J. OF PUBLIC BUDGETING, ACCOUNTING & FINANCIAL MANAGEMENT, 11(1), 81-116 SPRING 1999 ESTIMATING AND MANAGING THE FEDERAL SUBSIDY OF FANNIE MAE AND FREDDIE MAC: IS EITHER TASK POSSIBLE? Ron Feldman* ABSTRACT. Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac receive explicit and implicit off-budget subsidies from the federal government. This paper reviews the methods to estimate the dollar amount of the subsidies. None of the three techniques to estimate the indirect subsidy yield accurate point estimates. They do suggest that Fannie and Freddie could receive billions of dollars in subsidies in some years and much smaller amounts in other years. However, assessing the size of the implied subsidies is most valuable in demonstrating that Fannie and Freddie, not the federal government, control their size. Efforts to improve federal control face significant difficulties including informational asymmetries and the political incentives that have led to the status quo. These drawbacks bolster the rationale for eliminating federal support for Fannie and Freddie. INTRODUCTION The thrift industry debacle focused analytical and political resources on the contingent liabilities and implicit subsidies of the federal government. The Congress, for example, required several agencies in 1989 and 1990 to assess the risks undertaken by government sponsored enterprises (GSEs) that are implicitly borne and subsidized by taxpayers. (1) GSEs are privately owned, federally chartered corporations that operate nationally with specialized lending powers. Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac are the two largest GSEs and funders of one- to four-family mortgages in the United States. The studies were followed in 1992 by a ____________ * Ron Feldman is a senior financial analyst with the Banking Supervision Department at the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis. Copyright © 1999 by PrAcademics Press ESTIMATING AND MANAGING THE FEDERAL SUBSIDY OF FANNIE MAE AND FREDDIE MAC 83 Congressional mandate to evaluate the desirability and feasibility of eliminating Fannie and Freddie’s implicit federal support. (2) Given the attention generated by these inquiries, it is not surprising that a body of literature estimating the size of the subsidy that Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac enjoy developed over the last fifteen years. This article reviews the subsidy literature. Fannie and Freddie do not receive their subsidies through on-budget federal appropriations. Instead they receive explicit, but off-budget, subsidies through means such as exemptions from certain fees and taxes. They receive much larger implicit, off-budget subsidies through perceived, but not legal, credit support from the federal government. Subsidy estimates vary with the most recent set of calculations putting the total subsidy for both firms at about $6 billion for 1995. Methods of estimating the implicit subsidy include determining the net market value of Fannie and Freddie’s balance sheet assets and liabilities and contrasting it with their market capitalization, modeling the implicit support provided to Fannie and Freddie as a put option, and comparing the yields on Fannie and Freddie’s securities to the yields on similar securities issued by firms without GSE status. Estimating how much Fannie and Freddie have lowered rates on conforming mortgages also provides an indirect method for valuing the implicit subsidy. These methods have significant weaknesses and valuations of the GSE subsidy should not be considered accurate point estimates. Instead, these calculations provide valuable order of magnitude estimates and evidence that the subsidy could be quite large. The estimating techniques also indicate that Fannie and Freddie control the value of the subsidy and that the federal government has virtually no idea about the level of public resources it provides Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac at the time they receive the subsidy. Federal deficiencies in managing the GSE subsidy are no secret. As a result, analysts have also suggested a variety of methods for controlling its size. These techniques include requiring additional disclosure of the subsidy, levying fees on the use of the implicit guarantee, requiring that Fannie and Freddie maintain high bond ratings, restricting the amount and type of business they can conduct, and making the social goals they must meet more stringent. A standard method for controlling risk, prudential capital standards, are currently under development. Methods of subsidy management face serious obstacles given the huge informational advantage and political influence the two firms maintain. The benefit of providing firms with indirect subsidies only to devise methods to reduce the value of subsidies or to 84 FELDMAN redirect them is also questionable. The difficulties that the government faces in obtaining information on the GSE subsidy and managing it provide additional justification for considering its elimination. The first section of this article provides a very brief background on the two housing enterprises. The second section summarizes research estimating the size of subsidy, identifies weaknesses with these methods and discusses the benefits of conducting such estimates. The third section briefly reviews some recommendations for managing the subsidy and highlights two important reasons why these methods may not to be completely effective. A conclusion summarizes the findings. BACKGROUND ON FANNIE MAE AND FREDDIE MAC(3) The Congress charters GSEs to correct perceived failures in private credit markets. The private benefits GSEs provide policy makers, such as campaign contributions, are discussed later. The Congress created Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac specifically to intermediate funds between national capital markets and local mortgage markets. This intervention seemed necessary, in part, because other federal policies including prohibitions on interstate banking and branching and limitations on banks’ ability to pay market rates for deposits contributed to regional shortages of funds available for mortgage lending. Fannie and Freddie’s most common method of intermediating funds involves the securitization of mortgages. Usually, the agencies will receive a pool of mortgages from a seller and, in exchange, swap mortgage-backed securities (MBS) backed by that same pool. The enterprises earn a fee equal to the difference between rates paid on the underlying mortgages and rates paid on the MBS. Fannie and Freddie guarantee the payment of principal and interest on the mortgages underlying their MBS. Both agencies also engage in portfolio lending in which they purchase mortgages to hold, fund the purchase via issuance of unsecured debt and profit from the spread. Fannie and Freddie have been successful in limiting regional fund shortages; their intermediation has integrated national capital markets with local mortgage markets (Hendershott and Van Order, 1989). Fannie and Freddie’s current legislative mission focuses on providing stability and liquidity in the secondary market for residential mortgages. (4) The breadth of the firms’ operations to achieve that goal is enormous. As of year end 1996, about $1 trillion in Fannie and Freddie MBS were outstanding and the firms held $424 billion of mortgages in portfolio (5) (Fannie Mae, 1996a; and Freddie Mae, 1996a). By way of comparison, Fannie and ESTIMATING AND MANAGING THE FEDERAL SUBSIDY OF FANNIE MAE AND FREDDIE MAC 85 Freddie financed more of the mortgages outstanding as of year end 1996 than the entire commercial banking system and had as much debt outstanding as all state and local governments (Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, 1996a; 1996b). Fannie and Freddie are prevented from originating mortgages in carrying out their missions. The enterprises also cannot finance mortgages whose original principal amount exceeds the “conforming limit”, $214,600 in 1997, although the firms will have access to over 75 percent of all new mortgage originations under this limit (Nyhan, 1996). In addition, they cannot finance mortgages with loan-to-value ratios of greater than 80 percent unless an acceptable credit enhancement is offered. The enhancement usually takes the form of mortgage insurance. Finally, the firms can only purchase mortgages that meet the standards of private institutional mortgage investors. The enterprises are also less active in financing non-conventional mortgages, those insured by the federal government through the Federal Housing Administration (FHA) or the Department of Veterans Affairs (VA), because they are at a cost-disadvantage relative to the Government National Mortgage Association (GNMA). GNMA securitizes non-conventional mortgages and guarantees MBS with the full faith and credit of the U.S. Treasury. The Congress subsidizes Fannie and Freddie in support of their missions. Part of the subsidy is explicit. The enterprises do not have to pay state and local income tax on their earnings. The securities of Fannie and Freddie are also exempt from the Securities and Exchange Commission’s (SEC) registration process. Finally, both firms have a free back-up line of credit (LOC) of $2.25 billion from the Department of Treasury. Most attention, however, has focused on their implicit subsidy. Lenders believe that the federal government would make good on the enterprises’ financial obligations even though the federal government rejects any legal responsibility for these debts. The commitment of the Congress to the enterprises’ mission, the federal government’s previous financial support of GSE debt, and the intentional similarity between GSE securities and Treasury securities lead investors to act as if the credit of the U.S. Department of Treasury (1996) supports GSE securities. (6) The implicit subsidy benefits Fannie and Freddie in a number of ways. First, it reduces their cost of raising funds. This reduction can be characterized in terms of borrowing rates or capital and credit enhancements. Given their level of capital, the implicit guarantee allows Fannie and Freddie to raise funds on the debt and MBS markets at a lower rate than would 86 FELDMAN otherwise be available. Alternatively, because of the implicit guarantee, Fannie and Freddie do not have to incur the cost of capital or credit enhancements that they would otherwise have to in order to borrow at their current rates. In addition, federal implicit support provides bank regulators with the comfort to allow insured depositories to hold less capital against Fannie and Freddie MBS than they do against private MBS. This raises the price that banks are willing to pay for GSE MBS and thus lowers Fannie and Freddie’s cost of funds. Second, the implicit subsidy gives Fannie and Freddie almost guaranteed access to capital markets regardless of their solvency. Fannie and Freddie would not face the credit rationing that other firms in weak financial condition may meet. Finally, the combination of the subsidy and existence of only two secondary mortgage market GSEs conveys a duopoly to Fannie and Freddie in the securitization of conforming, conventional one- to four-family mortgages. The preponderance of evidence suggests that Fannie and Freddie tacitly collude in this market (Goodman and Passmore, 1992; Hermalin and Jaffee, 1996). The lack of a competitive market allows Fannie and Freddie to retain more of the subsidy than they would be able to if the government granted GSE status to a large number of non-colluding, secondary market firms. ESTIMATING FANNIE’s AND FREDDIE’s SUBSIDY The General Accounting Office (GAO) made the first estimate of some aspects of the direct subsidy that Fannie and Freddie receive. GAO arrived at a value of $400 million for 1995. Much more attention has been paid to the worth of the implicit subsidy. Analysts use four valuation techniques to estimate the value of the implicit subsidy. First, some economists have valued the implied guarantee as the difference between the market value of a GSE and the market value of its assets and liabilities. Second, analysts have treated the implied guarantee as creating an option to the GSEs to put their assets to the federal government when the value of the assets fall below the value of the liabilities backed by implied guarantee. The option is then assessed using variations on market pricing techniques. Third, analysts have calculated the implied subsidy as being equal to the difference between Fannie and Freddie’s cost of funds with GSE status and without it. Finally, a method that provides an indirect and incomplete valuation of the implicit ESTIMATING AND MANAGING THE FEDERAL SUBSIDY OF FANNIE MAE AND FREDDIE MAC 87 subsidy involves determining how Fannie and Freddie’s activities have lowered rates on conforming mortgages. These techniques produced a wide range of subsidy estimates. Some of the estimates are not directly comparable because they review different component parts of the total subsidy for different years. The most recent estimates of the total value of the subsidy for both firms put it at about $6 billion although estimates have been significantly lower in the past. All four of these techniques have serious flaws and the estimates they produce should not be taken too seriously as point valuations. Rather, they are better understood as order of magnitude estimates and indications that the subsidy could, at times, be extremely large. The estimates also demonstrate that the enterprises have much more control over the subsidy than does the federal government. More importantly, they provide evidence that the federal government has little idea about the amount of resources it provides Fannie and Freddie at the time the resources are provided. Estimating Explicit Subsidies Estimates of the three explicit subsidies, exemption from state and local income tax, exemption from SEC registration, and free provision of a Treasury back-up letter of credit, are rare with only one, by GAO, available (General Accounting Office, 1996a) SEC Registration Fee. The Congress sets the SEC fee for registration in legislation. In 1995, for example, the fee was .034 percent (or 3.4 basis points) of the face value of the security being issued. GAO estimated the savings of the exemption to Fannie and Freddie by multiplying the fee by the total face value of their debt issuance. GAO found this savings to be about $102 million in 1995. Even this simple estimate requires some assumptions. GAO excluded short-term debt from the calculation as ASEC officials told [GAO] that such debt could be defined as commercial paper and not be subject to SEC registration fees (emphasis added)” (General Accounting Office, 1996a: 5). State and Local Income Tax. Corporations such as Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac with regional operations and nationwide activities are taxed by a number of states. It is not clear, a priori, which states would tax Fannie and Freddie and how such a levy would be calculated by each state (Zimmerman, 1995). As a result, GAO used an estimated average state income tax and found that the state component of the exemption would be worth about $367 million. 88 FELDMAN GAO did not estimate the local government portion of the exemption. If possible, Fannie and Freddie would modify their legal structure and negotiate with their main state and local taxing authorities to reduce their tax payment once the exemption was lifted. Thus, Fannie and Freddie would not likely pay the full amount of the taxes that GAO (1996a) calculated. LOC and Credit Rating. GAO understated the worth of Fannie and Fannie’s direct benefits by not including an estimate of the value of the back-up LOC from the U.S. Treasury. Likewise analysts have not estimated the savings that Fannie and Freddie receive because they do not have to obtain credit ratings on their debt. Estimating Implicit Subsidies Analysts have used three general methods for estimating the value of the implicit guarantee: A market value accounting approach, a related option pricing approach, and a debt or capital comparison approach. Part of the subsidy could also be examined by determining the reduction in mortgage rates for loans financed by Freddie or Fannie. Table 1 summarizes the research findings. Market Value Accounting Technique. Kane and Foster (1986) provided the first estimate of the value of Fannie Mae’s implicit subsidy by modeling the income generated by the implicit guarantee as a capitalized, unbookable asset that would, by first accounting principles, equal the difference between the market value of Fannie as measured by its stock price and the net market value of Fannie’s assets (Kane and Foster, 1986). More specifically, they view the implicit guarantee as creating an income stream or premium for Fannie Mae each year. The premium represents the rate differential between Fannie’s cost of funds without the guarantee, what Kane and Foster (1986) called the warranted rate, and their cost of funds with the implicit guarantee. They argued that the capitalized value of the income premium minus the capitalized fees for the implicit guarantee, which they put at zero, is a capital asset that belongs on the asset side of Fannie Mae’s balance sheet. Kane and Foster (1986) marked Fannie’s assets and liabilities, almost entirely mortgage loans and borrowings respectively, to market as of the end of each year for the period 1978 to 1985. They also determined the market value of the firm for the same period based on outstanding shares and stock prices. The value of the implicit guarantee is then derived based on what Kane and Foster term, “the first principles of corporate finance.” Namely, the market value of Fannie Mae must equal the market value of its bookable ESTIMATING AND MANAGING THE FEDERAL SUBSIDY OF FANNIE MAE AND FREDDIE MAC 89 and unbookable assets (e.g., the capitalized value of the income premium from the implicit guarantee) less its bookable and unbookable liabilities (e.g., the capitalized fees of guarantees). In other words, the net value of the implicit guarantee will equal the market value of the firm minus the net value of marked-to-market booked items. They found that the value of the guarantee ranged from $600 million to $11 billion in the 1978 to 1985 period. The Congressional Budget Office (CBO) updated Kane and Foster (1986). CBO (1996) divided the annual cost to the government of providing the unbooked asset into two components. One component is the annual change in the value of the asset that the government provides to Fannie and Freddie. Of course, Fannie and Freddie will have more equity in periods where the unbooked asset is worth more. As such, CBO characterized the subsidy as the provision of equity to the GSEs. The second component tries to capture the value of the equity that the unbooked asset provided in earlier periods. This value was described as the return that taxpayers have foregone on equity provided in earlier periods. To measure the foregone return on equity, taxpayers were assumed to earn the same return as other equity holders. CBO found that the cost to the taxpayer of providing the implicit support to Fannie and Freddie averaged $7.8 billion for the period 1993 to 1995. Weaknesses of Market Value Technique. There are at least three serious concerns with the market value approach of Kane and Foster (1986).(7) First, they assumed that the only unbooked assets and liabilities of value for Fannie Mae relate to the implicit guarantee. However, Fannie and Freddie could benefit from unrecognized “goodwill” reflecting the value of their experience and relationships in the secondary mortgage market. The market value of thousands of publicly traded firms exceeds their book value in part because of such unbooked assets. Some of these non-GSE firms would also have market values exceeding their book values after the latter is adjusted to reflect market prices. Second, Kane and Foster (1986) could have underestimated the indirect costs of receiving the implicit guarantee such as regulation and restrictions on business opportunities. Finally, analysts may not correctly mark the GSEs’ assets to market. This problem would appear to be somewhat obviated because both Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac have disclosed their mark to market values since 1992. But, these estimates will become less reliable as the portfolios of both firms contain more complicated ESTIMATING AND MANAGING THE FEDERAL SUBSIDY OF FANNIE MAE AND FREDDIE MAC 91 92 FELDMAN ESTIMATING AND MANAGING THE FEDERAL SUBSIDY OF FANNIE MAE AND FREDDIE MAC 93 mortgages and securities, and as Fannie and Freddie have increasing incentives to manipulate their valuation to make the implicit subsidy appear small. Option Pricing Technique. There is a substantial literature of modeling and valuing federal deposit insurance (FDI) as a put option.(8) Under this approach, the deposit insurance guarantee is treated as if it were a European put option.(9) The examination schedule, or audit period, of the institution determines the maturity of the FDI option. The exercise price of the FDI option is captured in the value of its insured deposits. If the net of the bank’s assets and uninsured liabilities is less than this strike price, the bank is insolvent, the option is exercised and owners of the bank put its assets to the federal insurer who must bear the difference between net assets and insured liabilities. GSEs are provided with a conceptually identical put, although the guarantee that creates the option is implicit. This description suggests that the option approach is broadly similar to the Kane and Foster (1986) technique described above. Both methods view the implicit guarantee as creating an unbooked asset on the balance sheet of the GSE. The difference between the two methodologies arises in the valuation of the unbooked asset. Whereas Kane and Foster (1986) “back out” the value of the unbooked asset, analysts using the option approach try to directly value the put through the Black-Scholes framework.(10) Under a Black-Scholes approach the value of the put option to the GSE depends on the value of the firm’s assets, the value of the firm’s insured liabilities, the maturity of the put, the volatility of the GSE’s assets, and the level of interest rates. Increases in volatility of a firm’s assets or a decrease in the value of assets, for example, would increase the value of the put option. Schwartz and Van Order (1988) used a variant of the option approach to explore the value of the implied subsidy. However, because they believed the conditions under which the GSE would be closed and the option exercised were not clear, they solved the option equation for the maturity of the put and the riskiness of the firm’s assets where the value of the put was given by Kane and Foster (1986). By examining the riskiness of the GSE’s assets and the audit period, they were able to explore the degree to which Fannie fully exploited its subsidy. The more volatile the firm’s assets and the longer the audit period the more Fannie exploits its guarantee. A longer audit period suggests that Fannie can maintain a risky portfolio for an extended period without adjustments. Using this test, Schwartz and Van Order (1988) found that the subsidy was being exploited only partially during the period 1978 to 94 FELDMAN 1985.(11) The audit period was longest and the volatility of assets greatest during the periods when Fannie’s financial strength was weakest. Martin and Pozdena (1991) extended the same analysis for the period 1986 to 1990 and found that Fannie exploited the subsidy partially even during an economic climate conducive to very high profits. Both Cook and Spellman (1992) and Gatti and Spahr (1997) used a variant of the option pricing model to value the implicit guarantee. Cook and Spellman (1992) noted that GSEs pay a premium over the Treasury to borrow because investors have doubts about whether the government would bail them out. Cook and Spellman (1992) wanted to determine how this bailout premium affects taxpayer exposure to GSE losses. To do that, Cook and Spellman used the option pricing framework to determine how much the government should charge to provide the option to the GSE. This charge reflects the expected losses the government would suffer on the option and equals the GSE subsidy, and taxpayer exposure, as the option is provided to GSEs at no charge. This calculation allowed Cook and Spellman (1992) to determine how changes in the bailout premium affect taxpayer exposure. Cook (1996) and Spellman (1992) made a number of simplifying assumptions in order to provide values necessary to calculate the option value in the Black-Scholes framework. For example, as benchmarks for GSE asset variance they used the volatility of short-term Treasury securities and the variance of bank assets. Other parameters were also obtained via previous bank and thrift research. They found that the value of the option, and hence the value of the subsidy, depends a great deal on the capitalization of the GSE and the bailout premium charged by the market. If the bailout premium was 100 basis points and the GSE’s capital to asset ratio was 3 percent, the option would be worth 33 basis points. A bailout premium of 50 basis points and 2 percent capitalization would yield a 47 basis point subsidy. Although the authors did not make a point estimate of the implied guarantee, Cook and others suggested that their lower estimates (e.g., below 20 basis points) were most relevant (Cook, 1996; Shilling, 1996). In general, they found that higher bailout premiums increased the subsidy by making it more likely that the GSE would falter due to its higher borrowing costs. Gatti and Spahr (1997) used the same general technique to value the implicit guarantee on Freddie Mac MBS. (12) Since the Schwartz and Van Order (1988) analysis, the Congress mandated an annual safety and soundness inspection. This allowed Gatti and Spahr to set the maturity of the GSE put at one year. Gatti and Spahr also faced the difficulty of trying to ESTIMATING AND MANAGING THE FEDERAL SUBSIDY OF FANNIE MAE AND FREDDIE MAC 95 determine the volatility of the underlying assets of the put, in this case the mortgages supporting Freddie’s MBS. They addressed this concern by developing an actuarial model to estimate the expected losses that the government would face by implicitly insuring Freddie Mac’s MBS. The expected losses were the basis for determining the premium that a firm that cannot absorb losses from its own resources would pay to be insured by a risk neutral insurer that has no default risk. Gatti and Spahr used this premium as a proxy for the value of the put option and backed out an estimate for the variance of the underlying assets of Freddie Mac’s MBS through the Black-Scholes methodology. This figure was then used, in conjunction with the actual financial condition of Freddie Mac, to determine a recent value of the GSE put option for MBS. Gatti and Spahr took into account the capital level, loan loss reserves and cash flows of Freddie Mac to ensure they were only valuing the implicit guarantee of the federal government and not the value of the guarantee provided by Freddie Mac based on its own financial resources and/or the MBS collateral. They found that the most likely value for the implied guarantee in 1993 for Freddie Mac was 8.3 basis points, or about $410 million. Techniques Demonstrate GSE Subsidy Control. Both the option pricing and mark to market methods demonstrate that Fannie and Freddie, and not the providers of the subsidy, control the value of the subsidy they receive. The more risk the GSEs incur, the higher the value of the unbooked asset and the greater the subsidy. Weakness of Option Technique. The fact that a GSE controls the value of the put also suggests that it is not really like other puts and that this valuation method may have conceptual drawbacks. The Black-Scholes framework was designed for options where the holder cannot affect the value of the option. Yet, the holder of the GSE put controls its value. Practically, this means that the volatility of the assets of the GSE can change substantially in a very short period. This is problematic in option calculations because small errors in the estimation of volatility can have major effects on the value of the option (Blair and Fissel, 1991). Another concern with the option pricing approach is uncertainty about if, or when, the government would take over GSEs and make good on their debts. As Cook and Spellman demonstrated, the value of the option is very sensitive to the market’s perception of government closure policy. These types of problems mean that specific dollar estimates of the GSE subsidy estimates obtained via an option pricing model are extremely suspect. (13) 96 FELDMAN Debt and Capital Comparison Technique. A Congressional objective in providing Fannie and Freddie with an implied guarantee was to lower their costs of raising funds. Analysts have tried to directly estimate the value of the guarantee to the enterprises by determining how much of a cost of funds advantage GSE status provides them. Thygerson (1990) estimated the value of the implicit subsidy of Fannie and Freddie through a two-part comparison. First, Thygerson (1990) compared Fannie’s and Freddie’s borrowing costs to insured depositories’ borrowing costs. He stated that Fannie and Freddie borrow at rates about 20 to 35 basis points above comparable U.S. Treasuries. He then found the spread between a variety of one year bank CD rates and comparable Treasury securities and estimated that the agency cost of funds advantage was 30 to 80 basis points over insured depositories. Second, using a very simplified equation for the break-even rate of investing in conforming mortgages, he found that Fannie and Freddie could undercut depositories by 40 to 74 basis points on a given mortgage investment. He attributed the advantage exclusively to the lower capital requirements of Fannie and Freddie. Thygerson (1990) combined these figures to conclude that the implicit guarantee provides at least a value of 70 to 154 basis points in the cost of raising funds. Hemel (1994) compared GSE MBS versus top-rated MBS issued by private conduits, private organizations without implicit government support that assemble mortgages in large pools and issue securities backed by the cash flows of the pooled mortgages. He found that top rated private MBS trade at yields about 30 to 40 basis points above comparable Fannie and Freddie MBS. He argued that the guarantee fee charged by Fannie and Freddie on their MBS (about 20 to 25 basis points) was roughly equal to the credit enhancement and administrative costs that private conduits bear. As such, the 30 to 40 basis point advantage is approximately what Fannie and Freddie gain in the MBS market by being GSEs. Ambrose and Warga (1996) also compared GSE bonds to non-GSE corporate debt by pairing the bonds by factors including liquidity, callability, taxability and maturity. The non-GSE debt was grouped according to bond ratings and the types of firms issuing the debt. GSE debt was compared to finance industry debt, all corporate debt, and the debt of General Electric. Because they hold a variety of important bond structure features constant, Ambrose and Warga (1996) assumed that the spread between similar GSE and non-GSE debt resulted from GSE status. The value of the implicit ESTIMATING AND MANAGING THE FEDERAL SUBSIDY OF FANNIE MAE AND FREDDIE MAC 97 guarantee then depends on Fannie and Freddie’s true credit quality. Ambrose and Warga found that if the GSEs were rated ‘AA’ without GSE status, they would pay 100 basis points more to issue debt. A rating of ‘A’ would lead to a 200 basis point increase. These estimates put the after-tax value of the implicit subsidy for debt at between $1.4 billion and $2.75 billion for Fannie Mae and $330 million and $660 million for Freddie Mac in 1993. They did not provide an estimate of the value of the implied guarantee for the agencies’ MBS. Ambrose and Warga (1996) also tried to determine the value of the subsidy in 1993 by determining how much Fannie and Freddie’s weighted average cost of capital (WACC) would have increased if they lost their GSE status. The WACC measure captures both the cost of borrowing and equity. Ambrose and Warga compared the WACCs of Fannie and Freddie to that of a sample of banking and finance firms. They found that Fannie Mae’s WACC was significantly higher than that of the non-GSE sample even though the riskiness of an investment in Fannie Mae was significantly lower. Ambrose and Warga estimated a new WACC for Fannie by adjusting the riskiness of Fannie to reflect that of the banking and finance firms it would likely resemble if it lost its implied guarantee. That is, how much more of a return will investors demand from Fannie if the firm did not have an implied guarantee. They found that if Fannie received an ‘A’ rating without its government support, its cost of capital would have increased about $3.6 billion per year (this does not capture GSE benefits for MBS issuance). This increase almost entirely (90 percent) reflected increased costs of borrowing. The subsidy estimates generated through the WACC and debt comparison methods were similar. CBO (1996) also relied on a comparative method to generate values for the implicit subsidy. CBO argued that the savings in debt costs that GSEs reap represent the value of the subsidy because the GSE would pay, at a minimum, a sum equal to the cost savings in order to acquire the implicit guarantee. In order to determine the savings on debt, CBO assumed that Fannie and Freddie would have had a credit rating of ‘Aa’ without GSE status and that the amount and type of debt they would have issued would not change with the lower credit rating. Based on Ambrose and Warga’s (1996) methodology, CBO (1996) compared yields on GSE debt with yields on debt issued by ‘Aa’ rated financial firms to determine the savings on debt produced by GSE status. CBO relied on existing estimates of the reduction in MBS yields produced by GSE status when making their own estimate of the 98 FELDMAN MBS subsidy. Previous estimates of the spread between GSE and non-GSE MBS were between 25 to 60 basis points. CBO used 40 basis points to determine the savings that Fannie and Freddie receive on their MBS. Based on this assumption, the savings on debt and MBS for both GSEs in 1995 under the comparative approach was about $6.5 billion. The U.S. Treasury (1996) followed the same logic as CBO arguing that the value of the implicit guarantee for MBS equals the reduction in borrowing costs that the GSE status produces. The U. S. Treasury (1996) took the 25 to 60 basis point advantage developed by CBO and chose a 35 basis point estimate based on information provided by market participants. To estimate the savings in debt issuance, it compared the yield on debt issued by financial firms with large portfolios of residential mortgages and high credit quality (usually rated ‘A’) with the yields on Fannie and Freddie debt. The yield data were provided by Bloomberg Financial Services and were designed to compare bonds with different structures on an equal basis (e.g., embedded options are priced for each bond to facilitate comparisons). The U. S. Treasury (1996) found a spread of about 55 basis points between medium and long-term GSE and non-GSE debt and 18 basis points for short term debt. Finally, the U. S. Treasury added in the GAO estimates of direct cost savings that Fannie and Freddie receive. Based on the GSEs’ 1995 balance sheets, it estimated the Fannie and Freddie subsidy at $5.8 billion with a range of $5 to $6.5 billion. Weaknesses of the Comparative Technique. The comparison method of subsidy valuation also has serious limitations. The primary drawback is that GSE MBS and debt are inherently different than debt and MBS issued by non-GSE firms. For example, private conduits make use of a senior/subordinated structure for their MBS that the GSE can avoid because of the implied guarantee. Likewise, no other firms but GSEs can issue as much callable debt as Fannie and Freddie. These structural differences make it very difficult to compare similar securities. The small number of similar pairs means that the estimates of spreads between GSE and non-GSE securities will have a significant variance. The comparisons, as the U. S. Treasury (1996: 32) noted in terms of its valuation of the spread on long-term debt, “ ‘provide, at best, a rough estimate of the magnitude of the GSEs’ advantage’. Data for more careful comparison are not easily found.” Likewise, Shilling (1996) found the WACC calculations of Ambrose and Warga (1996) to be unreliable arguing that Fannie and Freddie were not really like firms to which they were being compared. Ambrose and Warga (1996) ESTIMATING AND MANAGING THE FEDERAL SUBSIDY OF FANNIE MAE AND FREDDIE MAC 99 were especially concerned about the aggregate comparisons between GSE and non-GSE MBS. Collateral varies from one MBS to another in terms of geographic distribution, use of private mortgage insurance, and seasoning. As such, an analyst could incorrectly attribute the reduction in yield to GSE status when the spread represents collateral differences between MBS. Even if the GSE and non-GSE securities were more similar, the comparative method requires analysts to guess as to the credit rating that Fannie and Freddie would have without agency status. This reduces the comparative method to providing wide ranges of subsidy estimates unless the rating agencies regularly issued ratings for Fannie and Freddie’s debt that did not take GSE status into account. Finally, these estimates provide significantly different values over time. Indeed, in some periods the comparison estimates show no subsidy at all (Shilling, 1996). This concern about consistency across time can be raised with the other subsidy methods as well. CBO notes that its estimates from the comparative method were “roughly consistent” with its estimates from the mark to market method. The two methods produce similar results, however, only when averaged over a three year period (1993-1995). CBO’s estimates using the mark to market and comparative methods for any given year were widely dissimilar. In 1995, the difference in the valuations produced by the two methods was about $14 billion (Congressional Budget Office, 1996: Tables 5 and 6). Finally, concerns about model specification used in the comparative method have been raised (Cook, 1996). Reduction in Mortgage Costs. Hendershott and Shilling (1989), ICF Incorporated (1990), and Cotterman and Pearce (1996) estimated the difference between rates on mortgage loans above the conforming limit and rates on loans below the conforming limit. All three studies used a similar regression approach in which they hold important factors affecting mortgage rates constant so that the effect of conforming status is isolated. All three studies found that, all else equal, a conforming mortgage is about 30 basis points cheaper than a mortgage above the conforming limit. (14) Attributing this difference solely to Fannie’s and Freddie’s GSE status would provide a minimum estimate of the value of the implied guarantee. This figure is a minimum because Fannie and Freddie are very unlikely to pass on the entire subsidy to home buyers. As noted, the two firms are not subject to full competition in their securitization markets. At the same time, the firms have a duty to maximize shareholder wealth. This combination almost surely leads both firms to retain part of their subsidy. 100 FELDMAN The Benefit of Subsidy Estimates The three estimation techniques have serious drawbacks if they are interpreted as point estimates. The estimates provide more benefits when viewed as the potential order of magnitude of the subsidy. The estimates suggest that the combined subsidy could be in the billions of dollars for Fannie and Freddie although in some years the subsidy could be much smaller. Recognizing that the subsidy estimates are not exact does not imply that they are too high. Indeed, none of these estimates tries to measure the benefit of continual market access that GSE status provides Fannie and Freddie. The estimates produce the most benefits when viewed as models of the basic relationship between GSE activity and the use of public resources. What are the most important lessons policy makers can learn from these models? First, the GSEs, not the federal government, control the size of the subsidy. No matter the valuation method, the size of the subsidy increases when the risk of the assets held or securitized by the GSE increases. The GSE determines the risk of these assets. Estimates using the comparative method, for example, demonstrate that the subsidy is greater for GSE portfolio lending than it is for securitization. Thus, the GSE can increase its consumption of public resources by issuing fixed-term debt in place of MBS. Second, in some years it is questionable whether the GSEs are passing the full subsidy on to home buyers given estimates of the subsidy and estimates of the reduction in mortgage costs caused by the GSEs. The gap between mortgage reduction and total subsidy is consistent with the fact that two firms with GSE status dominate the secondary mortgage market and that both firms are private corporations owned by shareholders. A recent model of Fannie and Freddie’s mortgage purchases also suggests that little or no subsidy may be passed on to home borrowers if the firms expend these resources in the process of ensuring that they do not purchase low quality mortgages (Passmore and Sparks, 1995). Finally, and most importantly, the models reveal that the federal government will never have a firm grasp on the amount of public resources consumed by Fannie or Freddie at the time the resources are provided. On the most basic level, policy makers do not have access to any accounting records that document the cash flows of the subsidy. Estimates are required ESTIMATING AND MANAGING THE FEDERAL SUBSIDY OF FANNIE MAE AND FREDDIE MAC 101 in the first place because the subsidies are off-budget, indirect or implicit. Even if these estimation techniques produced accurate results, the findings would still reflect after-the-fact valuations. Of course, the point at which the federal government transfers public resources to Fannie and Freddie is the only time at which the consumption can be controlled. Furthermore, the difficulty with valuing the subsidy arises directly from the circuitous method by which it is conveyed. Yet, indirect, off-budget subsidy transfers define GSEs and are the very purpose for their creation. Thus, analysts have no choice but to rely on uncertain estimating techniques that, in turn, require comparisons or analogies that are inherently difficult to make. It is by human design rather than bad luck or requirement of nature that the GSE put is not really like puts traded on exchanges, GSE debt and GSE MBS are not really like debt and MBS issued by private firms, and the GSE implied asset cannot be isolated from other unbooked assets and liabilities. It is not necessary to rely on third parties to come to the conclusion that the federal government is ignorant of and does not control the resources it provides Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac. Fannie Mae testified to the Congress that the process of trying to estimate their subsidy is a “highly theoretical and subjective” exercise because of the implicit, indirect manner in which the subsidy is provided (Zoellick, 1996). Freddie Mac (1996a) also found that methods of estimating the subsidy were too inaccurate to be relied upon.(16) CAN THE FEDERAL GOVERNMENT EFFECTIVELY MANAGE FANNIE AND FREDDIE’s SUBSIDY? Analysts have offered a variety of plans for the federal government to gain greater control over the amount of the subsidy that Fannie and Freddie receive.(17) These proposals include reporting estimates of the current subsidy in the federal budget and perhaps counting them as federal outlays, levying user fees, requiring Fannie and Freddie to maintain a high credit rating absent their implicit guarantee, further restricting the types of mortgages they can finance or increasing their social investment requirements. The Congress has already mandated risk-based capital requirements in order to better control Fannie and Freddie’s risk taking. All of these proposals face very significant challenges. First, the GSEs are much better informed about their risk-taking than third parties. This information asymmetry reduces the ability of any third party to effectively limit Fannie and Freddie’s risk exposure and subsidy. Second, political incentives favor a maintenance of the current, uncontrolled GSE subsidy. It also appears administratively inefficient for the Congress to 102 FELDMAN simultaneously provide GSEs with benefits only to devise methods to reduce the size of or redirect those benefits. These concerns among others has led some analysts to call for removal of federal support for Fannie and Freddie. Methods of Managing the GSE Subsidy The following methods could limit the ability of the GSEs to control the amount of subsidy they consume: Include Subsidy Estimates in the Federal Budget. This proposal would do nothing to directly control the size of the subsidy. But, the Congress may “feel pressure” to gain control over the subsidy if it is reported in the federal budget. The Congress will have greater incentive to exercise control if subsidy estimates count as outlays that increase the budget deficit. One method of achieving this budget outcome is to extend the Credit Reform Act of 1990 to include Fannie and Freddie’s implied subsidy (Kane, 1996). Levying User Fees. CBO (1997) and Miles (1995) suggest controlling the subsidy of Fannie and Freddie by levying a fee on their use of public credit. (18) The fee could be set equal to the estimated value of the implied guarantee or some portion of this estimate. Fannie and Freddie have a more limited incentive to use public credit without restraint when there is a charge on its use. While some policy makers called user fees a tax increase on home owners, it is actually a tax reduction for federal taxpayers whose credit is currently expropriated.(19) Mandated Credit Rating. The degree to which Fannie and Freddie could exploit the federal implied guarantee would be limited if they were required to maintain a ‘AAA’ rating without the credit rating firm considering their GSE status. The Office of Federal Housing Enterprise Oversight (OFHEO) (1997) is Fannie and Freddie’s safety and soundness regulator and contracted with Standard and Poors to provide such a credit rating in 1997. Some subsidy would still exist after this proposal was implemented as both firms currently borrow at super-AAA’ rates. (20) Furthermore, credit ratings are known to lag behind the financial condition of the rated firm’s and market’s assessment of risk (CBO, 1991). Limiting Financing Opportunities. Another method for limiting the ability of Fannie and Freddie to exploit the subsidy would be to further restrict the mortgages that they can finance. The conforming limit could be lowered, the total amount of MBS outstanding and mortgages in portfolio could be capped and/or the credit quality of mortgages they finance could be increased in order ESTIMATING AND MANAGING THE FEDERAL SUBSIDY OF FANNIE MAE AND FREDDIE MAC 103 to achieve this goal. The fewer mortgages they finance, the lower their subsidy all other things equal. Of course, “other things” are never equal and if Fannie and Freddie are prevented from taking risk in one aspect of their business, they will be able to exploit risk-taking opportunities in other areas. Capital Requirements. Legislation in 1992, the Federal Housing Enterprise Financial Safety and Soundness Act, established two new capital requirements for Fannie and Freddie. First, they must meet a minimum capital standard equal to the sum of 2.5 percent of aggregate on-balance-sheet assets, 0.45 percent of the unpaid principal balance of outstanding MBS and substantially equivalent instruments, and 0.45 percent of other off-balancesheet obligations. Both firms have met this standard each year since its inception. Second, both firms must meet a risk-based capital standard that has not yet been finalized. The standard will require that both firms maintain enough capital to withstand a severe interest rate shock together with adverse credit conditions over a 10-year period plus an additional 30 percent of that amount to cover management and operations risk. Increase Social Investment. Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac must meet three housing goals as promulgated by the Department of Housing and Urban Development. A certain percentage of the mortgages purchased by Fannie and Freddie must finance housing (1) for low- and moderate-income families, (2) located in areas considered to be geographically underserved, and (3) that meets the needs of very-low income families and low-income families living in low-income areas (Retsinas, 1996). Congress could increase the exisiting targets and/or create new, more focused goals to reduce the subsidy that Fannie and Freddie retain and better target the subsidy to specific households or firms. These reforms would not provide policy makers with a better grasp of the size of the subsidy but would offer them a crude to tool to manage it. Systemic Challenges of Managing the Subsidy of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac The options above would provide tools for the federal government to control the size of the subsidy that Fannie and Freddie receive if implemented with perfect information and operational skill. But, there are two hurdles that make anything approaching perfection an unachievable goal. First, the options require that a third party know the true risk profile of both firms on almost a continuous basis. Such a state is impossible to achieve with resource constraints. Second, Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac have extremely strong incentives to use their political clout to prevent the options from being 104 FELDMAN implemented effectively. Policy-makers should be receptive to Fannie and Freddie’s needs as the current subsidy structure increases their own welfare. Finally, these tools often appear administratively inefficient; why choose to provide housing subsidies through indirect, untargeted means only to implement tools to reduce the level of subsidizaton or make the subsidy more direct? Information Asymmetry. Several of the options of managing a subsidy discussed above require a third party to be able to accurately assess the level of the subsidy that Fannie and Freddie enjoy or accurately measure the risks that they bear many times a year. But, as discussed above, it is extremely difficult to assess either of these on an irregular basis. Moreover, whatever tool the federal government uses to manage the GSE subsidy will have to be fairly general to be practical. The federal government would face significant problems, for example, in implementing an extremely detailed system of fees based on a large number of variables. Such a system requires the agency assessing the fee to collect extremely detailed, virtually unverifiable, information on the regulated entity. The calculations would also require assumptions that cannot be made with confidence. The more complicated the fee setting process, the more likely the regulated institution could challenge the rate derived by the regulator. In addition, a fee based on very specific factors would become outdated as new variables take on increased importance in determining GSE risk. This would require the regulator to have the flexibility to change the tool quickly. But, the Congress and courts have developed a regulatory process to ensure public input, due process and deliberation rather than to minimize response time. The difficulties facing a detailed subsidy management program mean that regulators would likely implement a general protocol. But, a broad rule for measuring risk guarantees that risk will not be measured accurately. As such, the GSE should be able to alter its risk position without facing regulatory penalties (a higher fee, for example). The inability to accurately measure risk has traditionally plagued bank regulators and insurers. The regulator is at a profound informational disadvantage relative to the regulated party in recognizing and measuring risk. Moreover, the third party assessing these risks will not posses the incentives that entities assessing risks in private markets have to accurately make and update assessments. One way around this problem is to set fees or capital at a rate that cannot possibly be too low. This strategy, however, encourages the GSE to either drop its federal charter (as was the case with Sallie Mae) or take on ESTIMATING AND MANAGING THE FEDERAL SUBSIDY OF FANNIE MAE AND FREDDIE MAC 105 increased risk so that the overestimated charges eventually reflect or underestimate reality. Political Power. Fannie and Freddie obtained and maintain their subsidy via the political process. They derive substantial benefits from it. Thus, they have significant incentive to protect the subsidy from any governmental action that could reduce it. In other words, the enterprises obtain extremely high payoffs from being well organized politically, well informed and able to respond to critiques of their activities with credible responses. And their political instincts are highly regarded. The chairman of the House Banking Committee, Rep. James Leach, noted that the enterprises have Washington connections that “are much stronger than all 13,000 financial institutions in the 50 states” (Calmes, 1996). In contrast, the costs of the enterprises’ subsidy are small on a pertaxpayer basis. Individual taxpayers, who would have to expend resources to become informed about the enterprises, have little incentive to engage in political action to oppose the enterprises’ subsidies. Analysts have long considered subsidies, such as those accruing to Fannie and Freddie, with concentrated benefits and dispersed costs characteristic of our democracy and very difficult to eliminate.(21) The political power of the two agencies has been exercised on many occasions against plans that would reduce their subsidy. With regards to their new risk-based capital standards for example, “ the stress test was not performed before the bill was passed. Instead, it was negotiated between the Bush Administration and the GSEs and written into law by Congress without analysis of how much capital will be required to meet it” (Weicher, 1994: 58). Likewise, plans to levy a user fee were dismissed by market observers as having little chance of passage because of the political power of Fannie and Freddie (Kleinbard, 1996). Furthermore, Fannie and Freddie’s regulator is currently dependent on the two firms for its funding. This arrangement provides Fannie and Freddie with considerable political and financial leverage over the regulator and increases the potential that Fannie and Freddie could “capture” it. Policy makers also have several reasons for maintaining the current structure of indirect subsidies to Fannie and Freddie. First, the subsidies are not recorded in the federal budget. Policy-makers can get credit with constituents for Fannie and Freddie housing initiatives without having to give up financial support for other federal programs. Second, the indirect and 106 FELDMAN convoluted nature of the link between the GSEs and the federal government gives policy-makers plausible deniability if either of them suffers financial difficulties. (22) Third, Congresspersons can use the threat of subsidy reduction to increase contributions and other benefits that the agencies can directly bestow upon them. (23) Congress would not receive such pecuniary benefits from a federal agency that received an equal subsidy. Finally, Fannie and Freddie can brand those policy makers who try to eliminate their subsidy as supporters of a tax increase. Administrative Inefficiency. Some of the subsidy control tools described above appear inefficient, from an administrative perspective, even if the government could apply them perfectly. For example, “requiring the [GSE] to compensate the government for [its] privileges simply undoes the benefit” (Woodward, 1997: 4). Likewise setting housing targets such that the GSE transfers all of its subsidy begs the question why the government does not simplify its process and provide the subsidy directly to targeted beneficiaries. More generally, the findings of this review indicate that weak control and poor informational oversight are inherent in transmitting subsidies through Fannie and Freddie. Thus, the point at which policy makers must devote considerable resources to controlling GSEs’ use of their subsidy or making their subsidy more explicit is the time when the rationale for using a GSE as a conduit for subsidy transmission may have run its course. Indeed, the inability to obtain precise information on the subsidy, control its use, and ensure that its benefits flow to home buyers explains why some analysts favor its elimination (issues surrounding the mechanics of “privatization” have also been reviewed elsewhere (Stanton, 1996). CONCLUSION Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac receive direct and indirect benefits from the federal government. A recent estimate of the direct benefits placed their value at about $400 million. There are three primary methods for assessing the amount of the indirect subsidies. None of these will yield accurate point estimates for any given year. But, these estimates provide rough order of magnitude estimates that suggest Fannie and Freddie could receive billions of dollars in subsidies in some years and much smaller amounts in other years. Assessing the size of the implied subsidies is most valuable in demonstrating that Fannie and Freddie, not the federal government, control the size of the subsidy and proving that the federal government does not know the level of ESTIMATING AND MANAGING THE FEDERAL SUBSIDY OF FANNIE MAE AND FREDDIE MAC 107 resources it provides Fannie and Freddie at the time they consume the resources. There are several methods by which the federal government could try to gain better control over the size of the subsidy that Fannie and Freddie receive. However, the managers of these tools would have to overcome both the massive information disadvantage that a third party faces in assessing Fannie and Freddie’s risks and the political incentives that lead Fannie, Freddie and the Congress to maintain the status quo. The effect of these tools may also run counter to the rationale for creating Fannie and Freddie. These drawbacks provide a strong rationale for examining the elimination of the indirect subsidy. NOTES * The views expressed in this article are the author’s and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis or of the Federal Reserve System. 1. Section 1404 of the Financial Institutions Reform, Recovery and Enforcement Act of 1989 required the General Accounting Office and the U.S. Treasury to issue two studies on the risks posed by government sponsored enterprises and the potential methods for managing these risks. Section 135018 of the Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act of 1990 required the Congressional Budget Office to analyze the financial risks posed by the government sponsored enterprises and review risk management strategies. See, for example, Congressional Budget Office (1996), U.S. General Accounting Office (1996b), and U.S. Department of Treasury (1996). 2. Section 1355 of the Federal Housing Enterprise Safety and Soundness Act of 1992 directed the Secretary of the Treasury, the Secretary of Housing and Urban Development, the Comptroller General and the Director of the Congressional Budget Office to study the desirability and feasibility of repealing the charters of Fannie and Freddie, eliminating federal sponsorship of the enterprises, and permitting them to operate as fully private entities. 3. More detailed discussions of Fannie Mae’s and Freddie Mac’s operations are found in Congressional Budget Office (1991) and U.S. Department of Treasury (1990). 108 FELDMAN 4. Section 1381 of the Federal Housing Enterprise Safety and Soundness Act of 1992 amended Section 301 of the Federal National Mortgage Association Charter Act in order to update the firms’ charters. Kaufman (1988) found that Fannie Mae did not provide countercyclical housing credit. 5. Mortgages in portfolio include mortgage backed securities held in portfolio. 6. On two occasions the Federal government has effectively bailed out a government sponsored enterprise. In the late 1980s, the Congress bailed out holders of Farm Credit debt and in 1996 the Congress ensured that holders of FICO debt would receive full payment when such payment was in doubt. 7. These concerns were also raised by Schwartz and Van Order (1988), Congressional Budget Office (1996), and General Accounting Office (1985). 8. Marcus and Shaked (1984), Merton (1977) and Ronn and Verma (1986) are the seminal works of this literature. 9. An American option allows the holder to exercise their rights on or before the expiration date while a European option allows exercise only on the expiration date. 10. See Fortune (1996) for a discussion of this methodology. 11. Schwartz and Van Order (1988) offer three reasons why Fannie might not exploit the subsidy fully by engaging in risky behavior. First, in some models, excess risk-taking reduces the charter value of a monopolist. Second, the employees of Fannie Mae may face costs from excess risktaking. Third, excess risk-taking may encourage regulatory sanction. In addition, the Congress may seek to reduce the subsidy of Fannie Mae if it appears that the firm is exploiting the federal subsidy too aggressively. 12. Gatti and Spahr (1997) note that almost 90 percent of all mortgages financed by Freddie Mac in 1993 were securitized. Thus, their estimate of the value of the guarantee for the mortgage backed securities is a rough approximation of the value of the entire implied guarantee. 13. The literature review in Flood (1990) makes clear that option pricing models do not generate accurate point estimates for the value of the deposit insurance put. But, Flood finds that these models are useful for ESTIMATING AND MANAGING THE FEDERAL SUBSIDY OF FANNIE MAE AND FREDDIE MAC 109 determining the relative riskiness of banks or for investigating how changes in the structure of the government guarantee affects the value of the federal subsidy conveyed through deposit insurance. 14. More precisely, Cotterman and Pearce (1996) found a spread of 15 and 60 basis points between mortgages below the conforming limit and mortgages above the conforming limit. The lower estimates occurred in more recent years. Cotterman and Pearce (1996) found that 25 to 40 basis points was the core range of the differential. ICF’s point estimate was 23 basis points while Hendershott and Shilling’s (1989) was 30 basis points. 15. See Fannie Mae (1996b) for more detailed comments on Ambrose and Warga (1996). 16. Freddie Mac (1996b) argued that the subsidies it receive have “no cost to taxpayers”. This statement can be true only if the benefits provided by government sponsored enterprise status have no value. Yet, Freddie goes on to argue that its government sponsored enterprise status allows it to borrow at lower rates. Clearly, other firms would pay to receive this benefit. 17. See Congressional Budget Office (1991; 1996), U. S. Treasury (1990; 1991), U. S. General Accounting Office (1985; 1990; 1991) for in-depth reviews of many of these proposals. 18. Congressional Budget Office (1997) asserted that government sponsored enterprise status reduces the enterprises’ long-term debt costs by about 70 basis points and their mortgage backed securities costs by about 35 basis points and determined that a user fee set at an arbitrary level of 20 basis points and charged against average debt outstanding would generate $900 million a year in federal collections. Miles (1995) also discusses user fees for Fannie and Freddie. 19. Speaker of the House Gingrich, for example, argued that user fees on Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac were taxes (Kleinbard, 1996). 20. While it is standard to note that Fannie and Freddie have lower borrowing rates than AAA rated firms, one reflection of the difficulty in making subsidy estimates is found in Ambrose and Warga (1996) who found that government sponsored enterprise borrowing rates would not change if they obtained a AAA rating after losing the implied guarantee. 110 FELDMAN 21. Downs (1957) was one of the first analysts to identify this trend. 22. Fear that this veil might be pierced during a bailout would provide a countervailing force. 23. The Chairman of the Senate Banking Committee raised his request for political contributions from the two agencies at the same time the Congress was going to hold hearings on reports that were critical of their subsidy, see Prakash (1996). REFERENCES Ambrose, B. W. and Warga, A. D. (1996), “Implications of Privatization: The Costs to Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac,” in U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development (Ed.), Studies on Privatizing Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development, Washington D.C.: U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development, pp. 169-204. Blair, C. E. and Fissel, G. S. (1991, Fall), “A Framework for Analyzing Deposit Insurance Pricing,” FDIC Banking Review, 4(2): 25-37. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (1996a, November) Federal Reserve Bulletin, 82(11): 82. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (1996b, June 13), Z.1 Flow of Fun ds: 115-116. Calmes, J. (1996, May 14), “Loan Ranger: Federal Mortgage Firm Is Facing New Assault to Privileged Status,” Wall Street Journal: A1, A6. Congressional Budget Office (1991), Controlling the Risks of Government Sponsored Enterprises, Washington, DC: U. S. Government Printing Office Congressional Budget Office (1996), Assessing the Public Costs and Benefits of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, Washington, DC: U. S. Government Printing Office. Congressional Budget Office (1997), Reducing the Deficit: Spending and Revenue Options, Washington, DC: U. S. Government Printing Office. Cook, D. O. (1996), “Review of the Ambrose-Warga and Cotterman-Pearce Papers,” in U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development (Ed.), ESTIMATING AND MANAGING THE FEDERAL SUBSIDY OF FANNIE MAE AND FREDDIE MAC 111 Studies on Privatizing Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development, Washington, DC: U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development, pp. 205-210. Cook, D. O. and Spellman, L. J. (1992), “Taxpayer Resistance, Guarantee Uncertainty and Housing Finance Subsidies,” Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 5(2): 181-195. Cotterman, R. F. and Pearce, James E. (1996), “The Effects of the Federal National Mortgage Association and the Federal Home Loan Mortgage Corporation on Conventional Fixed-Rate Mortgage Yields” in U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development (Ed.), Studies on Privatizing Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development, Washington D.C.: U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development, pp. 97-168. Downs, A. (1957), An Economic Theory of Democracy, New York: Harper. Fannie Mae (1996a), 1996 Annual Report, Washington, DC: Author. Fannie Mae (1996b) “Comments on Ambrose and Warga,” in U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development (Ed.), Studies on Privatizing Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development, Washington, DC: U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development, pp. 219-221. Flood, M. D. (1990), “On the Use of Option Pricing Models to Analyze Deposit Insurance,” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, 72(1): 19-35. Fortune, P. (1996, March/April), “Anomalies in Option Pricing: The BlackScholes Model Revisited,” New England Economic Review, 17-40. Freddie Mac (1996a), 1996 Annual Report, McLean, VA: Author. Freddie Mac (1996b), Financing America’s Housing, McLean, VA: Author. Gatti, J. F. and Spahr, R. W. (1997), “The Value of Federal Sponsorship: The Case of Freddie Mac,” Real Estate Economics, 25(3). 453-485. 112 FELDMAN Goodman, J. L., Jr. and Passmore, S. W. (1992, March), “Market Power and the Pricing of Mortgage Securitization,” Federal Reserve Board Finance and Economics Discussion Series, 187: 1-31. Hemel, E. I. (1994, November), “GSEs and Mortgage Finance,” Morgan Stanley U.S. Investment Research: 1-5. Hendershott, P. H. and Shilling, J. D. (1989, June), “The Impact of Agencies on Conventional Fixed-Rate Mortgage Yields,” The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 2(2): 101-115. Hendershott, P. H. and Van Order, R. (1989, May), “Integration of Mortgage and Capital Markets and the Accumulation of Residential Capital,” Regional Science and Urban Economics, 19(2): 188-210. Hermalin, B. E. and Jaffee, D. M. (1996), “The Privatization of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac: Implications for Mortgage Industry Structure,” in U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development (Ed.), Studies on Privatizing Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development, Washington, DC: Author, pp. 225302. ICF Inc. (1990), Effects of the Conforming Loan Limit on Mortgage Markets, Final Report Prepared for the U.S. Department and Urban Development, Office of Policy Development and Research, Fairfax, VA: Author. Kane, E. J. (1996, February 12), “Statement of Shadow Financial Regulatory Committee on Extending the Credit Reform Act to GSEs,” Statement No. 131, Chicago, IL: Shadow Financial Regulatory Committee. Kane, E. J. and Foster, C. (1986), “Valuing the Conjectural Government Guarantees of FNMA Liabilities” in Proceedings of Conference on Bank Structure and Competition, Chicago: Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, pp. 347-368. Kaufman, H. M. (1988, November), “FNMA’s Role in Deregulated Markets: Implications from Past Behavior,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 20(4): 673-683. Kleinbard, D. (1996, October 23), “Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac Rise as Analysts Dismiss Fees (Update 1),” Bloomberg Business News: 1-3. ESTIMATING AND MANAGING THE FEDERAL SUBSIDY OF FANNIE MAE AND FREDDIE MAC 113 Marcus, A. J. and Shaked, I. (1984, November), “The Valuation of FDIC Insurance Using Option-Pricing Estimates,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 16(4), 446-460. Martin, D. L. and Pozdena, R. J. (1991, December 20), “Taxpayer Risk in Mortgage Policy,” Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Weekly Letter: 91-44. Merton, R. C. (1977, June), “An Analytic Derivation of the Cost of Deposit Insurance and Loan Guarantee: An Application of Modern Option Pricing Theory,” Journal of Banking and Finance, 1(1): 3-11. Miles, B. L. (1995, November 1), “Proposed Offset Fees for Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac,” Memorandum to House Banking and Financial Services Committee, Washington, DC: Congressional Research Service. Nyhan, P. (1996, November 27), “Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac Raise Loan Limit to $214,600 (Update 1),” Bloomberg Business News: 1-2. Office of Federal Housing Enterprise Oversight (1997), 1997 Report to Congress, Washington, DC: Author. Passmore, S. W. and Sparks, R. (1995, March), “Putting the Squeeze on a Market for Lemons: Government-Sponsored Mortgage Securitization,” Federal Reserve Board Finance and Economics Discussion Series, 9513: 1-31. Pozdena, R. and Martin, D. (1991, December 20), “Taxpayer Risk in Mortgage Policy,” FRBSF Weekly Letter, 91-44. Prakash, S. (1996, June 5), AWith Heat on, Fannie and Freddie Press for Relief,” American Banker, 1: 8. Retsinas, N. (1996, April 17), ATestimony before the Subcommittee on Capital Markets, Securities and Government Sponsored Enterprises of the Committee on Banking and Financial Services,”in U. S. House Committee on Banking and Financial Services, Oversight of the Federal National Mortgage Association [Fannie Mae] and the Federal Home Loan Mortgage Corporation [Freddie Mac], Washington, DC: U. S. of Representatives, pp. 5-7. Ronn, E. and Verma, A. K. (1986, September), APricing of Risk-Adjusted Deposit Insurance: An Option-Based Model, The Journal of Finance, 41(4): 871-95. 114 FELDMAN Shilling, J. D. (1996), “Comments on the Ambrose-Wagra and CottermanPearce Papers,” in U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development (Ed.), Studies on Privatizing Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development, Washington, DC: Author, pp. 211-217. Schwartz, E. and Van Order, R. (1988), AValuing the Implicit Guarantee of the Federal National Mortgage Association, Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 1: 23-34. Stanton, T. H. (1996), “Restructuring Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac: Framework and Policy Options,” in U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development (Ed.), Studies on Privatizing Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development, Washington, DC: Author, pp. 1-47. Thygerson, K. J. (1990, December), “Federal Mortgage Credit Agencies and the Decline in Thrift Charter Value,” paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Real Estate and Urban Economics Association, Washington, DC. U.S. General Accounting Office (1985), The Federal National Mortgage Association in a Changing Economic Environment, Washington D.C.: Government Printing Office. U.S. General Accounting Office (1990), Government Sponsored Enterprises: The Government’s Exposure to Risk, Washington D.C.: Government Printing Office. U.S. General Accounting Office (1991), Government Sponsored Enterprises: A Framework for Limiting the Government’s Exposure to Risk, Washington D.C.: Government Printing Office. U.S. General Accounting Office (1996a), FNMA and FHLMC: Benefits Derived From Federal Ties, Washington D.C.: Government Printing Office. U.S. General Accounting Office (1996b), Housing Enterprises: Potential Impacts of Severing Government Sponsorship, Washington D.C.: Government Printing Office. ESTIMATING AND MANAGING THE FEDERAL SUBSIDY OF FANNIE MAE AND FREDDIE MAC 115 U.S. Department of Treasury (1990), Report of the Treasury on Government Sponsored Enterprises, Washington D.C.: Government Printing Office. U.S. Department of Treasury (1991), Report of the Treasury on Government Sponsored Enterprises, Washington D.C.: Government Printing Office. U. S. Department of Treasury (1996), Government Sponsorship of the Federal National Mortgage Association and the Federal Home Loan Mortgage Corporation, Washington D.C.: Government Printing Office. Weicher, J. C. (1994, July/August), “The New Structure of the Housing Finance System,” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, 76(4): 47-65. Woodward, T. (1997, July 16), “Testimony before the Subcommittee on Capital Markets, Securities and Government Sponsored Enterprises of the Committee on Banking and Financial Services,” in U. S. House Committee on Banking and Financial Services, Government Sponsored Enterprises, (Washington, DC: U.S. House of Representatives. Zimmerman, D. (1995, September), Unfunded Mandates and State Taxation of the Income of Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac and Sallie Mae: Implications for D.C. Finances (Report for Congress, 95-952), Washington, DC: Congressional Research Services.. Zoellick, R. (1996, July 31), “Testimony before the Subcommittee on Capital Markets, Securities and Government Sponsored Enterprises of the Committee on Banking and Financial Services,” U. S. House Committee on Banking and Financial Services, Oversight of the Federal National Mortgage Association [Fannie Mae] and the Federal Home Loan Mortgage Corporation [Freddie Mac], Washington, DC: U. S. House of Representatives, pp. 5-6.
© Copyright 2024