Author: Ke Liu Advisor: Erik Strøjer Madsen How to Manage China’s Foreign Exchange Reserves? Aarhus School of Business MSc in Finance and International Business November 2007 Abstract Financial crisis is not a new term to the world and has been through the financial globalization in the past decades. Many developing countries choose to stockpile a large amount of foreign exchange reserves to protect their economy from external shocks. However, given the declining value of the US dollar, the rapid built-up of reserves also creates a new debate on what amount and which form to hold for emerging economies. This paper attempts to address the two questions for China, the largest reserve holder since 2006. By performing an empirical analysis of 42 developing countries, a series of conclusions are drawn, including a major confirmation that China’s holding of reserves exceeds the estimated adequate level. With a combination of telling evidence and theoretical interpretation, this paper provides a package of solutions to the issue of how to manage China’s foreign exchange reserves in the long-term and short-term scenarios. To fundamentally slowdown the growth rate of reserves and reduce the aggregate amount, a shift in economic policies is desired. Meanwhile, taking into account the opportunity cost of holding, a course of proactive reserve management would be advisable. JEL codes: E58, F31, F33 Keywords: foreign exchange, reserves, China, reserve management Scholium “It is one thing to save for a rainy day, but one trillion dollars in reserve accumulation is more like building Noah’s Ark.” By Ken Rogoff, former chief economist at IMF Contents Part I Introduction ............................................................................................................. 1 Part II Literature Review .................................................................................................. 5 2.1 Ratio Analysis ................................................................................................................ 5 2.2 Regression Analysis ...................................................................................................... 8 Part III Quantitative Analysis ......................................................................................... 11 3.1 Formulation of Model ................................................................................................. 11 Scatter Plots ................................................................................................................... 12 Cross-Section Analysis .................................................................................................. 15 Pooled Analysis for Each Variable .............................................................................. 16 Curvilinear Trend Test ................................................................................................. 17 Structural Change Test ................................................................................................. 19 3.2 Model Correction ........................................................................................................ 24 3.3 Final Conclusion From the Quantitative Analysis ...................................................... 25 Part IV Analysis of Economic and Policy Dynamics ..................................................... 27 4.1 Balance of Payments Analysis .................................................................................... 27 4.2 Foreign Exchange Policy Analysis ............................................................................... 33 4.3 Capital Control ............................................................................................................ 36 4.4 Shift in policy............................................................................................................... 40 Negative Influence of Foreign Reserve Surplus .......................................................... 42 Influence of Reserve Growth on Money Supply ......................................................... 43 Influence of Reserve Growth on National Economy .................................................. 45 Solutions ......................................................................................................................... 45 Management of Reserves ..................................................................................... 49 Part V 5.1 Diversification: From a Dollar Dominated Reserve to a Diversified One.................. 49 5.2 Trend in Composition of Instruments ........................................................................ 52 5.3 Different Foreign Reserve Management Frameworks .............................................. 56 5.4 Which way should China follow? ............................................................................... 58 Part VI Concluding Comments ....................................................................................... 60 Reference ................................................................................................................................ 63 Appendix A: Stylized Facts about China ............................................................................ 67 Appendix B: Selected Data ................................................................................................... 70 Appendix C: Curvilinear trend test ..................................................................................... 71 Appendix D: Structure Test with Quadratic Variables ..................................................... 72 Appendix E: Regression Output .......................................................................................... 73 Part I F Introduction oreign exchange reserves, also refer to international reserves, are indispensable financial resources of an economic entity. To every open economic region, the amount of reserves held by monetary authority varies dramatically based on an array of vested policies and objectives. The International Monetary Fund (IMF) identified an economy’s international reserves as “those external assets that are readily available to and controlled by monetary authorities for direct financing of payments imbalances through intervention in exchange markets to affect the currency exchange, and/or for other purposes.1” The commonly used form consists of convertible foreign exchange held by monetary authorities in the form of currency, deposits, securities or financial derivatives, monetary gold, special drawing rights (SDRs), and unconditional drawing rights with the IMF. Individual countries, especially those who have a large volume of international trade, experience a high risk of random shocks to their external balances, resulting from temporary or continuous sudden drops of their foreign exchange earnings. Therefore, international reserves serve to absorb such undesired crises through financing the payment deficits, which in turn avoid the costs of macroeconomic adjustment2. In addition, foreign exchange reserves can be used to serve external debt or act as the collateral for international borrowing. For those economic entities who undertake a fixed exchange rate policy, international reserves also play an important role in backing up their currencies and enhancing the countries’ credibility. As the international trade flow increases and global financial integration evolves, the demand for international reserves has grown as well. In 1990, the world aggregate holding of reserves amounts to $919 billion and China’s share merely equals 3.3 percent at that time. Sixteen years later, however, the world’s total holding grows up to $5,038 billion, more than one fifth of which is contributed by China. 1 2 See the latest Balance of Payments Manual (1993) published by IMF. See Clark 1970. 1 1200 Billion $ 1000 25 Percent 20 800 15 600 10 400 5 0 0 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 200 Total foreign exchange reserves of China (left axis) China's holding as of world aggregate (right axis) Figure 1: China’s recent built-up of reserves During the past decade, China has accumulated a huge lump sum of foreign exchange reserves due to its prominent economic development. In late February 2006, China surpassed Japan to become the world’s largest holder of foreign exchange reserves, and at the end of March 2007, this number reaches 1.2 trillion U.S. dollars. The reserve to GDP ratio is approximately 40 percent at the end of 2006, while the world average level was around 10 percent. One view is that reserves have been accumulated as insurance against the risk of balance of payments crises, which came to be perceived as higher after the 1997-98 Southeast Asian crisis. Although the strongly export-oriented economic development accounts for part of the upward trend, FDI inflows have been assumed to be responsible for a big portion of the reserves. Despite of capital controls, evidence also indicates that speculative capital flows into this country through various channels, betting on the appreciation of RMB. As a large transitional economy, China is in a stage of rapid economic development and restructuring. Large foreign exchange reserves help to maintain the credibility of both the country and its currency, to expand international trade, to attract overseas investment, to lower the cost of financing its institutions in their efforts to enter the international market, to enhance overseas financing capacity and to uphold steady growth as the country develops. 2 However, some economists argue that the recent heavy foreign exchange accumulation, including rapidly increased speculative capital flows, has augmented risks to the country’s financial system, exacerbated inflationary pressure, created huge opportunity costs that resulted in large wealth losses with the weakening dollar, intensified pressure for the RMB appreciation and finally increased the complexity of macroeconomic adjustment and foreign exchange reserve management. The recent large increase in international reserves has generated a debate on the optimal level of reserves for emerging countries. However, quantitative literature on reserves has lagged somewhat behind the policy questions raised by the international financial crisis of the 1990s. The heyday of the reserve adequacy study dates back to the 1960s and the 1970s with a major pitfall of difficulties in quantifying determinants. Policy makers have often used rules of thumb, such as maintaining reserves equivalent to quarterly imports or the “Greenspan-Guidotti rule” of full coverage of total short-term external debt. But this is not the case for Far East countries with more financial assets and liabilities under financial globalization. Dooley and others (2004) assert that reserves buildup in Asia is the unintended consequence of policies that maintain large current account surpluses. Li (2006) refutes that China’s foreign exchange reserves are not excessive because it needs sufficient reserves to maintain the stability of its currency and to maintain the confidence of international investors. He also argues that China’s foreign exchange reserves have been rewarded by sufficient returns. Frankel (2004) emphasizes the opportunity cost of huge foreign exchange reserves and concludes that China has been presumably paying foreign investors on their inward investment a higher return than the earning made from its foreign exchange reserves. Xia (2006) estimates that $700 billion in foreign exchange reserves should be sufficient. Therefore, the issue about what is the optimal size, or in other term, the adequate level of China’s foreign exchange reserves needs to be addressed. Currently, most relevant research either focuses on general discussions of determinants of the demand for foreign exchange reserves or empirically analyzes countries’ holding compositions. However, little work pays attention to a thorough analysis of foreign exchange reserves management with a Chinese feature. Furthermore, as the US dollar is expected to depreciate in the long-run due to its large current account deficit, both 3 evidence and theories suggest a diversification of foreign exchange reserves away from a single US dollar structure. Hence, how to allocate China’s foreign assets is the second question to be answered. This paper examines the claim that the foreign exchange reserves of China are not only sufficient but also exceed its demand for liquidity and other major economic considerations. With this confirmation, the latter phase centers on how to adjust the current level to the adequate level estimated. The layout of the paper is organized in a logically flashback manner. Section 2 digs into previous relevant research in order to summarize and compare the pros and cons of each measure of the optimality of foreign exchange reserves. Section 3 empirically tests the hypothesis that China is holding an excessive level of reserves. Given the affirmative conclusion drawn afterward, section 4 provides the whole picture of China’s balance of payments structure, economic and political environment, and the funding of its foreign reserves. Based on this analysis, a shift in a series of corresponding policies is suggested with a long-run perspective. Section 5 shows the trend of style changes in foreign reserves management and generates several channels of allocating the excessive amount in the short-run scenario. And also, suggestion for future research on this topic is given at the end of the thesis. 4 Part II Literature Review Most quantitative literature on international reserve holdings is based on theories developed in the 1960s, when the world adhered to the Bretton Woods System and the global capital flows were relatively small. The framework of analysis on reserve adequacy and optimality could be classified by the methodologies used into two categorizes: ratios as tools of analysis and regression analysis. The following gives a chronological retrospect of previous study. 2.1 Ratio Analysis Reserve to import ratio The most widely used ratio method was the ratio of reserve to import first generalized by Triffin (1947, 1960). It is argued that the demand for reserves should move in line with the trend in international trade since receipts and payments were observed to be volatile. He concludes that major countries should maintain a constant reserve to import ratio ranging from 20 percent as a minimum to 40 percent maximally. However, this method was born with almost equal number of critics and advocators. Machlup (1966) discredits the theoretical basis for the assumed rigid reserve-import ratio as it lacks of evidence and theory on why such ratio should remain constant across countries or through time. As his defense, three other ratios, including reserve to largest annual reserve losses, reserve to domestic money and quasi money, reserve to liabilities of central banks, were used to explain the behaviors of 14 industrial countries from 1949 to 1965. He stated that “on purely economic grounds, reserves are held only for the purpose of being eventually used.” However, this ex parte assumption also neglects a precautionary nature of reserves, especially under fixed exchange rate regime. Similarly, Olivera (1969) theoretically argues that precautionary demand for reserves should reflect variance of changes in annual imports, implying that a constant reserve-import ratio leads to a significant overestimation of present and future demands. 5 The IMF started to measure the adequacy of reserves in the 1950s by the ratio of reserve to import. European Central Bank (2006) regards four months’ import coverage as the “rule of thumb”. Since the major function of foreign exchange reserves is protecting a country from the uncertainty of international trade, the ratio of reserve to import has almost been included in all analysis on this subject. Reserve to domestic money supply Because enough stockpiles of international reserves would substantially improve the credibility of a country’s currency, the ratio of reserve to domestic money indicates the potential of capital flight from domestic currency. Machlup (1966) was the first one who managed to use this ratio, although he finally obtained a contradictory conclusion that the demand for reserves is independent of any identifiable variable. The procedure of the functioning of reserve holding is nevertheless sound while ratios act unstable through time. This evidence is proved by Frenkel (1971), who performed a regression equation on 55 countries, and the coefficient of domestic money supply was statistically significant, especially for less developed countries. Furthermore, Frenkel and Johnson (1976) expatiate that international reserves will increase if the demand for money exceed supply and vice versa. In that sense, international reserves are a residual. Based on this view, Frenkel (1978) suggests combine the demand for international reserves theory and the monetary approach to the balance of payments, followed by an attempted analysis by Lau (1980). Interestingly, Edwards (1984) empirically explores the relationship between reserve flows and domestic credit creation by using 23 fixed exchange rate developing countries and concludes that domestic credit cannot be considered completely exogenous but partial evidence. Reserve to short-term debt ratio Brown (1964) gives an analysis of the reserve to net external balance ratio on the ground that reserves function as a cushion against future balance of payments deficits. It is assumed that this ratio reflects an economy’s financial ability to serve its existing 6 short-term external debts3, especially in times of a sudden stop in short-term external debt flows. Greenspan and Guidotti4 (1990) suggest that developing countries, with limited access to international capital market, should at least cover all their short-term debts. Opportunity Cost of Capital The opportunity cost of holding international reserves plays a central role in models of optimal demand for foreign exchange reserves. Heller (1966) first introduces a cost-benefit perspective to solve the issue of adequacy of international reserves by means of econometric analysis. The theoretical definition of cost refers to the opportunity cost of holding reserves and the benefit derives from the avoidance of macro-adjustments for external deficits. The opportunity cost of holdings, practically proxied by government bond yield5, the domestic discount rate6, or the yield on domestic securities7, reduces a country’s national income which can be used for domestic consumption and investment. Therefore, it is expected to be negatively related to reserve demand. However, these farfetched proxies have failed to indicate a significant cost effect since none of them is accurately consistent with the theoretical definition. In addition, because foreign exchange reserves are to be invested abroad, domestic discount rate or yield on domestic securities are unsatisfactory in explaining the cost-benefit criteria. Nominal rate of return does not represent the real return because inflation varies dramatically, especially in developing countries. Macroeconomic adjustments, such as contractionary fiscal/monetary policy and exchange rate depreciation, result in costs in terms of aggregate income and welfare loss. Therefore, reserves serve as an alternative to absorb the balance of payments shocks facing the authorities. The reserve-yielded returns, though comparatively small due to policies and restrictions, are more often than not ignored in empirical studies. Heller’s model can be used to analyze the effects of adjustment to an external 3 4 5 6 7 Referring to foreign debts with a maturity of less than one year The Greenspan-Guidotti rule was justified by Jeane and Ranciere, 2006 Courchene and Youssef, 1967 Iyoha, 1976 Frenkel and Jovanovic, 1981 7 disequilibrium in a precise way. However, the model is far from perfect once it deals with the realistic world. First of all, evidence shows that the difference of demand for reserves between developed countries and developing countries are against the assumption made by Heller (1966) and Hamada and Ueda (1977) that the opportunity cost is constant over time and across countries. In addition, it fails to take into account the return on reserves, even though the amount is normally smaller than the cost. The assumption that the possibility of disequilibrium of international trade was stochastic is apparently no true because there might be a significant bias if applied to a specific country. Agarwal (1970s) modifies Heller’s model on the ground that the opportunity cost of reserve holdings is the value created by the foreign currency held by the monetary authority instead of the imported productive goods. Specifically, central banks are accumulating foreign exchange reserves at the expense of investment and current consumption. However, this model is not without pitfalls, either. It neglected the function of foreign exchange reserves as a source of international trade and foreign debt payments, as well as the options of different economic policies. 2.2 Regression Analysis The use of regressions as a technique to analyze reserve demand function also initiated back from the 1960s. The theoretical assumption of using regression equation to construct the relationship specified follows the empirical study on various individual determinants. The observed levels of reserve holdings reflect the behaviors of different countries as demanders of reserves, although not all countries are expected to fit the “long-term” demand function at each spot of time. Studies on the demand for international reserves under pegged exchange rate suggest that the variability of current account and the relative size of foreign trade are among the main explanatory variables 8 . Serving as a buffer stock accommodating fluctuations in external transactions, the desired amount of reserves is expected to be positively proportional to the variability of external net receipts9. 8 9 See Heller 1966; Kelly 1970; Clark 1970; Flanders 1971. This variable is emphasized by Kenen and Yudin 1965, Archibald and Richmond 1971. 8 Courchene and Youssef (1967) make use of three traditional variables: imports, money supply levels, and long-term interest rates to estimate the reserve holdings of 9 countries. Notably, the variable of money supply was proposed by Johnson (1958), whose major contribution was the theoretical foundation of the relationship between the domestic money supply and foreign payments imbalances. This theory of monetary approach to the balance of payments indicates that, given domestic credit, international reserves increase with an excess demand for money and decrease with an excess supply of money 10 . The long-term interest rate is used as proxy of the opportunity cost of holding. In the 1970s, a distinction had been made between developed and less developed countries and a separate analysis was suggested. Frenkel (1974) estimates separated demand functions for international reserves by developed and less-developed countries, showing that behavioral parameters of the two groups are significantly different. He finally gives an estimate of the function of demand for reserves explained by three related factors, including average propensity to import, the variability measure of the level of imports, and a inversely related input, the opportunity cost of reserves, despite of the overall poor predictive power of this variable due to the measurement problem. Edwards (1983) conducts an empirical research by taking into account the element of exchange rate adjustment. His report indicates that not all less-developed countries behave in the same way with respect to their demand for international reserves. In particular, the demands are higher by countries that have maintained a fixed exchange rate for a long period than those who occasionally devalued their currencies to correct payments imbalances. He suggests that the reserve holding decisions and exchange rate adjustments should be viewed as jointly determined simultaneously. Ford and Huang (1993) investigate the demand for foreign exchange reserves of a typical planned economy, China, using an error correction model. With the series of data from 1956 to 1989, they conclude that China had maintained the amount of reserve on the long-run level due to its prudential foreign reserve policy and monetary disequilibrium had significant short-run influence on reserve holdings, reflecting the 10 Empirically analyzed by Edwards, 1984 9 country’s special economic structure. While Asian central banks after the financial crisis of 1997-98 became more forethoughtful of their reserve holdings, many works found evidence of a change in the behavior of parameters. Gosselin and Parent (2005) claim a positive structural break in the demand for international reserves, indicating that the actual level of reserves accumulated in the post-crisis period was in excess relative to their estimated optimal level. They also predict a slowdown in the rate of accumulation because of the risk of depreciation of the U.S. dollar has put on their holdings. However, Papaioannou, Rortes, and Siourounis (2006) witness that the introduction of the euro in countries’ portfolio of reserve holdings allowed emerging economies to diversify away from the U.S. dollar while keeping their total liquidity unaffected. Following Grubel (1971), taste preferences and large numbers of structural characteristics of economies which determine the demand for reserves of individual countries cannot be measured adequately and incorporated in cross-section studies. In time series analysis involving one country alone, it is reasonable to assume that tastes and structural characteristics change only slow through time so that observed statistical relationships among variables are persistent and reflect rational economic behavior. 10 Part III Quantitative Analysis 3.1 Formulation of Model In this paper, the conventional theory of reserve-holding based on the notion of welfare or opportunity cost is abandoned due to the following two reasons. Firstly, the costs are the consequence of excessive reserves rather than the cause. From the economic perspective, these costs are endogenous. The management of costs matters only when the actual holdings are perceived to be excessive. In other words, the costs incurred should be considered to be reduced only if the liquidity needs and other requirements have been fulfilled. Besides, Proxies for these costs do not have explanatory power unless they possess predictive or forward-looking component. Therefore, it is more reasonable to have the welfare and economic policy issues analyzed within an equilibrium framework. Since some researchers have claimed a structural change in the demand for international reserves after the 1997 Asian financial crisis, it is necessary to examine the existence of this change in case of drawing a biased conclusion. Therefore, following Frenkel’s approach (1974), we formulate a regression model to test the crisis effect on the parameters of the function. If the determinants of the model behave differently before and after the year of 1997, the structural change exists and then we can only incorporate data after 1997 to run the estimation. Otherwise, the boundary fails to have a major effect on the independent variables, leading to employing a longer period, covering years both prior and after 1997, to obtain a better long-run estimate. The objective of this quantitative analysis is to draw a conclusion on whether China’s holding of foreign exchange reserves is larger than the desired amount. It is important to mention that this model explores the adequate level of holding rather than an optimal level. By adequacy, the model strives to define a sufficient level of holding to meet the general liquidity and security needs; optimality, on the contrary, takes into 11 account the risk/reward characteristics, which are not included within this section. The model is initially formulated as follows: ln( R) 1 ln(m) 2 ln( m ) 3 ln(var) 4 ln(d ) GDP where R is international reserves; m denotes annual imports; the ratio of import to GDP stands for the propensity of openness of the sample countries; var is the variance of current account balance; d is total external debt used as a proxy for international debt. All these variables in this equation are in log form. The sample set covers 42 less-developed countries (LDCs) from East Asia and Pacific, Europe and Central Asia, Latin America and Caribbean, and Middle East and North Africa. Some of the African developing economies which have too much risk of political uncertainty are excluded from the pool. In addition, the entire sample period contains 16 years, from 1990 to 2005. To demonstrate the existence of the structural change in the demand function, observations could be segmented into two groups in accordance with the two sub-periods, 1990-1996 and 1998-2005. Scatter Plots Before any test is performed, we use the scatter plot charts to visually explore the relationships between reserve holding and each of the four predictors. 12 Fitted Line Plot ln(R) = - 4.620 + 1.154 ln(m) 28 S R-Sq R-Sq(adj) 0.587668 88.7% 88.6% S R-Sq R-Sq(adj) 0.782258 79.9% 79.8% 26 ln(R) 24 22 20 18 20 21 22 23 24 ln(m) 25 26 27 28 Figure 2 Scatter Plots: ln(R) vs. ln(m) Fitted Line Plot ln(R) = 2.127 + 0.4887 ln(var) 28 26 ln(R) 24 22 20 18 35.0 37.5 40.0 42.5 ln(var) 45.0 47.5 50.0 Figure 3 Scatter Plots: ln(R) vs. ln(var) 13 Fitted Line Plot ln(R) = - 1.624 + 1.016 ln(d) 28 S R-Sq R-Sq(adj) 0.745859 81.7% 81.7% 26 ln(R) 24 22 20 18 19 20 21 22 23 ln(d) 24 25 26 27 Figure 4 Scatter Plots: ln(R) vs. ln(d) Fitted Line Plot ln(R) = 25.67 - 1.105 ln(m/GDP) S R-Sq R-Sq(adj) 27.5 1.74953 10.3% 10.2% 25.0 ln(R) 22.5 20.0 17.5 15.0 1.5 2.0 2.5 3.0 3.5 ln(m/GDP) 4.0 4.5 5.0 Figure 5 Scatter Plots: ln(R) vs. ln(m/GDP) Just as expected, import, the variance of current account, and foreign debt are positively proportional to reserves. However, although the plots of openness with respect to reserves on the last chart are distributed stochastically, it shows a negative effect on reserves. This is contradictory to the theoretical hypothesis that countries 14 that have a higher degree of openness appeal to stock more reserves. Cross-Section Analysis The purpose of performing a cross-section analysis is to detect the changes of parameters over time. With a large sample number of more than 30 countries in each year, the output is supposed to be statistically significant. Table 1: Cross-Section Analysis Constant ln(m) ln(m/GDP) ln(var) ln(d) 1990 -9.0099 0.14734 0.46724 0.50023 0.20107 1991 -5.1221 0.77023 -0.05264 0.24686 -0.0405 1992 -5.594 1.17665 -0.29256 -0.011 0.07004 1993 -4.6022 1.24758 -0.39126 0.05301 -0.1384 1994 -3.2036 0.97223 -0.34007 0.03788 0.09484 1995 -2.9343 1.00109 -0.3822 0.05848 0.02489 1996 -2.0711 0.9313 -0.46135 0.08516 0.02357 1997 -0.5985 0.721453 -0.46552 0.12743 0.09895 1998 -2.5943 0.90821 -0.39056 0.0581 0.10947 1999 -2.3095 0.75612 -0.30189 0.0653 0.22511 2000 -1.861 0.77075 -0.25613 0.05591 0.19972 2001 -1.3622 0.91136 -0.30855 0.05298 0.05652 2002 -3.1817 0.84717 -0.18699 0.13202 0.04108 2003 -1.9999 0.92546 -0.47194 0.1065 0.004 2004 -1.2319 1.03786 -0.41613 0.06626 -0.0777 2005 -1.5222 0.85814 -0.21869 0.1257 -0.0209 Shaded cells: 5% level of significance As shown above, the yearly data is unstable. Import performs relatively smooth, with the lowest point in 1997. And also, only in 1997, most of the tested determinants, including m, m/GDP, and var, are significant at the same time. This means that the Asian financial crisis has a significant influence on the convergence of the countries’ behaviors and their demand for foreign exchange reserves. Despite insignificant, it is roughly observed that constant is getting higher, indicating that the total demand is moving upward, with the peak in 1997. Most noticeably, the openness has a negative effect on the demand of reserves. 15 Pooled Analysis for Each Variable Table 2: Single Variable Analysis constant p-value std ln(m) p-value std ln(m/GDP) p-value std ln(var) p-value std 90-05 -5.773 0 0.41 1.199 0 0.018 90-05 25.672 0 0.453 90-05 0.164 0.732 0.48 90-05 -2.562 0 0.534 -1.105 0 0.127 0.53 0 0.012 1.044 0 p-value 0.023 std 87.40% 10.30% 75.80% 76.20% R-Sq 87.40% 10.20% 75.70% 76.20% R-Sq(adj) 655 655 655 655 No. obs ln(d) The output indicates that all of the four factors are individually significant in the regression with the sample period of 1990 to 2005. But comparing with other variables, m/GDP is relatively of low explanatory power with an adjusted R-square of 10.2 percent. The elasticity of external debt is around one when tested alone, where as the coefficient of variance is only half of import and debt, indicating that central banks weight much more on debt risks but less on the volatility of current account balance. In addition, even though the elasticity of import, 1.199, is greater than one, it does not mean that countries with larger import volumes tend to have more reserves at hand. The high correlation coefficient between import and debt, which is 0.916, shows that the coefficient of import has taken significant debt influence. Hence, we can not conclude that the large importers are expected to hold more reserves with the single variable analysis. Only m/GDP is against our expectation, which is that a country with a higher degree 16 of openness should have more foreign cash readily available in case of global turmoil. Curvilinear Trend Test According to Baumol-Torbin's inventory theory, one would expect a testable decrease in the demand for money relative to the scale variables as wealth increases. Applying to the reserve demand function, the linear relationship between reserves the four determinants is dubious and should be considered to be replaced with a curvilinear one. After testing, however, the curve trend is only significant for the variable of openness and foreign debt, which is not the same as our expectation11. Panel a. Openness- Range of x: (1.53, 4.65) Panel b. External Debt- Range of x: (19.7, 26.4) Figure 6: Curvilinearity Test The left-handed panel shows that the relationship between reserves and openness is not strictly linear, indicating a slight economic scale effect of openness on the level of holding. What’s more, the curve is moving to the left, becoming steeper and less curvilinear after 1997 than before. This means that countries become a bit more closed and accumulate more foreign reserves in the post-crisis period. Panel b also indicates that the debt curve is positively related to demand, but not in perfect linear way. As countries borrow more from overseas, they are willing to have 11 The test output is attached in the Appendix C. 17 more reserves in hand, although the scale effect is tiny. We could again speculate this effect with the high correlation between import and external debt as argued earlier, because countries with much debt usually would have a high import volume and thereby hold more reserves. In addition, the curve of the post-crisis period is more rightward positioned, steeper and less curvilinear comparing to the prior-crisis period. Hence, such change can be explained that countries are getting more conscious about the debt problem due to the scarring financial disaster of 1997. The reason why the curve trend for debt decreases a little can be interpreted from two perspectives. One is that countries after 1997 prefer taking more reference from others when making reserve decisions. In other words, central banks might tend to have synchronized moves. This is somewhat consistent with our previous finding from cross-section analysis that the convergence of countries’ reserve-related behavior exists. Another speculative statement is that, this phenomenon is probably due to chance since the post-crisis sub-period only consists of 8 years for each country. For this reason, to make a convincing conclusion, a longer period is required. However, adding the quadratic variables in the multivariable regression makes m/GDP and/or debt statistically insignificant. Moreover, although the quadratic feature for openness and debt is significant, the adjusted R-square only increases by 1.5 percent (from 10.2 to 11.7 percent) and 0.6 percent (from 76.2 to 76.8 percent) respectively. The benefit of plugging an extra quadric independent variable is limited while making other variables of high explanatory power become insignificant. Therefore, the curve trend could be skipped when performing the regression analysis in order to simplify the process. 18 Structural Change Test Table 3: Test of structural changes in demand for reserves, including openness Structure Test-With Openness 1990-2005 (655 obs) 1990-1996 (287 obs) 1998-2005 (325 obs) Coefficient P-Value Coefficient P-Value Coefficient P-Value Constant ln(m) -5.2474 0.9435 0.000 0.000 -5.0319 1.0104 0.000 0.000 -2.3753 0.8983 0.000 0.000 ln(m/GDP) -0.0668 0.001 -0.2262 0.012 -0.3093 0.000 ln(var) 0.0916 0.000 0.0945 0.004 0.0798 0.001 ln(d) 0.0779 0.058 0.0149 0.830 0.0654 0.290 Table 4: Test of structural changes in demand for reserves, excluding openness Structure Test-Without Openness 1990-2005 (655 obs) 1990-1996 (287 obs) Constant ln(m) ln(m/GDP) ln(var) ln(d) 1998-2005 (325 obs) Coefficient -5.6583 0.9194 P-Value 0.000 0.000 Coefficient -6.5333 0.9291 P-Value 0.000 0.000 Coefficient -4.1002 0.7596 P-Value 0.000 0.000 0.0959 0.1025 0.000 0.000 0.1124 0.0946 0.001 0.130 0.1001 0.1933 0.000 0.000 By comparing table3 and table4, we conclude that it is essential to drop the variable of propensity to openness and preserve the rest factors to perform the regression based on the following reasons: 1. Although the import to GDP ratio was initially used to proxy the degree of openness in the regression, it is also a derivative of import taking into account the economic scale of each country. As expected, picking out the import to GDP ratio, which eliminates the overlapped influence on demand for reserves by import, makes the elasticity of import become smaller (from 0.9435 to 0.9194) and lead to larger contribution from variance and debt. 2. Import was tested to have a positive linear relationship with reserves; therefore, there is no need to consider the non-existed effect of economic size with respect to import on reserves. 3. Either mixing import to GDP ratio or debt with import and variance to formulate the regression equation makes limited difference in the explanatory power (with an adjusted R-square of 88.5% and 88.2% respectively). 19 Another major finding from the above two tables is that there is a structural change in the demand for foreign exchange reserves after the 1997 Asian financial crisis. First of all, the dramatically increased intercept (from -6.5 to -4.1) after 1997 shows that the general demanding for reserves by sample countries is higher than that of the prior-crisis period. The change of average reserve holding is visually shown in below. Average Ratio of Reserves to GDP Percent 60 50 40 30 20 10 Other 33 LDCs 2005 2004 2003 2002 2001 2000 1999 1998 1997 1996 1995 1994 1993 1992 1991 1990 0 All 42 LDCs Figure 7: Increase in average holding of reserves Theoretically, high level of reserves relative to economic scale provides better protection of a country’s financial stability. This impact is particularly true for countries that have experience any financial crisis in history. As shown in the above chart, the average ratio of reserve to GDP is much lower for all 42 sample counties than that of countries which never had any financial crisis recently. To distinguish each of the crisis surviving countries from other 33 non-crisis LDCs, a separated analysis is given in the following. 20 Ratio of Reserve to GDP Percent 60 50 40 India 30 Indonesia Malaysia 20 Philippines 10 Thailand 2005 2004 2003 2002 2001 2000 1999 1998 1997 1996 1995 1994 1993 1992 1991 1990 0 Figure 8: Change in reserve holding (5 Asian countries) Asian victims from 1997 become conscious of the inadequacy of their stock of foreign reserves and begin to increase the level of holding immediately after that time. Interestingly, other suffering samples other than the five Asian countries behave nearly the same way. The only difference between the ratios of the two sub-groups is that the five Asian nations have been keeping a higher level of reserves than the other four countries. Percent 16 Ratio of Reserves to GDP 14 12 10 Mexico 1995 8 Turkey 1994 2001 6 Brazil 1999 4 Argentina 2002 2 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 0 Figure 9: Change in reserve holding (4 crisis sufferers) 21 Secondly, the fitted line for import is flatter after 1997, whereas the curve of m/GDP appears steeper. This demonstrate the fact that the weighted influence of import on reserves has been weakening over time and the function of serving trade payments is impaired regardless of economic size, which alternatively lead to an increased stress on other determinants. Indeed, despite of tiny impact of variance on the structural change, the decreasing influence of import is absorbed by the increasingly strengthened role of external debt in determining the demand for reserves. Even though the elasticity of debt is still much lower than that of import, the trend is significant and gives new clue about how financial globalization affects each member’s behavior. Apparently, countries are becoming more aware of the debt related problems as gaining wilder access to the international capital market. Ratio of External Debt to GDP India Indonesia Malaysia Philippines Thailand 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 Percent 180 160 140 120 100 80 60 40 20 0 Figure 10: Change in debt holding (5 Asian countries) The five crisis-affected Asian countries simultaneously choose to lower their default risks after 1997 by decreasing their borrowings from overseas but at different velocities. 22 Ratio of External Debt to GDP Percent 160 140 120 100 Mexico in 1995 80 Turkey 1994 2001 60 Brazil 1999 40 Argentina 2002 20 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 0 Figure 11: Change in debt holding (4 crisis sufferers) And likewise, the other four suffering countries from the pool have similar behaviors. It should be pointed out, however, that the relatively smaller emphasis on foreign debt is not without reasons. The debt to GDP ratio for most of the surviving countries, excluding Indonesia and Argentina, ranges approximately from 20 to 80 percent, while other 33 LDCs borrowed much more with an average of 200 to 300 percent before 1997. Therefore, we can conclude that even though external debt is part of their consideration, the major concern still remains on trade payment. Average ratio of External Debt to GDP 2005 2004 2003 2002 2001 2000 1999 1998 1997 1996 1995 1994 1993 1992 1991 1990 Percent 350 300 250 200 150 100 50 0 Other 33 LDCs Figure 12: Change in debt holding (non-crisis countries) 23 3.2 Model Correction Thus far, we have found sufficient evidence on the structural change in countries’ demand for foreign exchange reserves and the dynamics of other parameters. From the unusual observations (outliers), we find that there are 9 countries having a high deviation from the estimated line. After adding a dummy variable for each of the abnormal countries, 7 of the coefficients of the dummies are significantly different from zero. Therefore, the updated model becomes: ln( R) 1 ln(m) 2 ln(var) 3 ln(d ) 4 Di where i stands for China, Dominican Republic, Mongolia, Pakistan, Panama, Ecuador, and Haiti. ln( R) 2.11 0.686ln(m) 0.0942ln(var) 0.196ln(d ) 0.761DChina 1.47 DDo min ican 0.511DMongolia 0.625DPakis tan 1.13DPanama 1.12 DEcuador 0.953DHaiti China, among the seven outliers, is the only one above the regression line. To eliminate the effects of on the coefficient of China by other country dummies, all country dummies other than China was dropped and the China effect becomes slightly smaller as the dumped variables have opposite influence on the samples’ average level. ln( R) 3.45 0.696ln(m) 0.0973ln(var) 0.233ln(d ) 0.756DChina When computing the residuals for China with the model estimation given above, we have the following chart: 24 Residuals of China's Reserves billion $ 200 150 100 50 0 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 -50 -100 Figure 13: Excessiveness of China’s reserve holding Thus far, we could conclude that the actual level of international reserves held by China is far more than the adequate level estimated by our regression. It is also noticeable that the deviation of China’s foreign exchange reserves from an international average level began from the year of 2001. Therefore, the dummy variable for China was replaced with another two dummies for the two different sub-periods for the period of 1998 to 2005 to prove the upward trend of the residual growing. ln( R) 3.42 0.692ln(m) 0.0979ln(var) 0.235ln( d ) 0.607 DChina9801 0.916DChina 0205 In line with expectation, the increased dummy coefficient for the second sub-period indicates the acceleration of China’s accumulation of foreign exchange reserves. By the end of 2005, the excessive liquidity under China’s foreign exchange reserve account reaches nearly $200 billions. 3.3 Final Conclusion From the Quantitative Analysis The recent increased accumulation of international reserves has triggered intensive argument on optimality and adequacy of reserve holding. To quantitatively address the question whether China is holding an excessive amount of foreign exchange reserves, we performed the above series of regressions and come out with the answer to it and several by-products. 25 1. The hypothesized structural change in demand for foreign exchange reserves exists. Hence, the demand for reserves should be treated differently before and after 1997, indicating that only the post crisis observations should be considered when quantitatively solving for reserve issues. 2. Trade payment is still the primary concern of developing countries while its influence on demand for reserves is on a decline. Central banks have given more emphasis on the debt problem after the Asian financial crisis. 3. There is a proved convergence on the behavior of monetary authorities when making reserve-related decisions. 4. The relationship between reserves and openness, and that of reserves and debt, are not perfectly linear but quadratic. Yet, such curve feature is only of statistically significant, having little additional implications. 5. Victim countries have been borrowing less from overseas, and thus holding less foreign reserves at hand than other countries that never had the suffering experienced before. 6. Surprisingly, propensity to openness, proxied by the ratio of import to GDP, is negatively related to the demand for foreign cash. According to the Baumol-Tobin inventory theory of the demand for money, one would expect a testable decrease in the demand for money relative to the scale variables as wealth increases, which is totally contrasted with our quantitative finding. 7. The importance of variance of current account balance almost remains unchanged after the Asian financial crisis. 8. China’s holding of foreign exchange reserves has been exceeding the adequate level defined by the world average behavior and the existence of over-liquidity started from the year of 2002. 26 Part IV Analysis of Economic and Policy Dynamics This section provides an all-too-rare analysis of the interactions between the foreign exchange reserves of China and its major macroeconomic variables over time. The effects of reserves on balance of payments are discussed first, followed by a glimpse at the foreign exchange policy of the state. With such findings, we draw a conclusion partly consistent with our regression that China’s reserves are not only fully adequate in the light of precautionary and mercantilist views, but also generate a series of side effects by holding too much. 4.1 Balance of Payments Analysis The boom of China's economy initiated from early 1990s as it furthers economic revolution. The average rate of GDP growth was 10.21 from 1992 to 2005. Both the levels of export and import increase by more than 10 times during the period of 1990 to 2005, whereas the level of total reserves was 19.2 times higher in the same period. China's international reserves consist of four parts, including monetary gold, special drawing rights, reserve position in the fund, and foreign exchange reserves. The values of the first three components are relatively small and constant over time compared to foreign exchange reserves. Therefore, the first three parts are ignored in the following analysis and the focus will be net changes in foreign exchange reserves. 27 150 Percent growth rate of export (%) 900 Billion $ growth rate of import (%) 800 growth rate of reserves (%) 100 Total reserves(in billion $) 700 Exports (in billion $) Imports (in billion $) 600 50 500 400 0 300 200 -50 100 -100 0 Figure 14: Growth of China’s trading activities and reserves The total process of China's accumulation of international reserves could be divided into three phases. The first period was from 1990 to 1993, when the value of holding was quite small relative to its economic scale. The average ratio of reserve to GDP in the first phase was 7.5 percent. Since 1994, China's reserve level started soaring at a moderate speed till the year of 2000. The average growth rate of reserves in the second period is 38.7 percent and the mean of reserve to GDP ratios grew up to 12.9 percent. A steep incline began from 2001 and the level of holding reached 821.5 billion US dollars at the end of 2005. The ever large scale of foreign exchange reserves amounted to more than 40 percent of the country’s national income as of present. Referring to Triffin’s method, the ratio of import to reserve of China appeared a deviation from the rule of thumb, which is 3 to 4 months coverage, from the year of 1994 as well as its reserve to GDP ratio. With few exceptions, the ratio of broad money to total reserves experienced a similar structural change affected by the 28 tremendous increase in reserves. Therefore, it is obvious that the economic effects imposed on major economic variables are straight, direct, and intense. Because of the high volatilities of different ratios, indices and proxies during the period of 1990-2000, and the distinctive trend thereafter till 2005, a better method that calculates the averages among the years through the first period and combines with the data in latter periods is used to obtain a clearer result. Table 5: Major reserve-related economic indicators Order 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Index R/Debt (%) Total reserves in months of imports △Debt/△R (%) △FDI/△R (%) △trade/△R △Current Account/△R (%) △Capital Account/△R Annual Growth rate of reserves (%) Current Account/GDP (%) 91 - 93 42.34 5.68 68.91 327.78 -270.95 -291.93 464.88 1.13 0.81 94 - 00 88.53 8.00 28.70 275.33 225.54 156.50 62.95 38.73 1.85 01 - 05 201.73 10.97 27.73 47.99 44.79 46.80 49.10 37.52 3.45 Data Source: WDI database Since financing the payment imbalances resulted from international trade is the most important function of foreign exchange reserves, it is reasonable to assume that the value of reserves would be higher than before as China furthers its so-called “Reform and Opening Up” with an export-led development strategy. However, the growth rate of reserves compared with the nation’s current account balance should be maintained within a certain range. As recommended by international references, this index should fall between -50 and 0, indicating that countries that following an export-led policy, e.g. most Asian developing economies, should reduce their reserve holdings by purchasing foreign highly productive resources. Indicator 6 illustrates that, in the past two decades, China had been accumulating foreign exchange reserves while exporting economic resources in return for foreign currencies. Concerning on external debt, China’s borrowing booms from $55.3 billion in 1990 up to $281.6 billion at the end of 2005. Yet the 5 times increase of foreign debt is accompanied with a 27.8 times increase of foreign exchange reserves, which exceeded the total external debt for the first time in 1998 and never fall below that level thereafter. Based on Greenspan’s assumption, the value of a country’s 29 international reserves should never be less than its short-term foreign debt, which is normally less than half of a country’s total borrowing. Besides, international benchmark suggests that index 1 ought to sit between 30 percent and 50 percent. From the ratio of annual change in foreign debt to annual change in international reserves, it is shown that reserves had been accumulating at a faster speed than that of debt. This yearly measure is on a clear downtrend and never exceeds 100 percent. The large size of the foreign exchange reserves of China, therefore, is too much than what is needed to prevent from financial crises from a debt repayment perspective. As a main character of the Chinese economic prosperity, foreign direct investment (FDI) had been serving as the underpinning through the entire transition of its economic structure. It is not just that money is what is brought to the land, but also knowledge, such as technology, management skills, corporate culture, etc. With the help of FDI, China realized an average annual growth rate of GDP of more than 10 percent in the past decade, which is viewed as the engine of world economic development. According to a report from National Economic Research Institute (China), ever since 1994, FDI contributes the biggest part of China’s accumulation of reserves, while trade surplus being the second and foreign debt the third. In addition, the FDI effect on the expanded scale of reserves is larger than the sum of the two later factors. However, this fact only stays true before 1997. The value of net FDI inflow has been growing more than 25 times since 1990, when the economic opening-up was just initiated. The increase of FDI also experienced a similar three-phase process with a shape alike. During the first period, the average of net FDI is merely around $11.2 billion, whereas the value goes up to $37.3 billion and $50.5 billion in later time respectively. On the one hand, even though the increase in net FDI inflow is substantial, its influence on the accumulation of foreign exchange reserves is decreasing as other factors are contributing more to China’s holding through time. On the other hand, although the value of indicator 4 is decreasing, FDI would continue to facilitate lift up the level of international reserves as long as the indicator remains positive. 30 Table 6: Major reserve-related economic indicators Order 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 Index R/Debt (%) Reserves in months of imports △Debt/△R (%) △FDI/△R (%) △trade/△R △CA/△R(%) △Capital Account/△R Growth rate of reserves (%) 91-2000 74.7 7.3 40.7 291.1 76.6 22.0 183.5 27.5 2001 116.7 8.8 82.4 78.7 59.2 36.7 73.3 28.1 2002 156.4 10.2 1.7 62.2 49.7 47.1 42.9 35.0 2003 195.8 10.6 19.1 40.5 30.9 39.3 45.2 40.2 2004 248.1 11.9 19.0 25.8 23.9 33.3 53.7 50.6 2005 291.7 13.5 16.4 32.7 60.2 77.6 30.4 33.7 Reference 30~50 2.4~5.0 0~50 ≥0 -100~0 -50~0 ≥0 -20~20 Data Source: WDI database Note: Reference denotes an internationally recognized benchmark. With respect to the astonishing speed of stockpiling of foreign exchange reserves after 2001, what we can learn from the regression result mentioned earlier is how much the average holding of sample countries is affected by China. Table 6 illustrates the entire process of interactions between reserves and each of their sources through the period between 2001 and 2005. It is obvious that almost the magnitude of every single indicator is moving toward an opposite direction of the safe zone. The current account balance started rocketing from the year of 1994, when China initiated an “export-led” policy with continuous export award and import limit. Meanwhile, surplus in the capital account was caused by a dramatic increase in FDI and foreign debt. This “Dual-Surplus” indicates that China did not use the borrowed money from abroad to purchase real resource needed for development. Quite the contrary, it transferred resources, such as labor force and natural resources, in exchange for stockpiling foreign currencies. Traditional development economics suggests that developing economies should bring in foreign capital to buy real productive resources needed for economic development at the initial stage due to the fact that their domestic saving used to be lower than investment. The “Dual-Surplus” has and would continue to overdraft China’s economic potential, although it had been proved that such policy could stimulate a conspicuous economic development at present. From an economic view, the quality of a country’s international reserves has little to do with the proportion of each foreign currency held but most determined by the source of its funding. Based on the analysis of China’s balance of payment, the 31 country would have to spend a large portion of its reserves on interests and return on FDI since the difference between current account balance and capital account balance does not appear significant relative to its economic size during the underlying period. FDI and foreign debt are substitutable from a capital stand of point, but FDI is less risky than debt and helps much more in promoting the receiver’s technological evolution and industrial development. However, it is not a panacea since in the long run FDI could threaten the nationalization of a country’s major industries. Therefore, only a sustainable trade surplus could represent the high competence of a country’s product and economic development, leading to a healthy structure of international reserves. It is controversial what motives are behind China’s economic policy and behaviors to save a high amount of foreign exchange reserves, yet the obvious conclusion is that the country is not as strong as it looks. To some extent, it is hollow. Hence, on the management issue, whether China is running with a long-run interest should be taken with suspicion and a shift of the source of funding of its reserves deserves more attention. Such shift would lower the economy’s financial risk; and hence lower the need for cash, although it might be accompanied with a dramatic decrease in the absolute value of the reserves. 250 billion $ 200 Current Account Capital Account Net change in R 150 100 50 0 -50 Figure 15: Interactions between current account, capital account and the yearly incremental of reserves over time The current and capital account alternatively plays as the largest contributor to the net 32 increase in foreign exchange reserves. The current and capital account surpluses in 2005 reached at $160.8 billion (7.2 percent of GDP) and $63 billion (2.8 percent), respectively. Since the errors and omissions, $16.8 billion in 2005, are relatively small and negligible, we can conclude that current account, 134 percent higher than the level of the previous year, surpasses the capital account, which is 43 percent less than the 2004 level, as the greatest factor behind the increase of reserves. The de facto external imbalance itself refutes the argument given by the Chinese government that the upward pressure on RMB is the result of speculative capital flows rather than actual demand based on current transactions. 4.2 Foreign Exchange Policy Analysis In addition to the precautionary perspective, which is to serve foreign debts and international payment imbalances as the reason to accumulate foreign currencies, China has a second consideration—the mercantilist motive. Under a fixed exchange rate regime, the country needs sufficient money to support its pegging target, which in turn facilitates gain a cost advantage in international trades by keeping the RMB undervalued. To illustrate the motivation of China’s policy, a brief history of the Chinese foreign exchange policy is given below. China's present foreign exchange policy is the consequence of a series of reforms upon its national foreign exchange control system. Before the “Reform and Opening Up”, all foreign incomes and expenditures are settled centrally and distributed according to the plan of its economy. This unenlightened system ended up since 1979, when the settlement of foreign currencies of the nation updates to a “Quota” one, requiring companies that have business with foreign entities to turn in their foreign incomes in exchange for RMB while attaining the right to use part of them under regulations. In 1994, China enacted a new set of foreign exchange administration rules, including establishing a unified nation-wide inter-bank foreign exchange market, employing a market based managed floating exchange rate system, abandoning the examining and approval of foreign exchange spending, and realizing the conditional convertibility of the RMB. Beginning on July 21, 2005, China announced to reform the exchange rate regime again by moving to a managed floating exchange rate regime based on market supply and demand with reference to a basket of currencies. 33 The value of RMB appreciates by 2.1 percent immediately after the announcement. Currently, the framework of foreign exchange control system enables free exchange for transactions under the current account, but the capital account items are still under restrict control. As proclaimed by the Chinese government, the ultimate objective of free convertibility of RMB takes a long time and several prerequisites: (i) improvement of the country’s risk resistance, (ii) stable increase of its economy, (iii) a healthy internal financial system, and (iv) high efficiency of macroeconomic policy. However, the international society, particularly the US, is not satisfied with the slow speed and the degree of the reform on China’s foreign exchange policy. It has been argued that, from 1994 to 2001, the real effective exchange rate of RMB raised by 37.2 percent, whereas its current account surplus improved by 152 percent within the same period. Hence, China should pay a significant down payment12 to ease the trade imbalance between China and the US, and thereby influence on the trading relationship between the US with other Asian developing countries. 120 180 160 140 120 100 80 60 40 20 0 -20 -40 100 80 60 40 20 0 Real Effective Exchange Rate Index (2000 = 100, left axis) Current Account Balance (in billion $, right axis) Figure 16: Interaction between exchange rate and current account balance More often than not, China explains the motives behind its sterilization operation as concerns on its protection from harm to state-owned enterprises, unemployment, and domestic agriculture. Nevertheless, the country’s effort appears to have little effect on the improvement of its macroeconomic stability and the protection of inefficient 12 As of Sep, 2007, the exchange rate of RMB to USD raised by 9.2% since Jul, 2005. Yet Morris Goldstein, suggests an immediate change of at least 15% to 20%. 34 companies and industries. To achieve the two goals, based on Tinbergen and Mundell’s rules13, maintaining the RMB at a comparatively low level alone will not be sufficient. In detail, foreign exchange policy only works on macroeconomic stability, whereas internal institutional reforms are required to resolve structural problems. The “excuses”, such as increased unemployment, agriculture, and state-owned economies, all of them are structural in nature. Besides the redundant labor force in rural areas, the unemployment in the urban area is worsening resulting from the restructuring of state-owned companies. Also, large amount of productive resources taken by agriculture, and state-owned entities, including labor, land, capital, and so forth, are used in an inefficient manner. To improve the overall efficiency of the economy, these resources should be transferred to sectors of high productivity, rather than merely count on keep the RMB cheap. It is the market intervention by the Chinese monetary authorities to suppress its currency from appreciation that fundamentally causes the surge of external surplus. Theoretically, no external account imbalances would exist if a floating exchange regime was adopted. Since US is the largest trading partner of China and because of its large current account deficit, RMB is expected to appreciate against dollar and other major currencies in parallel. Despite rising upward pressure on the RMB, the central bank of China remains prudential about revaluation and continues to intervene in the foreign exchange market in massive amounts with part of its international reserves set aside14. It is also noticeable that, even now the Chinese authorities have been hesitating to revalue its currency; they are not completely ignorant about the negative effects of the economic disequilibrium, including increased trade friction with major trading partners and excess liquidity of reserve holdings. Specifically, on the current transaction side, they imposed export restraints on such goods as steel and wood products that require large amount of inputs and lead to pollutions, and on certain textile products, which is the focus of trade negotiations with the United States and European Union. To release the pressure of the White House from the American corporate society, the Chinese government made a nice gesture by confirming a large 13 Tinbergen’s rule: Achieving a multiple number of independent policy targets requires an equal number of policy instruments. Mundell’s rule: Each policy instrument should be assigned to the policy target on which it has greatest relative effect. 14 According to a report from Peterson Institute for International Economics, the heavy foreign exchange intervention by Chinese authorities was $20 billion a month in 2006, $45 billion a month in the first quarter of 2007 and had amounted to 10 percent of its GDP in each of the years from 2004 to 2007. 35 sum of orders 15 . In addition, the government introduced a “Qualified Domestic Institutional Investor” (QDII) mechanism to channel domestic capital off to overseas markets. These moves, however, have performed limited effects on China’s external imbalance and cannot ultimately solve the problem. 4.3 Capital Control Another medium-term objective announced by the Chinese monetary authorities, besides the exchange rate flexibility, is the capital account convertibility. The present mechanism of China’s capital controls is comprised of three functional components: controls over foreign debts, international portfolio investment and foreign direct investment. International borrowings subject to permission and registration contain foreign loans, project financing, external collateral, and risk control. The control involves government’s liability to such foreign entities as foreign governments, international organizations, international banks and companies. The management of debt operation covers the size, structure, maturity and repayment plan. 2005 2004 2003 0 2002 0.00 2001 10 2000 50.00 1999 20 1998 100.00 1997 30 1996 150.00 1995 40 1994 200.00 1993 50 1992 250.00 1991 60 1990 300.00 External debt, total (current US$, in billion, left axis) Short-term debt (% of total external debt, right axis) Total External Debt to GDP (%, right axis) Figure 17: Change in composition of capital inflow 15 Wu Yi, the Vice Premier of China, led a huge business delegation to the US and signed purchasing contracts worth some $16 billion with US firms, including a deal with major aircraft manufacturer Boeing to buy eighty 737 passenger jets (worth $ 4.6 billion). 36 China has been cautious about taking on foreign debt in the past decade. The total external debt to GDP ratio has remained stable around 15 percent, indicating a relatively effective control on discouraging companies from borrowing from overseas capital market as a consequent of certain policy. Meanwhile, in despite of dramatic increase in the total absolute value of external debt, the proportion of short-term borrowing maintained moderate with an average of 16.4 percent until 2001. In general, countries with a high level of short-term debt tend to be more susceptible to external shocks and crises. In this view, the sharp flying of the ratio of short-term debt as percent of total foreign debt (9 percent in 2000 and 53 percent in 2005) elicits a high risk potential. However, a considerable part of the raising short-term debt is contributed by the surge in trade credits, which accounts for 13 percent of total external debt in 2001 and 19 percent in 2003 16. Notwithstanding short maturity feature, trade credits impose less risk on China’s external balance as they are perceived to be closely linked to subsequent export receipts. Concerning on investment activities, as the country imposes restrictions on the residences’ ability of purchasing foreign securities, the primary guidelines deal with controlling upon international bonds backed by foreign governments, share listing of Chinese companies in overseas stock exchanges (including the Hong Kong Stock Exchange), and the issuance of B-share, which is a special form of Chinese shares dominated in non-local currency and designed for residents outside China mainland. As argued earlier, non-FDI have been playing a dominate role in building up the recently fast-paced accumulation of reserves. The noteworthy evidence on China’s management of FDI is the switching of the major policy focus from inward FDI to outward FDI generated by Chinese corporations. Driven by the distinguished attractiveness of investment environment, the traditional focus used to be the capital inflows, including paid-in capital, receipts in foreign currencies under capital account, and FDI firms and projects related external debt. In principal, the capital controls were initially applied to ensure the matching of imports and exports in financial terms in pursuing an external balance. A crucial consideration for less-developed economies is that such controls, in someway, impose 16 See Prasad and Wei, 2005 37 disciplines on macroeconomic policies. Empirical evidence suggests that countries, particularly those with underdeveloped financial intermediaries and limited access to international capital market, favor adopting rigid exchange rate regimes receive benefits in the form of macroeconomic stability17. For historical reasons in China, the designed financial mechanism worked well in serving the functions of preventing disruptive capital movements and mobilizing the scarce resource of foreign exchange within the country. However, these controls have become less effective and the benefits tend to erode over time. When countries become integrated with global markets and economies boom and mature, a flexible exchange rate regime appears more valuable. And also, since China is now having a big foreign exchange reserves surplus, it is neither necessary nor beneficial to maintain the rigid system. The domestic financial system in China is heavily dependent on the banking sector, which is dominated by state-owned commercial banks and lacks of competition. There will be considerable financial risks associated with capital flows in the absence of efficiently managed institutions. However, the porous banking industry may not experience substantial pressure resulting from the greater exchange rate volatility with the existing capital controls in place. As the overwhelming portion of foreign exchange is held in the hand of central government, banks do not have sufficient exposure to currency risk, and thereby will be short of incentives and channels to develop its foreign exchange market for currency risk management. If the national wealth dominated in foreign currencies can be distributed into the domestic banking system in a fairly comprehensive manner, the market will be expected to harness hedging instruments, e.g. financial derivatives, to manage the risk facing. In this wise, the introduction of exchange rate flexibility will not only expedite the process of capital account liberalization to cope with the influence of increasing capital flows, but also spread the excessive hoarding of foreign exchange reserves under the balance sheet of the people’s bank of China. Financial crises occurred in many developing countries illustrate that opening the capital account while maintaining the exchange rate regime inflexible provides a fertile ground for high potential of risks, especially for those nations that are not 17 See Rogoff, 2004 38 systematically ready for the requirement of opening. However, it has long been widely accepted that financial integration encourages a more efficient global allocation of capital. Developing countries equipped with lower capital entry barriers could be expected to be pushed to a high growth path. By sharing income risks across boarders, moreover, the capital-demanding developing economies that subscribed to this belief and liberalized their capital accounts would acquire more channels to investors and enhanced possibilities for consumption smoothing. The two-edged capital account liberalization delivers a mixed signal: more access to the international capital market but higher financial risks. Theoretically, capital inflows can help a developing country to spur economic growth in a number of ways, such as augmentation of domestic savings, lower cost of capital, and development of the domestic financial sector, all of which indirectly induce policy adjustments. A large literature shows that, it is the composition of capital flows, rather than the degree of financial openness, that determine the risks facing the developing countries18. FDI inflows are not as volatile as other capital flows and are of few possibilities of becoming reversed. Foreign debt, especially a high proportion of short-term debt, on the other hand, would lead to capital account vulnerability with financial integration. A crucial problem for most developing countries, so does China, is that they have little freedom in choosing the composition of capital flows as well as the accumulation of foreign exchange reserves. The semi-control power is mostly due to the weak domestic macroeconomic fundamentals, pushing the countries to rely heavily on external debt with a high share of short-maturity ones as they move further on the path toward financial openness. While having enhanced access to world capital markets, the actual borrowing probably would exceed the desired amount given the inefficient government expenditure, leading to increased debt exposure. In addition, transparency and corruption problems also threat the confidence of investors, inviting speculative behaviors and contagion effects. These negative influences of financial integration would inevitably float above surface if the threshold effects were not conquered. Only nations with efficient 18 See Prasad, Rogoff, Wei, and Kose, 2003 39 domestic institutions and sound economic policies are capable of gaining the full benefits of financial openness at a relatively lower risk associated in the initial phase. China has been enjoying the benefits from a pattern of capital composition heavily titled with FDI for a long time. In addition to the sufficient fund provided by FDI inflows, the country has also received a great deal of advanced technologies and managerial know-how through the cooperation with foreign institutions. However, although the financial system of China is centered on its banking sector, as shown by experience of the Asian crisis countries, foreign fund would flow into the domestic market through various channels and create serious imbalances. The declining proportion of FDI in China’s total capital inflows shows that the potential risks of financial globalization is increasing, implying that the country will be facing difficulties in having effective controls over those risks if a cautious approach to capital account liberalization was not to be taken. 4.4 Shift in policy Thus far, we have discussed the two major motives behind the accelerated accumulation of China’s foreign exchange reserves. In principal, having met the liquidity need, the remaining amount of holding is perceived to be excessive and operated at low efficiency. To fundamentally solve the problem of over holding, China should follow a “two-step” approach. The first step intends to slow down the growth rate of reserves via a series of policy changes, and the subsequent move is to allocate the economic resource in an efficient way to reduce the whole stockpile to an adequate level. Based on neoclassic economic theory, the pattern of capital import for a developing country will experience a four phases. Since the investment used to be higher than savings in emerging markets, they tend to borrow money from abroad to keep the domestic growth rate at a high level, and thus, a trade deficit exists which is the main feature of phase one. The gap between investment and saving illustrates the net inflow of capital, which is larger than the trade deficit because the capital importer needs to pay interests to the lenders. The persistence of such deficit would cause foreign debts to increase. As the national income grows and the saving increases, the gap between 40 investment and saving would shrink and subsequently reduce the trade deficit. However, because the interest on borrowing is increasing as well, the speed of changes in net inflows will be slower than that of the reduction of deficit. And also, the total amount of foreign borrowing would not stop growing but at a slower rate. When the domestic saving is sufficient to support its investment, the trade deficit would disappear and the capital importing phase calls to the end. The country goes to the second phase when the trade balance turns positive and becomes a capital exporter. But this is only an early exporting stage because it still has to pay foreign debtors the interests and returns, which are larger than the trade surplus. And correspondingly, the debt is climbing as usual. When the capital outflows exceed the inflows, foreign debts start to decrease until the country become a net capital exporter. At this time, both current account and trade balances are positive, symbolizing the medium capital exporting phase. The last phase defines the turning point when the country evolves to a developed economy and becomes a creditor nation. In practice, it takes a fairly long time for those developing countries that emphasize using foreign capital as a complement of the insufficient saving to promote to a trade surplus nation. China, as a low-income economy, is supposed to be a resource importer. In other words, the persisting trade surplus of China is a result of inappropriate economic policy. Theoretically, unlike a closed economy, an open economy is capable of raise investment and foreign borrowing without changing its savings. The current account may be the result of either high savings or low investment level. China is well known for its tremendous investment opportunities, but its savings are even much higher. Since 1990, the gross saving hovered around 40 percent as of GDP and reached the peak of 50.4 percent in 2005. Such high savings are built up by acquiring foreign wealth, rather than raising its own capital stock. Since a country’s current account surplus is also referred to as its net foreign investment, evidence shows that China is both a capital importer and a capital exporter. 41 60 50 40 Current account balance (% of GDP) 30 Gross savings (% of GDP) 20 Investment (% of GDP) 10 0 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 -10 Figure 18: China’s saving dilemma In general, the purpose of importing capital is to support the desire for investment and release the shortage of domestic funding. Therefore, there is usually an interactive relationship between current account and capital account: current account is normally accompanied by capital account deficit, and capital account surplus often goes with current account deficit. However, such relationship stopped appearing from 1994. This means that China’s surplus of savings over investment is approximately hundreds of billions of US dollars, while importing considerable amount at the same time. China has been among the countries of high saving rate recently. However, because of limited access to funding and the high cost of financing in the domestic financial market, companies have to borrow capital from abroad. The fundamental reason for such phenomena is that domestic savings was not used to support investment, or the money was not invested in an efficient way. Negative Influence of Foreign Reserve Surplus Apparently, it is necessary to hold a certain level of foreign exchange reserves at hand for the purpose of currency stabilization. But excessive holding will harm the national economy because holding is not without costs. The sufficient backup of reserves helped the RMB avoid substantial depreciation during the Asian financial crisis. However, this holding also follows the rule of diminishing marginal utility. For 42 instance, the utility of increase of reserves from zero to $100 billion will be larger than the increase from $300 billion to $400 billion. When the actual amount overreach the adequate point, the utility of holding every extra dollar will become negative, reducing the overall utility of holding and probably will cause other financial instability. In addition, as a developing economy, China has to pay a high interest when borrowing from overseas due to the country risk premium. Even though China has been heavily investing the foreign assets in US treasury bills, which is backed by the credit of the United States and deemed to be a safe asset with high liquidity, the average yield rate is about 2%. Hence, the more foreign reserves China holds the more costs it has to bear. Moreover, the capital that transferred from the low-income China to the high-income US should be used in an efficient way rather than financing the high current account deficit of the US. From this point of view, keeping substantive foreign reserves while borrowing largely from creditor nations could be regarded as exporting capital to foreign countries and importing the fund at a higher interest rate. In this way, by all appearances the de facto opportunity of cost of China’s holding of foreign exchange reserves is considerably high. On the other side, over-holding of reserves will make China exempted from having access to IMF concessional assistance. According to the IMF rules, member countries have the right to withdraw 100 percent of their respective deposits when facing adverse balance of foreign exchange deficit. Besides, they are also granted the right to borrow 160 percent of their deposits for funding the macro-adjustment at a low interest rate when their economies encounter structural problems. By contrast, countries with a foreign exchange surplus, like China, become givers than receivers when the world disequilibrium comes alone. Influence of Reserve Growth on Money Supply A country’s money supply is closely related to the asset structure of its monetary authority. In general, the reserve money is comprised of two deterministic components: domestic credit and net foreign assets. Because China is following a nearly centrally controlled foreign exchange policy, the people’s bank of China has to buy the increasingly accumulated foreign exchange from the domestic market with a 43 large amount of RMB, the so-called “funds outstanding for foreign exchange”. As one of the basic channels of currency issuance, the RMB equivalent of official foreign exchange holdings is positively related to the amount of reserves, and other things equal, the money supply would change accordingly as well. In absence of exchange rate flexibility and changes in domestic credit, the up scaling of foreign reserves would raise the monetary base, which in turn causing the aggregate money supply to increase. Percent Reserve to M2 ratio, China 25 20 15 10 5 2005 2004 2003 2002 2001 2000 1999 1998 1997 1996 1995 1994 1993 1992 1991 1990 0 Figure 19: Relationship between China’s reserves and money supply The proportion of the RMB counterpart of foreign exchange reserves maintains above 10 percent for most of the time in the 1990s. Similar to the shape of the regression residual chart of China’s reserve holdings given earlier, the climbing begins from the year of 2000 and starts accelerating from 2002. It is also worth noting that the share of total reserves increased by 118.3 percent through 2000 to 2005, which means that the level of reserves has been growing faster than money supply. The robust growth of reserves leads to a substantial booming of currency issuance. Such increasingly strong correlation between China’s money supply and foreign exchange reserves would also to some extent uplift the potential of instability of its domestic monetary system. Furthermore, the excessive money supply will invite a critical inflation problem since the supply side of money grows faster than the demand side. To maintain the same level of liquidity as before, people will tend to hold more money at hand, making 44 desired rate of hoarding moving upward. According to monetary approach to balance of payments, the rate of hoarding equals rate of change of money supply. This set of movements will further weaken the domestic consumption and result in a variety of macroeconomic problems. Influence of Reserve Growth on National Economy Being a less-developed economy, China has been promoting its national industrialization for many years, during which it needs a great deal of crucial resources, e.g. advanced technology, key equipments, and various scarce raw materials. The desire for productive resources unavailable within the country requires a transfer of part of the foreign exchange to support the purchase. On the other hand, the profit margin of investment in China is far greater than the low yield earned by foreign reserve holdings. When the growth of reserves declines, the capital provided through the fiscal channel and bank credit system encourages the sustaining of heavy investment. In other years, when the reserve level is accelerating, money issued goes to the foreign exchange reserve account, and consequently crowds out the normal demand for fund in the social system. Therefore, when the domestic industries are out of capital, productions and investments are going to decrease, leading to such serious social instabilities as the unemployment problem. Meanwhile, the giant national foreign exchange account has negative impact on the undertaking change of China’s economic structure. The share of tax revenue in national income has been declining as economy grows. Hence, the insufficient fund would delay the speed of macro or regional economic adjustment. Solutions On the surface, the persistent dual-surplus should be responsible for the over accumulation of foreign reserves. Yet among the variety of macroeconomic variables, reserves and the balance sheet of national account are only of subordinate when analyzing the interactions between them. It is unreasonable or even not worthy, for the sake of lowering reserve levels, to proactively manage exchange rate, adjust trade volumes, and make changes in the strategic choice of capital importing. Theory-based solutions include reducing export and/or increasing import, devaluation of the RMB, 45 lessening the capital inflows and/or encouraging overseas investment, and even ignoring capital flight, none of which is realistic or possible in the near future. Accordingly, taking the surplus of foreign reserves as a consequence rather than the source of external imbalance is a proper approach. Based upon the above analysis, to fundamentally address the series of economic problems incurred by the excessive holding of foreign reserves, a shift in economic policies should be taken into account. In an open economy where capital mobility and floating exchange rate regime are available, the amount set aside for foreign exchange market intervention is not necessary since the market would adjust external disequilibrium automatically. Therefore, to finally achieve the objectives of free conversion of the RMB and capital account liberalization, China has to perform a series of economic revolutions, which should be conducted in a gradual way in order to make the risks of policy shifting under control. At present, capital under current account flows freely but is subject to restrictive controls for capital account transactions. All foreign investors who are willing to participate in the Chinese financial market and domestic capitalists that plan to invest abroad need to obtain the approval from the government. These administrative regulations were placed to prevent capital speculations on the appreciation of the RMB and financial market hazard. However, as the volume of trade grows and the country’s integration with the global economy matures, the degree of such monitor would be less effective and hinders the targeted performance of the national economy. As the major motive of protection comes from speculation on the appreciation of the RMB, China could release the pressure once a broader range of intraday volatility is allowed. The current intra-day spread, 0.3 percent, obviously does not meet the need for the adjustment of external imbalances. If a wider scope was to be followed, e.g. 1 percent, the country would have more incentive to speed up its economic reform, especially within the financial sector. Besides, the sufficient fund of foreign exchange will grant China a smooth progress through the changes over time. When the currency stress is on a descending, bans on the capital account can be expected to be uplifted. But also, gradualism should be given more preference. For 46 instance, in line with the WTO agreement, China has to open its financial market to international financial institutions. The past protectionism of the Chinese financial industry has been hobbling the development of the market mechanism. Large amount of non-profitable bank loans indicates that the intermediary is running at low efficiency. By introducing more foreign competitors, the on-going restructuring of the banking sector can be enforced. To manage the risks taken by the domestic financial institutions, one option for the state is to enlarge the capital bases of major state-owned commercial banks by injecting capital out of the official foreign exchange reserves. Such actions would firm the competitive edge of the domestic financial industry and making a higher yield as the redeployed fund would eventually goes to the domestic market. In other words, this approach is consistent with investing the excessive liquidity of reserves in the domestic market while benefiting the country via making the shifted capital flow in the vessel of domestic financial system. The current account surplus can be divided into three parts: government budget surplus, savings of state-owned enterprises (SOEs) over investment by SOEs and savings of private companies over investment by the privates. According to the Central Intelligence Agency (CIA) data, China has been running a budget surplus for many years. In 2006, the tax revenue reaches $446.6 billion whereas expenditure increased to $489.6 billion. The economic activities by SOEs have a negative contribution to the current account due to the heavy investment in the domestic infrastructure. Hence, it is the private economy that underlies the sustaining current account surplus. Reducing this surplus, which can be done by lowering each of the three components, is meaningful because it would fundamentally help release the pressure on RMB’s revaluation. However, solely increasing the government expenditure on the improvement of social welfare could not address this issue efficiently and effectively. The reasons why the saving rate of China is such high is that there are many major social aspects remain underdeveloped as the entire economy prospers, including education, health care system, etc. For this reason, the internal turbulence can be viewed as the source of external imbalance. Once the savings started to turn down, the current account would adjust as well. In a nutshell, the accelerated accumulation of foreign exchange reserves is a result of both internal and external imbalances. External account balance is a natural reflection 47 of a country’s domestic economy, covering consumption, production, saving, and investment. The paradoxical situation of depositing too much while borrowing heavily from abroad is perceived to be the source of internal economic problem. The coexistence of the laggard domestic financial system is another weakness when China is on the path toward foreign exchange reform. To radically reduce the excessive holding of reserves, all the above-mentioned issued have to be addressed in a gradual manner in case of disruptive risks. 48 Part V Management of Reserves Eligible reserve management, which aims to adequately assist the major functions of foreign reserves, is supposed to follow three principles: (i) be consistent with the exchange rate policy features; (ii) balance the risk-return trade-off; and (iii) circumvent market turbulences. As the world foreign exchange reserves increased considerably in recent years, the style they are managed by central banks has evolved over time as well. Generally, the main trend in central bank reserve management is characterized by two common features: the use of a broader range of investment instruments and the shift in currency composition of reserves, both of which are confirmed by the evidence on investment of foreign reserves in U.S. assets. Individual frameworks for foreign reserve management employed by monetary authorities, however, vary vastly across countries. Against such background, this section reviews developments and trends of foreign exchange reserve management of major reserve accumulators, elaborating on various frameworks and methods undertaken by them in order to empirically provide suggestions on how should China improve its foreign asset management in an explicit way. 5.1 Diversification: From a Dollar Dominated Reserve to a Diversified One A report from European Central Bank outlined several factors that determine the currency composition of foreign reserves 19 . The first explanatory factor is the exchange rate regime adopted by the monetary authority. If a country is not employing a pure floating exchange rate system, the currency composition of reserves should be closely related to its choice of anchor currency or basket. A unique symbol of Asia is that currencies of countries in this region, more or less, are linked to the US dollar, due to the strong paired commercial relationships. This feature makes the Asian accumulators position the US dollar as part of their strategic considerations with respect to the foreign exchange policy, rather than a simple weight of reserves. 19 See “the Accumulation of Foreign Reserves”, Feb 2006. 49 Furthermore, with limited access to the international capital markets, developing countries view foreign reserves as a cushion for paying for imports and ensuring the servicing of external debt. Hence, the composition would to a large extent imitate the trade and financial flows. In addition, it is observed that central banks have increasingly taken into account optimal asset portfolio referring to risk management. Finally, besides these factors, the “market neutrality principle” is required to be followed prescribed by the IMF. Given the de facto existence of substantial increase of foreign exchange reserves over the past years, a trend toward a diversified composition of reserves is observed. As mentioned by Eichengreen (1998, 2005), “the importance of depth, breadth and stability of the financial markets, and the degree of international transactions have always played a decisive role when determining reserve currencies”. However, the dominant currency, currently the US dollar, as well as the composition itself, is not expected to change rapidly since non-gradual changes will lead to market turmoil. Table 7: Currency Composition of Official Foreign Exchange Reserves (COFER) (In millions of U.S. dollars) All countries 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 1,781,653 1,936,570 2,050,064 2,408,619 3,025,701 3,748,730 4,174,991 5,037,283 Total Claims 978,562 1,078,041 1,119,975 1,202,599 1,463,332 1,745,578 1,895,457 2,161,412 In U.S. dollars 55 56 55 50 48 47 45 43 % as of total 39,827 41,795 42,398 50,533 61,605 89,400 102,230 145,213 In pounds 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 3 % as of total 87,939 92,077 79,189 78,143 87,605 101,784 101,767 102,560 In Yen 5 5 4 3 3 3 2 2 % as of total 3,172 4,087 4,372 7,314 5,016 4,419 4,144 5,667 In Swiss francs 246,950 277,605 300,969 427,318 559,208 658,333 683,545 833,292 In Euros 14 14 15 18 18 18 16 17 % as of total 22,168 22,720 20,043 27,897 43,811 49,636 48,708 59,307 In others 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 % as of total Data Source: IMF Statistics Department COFER database The above table shows the annual changes in currency composition at an aggregate level. Since the reserve data for individual countries are strictly confidential, IMF grouped the reporting countries into three parts, all countries, industrial countries, and developing countries20. 20 It is the countries’ own will to report their reserve information to the IMF. In fact, these shares account for 50 Table 8: Currency Composition of Official Foreign Exchange Reserves (COFER) (In millions of U.S. dollars) Industrial 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 countries 726,113 783,171 789,427 905,573 1,121,070 1,318,343 1,295,046 1,395,259 Total Claims 528,404 565,639 570,976 618,223 783,799 935,234 946,133 995,748 In U.S. dollars 73 72 72 68 70 71 73 71 % as of total 15,675 15,959 15,053 19,116 17,176 24,994 27,451 35,380 In Pounds 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 3 % as of total 47,993 49,371 43,445 38,847 42,677 46,850 44,197 49,063 In Yen 7 6 6 4 4 4 3 4 % as of total 512 1,934 2,422 5,253 2,713 1,739 1,775 2,972 In Swiss francs 0.07 0.25 0.31 0.58 0.24 0.13 0.14 0.21 In Euros 249,977 277,976 250,286 288,068 % as of total 117,761 134,353 143,849 205,786 16 17 18 23 22 21 19 21 In others 22,066 28,323 21,373 19,450 % as of total 10,957 13,148 12,574 16,017 1.51 1.68 1.59 1.77 1.97 2.15 1.65 1.39 Total Claims Table 9: Currency Composition of Official Foreign Exchange Reserves (COFER) (In millions of U.S. dollars) Developing 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 Countries 1,055,540 1,153,399 1,260,637 1,503,046 1,904,631 2,430,387 2,879,946 3,642,024 Total Claims 450,158 512,402 548,999 584,376 679,533 810,345 949,324 1,165,664 In U.S. dollars 43 44 44 39 36 33 33 32 % as of total 24,152 25,836 27,345 31,417 44,429 64,406 74,779 109,833 In Pounds 2 2 2 2 2 3 3 3 % as of total 39,946 42,706 35,744 39,296 44,928 54,934 57,570 53,497 In Yen 4 4 3 3 2 2 2 1 % as of total 2,660 2,153 1,949 2,061 2,303 2,680 2,369 2,695 In Swiss francs 0.25 0.19 0.15 0.14 0.12 0.11 0.08 0.07 % as of total 129,190 143,252 157,120 221,532 309,231 380,358 433,259 545,223 In Euros 0.12 0.12 0.12 0.15 0.16 0.16 0.15 0.15 % as of total 11,211 9,573 7,469 11,880 21,745 21,313 27,335 39,857 In others 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 % as of total As noticed earlier, world total foreign exchange reserves have been increasing substantially after the Asian financial crisis. It is also noteworthy that the share of US dollar in global reserves has been reduced over time, especially for developing economies. Nevertheless, industrial countries have more confident in US dollar than sampled developing countries in the light of reserve holdings. Another remarkable approximately 70 % of reserve holdings, excluding important reserve accumulating countries. All industrial countries report to COFER since 1999, while only 80-90 (out of 160) developing countries contribute to the database. 51 change in the currency composition is the increased weight of euro as part of foreign reserves. The absolute value of euro held by industrial countries is more than doubled from 1999 to 2006, and for developing countries, this number have grown 4.2 times during the period. Hence, when limiting the analysis to developing countries, the small ratios of euro as percent of total reserves held are not negligible. The euro effect is supported by the booming economy of the euro zone and its continuous appreciation against other international currencies. Only Japanese yen, of other currencies, appears to have been significantly reduced in the world currency composition. This could be explained by the motive to avoid the reduction of absolute value of total reserves since yen had been depreciating considerably21. As regards the overall market aspects, changes in currency composition of reserves will result in a higher volatility in the foreign exchange market and international bond market. Specifically, given the large US current account deficit, the US dollar is expected to fall and thereby inflict losses on reserves. Taking into account the risk-return trade-off, central banks would actively managed to diversify out the US dollar influence by exchanging for other major currencies. IMF documented China as an extreme example that the constraints imposed on foreign exchange by the Chinese government lead to significant home bias22. It is argued that People’s bank of China prefers centrally process the accumulated foreign assets as by doing so the country could obtain the same benefit of diversification. Further diversification is perceived to add limited value to its current holding. 5.2 Trend in Composition of Instruments The spectrum of asset class in which managers of national foreign exchange reserves invest has been enlarged as well. McCauley and Fung (BIS, 2003a) summarize the evolution of reserve manager’s choice of instruments. The first phase is the mid-1970s, when monetary authorities started to pursue higher return by diversifying short-term debts out of treasury bills at the cost of taking more credit risks. Later, in the second phase, reserves rush to instruments with longer maturities, leaving central banks a market risk bearing position. In the 1990s, the preference on long-term instruments 21 22 The real effective exchange rate of Japanese yen depreciated 28% from 2000 to 2006. See IMF World Economic Outlook, 2005b. 52 became more popular as they are widely believed to offer higher returns while keeping risks at a limited and acceptable level. Due to the limited availability of disclosures on instrument composition of foreign official investments denominated in US dollar assets23, we analyzed the trend with data provided by “Treasury International Capital (henceforth TIC)” system from the United States department of the treasury24. Table 10: Foreign Portfolio Holdings of U.S. Securities—World Total In million $ Total Equity Total LT Debt Treasury Agency Corporate Total ST Debt Treasury Agency Corporate 2000 3,558,182 1,709,158 48.0 1,849,024 52.0 884,346 24.9 261,213 7.3 703,465 19.8 2002 4,338,049 1,395,402 32.2 2,530,517 58.3 908,058 20.9 492,416 11.4 1,130,043 26.0 412,130 9.5 231,960 5.3 88,084 2.0 92,087 2.1 2003 4,978,607 1,564,386 31.4 2,938,762 59.0 1,116,441 22.4 586,102 11.8 1,236,219 24.8 475,459 9.6 268,602 5.4 97,126 2.0 109,731 2.2 2004 6,019,234 1,930,499 32.1 3,500,524 58.2 1,426,046 23.7 619,412 10.3 1,455,066 24.2 588,212 9.8 316,920 5.3 123,798 2.1 147,493 2.5 2005 6,864,260 2,143,885 31.2 4,118,353 60.0 1,598,616 23.3 790,615 11.5 1,729,122 25.2 602,022 8.8 283,763 4.1 150,016 2.2 168,242 2.5 2006 7,777,565 2,429,517 31.2 4,732,607 60.8 1,726,953 22.2 984,476 12.7 2,021,178 26.0 615,441 7.9 253,187 3.3 146,991 1.9 215,263 2.8 Data Source: TIC System, Department of the Treasury, U.S. Note: Shaded numbers denote percentage as of total holdings within the same column. From the table above, we can detect that the world total foreign holdings of US securities had been doubled from 2000 to 2006. Most noticeably, the proportion of long-term debt in 2006 is 2.6 times more than the 2001 level, whereas the short-term debt share only increased 1.5 times in five years. Obviously, as the world accumulate more reserves, managers (including both reserve managers and non-reserve managers) weight less on liquidity with extra money at hand and are willing to extend their 23 This is because the confidentiality issues. Hence, private and official investments are not separated, making our conclusions cautious. 24 Other information sources, such as the IMF, the BIS, the Federal Reserve, and the Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA), also provide similar record but with different measurement. 53 investment horizon in exchange for higher return along the yield curve. Meanwhile, the share of treasury declined at a moderate speed with respect to a corresponding increase in securities of higher risks and returns. In detail, for long-term debt, both agency25 and corporate bonds are on an uptrend, whereas for short-term debt, only corporate issues are getting more attractive to global investors over time. Clearly, fund managers have been shifting some of their secured investment toward securities with higher credit risks so as to take additional yield spread pick-ups. This is particularly true for long-term agency bonds, as it grows 3.8 times during the five-year period. Table 11: Foreign Portfolio Holdings of U.S. Securities—Total of Top 10 Reserve Holders (Excluding China) In million $ Total Equity Total LT Debt Treasury Agency Corporate Total ST Debt Treasury Agency Corporate 2000 775,826 262,854 33.9 512,972 66.1 382,052 49.2 89,566 11.5 41,350 5.3 2002 1,053,987 224,045 21.3 655,459 62.2 411,843 39.1 147,411 14.0 96,204 9.1 174,481 16.6 117,889 11.2 47,596 4.5 8,997 0.9 2003 1,302,203 269,327 20.7 824,659 63.3 532,550 40.9 186,845 14.3 105,262 8.1 208,216 16.0 147,637 11.3 47,971 3.7 12,606 1.0 2004 1,645,404 330,722 20.1 1,090,790 66.3 754,698 45.9 196,269 11.9 139,822 8.5 223,889 13.6 157,993 9.6 51,929 3.2 13,967 0.8 2005 1,818,129 371,026 20.4 1,220,752 67.1 802,121 44.1 258,417 14.2 160,212 8.8 226,351 12.4 135,363 7.4 76,485 4.2 14,503 0.8 2006 1,971,188 423,424 21.5 1,338,363 67.9 800,503 40.6 350,077 17.8 187,783 9.5 209,399 10.6 102,949 5.2 86,625 4.4 19,825 1.0 Data Source: TIC System, Department of the Treasury, U.S. Note: Shaded numbers denote percentage as of total holdings within the same column. Overall, comparing with the world aggregate data, changes of top reserve holding countries in shares of investment in different asset class are magnified in the same direction. The reason to exclude China from the sample is to eliminate the odd effect on the result since China’s holding is much more than that of other countries. The 25 Agency bonds refer to securities issued by government-sponsored enterprises (GSEs). 54 total value of US securities held by the nine reserve accumulators raises up to 2.5 times, indicating that such countries enhanced the magnitude of investment in the US dollar dominated securities while stockpiling more reserves. However, since the built-up of reserves also increased by 2.57 times through the same period, it is not sufficient by far to conclude that the U.S. financial markets are given more emphasis. The sharp decrease of investment in the equity market from 2000 to 2002 is in line with the decline of major U.S. stock indices26 at that time. Likewise, the trend of debt market is consistent with that of the world data, whereas apparently, economies with large reserves other than China prefer holding bonds to putting money in the equity market. Another difference between the two groups is that large reserve nations are more risk-aversion than the rest since they are holding more share of treasury and agency bonds and less corporate securities. This fact confirms that, to some extent, those accumulated reserves are the intended results of government behaviors; otherwise, they would seek higher returns instead of merely earn the interests once the supply of reserves far exceed the demand for them. Table 12: Foreign Portfolio Holdings of U.S. Securities—China, Mainland In million $ Total Equity Total LT Debt Treasury Agency Corporate Total ST Debt Treasury Agency Corporate 2000 92,231 1,398 1.5 90,833 98.5 71,056 77.0 19,622 21.3 155 0.2 2002 181,478 4,034 2.2 164,704 90.8 95,200 52.5 58,607 32.3 10,898 6.0 12,740 7.0 1,257 0.7 11,275 6.2 207 0.1 2003 255,497 1,896 0.7 250,082 97.9 146,634 57.4 91,147 35.7 12,302 4.8 3,518 1.4 494 0.2 2,532 1.0 492 0.2 2004 340,972 2,523 0.7 320,287 93.9 189,181 55.5 114,903 33.7 16,203 4.8 18,163 5.3 5,029 1.5 12,854 3.8 279 0.1 2005 527,275 2,542 0.5 485,020 92.0 277,087 52.6 172,002 32.6 35,930 6.8 39,714 7.5 20,724 3.9 18,345 3.5 644 0.1 2006 698,929 3,818 0.5 677,944 97.0 364,065 52.1 255,386 36.5 58,494 8.4 17,167 2.5 8,170 1.2 8,492 1.2 505 0.1 26 The US equity market experienced a depression from January 2000 (DJIA 12,000 points) to March 2003 (DJIA 7400 points). 55 Data Source: TIC System, Department of the Treasury, U.S. Note: Shaded numbers denote percentage as of total holdings within the same column. The structure of China’s investment in the US financial market is significantly different from other countries. Most conspicuously, more than 90 percent of the country’s foreign assets are invested in U.S. long-term debt, particularly more than half of those in treasury bonds and more than 30 percent in agency bonds. Such figures reflect the strategic nature of China’s foreign reserves. Moreover, the low volatility of proportion of various instruments as percent of total investment indicates that there is no clear trend in direction of China’s actions. Admittedly, conclusions based on the TIC data analysis should be cautiously used to explain the trend in composition of instruments harnessed by reserve managers as it not only fails to distinguish the public investors from the privates, particularly for those industrial countries with a well-developed private sector, but also has little implication on the portfolio changes caused by trend in foreign exchange reserves management style. Furthermore, the reserve investment portfolio can be viewed as a country’s top secret. Given the confidentiality problem, only a paralleled simulation can be considered applicable. However, it is reasonable to assume that reserve managers, to some extent, have similar risk preference as the world reserve level grows dramatically. It is also reasonable to rely on the trend in investment in long-term debt and agency securities to draw a conclusion on the trend in the use of financial instruments, because as pointed earlier, reserve managers have been seeking a higher return while keep a relative level of liquidity. 5.3 Different Foreign Reserve Management Frameworks In connection to the colossal increase in foreign exchange reserves, Norges Bank, representing the Ministry of Finance in Norway, established a Government Petroleum Fund in 1990 to operate part of its reserves. Given the large volume of oil export27 and the roaring oil price, the Norwegians have been enjoying a current account surplus since a decade ago. A major consideration of the establishment of the Fund was the declining feature of long-run oil production and the high volatility of oil price. It is their responsibility to save part of the assets for future generation consumption by 27 The petroleum sector accounts for approximately 18 per cent of GDP, but only 3.5 per cent of total employment. 56 separating the current needs from the total accumulated reserves. In doing so, the excessive amount of holding was allocated to external fund manager, providing short-term fiscal stabilization through the oil price cycle. In addition, the Fund enables the government to channel its capital abroad and obtain higher return under regulations. However, it is important to keep in mind that the Petroleum Fund is nothing but an accounting technique. As quoted by Leif Eide28, “it provides an instrument for better, long-term budget discipline in a situation with government financial surpluses.” More importantly, macroeconomic developments would be roughly the same regardless the internal transaction behavior under a sound economic policy. Russia, on January 1, 2004, established a Stabilization Fund, managed by the Ministry of Finance of the Russian Federation pursuant to procedure defined by the government. Similarly, it was formed as a tool to absorb excessive liquidity, reduce inflation, and insulate the Russian economy in case of volatility of oil and gas export earnings. As of September 2007, the size of the Fund was $132, 91 billion29, most of which comes from the export duty for oil and tax on the oil mining operations. The capital of the Fund could be drawn to fulfill federal budget needs and other fiscal targets, most probably used for early foreign debt repayment 30 . Suggested by President Vladimir Putin’s budget address of March 2007, the Stabilization Fund will be split into a Reserve Fund and a National Welfare Fund, which are to be invested in foreign low-yield securities and riskier ones respectively. A common feature between the Norwegian and Russian frameworks is that those fund managed assets are not account for reserve holding because they are not used for foreign exchange intervention, even though they might appear on central banks’ balance sheets. More typically, some countries follow a more straight way in reserve management. Singapore is among the first-movers of the use external reserve managers. The Government of Singapore Investment Corporation (GIC) was established by the Government of Singapore in 1981. Its major capital sources are the accumulated budget surpluses and the Singapore Central Provident Fund (CPF), a 28 Executive Director of Bank of Norway, EMEAP (Executive Meeting of East Asia and Pacific Central Banks) reserves management seminar, Singapore, Feb 1997. 29 Approximately 3409, 07 billion rubles 30 Russia is a debtor to the IMF and the countries-members of the Paris Club. Transactions in 2005 under this account amount to $18.3 billion. 57 national pension scheme. Noticeably, the assets managed by GIC, currently over $100 billion, are not related to foreign reserves. Bank of Korea, likewise, transferred part of its reserves to an external institution31, while remaining the right to withdraw them in case of emergency. Allocating part of the reserves holdings to a separate institution when actual reserves exceed liquidity demand can be seen as a portfolio approach, aiming at achieving higher long-term returns. European Central Bank referred this method as heritage fund. Another alternative to utilize excessive reserves is to sponsor domestic economic developments. For instance, in Taiwan, 15 billion US dollars has been allocated to banks for use in major investment projects to foster economic growth. 5.4 Which way should China follow? There are several options for China in exchange for a high yield on reserves. For example, the excessive liquidity can be invested in securities with a high risk/return feature. To follow this approach, the country should hire external managers, like Norway’s approach, to manage the funds. Nonetheless, massive investment would make China a creditor nation while importing capital from abroad. Another option is to make use of the money to purchase other forms of overseas strategic assets, which is consistent with China’s recent financial aid to the African countries. Basically, no matter whether the de facto reserve holding of China is excessive or not, according to the large US current account deficit, it is highly risky to keep the dollar cash in hand. The newly announced pegging target of foreign exchange rate in July 2005 indicates that the dollar risk is to be controlled. The slow-paced appreciation of RMB is not only a release of international pressure, but also a shift toward freely floating regime. Apparently, evidence shows that China has been taking steps to diversify its reserve composition with a moderate mode. In December 2003, the Central Huijin Investment Company Limited (CHI) was established by the Department of Finance with a paid-in-capital of 45 billion US dollars. The primary objective was to operate the country’s foreign exchange reserves in a more efficient way. The company injected 31 The Korea Investment Corporation (KIC), operation began on 1 July 2005. 58 most of its assets to China’s four major state-owned commercial banks 32 . In September 2007, China Investment Company Limited (CIC) was founded and its initial capital was approximately $200 billion. Before its establishment, an attempted action was made to purchase $3 billion share of Blackstone Corporation, which is perceived to be a purely commercial deal. Theoretically, however, developing economies like China are not expected to execute large capital export activities since domestic investment is supposed to be higher than that of industrial countries. The recent economic history of capital-abundant Japan can be taken as an example for reference. It is argued that increasing the level of domestic investment by consuming reserves is an alternative to revaluing the RMB, particularly for those capital-intensive projects. Foreign direct investments could thus be replaced with the country’s national saving. Nevertheless, the root of the upward pressure of RMB will not be eliminated but purely increased in the long run because the trade surplus still exists and China has to convert its assets dominated in foreign currencies into RMB when investing in the domestic market. Therefore, although the management of foreign exchange reserves is effective in reducing the opportunity cost of holding, a shift in economic policies with a long run sight is required to accompany the proactive reserve-related actions. 32 From Dec 2003 to Aug 2005, CHI injected $22.5 billion to Bank of China, $20 billion to China Construction Bank, 3 billion yuan to Bank of Communications, and $15 billion to Industrial and Commercial Bank of China. 59 Part VI Concluding Comments The unprecedented scale of foreign exchange reserves held by China and many other emerging economies has triggered a debate on the management of these strategic assets. However, most of the argument deals the transferability of individual’s money demand to a country’s demand for reserves, the optimality of holding, the motives behind the substantial accumulation of reserves in recent years, and so forth. Few of these researches attempt to apply such theories to a specific region or country. Moreover, most of the theoretical conclusion was drawn based on a model of small open economy, albeit with some relaxation of assumptions. When applying to China, such a growing, big, and centrally-planned player with a distinct economic structure in the global economy, conventional analysis might fail to tackle the realities. This paper deals with the questions of how much to hold and what to hold for reserves by combining an empirical analysis of 42 developing economies with a peer of the dynamics of China’s economic and policies in the past decade. The major conclusion from the quantitative part is that China has been holding an excessive level of foreign exchange reserves with respect to the behaviors of other less-developed countries. To avoid the future potential costs incurred by the surplus of foreign reserves, a two-step approach is suggested to be followed. In the long run, China has to adopt a series of changes in its economic policies, including gradually moving toward free conversion of the RMB, liberalization of the capital account, etc. The short term solution would be allocating the excessive liquidity to the capital market to achieve higher returns. As forecasted by Roger (1993), the management of foreign exchange reserves has acquired increased prominence among the range of issues facing many central banks. The basic focus is on the amount and form of reserves. Concerning on the amount, the prevailing doing is to quantify a “comfort zone” level of reserves and invest the excess part. However, measurement problem is the biggest challenge since the reserve management is mainly the concern of monetary authorities of developing countries, which have many structural restrictions that are hardly quantified. Thus, the static comfort zone is usually not capable of tracking the dynamics driven by major 60 economic events. The principal function of keep accumulating is foreign exchange reserves is to obtain insurance and security which worth the cost as long as the demand is not fulfilled. Some economists too, propose to turn over a portion of quasi reserves to institutional investment authority. In this way, isolated from political influence, they can invest money in higher risk/yield investments and domestic spending. Since the management of foreign exchange reserves is a country-level issue, international institutions, e.g. the IMF and the World Bank, should seek to provide better facilities in assisting member country’s reserve management. Stiglitz (2002) brings forward a novel concept of “Global Greenbacks” to issue a new form of global money instead of holding reserves in dollars, giving an extension of the use of SDRs. Referring to Rogoff’s saying ahead of this paper, it is never easy to draw conclusions on reserve related issues. Also, it is neither necessary nor possible to answer the question whether a country is holding foreign exchange reserves at an optimal level with a precise number. The main concern should be focused on a range of benchmarks rather than a certain value33. Admittedly, this paper did not use a range approach but a series of residuals comparing with the world average level, which utilizes an underlying assumption that such average level is an ideal pattern for each economy to self-mirror with. Clearly, conclusions based on this argument should be seen as cautious because sample countries have different backgrounds and distinctive economic structure. And also, the various levels of foreign reserves might be stemming from different policy targets. However, the difference between adequacy and optimality is defined before the empirical analysis is performed. In line with Grubel (1971), both economists and policy makers are facing problems to relate interpreted past changes to projected future ones. Therefore, a more sophisticated reserve management system, including monitoring ratios, signaling liquidity, managing excessive reserves, should be developed with further research. Frenkel (2004) mentions that each of fixed and flexible exchange rate regimes has its own advantages and a country has the right to choose the regime best suited to its situations. One indubitable argument is that the de facto dollar pegging system has 33 Department of Finance, Beijing Normal University, develops a novel reserve management system based on demand factor analysis and signal lamp model. 61 somewhat become inappropriate for China, indicating a dramatic change of the composition of its foreign exchange reserves in the future. As discussed earlier, given the existence of internal imbalance, China’s economy is expected to experience inflationary pressure, which can be eased by the revaluation of the RMB. In addition, the appreciation would also help reduce the balance of payments surplus and thereby lessen the amount of foreign reserves that is perceived to be fully adequate and excessive. As the composition of China’s capital inflows changes, it becomes more difficult and costly to sterilize the inward capital over time, deteriorating the inflation problem. Experience of other emerging economies shows that China should bear in mind that the timing of exiting the current rigid exchange rate system is crucial in determining the risks associated with the changes of currency policy. It is better to switch the peg to other hard currencies or become freely convertible when the currency is strong, and vice versa. Despite political pressure, an intermediate exchange rate regime is viewed as more appropriate by the academic world. The need for a wilder flexibility of exchange rate does not necessarily imply a floating system. A gradual course of action might be better for China in case of taking too much risk. While maintaining the mercantilist strategy to pursue export-oriented development by keeping the RMB undervalued, China has created an abnormal dual-surplus and thereby accumulate a large volume of foreign exchange reserves. Only a turnaround of economic policy could fundamentally and effectively decrease the growth rate of reserves and finally reduce the aggregate amount to an adequate level. However, given the hundreds of billion dollars excessive reserves in existence, the Chinese monetary authorities ought to proactively manage the excessive portion to acquire higher return. Experiences of other pioneering countries have shown that hiring external managers to invest such fund is the prevailing choice. Therefore, China could strive to utilize such reallocated strategic assets for better use, e.g. purchase of key technology, financing domestic public projects, investing in the domestic education and health care system. 62 Reference Elias Papaioannou, Richard Portes, Gregorios Siourounis, 2006, “Optimal Currency Shares in International Reserves: The Impact of the Euro and the Prospects for the Dollar”, European Central Bank Working Paper No. 694 Julio H. G. Olivera, 1969, “A Note on the Optimal Rate of Growth of International Reserves”, The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 77, No. 2, pp. 245-248 Marc-André Gosselin, Nicolas Parent, 2005, “An Empirical Analysis of Foreign Exchange Reserves in Emerging Asia”, Bank of Canada Working Paper 05/38 Yongnian Zheng, Jingtao Yi, 2007, “China’s Rapid Accumulation of Foreign Exchange Reserves and Its Policy Implications”, China & World Economy, Vol. 15, No. 1, pp. 14-25 Peter B. Clark, 1970, “Demand for International Reserves: A Cross-Country Analysis”, The Canadian Journal of Economics, Vol. 3, No. 4, pp. 577-594 Emil-Maria Claassen, 1975, “Demand for International Reserves and the Optimum Mix and Speed of Adjustment Policies”, The American Economic Review, Vol. 65, No. 3, pp. 446-453 Dani Rodrik, 2006, “The Social Cost of Foreign Exchange Reserves”, NBER Working Paper Series No. 11952 Joshua Aizenman, Nancy Marion, 2002, “The High Demand for International Reserves in the Far East: What’s Going On?” NBER Working Paper Series No. 9266 John Nugée, “Foreign Exchange Management”, Bank of England CCBS Series, Handbooks in Central Banking, No.19 F. W. Paish, 1961, “Reviewed Work(s): Gold and the Dollar Crisis. The Future of Convertibility, By R. Triffin”, The Economic Journal, Vol. 71, No.281, pp. 142-144 63 Robert Clower, Richard Lipsey, 1968, “The Present State of International Liquidity Theory”, The American Economic Review, Vol. 58, No. 2, pp. 586-595 John R. Dodsworth, 1978, “International Reserve Economies in Less Developed Countries”, Oxford Economic Papers, Vol. 30, No. 2, pp. 277-291 Avraham Ben-Bassat, Daniel Gottlieb, 1992, “On the Effect of Opportunity Cost on International Reserve Holdings”, The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 74, No. 2, pp. 329-332 Jacob A. Frenkel, Boyan Jovanovic, 1980, “On Transactions and Precautionary Demand for Money”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 95, No. 1, pp. 25-43 Jacob A. Frenkel, Boyan Jovanovic, 1981, “Optimal International Reserves: A Stochastic Framework”, The Economic Journal, Vol. 91, No. 362, pp. 507-514 Heinz Robert Heller, 1966, “Optimal International Reserves”, The Economic Journal, Vol. 76, No. 302, pp. 296-311 Peter Barton Clark, 1970, “Optimum International Reserves and the Speed of Adjustment”, The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 78, No. 2, pp. 356-376 Lois Stekler, rolf Piekarz, 1970, “Reserve Asset Composition for Major Central Banks”, Oxford Economic Papers, Vol. 22, No. 2, pp. 260-274 Michael G. Kelly, 1970, “The Demand for International Reserves”, The American Economic Review, Vol. 60, No. 4, pp. 655-667 Herbert G. Grubel, 1971, “The Demand for International Reserves: A Critical Review of the Literature”, Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 9, No. 4, pp. 1148-1166 Sebastian Edwards, 1983, “The Demand for International Reserves and Exchange Rate Adjustments: The Case of LDCs, 1946-1972”, Economica, Vol. 50, No. 199, pp. 269-280 Sebastian Edwards, 1984, “The Demand for International Reserves and Monetary Equilibrium: Some Evidence from Developing Countries”, The Review of Economics 64 and Statistics, Vol. 66, No. 3, pp. 495-500 Jacob A. Frenkel, 1974, “The Demand for International Reserves by Developed and Less-Develop Countries”, Economica, Vol. 41, No. 161, pp. 14-24 J. L. Ford, Guobo Huang, 1994, “The Demand for International Reserves in China: An ECM Model with Domestic Monetary Disequilibrium”, Economica, Vol. 61, No. 243, pp. 379-397 William J. Baumol, 1952, “The Transactions Demand for Cash: An Inventory Theoretic Approach”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 66, No. 4, pp. 545-556 Robert P. Flood, Nancy Peregrim Marion, “The Transmission of Disturbances under Alternative Exchange-Rate Regimes with Optimal Indexing”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 97, No. 1, pp. 43-66 Kenneth Kletzer, Santa Cruz, 2000, “Will Self-protection Policies Safeguard Emerging Markets from Crises?” SCCIE Working Paper No. 99-10 Pentti J. K. Kouri, Jorge Braga De Macedo, Walter S. Salant, Marina V. N. Whitman, 1978, “Exchange Rates and the International Adjustment Process”, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Vol. 1978, No. 1, pp. 111-157 James Tobin, 1969, “A General Equilibrium Approach to Monetary Theory”, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol.1, No.1, pp.15-29 Harry G. Johnson, 1977, “The Monetary Approach to Balance of Payments Theory and Policy: Explanation and Policy Implications”, Economica, New Series, Vol. 44, No. 175, pp. 217-229 R. A. Mundell, 1963, “Capital Mobility and Stabilization Policy under Fixed and Flexible Exchange Rates”, The Canadian Journal of Economics and Political Science, Vol. 29, No. 4, pp. 475-485 People’s Bank of China, 2005, “Public Announcement of the People’s Bank of China on Reforming the RMB Exchange Rate Regime”, 21 July 2005. 65 Mark M. Spiegel, 2005, “A Look at China’s New Exchange Rate Regime”, FRBSF Economic Letter, No. 2005-23 Matthew Higgins, Thomas Klitgaard, 2004, “Reserve Accumulation: Implications for Global Capital Flows and Financial Markets”, Current Issues in Economics and Finance, Volume 10, No. 10, Federal Reserve Bank of New York International Relations Committee Task Force, 2006, “The Accumulation of Foreign Reserves”, European Central Bank, Occasional Paper Series, No.43 Chorng-Huey Wong, Luis Carranza, 1998, “Policy Responses to External Imbalances in Emerging Market Economies – Further Empirical Results”, IMF Working Paper, WP/98/103 Joshua Aizenman, Jaewoo Lee, 2005, “International Reserves: Precautionary vs. Mercantilist Views, Theory and Evidence”, IMF Working Paper, WP/05/198 Joshua Aizenman, 2007, “International Reserve Management and the Current Account”, NBER Working Paper No. 12734 Jeffrey A. Frankel, Shang-Jin Wei, 2007, “Assessing China’s Exchange Rate Regime”, NBER Working Paper No. 13100 IMF, 2001, “Guidelines for Foreign Exchange Reserve Management” Morris Goldstein, 2007, “A (Lack of) Progress Report on China’s Exchange Rate Policies”, Peterson Institute for International Economics Working Paper WP 07-5 Jeffrey Frankel, 2004, “On the Renminbi: The Choice between Adjustment under a Fixed Exchange Rate and Adjustment under a Flexible Rate”, KSG Faculty Research Working Paper Series RWP04-037 Marvin Goodfriend and Eswar Prasad, 2006, “A Framework for Independent Monetary Policy in China”, IMF Working Paper, WP/06/111 66 Appendix A: Stylized Facts about China Billion $ 1200 Reserves of Foreign Exchange 1000 800 600 400 200 0 Figure 20: Top 10 largest reserve holding countries Data Source: The World Factbook, Dec, 2006 Total reserves in months of imports 16 14 12 10 8 6 4 2 0 Figure 21: China’s import coverage of reserves 67 Reserve to GDP ratio (%) 40 35 30 25 20 15 10 5 0 Figure 22: China’s holding of reserves relative to its economic scale Net FDI (in billion $) 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 Figure 23: China’s yearly net FDI flows 68 40 35 30 25 20 15 10 5 Imports as percentage of GDP 2005 2004 2003 2002 2001 2000 1999 1998 1997 1996 1995 1994 1993 1992 1991 1990 0 Reserve to GDP ratio (%) Figure 24: Relationship between China’s import and its reserves M2 as % of GDP 160 140 120 100 80 60 40 20 0 Figure 25: China’s broad money relative to its economic scale 69 Appendix B: Selected Data Data Source: WDI (World Development Indicators, published by the World Bank) IFS (International Financial Statistics, published by the IMF) Reserves: Total reserves minus gold (current $) Import: Imports of goods and services (BOP, current $) Variance: 10-year variance of current account balance Debt: Total external debt (DOD, current $) Propensity of Import: Imports of goods and services as percent of GDP Sample Countries: 42 LCDs (Less-Developed Countries). Covered regions include East Asia & Pacific, Europe & Central Asia, Latin America & Caribbean, Middle East & North Africa; African developing countries which have too much risk of political uncertainty are excluded from the pool. List of 42 sample countries Albania China Guatemala Jordan Pakistan Romania Argentina Colombia Haiti Malaysia Panama Thailand Barbados Costa Rica Honduras Mexico Papua New Guinea Trinidad and Tobago Bolivia Dominican Republic Hungary Mongolia Paraguay Tunisia Brazil Ecuador India Morocco Turkey Bulgaria Egypt, Arab Rep. Indonesia Nicaragua Philippines Uruguay Chile El Salvador Jamaica Oman Venezuela, RB Peru Poland Sample period: 1990-2005 70 Appendix C: Curvilinear trend test Table 13: Test for Import: No Curve Significant 1990-2005 (655 obs) 1990-1996 (287 obs) 1998-2005 (325 obs) Coefficient P-Value Coefficient P-Value Coefficient P-Value -15.543 2.049 -0.018 0.004 0.000 0.068 -20.744 2.490 -0.028 0.032 0.004 0.137 -7.150 1.371 -0.005 0.341 0.033 0.735 Constant Import Sq-ln(m) Table 14: Test for Openness: Significant Curve Trend 1990-2005 (655 obs) Coefficient P-Value 1990-1996 (287 obs) Coefficient P-Value 1998-2005 (325 obs) Coefficient P-Value Constant 32.405 0.000 30.229 0.000 39.876 0.000 ln(m/GDP) -5.158 0.000 -4.202 0.004 -8.856 0.000 Sq-ln(m/GDP) 0.594 0.001 0.450 0.039 1.077 0.000 Table 15: Test for Variance of Current Account: No Curve Significant Constant ln(var) Sq-ln(var) 1990-2005 (655 obs) Coefficient P-Value 7.980 0.201 0.147 0.630 0.005 0.209 1990-1996 (287 obs) Coefficient P-Value -7.290 0.497 0.850 0.110 -0.004 0.587 1998-2005 (325 obs) Coefficient P-Value 19.169 0.011 -0.340 0.353 0.010 0.024 Table 16: Test for External Debt: Significant Scale Effect Constant ln(d) Sq-ln(d) 1990-2005 (655 obs) Coefficient P-Value 26.937 0.000 -1.508 0.013 0.055 0.000 1990-1996 (287 obs) Coefficient P-Value 24.040 0.047 -1.306 0.215 0.051 0.026 1998-2005 (325 obs) Coefficient P-Value 29.265 0.001 -1.635 0.025 0.057 0.000 71 Appendix D: Structure Test with Quadratic Variables Table 17: Test of Structural Change in Demand for Reserves with Quadric Variables Constant 1990-2005 (655 obs) Coefficient P-Value -9.57 0.076 1990-1996 (287 obs) Coefficient P-Value -18.685 0.048 1998-2005 (325 obs) Coefficient P-Value -0.596 0.928 m 1.028 0 1.028 0 0.904 0 m/GDP -0.062 0.89 -0.207 0.736 -0.685 0.375 Sq-ln(m/GDP) var Debt Sq-ln(d) -0.028 0.083 0.43 -0.009 0.658 0 0.35 0.358 -0.001 0.103 1.183 -0.026 0.909 0.002 0.151 0.156 0.053 0.076 -0.028 0.002 0.62 0.003 0.96 0.873 72 Appendix E: Regression Output Table 18: Estimation of the Parameters Constant P-value Std In(m) P-value Std ln(var) P-value Std ln(d) P-value Std D(China) P-value Std D(Dominican R) P-value Std D(Mongolia) P-value Std D(Pakistan) P-value Std D(Panama) P-value Std D(Ecuador) P-value Std D(Haiti) P-value Std D(China98-01) P-value Std D(China02-05) 1998-2005 -4.1 0 0.517 0.76 0 0.058 0.1 0 0.024 0.193 0 0.054 1998-2005 -2.106 0 0.448 0.686 0 0.049 0.094 0 0.018 0.196 0 0.042 0.761 0 0.161 -1.467 0 0.15 -0.511 0.002 0.166 -0.625 0 0.148 -1.13 0 0.147 -1.123 0 0.149 -0.953 0 0.174 1998-2005 -3.449 0 0.539 0.696 0 6012 0.097 0 0.023 0.233 0 0.054 0.756 0 0.211 1998-2005 -3.423 0 0.54 0.692 0 0.06 0.098 0 0.024 0.235 0 0.054 0.607 0.031 0.28 0.916 73 P-value Std Adj R-square No.obs 90.20% 326 94.50% 326 90.50% 326 0.002 0.288 90.50% 326 74
© Copyright 2024