An Ex Ante Evaluation of the Effects of Banning Advertising on Junk Food Markets Pierre Dubois, Rachel Griffith and Martin O’Connell Toulouse School of Economics University of Manchester and IFS UCL and IFS May 2015 Dubois, Griffith, O’Connell (TSE) Banning Junk Food Advertising May 2015 1 / 60 Introduction Motivation Growing obesity and diet-related disease across developed world Many policies proposed/introduced Education and information campaigns Fiscal measures Regulations One discussed policy consists in banning junk food advertising UK currently bans advertising of foods high in fat, salt or sugar during children’s programs (partial ban) Need ex ante evaluation Dubois, Griffith, O’Connell (TSE) Banning Junk Food Advertising May 2015 2 / 60 Introduction Motivation There are calls for restriction of advertising in junk food markets such as a complete ban But ex ante we don’t know what will be the impact on markets which depends on How the demand shape changes with advertising Whether advertising is expansionary or pure business stealing across brands Strategic response of firms: price equilibrium Need counterfactual evaluation of supply and demand As well as questioning on evaluating welfare effects Dubois, Griffith, O’Connell (TSE) Banning Junk Food Advertising May 2015 3 / 60 Introduction Contribution Develop model of consumer demand and oligopoly supply with multi-product firms competing in price and advertising Allow advertising to impact demand in a flexible way Allow past advertising to impact current demand meaning firms play a dynamic game Estimate the model on the typical junk food market in the UK (potato chips) Simulate the impact of advertising ban on equilibrium outcomes (prices, expenditures, quantities, nutrition) Consider welfare evaluation depending on whether advertising distorts consumer’s choices Dubois, Griffith, O’Connell (TSE) Banning Junk Food Advertising May 2015 4 / 60 Consumers Demand Outline of talk 1 2 3 4 5 6 Consumers Demand Firms Behavior Data Estimates Counterfactual Equilibrium Welfare Effects Dubois, Griffith, O’Connell (TSE) Banning Junk Food Advertising May 2015 5 / 60 Consumers Demand Advertising in consumer demand model Consumer demand model such that: Allow cooperative or rival effects of advertising such that increase in advertising of one brand may: Increase demand for another brand (cooperative) Decrease demand for another brand (predatory) Lead to expansion or contraction of market Allow dynamic effects of advertising on demand: Advertising state vector for brand b: abt can depend current and past advertising expenditures Denote abt = f (ebt , ebt −1 , ebt −2 , ..., eb0 ) Dubois, Griffith, O’Connell (TSE) Banning Junk Food Advertising May 2015 6 / 60 Consumers Demand Consumer discrete choice model Random utility for consumer i, brand b, pack size s, time (market) t v¯ibst = αi (abt , pbst ) + ψi (abt , xb ) + γbi (at ) + ηi (zbs , ξ b ) + eibst where: pbst is price xb is nutrient score abt is advertising states for brand b; at = (a1t , ..., aBt ) zbs are functions of pack size ξ b is an unobserved brand characteristic eibst individual deviation that may contain some product speficic time varying unobservables With outside good : v¯i00t = ζ d0t + ei00t Dubois, Griffith, O’Connell (TSE) Banning Junk Food Advertising May 2015 7 / 60 Consumers Demand Consumer discrete choice model A flexible specification: αi (abt , pbst ) = (α0i + α1i abt ) pbst ψi (abt , xb ) = (ψ0i + ψ1i abt ) xb γbi (at ) =λi abt + ρi ∑l 6=b alt 2 ηi (zbs , ξ b ) =η1i zbs + η2i zbs + ηi ξ b where πiu = (α0i , λi , ρi , ηi ) such that πiu = π0u + π1u di + υi di with υi ∼ N (0, Σπ ) and πio = (α1i , ψ1i , η1i , η2i ) with πio = π0o + π1o di Coefficients differ by demographics (di ) and purchase occasion All advertising coefficients allow potential shift with consumer’s observed and unobserved exposure to advertising. Exposure measure is based on how much TV the consumer reports watching. Dubois, Griffith, O’Connell (TSE) Banning Junk Food Advertising May 2015 8 / 60 Consumers Demand Consumer discrete choice model From choice set Ωκ consumer chooses (b, s ) if: v¯ibst ≥ v¯ib0 s 0 t for all (b 0 , s 0 ) ∈ Ωκ Probability of purchasing (b, s ) is sibs (pt , at , ζ t ) equal to: exp(ζ d0t ) + exp[αi (abt , pbst ) + ψi (abt , xb ) + γbi (at ) + ηi (zbs , ξ b )] exp [αi (ab0 t , pb 0 s 0 t ) + ψi (ab0 t , xb 0 ) + γbi (at ) + ηi (zb0 s0 , ξ b 0 )] ∑ (b 0 ,s 0 )∈Ωκ Then aggregate demand is: sbs (pt , at , ζ t ) = Dubois, Griffith, O’Connell (TSE) Z sibs (pt , at )dF (υi , di ) Banning Junk Food Advertising May 2015 9 / 60 Consumers Demand Impact of advertising on demand is flexible Brand advertising can be (even at individual level): predatory with respect to some products and cooperative with respect to others market expanding or contracting ∂sibst =sibst ∂abt ∂sibst =sibst ∂ab 0 t λ˜ ibst − ρi (1 − si00t ) − ∑ ! (λ˜ ibs 0 t − ρi )sibs 0 t s 0 ∈ Kb ρi si00t − ∂si00t = − si00t ∂ab 0 t ∑ ! (λ˜ ib 0 s 0 t − ρi )sib 0 s 0 t s 0 ∈ Kb 0 ρi (1 − si00t ) + ∑ ! (λ˜ ib 0 s 0 t − ρi )sib 0 s 0 t s 0 ∈Kb 0 where λ˜ ibst = λi + α1i psbt + ψ1i xb Dubois, Griffith, O’Connell (TSE) Banning Junk Food Advertising May 2015 10 / 60 Consumers Demand Willingness to pay for reduction in nutrient score Advertsising affects willingness to pay: ∂v¯ibst /∂xb ∂v¯ibst /∂pbst ψ0i + ψ1i abt = α0i + α1i abt WTPibt = Increases or decreases with abt depending on the sign of ψ1i α0i − ψ0i α1i Dubois, Griffith, O’Connell (TSE) Banning Junk Food Advertising May 2015 11 / 60 Firms Behavior Outline of talk 1 2 3 4 5 6 Consumers Demand Firms Behavior Data Estimates Counterfactual Equilibrium Welfare Effects Dubois, Griffith, O’Connell (TSE) Banning Junk Food Advertising May 2015 12 / 60 Firms Behavior Supply overview Multi-product firms compete by setting simultaneously two strategic instruments to maximize profits prices and advertising expenditures Firms’ problem is dynamic because advertising today affects future demand and hence profits Estimation is innocuous to product entry and exit firm optimization Dubois, Griffith, O’Connell (TSE) Banning Junk Food Advertising May 2015 13 / 60 Firms Behavior Profit Multi-product firm j chooses (pbst , ebt ) to maximize intertemporal profit: ∞ ∑ βt ∑ t =0 (pbst − cbst ) sbs (pt , at , ζ t ) Mt − (b,s )∈Njbs ∑ ebt b ∈Njb where abt = f (ebt , ebt −1 , ebt −2 , ..., eb0 ) Njbs : set of products owned by firm j Njb : set of brands owned by firm j cbst : constant marginal cost Mt : size of the potential market ebt : advertising expenditure Dubois, Griffith, O’Connell (TSE) Banning Junk Food Advertising May 2015 14 / 60 Firms Behavior Structure of game Timing of the game: at beginning of each period firms observe state variables (at −1 , θt ) play their strategy σj mapping states to decisions (pbst , ebt )((b,s )∈N bs ) j individual demand shocks are realized and firms get current profit We assume: cost and market size follow independent Markov processes such that Et [cbst +1 ] = cbst and Et [Mt +1 ] = Mt firms play strategies which depend only on payoff relevant state variables, so σj (at −1 , θt ) (where θt ≡ (ct , Mt , ζ t )) Dubois, Griffith, O’Connell (TSE) Banning Junk Food Advertising May 2015 15 / 60 Firms Behavior Markov perfect equilibrium Firm j makes an assumption on competitive strategy profile σ−j = (σ1 , ..., σj −1 , σj +1 , ..., σJ ) and chooses its own strategy σj Value function πj∗ (., .) from Bellman equation conditional on specific strategy profile σ−j : πj∗ (at −1 , θt ) = max ∑ (pbst − cbst )sbs (pt , at , ζ t )Mt σj =(pbst ,ebt )∈Njbs − ∑ ebt + (b,s )∈Njbs βE [πj∗ (at , θt +1 )] b ∈Njb A Markov perfect equilibrium is a list of strategies σ∗ = (σ1∗ , ..., σJ∗ ) such that no firm has an incentive to deviate from the action prescribed by σj∗ in the subgame that starts from the state (at −1 , θt ) Dubois, Griffith, O’Connell (TSE) Banning Junk Food Advertising May 2015 16 / 60 Firms Behavior Markov perfect equilibrium Assume existence of a subgame perfect Markov equilibrium, and restrict attention to Markov Perfect Equilibrium in pure strategies (Maskin and Tirole, 2001) Ericson and Pakes (1995), Doraszelski and Satterthwaite (2003) give general conditions for the existence of equilibria in similar games Each solution of Bellman equation πj∗ corresponds to each MPE of dynamic game. Do not need to assume equilibrium is unique Dubois, Griffith, O’Connell (TSE) Banning Junk Food Advertising May 2015 17 / 60 Firms Behavior Price first order conditions Price first order conditions depend on Markov perfect equilibrium only through observed goods and state vector (pt , at ) sbs (pt , at , ζ t ) + ∑ 0 0 (pb0 s 0 t − cb0 s 0 t ) (b ,s )∈Nj ∂sb0 s 0 (pt , at , ζ t ) =0 ∂pbst ... we can identify marginal costs without solving for the value function πj∗ Optimality conditions of entry, exit and advertising decisions not needed for identification of costs Dubois, Griffith, O’Connell (TSE) Banning Junk Food Advertising May 2015 18 / 60 Firms Behavior Advertising Ban Simulate Counterfactual equilibrium with ban on advertising (at = 0) New price equilibrium will be played and satisfy the following per period Bertrand-Nash conditions, for all (b, s ) sbs (p, 0, ζ ) + ∑ 0 0 (pb0 s 0 t − cb0 s 0 t ) (b ,s )∈Nj where sbs (p, 0, ζ ) = Z ∂sb 0 s 0 (p, 0, ζ ) =0 ∂pbs sibs (p, 0, ζ )dF (υi , di ) is aggregate demand for product (b, s ) when advertising is banned Can check exit decisions for all possible assortments Dubois, Griffith, O’Connell (TSE) Banning Junk Food Advertising May 2015 19 / 60 Data Outline of talk 1 2 3 4 5 6 Consumers Demand Firms Behavior Data Estimates Counterfactual Equilibrium Welfare Effects Dubois, Griffith, O’Connell (TSE) Banning Junk Food Advertising May 2015 20 / 60 Data Purchase data From Kantar/TNS Worldpanel June 2009 - October 2010 Use information on a subset of households all groceries brought into home by 2873 households (food at home), 161,513 transactions all snacks bought for consumption outside the home by 2306 individuals (food on the go), 99,636 transactions Observe all barcodes bought and transaction level prices Plus demographics and product characteristics Dubois, Griffith, O’Connell (TSE) Banning Junk Food Advertising May 2015 21 / 60 Data Food at home - 26 products in total Brand Pringles: Walkers Regular: Walkers Sensations: Walkers Doritos: Walkers Other: Golden Wonder: Size 150-300g 300g+ 150-300g 300g+ 150-300g 300g+ 150-300g 300g+ <150g 150-300g 300g+ <150g 150-300g 300g+ Purchase Share 1.34% 5.54% 1.77% 23.98% 0.43% 1.81% 1.30% 3.29% 0.69% 3.73% 8.66% 0.10% 0.25% 1.15% Price (£) 1.10 2.63 1.25 2.77 1.26 2.52 1.21 2.47 1.24 1.77 3.17 1.28 1.35 2.70 ... Dubois, Griffith, O’Connell (TSE) Banning Junk Food Advertising May 2015 22 / 60 Data Food on the go - 11 products in total Brand Walkers Regular Walkers Sensations Walkers Doritos Walkers Other KP Golden Wonder: Other Size 34.5g 50g 35g 50g <30g 30g+ 35g <40g 40g+ <40g 40g+ Purchase Share 27.16% 7.19% 2.04% 4.70% 4.34% 8.94% 0.83% 3.08% 1.09% 17.57% 20.01% Price (£) 0.45 0.63 0.61 0.54 0.45 0.61 0.57 0.39 0.73 0.48 0.59 ... Dubois, Griffith, O’Connell (TSE) Banning Junk Food Advertising May 2015 23 / 60 Data Nutrient score Interested in nutrient characteristics of the products Use nutrient profile model developed by Rayner et al (2005), used by FSA and Ofcom The nutrient profiling model aggregates all nutrient characteristics into a single score For potato chips, relevant nutrients are the amount of energy, saturated fat and sodium Score is the sum of points, 1 point for each 335kJ per 100g, 1 for each 1g of saturated fat per 100g, and 1 for each 90mg of sodium per 100g Dubois, Griffith, O’Connell (TSE) Banning Junk Food Advertising May 2015 24 / 60 Data Nutrient score Brand Pringles Walkers Walkers Walkers Walkers KP GW Asda Tesco Other Nutrient score Reg Sens Dor Oth 16 10 11 12 15 18 16 15 15 12 Energy (kj per 100g) 2160 2164 2023 2095 2020 2158 2101 2125 2145 2084 Saturated fat (g per 100g) 6.31 2.56 2.16 2.86 2.50 5.87 4.01 4.13 4.65 3.84 Sodium (g per 100g) 0.62 0.59 0.71 0.66 0.82 0.85 0.92 0.75 0.77 0.70 Proposal is to ban adversiting for score above 4 (fiber and protein not shown) Dubois, Griffith, O’Connell (TSE) Banning Junk Food Advertising May 2015 25 / 60 Data Advertising data (AC Nielsen digest of advertising) Advertising expenditure by brand and month from 2001 to 2010 Includes all potato chips advertising appearing on TV, in press, on radio, on outside posters and internet We compute the stock of advertising goodwill according to: at = δat −1 + et with δ = 0.75 Dubois, Griffith, O’Connell (TSE) Banning Junk Food Advertising May 2015 26 / 60 Data Advertising Expenditures Pringles Walkers Regular Walkers Sensations Walkers Doritos Walkers Other KP Golden Wonder Asda Tesco Other Dubois, Griffith, O’Connell (TSE) Monthly expenditure Mean Min 4.50 0.00 4.97 0.00 0.54 0.00 1.75 0.00 2.89 0.00 2.09 0.00 0.08 0.00 0.01 0.00 0.08 0.00 1.58 0.00 (£100,000) Max 10.14 18.29 1.46 8.25 8.99 8.49 0.80 0.23 0.68 5.74 Banning Junk Food Advertising Total (06/09-10/10) 76.54 84.47 9.12 29.67 49.07 35.60 1.34 0.23 1.44 26.83 May 2015 27 / 60 Data 0 2000000 4000000 6000000 Pringles Walkers_Regular Walkers_Sen 4000000 0 2000000 6000000 Advertising Stocks and Flows by Brands (2000-2012) Walkers_Dor Walkers_Oth KP 0 2/2004 4/2008 6/2012 0 2/2004 4/2008 6/2012 0 2/2004 4/2008 6/2012 date Advert. Stock (.85) Advert. Stock (.75) Advert. Stock (.8) Advert. Flow Graphs by agg_brand Dubois, Griffith, O’Connell (TSE) Banning Junk Food Advertising May 2015 28 / 60 Data Advertising Stocks and Flows 4000000 0 1000000 2000000 3000000 5000000 Pringles 0 2/2004 4/2008 6/2012 date Advert. Stock (.85) Advert. Stock (.75) Advert. Flow Dubois, Griffith, O’Connell (TSE) Banning Junk Food Advertising Advert. Stock (.8) Advert. Stock (.7) May 2015 29 / 60 Data Advertising Stocks and Flows 0 2000000 4000000 6000000 Walkers Regular 0 2/2004 4/2008 6/2012 date Advert. Stock (.85) Advert. Stock (.75) Advert. Flow Dubois, Griffith, O’Connell (TSE) Banning Junk Food Advertising Advert. Stock (.8) Advert. Stock (.7) May 2015 30 / 60 Data Advertising Stocks and Flows 0 1000000200000030000004000000 Walkers Sensations 0 2/2004 4/2008 6/2012 date Advert. Stock (.85) Advert. Stock (.75) Advert. Flow Dubois, Griffith, O’Connell (TSE) Banning Junk Food Advertising Advert. Stock (.8) Advert. Stock (.7) May 2015 31 / 60 Data Advertising Stocks and Flows 2000000 5000000 0 1000000 3000000 4000000 Walkers Doritos 0 2/2004 4/2008 6/2012 date Advert. Stock (.85) Advert. Stock (.75) Advert. Flow Dubois, Griffith, O’Connell (TSE) Banning Junk Food Advertising Advert. Stock (.8) Advert. Stock (.7) May 2015 32 / 60 Data 01000000 2000000 3000000 4000000 Pringles Walkers_Regular Walkers_Sen 3000000 01000000 2000000 4000000 Advertising Stocks and Flows by Brands (2009-2010) Walkers_Dor Walkers_Oth KP 2/20097/2009 12/2009 5/2010 10/2010 2/20097/2009 12/2009 5/2010 10/2010 2/20097/2009 12/2009 5/2010 10/2010 date Advert. Stock (.85) Advert. Stock (.75) Advert. Flow Advert. Stock (.8) Advert. Stock (.7) Graphs by agg_brand Dubois, Griffith, O’Connell (TSE) Banning Junk Food Advertising May 2015 33 / 60 Data 0 0 .5 1 1.5 2 2.5 3 3.5 4 500000 1000000150000020000002500000 Advertising Stocks, Flows and Prices 7/2009 12/2009 5/2010 10/2010 date Advert. Stock (.75) Price (Pringles:150-300g) Dubois, Griffith, O’Connell (TSE) Banning Junk Food Advertising Advert. Flow Price (Pringles:300g+) May 2015 34 / 60 Data 0 0 .5 1 1.5 1000000 2 2.5 3 2000000 3.5 4 3000000 Advertising Stocks, Flows and Prices 7/2009 12/2009 5/2010 10/2010 date Advert. Stock (.75) Price (Walkers Regular:150-300g) Dubois, Griffith, O’Connell (TSE) Advert. Flow Price (Walkers Regular:300g+) Banning Junk Food Advertising May 2015 35 / 60 Data 0 0 .5 1 200000 1.5 2 400000 2.5 3 600000 3.5 4 800000 Advertising Stocks, Flows and Prices 7/2009 12/2009 5/2010 10/2010 date Advert. Stock (.75) Price (Walkers Sens.:150-300g) Dubois, Griffith, O’Connell (TSE) Advert. Flow Price (Walkers Sens.:300g+) Banning Junk Food Advertising May 2015 36 / 60 Data 0 0 .5 1 1.5 500000 2 2.5 3 1000000 3.5 4 1500000 Advertising Stocks, Flows and Prices 7/2009 12/2009 5/2010 10/2010 date Advert. Stock (.75) Price (Walkers Doritos:150-300g) Dubois, Griffith, O’Connell (TSE) Advert. Flow Price (Walkers Doritos:300g+) Banning Junk Food Advertising May 2015 37 / 60 Data Advertising and Price Strategies Unconditionally, prices are uncorrelated with advertising stocks and advertising flows Conditional on product fixed effects: Prices are uncorrelated with advertising stocks and advertising flows Prices have brand specific within product correlations with (lagged) advertising stocks (positive for Pringles, Golden Wonders, negative for Walkers Sensations and not significant for others) Evidence consistent with multiple equilibria, pulsing strategies Dubois, Griffith, O’Connell (TSE) Banning Junk Food Advertising May 2015 38 / 60 Data Consumers Descriptive Statistics Demographic group Composition HH no children skill level high low Pensioners HH children high low Number of purchase occasions food at home food on-the-go income high medium low medium-high low high medium low medium-high low Child purchase 22721 13178 13341 10187 16147 14384 20426 14292 7091 15349 14397 14371 8376 8219 6667 8559 6016 12786 8502 4494 9549 8932 3165 All parameters are allowed to vary across cells Dubois, Griffith, O’Connell (TSE) Banning Junk Food Advertising May 2015 39 / 60 Estimates Outline of talk 1 2 3 4 5 6 Consumers Demand Firms Behavior Data Estimates Counterfactual Equilibrium Welfare Effects Dubois, Griffith, O’Connell (TSE) Banning Junk Food Advertising May 2015 40 / 60 Estimates Identification: price and advertising variations Use individual transaction level data Control for time and brand effects Price variation National pricing in the UK (no variation according to regional unobserved heterogeneity) Time series variation of prices within product due to promotions Advertising variation Exposure, demographics and random coefficients on advertising allow heterogenous effects across consumers Use control function approach (Blundell and Powell, 2004 and Petrin and Train, 2010) because brand advertising flows may be correlated with unobserved individual demand shocks. Use advertising expenditure on ready-meals interacted with brand fixed effects are used as instruments Many robustness checks Dubois, Griffith, O’Connell (TSE) Banning Junk Food Advertising May 2015 41 / 60 Estimates Advertising effects on brand demand % change in demand if advertising expenditure set to zero (ceteris paribus) Walkers Regular Pringles KP 0.497 0.450 0.209 -2.77 1.39 0.63 [-4.30, -1.44] [1.06, 1.72] [0.50, 0.76] Pringles 3.43 -19.53 0.25 [2.78, 4.10] [-21.54, -17.97] [0.11, 0.39] KP -0.35 0.03 -2.63 [-0.81, 0.11] [-0.35, 0.39] [-3.36, -1.99] ... ... ... ... -1.15 -1.10 -0.42 [-1.46, -0.85] [-1.41, -0.79] [-0.53, -0.31] Numbers are means across markets (i.e. months). Adv exp (£m) Walkers Regular Dubois, Griffith, O’Connell (TSE) Banning Junk Food Advertising May 2015 42 / 60 Estimates Effect of advertising on own price elasticities Walkers Regular Obs. Zero advert. advert. exp. exp. Pringles Obs. Zero advert. advert. exp. exp. <150g 150-300g -1.49 [-1.57, -1.44] 300g+ -2.20 [-2.32, -2.10] Dubois, Griffith, O’Connell (TSE) -1.62 [-1.69, -1.57] -2.54 [-2.67, -2.44] -1.40 [-1.46, -1.35] -2.37 [-2.51, -2.26] Banning Junk Food Advertising -1.53 [-1.60, -1.49] -2.74 [-2.88, -2.64] KP Obs. advert. exp. -1.33 Zero advert. exp. -1.37 [-1.38, -1.29] [-1.42, -1.32] -1.68 [-1.75, -1.63] -2.77 [-2.89, -2.67] May 2015 -1.74 [-1.80, -1.68] -2.88 [-3.01, -2.79] 43 / 60 Estimates Willingness to pay for one point reduction in nutrient score Advertising: Food at home Willingness to pay in pence None Medium High 5.3 [4.7, 5.8] 2.5 [2.3, 2.8] 3.5 [3.0, 3.9] 1.7 [1.5, 1.9] 0.6 [-0.4, 1.6] 0.3 [-0.2, 0.8] 0.9 [0.7, 1.1] 0.0 [-0.2, 0.1] -0.8 [-0.9, -0.5] 1.7 -0.1 [1.3, 2.1] [-0.4, 0.3] Numbers are median WTP in pence. -1.5 [-1.8, -1.0] % of mean price Food on-the-go Willingness to pay in pence % of mean price Dubois, Griffith, O’Connell (TSE) Banning Junk Food Advertising May 2015 44 / 60 Counterfactual Equilibrium Outline of talk 1 2 3 4 5 6 Consumers Demand Firms Behavior Data Estimates Counterfactual Equilibrium Welfare Effects Dubois, Griffith, O’Connell (TSE) Banning Junk Food Advertising May 2015 45 / 60 Counterfactual Equilibrium Counterfactual Estimate marginal costs using supply model Simulate counterfactuals no pricing response with pricing response check deviations of Nash equilibrim in product exits Dubois, Griffith, O’Connell (TSE) Banning Junk Food Advertising May 2015 46 / 60 Counterfactual Equilibrium Advertising ban: pricing response Banning advertising leads to toughening price competition The average price in the market falls by 9% Pricing response differs across firms and over products The big advertisers (e.g. Walkers and Pringles) lower prices For instance, Walkers reduces price of its most popular brand by the most, 34p (or 28%) reduction for the 150-300g pack, and 56p (or 20%) for the 300g+ pack Besides advertising ban, no products exit the market (keeping all products is a Nash equilibrium) Dubois, Griffith, O’Connell (TSE) Banning Junk Food Advertising May 2015 47 / 60 Counterfactual Equilibrium Advertising ban Pre ban Expenditure (£m) 220.86 [217.17, 222.99] % change Quantity (mKg) Mean pack size condi. on purchase % change Dubois, Griffith, O’Connell (TSE) [195.79, 216.42] [201.23, 220.38] -6.35 -3.92 [-10.88, -1.82] [-8.13, 0.41] 32.14 29.18 34.95 [31.62, 32.47] [27.62, 30.65] [33.18, 36.28] % change Probability of selecting potato chips % change Post ban No firm response With firm response 206.82 212.19 -9.21 8.73 [-13.60, -4.29] [3.39, 13.53] 0.37 0.37 0.38 [0.36, 0.37] [0.35, 0.39] [0.35, 0.39] 0.22 1.79 [-5.33, 6.16] [-4.02, 7.11] 0.17 0.15 0.18 [0.17, 0.17] [0.15, 0.16] [0.17, 0.19] -9.43 6.63 [-13.18, -5.65] [2.23, 10.83] Banning Junk Food Advertising May 2015 48 / 60 Counterfactual Equilibrium Advertising ban Saturates (1000 kg) Observed equilibrium 1264.91 [1244.03, 1279.87] % change Salt (1000 kg) % change Dubois, Griffith, O’Connell (TSE) -0.54 [-18.38, -9.31] [-5.53, 4.26] 515.34 601.74 [487.81, 540.07] [571.33, 625.24] -10.41 4.61 [-14.79, -5.56] [-0.42, 9.15] 13.80 13.33 13.05 [13.77, 13.83] [13.25, 13.42] [12.97, 13.15] -3.36 -5.41 [-3.96, -2.75] [-5.95, -4.66] 3.94 3.73 3.61 [3.92, 3.95] [3.69, 3.76] [3.58, 3.66] % change Salt intensity (g/100g) [1191.95, 1313.92] -14.08 575.20 % change Saturates intensity (g/100g) [1026.40, 1142.62] [565.94, 581.14] % change Nutrient score Advertising banned no price response with price response 1086.79 1258.06 -5.34 -8.28 [-6.17, -4.41] [-9.08, -7.09] 1.79 1.77 1.73 [1.79, 1.79] [1.76, 1.77] [1.72, 1.73] -1.32 -3.61 [-1.67, -0.93] [-3.95, -3.07] Banning Junk Food Advertising May 2015 49 / 60 Counterfactual Equilibrium Consumer welfare But what about welfare? Consumers may be hurt by advertising ban How we measure welfare depends on whether we view advertising as: Informative about prices/characteristics (Stigler, 1961; Nelson, 1995) A characteristic that consumers value (Stigler and Becker, 1977) Persuasive (Marshall, 1921; Robinson, 1933; Kaldor, 1950) Dubois, Griffith, O’Connell (TSE) Banning Junk Food Advertising May 2015 50 / 60 Counterfactual Equilibrium Consumer welfare: advertising as a characteristic If advertising is a characteristic, the payoff function represents the consumer’s (indirect) utility function; the consumer makes decisions to maximize utility (standard revealed preference approach) Expected utility is given by: Wit (pt , at ) = E max v¯ibst (b,s )∈Ωκ # " = ln ∑ exp [αi (abt , pbst ) + ψi (abt , xb ) + γbi (at ) + ηi (zbs , ξ b )] (b,s )∈Ωκ Issue: the normalization of common advertising effect on outside good will affect welfare changes of the ban Model with v¯ibst (at ) − γ(at ) and v¯i00t − γ(at ) is observationally equivalent but welfare change depends on γ(at ) being on inside or outside good Dubois, Griffith, O’Connell (TSE) Banning Junk Food Advertising May 2015 51 / 60 Counterfactual Equilibrium Consumer welfare: advertising distorts decisions Persuasive view Advertising can lead consumers to act as non-standard decision makers, by providing environmental “cues” to consumers (Bernheim and Rangel, 2005). Bernheim and Rangel (2009): “choices made in the presence of those cues are predicated on improperly processed information, and welfare evaluations should be guided by choices made under other conditions” Dubois, Griffith, O’Connell (TSE) Banning Junk Food Advertising May 2015 52 / 60 Counterfactual Equilibrium Consumer welfare: advertising distorts decisions If advertising is distorting, then consumer’s (“experience”) utility (Kahneman et al. 1997) should be evaluated in the absence of advertising : vbibst = αi (0, pbst ) + ψi (0, xb ) + γbi (0) + ηi (zbs , ξ b ) + eibst Expected “experience” utility from the choice made with different “decision” utility is: " # ci (at , pt ) =E vbarg max{v¯ } W (b,s )∈Ωκ Dubois, Griffith, O’Connell (TSE) Banning Junk Food Advertising ibst May 2015 53 / 60 Counterfactual Equilibrium Consumer welfare: advertising distorts decisions Expected “experience” utility from the choice made with different “decision” utility: # " ci (at , pt ) =E vbarg max{v¯ } W ibst (b,s )∈Ωκ =Wit (pt , at ) − ∑ sibst [ (αi (abt , pbst ) − αi (0, pbst )) (b,s )∈Ωκ + (ψi (abt , xb ) − ψi (0, xb )) + (γbi (at ) − γbi (0)) ] Dubois, Griffith, O’Connell (TSE) Banning Junk Food Advertising May 2015 54 / 60 Counterfactual Equilibrium Consumer welfare: advertising distorts decisions When advertising distorts decision making, welfare impact of advertising evaluated under preferences in absence of advertising Denote p0 a counterfactual price equilibrium with no advertising Welfare difference between the post and pre advertising ban is: ci (at , pt ) Wi 0, p0t − W ci (at , pt ) = Wi (0, pt ) − W +Wi 0, p0t − Wi (0, pt ) (choice distortion effect) (price competition effect) ci (0, p) = Wi (0, p) where we use W Dubois, Griffith, O’Connell (TSE) Banning Junk Food Advertising May 2015 55 / 60 Counterfactual Equilibrium Typical Junk Food Advertising Dubois, Griffith, O’Connell (TSE) Banning Junk Food Advertising May 2015 56 / 60 Counterfactual Equilibrium Consumer welfare: advertising distorts decisions Choice distortion effect (£m) Price competition effect (£m) Total compensating variation ($m) Change in profits ($m) Total change in welfare (£m) Dubois, Griffith, O’Connell (TSE) Advertising banned No price resp. With price resp. 35.9 35.9 [34.7, 40.5] [34.7, 40.5] 0.0 19.2 [15.9, 21.6] 35.9 55.1 [34.7, 40.5] [52.8, 60.1] 0.2 0.2 [-4.9, 5.9] [-4.8, 5.3] 36.1 55.3 [32.2, 43.7] [49.9, 62.6] Banning Junk Food Advertising May 2015 57 / 60 Counterfactual Equilibrium Consumer welfare: characteristic view Characteristics effect (£m) Price competition effect (£m) Total compensating variation ($m) Change in profits ($m) Total change in welfare (£m) Dubois, Griffith, O’Connell (TSE) Advertising banned No price resp. With price resp. -30.6 -30.6 [-38.6, -20.4] [-38.6, -20.4] 0.0 19.2 [15.9, 21.6] -30.6 -11.4 [-38.6, -20.4] [-20.4, -1.3] 0.2 0.2 [-4.9, 5.9] [-4.8, 5.3] -30.4 -11.2 [-43.6, -14.8] [-25.2, 3.0] Banning Junk Food Advertising May 2015 58 / 60 Conclusions Aggregate impact of ban We find that in response to introduction of an advertising ban in potato chips markets: Advertising ban leads to substitution to healthier products (higher WTP) At constant prices, quantity of potato chips purchased would decrease But stronger price competition leads to lower prices and thus increase in quantity consumed and total calories but not significant changes in salt or saturated fat Lack of advertising isn’t enough to deter bad products Profitability in the market is almost unchanged If advertising is viewed as distorting prices, total welfare would rise Welfare would decrease if advertising as a characteristic (assuming advertising affects only inside goods) Dubois, Griffith, O’Connell (TSE) Banning Junk Food Advertising May 2015 59 / 60 Conclusions Further research Current counterfactual considered does not need to solve fully for firms’ equilibrium policy functions But this is not the case for tax simulation How would firms adjust their price and advertising strategies in response to introduction of a nutrient tax? an advertising tax? Raises issues around multiple equilibria in counterfactuals Dubois, Griffith, O’Connell (TSE) Banning Junk Food Advertising May 2015 60 / 60
© Copyright 2024