Trust as a Strategy to Cope with Uncertainty in Delegated Portfolio

Running head: TRUST AS COPING
Trust as a Strategy to Cope with Uncertainty in Delegated Portfolio
Management
Anders Carlander1 & Lars-Olof Johansson2
1
Department of Psychology and Centre for Finance, School of Business, Economics,
and Law, University of Gothenburg, Göteborg, Sweden
2
Department of Psychology. University of Gothenburg, Göteborg, Sweden
Corresponding author:
Anders Carlander, Department of Psychology, University of Gothenburg, P.O. Box
500, SE-40530, Göteborg, Sweden. Email: [email protected]
TRUST AS COPING
2
Abstract
This paper investigates a savings choice scenario from a private investor perspective. In a
web-based experiment, participants chose to either construct a stock portfolio individually,
delegate to a financial adviser or to choose the equivalent of an index fund, all based on realtime stock information. Participants (N = 199) completed an inventory containing measures
of trust in financial advisers, financial literacy, and subjective uncertainty. The data was
analyzed with analysis of variance (ANOVA) and multinomial logistic regression. As
hypothesized, trust increases the probability of choosing the financial adviser whereas
financial literacy increases the probability of choosing to invest individually or the index
fund. And as further hypothesized, the results showed that the choice to delegate to a
financial adviser reduces subjective uncertainty. The results suggest that trust is a way of
coping with uncertainty.
Keywords: delegated portfolio management; trust; financial literacy; uncertainty
TRUST AS COPING
3
Trust is thought to arise as a response to uncertainty in situations where cooperation
between people is needed but the relevant information is asymmetrically distributed. Trust
has been defined as “a state involving confident positive expectations about another’s
motives with respect to oneself in situations entailing risk” (Boon & Holmes, 1991, p. 194).
Trust can thus be understood as a subjective prediction model of another person’s future
actions. It is a solution to a principal agent problem referring to situations where the decisions
of one individual, the agent, have an impact on another individual, the principal. Since such
situations are thought to originate from a contractual or incentivized obligation where the
agent is acting on behalf of the principal, various problems can occur because of different
goals or preferences between the agent and principal (see Eisenhardt, 1989 and Shapiro,
2005). Because of this asymmetry, informed people can take advantage of less informed
people, something which is believed to disrupt the efficient market mechanism and lead to a
disproportionate amount of advantage-taking people. The market will thus suffer from an
adverse selection problem (Akerlof, 1970).
Two solutions have been proposed to address the problems associated with adverse
selection. Signaling (Spence, 1973), which means that agents chooses to signal in some way
that they will not act opportunistically, and screening (Stiglitz, 1975), which means that
principals make use of an opportunity to retrieve more information about agents (for a
comprehensive overview on screening and signaling, see Riley, 2001). Information
asymmetries may in other words lead to different ways of trying to reach information
equilibrium or to simply retrieve more information. In finance, the efficient market
hypothesis (Malkiel, 2003) dictates that all relevant information is already known and is
reflected in the current share price. An implication is that there rarely exists any additional
information to retrieve for a specific investor. In line with Dia (2011) we propose that
peoples’ financial decision making under uncertainty may be based on the perceived
TRUST AS COPING
4
knowledge of other agents when own information or knowledge is lacking. This means that
trust in an agent would act as a substitute for information, thus reducing the perceived
information asymmetry.
In this paper we investigate a savings choice scenario from a private investor
perspective. In a web-based experiment participants could choose to construct a stock
portfolio individually, delegate to a financial adviser, or to choose an index fund. The choices
were made based on real-time stock information. The choice is assumed to be part of a
psychological process where relevant information is substituted with trust in a financial
adviser, and financial knowledge with a belief in one’s self-assessed financial literacy.
Trust
Since most economic actions, including agency theory, reside within a social context
(Granovetter, 1985) people are often more socially oriented than self-interested and rational
(Fehr & Gächter, 2000), which may stem from a cost-benefit analysis influencing affect,
cognition and behavior accordingly (for an overview see Kamleitner & Hoelzl, 2009). For
example, people evaluate risk cognitively but they respond to it emotionally, and it is usually
the emotional reaction that results in a specific behavior (Loewenstein, Weber, Hsee &
Welch, 2001). In finance several deviations from rational decision making have been
observed (see for example Shefrin, 2007). One of the most reported is the disposition effect
which refers to a tendency to sell commodities that increase in value too soon while holding
on to commodities that have decreased in value for too long (Shefrin & Statman, 1985). This
effect seems to apply mainly to commodities that are non-delegated. Investors therefore show
this tendency when buying and selling shares, but not to the same extent when buying and
selling mutual funds. Instead, a reversed disposition effect has been observed when trading
with mutual funds that are delegated to a fund manager (Chang, Solomon & Westerfield,
2014; Kaustia, 2010). There are many potential explanations for this reversed effect but it has
TRUST AS COPING
5
been suggested that because of the shift in responsibility towards another person (the agent),
investors (principals) can act more rationally since they do not have to worry about
impediments to their self-esteem caused by erroneous investment decisions (Nofsinger,
2007).
Agency theory is often based on an incomplete contract consisting of both calculable
and incalculable factors that depend on trust (see e.g. Möllering, 2014). Trust can hence be
seen as a heuristic or shortcut that begins where rational prediction ends (Lewis & Weigert,
1985). When solutions to the information asymmetries are unavailable, or come at a too high
cost, people must act without having complete and perfect information. It has consistently
been found that people respond to higher levels of uncertainty with a raised demand for
information (Dzielinski, 2012), and increased levels of information stemming from higher
levels of control have been reported to increase trust (Emsley & Kidon, 2007). In this vein,
trust has been proposed to function as a supplement to control (Das & Teng, 1998) and one
way to exercise control is through the use of contracts. Under the restrictions of a binding
contract trust is found to be high, such that when the contract is removed, trust drops
significantly but considerably less under a non-binding contract (Malhotra & Murnighan,
2002).
Another application of the trust-control relation is that stock market development is
determined by trust in terms of both stock market depth and liquidity, especially in countries
with weak regulations and a lower formal institutional quality (Ng, Ibrahim & Mirakhor,
2014). One explanation for the positive trust effect on the stock market is that trust seems to
reduce investors’ risk perceptions, something which may allow fund managers to charge a
trust premium (Gennaioli, Shleifer & Vishny, 2015).
All common definitions of trust are concerned with risk or uncertainty since trusting is
a risky choice - without risk or uncertainty trust would not be needed. Willingness to trust is
TRUST AS COPING
hence the acceptance of risk (Mayer, Davis & Schoorman, 1995) and it has been suggested
that trust and risk are mirror images of the same appraisal where trust is the optimistic and
risk is the pessimistic evaluation (Das & Teng, 2004). The relationship between trust and risk
seems furthermore to be stronger when levels of self-reported knowledge are low (Siegrist &
Cvetkovich, 2000; Viklund, 2003).
The tendency to trust expertise is evident in many different domains. In medicine, for
example, people trust doctors to a higher degree if they are dressed in a white coat instead of
casual clothing since the former presumably signals expertise (Brase & Richmond, 2004). In
investment games, people show behavior consistent with the hot hand bias choosing
“experts” in games of pure chance (Huber, Kirchler & Stöckl, 2010), which is explained by
the mere label expert. Another example of trust in expertise is that the Morningstar fund
rating positively affects fund investments irrespectively of underlying fundamentals (Del
Guercio & Tkac, 2008).
It should however be acknowledged that the general public does not always trust
experts or agree with their opinions. If experts are trusted or not seem to depend on, for
example, the level of uncertainty, whether experts agree, and to which extent theoretical
simulations or lab experiments seem generalizable (Sjöberg, 1999). Similarly, when
knowledge is lacking a tendency to believe that one has control over uncontrollable
situations, referred to as the illusion of control (Langer, 1975), can occur. This illusion can
yet to some degree be seen as an adaptive and positive part of human reasoning (Taylor &
Brown, 1988). But illusion of control can also have serious negative consequences in the
financial market if individual traders start to think that they are in control when they in fact
are not. Illusion of control has, for example, been reported to be inversely related to several
measures of financial competence (Fenton-O’Creevy, Nicholson, Soane & Willman, 2003).
6
TRUST AS COPING
Financial literacy
Financial literacy is strongly related to a range of different financial behaviors. For
example, financial literacy predicts higher stock market participation (van Rooij, Lusardi &
Alessie, 2011), more advantageous investment strategies, and fewer mistakes (Hilgert,
Hogarth & Beverly, 2003). One recommended investment strategy is to diversify an asset
portfolio, and this is a more common strategy by investors with higher financial literacy
(Calvet et al., 2009; Graham, Harvey & Huang, 2009). The pattern of under-diversification
by investors with lower financial literacy seems to be robust when controlling for a number
of alternative explanations such as education, age, risk-taking or wealth (von Gaudecker,
2013). It has also been shown that people with lower financial literacy delegate portfolio
choice more often or avoid investing in risky assets altogether (Calcagno & Monticone,
2015). At the same time, financial advice has been suggested to be a complement rather than
a substitute to financial literacy (Collins, 2012).
The most common method of assessing financial literacy is through the number of
correct answers on financial knowledge tests, using a set of three or five financial literacy
questions, referred to as the “Big Three” or the “Big Five”. It is also common to use
individuals’ confidence in their financial knowledge through self-reports (for an overview,
see Hastings, Madrian & Skimmyhorn, 2013). Although less common, it is possible to
measure financial literacy through an outcome-based approach assessing peoples’ level of
financial sophistication by identifying their behavior in the stock market such as for instance
under-diversification or the disposition effect (Calvet, Campbell & Sodini, 2009). Selfreported financial literacy is usually positively correlated with actual knowledge but to an
even stronger degree with actual behavior (Parker, Bruine de Bruin, Yoong & Willis, 2012).
This indicates that financial literacy is consistent across methods of measurement and that
behavior is affected by the level of knowledge that people think that they have, which likely
7
TRUST AS COPING
8
reflects a biased view of actual financial knowledge.
Aims, hypotheses, and expectations
The tenet of the present study is that uncertainty will occur in situations where there is
an asymmetry in information between at least two people. A specific case is when people
make savings investments in the stock market, either directly or through bundled investment
products. The approach to solving this asymmetry is to obtain more information. Since
information is costly or can be illegal to act upon, which is the case with insider information
in the stock market, people are likely to rely on other ways to retrieve information and thus
reduce uncertainty. One way to handle uncertainty is to delegate the decision making to
another person and thereby substitute lack of information or knowledge with the belief in
someone else’s financial knowledge (Dia, 2011). We thus hypothesize (first hypothesis) that a
higher level of uncertainty increases the probability of delegating the responsibility to a
financial adviser compared to investing individually or choosing an index fund. Trust will
likely result in a belief that the risky choice is less risky (Gennaioli et al., 2015) and
subjective uncertainty is therefore hypothesized (second hypothesis) to be lower for those
who choose to delegate to the financial adviser. Moreover, and in connection to both these
hypotheses, trust in financial advisers (or “experts”, Huber et al., 2010) will positively affect
the choice to delegate (Carlander et al., 2013), which is the basis for our third hypothesis.
Lastly, another way to handle uncertainty is through the belief that one possesses more
information or control than justified. Our fourth hypothesis is therefore that financial literacy
will be positively related to both choices of investing individually and index fund since
higher financial literacy has been reported to be related to a higher degree of stock market
participation and with making more advantageous financial decisions (Hilgert et al.,2003; van
Rooij et al., 2011).
The first hypothesis will be analyzed with a chi square test for differences of how
TRUST AS COPING
9
many of the participants choose to delegate or not. The second hypothesis will be analyzed
with an analysis of variance (ANOVA) investigating to what degree the subjective
uncertainty measure differs depending on whether the participant chose to delegate to the
financial adviser, invest individually or the index fund. Finally, hypothesis three and four will
be analyzed with multinomial logistic regression that will allow us to show the individual
effects of trust and financial literacy on the three-way choice as a dependent variable.
Hypotheses
I. The financial adviser alternative will be chosen more frequently in a high risk scenario,
because
II. The perception of uncertainty will be lower if an adviser takes responsibility for the
construction of the stock portfolio, and for this reason it is highly likely that
III. Trust will be positively related to the choice of financial adviser, while
IV. Financial literacy will be positively related to both choices of investing individually and
index fund
In addition to the above formalized hypotheses several patterns are expected.
Mirroring Hypothesis III, we expect that trust will be negatively related to the choices of
investing individually and the index fund. Financial literacy is furthermore expected to be
negatively related to the choice of financial adviser. Self-reported financial literacy is likely
to have a stronger relation to the choice of investing individually compared to actual financial
literacy. A person who believes that he or she is proficient in stock trading would thus rather
act on such a belief than on actual knowledge. It is also more likely that actual financial
literacy will show a stronger effect on the choice of index fund compared to self-reported
financial literacy. A reason for this is that nearly all empirical research shows that investors
are not likely to beat the market in the long run, i.e. the index.
The included subjective uncertainty measure is expected to be positively correlated
TRUST AS COPING
10
with the number of additional sources used to gather information before the choice, since
more information can be an expression of a desire to reduce uncertainty (Dzielinski, 2012).
The risk manipulation is thus expected to affect the subjective uncertainty measure, and since
higher uncertainty is associated with need for more information, the number of sources
should be higher in the high risk group. Finally, since trust has been suggested to be an
expression of effort aversion (Kramer, 2006), we included a question measuring effort.
Method
Participants and Research Design
One hundred and ninety-nine participants from a national U.S survey panel
(Qualtrics) provided usable data from a total of 4,191 invited. Fifty-nine point eight percent
(59.8 %) were female and the mean age for men and women respectively were 47.6 and 44.3
years old. The highest degree or level of school completed was 32.7 % high school graduates,
27.7 % trade/technical/vocational/associate degree, whereas the remaining 39.6 % of the
participants had a bachelor’s degree or higher.
The experiment was constructed with a nominal 3(choice: invest vs. delegate vs.
index) outcome variable with two categorical predictor variables; risk (high vs. low) and
order (ab vs. ba). The difference between the task orders was whether each participant
completed the trust ratings (a) or the investment task (b) first. Trust and financial literacy was
regarded as covariates in the analysis of nominal choice.
Procedure
The participants were recruited to a study about financial decision making. Two
mandatory screening questions were introduced and the requirement to partake in the study
was that at least one of the questions “I frequently make, or will within the next six months,
make investment decisions about stocks” and “I have made and intend to make investment
decisions in the foreseeable future about mutual funds, bonds or other interest bearing
TRUST AS COPING
11
securities issued by a corporation or financial institution” was answered affirmatively.
After having answered questions of gender, age, and education level, each participant
was randomly assigned to one of four conditions of which two contained a manipulation of
high risk and the other two a low risk. Within each risk manipulation the investment task was
placed in one of two different orders, either before or after the trust measure. After
completion of the trust measure and investment task followed measures of financial literacy,
subjective uncertainty associated with the investment task, need for information (i.e.,
additional sources such as web pages), and effort (how taxing the task was perceived to be).
In the high-risk condition participants received a predefined list of ten companies selected
from the S&P 600 small cap segment, whereas in the low-risk condition participants were
presented with a similar list but with companies from the S&P 100 large cap segment. In each
condition participants were informed of the general properties pertaining to each segment, for
example that the variation in share prices in the large cap segment is generally lower
compared to the small cap list. This means that the difference in volatility and hence risk
between the two lists was the risk manipulation such that the risk was higher in the small cap
list compared to the large cap list. The participants were presented with portfolio weight,
volatility, beta and max drawdown the current year for each single share and for the portfolio
of the ten shares. Each participant was presented with three options for an imagined
investment of $10,000 USD: (1) they could construct a stock portfolio individually or; (2)
delegate the portfolio construction to a financial adviser or; (3) choose a value-weighted
index fund consisting of the ten shares in the list. Costs pertaining to each option were
presented with the aim of being close to a real-world scenario. Each share buy order would
cost USD 10 whereas the financial adviser would charge an annual management fee of 1.5%
and the index fund would cost 0.2% of the total assets under management annually. After
having choosing financial adviser or index fund the participant moved to the next series of
TRUST AS COPING
12
questions but investing individually led to a new page containing ten real-time stock widgets
provided by TradingView1. Each participant could then evaluate the real-time movements in
each share price together with other relevant financial data. In addition, the participants were
encouraged to search for more information from other web pages to complete the task.
Measures
The questionnaire part consisted of six trust statements where three items measured
competence and the other three measured benevolence. The items were taken from Carlander
et al., (2013) with the minor modification of changing the object of one’s trust to “financial
advisers” instead of “banks and fund managers”.
Self-reported financial literacy was measured through the question “On a scale
from 1 to 7, where 1 means very low and 7 means very high, how would you assess your
overall financial knowledge?” Five additional questions pertaining to financial literacy were
included, three of which were taken from the 2004 Health and Retirement Study (HRS) 2 and
the other two from the 2009 National Financial Capability Study 3. Together, the five
questions make up the “big five” financial literacy inventory. There was also a measure of the
subjective uncertainty for the task of investing individually that was phrased as “How
uncertain did you feel about choosing to invest in the shares yourself?” ranging from
“completely certain” to “completely uncertain” on a 7-point rating scale.
In addition, two different 7-point rating-scale measures for the manipulation check
items were included. One statement pertaining to the need for information was formulated as
“How many different sources/sites other than the stock widgets did you use in order to make
up your mind about what shares to choose?” We also included a statement to assess how
much effort each respondent felt that the task involved. This item was formulated as “It was
demanding to choose between investing yourself, the financial adviser, and the index fund.”
1
https://www.tradingview.com/widget/
2004 U.S. Health and Retirement Survey: http://hrsonline.isr.umich.edu/index.php?p=data
3
2009 U.S. National Financial Capability Study: http://www.finrafoundation.org/programs/p123306
2
TRUST AS COPING
13
Pre-analysis
An independent samples t-test showed no significant difference in the subjective
uncertainty measure between the high (M = 3.52, SD = 1.79) and the low (M = 3.47, SD =
1.71) risk group. Neither did the number of additional sources differ significantly between the
high (M = 1.45, SD = 2.10) and the low (M = 1.72, SD = 3.4) risk group. A significant
positive correlation was however detected between subjective uncertainty and the number of
additional sources used for the task r(196) = .17, p <.05.
The two theoretical components of trust (competence and benevolence) were
correlated r(197) = .74, p < .001 and an initial principal component analysis suggested that
the statements from both components comprised of one single factor accounting for 69.2% of
the variance. Competence and benevolence were for this reason merged into a single trust
component in the main analysis. There was no evidence of effort aversion or any effects of
order, i.e. whether participants were presented with the trust inventory or the task choice first.
Results
Hypothesis I
A total of 54.8 % chose the financial adviser compared to investing individually (21.1
%) or the index fund (24.1%). The choice was not significantly affected by the risk
manipulation χ2(2) = .047, p = .982 since there was an almost equal number of participants
choosing the financial adviser in the high risk (n = 54) compared to the low risk (n = 55)
condition. Descriptive data of all variables across the three groups by choice are presented in
Table 1.
TRUST AS COPING
14
Table 1. Means and standard deviations of competence, benevolence, subjective uncertainty,
financial literacy (self-report and actual based on the “big five”), effort (cognitive effort of
the investment task) and the number of additional sources each participant used in order to
make the decision.
Competence
Benevolence
Subjective uncertainty
Financial literacy (self-report)
Financial literacy (actual)
Effort
Sources
Invest individually
M
SD
n
4.56 1.32
42
4.09 1.58
42
4.36 1.82
42
4.69 1.33
42
3.50 1.49
42
4.17 1.95
42
1.24 1.62
42
Financial adviser
M
SD
n
5.28 1.11 109
5.32 1.20 109
3.16 1.75 109
3.90 1.50 109
2.76 1.35 109
4.28 1.79 109
1.98 3.54 109
Index fund
M
SD
n
4.81 .93
48
4.72 1.12
48
3.50 1.40
48
4.27 1.01
48
3.60 1.30
48
3.60 1.65
48
1.02 1.36
48
Hypothesis II
In a one-way ANOVA with the investment choice (invest vs. delegate vs. index) as a
between-groups factor, there was a significant difference on the subjective uncertainty
ratings, F(2, 196) = 7.656, p = .001. A Bonferroni post-hoc test at p <.001 revealed that
choosing the financial adviser resulted in a significantly lower estimate of subjective
uncertainty (M = 3.16, SD 1.75) compared to investing individually (M = 4.36, SD = 1.82).
Hypotheses III & IV
In order to analyze which factors influence the choice between investing individually,
financial adviser and index fund, a multinomial logistic regression was conducted. The results
are presented in Table 2 where the choice of financial adviser is the comparison group. Trust
reduces the probability of choosing to invest individually while financial literacy (both selfreported and actual but self-reported to a higher degree) increases the probability of investing
individually compared to the financial adviser choice. A similar pattern emerges for the
choice of index fund where trust reduces the probability of choosing an index fund and
financial literacy (both self-reported and actual but actual to a higher degree) increases the
probability of choosing the index fund compared to the financial adviser.
TRUST AS COPING
15
Table 2. Results from the multinomial logistic regression presenting coefficients (B), standard
errors (SE), relative risk ratios (RRR) together with a 95% confidence interval.
B (SE)
Invest individually
Intercept
Trust
Subjective uncertainty
Financial literacy (self)
Financial literacy (actual)
Effort
Sources
Financial adviser
Index fund
Intercept
Trust
Subjective uncertainty
Financial literacy (self)
Financial literacy (actual)
Effort
Sources
Lower
-.82 (1.25)
.04
***
-1.01 (.22)
.24
.32 (.17)
1.00
.52 (.23)*
1.07
.40 (.16)*
1.10
.08 (.13)
.83
-.20 (12)
.64
Base outcome comparison
-.07 (1.22)
-.54 (.19)*
-.02 (.15)
.41 (.19)*
.42 (.15)*
-.20 (.11)
-.23 (.13)
.09
.38
.74
1.03
1.14
.66
.62
95% CI for RRR
RRR
Upper
.44
.37
1.38
1.68
1.49
1.08
.82
5.09
.56
1.92
2.63
2.04
1.41
1.06
1.06
.58
.98
1.50
1.53
.82
.80
11.51
.84
1.31
2.20
2.04
1.02
1.04
Note: R2 =.30 (Cox & Snell), .35 (Nagelkerke). Model χ2(12) = 71.47, p <.001. * p <.05, *** p <.001
Discussion
This study investigates reasons for choosing between different financial products from
a private investor perspective. Hypothesis I was not confirmed since choosing from a list of
shares with a relative higher risk did not result in a higher propensity to delegate the
responsibility of constructing a stock portfolio to a financial adviser. However, the results
showed that those who chose to delegate to a financial adviser rated their subjective
uncertainty lower which confirms Hypothesis II. Hypothesis III was supported in that the
probability of choosing to delegate increases with trust in financial advisers. Hypothesis IV
was also confirmed in that financial literacy increased both the probability of choosing to
invest individually and the probability of choosing the index fund alternative.
We further report the additional finding that trust was negatively related to invest
individually and index fund, whereas financial literacy was negatively related to delegation to
the financial adviser. In addition, self-reported financial literacy showed a stronger influence
TRUST AS COPING
16
on investing individually than actual financial literacy did, whereas this pattern was reversed
for the index fund alternative.
In line with previous studies we report that trust has an impact on people´s financial
decision making (Carlander et al., 2013; Del Guercio & Tkac, 2008; Huber et al., 2010; Ng et
al., 2014). A reason for this may be that trust reduces subjective uncertainty (Gennaioli et al,
2015). Consistent with this we report that choosing to delegate to a financial adviser reduces
subjective uncertainty. This is in line with previous studies reporting that higher levels of
uncertainty is related to higher levels of trust (Das & Teng, 2004) and it has been suggested
that trust is a coping response in order to handle potential threats pertaining to high
uncertainty (Wilson & Darke, 2012). This may imply that trust and risk are inversely related
over time such that trust is a response to risk.
Subjective risk assessments are based on knowledge, but in the absence of own
knowledge trust in knowledgeable people can act as a substitute when assessing risks
(Siegrist & Cvetkovich, 2000; Viklund, 2003). This pattern seems to be present when making
savings choices, since knowledge and trust has been reported to be complementary
(Carlander et al., 2013). Since information usually is asymmetric and scarce in financial
decision making, decisions are, especially under delegation, often based on a subjective belief
in other peoples’ knowledge as a substitute for own knowledge (Dia, 2011). In the present
study it is shown that financial literacy increases the probability of choosing to invest
individually or in the index fund, similar to studies showing a higher involvement in the
financial market by for example investing in shares (van Rooij et al., 2011). A lower level of
financial literacy is related to delegation to advisers (Calcagno & Monticone, 2015) and
making more common financial mistakes (von Gaudecker, 2013), something which may or
may not occur because of a higher level of illusion of control (Fenton-O’Creevy et al., 2003).
We report, in support of these findings, that a lower level of financial literacy increases the
TRUST AS COPING
17
probability of choosing the financial adviser.
The decision making process described in the present study hence seems to follow a
certain pattern since participants seem motivated to eliminate a lack of information and
reduce a sense of uncertainty. Choosing to delegate the responsibility to the financial adviser
is evidently affected both by an actual and a subjective lack of knowledge as measured by
financial literacy in the present study. This choice puts the adviser’s perceived knowledge at
the focal point, transforming the knowledge or risk assessment to a trust assessment (Das &
Teng, 2004). Trust may in our view under some circumstances act as an illusion of control by
proxy (Wohl & Enzle, 2009), and in this particular case the proxy is the financial adviser.
Lastly, choosing to invest in the index fund may be the “correct” choice according to both
theory and practice. It is therefore not surprising that actual financial literacy is showing a
stronger effect than self-reported financial literacy in this choice group.
An obvious limitation in the present study is that the participants did not handle real,
their own, or a large amount of money. It has been reported that the effects of performancebased compensation in experiments vary, but higher incentives seem to have stronger impact
on judgment tasks and provide data that is more externally valid in terms of less risk-seeking
or social desirability (Camerer & Hogarth, 1999).
Another limitation is that the goal of the present study was to create a real-world
scenario with real-time stock information, realistic costs and a reasonably realistic choice
from a savings perspective. This scenario obviously came at the expense of a weak risk
manipulation for the experimental setting to work as intended. It may also mean that people
do not discriminate between shares from different stock segments. In addition, measuring
uncertainty directly after the choice would perhaps have given a different result. Still, the
different risk levels did not show any effect on the choice either, so it is reasonable to believe
that the risk levels were too similar.
TRUST AS COPING
18
With these limitations in mind, it is important to replicate the present study with a
more elaborate uncertainty measure. In the present study the perceived uncertainty measure is
limited to one single item and will need to be expanded in terms of theoretical underpinnings
and components. It is likely that individual risk preferences or traits can explain a range of
behaviors. It is therefore important to consider concepts such as tolerance of ambiguity since
people generally differ in terms of tolerance of, and in response to, uncertainty (for a review
on tolerance of ambiguity and related concepts, see Furnham and Marks, 2013).
We conclude that the delegation of a stock portfolio construction to a financial adviser
lowers the subjective uncertainty level of the investment. This is likely due to the mental
substitution of own knowledge and information with trust in the financial adviser’s
knowledge and information.
TRUST AS COPING
19
References
Akerlof, G. A. (1970). The market for “lemons”: Quality uncertainty and the market
mechanism. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 84(3), 488-500.
http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/1879431
Boon, S. D., & Holmes, J. G. (1991). The dynamics of interpersonal trust: Resolving
uncertainty in the face of risk. In R. A. Hinde & J. Groebel (Eds.), Cooperation and
prosocial behavior (pp. 190-211). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Brase, G. L., & Richmond, J. (2004). The white-coat effect: Physician attire and perceived
authority, friendliness and attractiveness. Journal of Applied Social Psychology,
34(12), 2469-2481. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1559-1816.2004.tb01987.x
Calcagno, R., & Monticone, C. (2015). Financial literacy and the demand for financial
advice. Journal of Banking and Finance, in press.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2014.03.013
Calvet, L. E., Campbell, J. Y., & Sodini, P. (2009). Measuring the financial sophistication of
households. American Economic Review, 99(2), 393-398.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.99.2.393
Camerer, C. F., & Hogarth, R. M. (1999). The effects of financial incentives in experiments:
A review and capital-labor-production framework. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty,
19(1-3), 7-42. http://dx.doi.org/10.1023/A:1007850605129
Carlander, A., Peterson, D., Gamble, A., Gärling, T., Johansson, L.-O. & Holmen, M. (2013).
Choices of savings options related to trust in banks’ competence, benevolence and
stability. Journal of Financial Services Marketing, 18(2), 121–136.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1057/fsm.2013.9
Chang, T., Solomon, D. H., & Westerfield, M. M. (2014). Looking for someone to blame:
Delegation, cognitive dissonance, and the disposition effect. Journal of Finance,
TRUST AS COPING
20
forthcoming. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2255674 or
http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2255674
Collins, M. J. (2012). Financial advice: A substitute for financial literacy? Financial Services
Review, 21(4), 307-322.
Das, T. K., & Teng, B-S. (1998). Between trust and control: Developing confidence in
partner cooperation in alliances. Academy of Management Review, 23(3), 491-512.
http://dx.doi.org/10.5465/AMR.1998.926623
Das, T. K., & Teng, B-S. (2004). The risk-based view of trust: A conceptual framework.
Journal of Business and Psychology, 19(1), 85-116.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1023/B:JOBU.0000040274.23551.1b
Del Guercio, D., & Tkac, P. A. (2009). Star power: The effect of Morningstar ratings on
mutual fund flow. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 43(4), 907-936.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/S0022109000014393
Dia, E. (2011). Uncertainty, trust, and the regulation of the banking industry. International
Review of Economics, 58(2), 213-228. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s12232-011-0121-1
Dzielinski, M. (2012). Measuring economic uncertainty and its impact on the stock market.
Finance Research Letters, 9(3), 167-175. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.frl.2011.10.003
Eisenhardt, K. M. (1989). Agency theory: An assessment and review. Academy of
Management Review, 14(1), 57-74. http://dx.doi.org/10.5465/AMR.1989.4279003
Emsley, D., & Kidon, F. (2007). The relationship between trust and control in international
joint ventures: Evidence from the airline industry. Contemporary Accounting Research,
24(3), 829-858. http://dx.doi.org/10.1506/car.24.3.7
Fehr, E., & Gächter, S. (2000). Fairness and retaliation: The Economics of reciprocity. The
Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14(3), 159-181.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/jep.14.3.159
TRUST AS COPING
21
Fenton-O’Creevy, M., Nicholson, N,. Soane, E., & Willman, P. (2003). Trading on illusions:
Unrealistic perceptions of control and trading performance. Journal of Occupational
Organizational Psychology, 76(1), 53-68.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1348/096317903321208880
Furnham, A., & Marks, J. (2013). Tolerance of ambiguity: A review of the recent literature.
Psychology, 4(9), 717-728. http://dx.doi.org/10.4236/psych.2013.49102
Gennaioli, N., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. (2015). Money doctors. The Journal of Finance.
70(1), 91-114. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/jofi.12188
Graham, J. R., Harvey, C. R., & Huang, H. (2009). Investor competence, trading frequency,
and home bias. Management Science, 55(7), 1094-1106.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.1090.1009
Granovetter, M. (1985). Economic action and social structure: The problem of
embeddedness. American Journal of Sociology, 91(3), 481-510.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/228311
Hastings, J. S., Madrian, B. C., & Skimmyhorn, W. L. (2013). Financial literacy, financial
education and economic outcomes. Annual Review of Economics, 5(1), 347-343.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1146/annurev-economics-082312-125807
Hilgert, M. A., Hogarth, J. M., & Beverly, S. G. (2003). Household financial management:
The connection between knowledge and behavior. Federal Reserve Bulletin, 89(7),
309-322. Available at: http://www.federalreserve.gov/pubs/bulletin/2003/0703lead.pdf
Huber, J., Kirchler, M., & Stöckl, T. (2010). The hot hand belief and the gambler’s fallacy in
investment decision under risk. Theory and Decision, 68(4), 445-462.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s11238-008-9106-2
Kamleitner, B., & Hoelzl, E. (2009). Cost-benefit associations and financial behavior.
Applied Psychology, 58(3), 435-452.
TRUST AS COPING
22
http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1464-0597.2009.00400.x
Kaustia, M. (2010). Disposition effect. In. H. Kent Baker & John R. Nofsinger (Eds.),
Behavioral Finance: Investors, Corporations, and Markets (pp. 171-190). Hoboken,
N.J.: John Wiley & Sons.
Kramer, R. M. (2006). Trust as situated cognition: an ecological perspective on trust
decisions. In R. Bachmann & A. Zaheer (Eds.), Handbook of Trust Research (pp. 6884). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Langer, E. J. (1975). The illusion of control. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology,
32(2), 311-328. http://dx.doi.org/10.1037/0022-3514.32.2.311
Lewis, D. J., & Weigert, A. (1985). Trust as a social reality. Social Forces, 63(4), 967-985.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/sf/63.4.967
Loewenstein, G. F., Weber, E. U., Hsee, C. K., & Welch, N. (2001). Risk as feelings.
Psychological Bulletin, 127(2), 267-286.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1037/0033-2909.127.2.267
Malhotra, D., & Murnighan, J. K. (2002). The effects of contracts on interpersonal trust.
Administrative Science Quarterly, 47(3), 534-559. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/3094850
Malkiel, B. G. (2003). The efficient market hypothesis and its critics. Journal of Economic
Perspectives, 17(1), 59-82. http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/089533003321164958
Mayer, R. C., Davis, J. H. & Schoorman, D. F. (1995). An Integrative Model of
Organizational Trust. Academy of Management Review, 20(3), 709-734.
http://dx.doi.org/10.5465/AMR.1995.9508080335
Möllering, G. (2014). Trust, calculativeness, and relationships: A special issue 20 years after
Williamson's warning. Journal of Trust Research, 4(1), 1-21.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/21515581.2014.891316
TRUST AS COPING
23
Ng, A., Ibrahim, M. H., & Mirakhor, A. (2014). Does trust contribute to stock market
development? Economic Modelling, in press.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2014.10.056
Nofsinger, J. (2007). The Psychology of Investing. New York, NY: Prentice Hall.
Parker, A. M., Bruine de Bruin, W., Yoong, J., & Willis, R. (2012). Inappropriate confidence
and retirement planning: Four studies with a national sample. Journal of Behavioral
Decision Making, 25(4), 382-389. http://dx.doi.org/10.1002/bdm.745
Riley, J. G. (2001). Silver signals: Twenty-five years of screening and signaling. Journal of
Economic Literature, 39(2), 432-478. http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/jel.39.2.432
Shapiro, S. P. (2005). Agency theory. Annual Review of Sociology, 31(1), 263-284.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1146/annurev.soc.31.041304.122159
Shefrin, H. (2007). Beyond greed and fear: Understanding behavioral finance and the
psychology of investing. New York, NY: Oxford University Press.
Shefrin, H., & Statman, M. (1985). The disposition to sell winners too early and ride losers
too long: Theory and evidence. The Journal of Finance, 40(3), 777-790.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.1985.tb05002.x
Siegrist, M., & Cvetkovich, G. (2000). Perceptions of hazards: The role of social trust and
knowledge. Risk Analysis, 20(5), 713-720. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/0272-4332.205064
Sjöberg, L. (1999). Risk perception by the public and by experts: A dilemma in risk
management. Human Ecology Review, 6(2), 1-9.
Spence, M. (1973). Job market signaling. The quarterly journal of economics, 87(3), 355374. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/1882010
Stiglitz, J. E. (1975). The theory of “screening,” education and the distribution income. The
American Economic Review, 65(3), 283-300.
Taylor, S. E., & Brown, J. D. (1988). Illusion and well-being: A social psychological
TRUST AS COPING
24
perspective on mental health. Psychological Bulletin, 103(2), 192-210.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1037/0033-2909.103.2.193
Van Rooij, M., Lusardi, A., & Alessie, R. (2011). Financial literacy and stock market
participation. Journal of Financial Economics, 101(2), 449-472http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2011.03.006
Viklund, M. J. (2003). Trust and risk perception in Western Europe: A cross-national study.
Risk Analysis, 23(4), 727-738. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/1539-6924.00351
Von Gaudecker, H-M. (2013). How does household portfolio diversification vary with
financial literacy and financial advice? Journal of Finance, forthcoming. Available at
SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1810560 or http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1810560
Wilson, A. E., & Darke, P. R. (2012). The optimistic trust effect: Use of belief in a just world
to cope with decision-generated threat. Journal of Consumer Research, 39(3), 615-628.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/664499
Wohl, M. J. A., & Enzle, M. E. (2009). Illusion of control by proxy: Placing one's fate in the
hands of another. British Journal of Social Psychology, 48(1), 183-200.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1348/014466607X258696