Why Now? A contribution towards the first IEWG meeting Contributors: Robert Costanza, Richard Wilkinson, Kate Pickett & Ida Kubiszewski January 27 – February 2, 2013 Thimphu, Bhutan 2 Bhutan’s NDP Initiative Why Now? Robert Costanza, Richard Wilkinson, Kate Pickett, Ida Kubiszewski 2 A contribution towards the first IEWG meeting 3 Why Now? INTERDEPENDENCE The world has changed dramatically. We now live in a world that is far more interdependent than it has ever been. The local self-sufficiency of peasant farmers and craft workers of the past has been overtaken by the growing global network of economic interdependence. Human beings everywhere now work to supply the needs of others and depend on what others across the globe have produced. Spanning continents, the international division of labour now links us together in an intricate web of trade, communication and exchange. Just as single celled organisms once came together to form multi-celled organisms, humanity has become a truly global entity. The vast scale of the modern system of mutual reliance is changing what it means to be human. Alongside the expansion of international trade networks has been an equally dramatic development of communications – cell phones, television, international air travel, email and the Internet – and out of that has come a worldwide sharing of knowledge, science, music, culture and sport. Rather than simply being materially dependent on distant people we have never met, we are also getting to know more about the kind of lives people lead in what were once faraway places but are now part of the global village. As we are drawn together, there are growing signs of a corresponding widening of our moral boundaries, not only through knowledge of each other, but also of our capacity for identification and empathy, which was once confined to family and tribe. This is shown in the growth of concern for world poverty, the individual contributions of those who give aid to victims of distant earthquakes, famines and tsunamis, the increasing concern for social justice and human rights across the globe, and by the reputational risk companies face if they are found to employ child labour or expose their employees and local communities to dangerous pollutants. But despite the profundity of these practical changes in the nature of human life, we appear politically, economically and socially unable either to tackle problems that threaten humanity as a whole, or to make use of the productive and creative power of modern societies to maximize human wellbeing. Much of our thinking, as well as our institutions and economic systems, remain stuck in what is now a past epoch, unable to cope with new realities. Governments fail to reach agreement on preventing runaway global warming; they fail to respond adequately to world poverty or to the burden of preventable disease; they continue to spend appalling sums of money on armaments; they fail to deal with tax havens, leading to vast losses of revenue from those who can most afford to pay; and the governments of wealthy countries continue to promote international trade agreements which often serve only their own interests. Those failures are symptoms of a paradigm that no longer works. Thus, our attempts to deal with this new reality have been largely within the obsolete structures of competition rather than cooperation among nation states, and through preconceptions and institutions that do more to create than to solve the new problems. The extraordinary potential of this new world to increase human wellbeing lies wasted and unexplored. Nations compete in what becomes a race to the bottom, for fear they will go under if they don’t; yet the truth is that we will go under unless we develop new international cooperative structures, institutions, and ways of thinking. The problems that confront humanity demand a new paradigm based on a new level of international agreement and cooperation. Interdependence and competition are not only antithetical in nature but also risk inflicting irretrievable damage on the planet. 3 4 Bhutan’s NDP Initiative The time has come to make a transition. The challenge is daunting, but we have no choice. However the problems we face are linked in such a way that solving one paves the way to solving others. We are, for instance, unlikely to get international agreement on measures strong enough to check global warming without also addressing world poverty. That will be easier with the establishment of international trade agreements that prioritize the development of poorer countries. Similarly, dramatic reductions in the burden of preventable diseases and deaths would be facilitated if we reduced the exorbitant levels of military spending. And the ability to promote wellbeing within nations would be very substantially increased if effective international measures were taken to prevent the use of tax havens for avoiding national taxes. Envisioning a new world order is not a task for the faint hearted. These problems need to be solved together because they are so interlinked that they reinforce each other. However, solving any one of them begins to loosen the tangle, making it easier to solve the others. THE RELATION BETWEEN ECONOMIC GROWTH AND WELLBEING So long as our thinking is conditioned by the assumptions of the present consumption and growth-based paradigm, it will be difficult to make the required transition to a sane world order and to fashion sane policies that enhance human happiness and the wellbeing of all life forms. For example, one of the most important obstacles to reaching an international agreement on policies to reduce carbon emissions hinges on the very different levels of responsibility for past carbon emissions and the very different stages of economic development and living standards countries have reached. But it begins to be easier to see a way through this conundrum if we recognise how the relation between economic growth and human wellbeing changes during the long course of economic development. Figure 1 shows the relation between life expectancy and Gross National Income per capita (GNIpc) internationally. We can see that life expectancy rises rapidly in the earlier stages of economic growth before levelling out. The levelling out is not simply a ceiling effect as rich nations approach some limit of life expectancy; life expectancy in these countries is still rising as fast as it has done during most of the last century. What has changed is that among the rich countries these increases in life expectancy are no longer related to economic growth. Even without further growth, life expectancy continues to rise. If instead of life expectancy, we plot measures of happiness or wellbeing against GNIpc, the result is a curve very much like that in Figure 1: economic growth makes an important contribution to health, happiness and wellbeing in its early stages, but makes less and less difference as countries become richer. That basic curve illustrates a pattern of strongly diminishing returns to human wellbeing of continued economic growth. Although economic growth in the past has transformed the quality of life in the rich world, it now appears to have largely finished its work in these countries. Higher material living standards are clearly still important for people in poorer countries where many lack important necessities, but for people in the rich world it looks as if having more and more of everything makes less and less difference. Indeed, after over a century and a half of rising income levels, it would seem inevitable that diminishing returns would set in at some point. 4 A contribution towards the first IEWG meeting 5 Why Now? The curve in Figure 1 suggests that there is a threshold level of material living standards at which absolute poverty ceases to be an important constraint on health and wellbeing. As middle income countries move from the more vertical to the more horizontal part of that curve, the infectious diseases of absolute poverty – which kill particularly in childhood – give way to the degenerative diseases which kill very predominantly in old age. At the same time, as countries go through that transition, the so-called ‘diseases Figure 1: Only in its early stages does economic income boost life expectancy. Source: [3] of affluence’ tend to reverse their social distribution. Diseases such as heart disease and stroke, which once were more common among the better off in each society, become more common among the less well off. Indeed, in the developed countries it is, for the first time in human history, the poor who are fatter and the rich who are thinner. This evidence that economic growth no longer increases wellbeing in the rich countries is strongly confirmed by the picture gained from successive surveys of people’s life satisfaction over time. These show that levels of happiness have been relatively flat in the United States and many other developed countries since about 1975, in spite of a near doubling in per capita income (Figure 2). 5 6 Bhutan’s NDP Initiative Figure 2: Happiness and Real Income in the United States, 1972–2008. NOTE: Mean happiness (left scale) is the average reply from respondents to the U.S. General Social Survey. The survey question asks: "Taken all together, how would you say things are these days? Would you say that you are not too happy, pretty happy or very happy?" These values were coded as 1, 2 and 3, respectively. Source: [4] As a measure of true human wellbeing, Gross Domestic Product (GDP) is limited because it measures only marketed economic activity or gross income, and also because it counts all of this activity as positive. It does not separate desirable, wellbeing-enhancing activity from undesirable, wellbeing-reducing activity. So, for example, an oil spill increases GDP because someone has to clean it up, but it obviously detracts from society’s wellbeing. Similarly, from the perspective of GDP, more crime, more sickness, more war, more pollution, more fires, storms, and pestilence are all potentially good things, because they can increase marketed activity in the economy. GDP also leaves out many things that do enhance wellbeing but are outside the market. For example, the unpaid work of parents caring for their own children at home does not show up; but if these same parents decide to work outside the home to pay for childcare, GDP suddenly increases. The non-marketed work of natural capital in providing clean air and water, food, natural resources, and other ecosystem services, does not adequately show up in GDP either; but if those services are damaged and we have to pay to fix or replace them, then GDP suddenly increases. Finally, GDP takes no account of the distribution of income among individuals. But it is well known that an additional dollar of income produces more wellbeing if one is poor rather than rich. In fact, GDP is maximized by allocating resources to those with the greatest willingness to pay. In a highly unequal society, a rich person may be willing to pay more for drinking water to flush their toilets than a poor family can pay to prevent a child from dying of dysentery. It is also clear that a highly skewed income distribution has negative effects on a society’s social capital. A new development paradigm will certainly require new and more comprehensive measures of progress that properly account for core determinants of wellbeing and that thereby enhance opportunties for human happiness. For example, one emerging alternative measure which makes adjustments to GDP to take account of its weaknesses as a measure of wellbeing is the Index of Sustainable Economic Well-Being (ISEW) and a variation on it called the Genuine Progress Indicator (GPI). The GPI separates the positive from the negative components of marketed economic activity, adding in estimates of the value of nonmarketed goods and 6 A contribution towards the first IEWG meeting 7 Why Now? services provided by natural, human, and social capital, and adjusting for income-distribution effects. While the measure is by no means a perfect representation of the real wellbeing of nations, GPI ⎯ or for that matter Bhutan’s Gross National Happiness Index ⎯ is a much better approximation of wellbeing than GDP. As many have noted, it is much better to be approximately right in these measures than precisely wrong. Comparing GDP and GPI for the United States (Figure 3) shows that, while GDP has steadily increased since 1950, with the occasional dip or recession, GPI peaked in about 1975 and has been flat or gradually decreasing ever since. From the perspective of the real economy, as opposed to just the market economy, the United States has been in recession since 1975. The United States and several other developed countries are now in a period of what Herman Daly has called "uneconomic growth," where further growth in marketed economic activity (GDP) is actually reducing wellbeing, on balance, rather than enhancing it. GPI is certainly not a perfect indicator of wellbeing or quality of life (QOL) and there are several other alternatives, like Bhutan’s GNH Index and new measures developed by the OECD, European Union, Japan and others, under active discussion [5,6]. QOL is a complex interaction of objective and subjective factors and the relationships among them, and with sustainable human wellbeing is an active area of research. Nevertheless, GPI is certainly a better approximation to the objective elements of wellbeing than GDP, a function for which GDP was never designed. 7 8 Bhutan’s NDP Initiative Figure 3: GDP (Gross Domestic Product) and GPI (Genuine Progress Indicator) for the U.S. from 1950 to 2005) Source: [7] In summary, the conclusion that GDP growth no longer contributes to human wellbeing and happiness in the rich developed countries is strongly and consistently supported by a number of quite different kinds of evidence: by the international cross-sectional relations between GDP growth and both life expectancy and happiness; by the time series analyses within countries of the relation between measures of happiness and wellbeing; and by measures such as the GPI over time within countries. 8 A contribution towards the first IEWG meeting 9 Why Now? The significance of further economic growth for wellbeing and happiness is then very different in richer and poorer countries. This fact is part of the essential basis for reaching international agreement on reducing carbon emissions. Figure 4 is just one illustration of its importance. It shows the relation between life expectancy and carbon emisions internationally. The curve is very similar to that shown in Figure 1. It shows that high levels of life expectancy – and so presumably of wellbeing – can be achieved at very much lower levels of carbon emisions than are typical of many rich countries. Even on the basis of existing technology, the conclusion that in many rich countries carbon is being emitted far above the minimum levels needed to attain current levels of wellbeing, is almost unavoidable. This implies that it would be possible to reduce emissions in many rich countries without sacrificing wellbeing. However, more positively, the decoupling of wellbeing from GDP growth may also mean (as we shall discuss later) that it is possible to make further improvments in wellbeing by methods which do not involve growth, such as improving the quality of the social environment. Figure 4: Relation between life expectancy and carbon dioxide emissions. [8] 9 10 Bhutan’s NDP Initiative CLIMATE CHANGE AND NATURAL RESOURCES Clearly any new development paradigm must rest on a re-definition of humanity’s relation to nature. Indeed, sustainability and human survival is obviously the most basic prerequisite for human happiness and the wellbeing of all life forms. And yet, our understanding of how the thinking, policies, and behaviour that characterize our present economic system have severed humanity’s connection with nature and literally threatened the survival of this and countless other species is still emerging. Only relatively recently, with advances in environmental sciences, global remote sensing and monitoring systems, has a more comprehensive assessment of local and global environmental deterioration become possible. The CO2 content of the atmosphere, for example, has risen from 290 ppm to 390 ppm since the late 19th century – a rise of over one-third – and sharply in excess of the 350 ppm that leading scientists say is the safe upper limit for carbon dioxide, beyond which runaway climate change in the form of melting ice caps, sea level rise, and rapidly spreading drought becomes a real danger. [9] Global emissions were at record levels in 2011 and are expected to rise substantially again during 2012. [10] An international goal of limiting the warming of the planet to 2.0oC, established three years ago, is on the verge of becoming unattainable. [10] This is despite what is likely to be only a temporary drop in emissions from the developed countries during the economic turn down. The 2.0oC threshold had been regarded as essential to avoid the most serious damage to natural and human systems. Average global temperatures during each of the last 12 years have been among the highest on record and the last decade as a whole has been the hottest for hundreds of years (UN’s World Meteorological Organization). [11] Sea levels are now rising at a rate of around 3mm a year, mainly due to the expansion of warmer water. [12] In September 2012, scientists at the US National Snow and Ice Data Center in Colorado said the area of Arctic Sea ice was 18 percent below the previous record low set in 2007. [13] Although it is not yet possible to attribute specific extreme weather events to global warming, global warming is predicted to produce more of them, and more are being experienced. Estimates of the number of deaths attributable to global warming therefore vary widely, but several reputable studies – including one led by former U.N. Secretary General Kofi Annan – suggest that they may already be as high as several hundred thousand a year and rising. Evidence is also accumulating of an accelerating loss of vital rain forests, of species extinctions, depletion of ocean fisheries, increasing freshwater shortages in some areas and flooding in others, soil erosion, depletion and pollution of underground aquifers, decreases in quantity and quality of irrigation and drinking water, and growing global pollution of the atmosphere and oceans (even in the polar regions). (See sidebar, Evidence of Environmental Decline.) [1,14] The exponential growth of human population (which recently surpassed 7 billion) is rapidly crowding out other species, even before we have any real understanding of our dependence on species diversity. 10 A contribution towards the first IEWG meeting 11 Why Now? Evidence of Environmental Decline • • • • • • • • • • • • Half of the world’s tropical and temperate forests have disappeared,3 and a high rate of deforestation in the tropics continues.4 About half the wetlands and a third of the mangroves are gone.5 An estimated 90 percent of the large predator fish are gone, and 75 to 80 percent of marine fisheries are now overfished or fished to capacity.6 Twenty percent of the corals are gone, and another 20 percent damaged and threatened.7 Species are disappearing about a thousand times faster than they did on average in the past before humans.8 The planet has not seen such a spasm of extinction in sixty-five million years--not since the dinosaurs disappeared.9 Though decried for decades, the decimation of the planet’s rich endowment of species and ecosystems continues. Recent assessments show a continued, steady overall decline in wild species’ population sizes and in the extent, condition, and connectivity of many habitats with accelerating levels of extinction risk and accelerating or steady declines in the benefits people derive from biodiversity.”17 Over half the agricultural land in drier regions suffers from some degree of deterioration and desertification.10 Persistent toxic chemicals can be found by the dozens in essentially each and every one of us.11 We have pushed atmospheric carbon dioxide up by more than a third. The earth’s ice fields are melting almost everywhere.12 Industrial processes are fixing nitrogen, making it biologically active, at a rate equal to nature’s; one result is the development of more than two hundred dead zones in the oceans due to overfertilization.13 Human actions already consume or destroy each year about 40 percent of nature’s photosynthetic output, leaving too little for other species.14 Freshwater withdrawals doubled globally between 1960 and 2000, and are now over half of accessible runoff.15 The following rivers no longer regularly reach the oceans in the dry season: the Colorado, Yellow, and Nile, among others.16 In just the first five years of this century, the extent of world forests declined by 3 percent.20 Mangrove forests are now being destroyed at four times the rate of other forests.21 A recent assessment by the United Nations Environment Programme (UNEP) concluded that if overfishing trends continue, we will have largely exhausted commercial ocean fisheries in forty years.22 Emissions of greenhouse gases have already committed the planet to a global average warming of 1.4°C over the preindustrial (1880) level. Even if all the emission cuts pledged by governments in Copenhagen in 2009 are met, it is estimated that global average temperatures will rise between 2.5°C and 5°C over the preindustrial level by 2100.23 Estimates vary, but additional global warming of 1.5°C to 2.5°C over today’s level will likely put 20 to 30 percent of species at increased risk of extinction.24 Staying on the course we are on today will likely lead us to:26 Extensive drought.27 Sea level rise of 2–3 feet in this century, and possibly up to five feet. 30,31, 32 Extensive loss of forests, 33,34 Killer heat waves,35,36 Millions of climate refugees37,38More-intense hurricanes and floods. 39 40 , Potential climate tipping points. 41.42 Ocean acidification. 43,44 ,45Potential food, water, and resource shortages..46 ,47 .48 49,50,52 Ongoing energy supply problems 53 and profound strategic challenges 54 Sources: Various, drawn from Speth, J. G., America the Possible: Manifesto for a New Economy (New Haven: Yale University Press, 2012) 11 12 Bhutan’s NDP Initiative Our planet’s ability to provide an accommodating environment for humanity is being challenged by our own activities. The environment—our life-support system—is changing rapidly from the stable Holocene state of the last 12,000 years, during which we developed agriculture, villages, cities, and contemporary civilizations, to an unknown future state of significantly different conditions. We have entered what Paul Crutzen [15] has identified as a new geologic era—the Anthropocene. One important way to address this challenge is to determine “safe boundaries” based on fundamental characteristics of our planet and to operate within them. “Boundaries” here mean specific points related to a global-scale environmental process beyond which humanity should not go. Identifying our planet’s intrinsic, non-negotiable limits is not easy, but recently a team of scientists has specified nine areas that are most in need of well-defined planetary boundaries [1]. These nine areas are (1) climate change, (2) biodiversity loss, (3) excess nitrogen and phosphorus production, (4) stratospheric ozone depletion, (5) ocean acidification, (6) global consumption of freshwater, (7) change in land use for agriculture, (8) air pollution, and (9) chemical pollution (Figure 5). Rockström and colleagues estimate that humanity has already transgressed three of these boundaries: climate change, biodiversity loss, and nitrogen production, with several others rapidly approaching the safe boundary. As well as crossing these boundaries, there are numerous ways in which human activity could trigger natural systems to contribute to further, possibly ‘run-away’ global warming. Locked into the assumptions of our present consumerist and growth-based development Figure 5: Planetary Boundaries [1,2] 12 A contribution towards the first IEWG meeting 13 Why Now? paradigm, remedial policy responses to date have been local, partial, and inadequate. Early discussions and the resulting responses tended to focus on symptoms of environmental damage rather than basic causes, and policy instruments tended to be ad hoc rather than carefully designed for efficiency, fairness, and sustainability. For example, in the 1970s, emphasis centred on end-of-pipe pollution which, while a serious problem, was actually a symptom of the way expanding populations and inefficient technologies fuelled exponential growth of material and energy use, and simultaneously threatened the recuperative powers of the planet’s life-support systems. But as a result of early perceptions of environmental damage, people learned a lot about policies and instruments for attacking pollution. These insights will help in dealing with the more fundamental and intractable environmental issues identified here. The basic environmental problems that can only be solved by a radically new development paradigm, and for which we need truly innovative policies and management instruments, include:§ § § unsustainably large and growing human populations with growing per capita consumption levels that are fast approaching, or already exceed, planetary boundaries; highly entropy-increasing technologies that deplete the earth of its resources and whose unassimilated wastes poison the air, water, and land; and land conversion that destroys habitat, increases soil erosion, and accelerates loss of species diversity, and which, coupled with resource extraction and waste emissions, decreases the ecosystem services that support humanity. These problems are evidence that the material scale of human activity is rapidly approaching, or already exceeds, the safe operating space for humanity on the earth. We believe that, in addressing these problems, a new development paradigm should adopt courses of action based on:§ § § § an understanding that the purpose of development is human happiness and the wellbeing of all life forms rather than the narrow consumerism and limitless growth that characterize the present system; a recognition of the planetary boundaries that the earth places on the type and scale of economic activity; a fair distribution of resources and opportunities among groups not only within the present generation but also between present and future generations, and between humans and other species; and an economically efficient1 allocation of resources that adequately accounts for protecting the stocks of natural and social capital. 1 “Economically efficient” simply means that increasing marginal costs and diminishing marginal benefits from an activity are in balance. Marginal costs and benefits should be measured in terms of contributions to the sustainable welfare of humans and other species. Precise measurement of these contributions is not currently possible. Conventionally, economists emphasize purely monetary costs and benefits, which are determined by willingness to pay, and hence fail to reflect both costs and benefits for those with limited purchasing power and a wide range of environmental, social, and human benefits and costs. Under these conditions, as defined by conventional economists, an efficient allocation is simply one that maximizes 13 14 Bhutan’s NDP Initiative These four principles were presented to and endorsed by the high-level meeting hosted by Bhutan at the United Nations on 2nd April this year, which was attended by 800 distinguished representatives of governments, academia, civil society, business, and major religions. These four principles now also constitute the basis for our present endeavour to elaborate the details of the new development paradigm. The first principle constitutes the goal of development, and the remaining three principles constitute the essential conditions and prerequisites for realization of that goal. Thus the new paradigm acknowledges that homo sapiens’ activities on the planet have now reached such a scale that they are beginning to affect the ecological life-support system itself. The entire concept of economic growth (defined as increasing material production and consumption) must be rethought, especially as a solution to the growing host of interrelated social, economic, and environmental problems. What we need now is real economic and social development (qualitative improvement without growth in resource throughput) and an explicit recognition of the interrelatedness and interdependence of all aspects of life on the planet. We need to move from an economics that ignores this interdependence to one that acknowledges and builds on it. We need to develop an economics that is fundamentally “ecological” in the broadest sense and in its basic view of the problems that our species currently faces. ECONOMIC MODELS – PAST AND FUTURE To take the first and most basic condition of human survival, the evidence now clearly and incontrovertibly demonstrates that our present path is unsustainable. As Paul Raskin said: “Contrary to the conventional wisdom, it is business as usual that is the utopian fantasy; forging a new vision is the pragmatic necessity.” [16] But we do have a choice about how to make the transition and what the new state of the world should be. Sustainability involves environmental, economic, social and political components. The current mainstream model of the economy is based on a number of assumptions about the way the world works, what the economy is, and what the economy is for. These assumptions arose when built capital was the limiting factor, while natural capital was abundant. Then it made apparent sense not to worry about environmental “externalities,” since they could be assumed to be relatively small and ultimately solvable. It appeared to make sense to focus on the growth of the market economy – as measured by GDP – as a primary means to improve human welfare. It made apparent sense, in that context, to think of the economy as comprised only of marketed goods and services and to think of the goal as increasing the amount of these goods and services produced and consumed. But we now live in a world relatively full of humans and their built capital infrastructure. In this new context, we have to re-conceptualize what the economy is and what it is for. We have to first remember that the goal of the economy should be to sustainably improve human wellbeing and quality of life, which in turn can enhance opportunities for human happiness. We need to remember that material consumption and GDP are merely partial means to that end, not ends in themselves. Crucial is a better understanding of what really does contribute to sustainable human wellbeing (SHW) and happiness, including the substantial contributions of natural and social capital and of other factors unrelated to income which are now limiting wellbeing in many countries. We should also recognise, as both ancient wisdom and new psychological research marketed exchange value. While measurements may be fairly precise, this narrow goal is inappropriate to the purpose of the new development paradigm. 14 A contribution towards the first IEWG meeting 15 Why Now? tell us, that too much of a focus on material consumption can actually reduce our wellbeing and happiness. [17] It is also necessary to distinguish between the effect of absolute poverty, in terms of an absence of material necessities, and the psychosocial effects of poverty relative to others. Ultimately we have to create a new vision of what the economy is and what it is for, and a new model of the economy that acknowledges this new “full-world” highly interdependent, context and vision. Some argue that relatively minor adjustments to the current economic model will produce the desired results. For example, they argue that by adequately pricing the depletion of natural capital (e.g. by putting a price on carbon emissions), we can address many of the problems of the current economy while still allowing GDP growth to continue. We call this approach the “green economy” (GE) model. Some of the areas of intervention promoted by GE advocates, such as investing in natural capital, are necessary and we should definitely pursue them. However, we believe they are insufficient to achieve sustainable human wellbeing and happiness. We need a more fundamental change, a change of goals and paradigm as discussed throughout this report. Table 1. Basic characteristics of the current economic model, the green economy model, and the ecological economics model (as a contribution to a new development paradigm) [18] Current Model Economic Green Economy Model Ecological Economics Model Primary policy goal More: Economic growth in the conventional sense, as measured by GDP. The assumption is that growth will ultimately allow the solution of all other problems. More is always better. More but with lower environmental impact: GDP growth decoupled from carbon and from other material and energy impacts. Better: Focus must shift from merely growth to “development” in the real sense of improvement in sustainable human wellbeing and happiness, recognising that growth has significant negative by-products. More is not always better. Primary measure of progress GDP Still GDP, but recognising impacts on natural capital. Index of Sustainable Economic Welfare (ISEW), Genuine Progress Indicator (GPI), GNH Index, or other improved measures of real welfare. Scale/carrying capacity/role environment Not an issue, since markets are assumed to be able to overcome any resource limits via new technology, and substitutes for resources are always Recognised, but assumed to be solvable via decoupling. A primary concern as a determinant of ecological sustainability. Natural capital and ecosystem services are not infinitely substitutable and real limits exist. of 15 16 Bhutan’s NDP Initiative available. Distribution/poverty Given lip service, but relegated to “politics” and a “trickle-down” policy: a rising tide lifts all boats. Recognised as important, assumes greening the economy will reduce poverty via enhanced agriculture and employment in green sectors. A primary concern, since it directly affects quality of life and social capital and since poverty is often exacerbated by growth: a too rapidly rising tide only lifts yachts, while swamping small boats. Economic efficiency/allocation The primary concern, but generally including only marketed goods and services (GDP) and market institutions. Recognised to include natural capital and the need to incorporate the value of natural capital into market incentives. A primary concern, but including both market and nonmarket goods and services, and effects. Emphasis on the need to incorporate the value of natural and social capital to achieve true allocative efficiency. Property rights Emphasis on private property and conventional markets. Recognition of the need for instruments beyond the market. Emphasis on a balance of property rights regimes appropriate to the nature and scale of the system, and a linking of rights with responsibilities. Includes larger role for common-property institutions in addition to private and state property. Role of government Government intervention to be minimized and replaced with private and market institutions. Recognition of the need for government intervention to internalize natural capital. Government, at local, national, regional, and international levels, plays a central role, including new functions as referee, facilitator, and broker in a new suite of common-asset institutions. Laissez-faire capitalism. Recognition of the need for government. Lisbon principles of sustainable governance. Principles governance of market GROWTH IN MATERIAL CONSUMPTION IS UNSUSTAINABLE Historically, human recognition of our impact on the earth has consistently lagged behind the magnitude of the damage we have imposed, thus seriously weakening efforts to control this damage. [19] Even today, technological optimists and others ignore the mounting evidence of global environmental degradation, including climate disruption. Even some serious observers draw comfort from arguments such as the following:§ GDP figures are still increasing throughout much of the world. 16 A contribution towards the first IEWG meeting 17 Why Now? § § § § Life expectancies are still increasing in many nations. Evidence of human-caused climate disruption is still not absolutely definitive. Some claims of environmental damage have been exaggerated. Some previous predictions of environmental catastrophe have not been borne out. Each of these statements is correct. However, not one of them is a reason for complacency. The pervasive uncertainty about the basic nature of our ecological life-support systems and the recognition that complex systems often exhibit rapid, nonlinear changes and threshold effects emphasizes the need for building precautionary minimum safety standards into our policies. [1] Our purpose in this contribution to a new development paradigm is to lay out a new model of development and of the economy based on the four principles outlined above. These principles are fully consonant with the worldview and principles of ecological economics, of Bhutan’s Gross National Happiness development philosophy, and of related “new paradigm” approaches [5,8,9] and include the ideas that:(1) our material economy is embedded in society which is embedded in our ecological lifesupport system, so that we cannot understand or manage our economy without understanding the whole, interconnected system; (2) growth and development are not always linked. True development must be defined in terms of the improvement of sustainable human wellbeing and happiness, not merely in increasing material consumption; and (3) a balance of four basic types of assets (built, human, social, and natural capital) are necessary for sustainable human wellbeing that in turn can provide the basis for enhancing human happiness. (Financial capital is merely a marker for real capital and must be managed as such). World Poverty, Inequality and Ill-health Our discussion above has focussed on the first basic condition of wellbeing and happiness ⎯ namely ecological sustainability, which in turn, as we have seen, requires limits to growth, material consumption, and waste generation. But having acknowledged the finite limits of planetary boundaries and resource availability, a new development paradigm must then address how those limited resources are to be fairly distributed and most efficiently utilized. Again, the contrast in these areas between the assumptions, thinking, policy, and behaviour of the existing economic system and those proposed to characterize a new development paradigm is stark. Our world is still unacceptably divided between the haves and the have-nots. Infant mortality rates are as low as 2 per thousand live births in some of the Scandinavian countries but at least 50 times that in some of the poorer nations of Africa such as the Democratic Republic of Congo, Sierra Leone, or Somalia. [20] We are used to dividing the globe into First World wealthy nations and the poor states of the Third World. But in 1820 (when the data start), rich countries, such as Great Britain and the Netherlands, were only three times as rich as China and India; now the current gap between the real incomes of the richest and poorest countries is over a hundred-fold. [21] The World Bank (WB) and the International Monetary Fund (IMF), both founded at the Bretton Woods conference at the end of World War II, were chartered to speed economic development, 17 18 Bhutan’s NDP Initiative stabilize the world economy, and end poverty. But although we could now rather easily feed, clothe, educate and shelter every living person on earth, we have failed to do so. It was estimated in 1998 that it would cost only US $40 billion to provide basic education, water and sanitation, basic health and nutrition for all, and reproductive health for all women. [22] In the same year, $50 billion were spent just on cigarettes in Europe alone, $35 billion were spent just on business entertainment in Japan, and worldwide military spending came to $780 billion. And yet today, nearly 1.3 billion people, or 22% of the world’s population, remain below the extreme poverty line, with an income of US $1.25 or less a day. [23] In 2000, the global target of halving extreme poverty by 2015 was set as the first Millennium Development Goal and whilst this will likely be achieved five years early (⎯ extreme poverty had fallen from 43% of the world’s population in 1990), almost all of this progress can be accounted for by economic growth in China. [24] However, rising food and fuel prices and financial crises may stall, or even reverse, these positive trends. Even if these price rises can be averted, hundreds of millions of people will remain in poverty, especially in Sub-Saharan Africa and South Asia. As well as those in extreme poverty, almost 2.5 billion people – more than one-third of the world's population – live on less than US $2 a day, and 80 percent live on less than $10 a day. [24] The Food and Agriculture Organization estimated that there were 739 million people without adequate daily food intake in 2008. [23] Over a quarter of all children in developing countries are underweight, close to a third are stunted, and more than 26,000 children die each day, most from poverty-related causes. [25] Conservative estimates are that 863 million people live in slum conditions, 61 million children who should be in primary school are not, 122 million young people cannot read or sign their name, and many millions of women spend hours each day just collecting water. [26] But poverty is only one side of the present equation of “unfair distribution”. At the other extreme is gluttony of excess consumption that is rapidly depleting resources, generating massive wastes, spewing carbon into the atmosphere, and destroying the ecological life support systems that sustain us. Thus: • • • • • 20% of the world’s people presently consume 86% of its goods while the poorest 20% consume just 1.3%; the richest 20% use 58% of all energy and the poorest 20% less than 4%; 20% of people produce 63% of the world’s greenhouse gas emissions while another 20% produce only 2%; 12% of the world’s people use 85% of the world’s water; the richest 20% consume 84% of all paper and have 87% of all vehicles, while the poorest 20% use less than 1% of each. The stress on the planet of the lifestyles of the rich is no less than the stress of poverty on the lives of countless millions of our fellow human beings. Indeed, the two phenomena are closely related. Given the reality that we live on a finite planet with limited resources, we simply cannot alleviate the extreme poverty of 1.3 billion of our fellow global citizens without curbing the excess consumption of more than a billion more. Humanity is already consuming resources and generating waste 60% faster than the planet can regenerate, absorb, and sustain. If everyone were to consume at North American levels, we would need four more planets to provide the necessary resources. Put another and perhaps less palatable way, we presently need a billion people to live in extreme poverty if we are to maintain the lifestyles of the rich without creating even more damage to our planet. In sum, as Mark Mancall writes in his companion piece in this 18 A contribution towards the first IEWG meeting 19 Why Now? volume, poverty alleviation cannot be tackled without also addressing ‘wealth alleviation’ and glaring present inequities. This is why “fair distribution” is one of the four core principles of the new development paradigm. And all these statistics are only the visible tip of the iceberg, the numerated facts of the waste of human life, energy, resources, and talent that is a scourge of catastrophic proportions. Below the water line is the burden of ill health and premature death it causes. The World Health Organization’s Commission on the Social Determinants of Health has called for action to close the world’s health gap in a generation. This means addressing the health of the poor, the social gradient in health within countries, and the striking disparities in population health and access to health care between nations. [27] According to the World Health Organization: “This unequal distribution of health-damaging experiences is not in any sense a ‘natural’ phenomenon but is the result of a toxic combination of poor social policies and programs, unfair economic arrangements, and bad politics…. Certainly, maldistribution of health care – not delivering care to those who most need it – is one of the social determinants of health. But the high burden of illness responsible for appalling premature loss of life arises in large part because of the conditions in which people are born, grow, live, work and age.” — Closing the Gap in a Generation, World Health Organization, 2008 The Commission’s three overarching recommendations are to: improve daily living conditions; tackle the inequitable distribution of power, money and resources; and lastly, to measure and understand the problem and assess the impact of action. Disease prevention and health promotion could prevent a large proportion of the global burden of disease, and there is a compelling economic argument to be made in favour of preventive action. But the Millennium Development Goals for 2015, relating to poverty reduction, universal primary education, gender equality, reductions in child mortality, improving maternal health, and combating HIV/AIDS, malaria and other diseases, seem unlikely to be met in the wake of the global economic crisis. Indeed progress has been slow or has reversed for some MDG targets: vulnerable employment has decreased only slightly; maternal mortality rates are a long way off target; clean and safe water sources are still lacking – particularly in rural areas; world hunger has risen; and the number of people living in slum conditions is rising. According to the United Nations Secretary-General: “Achieving the MDGs by 2015 is challenging but possible. Much depends on the fulfilment of MDG-8—the global partnership for development. The current economic crises besetting much of the developed world must not be allowed to decelerate or reverse the progress that has been made.” — Ban Ki-moon, Secretary General, United Nations, The Millennium Development Goals Report, 2012 An estimate of what it would have cost in 2010 to close the MDG financing gap for every low-income country is U S$143 billion. [28] 19 20 Bhutan’s NDP Initiative INTERNATIONAL T RADE AND G LOBALIZATION To a large extent, current global inequities are maintained and reinforced through the institutions, structures, and regulatory mechanisms of the existing growth-based paradigm, and it will therefore be one of the key tasks of our working group to define appropriate institutions, structures, and regulatory mechanisms for the new development paradigm. At the beginning of this paper we mentioned the increasing economic interdependence of nation states – through international movement of capital, goods, services, technology and communications. Economic globalization has been supported by reduced regulation of international trade, and the removal of tariffs and tax barriers. Supporters of globalization see it as a contribution to raising world GDP; critics point to its impact on rising inequality and social disruption, poverty levels, and environmental degradation. The World Bank (WB) and the International Monetary Fund (IMF) have relied largely on the current economic model as described above and in Table 1. The inability of these institutions and the World Trade Organization (WTO) to fully achieve their original goals of improving lives even in the poorest countries and of stabilizing the global economy has given rise to many critics, who are no longer merely marginalized voices. These critics include former World Bank economists, the Group of 77 (G-77), and, increasingly, the millions of people in developed countries who have taken to the streets in protest. A strong critique of globalization points to the rise in power and autonomy of multinational corporations over nation states and international institutions. Such corporations can even over-ride national laws instituted through democratic processes. As examples, the WTO once ruled that the United States Clean Air Act was a barrier to free trade, and a report from the Economic Policy Institute describes how the North American Free Trade Agreement gives corporations protection from government policies and rights to the privatization of public services, whilst omitting protections for workers, the environment, and the public. [6] Such policies are antithetical to the goal of developing in a way that is sustainable, democratic, and equitable. Too often they reflect the dictates of a few powerful countries and their attendant organizations rather than a broad consensus of agreement. Lending countries and their economists have driven these policies, and borrowing nations have had little say in their implementation. Loans have required cuts in government salaries and privatization of social services. The conditional loans foisted upon many Latin American countries resulted in massive unemployment and devastating economic crises. In short, the execution of policies that flow from the assumptions underlying the present economic system has led to unemployment, falling worker wages, biodiversity loss, environmental degradation, and disintegration of the social fabric. Economist Herman Daly describes how international competition and trade, rather than lowering production costs through efficiency, does so by externalizing costs. [7] Within richer nation states, production costs include workplace safety, minimum wages, welfare, social security, medical and accident insurance, and restrictions on the length of the working day, on child labour and on pollution. With globalization, the shift of production from high to low cost nations that do not have such controls or welfare provisions, lowers the moral and ethical standards of production, increasing exploitation and child labour, weakening human rights, and escalating environmental damage. The costs are compounded by the environmental impact of transport. 20 A contribution towards the first IEWG meeting 21 Why Now? As Daly points out [7]: “…even the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) concedes that it is too much to expect the working class in one country to freely compete with prison labor in another. But then what about child labor? Or sixteen-hour-perday labor? Or uninsured risky labor? What about subsistence-wage labor in overpopulated countries? What about cheap goods subsidized by the uncounted divestment of natural capital?” A new development paradigm must pay serious attention to the contrast between fair trade and free trade, to supporting the globalization of communication and people while opposing the expansion of exploitative corporate power: a coherent and viable alternative is sorely needed. INEQUALITY W ITHIN C OUNTRIES Increasingly, and antithetically to our growing sense of social justice and human rights, we also live in a world of growing within-nation inequality – more than 80 percent of us live in countries where income gaps are widening. Large income gaps between nations drive unsustainable and increasingly problematic international migration; large income gaps within nations foment political instability and conflict. [21] Whilst a growing body of research recognises that the distribution of income is an important determinant of social capital, health and quality of life, the conventional economic development model, while it claims to reduce poverty, has assumed that the best way to do this is through growth in GDP. However, this has not proved to be the case, and attention to distributional issues is now urgent. Increasing inequality of income actually reduces overall societal wellbeing, not just for the poor but across the income spectrum. Wilkinson and Pickett have produced empirical data that show strong links between income inequality in rich countries and a whole range of health and social problems. [3] Countries with larger income differences suffer higher rates of almost all the health and social problems associated with low social status. In effect, inequality strengthens all the ways class and status imprint themselves on us from earliest life onwards. More unequal countries tend to have:• • • • • • • • Lower life expectancy and poorer health Higher homicide rates More mental illness Lower standards of child wellbeing Higher prison populations Greater use of illicit drugs Higher rates of teenage births Lower math and literacy scores and lower social mobility Each of these indicators is anything from twice as common to ten times as common in the more unequal of the developed countries (such as USA, Portugal, UK) as they are among the more equal Scandinavian countries. The differences are so large because, rather than being confined to the poor, the effects of inequality extend to the vast majority of the population. Inequality damages the social fabric of the whole society: the effects are biggest among those lower on the social ladder, but the disadvantages of greater inequality are experienced to a 21 22 Bhutan’s NDP Initiative lesser extent even among the better off. Indeed, countries with bigger income differences between rich and poor seem to suffer a general social dysfunction. They are less cohesive, community life is weaker, and people trust each other less. [3] Since before the French Revolution, people have recognised that inequality is divisive and socially corrosive. Now that we can compare data for more and less equal countries, it is clear that this is profoundly true. Key to the impact of inequality is its effect on the quality of social relations: – in more unequal societies reciprocity and cooperation give way to status competition and status insecurity and to feelings of superiority and inferiority. And because humans are highly social beings, the quality of social relations is a key component of the real quality of life, of SHW, and of human happiness. Indeed, the World Happiness Report shows that differences in just one form of social network (having someone to count on in times of trouble) are as important as differences in GDP per capita in explaining subjective wellbeing differences across 139 countries [44. Table 3.1]. Particularly pertinent in the present context is that Wilkinson and Pickett found that among the rich countries both their Index of Health and Social Problems and the UNICEF Index of Child Wellbeing in Rich Countries were strongly affected by the scale of inequality in a society but, just like the measures of wellbeing discussed earlier, unrelated to GDP per head. AN INTEGRATIVE DEFINITION OF QUALITY OF LIFE AND WELLBEING Just as abundant and growing evidence now points to the failure of the present consumption and growth-based development paradigm, there is equally a substantial and growing body of research on what does actually contribute to human wellbeing, quality of life, and happiness. While there is still much on-going debate, this new science clearly demonstrates the limits of conventional income and consumption in contributing to wellbeing. For example, psychologist Tim Kasser, in his 2003 book The High Price of Materialism [4], points out that people who focus on material consumption as a path to wellbeing are actually less satisfied with their lives and even suffer higher rates of both physical and mental illness than those who do not focus so much on material consumption. Economist Richard Easterlin has shown that wellbeing tends to correlate with health, level of education, and marital status and shows sharply diminishing returns to income beyond a fairly low threshold. He concludes [30] that “…people make decisions assuming that more income, comfort, and positional goods will make them happier, failing to recognise that hedonic adaptation and social comparison will come into play, raise their aspirations to about the same extent as their actual gains, and leave them feeling no happier than before. As a result, most individuals spend a disproportionate amount of their lives working to make money, and sacrifice family life and health, domains in which aspirations remain fairly constant as actual circumstances change, and where the attainment of one’s goals has a more lasting impact on happiness. Hence, a reallocation of time in favor of family life and health would, on average, increase individual happiness.” British economist Richard Layard synthesizes many of these ideas and concludes that current economic policies are not improving wellbeing and happiness, and that “happiness should become the goal of policy, and the progress of national happiness should be measured and analyzed as closely as the growth of GNP.”[31] Economist Robert Frank, in his book Luxury 22 A contribution towards the first IEWG meeting 23 Why Now? Fever [32], also concludes that some nations would be better off—that is, overall national wellbeing would be higher—if we consumed less and spent more time with family and friends, working for our communities, maintaining our physical and mental health, and enjoying nature. There is also substantial and growing evidence that natural systems contribute strongly to human wellbeing. In a paper published in the journal Nature [5], the annual, nonmarket value of the earth’s ecosystem services was estimated to be substantially larger than global GDP. This estimate was admittedly a rough first cut – the paper’s goal was simply to stimulate interest and research on the value of natural capital and ecosystem services. The UN Millennium Ecosystem Assessment [33] was a global update and compendium of ecosystem services and their contributions to human wellbeing. The Economics of Ecosystems and Biodiversity (TEEB) Synthesis report [34] is a more recent contribution to this rapidly expanding field of study and policy. The World Bank has recently announced its Wealth Accounting and Valuation of Ecosystem Services (WAVES) project. The new Intergovernmental Platform on Biodiversity and Ecosystem Services (IPBES) is also in the formation stages (www.ipbes.net). Finally, the recently established Ecosystem Services Partnership (ESP) is a global effort to coordinate the thousands of researchers and practitioners around this topic (www.es-partnership.org). In sum, if we want to assess the “real” economy—all the things that contribute to real, sustainable, human wellbeing and happiness—as opposed to only the “market” economy, we have to include the non-marketed contributions to human wellbeing – from nature, from family, friends, and social relationships at many levels, and from health and education. What does such a more comprehensive, integrative definition of wellbeing, quality of life, and happiness, which constitute the goal and purpose of development in the new development paradigm, look like? The Prime Minister of Bhutan, in his introduction to this volume, has already explained the profound meaning of the term ‘happiness’, as it used in the context of his country’s unique Gross National Happiness development philosophy that fundamentally challenges existing materialist development approaches and that is one of the core inputs into the new development paradigm. Here we delve into some detail into ways of defining wellbeing and quality of life that are seen as providing vital opportunities for the pursuit of happiness. When we evaluate the state of human affairs or propose policies to improve it, we typically proceed from assumptions about the characteristics of a good life to assumptions about how to achieve them. We might suppose, for example, that access to particular material resources is a part of a good life and, therefore, that increasing economic production per-capita is an appropriate goal. But our underlying assumptions are rarely tested and established. We therefore need a more basic approach to defining wellbeing or quality of life (QOL) that, in turn, can guide our efforts to improve human experience. Examinations of QOL often fall under two headings: (1) So-called “objective” indicators of QOL include, for example, indices of living standards, literacy rates, life expectancy, and other data that can be gathered without a subjective evaluation being made by the individual being assessed (although subjective judgments of the researcher are likely to be involved in the process of defining and gathering “objective” measures). Objective indicators may be used singly or in combination to form summary indexes, as in the UN’s Human Development Index (HDI) [36], the Index of Sustainable Economic Welfare, or the Genuine Progress Indicator. To the extent that such measures can be shown to be valid and reliable across assessment contexts (sometimes a difficult task), these 23 24 Bhutan’s NDP Initiative relatively objective measures may help us gather standardized data that are less vulnerable to social comparison and local adaptation. For example, a valid measure should minimize the degree to which QOL is largely a function of comparing one’s life to others’, whether in one’s locale, in the media, or in some other narrowly construed group: In other words, a person’s QOL should not be considered high simply because others in the locale are more miserable. (2) Subjective indicators of QOL typically rely on survey or interview tools to gather respondents’ own assessments of their lived experiences in the form of self-reports of satisfaction, happiness, wellbeing, or some other near-synonym. Rather than presume the importance of various life domains (e.g., life expectancy or material goods), subjective measures can also tap the perceived significance of the domain (or “need”) to the respondent. Diener and Suh provide convincing evidence that subjective indicators are valid measures of what people perceive to be important to their happiness and wellbeing [37]. Nevertheless, there are individuals who cannot provide subjective reports or whose subjective reports may not be as trustworthy in reflecting their true welfare because of the internalization of cultural norms [38], mental illness, lack of information, or other reasons. The best strategy is likely to be an approach to QOL that combines objective and subjective approaches. Our integrative definition of QOL is as follows: QOL is the extent to which objective human needs are fulfilled in relation to personal or group perceptions of subjective wellbeing (Figure 6). Human needs are basic needs for subsistence, reproduction, security, affection, etc. (see Table 1 and below). Subjective wellbeing (SWB) is assessed by individuals’ or groups’ responses to questions about happiness, life satisfaction, utility, or welfare. The relation between specific human needs and perceived satisfaction can be affected by mental capacity, cultural context, information, education, temperament etc. in complex ways. Moreover, the relation between the fulfilment of human needs and overall subjective wellbeing is affected by the varying priority individuals, groups, and cultures give to fulfilling each of the human needs relative to the others. 24 A contribution towards the first IEWG meeting 25 Why Now? Figure 6: Quality of Life (QOL) as the interaction of human needs and the subjective perception of their fulfilment, as mediated by the opportunities available to meet the needs [29] From this ‘new paradigm’ perspective that sees wellbeing and happiness as the goal and purpose of development, the role of policy, therefore, is to create opportunities for human needs to be met, understanding that there are different ways to meet any particular need. Social norms affect both the weights given to various human needs when aggregating them to overall individual or societal assessments of SWB, and also policy decisions about social investments in improving opportunities. Social norms evolve over time due to collective population behaviour [40]. The evolution of social norms can be affected by conscious shared envisioning of preferred states of the world. [41] A convenient way to summarize the opportunities for meeting human needs is to group them into four basic types of assets or “capital” that are necessary to support a genuine humanwellbeing-and-happiness-producing economy: built capital, human capital, social capital, and natural capital. Time is also an independent constraint on the achievement of human needs. We refer to these assets as “capital” in the sense of a stock or accumulation or heritage—a patrimony received from the past and contributing to the welfare of the present and future. (Our use of the term “capital” here is much broader than that associated with capitalism.) These assets, which overlap and interact in complex ways to produce all benefits, are generally defined as follows: 25 26 Bhutan’s NDP Initiative • • • • Natural capital: The natural environment and its biodiversity. Among other things, natural capital is needed to provide ecosystem goods and services. These goods and services are essential to basic human needs such as survival, climate regulation, habitat for other species, water supply, food, fibre, fuel, recreation, cultural amenities, and the raw materials required for all economic production. Social and cultural capital: The web of interpersonal connections, social networks, cultural heritage, traditional knowledge, and trust, and the institutional arrangements, rules, norms, and values that facilitate human interactions and cooperation between people. These contribute to social cohesion; strong, vibrant, and secure communities; and good governance, and help fulfil basic human needs such as participation, affection, and a sense of belonging. Human capital: Human beings and their attributes, including physical and mental health, knowledge, and other capacities that enable people to be productive members of society. This involves the balanced use of time to fulfil basic human needs such as satisfying employment, spirituality, understanding, skills development, creativity, and freedom. Built capital: Buildings, machinery, transportation infrastructure, and all other human artefacts and services that fulfil basic human needs such as shelter, subsistence, mobility, and communications. We recognise that human, social, and produced assets depend entirely on the natural world, and that natural capital is therefore ultimately non-substitutable. Sustainability therefore requires that we live off the interest (sustainable yields) generated by natural capital without depleting the capital itself. To think of nature, the biosphere, the earth, as a form of capital is a way of recognising its importance to the economy, an importance that is often overlooked. Ecological economics understands economies as embedded in cultures and societies, which in turn are embedded in the geo-biosphere. This means that economies rely on the geo-biosphere to provide materials and energy and accommodate all the wastes that economic activity inevitably produces. Natural capital is conceptually similar to built capital (buildings, machines, infrastructure, warehouses) in the sense that it provides goods (e.g., minerals, fossil fuels, timber, water) and services (e.g., pollination, flood control, watershed protection, nutrient cycling) without which economies could not function. In speaking of “natural capital” we are using the term “capital” in its physical, not financial sense, e.g., in the same way that we might speak of a carpenter’s stock of tools or a factory assembly line. A herd of livestock is a capital stock that yields a flow of new members. The physical herd converts grass, water, etc., into new animals. The net increment is income or sustainable yield. The constant herd is capital, reproducing stock. This is a physical stock-flow relation independent of financial arrangements. Indeed the word “capital” derives from “capitas,” ⎯ the number of heads the herdsman has in his livestock. Similar stock-flow relationships hold for forests, fisheries, and other populations. Problems may arise when the physical descriptive term “natural capital” is converted into financial monetary terms, and especially when natural growth rates are converted into monetary yields of different physical stocks, and then compared to the rate of interest on a stock of money in the bank. But reasonable concerns with misuses of the monetization of nature should not keep us from recognising the physical importance of natural capital as a stock that yields desired flows. Nor should such concerns prevent us, as a strategy, from demonstrating the 26 A contribution towards the first IEWG meeting 27 Why Now? extraordinary economic value of nature to human society through demonstrating, for example, what it might cost even partially to replace services currently provided by nature for ‘free’. Natural capital is also very different from built capital in other ways. First of all, built capital is made from natural capital. In other words, nature can exist without built capital, but built capital cannot exist without nature. There is, therefore, an essential hierarchy limiting the extent to which built capital can substitute for natural capital, and they are better thought of as complements than substitutes. Second, built capital represents a ‘fund’ that provides a ‘service’ as, for example, a lathe provides a service when it is used to shape wood. The lathe is not consumed in the process. Natural capital can also be a fund that provides services, such as when a forest provides habitat for forest creatures. But natural capital can also be a stock out of which a supply of material flows. So the forest that provides habitat as a fund-service is also a stock of trees that supplies a flow of wood (the very wood used on the lathe.) Services do not deplete funds, but material flows do deplete stocks, which can however be regenerated if renewable. Since materials flowing from natural capital are usually sold through markets, and ecosystem services often are not, there is an ever-present tendency to overuse natural capital for the material flows it can provide to the detriment of its capacity to provide services. A third and more profound reason for differentiating between natural and built capital is that built capital is simply an object for the benefit of humans. That is why it exists. When built capital no long provides a useful service, it is frequently demolished. Nature, of which humans are an integral part, is much more than that. Nature is populated by countless species, many of whom are sentient, experience a range of emotions, learn, and live in communities of their own making. Reverence for all life, which is a cardinal principle of the new development paradigm, acknowledges that the rest of nature has rights and that a fair distribution of resources needs to acknowledge those rights. Thus, thinking of built capital and natural capital as substitutes is not appropriate, as a common designation of both of them as forms of capital might otherwise suggest. With these caveats in mind, we employ the concept of natural capital in this report cognizant of its limitations. [42] Lest the evidence on the failures of the present growth-based economic system and the case for a new development paradigm presented to this point appear too conceptual or separated from policy and fiscal realities, we now examine two examples of the kinds of practical policy choices and actions that might be taken in the shift to the new paradigm. These examples have been chosen because they illustrate that the financial resources exist for substantial social, human, and natural capital investments that can genuinely enhance wellbeing and happiness. They show that one policy consequence of adopting the new paradigm is the diversion of unproductive (and even destructive) expenditures that reflect detriments to wellbeing and widen inequities to constructive investments that enhance wellbeing. In conventional accounting procedures, such productive investments in common assets are generally labelled as costs, and are often the first items on the chopping block as indebted governments cut social expenditures. But the following two examples clearly demonstrate ample available resources for such social and common asset investments. R EDUCING AND D IVERTING M ILITARY E XPENDITURES 27 28 Bhutan’s NDP Initiative The New Internationalist magazine famously observed that it would cost less than one percent of what the world spends on weapons every year to put every child in the world in school. In 1997, the same magazine observed that “this kind of comparison between military and social spending is […] now somewhat out of fashion.” [30] Perhaps we have become desensitized. And yet the enormous financial cost of the international arms trade and the typically high proportion of national wealth spent on the military must be seen through just such a comparative lens. Reductions in world military expenditure must be part of a new development paradigm because without such reductions, all other goals – sustainability, reducing world poverty, and higher levels of human wellbeing – are that much less attainable. But as well as the cost of diverting money that could be spent on positive social, economic and cultural goals, conflict and the arms trade have a devastating impact on human rights, security, and economic development. “Every gun that is made, every warship launched, every rocket fired signifies, in the final sense, a theft from those who hunger and are not fed, those who are cold and are not clothed. The world in arms is not spending money alone. It is spending the sweat of its laborers, the genius of its scientists, the hopes of its children…” — Former U.S. President, Dwight D. Eisenhower, in a speech on April 16, 1953 The world should take note of examples such as Costa Rica, which abolished its army in 1949, redirecting its military spending to security, education, environmental conservation, and culture. Despite its location in a conflict-prone region and the instability of its neighbours, Costa Rica has had no civil war or been engaged in external conflict since that time. It is one of the most stable, peaceful, and seasoned democracies in the world; ranked among the High Human Development countries by the United Nations [31]; fifth in the world in 2012 by the Environmental Performance Index and top of the Americas [32]; the only country in the world to meet all five criteria for environmental sustainability; and first in both the 2009 and 2012 Happy Planet Index from The New Economics Foundation (NEF) [33]. Costa Rica has a tax on water pollution and produces more than 90% of its electricity through renewable sources; it aims to become carbon neutral by 2021. It has a higher life expectancy than the United States, provides universal health care, and has a literacy rate of 95%. Even a single conflict can massively distort the money available for development and incur unaccountable costs in terms of human life and wellbeing. The invasions of Afghanistan and Iraq cost the USA at least US$1.2 trillion by 2011 and may cost as much as $4 trillion in the long-term – that is without counting the costs of the destruction of capital and infrastructure, loss of economic activity and investment, and loss of life and human capital.[34] World military spending came down after the Cold War ended, but has since risen again, even while public welfare spending is cut. Global military spending now stands at over US $1.6 trillion, a 50 percent increase since 2001.This compares with the total annual cost of the United Nations of around $30 billion each year ⎯ less than 3 percent of the world’s military spending.[35] 28 A contribution towards the first IEWG meeting 29 Why Now? If we are to develop sustainable economic systems, respond adequately to world poverty, and invest adequately in health, education, culture, and other wellbeing enhancing activities, it is clear we must reduce military expenditure. A new development paradigm must consider ways of reducing world military expenditure, including phased annual percentage reductions, as well as a prohibition on the import and export of arms wherever they fuel aggression, support conflict, or undermine democracy. T AX H AVENS AND F INANCIAL R EGULATION A second policy option in the new development paradigm ⎯ both to reduce currently widening inequities and to make more resources available for wellbeing enhancing social investments ⎯ is to prevent the presently high levels of tax avoidance by the wealthy. There is increasing recognition that the tax avoidance of a small group of rich people and rich corporations operating outside the laws, regulations and norms of society, has a massive and adverse international impact on public funding for everything from foreign aid to welfare, increases inequality, and punishes individuals and institutions who comply with both the letter and the spirit of the law. Over and above the assets of corporations, research by the Tax Justice Network suggests that, worldwide, US $32 trillion of assets are held offshore by rich individuals. [36] If this earned even a modest rate of return of 3 percent, then just the tax not paid as a result of this money being held offshore is likely to amount to between US $190-280 billion every year. This is twice the amount spent on overseas development aid by all the OECD countries combined. Beyond rich individuals, the scale of corporate use of tax havens is staggering. Nicholas Shaxson, author of Treasure Islands, reports that more than half of world trade passes through tax havens (at least on paper) and that more than half of all banking assets and a third of foreign direct investment by multinational corporations is channelled offshore. [37] In 2010, small island tax havens had approximately a third of the world’s GDP (US $18 trillion) on their balance sheets. The charity Action Aid reports that 98 of the 100 biggest corporations listed on the London Stock Exchange use tax havens. [38] Tax havens are not only problematic because of tax avoidance. As so-called ‘secrecy jurisdictions’, they also shelter individuals and institutions from scrutiny, from financial regulation, and from criminal law. Following the global financial crash, a meeting of G20 leaders in London in April 2009 concluded that the crisis was kick-started by a lethal mix of byzantine financial products moved through tax havens. [38] Tax havens undermine the economies of both developed and developing countries, particularly in the current era of financial austerity in rich countries. The adverse impact on the ability of governments, particularly those of poorer countries, to raise the taxes they need amounts to theft from the poor and is the strongest argument for regulating tax havens. Focusing on 139 mainly low-to-middle income countries, The Tax Justice Network reports that private elites in those countries had accumulated between US $7.3 and $9.3 trillion of unrecorded offshore wealth by 2010. [36] In that year, the same countries had foreign debts of US $4.08 trillion. However, after subtracting foreign reserves, net foreign debts were actually minus US $2.8 trillion. In other words, when offshore assets are included in the 29 30 Bhutan’s NDP Initiative balance sheet, these ‘indebted’ developing countries are actually net lenders of some US $10.1 to $13.1 trillion to the developed world. But while the assets are held by the wealthy private elites of those countries, the debts are held by the state, and the consequences are suffered by ordinary citizens. While climate change and resource depletion are markers of the ecological failure of the current paradigm, and growing global inequities epitomize its social failure, the grotesque distortions of tax havens typify and symbolize its economic failure. The primary argument used against government action to prevent this tax avoidance is that countries acting alone will harm their national enterprise and economic growth. This is why a new international paradigm is needed to tackle this scourge on development. Preventing tax avoidance is merely one contribution to funding a new global development paradigm that ensures humanity’s survival and enhances human happiness and the wellbeing of all life forms. The organization Share the World’s Resources suggests very practical ways of raising US $2.8 trillion each year to “mitigate the human impacts of climate change” and to “prevent life-threatening deprivation”. [28] This sum includes proceeds from preventing tax avoidance, increasing Official Development Assistance from donor countries to 1 percent of GDP, ending support to ‘agribusiness’, as well as smaller contributions from other sources. The organization estimates that $650 billion could be raised from a financial transactions tax alone, which would have the additional benefit of reducing the volume of destabilizing financial transactions. Another $531 billion could be gained by ending subsidies to the producers and consumers of fossil fuels. If, over a number of years, world military expenditure were reduced by 25 percent, that would yield over $400 billion. In sum, there is no shortage of money in the world and no dearth of very practical means to break from the destructive and inefficient present system, to implement the new development paradigm, and to invest in actions and infrastructure that genuinely enhance sustainability, equity, human happiness, and the wellbeing of all life. It is simply a matter of what that money is used for and how it is allocated. VIABLE ALTERNATIVES EXIST THAT ARE BOTH SUSTAINABLE AND DESIRABLE, BUT THEY REQUIRE A FUNDAMENTAL REDESIGN OF THE ENTIRE “REGIME” A new model of the economy and new development paradigm consistent with our new full-world context will be based clearly on the goal of sustainable human happiness and wellbeing. It will use measures of progress that clearly acknowledge this goal (e.g., GPI or GNH instead of GDP). It will acknowledge the importance of wellbeing and happiness, ecological sustainability, social fairness, and real economic efficiency. Ecological sustainability implies recognising that natural and social capitals are not infinitely substitutable by built and human capital and that real bio-physical limits and planetary boundaries exist to the expansion of the market economy. Climate change is perhaps the most obvious and compelling of these limits. Social fairness implies recognising that the distribution of wealth is an important determinant of social capital and the quality of life. The conventional economic model, while it claims to reduce poverty, has bought into the assumption that the best way to do this is through growth in GDP. This has not proved to be the case, and explicit attention to distribution issues is sorely needed. 30 A contribution towards the first IEWG meeting 31 Why Now? As Robert Frank has argued [39], economic growth beyond a certain point sets up a “positional arms race” that changes the consumption context and forces everyone to consume too much of positional goods (like houses and cars) at the expense of non-marketed, non-positional goods and services from natural and social capital. As we have seen, increasing inequality of income within societies reduces overall societal wellbeing, across the income spectrum. [3] Real economic efficiency implies including all resources that affect sustainable human wellbeing in the allocation and management system. Our current market-focused allocation system excludes most non-marketed natural and social capital assets and services that are huge contributors to human wellbeing. The current economic model ignores this and therefore does not achieve real economic efficiency. A new, sustainable model will measure and include the contributions of natural and social capital in ways that go well beyond the market. This will better approximate real economic efficiency. The new development paradigm will also acknowledge that a complex set of property rights regimes is necessary to adequately manage the full range of resources that contribute to human wellbeing. For example, most natural and social capital assets are part of the commons. Making them private property does not work well. If a resource is ‘non-rival’ (meaning that use by one person does not leave less for others to use), market prices will ration access to those who can afford to pay, even though additional use incurs no additional costs. The clearest example of this is information and almost all the other products of human creativity which can be reproduced digitally. In fact, for information that protects the environment or provides other social benefits—for example, an inexpensive, carbon-free energy technology—additional use actually reduces social costs. The value of such resources is paradoxically maximized at a price of zero (or less). Since the private sector will not provide products for free, the public sector must be responsible for their protection and provision. What is needed, therefore, is a third way to propertize these resources without privatizing them. Several new (and old) common-property-rights systems have been proposed to achieve this goal, including various forms of common-property trusts. The role of government also needs to be reinvented. Beyond government’s present role in regulating and policing the private market economy, local, national, regional, and international governmental structures have a significant role to play in expanding the commons sector, which can propertize and manage non-marketed natural and social capital assets. Government can also help develop new common-ownership models at various levels of scale that are not driven by growth principles, and it can play a planning and coordinating role to help manage a reduced-growth regime. [40] Government also has a major role to play in facilitating societal development of a shared vision of what a sustainable and desirable future would look like. As Tom Prugh and colleagues [41] have argued, strong participatory democratic forms, based on developing a shared vision, are an essential prerequisite to building a sustainable and desirable future that supports human happiness and the wellbeing of all life. One way to look at our goals for the new development paradigm is shown in Figure 7 below. This figure combines planetary boundaries (Figure 5 above) as the “environmental ceiling” with basic human needs as the “social foundation”[42]. This creates an environmentally sustainable and socially desirable and just “doughnut” as the space within which humanity can thrive and realize its true purpose. 31 32 Bhutan’s NDP Initiative Figure 7. A safe and just space for humanity - the sustainable and desirable doughnut [43] 32 A contribution towards the first IEWG meeting 33 Why Now? R EFERENCES 1. Rockström J, Steffen W, Noone K, Persson Å, Chapin FS, et al. (2009) A safe operating space for humanity. Nature 461: 472-475. 2. Steffen W, Rockström J, Costanza R (2011) How defining planetary boundaries can transform our approach to growth. Solutions 2: 59-65. 3. Wilkinson R, Pickett K (2009) The Spirit Level: why more equal societies almost always do better. London: Penguin. 4. Hernández-Murillo R, Martinek CJ (2010) The dismal science tackles happiness data. The Regional Economist. pp. 14-15. 5. Costanza R, Hart M, Posner S, Talberth J (2009) Beyond GDP: The need for new measures of progress. Boston, MA: Frederick S. Pardee Center for the Study of the Longer-Range Future. 6. Stiglitz JE, Sen A, Fitoussi JP (2010) Mismeasuring our lives: Why GDP doesn't add up. New York: The New Press. 7. Talberth J, Cobb C, Slattery N (2007) The Genuine Progress Indicator 2006: A tool for sustainable develoment. Oakland, CA: Redefining Progress. 8. Wilkinson RG, Pickett KE, De Vogli R Equality, sustainability, and quality of life. Bmj 341: c5816. 9. Centre for Climate and Energy Solutions (2012) Atmospheric carbon dioxide & global surface temperature trends. www.c2es.org/facts-figures/trends/co2-temp. 10. Peters G, Andrew R, Boden T, Canadell J, Ciais P, et al. (2012) The challenge to keep global warming below 2 degrees C. Nature Climate Change doi: 10.1038/nclimate1783. 11. International Panel on Climate Change (2007) How are temperatures on earth changing? : www.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/ar4/wg1/en/faq-3-1.html. 12. Merrifield M, Merrifield S, Mitchum G (2009) An anomolous recent acceleration of global sea level rise. Journal of Climate 22: 5772-5781. 13. Center NSaID (2012) Arctic Sea Ice News and Analysis. nsidc.org/arcticseaicenews/. 14. MEA MEA (2005) Ecosystems and Human Well-Being: Synthesis. Island Press. 15. Crutzen PJ (2002) The effects of industrial and agricultural practices on atmospheric chemistry and climate during the Anthropocene. Journal of Environmental Science and Health, Part A 37: 423-424. 16. Raskin P, Banuri T, Gallopin G, Gutman P, Hammond A, et al. (2002) Great transition: The promise of lure of the times ahead. Boston: Stockholm Environment Institute. 17. Kasser T (2002) The high price of materialism: The MIT Press. 18. Costanza R, dArge R, de Groot R, Farber S, Grasso M, et al. (1997) The value of the world's ecosystem services and natural capital. Nature 387: 253-260. 19. Costanza R, Graumlich L, Steffen W, Crumley C, Dearing J, et al. (2007) Sustainability or collapse: What can we learn from integrating the history of humans and the rest of nature? Ambio 36: 522-527. 20. UN Inter-agency Group for Child Mortality Estimation (2011) Levels and trends in child mortality. World Bank. 21. Milanovic B (2011) The haves and the have-nots. New York, N.Y.: Basic Books. 22. United Nations Development Program (1998) The state of human development. Human Development Report. New York: Oxford University Press. pp. 37. 23. World Bank (2012) World Development Indicators. Washington, D.C.: World Bank. 24. Chen S, Ravallion M (2008) The developing world is poorer than we thought, but no less successful in the fight against poverty. Washington, D.C.: World Bank. 25. Unicef (2007) State of the world's children: 2008. New York, N.Y.: United Nations Children's Fund (Unicef). 33 34 Bhutan’s NDP Initiative 26. United Nations (2012) Millennium Development Goals Report 2012. New York, N.Y.: United Nations. 27. Commission on the Social Determinants of Health (2008) Closing the gap in a generation: Health equity through action on the social determinants of health. Final report. Geneva: World Health Organization. 28. Share the World's Resouces (2012) Financing the global sharing economy. London: Sharing the World's Resources. 29. Costanza R, Fisher B, Ali S, Beer C, Bond L, et al. (2007) Quality of life: An approach integrating opportunities, human needs, and subjective well-being. Ecological Economics 61: 267-276. 30. Brazier C (1997) State of the world report. New Internationalist 287. 31. United Nations Development Program (2011) Human Development Report. New York: Oxford University Press. 32. Emerson JW, A. Hsu, M.A. Levy, A. de Sherbinin, V. Mara, D.C. Esty, and M., Jaiteh. (2012) 2012 Environmental Performance Index and Pilot Trend Environmental Performance Index. New Haven, C.T.: Yale Center for Environmental Law and Policy. 33. Abdallah S, Michaelson J, Shah S, Stoll L, Marks N (2012) The Happy Planet Index 2012 report. London: new economics foundation (nef). 34. Stockholm International Peace Research Institute (2012) SIPRI Yearbook 2012. Stockholm: Stockholm International Peace Research Institute. 35. Global Policy Forum (2011) UN Finance. New York, N.Y.: Global Policy Forum. 36. Henry JS (2012) The price of offshore revisited. Tax Justice Network: http://www.taxjustice.net/cms/front_content.php?idcat=148. 37. Shaxson N (2011) Treasure islands: tax havens and the men who stole the world. London: Bodley Head. 38. Action Aid (2011) Addicted to tax havens: The secret life of the FTSE 100. London: ActionAid UK. 39. Frank RH (2007) Falling behind: How rising inequality harms the middle class: University of California Press. 40. Alperovitz G (2011) America beyond capitalism: Reclaiming our wealth, our liberty, and our democracy. New York: Democracy Collaborative Press. 41. Prugh T, Costanza R, Daly HE (2000) The local politics of global sustainability. Washington, DC: Island Press. 42. Williamson T, Dubb S, Alperovitz G (2010) Climate Change, Community Stability and the Next 150 Million Americans. College Park: The Democracy Collaborative at the University of Maryland. 43. Raworth K (2012) A Safe and Just Space for Humanity: Can we live within the doughnut? : Oxfam International. 44. Helliwell, John, Richard Layard, and Jeffrey Sachs, World Happiness Report (2012). http://www.earth.columbia.edu/sitefiles/file/Sachs%20Writing/2012/World%20Happiness %20Report.pdf. 34
© Copyright 2024