe. However, the DTCC only discloses data for the largest firms to the public. 18 4.4. Risk-shifting and Monitoring The results, thus far, suggest that firms adopt a more conservative liquidity management policy because of their precautionary considerations following the introduction of CDS trading on their debt, which is consistent with the prediction that CDS trading creates tougher creditors. However, CDS can change creditors’ incentives in multiple ways. Ex ante, when the firm is far from distress, empty creditors are more willing to lend based on the risk mitigation effect of CDS, which also weakens creditors’ monitoring incentive. Ex post, when the firm is in distress, empty creditors tend to be tougher and are incentivized to push the firm into bankruptcy. These diverse empty creditor incentives have different effects on firms’ behavior. Whereas the tougher creditor effect predicts more conservative liquidity policies, there are other implications associated with reduced monitoring by creditors. The decreased monitoring incentives of empty creditors may induce CDS firms to take on more risk in the form of a lower liquidity cushion. In addition to the risk-taking effect, governance from other parties may offset the effect of the decreased monitoring by creditors. Moreover, internal governance may be strengthened to compensate for the lack of monitoring by creditors. Furthermore, weakened monitoring may further affect the cost of debt (as suggested by Ashcraft and Santos (2009) and Che and Sethi (2014)), which increases precautionary cash savings. In this section, we investigate the effects of monitoring on the tension in the relationship between cash holdings and CDS trading.19 4.4.1. Financial Constraints The marginal value of cash may depend on a firm’s financial constraints. Faulkender and Petersen (2006) use credit ratings to measure access to the credit markets and financial constraints. The “tougher creditor” implication of the empty creditor theory is that more financially constrained firms may be concerned more about the impact of CDS trading. Therefore, the effect of CDS trading on corporate cash holdings may vary with the credit rating of the issuing firm. Almeida, Campello, and Weisbach (2004) find that firms facing greater capital market frictions, i.e., financially constrained firms, are more likely to retain more cash from their free cash flows. Similarly, because financially constrained firms have fewer alternative external financing options when their lenders become tougher CDS-protected creditors, they 19 The risk mitigation effect also predicts a decrease in cash holdings because the relaxed borrowing constraint may induce firms to rely more on external financing to manage the liquidity risk. We find evidence that is consistent with this prediction. For example, in Section 5.5 below, we find that CDS firms with more tangible assets have a greater increase in leverage and a lesser increase in cash holdings. Therefore, these multiple channels may co-exist, and the net effect is an empirical question that depends on firms’ characteristics. 19 tend to build up greater cash holdings after CDS trading is introduced on their debt.20 However, the liquidity and monitoring arguments can yield contradictory predictions. Borrowers may engage in risk shifting in the form of lower liquidity cushion following the decreased creditor monitoring, particularly for firms closer to financial distress or with stringent financial constraints. Therefore, if the tougher creditor effect dominates, we expect the cash holdings of financially constrained firms to be more positively affected by CDS trading. Table 5 examines the impact of CDS trading on cash holdings, conditional on firms’ financial constraints. Following the previous literature, credit ratings are used as the measure of the tightness of financial constraints facing a firm. Firms are divided into rated and unrated categories based on their rating status during the current quarter, and unrated firms are expected to be more financially constrained. Next, we conduct the cash holdings analysis and compare firms with and without credit ratings. The variable of interest is CDS Trading, which captures the CDS trading impact and is conditional on a firm’s rating status. The results indicate that the impact of CDS trading on firms cash holdings is even more significant for firms without credit ratings (0.040 vs. 0.023), which is consistent with the “tougher creditor” argument. 4.4.2. Analyst Coverage Governance of a firm from other parties, such as financial analysts, may offset the effects of decreased creditor monitoring, because financial analysts play an important role in corporate governance (see, e.g., Chen, Harford, and Lin (2015)). Using analyst coverage as a proxy for monitoring, we expect that CDS may induce risk taking and decrease cash holdings for unmonitored firms (CDS firms without analyst coverage). Furthermore, Shan, Tang and Winton (2014) find that the covenant loosening effect (decreased creditor monitoring) associated with CDS trading is most pronounced for firms with less serious information asymmetry problems (i.e., firms with analyst coverage). Table 6 provides the results of our test of whether monitoring affects the relationship between cash holdings and CDS trading. We separate the sample by analyst coverage information from I/B/E/S. The first model in this table presents the results for firm-quarters with analyst coverage. The second model presents the results for firm-quarters with no analyst coverage. The coefficient on CDS Trading in the first model is similar in both magnitude and significance level to that of the second model (0.025 vs. 0.023), which suggests that monitoring is not the driving force for the CDS effect on cash holdings. 20 In addition, the CDS spread provides valuable information about the credit quality of a firm without credit ratings. Consequently, it is even more valuable for unrated firms to maintain liquidity for purposes of sustaining a reasonable CDS spread. Thus, the CDS feedback effect argument also predicts that unrated firms will be more heavily affected by CDS trading. 20 We have further explored the distinctive role of monitoring by adding a corporate governance control. Corporate governance is another factor that may restrict the risk-taking behavior of borrowers. We expect CDS firms with better governance (i.e., a low E-index) to be less affected by relaxed bank monitoring after CDS introduction and to exhibit a higher increase in cash holdings. We find some evidence (see Internet Appendix Table A3) that firms with poor corporate governance have smaller increases in cash holdings after the introduction of CDS. Therefore, the evidence is consistent with the monitoring and governance theory, but the overall effect is dominated by the precautionary effect. 5. Cash and Debt in A Unified Framework The financing and liquidity management policies of firms are likely to be jointly determined. Because we find increased cash holdings – whereas Saretto and Tookes (2013) and Subrahmanyam, Tang, and Wang (2014) document an increase in leverage – following the inception of CDS trading, we investigate the joint CDS effects on cash and leverage using a simultaneous equations system in this section. We aim to shed light on the overall effects of CDS on corporate finance in a unified framework proposed by Bolton, Chen, and Wang (2011, 2013, and 2014). 5.1. Linkage Between Cash and Leverage: Cash Is Not Negative Debt When there are external financing costs, corporate policies are intertwined (Bolton, Chen, Wang (2011)). In this setting, cash is not simply regarded as negative debt, and corporate policies are characterized by the marginal value of liquidity. Firms may prefer to issue additional debt and save the proceeds as cash holdings when their hedging needs are high (Acharya, Almeida, and Campello (2007)). With the same level of net debt, a high debt–high cash strategy helps firms to be in the lower credit risk region than a low debt–low cash strategy (as suggested by the Bolton, Chen, and Wang (2014) model). Moreover, under stochastic financing conditions, firms have both a precautionary savings motive and a market timing motive. Firms may time the market and obtain external financing during favorable market conditions (in a period of low external financing costs) even when there is no immediate need for external funds (as Bolton, Chen, and Wang (2013) argue). Eisfeldt and Muir (2014) also predict a positive relationship between issuance and accumulated liquidity. Firms raise external financing and use it for liquidity accumulation when the cost of their external financing is low or their return to liquidity accumulation is high. Under this unified framework of 21 corporate policies, we expect CDS firms to time their financing decisions by borrowing more ex-ante during favorable borrowing conditions in the market and simultaneously to increase their cash holdings due to their precautionary motives, i.e., they will be characterized by both high leverage and high cash holdings after the introduction of CDS. We first investigate whether debt issuance is an important source of cash holdings for CDS firms. In Table 7, we jointly estimate the marginal cash savings and debt issuance decisions for CDS firms and non-CDS firms, respectively. ∆Debt is the ratio of the net long-term debt issuances to the total book value of assets, and ∆Cash is the change in the holdings of cash and other marketable securities divided by total assets. We follow the previous literature, such as Acharya, Almeida, and Campello (2007), and use Cash Flow/Assets, Market to Book, Size, and Lag Debt or Lag Cash (i.e., lagged levels of long-term debt and cash holdings scaled by total assets) as controls. The results indicate that both cash flow and long-term debt issuances are important source of cash for CDS firms, as evidenced by the positive and significant coefficients for Cash Flow/Assets and ∆Debt (0.163 and 0.093, respectively). Increased cash flow increases debt capacity, whereas long-term debt issuance significantly increases cash holdings. However, for non-CDS firms, the main source of cash is operating cash flow, as shown by the significant and positive coefficient for cash flow (0.322). Moreover, the coefficient for ∆Debt is insignificant (0.005) in the change in the cash model for non-CDS firms. Therefore, long-term debt issuance does not seem to significantly increase cash for non-CDS firms. Our finding of an increase in cash holdings following the introduction of CDS trading may imply a decrease in leverage because firms may wish to preserve their debt capacity for future contingencies if cash is, in fact, negative debt. However, Saretto and Tookes (2013) and Subrahmanyam, Tang, and Wang (2014) find that firm leverage is higher after CDS trading. To understand the joint effect of CDS on leverage and cash, we further estimate the leverage and cash equations simultaneously by two-stage least squares procedures. In the leverage equation, we include Cash based on the idea that firms may use cash to pay down leverage. In the cash equation, Leverage is included because leverage might be a source of cash. In addition to the conventional determinants of leverage and cash holdings, we also add industry variables for identification in the simultaneous equation model. As discussed in Saretto and Tookes (2013), the potential simultaneity of corporate policies is expected to occur at the firm level. Industry Leverage is included in the leverage model but is excluded from the cash model. Industry Cash is in the cash model but is excluded from the leverage model. Industry leverage (cash) should not affect individual firms’ cash holding (leverage) decisions, after controlling for the firm level variables. Panel A of Table 8 reports the estimated 22 coefficients of the leverage and cash models. In the interests of brevity, we show the secondstage estimates for both leverage and cash equation. We find that cash and leverage policies are indeed intertwined, which is evidenced by the significant coefficients for cash and leverage in the simultaneous equation model. More importantly, both cash and leverage increase following introduction of CDS trading in the joint estimation. The coefficients of CDS Trading are positive and statistically significant for both the leverage and the cash models. These results suggest that there are substitution effects between leverage and cash holdings (i.e., less conservative leverage but more conservative cash holdings). The evidence of less conservative leverage and more conservative cash is consistent with the argument that cash is not negative debt. Moreover, the magnitudes of the coefficients are economically significant, with a higher increase in leverage than in the cash ratio (0.040 and 0.018, respectively). In Panel B of Table 8, we further explore the short-term and long-term effects of CDS on both leverage and cash holdings. The simultaneous equation models for leverage and cash are estimated for different windows, i.e., from t + 1 to t + 5. For date t + i (i = 1, 2, ..., 5), we keep observations from the beginning until year i after the CDS introduction date and investigate the CDS effect. We find that CDS trading continues increasing the leverage, from 0.023 in window t + 1 to 0.042 in window t + 5. The effect of CDS trading on cash is quite stable, with a jump in year t + 1 and remains at approximately 2%. These result suggests that there are some unique aspects of the presence of CDS trading for both cash and leverage and that the pure substitution of one for the other is not the entire story. In sum, the results in this section indicate that CDS trading increases both leverage and cash holdings, suggesting that cash is not equivalent to negative debt. Debt issuance is an important source of cash for CDS firms. However, the correlation between leverage and the increase in cash holdings is less than perfect. On average, the increase in leverage after CDS trading is higher than that for cash holdings. In the following sections, we identify settings that are based on the marginal value of liquidity and the demand for external financing to distinguish the CDS effects on leverage and cash policies.21 5.2. Dividend Payout A key result of the Bolton, Chen, and Wang framework is that a firm has three regions for the future state of the world in terms of its cash-capital ratio. To more specifically tie our 21 Lines of credit are an alternative tool for liquidity and risk management. As a robustness check, we estimate a three-equation model in which leverage, cash holdings, and lines of credit are jointly determined. We find that CDS trading increases both leverage and cash holdings. However, the impact on the lines of credit is not significant (Internet Appendix Table A4). 23 empirical analysis to the model specification, we also investigate the CDS effect for dividendpaying firms and their non-dividend-paying counterparts: When a firm is not paying out dividends (a characteristic of financially constrained firms), the existence of CDS positions increases both its leverage and cash holdings. However, when it is making dividend payments, the existence of CDS positions increases its leverage much more than its cash holdings. According to the results in Bolton, Chen, and Wang (2011, 2014), a firm’s cash policy involves a double-barrier policy characterized by the marginal value of liquidity, and continuous management in between the barriers. At the upper barrier (i.e., the payout region), the marginal value of cash is low. The threat from the empty creditors is minimal because the firm has adequate liquidity, and it is thus less optimal for the firm to accumulate even more cash. However, even following the introduction of CDS, firms can still time their financing decision to better take advantage of favorable financing conditions in the market. Therefore, we expect CDS trading to increase leverage – but not cash holdings – for dividend payers. For non-dividend payers, the marginal value of cash is higher. These firms may borrow more and simultaneously increase their cash holdings due to their precautionary motives. Thus, CDS trading increases both leverage and cash for such non-dividend payers. Table 9 provides the estimation results, which are consistent with these predictions. Firms are classified into Non-dividend Payers and Dividend Payers, based on dividend payment information from Compustat during a particular quarter. The simultaneous equation models for leverage and cash are then estimated for Non-dividend Payers and Dividend Payers. The first two models in this table report the results for quarters in which firms do not pay dividends. Models 3 and 4 report the findings for quarters in which firms pay dividends. As expected, the coefficients on CDS Trading are significantly positive in both the leverage and cash models for non-dividend payers. For dividend payers, CDS trading significantly increases leverage but not cash holdings, which is consistent with the prediction that the value of cash is low in the payout region. 5.3. Cash Flow Risk CDS trading increases leverage due to increased credit supply (Saretto and Tookes (2013)). However, the effect of CDS trading on corporate policies also depends on firms’ demand for leverage and precautionary cash savings. Cash flow risk can be used as a proxy for a firm’s demand for both leverage and cash. A unique and surprising prediction from the Bolton, Chen, and Wang (2014) model is the firm’s response to cash flow volatility. Thus, conditional on debt financing, financially 24 constrained firms would raise their debt levels to increase their cash buffers in response to an increase in their cash flow volatility. For CDS firms with high cash flow risk, the demand for debt is lower. When cash flow volatility reaches sufficiently high levels, “debt financing becomes more costly than equity due to the toll of debt servicing costs on corporate liquidity” (Bolton, Chen, and Wang (2014)). Therefore, an increase in cash flow risk reduces the demand for leverage. With high cash flow risk, the marginal value of liquidity is that much greater. Firms may choose to build a larger cash reserves to reduce the probability of liquidation. Thus, an increase in cash flow risk increases the demand for precautionary cash holdings, and we therefore expect CDS firms with greater cash flow risk to have a lower increase in leverage but a higher increase in cash holdings. To investigate the effects of cash flow volatility, we include Cash Flow Volatility and the interaction term of CDS Trading×Cash Flow Volatility in the simultaneous equation model. The results are presented in Table 10 where we measure Cash Flow Volatility for each firm. We find that CDS trading increases both leverage and cash. Moreover, the positive association between CDS trading and cash holdings increases with the firms’ cash flow risk. The coefficient for the interaction term CDS Trading×Cash Flow Volatility is positive and significant for the cash model, which is consistent with our expectations because the value of cash is higher for firms with greater cash flow risk (and, therefore, a greater precautionary demand for cash). However, the effect of CDS on leverage decreases with the cash flow risk. The coefficient of the interaction term CDS Trading×Cash Flow Volatility is -0.055, which is significantly negative in the leverage model. These findings are consistent with the predictions from Bolton, Chen, and Wang (2014) in that firms may choose the high leverage–high cash strategy. However, when the cost of debt is high (high cash flow risk), firms may increase their cash holdings but decrease their leverage as a result of concerns over debt servicing costs. 5.4. The Marginal Value of Cash Corporations often roll over their outstanding debt, i.e., issuing new debt to redeem existing debt. Such refinancing of existing debt may involve rollover risk, particularly with respect to future states of the world in which firms’ credit situations change adversely, when new debtholders are reluctant to lend (as in He and Xiong (2012) and Choi, Hackbarth, and Zechner (2014)). In this setting, the marginal value of liquidity is high. Firms may mitigate this rollover risk by holding additional cash and reducing debt in anticipation of this contingency. Harford, Klasa, and Maxwell (2014) provide empirical support for this conjecture by showing that debt rollover risk is a key determinant of corporate cash holdings. Similarly, in our setting, if CDS trading were to affect firms’ financial policy decisions, we would expect that 25 CDS firms with a higher rollover risk would exhibit correspondingly larger increases in their respective cash holdings than those firms with no CDS trading on their debt. We follow Gopalan, Song, and Yerramilli (2014) and measure rollover risk as the long-term debt payable within a year, as defined in the Compustat data base. Long-Term Debt Due in One Year is the ratio of debt due in one year to total debt. Table 11 presents the results after controlling for this rollover risk. As expected, we find that the coefficient of Long-Term Debt Due in One Year is positive for cash holdings and negative for leverage, which implies that a firm’s rollover risk has a positive (negative) effect on its cash holdings (leverage). To examine whether the CDS effect on firms’ financial policies is larger for firms with a greater rollover risk, we further incorporate an interaction variable, CDS Trading×LongTerm Debt Due in One Year, into the regression models. We find that the coefficient of the interaction term is significantly positive for the cash model, indicating that CDS trading has a more pronounced positive effect on cash holdings for firms with greater refinancing risk, which is consistent with our prediction. Based on the model, CDS trading leads to an extra 1.7% increase in cash holdings. However, for firms with greater refinancing risk, CDS trading leads to a 3.4% increase in cash holdings, which is an economically significant increase. By contrast, there is no moderating effects from rollover risk for the CDS-leverage relationship. 5.5. Asset Tangibility Bolton, Chen, and Wang (2011) also discuss the role of asset sales in corporate risk management. Because tangible assets are more liquid and saleable, they provide real liquidity when firms must consider asset sales to manage their liquidity. In the worst case scenario, firms can sell part of their assets to weather financial distress, but only if they are liquid. Edmans and Mann (2015) solve a model to determine the conditions under which firms raise external funds by selling assets rather than by selling equity. Arnold, Hackbarth, and Puhan (2015) demonstrate that a large proportion of investments are financed with asset sales. Therefore, we examine asset tangibility to distinguish its differential effects on leverage and cash policies after CDS trading has been introduced. Asset sales are a useful alternative tool for risk management because tangible assets can be used as collateral for borrowing (Rampini and Viswanathan (2013) and Rampini, Sufi and Viswanathan (2014)). Hence, more tangible assets imply greater debt capacity. However, the value of cash might be lower for firms with more tangible assets because firms may rely on asset sales as an alternative tool for risk management and may thus substitute asset liquidity for financial liquidity. In our setting, we expect a greater increase in leverage – and a lesser 26 increase in cash – for CDS firms with more tangible assets. We investigate this prediction and present the estimation results in Table 12. We measure Tangible Assets as the ratio of property, plant and equipment to total assets. We also include the cross-term of CDS Trading and Tangible Assets in the simultaneous model for leverage and cash. The positive and significant coefficient estimate for CDS Trading indicates that CDS trading increases both leverage and cash holdings after asset tangibility is controlled for. The magnitudes of the CDS effects are quite similar for leverage and cash (0.029 versus 0.021). Notably, the coefficient for CDS Trading×Tangible Assets is significantly positive (0.043) for the leverage model but is significantly negative (−0.015) for the cash model. The results imply that CDS firms with more tangible assets exhibit higher increases in their leverage and lower increases in their cash holdings. Such findings are consistent with the prediction that firms also incorporate asset liquidity into their risk management framework. 6. Conclusion This paper investigates the impact of credit default swaps (CDS) on corporate risk and liquidity management. Using a comprehensive data set tracking the introduction of trading in North American corporate CDS between 1997 and 2009, we find evidence that the initiation of CDS trading on firms’ debt increases their cash holdings. On average, the cash ratios for firms increase by 2% following the introduction of CDS trading on their debt. Given a mean cash ratio of 8.2% for CDS firms, this increase is economically significant. This finding of increased cash holdings prevails even after controlling for the endogeneity of the introduction of CDS trading using propensity score matching and instrumental variable estimation. The empirical results are consistent with the predictions of the model by Bolton and Oehmke (2011) motivated by the idea of tougher CDS-protected creditors: Creditors tend to be excessively “tough” negotiators after CDS trading has been introduced on a firm’s debt. Anticipating the potential threat of these tougher creditors, firms hold more cash ex ante to be able to manage their future liquidity needs. Our finding is consistent with the insights from Bolton, Chen, and Wang (2011, 2013, and 2014) that cash holdings will be high when the marginal value of cash holdings is high. Their unified framework provides guidance for a joint analysis of both cash and leverage. We find that part of the cash increase following the introduction of CDS trading can be attributed to debt issuance. However, when firms are paying dividends, suggesting that they have abundant liquidity, they increase their leverage but do not increase their cash holdings. By contrast, when firms are characterized by high cash flow volatility, the increase in cash holdings is more 27 pronounced than the increase in leverage after introduction of CDS trading. Our research contributes to the ongoing debate regarding the real effects of CDS. In contrast to the redundant security argument that is the basis of derivatives pricing, growing empirical evidence suggests that CDS increase the credit supply, corporate leverage, and bankruptcy risk. However, we delve further into the firms’ responses to the increase in credit risk than previous studies by showing that CDS trading affects both corporate liquidity policies and their risk management practices. We identify and contrast the ex ante and ex post effects of so-called empty creditors that result from the introduction of CDS trading. These findings have implications for policy discussions regarding the welfare effects of the CDS markets. On the one hand, CDS trading can increase the credit supply and help increase the CDS firms’ leverage. If the additional funding is used to finance valuable new investment projects, benefiting shareholding interests, this increase might be welfare-enhancing. On the other hand, firms might simply hold onto the new funds in the form of corporate cash reserves based on precautionary motives. In that case, the increased borrowing capacity might not necessarily translate into higher welfare benefits for the economy.22 Future research can add more evidence and provide an even more comprehensive picture of CDS effects on corporate finance to help market participants and regulators develop more effective policies and practices. 22 For example, in the current context of industrialized economies suffering anemic growth, strong motives to hold additional cash might complicate (and even work against) government efforts to stimulate the economy by lowering corporate borrowing costs by means of fiscal and monetary measures. It is frequently argued that firms tend to postpone valuable investments not because of the higher cost of borrowing but because of precautionary motives that drive them to accumulate additional liquidity. 28 References Acharya, Viral V., Heitor Almeida, and Murillo Campello, 2007, Is cash negative debt? A hedging perspective on corporate financial policies, Journal of Financial Intermediation 16, 515–554. Acharya, Viral V., Heitor Almeida, and Murillo Campello, 2013, Aggregate risk and the choice between cash and line of credit, Journal of Finance 68, 2059–2116. Acharya, Viral V., Jing-zhi Huang, Marti G. Subrahmanyam, and Rangarajan K. Sundaram, 2006, When does strategic debt service matter? Economic Theory 29, 363–378. Acharya, Viral V., Sergei A. Davydenko, and Ilya A. Strebulaev, 2012, Cash holdings and credit risk, Review of Financial Studies 25, 3572–3609. Almeida, Heitor, Murillo Campello, Igor Cunha, and Michael Weisbach, 2014, Corporate liquidity management: A conceptual framework and survey, Annual Review of Financial Economics 6, 135–162. Almeida, Heitor, Murillo Campello, and Michael Weisbach, 2004, The cash flow sensitivity of cash, Journal of Finance 59, 1777–1804. Anderson, Ronald W., and Andrew Carverhill, 2012, Corporate liquidity and capital structure, Review of Financial Studies 25, 797–837. Arnold, Marc, Dirk Hackbarth, and Tatjana Xenia Puhan, 2015, Financing asset sales and business cycles, Working paper, University of St. Gallen, Boston University, and University of Zurich. Arping, Stefan, 2014, Credit protection and lending relationships, Journal of Financial Stability 10, 7–19. Ashcraft, Adam B., and Jo˜ao A.C. Santos, 2009, Has the CDS market lowered the cost of corporate debt? Journal of Monetary Economics 56, 514–523. Augustin, Patrick, Marti G. Subrahmanyam, Dragon Yongjun Tang, and Sarah Qian Wang, 2014, Credit default swaps: A survey, Foundations and Trends in Finance 9, 1–196. Bates, Thomas, Kathleen Kahle, and Rene Stulz, 2009, Why do US firms hold so much more cash than they used to? Journal of Finance 64, 1985–2021. 29 Bolton, Patrick, Hui Chen, and Neng Wang, 2011, A unified theory of Tobin’s q, corporate investment, financing, and risk management, Journal of Finance 66, 1545–1578. Bolton, Patrick, Hui Chen, and Neng Wang, 2013, Market timing, investment, and risk management, Journal of Financial Economics 109, 40–62. Bolton, Patrick, Hui Chen, and Neng Wang, 2014, Debt, taxes, and liquidity, Working paper, Columbia University and MIT. Bolton, Patrick, and Martin Oehmke, 2011, Credit default swaps and the empty creditor problem, Review of Financial Studies 24, 2617–2655. Bolton, Patrick, and Martin Oehmke, 2013, Strategic conduct in credit derivative markets, International Journal of Industrial Organization 31, 652–658. Bolton, Patrick, Huntley Schaller, and Neng Wang, 2013, The marginal value of cash and corporate savings, Working paper, Columbia University. Campello, Murillo, and Rafael A. Matta, 2013, Credit default swaps, firm financing and the economy, Working paper, University of Illinois. Che, Yeon-Koo, and Rajiv Sethi, 2014, Credit market speculation and the cost of capital, American Economic Journal: Microeconomics 6, 1–34. Chen, Tao, Jarrad Harford, and Chen Lin, 2015, Do analysts matter for governance? Evidence from natural experiments, Journal of Financial Economics 115, 383–410. Choi, Jaewon, Dirk Hackbarth, and Josef Zechner, 2014, Granularity of corporate debt, Working paper, University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign, Boston University, and Vienna University of Economics and Business. Cust´odio, Cl´audia, and Daniel Metzger, 2014, Financial expert CEOs: CEO’s work experience and firm’s financial policies, Journal of Financial Economics 114, 125–154. Dittmar, Amy, and Ran Duchin, 2013, Looking in the rear view window: The effect of managers’ professional experience on corporate financial policy, Working paper, University of Michigan and University of Washington. Edmans, Alex, and William Mann, 2015, Financing through asset sales, Working paper, LBS, Wharton, and UCLA. 30 Eisfeldt, Andrea, and Tyler Muir, 2014, Aggregate issuance and savings waves, Working paper, UCLA and Yale. Faulkender, Michael, and Mitchell A. Petersen, 2006, Does the source of capital affect capital structure? Review of Financial Studies 19, 45–79. Foley, Fritz, Jay Hartzell, Sheridan Titman, and Garry Twite, 2007, Why do firms hold so much cash? A tax-based explanation, Journal of Financial Economics 86, 579–607. Gamba, A., and A. J. Triantis, 2014, Corporate risk management: Integrating liquidity, hedging, and operating policies, Management Science 60, 246–264. Gopalan, Radhakrishnan, Fenghua Song, and Vijay Yerramilli, 2014, Debt maturity structure and credit quality, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 49, 817–842. Harford, Jarrad, Sandy Klasa, and William Maxwell, 2014, Refinancing risks and cash holdings, Journal of Finance 69, 975–1012. Harford, Jarrad, Sattar Mansi, and William Maxwell, 2008, Corporate governance and firm cash holdings in the US, Journal of Financial Economics 87, 535–555. Hart, Oliver, and John Moore, 1998, Default and renegotiation: A dynamic model of debt, Quarterly Journal of Economics 113, 1–41. He, Zhiguo, and Wei Xiong, 2012, Dynamic debt runs, Review of Financial Studies 25, 1799–1843. Karolyi, Stephen, 2013, Borrower risk-taking, CDS trading, and the empty creditor problem, Working paper, Yale University. Li, Kai, and Nagpurnanand R. Prabhala, 2007, Self-selection models in corporate finance, in B. Espen Eckbo ed., Handbook of Corporate Finance: Empirical Corporate Finance I, Elsevier, Chapter 2, 37–86. Minton, Bernadette A., Jerome A. Taillard, and Rohan Williamson, 2014, Financial expertise of the board, risk taking and performance: Evidence from bank holding companies, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 49, 351–380. Morrison, Alan D., 2005, Credit derivatives, disintermediation, and investment decisions, Journal of Business 78, 621–47. 31 Oehmke, Martin, and Adam Zawadowski, 2014, The anatomy of the CDS market, Working paper, Columbia Business School and Boston University. Opler, Tim, Lee Pinkowitz, Rene M. Stulz, and Rohan Williamson, 1999, The determinants and implications of corporate holdings of liquid assets, Journal of Financial Economics 52, 3–46. Parlour, Christine A., and Andrew Winton, 2013, Laying off credit risk: Loan sales versus credit default swaps, Journal of Financial Economics 107, 25–45. Pinkowitz, Lee, and Rohan Williamson, 2001, Bank power and cash holdings: Evidence from Japan, Review of Financial Studies 14, 1059–1082. Rampini, Adriano A., Amir Sufi, and S. Viswanathan, 2014, Dynamic risk management, Journal of Financial Economics 111, 271–296 Rampini, Adriano A., and S. Viswanathan, 2013, Collateral and capital structure, Journal of Financial Economics 109, 466–492. Roberts, Michael R., and Toni M. Whited, 2012, Endogeneity in empirical corporate finance, in George Constantinides, Milton Harris, and Rene Stulz, eds., Handbook of the Economics of Finance 2, Elsevier, 493–572. Saretto, Alessio, and Heather Tookes, 2013, Corporate leverage, debt maturity and credit supply: The role of credit default swaps, Review of Financial Studies 26, 1190–1247. Shan, Susan Chenyu, Dragon Yongjun Tang, and Andrew Winton, 2014, Do credit derivatives lower the value of creditor control rights? Evidence from debt covenants, Working paper, SJTU, University of Hong Kong, and University of Minnesota. Subrahmanyam, Marti G., Dragon Yongjun Tang, and Sarah Qian Wang, 2014, Does the tail wag the dog? The effect of credit default swaps on credit risk, Review of Financial Studies 27, 2927–2960. Tett, Gillian, 2009, Fool’s Gold, The Free Press, New York, NY. 32 Figure 1: Changes in Cash Ratios around the Introduction of Credit Default Swaps. This figure plots the changes in cash ratios for firms with CDS and their corresponding matching firms, from one year before the inception of CDS trading to zero, one, two or three years after the inception of CDS trading. Matching firms are selected based on industry and size. The cash ratio is measured as the ratio of cash and marketable securities to total assets. The CDS data come from CreditTrade and the GFI Group. There are 901 firms in our sample that have CDS traded at some point during the sample period of June 1997 to April 2009. 33 Figure 2: Cash Ratios for CDS Firms and Propensity-Score-Matched Non-CDS Firms. This figure plots cash ratios for firms with CDS and their corresponding matching firms, from two years before the inception of CDS trading to two years after the inception of CDS trading. For each CDS firm, we select a non-CDS matching firm based on propensity scores that measure the probability of CDS trading at the time of CDS introduction. 34 Table 1 Summary Statistics This table provides summary statistics for our sample firms. Panel A reports the distribution of firms in our sample, including those with CDS traded, and their average cash ratios, by year, between 1997 and 2009. The overall sample of firms is taken from Compustat, and includes all companies in that database during 1997-2009. The CDS data are taken from CreditTrade and the GFI Group. There are 901 firms in the sample that have CDS traded at some point during the sample period of June 1997 to April 2009. We measure the cash ratio as cash and marketable securities divided by total assets. The first column in the table is the year. The second column shows the total number of U.S. companies included in the Compustat database. The third column reports the number of firms for which CDS trading was initiated during that year. The fourth column presents the number of firms with active CDS trading during each year. The last two columns report average cash ratios for non-CDS and CDS firms respectively. Panel B provides summary statistics of firm characteristics for the matching sample discussed in Section 4.2. Leverage is the book value of the long-term debt plus debt in current liabilities, divided by total assets. Industry Cash is the industry mean cash ratio across two-digit SIC codes. Industry Leverage is the industry mean leverage ratio across two-digit SIC codes. Industry Sigma is the industry cash flow risk, measured by the mean cash flow volatility across two-digit SIC codes. Cash Flow/Assets is the ratio of cash flow to total assets, where cash flow is defined as the earnings after interest and related expenses, income taxes, and dividends. Market to Book is the book value of assets minus the book value of equity plus the market value of equity, all divided by the book value of assets. Size is the logarithm of total assets. Capital Expenditure is the ratio of capital expenditure to total assets. R&D/Sales is the ratio of R&D to sales. Net Working Capital/Assets is measured as net working capital minus cash, divided by total assets. Dividend Dummy is a dummy variable that equals one if the firm pays a common dividend. Acquisition Activity is the ratio of acquisitions to total assets, and Foreign Pretax Income is the ratio of foreign pretax income to total assets.(† from June 1997, ‡ until April 2009) (Continued) 35 (1) Year 1997† 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009‡ Total/Average Table 1 – Continued Panel A: CDS Trading and Cash Ratios by Year (2) (3) (4) (5) Total # # of New # of Active Non-CDS Firm of Firms CDS Firms CDS Firms Cash Ratio 9366 22 22 0.187 9546 58 72 0.191 9545 55 106 0.202 9163 102 196 0.200 8601 172 334 0.201 8190 221 547 0.203 7876 93 582 0.221 7560 58 593 0.221 7318 73 629 0.224 6993 28 533 0.226 6651 9 418 0.225 6223 9 375 0.205 5686 1 234 0.216 901 0.209 Panel B: Summary Statistics for Propensity-Score-Matched Sample Mean StdDev Q1 Median Cash 0.095 0.114 0.017 0.048 Leverage 0.274 0.171 0.154 0.257 Industry Cash 0.171 0.098 0.091 0.138 Industry Leverage 0.259 0.080 0.197 0.243 Industry Sigma 0.083 0.046 0.046 0.072 Cash Flow/Assets 0.023 0.029 0.014 0.023 Market to Book 1.936 1.312 1.198 1.516 Size 8.391 1.334 7.554 8.300 Capital Expenditure 0.033 0.035 0.009 0.021 R&D/Sales 0.027 0.052 0.000 0.000 Net Working Capital/Assets 0.043 0.143 −0.031 0.031 Dividend Dummy 0.572 0.495 0.000 1.000 Acquisition Activity 0.022 0.037 0.000 0.002 Foreign Pretax Income 0.021 0.039 0.000 0.005 36 (6) CDS Firm Cash Ratio 0.072 0.070 0.068 0.064 0.072 0.081 0.090 0.095 0.092 0.089 0.084 0.088 0.103 0.082 Q3 0.134 0.370 0.243 0.310 0.109 0.035 2.131 9.273 0.044 0.028 0.123 1.000 0.025 0.034 Table 2 CDS Trading and Cash Holdings: Propensity Score Matching This table presents the estimates of the effect of CDS on corporate cash holdings in a sample including firms with CDS and non-CDS propensity-score-matched firms. Propensity-score-matched firms are selected based on propensity scores estimated from Model 3 of the probability of CDS trading presented in Internet Appendix Table A1. We use four different propensity score matching criteria to choose matching firms: (1) the one non-CDS firm nearest the CDS firm in terms of propensity score; (2) the one firm with the propensity score nearest the CDS firm and within a difference of 1%; (3) the two non-CDS firms with the propensity scores nearest the CDS firm; and (4) the two non-CDS firms with the propensity scores nearest the CDS firm and within a difference of 1%. To estimate the impact of CDS trading on the corporate cash holdings, we include CDS variables in the model specifications. CDS Trading is a dummy variable that equals one if the firm has CDS traded on its debt one year before time t. The coefficient of interest is that of CDS Trading, which captures the impact of the inception of CDS trading on cash holdings. The sample period is 1997-2009, based on quarterly observations. (*** denotes significance at the 1% level, ** significance at the 5% level, and * significance at the 10% level. The numbers in parentheses are standard errors.) Cash Nearest One Nearest One Nearest Two Nearest Two Matching PS Diff<1% Matching PS Diff<1% CDS Trading 0.026∗∗∗ 0.025∗∗∗ 0.027∗∗∗ 0.027∗∗∗ (0.006) (0.006) (0.006) (0.006) Industry Sigma 0.060 0.055 0.081 0.089∗∗ (0.044) (0.038) (0.050) (0.043) Cash Flow/Assets −0.008 −0.043 −0.010 −0.059 (0.070) (0.062) (0.079) (0.063) Market to Book −0.001 −0.001 −0.000 −0.000 (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.003) Size −0.025∗∗∗ −0.022∗∗∗ −0.027∗∗∗ −0.021∗∗∗ (0.007) (0.006) (0.007) (0.006) Net Working Capital/Assets −0.058 −0.054 −0.044 −0.040 (0.055) (0.049) (0.060) (0.048) Capital Expenditure −0.166∗∗∗ −0.170∗∗∗ −0.176∗∗∗ −0.185∗∗∗ (0.025) (0.026) (0.030) (0.031) Leverage −0.048 −0.061∗ −0.055 −0.062 (0.039) (0.036) (0.048) (0.041) R&D/Sales 0.243∗∗ 0.246∗∗ 0.238∗ 0.242∗ (0.111) (0.110) (0.132) (0.136) Dividend Dummy −0.017 −0.017 −0.021∗ −0.017∗ (0.010) (0.010) (0.011) (0.009) Acquisition Activity −0.181∗∗∗ −0.151∗∗∗ −0.188∗∗∗ −0.136∗∗ (0.058) (0.055) (0.067) (0.061) Foreign Pretax Income 0.223∗∗∗ 0.213∗∗∗ 0.257∗∗∗ 0.248∗∗∗ (0.058) (0.056) (0.063) (0.060) Time Fixed Effect Yes Yes Yes Yes Firm Fixed Effect Yes Yes Yes Yes Clustered Standard Error Yes Yes Yes Yes N 40668 36426 57684 48872 R2 75.25% 74.57% 73.53% 72.81% 37 Table 3 CDS Trading and Cash Holdings: An Instrumental Variable Approach This table presents the second-stage estimation of the two-stage instrumental variable (IV) estimation results. The second-stage analysis looks at the impact of CDS on corporate cash holdings in a sample including firms with CDS and all non-CDS firms in Compustat. In Model 1, we employ Lender FX Usage as the instrumental variable which is a measure of the FX hedging activities carried out by the firm’s lending banks and underwriters. In Model 2, Lender Tier 1 Capital is the instrumental variable which measures the Tier 1 capital ratio of the bank lenders. In Model 3, we use both Lender FX Usage and Lender Tier 1 Capital as instruments. The coefficient of interest is that of Instrumented CDS Trading, which captures the impact of the inception of CDS trading on cash holdings. The sample period is 1997-2009, based on quarterly observations. (*** denotes significance at the 1% level, ** significance at the 5% level, and * significance at the 10% level. The numbers in parentheses are standard errors.) Cash (1) (2) (3) Instrumented CDS Trading 0.062∗∗∗ 0.038∗∗ 0.045∗∗ (0.023) (0.016) (0.019) Industry Sigma 0.077∗∗∗ 0.076∗∗∗ 0.076∗∗∗ (0.016) (0.016) (0.016) Cash Flow/Assets 0.065∗∗∗ 0.068∗∗∗ 0.068∗∗∗ (0.009) (0.009) (0.009) Market to Book 0.008∗∗∗ 0.008∗∗∗ 0.008∗∗∗ (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) Size −0.009∗∗∗ −0.010∗∗∗ −0.010∗∗∗ (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) Net Working Capital/Assets −0.046∗∗∗ −0.046∗∗∗ −0.046∗∗∗ (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) Capital Expenditure −0.211∗∗∗ −0.207∗∗∗ −0.206∗∗∗ (0.012) (0.012) (0.012) Leverage −0.083∗∗∗ −0.083∗∗∗ −0.083∗∗∗ (0.005) (0.005) (0.005) R&D/Sales 0.200∗∗∗ 0.199∗∗∗ 0.199∗∗∗ (0.014) (0.014) (0.014) Dividend Dummy 0.006∗∗∗ 0.006∗∗∗ 0.006∗∗∗ (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) Acquisition Activity −0.198∗∗∗ −0.192∗∗∗ −0.190∗∗∗ (0.013) (0.014) (0.013) Foreign Pretax Income 0.004∗ 0.004∗ 0.004∗ (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) Time Fixed Effect Yes Yes Yes Firm Fixed Effect Yes Yes Yes Clustered Standard Error Yes Yes Yes N 307672 307672 307672 38 Table 4 CDS Trading and Cash Holdings: Financial Expertise and CDS Outstanding This table presents the estimates of the effect of CDS on corporate cash holdings after controlling for the financial expertise of board members and CDS outstanding. The analysis is conducted on the sample of CDS firms. The measure of financial expertise comes from Riskmetrics. Number of Financial Experts is the number of financial expert board members the firm has. CDS Outstanding/Total Debt is the ratio of total notional CDS outstanding to the book value of the total debt. The coefficients of interest are those of CDS Trading, CDS Trading×Number of Financial Experts and CDS Outstanding/Total Debt, which capture the impact of the inception of CDS trading on cash holdings. The sample period is 1997-2009, based on quarterly observations. (*** denotes significance at the 1% level, ** significance at the 5% level, and * significance at the 10% level. The numbers in parentheses are standard errors.) Cash (1) (2) ∗∗∗ CDS Trading 0.019 (0.002) Number of Financial Experts −0.003∗∗∗ (0.001) CDS Trading×Number of Financial Experts 0.004∗∗∗ (0.001) CDS Outstanding/Total Debt 0.005∗∗ (0.003) Industry Sigma 0.016∗∗∗ 0.040 (0.006) (0.029) Cash Flow/Assets −0.137∗∗∗ −0.039 (0.018) (0.026) Market to Book 0.013∗∗∗ 0.000 (0.001) (0.002) Size −0.010∗∗∗ −0.007∗∗∗ (0.000) (0.002) Net Working Capital/Assets −0.128∗∗∗ −0.056∗∗∗ (0.004) (0.012) Capital Expenditure −0.136∗∗∗ −0.116∗∗∗ (0.014) (0.022) Leverage −0.145∗∗∗ −0.050∗∗∗ (0.003) (0.013) R&D/Sales 0.644∗∗∗ 0.143∗∗ (0.011) (0.063) Dividend Dummy −0.041∗∗∗ 0.004 (0.001) (0.005) Acquisition Activity −0.212∗∗∗ −0.082∗∗∗ (0.014) (0.024) Foreign Pretax Income 0.262∗∗∗ 0.164∗∗∗ (0.013) (0.037) Time Fixed Effect Yes Yes Industry Fixed Effect Yes No Firm Fixed Effect No Yes Clustered Standard Error Yes Yes R2 42.90% 71.87% N 29120 29120 39 Table 5 CDS Trading and Cash Holdings: Financial Constraints This table presents the estimates of the effect of CDS on corporate cash holdings in a sample including firms with CDS and non-CDS propensity-score-matched firms. Firms are separated into Rated and Unrated categories based on their credit ratings. Unrated firms are expected to be more constrained. The coefficient of interest is that of CDS Trading, which captures the impact of the inception of CDS trading on cash holdings. The sample period is 1997-2009, based on quarterly observations. (*** denotes significance at the 1% level, ** significance at the 5% level, and * significance at the 10% level. The numbers in parentheses are standard errors.) Cash CDS Trading Industry Sigma Cash Flow/Assets Market to Book Size Net Working Capital/Assets Capital Expenditure Leverage R&D/Sales Dividend Dummy Acquisition Activity Foreign Pretax Income Time Fixed Effect Firm Fixed Effect Clustered Standard Error R2 N Rated 0.023∗∗∗ (0.006) 0.052 (0.045) 0.011 (0.078) −0.000 (0.002) −0.027∗∗∗ (0.009) −0.036 (0.059) −0.111∗∗∗ (0.022) −0.022 (0.043) 0.197∗ (0.112) −0.018 (0.011) −0.168∗∗∗ (0.054) 0.272∗∗∗ (0.065) Yes Yes Yes 71.67% 35169 40 Unrated 0.040∗∗ (0.016) 0.057 (0.090) −0.152∗ (0.079) −0.004 (0.006) −0.017∗∗∗ (0.006) −0.083∗ (0.047) −0.241∗∗∗ (0.064) −0.154∗∗∗ (0.034) 0.239 (0.244) −0.013 (0.015) −0.208∗∗ (0.091) 0.052 (0.165) Yes Yes Yes 82.35% 5499 Table 6 CDS Trading and Cash Holdings: Analyst Coverage This table presents the estimates of the effect of CDS on corporate cash holdings in a sample including firms with CDS and non-CDS propensity-score-matched firms. Firms are separated into With Analyst Coverage and Without Analyst Coverage categories based on the analyst coverage information from I/B/E/S. The coefficient of interest is that of CDS Trading, which captures the impact of the inception of CDS trading on cash holdings. The sample period is 1997-2009, based on quarterly observations. (*** denotes significance at the 1% level, ** significance at the 5% level, and * significance at the 10% level. The numbers in parentheses are standard errors.) Cash With Analyst Coverage Without Analyst Coverage CDS Trading 0.025∗∗∗ 0.023∗∗∗ (0.006) (0.007) Industry Sigma 0.118∗∗ 0.018 (0.046) (0.066) Cash Flow/Assets −0.019 0.002 (0.091) (0.087) Market to Book −0.001 −0.003 (0.002) (0.005) Size −0.020∗∗∗ −0.031∗∗∗ (0.007) (0.009) Net Working Capital/Assets −0.016 −0.132∗∗∗ (0.065) (0.042) Capital Expenditure −0.179∗∗∗ −0.138∗∗∗ (0.029) (0.045) Leverage −0.073 0.014 (0.048) (0.048) R&D/Sales 0.320∗∗ 0.081 (0.130) (0.160) Dividend Dummy −0.023∗ −0.005 (0.013) (0.008) Acquisition Activity −0.208∗∗∗ −0.104∗ (0.062) (0.060) Foreign Pretax Income 0.274∗∗∗ 0.191∗∗∗ (0.094) (0.061) Time Fixed Effect Yes Yes Firm Fixed Effect Yes Yes Clustered Standard Error Yes Yes R2 73.74% 70.60% N 29021 11647 41 Table 7 Source of Cash and Long-term Debt Issuance In this table, we jointly estimate the marginal cash savings and debt issuance decisions, in the sample of CDS firms and propensity-score-matched non-CDS firms respectively. ∆Debt is the ratio of the net long-term debt issuances to total book value of assets, and ∆Cash is the change in the holdings of cash and other marketable securities divided by total assets. Lag Debt and Lag Cash are lagged levels of long-term debt and cash holdings scaled by total assets. The sample period is 1997-2009, based on annual observations. (*** denotes significance at the 1% level, ** significance at the 5% level, and * significance at the 10% level. The numbers in parentheses are standard errors.) Cash Flow/Assets Market to Book Size ∆Cash Lag Debt ∆Debt Lag Cash R2 N CDS Firms ∆Debt ∆Cash 0.205∗∗∗ 0.163∗∗∗ (0.038) (0.014) 0.007∗∗∗ 0.001 (0.003) (0.001) −0.034∗∗∗ −0.006∗∗∗ (0.003) (0.001) 0.159∗ (0.096) 0.320∗∗∗ (0.016) 0.093∗∗∗ (0.020) −0.259∗∗∗ (0.010) 44.06% 22.74% 6281 6281 42 Non-CDS Firms ∆Debt ∆Cash 0.067 0.322∗∗∗ (0.047) (0.015) −0.001 −0.001 (0.002) (0.001) −0.031∗∗∗ −0.023∗∗∗ (0.004) (0.002) 0.568∗∗∗ (0.102) 0.489∗∗∗ (0.018) 0.005 (0.017) −0.239∗∗∗ (0.011) 44.8% 33.02% 5123 5123 Table 8 Simultaneous Effect of CDS on Leverage and Cash This table presents the estimates of the simultaneous effect of CDS on corporate leverage and cash holdings in a sample including firms with CDS and non-CDS propensity-score-matched firms. Leverage and Cash equations are estimated simultaneously by two-stage least squares procedures. The coefficient of interest is that of CDS Trading, which captures the impact of the inception of CDS trading on cash holdings and leverage. In Panel A, the sample period is 1997-2009, based on quarterly observations. In Panel B, the simultaneous equation models for leverage and cash are estimated for different windows, from t + 1 to t + 5. For date t + i (i = 1, 2, ..., 5), i.e., we keep observations from the beginning until year i after the CDS introduction date and investigate the CDS effect. The coefficients for CDS Trading are reported. (*** denotes significance at the 1% level, ** significance at the 5% level, and * significance at the 10% level. The numbers in parentheses are standard errors.) (Continued) 43 Table 8 – Continued Panel A: Simultaneous Effect on Leverage and Cash Leverage Cash CDS Trading 0.040∗∗∗ 0.018∗∗∗ (0.002) (0.003) Cash −0.582∗∗∗ (0.069) Industry Leverage 0.147∗∗∗ (0.018) Leverage 0.173∗ (0.095) Industry Cash 0.401∗∗∗ (0.030) Industry Sigma 0.002 0.029∗∗∗ (0.013) (0.009) Cash Flow/Assets −0.224∗∗∗ 0.050∗ (0.021) (0.026) Market to Book −0.014∗∗∗ 0.002∗ (0.001) (0.001) Size −0.028∗∗∗ −0.024∗∗∗ (0.002) (0.001) Net Working Capital/Assets −0.050∗∗∗ −0.035∗∗∗ (0.007) (0.005) Capital Expenditure −0.191∗∗∗ −0.125∗∗∗ (0.021) (0.016) R&D/Sales −0.004 0.271∗∗∗ (0.030) (0.022) Dividend Dummy −0.023∗∗∗ −0.012∗∗∗ (0.002) (0.002) Acquisition Activity 0.077∗∗∗ −0.209∗∗∗ (0.019) (0.019) Foreign Pretax Income −0.050∗∗ 0.232∗∗∗ (0.023) (0.020) Time Fixed Effect Yes Yes Firm Fixed Effect Yes Yes Clustered Standard Error Yes Yes R2 71.46% 69.05% N 40293 40293 Panel B: Short-term and Long-term Effect on Leverage and Cash Year after CDS Introduction Leverage Cash 1 0.023∗∗∗ 0.023∗∗∗ (0.004) (0.002) 2 0.030∗∗∗ 0.026∗∗∗ (0.003) (0.002) 3 0.037∗∗∗ 0.028∗∗∗ (0.003) (0.002) 4 0.039∗∗∗ 0.024∗∗∗ (0.003) (0.002) 5 0.042∗∗∗ 0.019∗∗∗ (0.003) (0.003) 44 Table 9 Dividend Payout and The CDS Effects on Cash and Leverage This table presents the estimates of the simultaneous effect of CDS on corporate leverage and cash holdings in a sample including firms with CDS and non-CDS propensity-score-matched firms. Leverage and Cash equations are estimated simultaneously by two-stage least squares procedures. Firms are separated into Non-dividend Payers and Dividend Payers based on dividend payment information from Compustat. The coefficient of interest is that of CDS Trading, which captures the impact of the inception of CDS trading on cash holdings and leverage. The sample period is 1997-2009, based on quarterly observations.(*** denotes significance at the 1% level, ** significance at the 5% level, and * significance at the 10% level. The numbers in parentheses are standard errors.) CDS Trading Cash Industry Leverage Leverage Industry Cash Industry Sigma Cash Flow/Assets Market to Book Size Net Working Capital/Assets Capital Expenditure R&D/Sales Acquisition Activity Foreign Pretax Income Time Fixed Effect Firm Fixed Effect Clustered Standard Error R2 N Non-dividend Payers Leverage Cash (1) (2) 0.064∗∗∗ 0.050∗∗∗ (0.016) (0.004) −1.094∗∗∗ (0.390) 0.092 (0.066) −0.478∗∗∗ (0.152) 0.075 (0.056) −0.062∗ −0.011 (0.032) (0.024) −0.145∗∗∗ −0.054 (0.036) (0.036) −0.011∗∗∗ −0.006∗∗∗ (0.001) (0.002) −0.052∗∗∗ −0.042∗∗∗ (0.014) (0.002) −0.059∗∗∗ −0.040∗∗∗ (0.016) (0.009) −0.305∗∗∗ −0.236∗∗∗ (0.084) (0.029) 0.128∗ 0.126∗∗∗ (0.066) (0.026) −0.200∗∗ −0.200∗∗∗ (0.089) (0.019) 0.084 0.132∗∗∗ (0.086) (0.034) Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes 66.16% 64.79% 17060 17060 45 Dividend Payers Leverage Cash (3) (4) 0.031∗∗∗ 0.001 (0.002) (0.003) −0.475∗∗∗ (0.064) 0.149∗∗∗ (0.019) 0.218∗∗ (0.111) 0.444∗∗∗ (0.032) 0.125∗∗∗ −0.088∗∗∗ (0.014) (0.019) −0.382∗∗∗ −0.023 (0.030) (0.044) −0.013∗∗∗ −0.003∗∗ (0.001) (0.001) −0.009∗∗∗ −0.004∗∗∗ (0.001) (0.001) −0.056∗∗∗ −0.057∗∗∗ (0.009) (0.007) −0.140∗∗∗ −0.060∗∗∗ (0.021) (0.019) −0.038 0.232∗∗∗ (0.045) (0.036) 0.249∗∗∗ −0.092∗∗∗ (0.016) (0.031) −0.143∗∗∗ 0.234∗∗∗ (0.023) (0.029) Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes 72.08% 55.82% 23233 23233 Table 10 Cash Flow Volatility and the CDS Effects on Cash and Leverage This table presents the estimates of the simultaneous effect of CDS on corporate leverage and cash holdings in a sample including firms with CDS and non-CDS propensity-score-matched firms. Leverage and Cash equations are estimated simultaneously by two-stage least squares procedures. Cash Flow Volatility is a measure of individual firm’s cash flow risk. The coefficient of interest are those of CDS Trading and CDS Trading×Cash Flow Volatility, which capture the impact of the inception of CDS trading on cash holdings and leverage. The sample period is 1997-2009, based on quarterly observations. (*** denotes significance at the 1% level, ** significance at the 5% level, and * significance at the 10% level. The numbers in parentheses are standard errors.) CDS Trading CDS Trading×Cash Flow Volatility Cash Flow Volatility Cash Industry Leverage Leverage 0.042∗∗∗ (0.002) −0.055∗∗∗ (0.016) 0.029∗∗∗ (0.005) −0.572∗∗∗ (0.066) 0.145∗∗∗ (0.018) Leverage Industry Cash Cash Flow/Assets Market to Book Size Net Working Capital/Assets Capital Expenditure R&D/Sales Dividend Dummy Acquisition Activity Foreign Pretax Income Time Fixed Effect Firm Fixed Effect Clustered Standard Error R2 N −0.224∗∗∗ (0.021) −0.014∗∗∗ (0.001) −0.029∗∗∗ (0.002) −0.053∗∗∗ (0.007) −0.192∗∗∗ (0.021) −0.015 (0.030) −0.023∗∗∗ (0.002) 0.079∗∗∗ (0.019) −0.052∗∗ (0.023) Yes Yes Yes 71.74% 40287 46 Cash 0.018∗∗∗ (0.003) 0.032∗∗ (0.013) 0.021∗∗∗ (0.004) 0.140 (0.093) 0.403∗∗∗ (0.030) 0.042 (0.026) 0.002 (0.001) −0.024∗∗∗ (0.001) −0.035∗∗∗ (0.005) −0.127∗∗∗ (0.016) 0.266∗∗∗ (0.022) −0.013∗∗∗ (0.002) −0.208∗∗∗ (0.019) 0.229∗∗∗ (0.020) Yes Yes Yes 69.93% 40287 Table 11 Rollover Risk and the CDS Effects on Cash and Leverage This table presents the estimates of the simultaneous effect of CDS on corporate leverage and cash holdings in a sample including firms with CDS and non-CDS propensity-score-matched firms. Leverage and Cash equations are estimated simultaneously by two-stage least squares procedures. Long-Term Debt Due in One Year is the ratio of long-term debt due in one year to total debt. The coefficient of interest are those of CDS Trading and CDS Trading×Long-Term Debt Due in One Year, which capture the impact of the inception of CDS trading on cash holdings and leverage. The sample period is 1997-2009, based on quarterly observations. (*** denotes significance at the 1% level, ** significance at the 5% level, and * significance at the 10% level. The numbers in parentheses are standard errors.) Leverage 0.035∗∗∗ (0.002) 0.005 (0.007) −0.062∗∗∗ (0.004) −0.552∗∗∗ (0.070) 0.154∗∗∗ (0.018) CDS Trading CDS Trading × Long-Term Debt Due in One Year Long-Term Debt Due in One Year Cash Industry Leverage Leverage Industry Cash −0.008 (0.013) −0.239∗∗∗ (0.021) −0.012∗∗∗ (0.001) −0.025∗∗∗ (0.002) −0.056∗∗∗ (0.007) −0.184∗∗∗ (0.021) −0.003 (0.030) −0.023∗∗∗ (0.002) 0.081∗∗∗ (0.019) −0.060∗∗∗ (0.023) Yes Yes Yes 72.04% 40293 Industry Sigma Cash Flow/Assets Market to Book Size Net Working Capital/Assets Capital Expenditure R&D/Sales Dividend Dummy Acquisition Activity Foreign Pretax Income Time Fixed Effect Firm Fixed Effect Clustered Standard Error R2 N 47 Cash 0.017∗∗∗ (0.002) 0.017∗∗∗ (0.006) 0.031∗∗∗ (0.007) 0.153∗ (0.088) 0.389∗∗∗ (0.028) 0.034∗∗∗ (0.009) 0.055∗∗ (0.026) 0.001 (0.001) −0.025∗∗∗ (0.001) −0.033∗∗∗ (0.005) −0.127∗∗∗ (0.015) 0.262∗∗∗ (0.020) −0.013∗∗∗ (0.002) −0.203∗∗∗ (0.018) 0.232∗∗∗ (0.020) Yes Yes Yes 69.81% 40293 Table 12 Asset Tangibility and the CDS Effects on Cash and Leverage This table presents the estimates of the simultaneous effect of CDS on corporate leverage and cash holdings in a sample including firms with CDS and non-CDS propensity-score-matched firms. Leverage and Cash equations are estimated simultaneously by two-stage least squares procedures. Tangible Assets is the ratio of property, plant and equipment to total assets. The coefficient of interest are those of CDS Trading and CDS Trading×Tangible Assets, which capture the impact of the inception of CDS trading on cash holdings and leverage. The sample period is 1997-2009, based on quarterly observations.(*** denotes significance at the 1% level, ** significance at the 5% level, and * significance at the 10% level. The numbers in parentheses are standard errors.) CDS Trading CDS Trading × Tangible Assets Tangible Assets Cash Industry Leverage Leverage 0.029∗∗∗ (0.004) 0.043∗∗∗ (0.006) −0.341∗∗∗ (0.033) −0.900∗∗∗ (0.111) 0.177∗∗∗ (0.019) Leverage Industry Cash Industry Sigma Cash Flow/Assets Market to Book Size Net Working Capital/Assets Capital Expenditure R&D/Sales Dividend Dummy Acquisition Activity Foreign Pretax Income Time Fixed Effect Firm Fixed Effect Clustered Standard Error R2 N 0.006 (0.015) −0.195∗∗∗ (0.023) −0.014∗∗∗ (0.001) −0.040∗∗∗ (0.003) −0.077∗∗∗ (0.009) −0.115∗∗∗ (0.020) 0.121∗∗∗ (0.042) −0.024∗∗∗ (0.003) −0.020 (0.028) −0.024 (0.027) Yes Yes Yes 68.32% 40293 48 Cash 0.021∗∗∗ (0.002) −0.015∗∗∗ (0.005) −0.264∗∗∗ (0.009) 0.118 (0.077) 0.273∗∗∗ (0.027) 0.041∗∗∗ (0.008) 0.055∗∗ (0.022) 0.001 (0.001) −0.028∗∗∗ (0.001) −0.046∗∗∗ (0.005) −0.036∗∗∗ (0.013) 0.302∗∗∗ (0.019) −0.010∗∗∗ (0.002) −0.232∗∗∗ (0.016) 0.190∗∗∗ (0.018) Yes Yes Yes 71.91% 40293 Appendix: Variable Definitions Variable Cash ∆Cash Lag Cash Leverage ∆Debt Lag Debt CDS Trading CDS Outstanding/Total Debt Industry Cash Industry Leverage Industry Sigma Cash Flow/Assets Market to Book Size Net Working Capital/Assets Capital Expenditure R&D/Sales Dividend Dummy Acquisition Activity Foreign Pretax Income Lender FX Usage Lender Tier 1 Capital Number of Financial Experts Unrated Rated With/Without Analyst Coverage Long-Term Debt Due in One Year Tangible Assets Definition The ratio of cash and marketable securities to total assets. Source: Compustat The change in the holdings of cash and marketable securities divided by total assets. Source: Compustat The ratio of cash and marketable securities to total assets in previous year. Source: Compustat The book value of the long-term debt plus debt in current liabilities, divided by total assets. Source: Compustat The ratio of the net long-term debt issuances to total assets. Source: Compustat The ratio of long-term debt to total assets in previous year. Source: Compustat A dummy variable that equals one if the firm has CDS traded on its debt one year before current month. Source: CreditTrade, GFI, Markit The ratio of the total notional dollar amount of all CDS contracts outstanding (before maturity) in our database to the total dollar amount of debt outstanding. Source: CreditTrade, GFI, Compustat The industry mean cash ratio across two-digit SIC codes. Source: Compustat The industry mean leverage across two-digit SIC codes. Source: Compustat The industry cash flow risk, measured by the mean cash flow volatility across two-digit SIC codes. Source: Compustat The ratio of cash flow to total assets, where cash flow is defined as the earnings after interest and related expenses, income taxes, and dividends. Source: Compustat The book value of assets minus the book value of equity plus the market value of equity, all divided by the book value of assets. Source: Compustat The logarithm of total assets. Source: Compustat Net working capital minus cash, divided by total assets. Source: Compustat The ratio of capital expenditure to total assets. Source: Compustat The ratio of R&D to sales. R&D is set to zero if missing. Source: Compustat A dummy variable that equals one if the firm pays a common dividend. Source: Compustat The ratio of acquisitions to total assets. Source: Compustat The ratio of foreign pretax income to total assets. Source: Compustat A measure of the average FX hedging activities carried out by the firm’s lending banks and underwriters. Source: Dealscan, FISD, Call Report A measure of the average Tier 1 capital ratio of the bank lenders. Source: Dealscan, FISD, Compustat The number of financial expert board members of the firm. Source: Riskmetrics Indicator variable which equals to 1 if the firm has no bond rating. Source: Compustat, FISD Firms with a bond rating are classified as rated. Source: Compustat, FISD Dummy variables indicating whether firms are covered by equity analysts or not. Source: I/B/E/S The ratio of long-term debt due in one year to total debt. Source: Compustat The ratio of property, plant and equipment to total assets. Source: Compustat 49 Internet Appendix to “Credit Default Swaps, Debt Financing and Corporate Liquidity Management” (not to be included for publication) Table A1 Probability of Credit Default Swaps Trading This table presents the estimates of the probability of credit default swaps (CDS) trading, obtained using a probit model. Propensity scores are estimated based on the model parameters. ln(Assets) is the logarithm of the firm’s total asset value. Leverage is defined as the ratio of book debt to total assets. ROA is the firm’s return on assets. rit−1 − rmt−1 is the firm’s excess return over the past year. Equity Volatility is the firm’s annualized equity volatility. PPENT/Total Asset is the ratio of property, plant and equipment to total assets. Sales/Total Asset is the ratio of sales to total assets. EBIT/Total Asset is the ratio of earnings before interest and tax to total assets. WCAP/Total Asset is the ratio of working capital to total assets. RE/Total Asset is the ratio of retained earnings to total assets. Cash/Total Asset is the ratio of cash to total assets. CAPX/Total Asset is the ratio of capital expenditure to total assets. Rated is a dummy variable that equals one if the firm is rated. Senior Unsecured Debt is the ratio of senior unsecured debt to total debt. Lender Size is a measure of the size of the lending banks and underwriters. Lender Credit Derivatives measures the credit derivative activities of the lenders. Lender FX Usage is a measure of the FX hedging activities of the lending banks and underwriters, and Lender Tier 1 Capital is the Tier 1 capital ratio of the lenders. The sample period is 1997-2009. (*** denotes significance at the 1% level, ** significance at the 5% level, and * significance at the 10% level. The numbers in parentheses are standard errors.) 50 Ln(Assets) Leverage ROA rit−1 − rmt−1 Equity Volatility PPENT/Total Asset Sales/Total Asset EBIT/Total Asset WCAP/Total Asset RE/Total Asset Cash/Total Asset CAPX/Total Asset Rated Senior Unsecured Debt Lender Size Lender Credit Derivatives Lender FX Usage CDS Prediction Model 1 0.790∗∗∗ (0.006) 0.429∗∗∗ (0.025) −0.001 (0.001) −0.104∗∗∗ (0.011) 0.063∗∗∗ (0.017) 0.306∗∗∗ (0.031) −0.026∗∗∗ (0.009) 0.315∗∗∗ (0.064) 0.142∗∗∗ (0.024) 0.022∗∗∗ (0.005) 0.290∗∗∗ (0.023) −1.611∗∗∗ (0.122) 0.667∗∗∗ (0.203) 0.375∗∗∗ (0.014) 0.369∗∗∗ (0.011) 1.006∗∗∗ (0.024) 8.979∗∗∗ (0.788) Probability of CDS Trading CDS Prediction Model 2 0.804∗∗∗ (0.006) 0.440∗∗∗ (0.025) −0.001 (0.001) −0.104∗∗∗ (0.011) 0.069∗∗∗ (0.017) 0.321∗∗∗ (0.031) −0.027∗∗∗ (0.003) 0.375∗∗∗ (0.064) 0.145∗∗∗ (0.024) 0.023∗∗∗ (0.005) 0.302∗∗∗ (0.023) −1.677∗∗∗ (0.122) 0.645∗∗∗ (0.205) 0.377∗∗∗ (0.014) 0.378∗∗∗ (0.011) 1.013∗∗∗ (0.024) −3.865∗∗∗ (0.756) 26.13 0.000 Yes Yes Yes Yes 38.79% 690111 Lender Tier 1 Capital F-statistic (instruments) p-value (F-statistic) Credit Rating Controls Time Fixed Effect Industry Fixed Effect Clustered Standard Error Pseudo R2 N 129.89 0.000 Yes Yes Yes Yes 38.96% 690111 51 CDS Prediction Model 3 0.797∗∗∗ (0.006) 0.431∗∗∗ (0.026) −0.001 (0.001) −0.104∗∗∗ (0.011) 0.067∗∗∗ (0.017) 0.307∗∗∗ (0.031) −0.026∗∗∗ (0.003) 0.338∗∗∗ (0.064) 0.143∗∗∗ (0.024) 0.024∗∗∗ (0.005) 0.294∗∗∗ (0.023) −1.604∗∗∗ (0.122) 0.638∗∗∗ (0.205) 0.375∗∗∗ (0.014) 0.385∗∗∗ (0.011) 1.019∗∗∗ (0.025) 9.104∗∗∗ (0.789) −4.000∗∗∗ (0.757) 159.74 0.000 Yes Yes Yes Yes 38.99% 690111 Table A2 Effect of CDS on Cash Holdings: Robustness Checks This table presents robustness checks for the effect of CDS trading on cash holdings. In Panel A, Model 1 is based on the sample of all Compustat firms. Model 2 is based on the sample of all Compustat firms, for firm-years with at least 100 million in assets. Model 3 is the cash holding analysis conducted on the sample of all Compustat firms, excluding financial firms. Model 4 is the cash holding analysis conducted on the sample of all Compustat firms with firm-years with at least 100 million in assets, excluding financial firms. Panel B investigates the CDS effect in the propensity-score-matched sample, excluding financial firms. Panel C conducts a placebo test on the propensity-score-matched sample. We use data from the 1980s when there was no CDS trading, and perform the cash holding analysis using pseudo-CDS firms and their control groups. (*** denotes significance at the 1% level, ** significance at the 5% level, and * significance at the 10% level. The numbers in parentheses are standard errors.) Panel A: All Compustat Firms As Control Group All Firms Non-Financial Firms (1) (2) (3) (4) CDS Trading 0.020∗∗∗ 0.024∗∗∗ 0.020∗∗∗ 0.023∗∗∗ (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) Industry Sigma 0.076∗∗∗ 0.071∗∗∗ 0.073∗∗∗ 0.074∗∗∗ (0.016) (0.017) (0.016) (0.017) Cash Flow/Assets 0.066∗∗∗ 0.016 0.062∗∗∗ 0.013 (0.009) (0.013) (0.010) (0.013) Market to Book 0.008∗∗∗ 0.008∗∗∗ 0.008∗∗∗ 0.007∗∗∗ (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) Size −0.009∗∗∗ −0.011∗∗∗ −0.009∗∗∗ −0.011∗∗∗ (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) Net Working Capital/Assets −0.046∗∗∗ −0.063∗∗∗ −0.046∗∗∗ −0.061∗∗∗ (0.004) (0.006) (0.004) (0.006) Capital Expenditure −0.211∗∗∗ −0.146∗∗∗ −0.212∗∗∗ −0.148∗∗∗ (0.012) (0.011) (0.012) (0.011) Leverage −0.084∗∗∗ −0.073∗∗∗ −0.084∗∗∗ −0.075∗∗∗ (0.005) (0.006) (0.005) (0.006) R&D/Sales 0.195∗∗∗ 0.161∗∗∗ 0.196∗∗∗ 0.152∗∗∗ (0.015) (0.032) (0.015) (0.033) Dividend Dummy 0.007∗∗∗ 0.001 0.008∗∗∗ 0.001 (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) Acquisition Activity −0.197∗∗∗ −0.164∗∗∗ −0.191∗∗∗ −0.161∗∗∗ (0.013) (0.012) (0.013) (0.012) Foreign Pretax Income 0.004∗ 0.108∗∗∗ 0.004∗ 0.101∗∗∗ (0.002) (0.028) (0.002) (0.027) Time Fixed Effect Yes Yes Yes Yes Firm Fixed Effect Yes Yes Yes Yes Clustered Standard Error Yes Yes Yes Yes N 308510 167492 294893 160998 R2 74.94% 83.38% 75.05% 83.35% 52 Panel B: Propensity-score-matched Firms as Control Group, Excluding Financial Firms CDS Trading Leverage Single Equation (1) Cash 0.025∗∗∗ (0.006) −0.046 (0.039) Simultaneous Equations (2) Leverage Cash 0.039∗∗∗ 0.017∗∗∗ (0.002) (0.003) 0.195∗ (0.101) 0.405∗∗∗ (0.031) −0.574∗∗∗ (0.071) 0.143∗∗∗ (0.018) 0.002 0.036∗∗∗ (0.013) (0.009) −0.222∗∗∗ 0.052∗ (0.021) (0.027) −0.014∗∗∗ 0.003∗ (0.001) (0.001) −0.028∗∗∗ −0.024∗∗∗ (0.002) (0.001) −0.051∗∗∗ −0.033∗∗∗ (0.007) (0.005) −0.190∗∗∗ −0.124∗∗∗ (0.021) (0.016) −0.005 0.275∗∗∗ (0.031) (0.022) −0.023∗∗∗ −0.012∗∗∗ (0.002) (0.002) 0.075∗∗∗ −0.212∗∗∗ (0.019) (0.020) −0.045∗ 0.236∗∗∗ (0.023) (0.021) Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes 39652 39652 71.47% 67.68% Industry Cash Cash Industry Leverage Industry Sigma Cash Flow/Assets Market to Book Size Net Working Capital/Assets Capital Expenditure R&D/Sales Dividend Dummy Acquisition Activity Foreign Pretax Income Time Fixed Effect Firm Fixed Effect Clustered Standard Error N R2 0.067 (0.044) −0.008 (0.070) −0.001 (0.002) −0.026∗∗∗ (0.007) −0.057 (0.056) −0.167∗∗∗ (0.025) 0.245∗∗ (0.110) −0.017∗ (0.010) −0.181∗∗∗ (0.058) 0.223∗∗∗ (0.058) Yes Yes Yes 40018 75.01% 53 Panel C: Placebo Test Cash 0.007 (0.004) −0.001 (0.001) −0.085∗∗ (0.036) 0.027∗∗∗ (0.003) −0.010∗∗∗ (0.002) −0.229∗∗∗ (0.018) −0.273∗∗∗ (0.030) −0.201∗∗∗ (0.015) 0.031 (0.028) −0.058∗∗∗ (0.007) −0.104∗∗∗ (0.013) Yes Yes Yes 10333 56.11% Placebo CDS Trading Industry Sigma Cash Flow/Assets Market to Book Size Net Working Capital/Assets Capital Expenditure Leverage R&D/Sales Dividend Dummy Acquisition Activity Time Fixed Effect Firm Fixed Effect Clustered Standard Error N R2 54 Table A3 Simultaneous Effect of CDS on Corporate Finance: Corporate Governance Control This table presents the estimates of the simultaneous effect of CDS on corporate leverage and cash holdings in a sample including firms with CDS and non-CDS propensity-score-matched firms. Leverage and Cash equations are estimated simultaneously by two-stage least squares procedures. E-index is the entrenchment index, which is a measure of the quality of firms’ governance provisions. The coefficient of interest are those of CDS Trading and CDS Trading×E-index, which capture the impact of the inception of CDS trading on cash holdings and leverage. The sample period is 1997-2009, based on quarterly observations. (*** denotes significance at the 1% level, ** significance at the 5% level, and * significance at the 10% level. The numbers in parentheses are standard errors.) CDS Trading CDS Trading×E-index E-index Cash Industry Leverage Leverage 0.064∗∗∗ (0.003) −0.008∗∗∗ (0.001) 0.004∗∗∗ (0.001) −0.582∗∗∗ (0.072) 0.164∗∗∗ (0.019) Leverage Industry Cash Industry Sigma Cash Flow/Assets Market to Book Size Net Working Capital/Assets Capital Expenditure R&D/Sales Dividend Dummy Acquisition Activity Time Fixed Effect Firm Fixed Effect Clustered Standard Error R2 N 0.044∗∗∗ (0.015) −0.345∗∗∗ (0.023) −0.014∗∗∗ (0.001) −0.031∗∗∗ (0.002) −0.052∗∗∗ (0.007) −0.200∗∗∗ (0.023) −0.043 (0.031) 0.016∗∗∗ (0.005) 0.101∗∗∗ (0.019) Yes Yes Yes 72.06% 34516 55 Cash 0.032∗∗∗ (0.004) −0.004∗∗∗ (0.001) 0.002∗∗∗ (0.001) 0.000 (0.077) 0.376∗∗∗ (0.028) 0.059∗∗∗ (0.009) 0.005 (0.031) 0.002 (0.001) −0.022∗∗∗ (0.002) −0.010∗ (0.006) −0.139∗∗∗ (0.016) 0.239∗∗∗ (0.021) −0.035∗∗∗ (0.004) −0.168∗∗∗ (0.018) Yes Yes Yes 73.17% 34516 Table A4 Simultaneous Effect of CDS on Leverage, Cash and Lines of Credit This table presents the estimates of the simultaneous effect of CDS on corporate leverage, cash holdings and lines of credit in a sample including firms with CDS and non-CDS propensity-score-matched firms. Lines of credit data are drawn from Dealscan. Leverage, cash, and lines of credit equations are estimated simultaneously. (*** denotes significance at the 1% level, ** significance at the 5% level, and * significance at the 10% level. The numbers in parentheses are standard errors.) Leverage Cash Lines of Credit CDS Trading 0.040∗∗∗ 0.019∗∗∗ 0.127 (0.002) (0.003) (0.129) Lines of Credit 0.009∗∗∗ −0.004∗∗∗ (0.001) (0.001) Industry Leverage 0.150∗∗∗ (0.018) Cash −0.501∗∗∗ −5.210∗∗ (0.069) (2.319) Industry Lines of Credit 0.931∗∗∗ (0.025) Industry Cash 0.385∗∗∗ (0.026) Leverage 0.119 −5.976∗∗ (0.087) (2.794) Industry Sigma −0.022∗ 0.046∗∗∗ 0.388 (0.013) (0.009) (0.295) Cash Flow/Assets −0.214∗∗∗ 0.044∗ −2.987∗∗∗ (0.021) (0.024) (0.788) Market to Book −0.014∗∗∗ 0.002∗ −0.026 (0.001) (0.001) (0.040) Size −0.025∗∗∗ −0.025∗∗∗ −0.266∗∗∗ (0.002) (0.001) (0.092) Net Working Capital/Assets −0.036∗∗∗ −0.040∗∗∗ −1.324∗∗∗ (0.007) (0.005) (0.210) Capital Expenditure −0.160∗∗∗ −0.146∗∗∗ −3.125∗∗∗ (0.021) (0.014) (0.712) R&D/Sales −0.010 0.231∗∗∗ −0.763 (0.029) (0.019) (0.641) Dividend Dummy −0.022∗∗∗ −0.012∗∗∗ −0.152∗ (0.002) (0.002) (0.085) Acquisition Activity 0.095∗∗∗ −0.200∗∗∗ −0.334 (0.019) (0.018) (0.444) Time Fixed Effect Yes Yes Yes Firm Fixed Effect Yes Yes Yes Clustered Standard Error Yes Yes Yes R2 72.23% 70.34% 53.03% N 40293 40293 40293 56
© Copyright 2024