Pursuing Universal Design for Lifetime Housing Battling ‘Why Bother?’, the Silver

Pursuing Universal Design for
Lifetime Housing
Battling ‘Why Bother?’, the Silver
Bullet and the Past
Kay Saville-Smith
Inaugural Universal Design Conference
Auckland 24 May 2013
Today I want to address:
• Three barriers to:
 universal design in the housing sector and
 the development of dwellings that work over
the lifetime
• They are
 The ‘why bother’ syndrome
 The silver bullet syndrome
 The past
The ‘why bother’ syndrome:
• Change takes effort
 Along the value chain
 Among consumers
 Among regulators
• To make an effort people need to:
 ‘Get it’
 Know they can do it:
• With a good chance of return
• Without substantial risks of negative, unintended
consequences.
Getting It: Competing Paradigms
• Housing for ordinary people
 Assumes a minority with specialised and unique
accessibility amenity requirements
 This ‘other’ don’t live in ordinary communities,
families or households
 They are immobile across time and place
 Don’t need to be connected
 Ordinary people want a house to impress, be
tasteful and don’t want to pay for things they
will never benefit from
Getting It: Competing Paradigms
• Housing for life treats:
 Ordinary lives as changing and dynamic
 Disability as dynamic
 Accessibility as an amenity providing value to a
diversity of individuals of all ages
 Dwellings as sites of social and economic
interaction not simply shelter for a specified
individual
Special Housing pathway:
• Involves commissioning dwellings for the
‘special’ population.
• Ad hoc adaptation of existing dwellings as
a short, medium and long term strategy.
• Is heavily reliant on forecasting incidence
and prevalence.
• Command and control approach to supply.
• Heavily reliant on public funding.
The Lifetime Housing pathway:
• Application of universal design principles to the
housing stock
• Requires a transformation approach to the
building industry and housing sectors
• Based on market transactions and has the
potential for leveraging private and public
investment streams
• Stock oriented with the goal of reducing future
burden of ad hoc house adaptation
• Not dependent on fine grained forecasting of
disability incidence and prevalence
Special Vs Lifetime Housing
• Both attempt to control cost.
• Special housing pathway by:
 Closely defining the ‘target’ of special housing –
rationing
 Monopsony-based price control
• Lifetime housing by:
 Generating increased demand for solutions
 Addressing cost drivers
 By applying universal design principles
Special Vs Lifetime Housing
• Special Housing approach:
 Easy to implement
 Multiple levers to manage fiscal risk:
• Rationing
• Economies of scale
• Productivity gains
• But typically:
 Fails to meet need
 Generates inefficiencies, rigidities and waste
 Poor value for money
“Predict and Provide”
•
•
•
•
Stifles labour mobility
Generates moral hazard
Forecasting problematic
Ignores dwelling life – 60% have a disabled
person resident over dwelling life
• Fails the quantum test:
 45%-50% mod to severely disabled in
unmodified dwellings
 28%-53% of dwellings housing mod to severely
disabled have been modified
Universal Design for Lifetime
Housing: No Silver Bullet
• Stock transformation is inhibited by:
 Stock inertia
 Vicious circle of blame
 Innovation chasm
• Stock inertia:
 In 2050 most of the stock (68%) will have
been built prior to 2006
 But between now and 2050 we will need around
20,000 stock units added annually
Householders
“We want an accessible
house but there aren’t any
and we can’t afford them.”
Constructors
“We can build houses but the
developers don’t ask for
them.”
Housing Sector
“We would invest in
accessible houses but there
is no demand for them”
Developers
“We would ask for accessible
houses but investors and
householders don’t ask for
them and won’t pay for them”
Cost and Returns
• Cost is often cited as the major barrier
• Costs are minimised by early design
incorporation and range from - <1%-5.5%.
• Build costs need to be calculated in
relation to reductions in:
 In-home support
 Home modification costs – 10%-15%
 Probability of residential care – 12%-30%
 Injury and fall prevention – 14%-41%
Cost and Returns
• Exacerbated by low industry supply of
affordable housing
• Blurred distinctions - cost and price.
• Additional costs frequently represent poor
productivity and limited innovation:
 Capability issues
 Product deficiencies
 Difficulties in managing costs due to:
• Complex value chain
• Asymmetric information
• Low transparency
Anxieties about Doing It
• Building industry is innovative
• Take-up usually occurs when:






Little impact on work processes or design
Driven by manufacturers or product suppliers
Direct marketing to householders
Low impact on consent processes
No hump costs for builders or developers
Easily accommodated within existing price structures.
• Universal design for lifetime housing isn’t like
that.
The Innovation Gap
Levers on Housing
• Five levers commonly used to increase
supply:
 Regulatory and control levers
 Funding, subsidies, grants and lending
 Accreditation programmes
 Planning and procurement initiatives
 Capability development and demonstrations
International Practice & Outcomes
• Marked by:
 Levers restricted largely to the owner occupier
market, some social housing but virtually
absent in the private rental market
 Hesitancy to use mandatory requirements.
• Where mandatory requirements used:
 Low standard of accessibility
 Many loopholes
 Poorly enforced
 Requirements contradictory with other rules
 Founder on poor capability development
Lifetime housing supply best when:
• Part of a wider societal commitment to
universal design beyond the housing sector
• Clear regulatory requirements for:
 building industry
 housing sector
• Compliance costs are low
• Demonstrated and achievable solutions for:
 new builds
 refurbished stock
Supply is stimulated when:
• ‘Gear up’ is encouraged by:
 Opportunities for provision at scale
 Certainty around expectations and phased introduction
of regulatory requirements
 Developing consumer expectation
 Opportunities to reduce systemic costs
• Consumers know lifetime housing, have
appropriate price expectations and the ability
to make informed choices
• Standards are credible, flexible and designed
to a series of step-wise outcomes
Keys to Transformation:
• A consistent, single framework of standards that
operationalise for universal design:
 specified outcome levels (vistability, liveability etc)
 housing stocks (existing and new builds)
• Value cases
• Technical, product and process initiatives
implemented through demonstrations
• Central and local government strategic leadership,
statutory levers and investments
• Giving consumers the power to choose
 New builds
 Existing stock
Some Useful Levers
• Dwelling matching registers identifying
three types of stock:
 Modified housing stock
 Stock built to meet accredited standards, and
 Existing stock assessed according to agreed
standards
• Existing stock assessment and ‘marking’ at
point of sale or rent
Some Useful Levers:
• Triage and rapid management for building
consents approved as Lifemark compliant
at a certain level (for permitted use only)
• Capacity and capability of building consent
officers, designers and developers:
 Approved solutions register
 Training
 Promulgation to designers
 Improved training and curriculum development.
Some Useful Levers
• Targeted product solutions
• Incentives and disincentives:
 Building consent fees/development levies relief
 Recognition through the Accommodation Supplement or
tax systems
• Funding and procurement to establish:
 Better integration across home modifications, retrofit
funding, and repairs and maintenance funding for social
housing and households
 Review opportunities to develop funding stream to
facilitate some initiatives in the rental sector in
particular the management of tenancy bond funds