The Impact of Entrepreneurial Risk Aversion on Wages in General

The Impact of Entrepreneurial Risk Aversion on Wages in General
Equilibrium∗- A Second Proof
Ying Feng¶
UC San Diego
James E Rauch‡
UC San Diego, NBER and CESifo
March 17, 2015
Let the assumptions in KL theorem 1 (existence) and KL theorem 2 (uniqueness) hold, as well as
the assumption in their Lemma (risk aversion increasing in α, not merely non-decreasing). We can
then state and prove the following revised version of KL theorem 41 :
THEOREM 4 (REVISED). An increase in the Arrow-Pratt absolute risk aversion measure r(I, α)
for all α ∈ [0, 1] and for all I lowers the equilibrium wage.
PROOF 2: Consider a transformation f (·) of the Arrow-Pratt absolute risk aversion index for agent
α such that r0 (I, α) = r(I, f (α)) for all income I, where f (·) satisfies f (x) > x and f 0 (x) ≥ 12 .
Thus there is an economy-wide increase in risk aversion: r0 (I, α) > r(I, α) for all I. Then individual
α has a risk attitude indexed by f (α) while the functional forms of L(w, ·) solving
Max Eu(A + g(L, x
˜) − wL, α).
(1)
Eu[A + g(L(w(α), α), x
˜) − w(α)L(w(α), α), α] = u(A + w(α), α).
(2)
L
and w(·) defined by
stay the same, so the new equilibrium is characterized by α
ˆ 0 such that labor market clears,
Zαˆ 0
L(w(f (ˆ
α0 )), f (α)) dα = 1 − α
ˆ0.
(3)
0
Suppose new equilibrium wage is unchanged or larger i.e. w(f (ˆ
α0 )) ≥ w(α
ˆ ), then f (ˆ
α0 ) ≤ α
ˆ follows
since the certainty equivalent wage w(α) is continuous and monotonically decreasing. Recall L is
Rαˆ
ˆ ), α) dα is increasing
a decreasing function of w when holding α fixed, so the integration L(w(α
0
∗
Our thanks to Alexis Akira Toda and Richard Kihlstrom for helpful comments. We are responsible for any
errors.
¶
[email protected][email protected] (econweb.ucsd.edu/ jrauch/ ).
1
Note we are not assuming neither “g(L, x) and gL (L, x) are both monotonically increasing (or decreasing) functions of x”, assumption iii stated in KL theorem 4 above.
2
A rich set of transformations of risk aversion are consistent with this assumption. The easiest example can be
f (α) = 2α.
1
in α
ˆ . Therefore,
Rαˆ
L(w(ˆ
α), α) dα − (1 − α
ˆ ) is a continuous and increasing function of α
ˆ . Recall
0
Rαˆ
L(w(ˆ
α), α) dα = 1 − α
ˆ at the old equilibrium and f (ˆ
α0 ) ≤ α
ˆ , so we get
0
fZ(α
ˆ0 )
L(w(f (ˆ
α0 )), α) dα ≤ 1 − f (ˆ
α0 ).
(4)
0
Therefore,
Zαˆ 0
L(w(f (ˆ
α0 )), f (α)) dα
0
fZ(α
ˆ0 )
L(w(f (ˆ
α0 )), f (α)) dα
<
0
fZ(α
ˆ0 )
L(w(f (ˆ
α0 )), f (α)) df (α)
≤
0
Zαˆ 0
=
L(w(f (ˆ
α0 )), α) dα
0
fZ(α
ˆ0 )
L(w(f (ˆ
α0 )), α) dα
<
0
≤ 1 − f (ˆ
α0 )
<1−α
ˆ0
, where the first “≤” follows by assumption f 0 (x) ≥ 1, three “<” follow from f (x) > x and “=” is
only a change of integration variable. This inequality shows that if the new equilibrium wage is not
smaller, there will be an excess supply of labor, which is a contradiction. So the new equilibrium
wage must decline. Q.E.D.
References
[1] Kihlstrom, Richard E., and Jean-Jacques Laffont.“A general equilibrium entrepreneurial theory of firm formation based on risk aversion.”The Journal of Political Economy (1979): 719748.
2