Impact of Environmental Degradation and POVERTY on Food Security

Impact of Environmental Degradation and POVERTY
on Food Security:
"Case study of White Nile State, Sudan"
By
Adil Yousif Yagoub Eisa
B.Sc. (Honors) - 1997
University of Kordofan
Supervisor
Dr. Kamil Ibrahim Hassan
A Thesis submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for
the degree of Master of Science in Agricultural Economics
Department of Agricultural Economics
Faculty of Agriculture
University of Khartoum
DEDICATION
To my dear Father Yousif
Mother,
Sisters,
Brothers and
All the family,
I dedicate this work with my love
Adil
Acknowledgement
Firstly, I am most grateful to Allah for assistance, health and
patience he has given me to complete this work.
I wish to express my special appreciation to my supervisor Dr.
Kamil Ibrahim Hassan, Department of Agricultural Economics, Faculty
of Agriculture, University of Khartoum for his help guidance,
suggestions, advices and persistent encouragement to carry out this study.
I am gratefully, indebted to my friend Adam Alajab, who helped
me during the data collection and Abdelhameed for his invaluable help.
Thanks are also extending to my uncles' families and to my
friendly Uncle Khalid Dawelbait for their invaluable assistance and
encouragement. Special thank to my sister Sayda for her finance and
encouragement.
Finally, thanks are also extended to my family for their
encouragement during the course of this study.
ABSTRACT
The study was conducted in the White Nile State. It aimed to assess
the environmental situation and poverty in the area and its impact on food
security.
This study aimed to investigate the socio-economic characteristics
of the population, production cost, net returns and the effect of some
socio-economic characteristics of the population and agronomic factors
on crop yield in the area.
The primary data were collected by a multi stage stratified random
sample of 160 respondents (80 farmers and 80 non- farmers) in the White
Nile State in the year 2002 using a questionnaire. In addition to the
secondary data from the relevant sources.
The descriptive statistics were used to investigate the socioeconomic characteristics of the respondent, environmental situation, food
status and poverty distribution. Crop budget analysis was conducted to
estimate the production cost and profitability of the crops under study. An
econometric model of food crops (dura and wheat) constructed with yield
being the dependant variable and the different agricultural inputs as
independent variables. Cobb-Douglas production function was fitted to
the data to investigate the effect of the main socio-economic and
agronomic factors.
The descriptive statistics analysis revealed that 91.2% of nonfarmer respondents were within the productive age group (20-60) years,
while 33.8% of farmers were older (over 60) years. Although 47.5% and
70% from farmers and non farmers, respectively received formal
education, which is reflected in the deteriorated situation of the
agricultural labors that lead to the weak awareness of farmers on
environmental issues, which resulted on deforestation of the region this
deprived the local population from the benefits of trees. Most of the
respondents said that the main factors curtailing agricultural productivity
were shortage of irrigation water, lack of finance and inputs. The
environmental impact clearly present on the cost structure that the cost of
land preparation, irrigation and fertilizer represent a high percentile ratio
comparable to the other items of cost that it present 53, 62, 68.4, 68.2 and
45% of the total cost for dura wheat, tomato, okra and onion,
respectively. The studies revealed that vegetable were more profitable
than food crops, but in spite of that farmer preferred to cultivate food
crops rather than vegetables for the purpose of self satisfaction.
Regression analysis for food crops showed that the environmental
factors have significant effect on productivity and that the northern
degraded area (stratification) has negative impact while irrigation has
positive significant impact that mean the utilization of low level of
irrigation input mainly due to soil erosion that logged the irrigation
canals. This calls for the maintenance and rehabilitation of the irrigation
system by mean of increasing the investment on the irrigation
infrastructure, which appear on the positive significant effect of the
production cost that the increase of the cost increased the productivity. In
addition to that, some of the elasticities of the individual variable
indicated the existence of increasing returns to scale for all crops.
Time series analysis revealed that the trend of food crop
productivity are declining, the productivity of dura and wheat will reach
zero level after 55 and 18 years respectively.
For food security and poverty alleviation the study recommended
the following:
•
Putting
the
White
Nile
Scheme
under
governmental
administration.
•
Provision of inputs at proper time and for reasonable prices.
•
Improvement of extension services and marketing systems.
•
Agricultural diversification and increase the area under the
vegetables.
‫ﺑﺴﻢ اﷲ اﻟﺮﺣﻤﻦ اﻟﺮﺣﻴﻢ‬
‫ﻤﻠﺨﺹ ﺍﻷﻁﺭﻭﺤﺔ‬
‫ﺃﺠﺭﻴﺕ ﻫﺫﻩ ﺍﻟﺩﺭﺍﺴﺔ ﺒﻭﻻﻴﺔ ﺍﻟﻨﻴل ﺍﻷﺒﻴﺽ‪ .‬ﻭﻫﺩﻓﺕ ﺍﻟﺩﺭﺍﺴﺔ ﻟﺘﻘﻴﻴﻡ ﺍﻟﻭﻀﻊ ﺍﻟﺒﻴﺌﻲ ﻭﺤﺎﻟﺔ‬
‫ﺍﻟﻔﻘﺭ ﺒﺎﻟﻤﻨﻁﻘﺔ ﻭﺃﺜﺭﻩ ﻋﻠﻲ ﺍﻷﻤﻥ ﺍﻟﻐﺫﺍﺌﻲ‪.‬‬
‫ﺃﺭﺍﺩﺕ ﺍﻟﺩﺭﺍﺴﺔ ﺍﻟﺘﻌﺭﻑ ﻋﻠﻰ ﺍﻟﺨﺼﺎﺌﺹ ﺍﻹﺠﺘﻤﺎﻋﻴﺔ ﻭﺍﻹﻗﺘﺼﺎﺩﻴﺔ ﻟﻠﻤﺴﺘﻬﺩﻓﻴﻥ ﻭﺘﺤﺩﻴـﺩ‬
‫ﺘﻜﺎﻟﻴﻑ ﺍﻹﻨﺘﺎﺝ ﻭﺼﺎﻓﻰ ﺍﻟﻌﺎﺌﺩ ﻟﻜل ﻤﺤﺼﻭل ﻋﻠﻲ ﺤﺩﺓ ﻭ ﺃﺜـﺭ ﺒﻌـﺽ ﺍﻟﻌﻭﺍﻤـل ﺍﻹﺠﺘﻤﺎﻋﻴـﺔ‬
‫ﻭﺍﻹﻗﺘﺼﺎﺩﻴﺔ ﻭﺍﻟﺤﻘﻠﻴﺔ ﻋﻠﻲ ﺇﻨﺘﺎﺝ ﺍﻟﻤﺤﺎﺼﻴل ﺒﺎﻟﻤﻨﻁﻘﺔ ﻭﺘﺄﺜﻴﺭ ﺫﻟﻙ ﻋﻠﻲ ﺩﺨل ﺍﻟﻤﺯﺍﺭﻋﻴﻥ‪.‬‬
‫ﺠﻤﻌﺕ ﺍﻟﻤﻌﻠﻭﻤﺎﺕ ﺍﻷﻭﻟﻴﺔ ﻓﻲ ﻋﺎﻡ ‪2002‬ﻡ ﻤﻥ ﻋﻴﻨﺔ ﻋﺸﻭﺍﺌﻴﺔ ﻁﺒﻘﻴﺔ ﻤﺘﻌﺩﺩﺓ ﺍﻟﻤﺭﺍﺤـل‬
‫ﻤﻥ ‪ 160‬ﻤﺴﺘﻬﺩﻑ )‪ 80‬ﻤﺯﺍﺭﻋﻴﻥ ﻭ‪ 80‬ﻏﻴﺭ ﻤﺯﺍﺭﻋﻴﻥ( ﻤﻥ ﻭﻻﻴﺔ ﺍﻟﻨﻴل ﺍﻷﺒﻴﺽ ﻋﻥ ﻁﺭﻴـﻕ‬
‫ﺍﻹﺴﺘﺒﻴﺎﻥ‪ ،‬ﺇﻀﺎﻓﺔ ﺇﻟﻲ ﺍﻟﻤﻌﻠﻭﻤﺎﺕ ﺍﻟﺜﺎﻨﻭﻴﺔ ﻤﻥ ﺍﻟﻤﺼﺎﺩﺭ ﺫﺍﺕ ﺍﻟﺼﻠﺔ‪ .‬ﺃﺨﻀﻌﺕ ﺍﻟﻤﻌﻠﻭﻤﺎﺕ ﺇﻟـﻲ‬
‫ﺍﻟﺘﺤﻠﻴل ﺍﻟﻭﺼﻔﻲ ﺍﻹﺤﺼﺎﺌﻲ ﻟﻠﺨﺼﺎﺌﺹ ﺍﻹﺠﺘﻤﺎﻋﻴﺔ ﻭﺍﻹﻗﺘﺼﺎﺩﻴﺔ ﻟﻠﻤﺴﺘﻬﺩﻓﻴﻥ ﻭﺍﻷﻭﻀﺎﻉ ﺍﻟﺒﻴﺌﻴﺔ‬
‫ﻭﺍﻟﻭﻀﻊ ﺍﻟﻐﺫﺍﺌﻲ ﻭﺍﻟﺘﻭﺯﻴﻊ ﺤﺴﺏ ﻤﻌﺎﻴﻴﺭ ﺍﻟﻔﻘﺭ‪ .‬ﻭﺘﻡ ﻓﺤﺹ ﺍﻟﻤﻴﺯﺍﻨﻴﺔ ﺍﻟﻤﺯﺭﻋﻴﺔ ﻟﺘﺤﺩﻴﺩ ﻋﻨﺎﺼﺭ‬
‫ﺍﻟﺘﻜﺎﻟﻴﻑ ﺍﻷﺴﺎﺴﻴﺔ ﻭﺭﺒﺤﻴﺔ ﺍﻟﻤﺤﺎﺼﻴل ﺘﺤﺕ ﻗﻴﺩ ﺍﻟﺩﺭﺍﺴﺔ‪ .‬ﻜﻤﺎ ﺘﻡ ﺘـﺼﻤﻴﻡ ﺃﻨﻤـﻭﺫﺝ ﺇﻗﺘـﺼﺎﺩﻱ‬
‫ﻗﻴﺎﺴﻲ ﻟﻤﺤﺎﺼﻴل ﺍﻟﺫﺭﺓ ﻭﺍﻟﻘﻤﺢ ﻭﺫﻟﻙ ﺒﻭﻀﻊ ﺍﻹﻨﺘﺎﺠﻴﺔ ﻜﻌﺎﻤل ﺘﺎﺒﻊ ﻭﻤﺨﺘﻠﻑ ﺍﻟﻤﺩﺨﻼﺕ ﻜﻌﻭﺍﻤـل‬
‫ﻤﻔﺴﺭﺓ‪ ،‬ﺃﺴﺘﺨﺩﻤﺕ ﺩﺍﻟﺔ ﺍﻹﻨﺘﺎﺝ )ﻜﻭﺏ ‪ -‬ﺩﻭﻗﻼﺱ( ﻟﻠﺘﻌﺭﻑ ﻋﻠﻲ ﺃﻫـﻡ ﺍﻟﻌﻭﺍﻤـل ﺍﻹﺠﺘﻤﺎﻋﻴـﺔ‬
‫ﻭﺍﻹﻗﺘﺼﺎﺩﻴﺔ ﻭﺍﻟﺤﻘﻠﻴﺔ ﺍﻟﻤﺅﺜﺭﺓ ﻋﻠﻲ ﺇﻨﺘﺎﺠﻴﺔ ﻫﺫﻩ ﺍﻟﻤﺤﺎﺼﻴل‪.‬‬
‫ﺃﻭﻀﺢ ﺍﻟﺘﺤﻠﻴل ﺍﻹﺤﺼﺎﺌﻲ ﺍﻟﻭﺼﻔﻲ ﺃﻥ ‪ %91.2‬ﻤﻥ ﻏﻴﺭ ﺍﻟﻤﺯﺍﺭﻋﻴﻥ ﻴﻘﻌﻭﻥ ﻀﻤﻥ ﻓﺌﺔ‬
‫ﺍﻷﻋﻤﺎﺭ ﺍﻟﻤﻨﺘﺠﺔ)‪ (60-20‬ﺴﻨﺔ ﺒﻴﻨﻤﺎ ‪ %33.8‬ﻤﻥ ﺍﻟﻤﺯﺍﺭﻋﻴﻥ ﻤﺴﻨﻴﻥ)ﻓﻭﻕ ﺍل‪ (60‬ﺴﻨﺔ‪ .‬ﻜـﺫﻟﻙ‬
‫‪ %47.5‬ﻭ‪ %70‬ﻨﺎﻟﻭﺍ ﺘﻌﻠﻴﻤﺂ ﺭﺴﻤﻴﺂ ﻤﻥ ﺍﻟﻤﺯﺍﺭﻋﻴﻥ ﻭﻏﻴﺭ ﺍﻟﻤﺯﺍﺭﻋﻴﻥ ﻋﻠﻰ ﺍﻟﺘﻭﺍﻟﻰ ﻤﻤﺎ ﻴﻌﻨـﻰ‬
‫ﺃﻥ ﺍﻟﻤﺯﺍﺭﻋﻴﻥ ﺃﻗل ﺘﻌﻠﻴﻤﺂ ﻤﻤﺎ ﻗﺎﺩ ﺍﻟﻰ ﻀﻌﻑ ﺍﻟﻭﻋﻰ ﺒﺎﻟﻤﻭﻀﻭﻋﺎﺕ ﺍﻟﺒﻴﺌﻴﺔ ﺍﻟﺫﻯ ﺇﻨﻌﻜـﺱ ﻓـﻰ‬
‫ﻏﻴﺎﺏ ﺍﻟﻐﻁﺎﺀ ﺍﻟﺸﺠﺭﻯ ﻭﺍﻟﻭﻋﻰ ﺒﺄﻫﻤﻴﺔ ﺍﻟﻨﺴﺒﺔ ﺍﻟﻤﺌﻭﻴﺔ ﻤﻥ ﺍﻷﺤﺯﻤﺔ ﺍﻟﺸﺠﺭﻴﺔ ﺍﻟﻭﺍﻗﻴـﺔ ﺇﻀـﺎﻓﺔ‬
‫ﻹﻋﺘﻤﺎﺩ ﺍﻟﻤﺯﺍﺭﻋﻴﻥ ﻋﻠﻰ ﺍﻟﻤﻨﺘﺠﺎﺕ ﺍﻟﻐﺎﺒﻴﺔ ﻜﻤﺼﺩﺭ ﻟﻁﺎﻗﺔ ﺍﻟﻁﻬﻰ ﻤﻤﺎ ﻴﺅﺜﺭ ﺴﻠﺒﺂ ﻋﻠﻰ ﺍﻹﻨﺘﺎﺠﻴـﺔ‬
‫ﺍﻟﺯﺭﺍﻋﻴﺔ ﻭﻗﺩ ﺫﻜﺭ ﺍﻟﻤﺴﺘﻬﺩﻓﻴﻥ ﺃﻥ ﺃﻫﻡ ﺍﻟﻌﻭﺍﻤل ﺍﻟﺘﻰ ﺘﻌﻭﻕ ﺍﻹﻨﺘﺎﺝ ﺍﻟﺯﺭﺍﻋﻰ ﻫﻰ ﻨﻘـﺹ ﺍﻟـﺭﻯ‬
‫‪،‬ﺍﻟﺘﻤﻭﻴل ﻭﺍﻟﻤﺩﺨﻼﺕ‪ .‬ﺍﻷﺜﺭ ﺍﻟﺒﻴﺌﻰ ﻴﻅﻬﺭ ﺒﻭﻀﻭﺡ ﻓﻰ ﺍﻟﺘﻜـﺎﻟﻴﻑ ﺤﻴـﺙ ﺃﻥ ﺘﻜﻠﻔـﺔ ﺘﺤـﻀﻴﺭ‬
‫ﺍﻷﺭﺍﻀﻰ‪ ،‬ﺍﻟﺭﻯ ﻭﺍﻷﺴﻤﺩﺓ ﺘﻤﺜل ﻨﺴﺒﺔ ﻋﺎﻟﻴﺔ ﻤﻘﺎﺭﻨﺔ ﺒﺒﻘﻴﺔ ﺒﻨﻭﺩ ﺍﻟﺘﻜﺎﻟﻴﻑ ﺤﻴﺙ ﺘﻤﺜـل ‪،62 ،53‬‬
‫‪ 68.2 ،68.4‬ﻭ‪ %45‬ﻤﻥ ﺠﻤﻠﺔ ﺍﻟﺘﻜﻠﻔﺔ ﻟﻜل ﻤﻥ ﺍﻟﺫﺭﺓ‪ ،‬ﺍﻟﻘﻤﺢ‪ ،‬ﺍﻟﻁﻤﺎﻁﻡ‪ ،‬ﺍﻟﺒﺎﻤﻴﺔ ﻭﺍﻟﺒﺼل ﻋﻠﻰ‬
‫ﺍﻟﺘﻭﺍﻟﻰ‪ .‬ﻜﻤﺎ ﺃﻭﻀﺢ ﺘﺤﻠﻴل ﺍﻟﻤﻴﺯﺍﻨﻴﺔ ﺍﻟﻤﺯﺭﻋﻴﺔ ﺃﻥ ﺍﻟﻤﺤﺎﺼﻴل ﺘﺤـﺕ ﻗﻴـﺩ ﺍﻟﺩﺭﺍﺴـﺔ ﻤﺭﺒﺤـﺔ‬
‫ﻟﻠﻤﺯﺍﺭﻋﻴﻥ ﻭﺃﻥ ﺃﻜﺜﺭ ﺍﻟﻤﺤﺎﺼﻴل ﺭﺒﺤﻴﺔ ﻫﻲ ﺍﻟﻁﻤﺎﻁﻡ ﺘﻠﻴﻬﺎ ﺍﻟﺒﺎﻤﻴﺔ ﺜﻡ ﺍﻟﺒﺼل ﻭﺍﻟـﺫﺭﺓ ﻭﺃﺨﻴـﺭﹰﺍ‬
‫ﺍﻟﻘﻤﺢ‪ ،‬ﻤﻤﺎ ﻴﺩل ﻋﻠﻰ ﺃﻥ ﻤﺤﺎﺼﻴل ﺍﻟﺨﻀﺭ ﺃﻜﺜﺭ ﺭﺒﺤﻴﺔ ﻤﻥ ﺍﻟﻤﺤﺎﺼﻴل ﺍﻟﻐﺫﺍﺌﻴﺔ ﻭﻟﻜﻥ ﺒﺎﻟﺭﻏﻡ ﻤﻥ‬
‫ﺫﻟﻙ ﻨﺠﺩ ﺃﻥ ﺍﻟﻤﺯﺍﺭﻋﻴﻥ ﻴﺯﺭﻋﻭﻥ ﺍﻟﻤﺤﺎﺼﻴل ﺍﻟﻐﺫﺍﺌﻴﺔ ﻓﻀﻼ ﻋﻥ ﺍﻟﺨﻀﺭﻭﺍﺕ ﺒﻐﺭﺽ ﺍﻹﻜﺘﻔـﺎﺀ‬
‫ﺍﻟﺫﺍﺘﻰ‪.‬‬
‫ﺃﻅﻬﺭﺕ ﻨﺘﺎﺌﺞ ﺍﻟﺘﺤﻠﻴل ﺍﻻﻗﺘﺼﺎﺩﻱ ﺍﻟﻘﻴﺎﺴﻲ ﻟﻠﻤﺤﺎﺼﻴل ﺍﻟﻐﺫﺍﺌﻴﺔ ﺃﻥ ﺍﻟﻌﻭﺍﻤل ﺍﻟﺒﻴﺌﻴﺔ ﻟﻬﺎ ﺃﺜﺭ‬
‫ﻤﻌﻨﻭﻯ ﻓﻰ ﺍﻹﻨﺘﺎﺠﻴﺔ ﺤﻴﺙ ﺃﻥ ﺍﻟﻤﻨﺎﻁﻕ ﺍﻟﺸﻤﺎﻟﻴﺔ )ﺍﻟﻘﻁﺎﻋﺎﺕ( ﻟﻬﺎ ﺃﺜﺭ ﺴﺎﻟﺏ ﻋﻠﻰ ﺍﻹﻨﺘﺎﺠﻴﺔ ﺒﻴﻨﻤﺎ‬
‫ﻟﻠﺭﻱ ﺃﺜﺭ ﻤﻌﻨﻭﻯ ﻤﻭﺠﺏ ﻭﺍﻟﺫﻯ ﻴﻌﻭﺩ ﻟﻠﻤﺴﺘﻭﻯ ﺍﻷﺩﻨﻰ ﺍﻟﻤﺴﺘﺨﺩﻡ ﻤﻥ ﻫﺫﺍ ﺍﻟﻌﺎﻤل ﻨﻅﺭﺁ ﻟﻌﺎﻤـل‬
‫ﺍﻟﺘﻌﺭﻴﺔ ﻭﺯﺤﻑ ﺍﻟﺭﻤﺎل ﺍﻟﺫﻯ ﻴﺅﺩﻯ ﺍﻟﻰ ﻏﻠﻕ ﻗﻨﻭﺍﺕ ﺍﻟﺭﻯ‪ ،‬ﻤﻤﺎ ﻴﻌﻨﻰ ﺍﻟﺤﺎﺠـﺔ ﺍﻟـﻰ ﺇﺼـﻼﺡ‬
‫ﻭﺇﻋﺎﺩﺓ ﺘﺄﻫﻴل ﺸﺒﻜﺔ ﺍﻟﺭﻯ ﺒﺯﻴﺎﺩﺓ ﺍﻹﺴﺘﺜﻤﺎﺭ ﻓﻰ ﻫﺫﺍ ﺍﻹﻁﺎﺭ ﻭﺍﻟﺫﻯ ﻴﻅﻬﺭ ﻓﻰ ﺍﻷﺜـﺭ ﺍﻟﻤﻌﻨـﻭﻯ‬
‫ﺍﻟﻤﻭﺠﺏ ﻟﻠﺘﻜﺎﻟﻴﻑ ﺍﻟﺫﻯ ﻴﻌﻨﻰ ﺒﺯﻴﺎﺩﺓ ﺍﻟﺘﻜﺎﻟﻴﻑ ﺴﺘﺯﻴﺩ ﺍﻹﻨﺘﺎﺠﻴﺔ‪ .‬ﻜﻤـﺎ ﺃﻭﻀـﺤﺕ ﺍﻟﺩﺭﺍﺴـﺔ ﺃﻥ‬
‫ﻤﺠﻤﻭﻉ ﻤﺭﻭﻨﺎﺕ ﺍﻟﻌﻭﺍﻤل ﺍﻟﻔﺭﺩﻴﺔ ﺍﻟﻤﺘﻐﻴﺭﺓ ﺘﺩل ﻋﻠﻰ ﻭﺠﻭﺩ ﺘﺯﺍﻴﺩ ﻓـﻲ ﻋﺎﺌـﺩﺍﺕ ﺍﻟـﺴﻌﺔ ﻟﻜـل‬
‫ﺍﻟﻤﺤﺎﺼﻴل‪.‬‬
‫ﺃﻅﻬﺭ ﺘﺤﻠﻴل ﺍﻟﺴﻼﺴل ﺍﻟﺯﻤﻨﻴﺔ ﺃﻥ ﺇﻨﺘﺎﺠﻴﺔ ﺍﻟﻤﺤﺎﺼﻴل ﺍﻟﻐﺫﺍﺌﻴﺔ ﻤﺘﻨﺎﻗـﺼﺔ‪ ،‬ﻭﺃﻥ ﺇﻨﺘﺎﺠﻴـﺔ‬
‫ﺍﻟﺫﺭﺓ ﻭﺍﻟﻘﻤﺢ ﺴﺘﺼل ﺇﻟﻲ ﺍﻟﺼﻔﺭ ﺒﻌﺩ ‪ 55‬ﻭ ‪ 18‬ﺴﻨﺔ ﻋﻠﻲ ﺍﻟﺘﻭﺍﻟﻲ‪.‬‬
‫ﺃﻭﺼﺕ ﺍﻟﺩﺭﺍﺴﺔ ﺒﺈﻋﺎﺩﺓ ﺍﻟﻤﺸﺎﺭﻴﻊ ﺇﻟﻰ ﺍﻹﺩﺍﺭﺓ ﺍﻟﺤﻜﻭﻤﻴﺔ ﻭﺇﻋﺎﺩﺓ ﺘﺄﻫﻴﻠﻬـﺎ ﻤـﻥ ﺨـﻼل‬
‫ﺇﺼﻼﺡ ﻨﻅﻡ ﺍﻟﺭﻱ ﻭﺘﻭﻓﻴﺭ ﻤﺩﺨﻼﺕ ﺍﻹﻨﺘﺎﺝ ﻓﻲ ﺍﻟﻭﻗﺕ ﺍﻟﻤﻨﺎﺴـﺏ ﻭﺒﺄﺴـﻌﺎﺭ ﻤﻌﻘﻭﻟـﺔ ‪ ،‬ﺘﻘﻭﻴـﺔ‬
‫ﺍﻟﻭﺤﺩﺍﺕ ﺍﻹﺭﺸﺎﺩﻴﺔ ﻭﻨﻅﺎﻡ ﺍﻟﺘﺴﻭﻴﻕ‪ ،‬ﺘﻭﻓﻴﺭ ﺍﻟﺘﻤﻭﻴل ﺍﻟﺯﺭﺍﻋﻲ ﻭﺘﻨﻭﻴﻊ ﺍﻟﺯﺭﺍﻋﺔ ﻭﺇﺴﺘﻘﻁﺎﻉ ﻤﺴﺎﺤﻪ‬
‫ﺃﻜﺒﺭ ﻟﻤﺤﺎﺼﻴل ﺍﻟﺨﻀﺭ‪.‬‬
LIST OF CONTENTS
Page
Dedication ...................................................................................................
I
Acknowledgement ......................................................................................
Ii
Abstract ......................................................................................................
Iii
Arabic Abstract ............................................................................................
v
List of Contents ...........................................................................................
vii
List of Tables ..............................................................................................
xi
List of Appendices........................................................................................
xii
List of Figures .............................................................................................
xiii
CHAPTER ONE: INTRODUCTION ...................................................
1
1.1 General..............................................................................................
1
1.2. Poverty ……………………………………………………………….
1
1.3. Food security.......................................................................................
3
1.4. Background to the problem.................................................................
4
1.5. Problem statement...............................................................................
6
1.6. Justification...........................................................................................
7
1.7. Objective of the study............................................................................
9
1.8 Hypotheses formulation.........................................................................
9
1.9. Research Methodology..........................................................................
9
1.9.1 Methods of data collection..................................................................
9
1.9.2 Methods of analysis............................................................................
12
1.10 Organization of the study.....................................................................
12
CHAPTER TWO: LITERATURE REVIEW ........................................
14
2.1 Environmental Degradation...................................................................
14
2.1.1 Environment as a global crisis.............................................................
14
2.1.2 Meta problem......................................................................................
21
2.1.3 Environment and poverty....................................................................
22
2.1.4. Energy and environment....................................................................
23
2.1.5 Environmental degradation in developing countries...........................
24
2.1.5 Environmental Degradation in Sudan.................................................
26
2.1.5.1 Over cultivation................................................................................
27
2.1.5.2 Overgrazing......................................................................................
27
2.1.5.3 Deforestation....................................................................................
28
2.1.5.4 Desertification..................................................................................
29
2.2. Food security.........................................................................................
30
2.2.1. Food Shortages and Emergencies.......................................................
32
2.3. Poverty........................................................... ......................................
33
2.2.1. The role of agriculture to alleviate poverty........................................
34
CHAPTER THREE: RESULTS AND DISCUSIONS............................
36
3.1. Social characteristics of respondent families........................................
36
3.2. Respondent level of Education..............................................................
37
3.3. Institutional services..............................................................................
41
3.4. Environmental services.........................................................................
41
3.5. Economic activities...............................................................................
43
3.6. Nutritional Status...................................................................................
45
CHAPTER FOUR:RESULTS OF THE CROP BUDGET
ANALYSIS................................................................
47
4.1. Production costs....................................................................................
47
4.1.1. Land preparation cost.........................................................................
47
4.1.2. Seeds cost...........................................................................................
48
4.1.3. Irrigation cost........... .........................................................................
48
4.1.4. Fertilizer cost........................ .............................................................
49
4.1.5. Harvesting and threshing cost............................................................
52
4.1.6. Sacks and Strings cost........................................................................
52
4.1.7. Zakat.................................... ..............................................................
52
4.1.8. Other cost............................. .............................................................
53
4.1.9. Total variable cost of production........................................................
53
4.2. Analysis of crop returns............................ ..........................................
55
4.2.1. Crop yield............................................ ..............................................
55
4.2.2. Farm gate prices............................... ................................................
55
4.2.3. The break even yield..........................................................................
56
4.2.4. Gross returns (Ls/feddan) ..................................................................
58
4.2.5. Gross margins (Ls/feddan).................................................................
58
4.2.6. The coefficient of private profitability (CCP)...................................
60
4.3. Respondent income and Poverty indicators..........................................
63
CHAPTER FIVE: RESULTS AND DISCUSSION OF
REGRESSION EQUATIONS.... ..............................................................
65
5.1. Theoratical Frame work.... ...................................................................
65
5.1.1. The production function.... ................................................................
65
5.1.2. Some forms of production function.... ..............................................
66
5.1.2.1. Linear production function.... .......................................................
66
5.1.2.2. The quadratic form.... ....................................................................
67
4.1.2.3. Cubic or New-classical production function...................................
68
5.1.2.4. Cobb-Douglas production function................................................
69
5.1.2. Model Specification.... ......................................................................
71
5.1.3. The econometric model estimation method.......................................
71
5.1.4. The R-squared.... ...............................................................................
72
5.1.5 The test of hypothesis.... .....................................................................
73
5.1.5.1. The T-test.... ...................................................................................
73
5.1.5.2. The F-test.... ....................................................................................
73
5.1.6. The selected production model...........................................................
74
5.2. Regression analysis results.... ...............................................................
75
5.2.1. Dura regression result.... ....................................................................
75
5.2.2. Wheat regression result......................................................................
77
5.3. Discussion of the two crops regression equations.......................................
79
5.3.1. The irrigation variable........................................................................
79
5.3.2. The farm income variable ..................................................................
80
5.3.3. Credit variable ...................................................................................
80
5.3.4. Extension services variable................................................................
81
5.3.5. The cost of production variable.........................................................
81
5.3.6. The stratification variable…………………………………………...
81
5.4. The nature of returns to scale................................................................
81
5.5. Forecasting food crop productivity ......................................................
81
CAPTER SIX : CONCLUSION AND RECOMMENDATION
87
6.1. Summary.................................................. ............................................
87
6.2. Conclusions...........................................................................................
88
6.3. Recommendations.................................................................................
90
REFERENCES ..........................................................................................
92
APPENDICES............................................................................................
96
LIST OF TABLES
Table
Title
No.
1.1 Five years average area and productivity (1975-1993) for cotton and
Dura in White Nile schemes................................................................. 8
2.1 Consumption of selected items, North / South .................................... 19
2.2 Ratio of income of richest 20% to poorest 20% of world population
20
2.3 Absolute poverty, 1993.......................................................................
35
3.1 Respondent family characteristic........................................................
38
3.2 Age distribution of respondent............................................................
38
3.3 Respondent marital status.................................................................... 38
3.4 Respondent educational level.............................................................. 40
3.5 Agricultural credit and extension services..........................................
40
3.6 Project management............................................................................. 40
3.7 Reason of non-agroforestry application..............................................
42
3.8 Source of cooking power..................................................................... 42
3.9 Economic Activity............................................................................... 42
3.10 Livestock Ownership............................................................................ 44
3.11 Kind of Livestock owned..................................................................... 44
3.12 Impact of livestock in income.............................................................
44
3.13 Production constraints.......................................................................... 46
3.14 Number of meals per day....................................................................
46
3.15 Meals components................................................................................ 46
4.1 The average production cost Ls/feddan............................................... 50
4.2 The percentage share of each item in the total cost of production....... 51
4.3 The average yield of crops per feddan season 2001-2002................... 57
4.4 The average farm gate price................................................................
57
4.5 The break even yield of crops per feddan...........................................
59
4.6 The average gross returns Ls/feddan................................................... 59
4.7 The average gross margins Ls/feddan.................................................. 62
4.8 The coefficient of private profitability................................................. 62
4.9 The respondent average income …………………………………….. 64
4.10 The poverty indicator .......................................................................... 64
5.1 Dura regression equation......................................................................... 76
5.2 Wheat regression equation....................................................................... 78
LIST OF FIGURES
Fig. No.
Title
Page No.
2.1
Rates of change on the planet...................................................
16
2.2
The distribution of world income..............................................
18
5.1
Trend for dura productivity (sacks/feddan) .............................
85
5.2
Trend for wheat productivity (sacks/feddan) ...........................
86
LIST OF APPENDICES
App No.
1
Title
No.
Area and average production of cotton and Dura in White Nile
Scheme from season 1973/74 to 1997/98.....................................
96
CHAPTER ONE
INTRODUCTION
1. General Introduction:
In recent years, environmental degradation has become a matter of
great concern worldwide. Environmental degradation, ranging from soil
erosion, desertification and air pollution to shrinking of ozone layer,
pollution of the world oceans, global warming and deforestation is
increasingly drawing the attention of the international community. In
large parts this has resulted from the growing awareness of the linkage
between the nature of economic activities and the environment on one
hand and the desire to ensure that the design of economic policies takes
due account of the environment conservation on the other hand.
Most of developing countries depend mainly on their resource
endowments for production and exports. Thus, excessive degradation of
natural resources will limit their chances for sustainable development.
In Sudan since independence there were major developmental
plans adopted by the various political systems. In those plans, there was
virtual neglect to their environmental consequences. The result is
environmental degradation in its different forms.
Accordingly, the impact of environmental degradation constituted
a threat to the economic development and growth as well as the quality of
life of people in the Sudan.
Therefore, environmental conservation is necessary for maintaining
the natural resources for economic development as well as for human
existence.
1.1 Poverty:
Poverty is becoming a stunning phenomenon and the denial of
opportunities is presenting an obstacle and a challenge to the process of
human development and to environmental conservation. As a
phenomenon, poverty stems from a complexity of economic, physical,
social and political factors and has adverse impacts on both the physical
and social environments. Its results are more degradation to the physical
and social environments and lower population quality. Lower population
quality, in turns, implies vulnerability to death at all ages, more ignorance
and inability to execute development (El Nayal, 2002).
According to its human poverty index (HPI), and out of the 174 Countries
listed. The Sudan ranks No.143 (UNDP, 1998), and local studies claim
that at present, 93% of the Sudanese population live below poverty line
(El Nayal, 2002).
Poverty can be defined as poverty is a multi-dimensional phenomenon. It
is not only "the lack of opportunities and choices most basic to human
development, to lead a long, healthy and creative life, to enjoy dignity,
self-esteem, the respect of others, and things that people value in life
(UNDP, 1998).
Poverty inflicts a negative impact on both the environment and the
process of human development. Due to the diverse physical and cultural
setups of the Sudan, the impacts of poverty on Sudanese population vary
from one region to another.
The main characteristic situation of the rural poor in the Sudan is one of
high level of illiteracy rates, high disease incidence, high infant mortality
rates, short life expectancy, lack of access to basic services and low per
capita income, and conflicts over natural resources (water and grazing
land) (El Nayal, 2002).
1.2 Food security:
Food security defined as: assuring to human beings the physical
and economic access to the basic food they need, is a broad, crosscutting
issue, which has implications for a number of different sectors in the
economy. Food Security is often associated with food self-sufficiency and
the need to grow more food. However, in reality it has much stronger
links with issues of poverty, employment and income generation. For
low-income economies, where a large percentage of the population lives
in the rural areas and depends on agriculture for its income, increasing
food production may be an important element in increasing food security
(FAO, 1997).
This definition implies three different aspects: availability, stability
and access to the basic food needed. This definition is clearly stated in
terms of food security for each individual, and it can be argued that this is
the most indeed some would say the only, meaningful definition of food
security. The definition of household food security accepted by the
committee on world food security refines this definition also follows:
"Physical and economic access to adequate food for all households
members, without undue risk of losing such access" (FAO, 1997). This
introduces the concept of vulnerability (Ibid, 1997).
Food availability is determined by the level of food supplies,
composed of subsistence production and market supplies stemming from
domestic production, foods stocks and food imports. Access to food is the
result of the ability to express food needs (beyond subsistence
production) as effective demand. Stability refers to variations and the risk
of shortfalls in food production, supplies and/or demand over time.
Food security is defined as a situation where both food supply and
demand are sufficient to cover food requirements on a continuous and
stable basis. This general definition of food security applies, in principle,
to individual household as well as to aggregate national food security.
Food insecurity prevails if, at any time (occasionally, repeatedly, or
permanently), either the volume of food supply, or food demand, or both
fall short of requirements (Ibid, 1997).
1.4. Background of the problem:
Salih, et al. (1997) reported that the instability of management, lack
of finance, reduction of cultivated area and decrease of productivity are
among the main problems facing the White Nile schemes.
The establishment of private pumps schemes dates back to the
period (1929 – 1931) after the construction of Sennar and Gebel Awlia
dams. To compensate the citizens for their flooded land due to the
construction of Gebel Awlia dam, the government established in 1931 the
White Nile Pump Schemes with a total area of 27.000 feddans around ElDuiem and to the South of the dam.
In 1943, what was known as the White Nile Pump Schemes Board
(WNPSB) was formed to run them.
In June 1968, the Agricultural Reform Corporation (ARC) was
created to act as an independent managing body for the schemes taken
over by the government. Gradually, by 1970, all the private schemes with
pumps above six inches came under the management of the agricultural
Reform Corporation.
In 1975 the rules of the Public Corporation for Agricultural
Production (PCAP), were amended to add to its responsibilities, the
management of the (ARC) schemes and those, which were run by the
White Nile Pump Scheme Board (WNPSB).
In 1978/79 a trend of decentralization, aiming at giving the
Agricultural Corporations more autonomy in decision making and
loosening the grip of the headquarter on them, led to the creation of
White Nile Agricultural Corporation (WNAC) with its headquarters in
Kosti and regional offices in El-Duiem and El-Renk.
In 1986, a ministerial resolution was issued and the name has been
changed from White Nile Agricultural Corporation (WNAC) to the White
Nile Pump Scheme Administration (WNPSA), which in 1994/95 has been
divided into two administrations, the Northern one in El-Duiem and the
southern in Kosti.
In 1996 until now the administrations charged to be many
companies they are:
● The North White Nile Pump Schemes Company (El-Duiem).
● The South White Nile Pump Schemes Company (Kosti).
● The White Nile Agricultural services Company (IFAD).
● The White Nile Company (El-Gaabidda).
● Acala
Company,
and
other
companies
and
co-operative
associations.
The traditional rotation on the scheme is the three courses of cotton –
1/2 Dura, 1/2 follow – follow. Recently, wheat replaced dura or cotton in
case water pumping is commenced late, particularly in some schemes in
El-Duiem region. For a long period, the crop structure predominant in the
scheme is the following: Dura, Cotton and Wheat.
Production relations within the White Nile Pump Scheme were
originally based on the joint account system (J.A). It started with 60% as
the share of the scheme owner and 40% for the tenant. In 1968 the share
of the tenants reached 50% of cotton net proceeds. In 1981/82, the (J.A)
was abandoned to be replaced by what is known as the individual account
(I.A). According to this new system, the White Nile Pump Scheme
Administration provides irrigation water and other inputs, prepares the
land and avails loans for the different agricultural operations. The cost of
inputs and the rent of land and all other activities performed by the
administration on behalf of the tenants would then be deducted from the
gross proceeds of cotton and the balance would be given to the tenants.
Food and Agriculture Organization (FAO) (1986) reported that
during the last few years moving sands have reached White Nile Pumps
schemes covered villages, clogged canals and made irrigated agriculture
difficult or impossible in some areas.
The causes of desertification in the White Nile State also include
severe felling of natural forests. The over cutting helped by expansion in
rainfed agriculture resulted into wind erosion and moving sands.
Desertification in White Nile state has led to sedimentation of
canals and coverage of fields with sand, reduction in the cropped area and
low productivity, which reduced tenant income and hence resulted in
food deficiency and non-sustainable development in the area.
1.5. Problem statement:
In recent years, the efficiency of the major irrigated projects
witnessed a considerable deterioration in productivity and thus decrease
in tenants' income has been noticed.
Environmental degradation in the White Nile state influenced
cropped area, productivity and income of people in the affected areas. We
notice the decline and fluctuation of cotton and dura cultivated area and
average production Table (1) and appendix (1) show the average area and
average productivity during seasons (1973-1998).
This study intends to assess the impact of environmental
degradation and poverty on the state of food and agricultural production.
In this study crop, profitability will be investigated to assess the attitude
of farmers' whether they seek for profitability or self-sufficiency. It is
also the aim of the study to determine the factors affecting productivity.
1.6. Justification:
Environmental degradation in many forms is a serious problem that
threats economic development. Due to the lack of reliable data on its
impact, it is difficult to quantify the adverse effect and the exact cost on
the economy. In White Nile State, there are many phenomena that need to
be investigated: The major policy change shifting from cotton producing
before independence to major food production in the recent drought
years. Besides wind erosion, desertification and poverty necessitate
intervention. We believe it is high time to evaluate the effect of these
changes on development in form of resource use, crop yields and returns.
This call for an overall study to assess farmers attitude towards cropping
patterns e.g. assess the profitability of crops in order to achieve a healthy
environment and higher income to keep up the White Nile state in
sustainable manner as a food supplier. Even a surplus could be achieved
for export to earn foreign currency.
Table (1.1) Five years average area and productivity (1975-1993) for
cotton and Dura in White Nile schemes.
Cotton
The period
Dura
Average
Average area
Average area
Average
1000 fed
productivity/kg
productivity/
1000 fed
kantar/ feddan
1973/74-77/78
125.8
3.02
70.2
241.2
1978/79-82/83
85.4
2.42
31.6
423.6
1983/84-87/88
50.2
3.04
38.6
397.2
1988/89-92/93*
23.2
3.27
47.6
462
1992/93-97/98
36.4
3.55
49.2
446
* in 1991/92 cotton was not cultivated
Source: statistics and information management, Ministry of Agriculture and Forestry.
1.7. Objective of the study:
The main objective of this study is to seek ways for conserving and
improving natural resources existing, and trying to evaluate the expected
impact on:
?
Food security;
?
Poverty alleviation, and
?
Improving living condition for the future generations in a
sustainable manner.
1.8. Hypotheses formulation:
Hypotheses are based on the objectives of the study. The following
hypotheses will be tested:
● Environmental factors (rainfall, irrigation and population
density), has strong effect on crop yield.
● Cost of production, credit, irrigation availability and rainfall are
the main constrains of agricultural production in WNS.
● The people in the White Nile State live under poverty line.
1.9 Research Methodology:
1.9.1 Methods of data collection:
1.9.1.1 Data source: Both primary and secondary data will be used.
Secondary data will be obtained from textbooks, published papers,
reports, Ph.D., M.Sc. Theses and from governmental administrations,
research centres, the White Nile Scheme Companies and Ministry of
Agriculture and Forests … etc.
For primary data, two types of questionnaires will be designed.
Type one is a farmer's questionnaire for the owners and rentals in the
scheme. The second being a household questionnaire for the targeted
population (people inhabiting the study area). This is mainly to collect
cross-sectional data for the season 2002 – 2003.
1.9.1.2 Sampling technique: Historically, the northern (Ed-Duiem)
region had been dominated by schemes established by the government,
while the majority of the schemes in (Kosti) region were established by
the private sector. Although there is no clear-cut line of demarcation
between the regions, it is hypothesized that, tenants in the different
regions, have different attitudes towards agricultural work. The
justification for this hypothesis stems from the assumption that, the
regions are of different ethnic groups and accordingly different
population characteristics.
For improving the precision of estimates and to avoid bias in
selection, a multi–stage stratified random sample, in which the population
of the White Nile farmers is divided into two strata, was used. This
resulted in Ed-Duiem and Kosti stratum. The use of stratification is
justified by the existence of the above-mentioned differences between the
strata and the belief that, each stratum is relatively more or less
homogenous.
At later stage of stratification, from Ed-Duiem stratum, which
consists of two regions namely Um Gar and Abgar, three schemes are
selected randomly; Wakara, Um Gar and El-Ain have been selected. In
addition, from Kosti stratum, which consists of four regions namely Am
jalala, Algaiger, Rabak and Um Hany, three schemes are selected
randomly, Khour Agwal, Gezira Abba and Um Hany.
At a further stage of stratification and for the purpose of the study,
the simple random sampling is used for the selection of respondents from
each scheme since lists of tenants are available in the headquarters of the
concerned schemes. The selection was then carried out with the help of
random numbers.
1.9.1.3 Sample size:
The sample size to be chosen is a trade-off between the level of
precision aimed at and the resources available in terms of time, cost and
other facilities.
The sample size determined according to the formula:
n=
KV
D
Where:
K = Z value (the normal deviation of 0.9 probability).
V = the estimated standard deviation of out put in the area of the
study, which assume to be 2.39 according to Abdel-Rahim (1989).
D = the magnitude of the difference to be detected "significant
level" (0.05).
So according to the formula above the sample size was:
n=
1.654 (2.39)
0.05
= 78.631
= 80 respondents.
1.9.2 Methods of analysis:
The analytical techniques to test the above hypotheses include:
1. Descriptive statistics to present the bio-data of the respondents
include:
mean,
standard
deviation,
percentage,
frequency
distribution and tabular.
2. Private profitability of crops for main crops cultivated in the area
and comparing different crops to achieve the best ones.
The coefficient of private profitability (CPP) shows the extent to which
the production of a crop is profitable or not profitable for the producer.
Coefficient of private profitability is of primary interest to the individual
producers.
CPP =
Total revenue per feddan at farm-gate
Total production cost at farm-gate
A coefficient of less than one (CPP < 1.00) indicates that it is not
profitable to the producer to produce that product as the particular
productivity level.
3. Multiple regressions to investigate the main constrains of
agricultural production in WNS.
1.10 Organization of the study:
The study will consist of five chapters:
Chapter one: An introductory chapter includes general information,
background; statement of the problem summarizes the problems facing
the study area, justification to explore the reasons behind the choice of
the research topic, objectives of the study, hypotheses, methodologies and
organization of the study.
Chapter two: Deals with literature review and background, it
concentrates on various aspect of environmental degradation and includes
the causes of environmental degradation in Sudan, food security, poverty
and the role of agriculture to alleviate poverty.
Chapter three: descriptive chapter deals with descriptive procedures to
assess the main characteristics of parameter and presents causes and
consequences
of
environmental
degradation
and
non-sustainable
development in the area.
Chapter four: Results analysis and discussion of crop profitability.
Chapter five: Impact of environmental factors and poverty on food
crops.
Chapter six: Conclusions and recommendations.
CHAPTER TWO
LITERATURE REVIEW
2.1 Environmental Degradation:
2.1.1 Environment as a global crisis:
In recent years it is common to talk about global problems,
although environmental concern–or more properly concern about
problems caused by development–first arose on a local scale in the
expanding industrial economics of the North, where such problems are as
love canal and, later, seveso were seen as local, despite there seriousness
(David, 1996).
In the mid – 1990's, some 30 years after evidence of trans-border
pollution began to accumulate, it does indeed seem appropriate to talk in
terms of a global crisis. A considerable amount of evidence is now
available to prove that if unsustainable development continues, it will be
at the cost of even greater human suffering world wide, and will create
even more serious and pervasive ecological damage to the biosphere.
Such evidence is documented in great detail in a range of
publications–U.N. Agency reports "UNEP, UNDP and FAO", World
Bank reports …etc.–from the mass of statistics three issues standout:
●
The increase in human related activities and its impacts on the
resources:
Since 1900 the world's population has tripled and global industrial
production has increased 50 times.
Some 80 % of the increase in
industrial production has occurred since 1950 (Mac Neill, 1989 cited in
Reid, 1996). Throughout much of the century, there have been
accelerating increases in the consumption of both renewable and
nonrenewable resources. Agricultural production has risen dramatically
(but so have desertification, soil erosion and the salinization of productive
lands). It has been estimated that humanity now consumes about 40% of
total terrestrial photosynthetic production (Reid, 1996).
Over recent decades, these increases have been accompanied by
accelerating rates of deforestation, declined in fish stocks, loss of
agricultural land, loss of soil, depletion of fresh water, loss of habitats,
loss of species and loss of biodiversity. These losses in natural resources
are paralleled by a loss of human diversity in many skills and in many
areas (e.g. cultural diversity). While many of the impacts of these changes
appear to be most graphically illustrated in the poorer countries, there are
by no means confined to tropical regions. These unsustainable trends can
be represented by the annotated sketch graphs in figure (2.1).
These accelerating trends have been punctuated by dramatic
events, the natural disasters (flood, drought, disturbance of the weather
patterns and famine) which seem to follow each other with increasing
frequency. During the 1970's the death toll from such events increased six
fold over the preceding decade (WCED, 1987).
Even more serious is the evidence that the combined effects of
resource depletion on a massive scale and the global diffusion of waste
emissions (particularly greenhouse gases and chlorofluorocarbon)
represent another order of ecological damage.
The accumulated evidence makes it increasingly plain that
environmental problems have been problems of development all along.
The sheer weight of the evidence of ecological damage leads more and
more people to doubt seriously weather the end justifies the means.
● Growing Inequity Between Rich and Poor:
The global situation is represented by the graph in figure (2.2)
which shows the distribution of world income at the beginning of the
1990's. The disparities in income are matched by many other inequities,
including the inequitable consumption of resources, as shown in table
(2.1). These inequities mean that, for the poorest life is a daily
confrontation with a reality which is hardly imaginable to most
northerners but which exists on a massive scale. It is estimated that over a
billion people (approximately 20 % of the world's population) exists in
conditions of extreme poverty, lacking adequate nutrition, access to safe
drinking water, sanitation, health care and housing. Children are at
particular risk from these deprivatation. A child born in the South is on
average about 15 – 20 times less likely to survive beyond the age of five
than a child in the North. About 4 million of the children who die before
the age of five in the South each year die of diseases caused by lack of
safe water and sanitation (Elhot, 1994). More
Table (2.1): Consumption of selected items, North / South
Item
Share percent
ADR
EDR
North
South
North / South
North / South
Meat
64
36
6
52
Cereals
48
52
3
6
Round wood
46
54
1
6
Paper, etc.
81
19
14
115
Fertilizer
60
40
5
6
Iron and steel
80
20
13
22
Cars
92
8
24
320
Electricity
81
19
13
46
CO2
70
30
8
27
Notes: The average disparity ratio (ADR) is the ration of per capita consumption levels in
North and South. For example, on average a person in the North eats six times as much meat
as a person in the South. The extreme disparity ratio (EDR) is the ratio between the riches and
poorest countries, using the USA and Indian. Thus on average and American eats 52 times as
much meat as an Indian, the Eastern European countries are included in the North, and the
newly industrialized countries of Asia are included in the South. The ADR is therefore
smaller than the real disparities between many European countries and the low income
countries of Asia and Africa.
Source: Parikh, et al. (1991). Quoted in Reid, 1996.
and more people try to grow staple food on unsustainable soil and have to
travel further and further for fuel wood and water. Declining yields,
exhausted soils and the increasing marginalization of the landless poor
mean increasing rates of migration to settlements around cities. Even in
the remotest areas, indigenous groups find their livelihoods threatened.
Moreover, in some countries, repressive regimes deny their citizens
human rights or deprive them of civil liberties. This is not, however, a
static situation, the plight of the poorest, relative to the richest, has been
worsening over recent decades. The gap continues to widen as table (2.2)
indicates (David, 1996).
Table (2.2): Ratio of income of richest 20% to poorest 20% of world
population
Years
Ratio
1960
30 : 1
1970
32 : 1
1980
45 : 1
1989
59 : 1
1991
61 : 1
Source: UNDP, 1991 and UNDP, 1994.
● Population Growth:
The world population of almost six billion is now rising by over 90
million a year. It has more than doubled since 1950 and may double
again. It is estimated that, because of the phenomenon known as
"demographic momentum" world population will not stabilize till the
year 2040 at a figure of some where between 8 billion (the UN's low
projection) and 14 billion (the UN's high projection) (WECD, 1987).
Despite significant falls in the rate of increase in some countries, "a head
lie four decades of the fastest growth in human numbers in all history"
(Reid, 1996).
It is almost impossible to contemplate such figures without relating
them to the question of food supplies. While it is accepted that at present
the world produces enough food to feed the present population (despite
and estimated one billion suffering from chronic malnutrition), there will
have to be at least a doubling of the food production in 1993 if the
population of 2040 is to be adequately fed. Yet per capita food production
has declined in many countries since 1980; world per capita grain
production continued to increase till 1990, since when it has dropped
(Brown, et al. 1994); and it seems doubtful if increased applications of
nitrogenous fertilizers will increase yields, by the amount require
(although other developments, e.g. in biotechnology and genetic
engineering, may have this potential). Such considerations have let Paul
& Ann Ehrlich, authors of the population explosion, to assert, "arresting
global population growth should be second only in importance to
avoiding nuclear war in humanity's agenda (Ehrlich & Ehrlich, 1990).
2.1.2 Meta problem:
Some commentators use the term Meta – problem to refer to a
cluster of very closely interconnected problems. e.g., in some tropical
countries soil erosion, decline in soil fertility and productivity, lack of
labour, the consequent failure to maintain, say, soil terraces or irrigation
channels, poor management of water sources and encroaching
desertification are all really part of one larger problem of inappropriate –
or unsustainable – rural development. Each aspect of the problem is so
closely related to the others that any attempt to solve it is unlikely to be
successful unless the others are treated simultaneously.
The term Meta problem is also a useful way of referring to very
large underlying problems. These usually represent powerful forces,
which generate a number of problems on different scales and indifferent
guises. It is possible to identify a number of meta problems e.g., rate of
population growth in the South, over population in the North, poverty,
unequal access to resources, systems of land tenure and ownership, lack
of democratic rights and the western model of development.
2.1.3 Environment and poverty:
Rural poverty is generally seen as both a cause and consequence of
environmental degradation in most developing countries. The relationship
is, however, complex. Although there were many instance in recent years
where the poor over exploited and irreversibly degraded their natural
resource base, where was also evidence of environmentally sound and
often innovative ways in which the poor secured their livelihood. (FAO,
1993).
In many parts in the world, it is the poor who suffer most from
environmental degradation, from climate change, from deforestation,
from drought, disease and from wide spread desertification. These
environmental conditions can, at worst threaten their very survival.
Environment is inevitably global, and what happen in one part of the glop
has inescapable effects elsewhere, and on our common future. No society
can afford environmental degradation (Reed, 2001).
In 1987, WCED published the report: "our common future" it is
goes on to trace the relationship between environment and development:
"many forms of development erode the environmental resources on which
they must be based, and environmental degradation can undermine
economic development". There are also reciprocal links between poverty
and the environment, poverty being recognized "as a major cause and
effect of global environmental problems" (WCED, 1987). It is the high
level of consumption of resources, largely in the North but also among
the elites in the South, that accounts for development's impact on both
planet and people, and that forces the poor in the South exhaust resources
and destroys ecosystems in their attempts to maintain their existence.
2.1.4. Energy and environment:
There are multiple links between energy and the environment;
between wood use and deforestation and desertification, between air
pollution and the choice of fuel technology for domestic use, industry,
transport...etc. Climatic change is in timely related to energy supply and
use (Mann, 2001).
It has been estimated that almost one-third of world's populationaround 2 billion people- does not has access to adequate energy services;
many of these rely on fuel wood and animal dung for the majority of their
energy needs. With population increases, the number without access to
adequate energy services will increase. Yet energy resources are plentiful,
special when one considers renewable energies such as those from the
sun, wind, water and the earth (ibid, 2001).
Energy is essential aspect of human life. Food must be grown and
cooked, water moved from its source, goods carried to and from the
market. For the poor many of the basic energy inputs are currently
human, such as those for water and wood gathering requiring precious
time and effort, particularly for women and children. Alternatives to
human power can free time and radically improve basic livelihood,
helping to alleviate poverty. Improved energy services also lay the
foundations for the development of new enterprises and improved
opportunities for access to health services, education and communication.
One might say that improve energy services brings choice (ibid, 2001).
2.1.5 Environmental degradation in developing countries:
Recently environmental degradation has become a matter of central
concern for both industrialized as well as developing countries.
Environmental conservation, far from being a luxury is an essential
ingredient for maintaining the national resource based upon which most
nations depend for their continued economic development. (Ward Ford
and Partow, 1989).
Developing countries are facing degradation not only in their
physical environment, but also in their social environment. Degradation
physical environment results into misuse of natural resources, which
cause reduction in social environment quality. This in turn results in
hunger, poverty, high mortality and morbidity, sanitation and migration.
Moreover, in those countries environmental problems and poverty are
separable.
Most of the developing countries are similar in social and political
structure, lack of institutional capacity and political structure and absence
of public investment. In 1987, many of the developing countries
particularly in Africa were facing devastating drought and prolonged
famine and declining stable food production. These carried the
phenomenon of environmental refugees and provoked rural–urban
migration.
In effect, natural resources essential for human survival and
sustainable development are increasingly being destroyed and / or being
depleted. At the same time, human demand for those resources is growing
faster than the rate of their replenishment it was reported that if the
current rate of land degradation continues, close to one third of the world
arable land will be destroyed in the next thirty years. (I.U.C.N., 1986).
In Africa, north of the equator, 35 percent of arable land is believed
to be affected by winds or water erosion or silinization.
Furthermore, in the developing countries productive land become
scarce since the loss of forests together with rising population pressure on
agriculture, which forced farmers to shorten their fallow period,
ultimately led to degrading the productive capacity of the land (WRI,
1985).
2.1.5 Environmental Degradation in Sudan:
Sudan like other developing countries has been seriously affected
by environmental degradation during the last decades, mainly in the form
of deforestation, drought and desert creep. In fact the Sudan was once a
home of great coniferous forests in the remote geological past – forests,
specially in the northern parts of the Sudan are constantly changing from
the coniferous forest and moist tropical forests to the present denuded
sandy undulating plains. The different national governments in Sudan
exhibited enormous concern and awareness with the environmental issues
and the importance of environmental conservation measures.
The major environmental problems in Sudan stem from the virtual
neglect of environmental consideration in policies, strategies and plans
for the development of the country. In these, there is no adequate
consideration for the simplest environmental principles pertaining to the
proper utilization of available resources for development purposes. As a
result, the country has undergone tremendous environmental degradation
during the last four decades.
The major environmental problems of the Sudan are depletion and
misuse of natural resources through over cultivation, overgrazing, and
deforestation, desertification and drought, environmental refugees and
displacement, misuse of agricultural chemicals and wild life destruction.
2.1.5.1 Over cultivation:
Over-cultivation refers to the expansion in cropping both under
rain-fed and/or irrigated agriculture and shortening of follow periods.
Grainger (1990) reported that over-cultivation occurs when farmers try to
use land more intensively regardless of the natural fertility of the soil,
damages its structure and exposes it to erosion. In dry land areas overcultivation is caused by either expanding cultivation of cash crops or
irrigated food crops as a response to outside pressures or because these
areas are unable to produce enough food to sustain the high and
increasing population demand.
2.1.5.2 Overgrazing:
Overgrazing occurs where the number of livestock is increased i.e.
too many animals are grazed on the same area of rangeland leading to the
destruction of vegetation and the compaction and erosion of soil
(Grainger, 1990). Causes of overgrazing in Sudan include the enormous
increase in livestock particularly sheep and cattle, deterioration of
rangeland, settlement of nomads in order to provide services; and the
provision of waterholes (Boon, 1990). Desert Encroachment Control and
Rehabilitation Program (D.E.C.A.R.P) (1976) indicated that the livestock
number in the Sudan increased nearly four times in the period (19571966). This increase was only due to development of more water points
and improvement in veterinary surveys. Grainger (1990), reported that
livestock density can rise in four main ways which include reduction of
grazing area for cropping, nomads settlement scheme, the breakdown of
traditional controls on the grazing of range land and herds increment.
2.1.5.3 Deforestation:
Deforestation means the loss of trees with their many functions
(Boon, 1990). Deforestation is attributed partly to clearing of land for
cultivation and partly to fuel wood consumption (Noordwijk, 1984).
Boon (1990) cited : "the major causes of destruction of trees include the
following : drought, clearing for agriculture, charcoal making for urban
area, fuel wood collection for rural areas, construction of housing,
grazing pressure of livestock, excessive cutting of branches for fodder,
uncontrolled fire e.g. improving grazing, clearing lands for crops and
honey collection".
According to the FAO between 1990 and 2000 (13.7) million
hectares of forest per year disappeared from developing countries
(Ngangue, 2001).
Energy in Sudan is mainly obtained by felling trees 70 percent for
firewood, charcoal production, mechanized farming expansion resulted in
removal of large area of forest. Misuse of land and mismanagement of
forest decreased forestland. In all Sudan that practice common, removal
of forest exposed the soil erosion and is the main reason for
desertification (Boon, 1990).
2.1.5.4 Desertification:
Recently the issue of desertification in both developed and
developing countries has received much concern worldwide is considered
as one of the major environmental problem facing the world. The term
desertification has been given different definitions among them
"desertification is a process of environment degradation" (Bayoumi,
1984). Another definition of desertification is " a process that lead to a
reduction of plant biomass and carrying capacity to support crops and
livestock" (U.N. 1977), also UNCED defined it as "desertification is land
degradation in arid, semi-arid, and dry sub-humid areas resulting from
various factor including climatic variations and human activities.
Desertification affects one sixth of the world's population, 70% of all dry
land, amounting to 3.6 billion hectares, and one quarter of the total land
area of the world. The most obvious impact of desertification, in addition
to widespread poverty, is the degradation of 3.3 billion hectares of the
total area of rangeland, constituting 73% of the rangeland with a low
potential for human and animal carrying capacity ; decline in soil fertility
and soil structure on about 47% of the dry land areas constituting
marginal rainfed cropland; and the degradation of irrigated cropland,
amounting to 30% of the dry land areas with a high population density
and agricultural potential.
In combating desertification on rangeland, rain-fed cropland and
irrigated land, preventative measures should be launched in areas which
are not yet affected or are only slightly affected by desertification;
corrective measures should be implemented to sustain the productivity of
moderately desertified land; and rehabilitative measures should be taken
to recover severely or very severely desertified dry lands
The
priority
in
combating
desertification
should
be
the
implementation of preventive measures for land that are not yet degraded,
or which are only slightly degraded. However, the severely degraded
areas should not be neglected. In combating desertification and drought,
the participation of local communities, rural organization, national
governments, non-governmental organization and international and
regional organizations is essential.
2.2. Food security:
World Bank defines Food security as the access by all people at all
times to enough food for an active, healthy life (Abdul-Hai, 1996). Its
essential elements are the availability of food and the ability to acquire it.
Food insecurity, in turn, is the lack of access to enough food. There are
two kinds of insecurity: chronic and transitory. Chronic food insecurity is
a continuously inadequate diet caused by the inability to acquire food. It
affects household that persistently lack the ability either to buy enough
food or to produce their own. Transitory food insecurity is temporary
decline in household access to enough food. It results from instability in
food prices, food production, or household income-and, in its worst form
it produces famine (Maxwell, 1991).
Maxwell reported that a country and people are food secure when
their food system operates efficiently in such away as to remove the fear
that there will not be enough to eat. He argues that food security will be
achieved when equitable growth ensures that (Vulnerable) groups have
sustainable livelihood...in addition... food security requires the efficient
and equitable operation of the food system(Maxwell, 1991). In particular,
food security will be achieved when the poor and vulnerable, particularly,
women, children and those living in marginal areas, have secure access to
the food and want (Abdul-Hai, 1996).
A food system can be defined as Maxwell pointed: a food system is
the combination of agro-ecological and socio-economic processes, which
determines the production, marketing and consumption of food (Maxwell,
1991).
A food system should in principle be efficient and equitable.
"Efficient" means that all stages in the food chain, from production to
final consumption, should be efficient in a social-welfare sense.
Production policies should take account of dynamic comparative
advantage; marketing margins should provide no more than normal
profits in the long term; and consumer prices should reflect real scarcity
values. "Equitable" means that the benefits of production should be
distributed equally and that food should be available to all (ibid, 1991).
As with a farming system, a food system is the product of
determinants, which may be exogenous or endogenous. Endogenous
factors will include the characteristics of the natural resource base and the
society, which draws upon it, as well as the range of government policies,
which modify the interaction between environment, economy and
society; exogenous factors will include the operation of world markets for
agricultural inputs, food and alternative agricultural product (Ibid, 1991).
2.2.1. Food Shortages and Emergencies:
Food shortage caused by natural and human caused disasters
continues to affect many countries in all regions of the world. As of early
2001, there were 33 countries and more than 60 million people facing
food emergencies of varying intensity (FAO, 2001).
In eastern Africa, some 13 million people still rely on food
assistance because of the lingering effects of last year's drought, coupled
with conflict in some parts. The situation is particularly severe in Eritrea,
Ethiopia, Kenya and Sudan, where recent drought have sharply reduced
food production and killed large numbers of livestock. However, recent
rains, and the near-normal rainfall forecast for most eastern Africa during
the March to May 2001 cropping season, have improved the food outlook
for the sub-region. In the Kenya, the severe drought in 1999/2000
seriously undermined the food security of nearly 4.4 million people. In
Eritrea, more than 1.8 million people are in need of urgent assistance
owing to displacement by the war with neighbouring Ethiopia and to
drought. The outlook for the 2001 agricultural season remain bleak, with
farmer so far unable to return to their farms and large tracts of land still
inaccessible because of the risk of landmines. In the Sudan, serious food
shortages have emerged because of drought. The continuing civil conflict
is aggravating the situation by impeding rural households' cultivation
activities (FAO, 2001).
2.3. Poverty:
Poverty refers to the inability to attain a minimal standard of living.
Criteria for assessing minimum nutritional needs and other necessities
vary from country to country. Since they reflect country-specific
conditions, national priorities and concept of welfare and rights, the
minimum acceptable level of consumption. The poverty thresholdgenerally rises as national income increases. Despite difficulties in
selecting a single poverty threshold, such a threshold is necessary in order
to make cross-country comparisons (FAO, 1993).
Poverty can be said to exist in a given society when at least one
person does not have a level of well-being deemed to constitute a
reasonable minimum by the standards of that society.
A poverty line is the starting point for poverty analysis, the
yardstick used in assessing well-being and determining who is poor and
who is not. People are counted as poor when their measured standard of
living (generally in either income or consumption) is below the minimum
acceptable level. The poverty line is essentially defined as the value of
income or consumption necessary for the minimum standard of nutrition
and other necessities.
Poverty lines can be defined in absolute or relative terms. Absolute
poverty refers to the position of an individual or household in relation to a
poverty line whose real value is fixed overtime. Relative poverty refers to
their position vis-à-vis the average income in the country. For poverty
assessments, the concept of absolute poverty is preferred because it
facilitates comparative analysis. However, at the same time, it is unclear
whether "a minimum acceptable level" can be given absolute meaning.
2.3.1. The role of agriculture to alleviate poverty:
The extend and depth of poverty in the developing world at the
close of the 20th century is astonishing. About 1.3 billion people – 30
percent of the population – live in absolute poverty, with only a dollar a
day or less per person to meet food, shelter and other needs. Not
surprisingly, hunger, malnutrition and associated diseases are widespread:
more than 800 million people do not have access to sufficient food to lead
healthy, productive lives; millions more lives on the edge of hunger; and
more than 180 million preschool children are significantly under-weight
for their age, sowing the seeds for future food insecurity (Neumann et al.
1999).
Absolute poverty is deeply entrenched in South Asia and SubSaharan Africa where two-fifths of the populations are absolutely poor
(Table 2.3). Poverty is a rural phenomenon in most of the developing
world, specially the low-income countries. The rural poor makeup more
than 75 percent of the poor in many Sub Saharan Africa and Asian
countries (ibid, 1999).
Table (2.3): Absolute poverty, 1993
Region
People living below US$1 per day
Number (million)
Percent
South Asia
514.7
43.1
East Asia and the Pacific
445.8
26.0
Sub-Saharan Africa
218.6
39.1
Latin America and the Caribbean
109.6
23.5
Eastern Europe and Central Asia
14.5
3.5
Middle East and North Africa
10.7
4.1
1.313.9
29.4
Total
Source : World Bank, (1996). Poverty reduction and the World Bank
CHAPTER THREE
Socio-economics Characteristics of respondent
This chapter presents and discusses the empirical results of the
study. It presents the socio-economic characteristics of respondents, the
institutional services, environmental situation, economic activity and
nutritional status in the area.
3.1. Social characteristics of respondent families:
Production, consumption pattern and decision-making are partially
affected by size, age and sex distribution of producer household members
(Elgozouli, 1998).
Table (3.1) shows the respondents family characteristics. The
family structure in this area is regarded as important factor that influence
the respondents' contribution to economic activities, with regard to family
characteristic in this study the average family size is 6.7 & 5.65 persons
for farmers and non-farmers respectively.
Yassin (1996) cited that tenants' age is assumed to be one of the
factors that determine productivity; also Atta (1990) reported that the
distribution of the farmers' population in term of age helps in the
determination
of
their
potential
labor
force
qualitatively
and
quantitatively. Considering respondent age table (3.1) shows the average
respondent age is 54 & 42 years for farmers and non-farmers
respectively.
With regard to respondent age distribution table (3.2) shows that
most of respondents were within the productive age 15- 60 year, 66.3%
&91.3% for farmers and non-farmers respectively and only 33.7% and
8.7% were above 60 years old; this result show that there is a
considerable number (one third) of the farmers were above the productive
age which will affect the productivity of the farmers, also this result
revealed that agriculture was been un-incentive job so the majority of
young's producers works in other fields rather than agriculture.
Table (3.3) shows that about 82.5% of respondent were married;
and few of them 21.2% have one wife. With regard to classification of
respondent 92.5% &72.5% of farmers and non-farmers respectively were
married which reflect that married farmers were more than non-farmers
one's, this result imply that farmers were better than non-farmers by
means of income opportunity and settlement.
3.2. Respondent level of Education:
Education is considered as a human investment. It helps the
tenants to improve their cultural, techniques and adopt new idea (Atta,
1990).
The level of farmer education and expertise are assumed to have
significant effects on the output of the agricultural crops (El feil, 1993).
Through Education farmer's knowledge and skills can be
improved and many researcher have investigated the relationship between
farmers' education level and their willingness to adopt new methods and
techniques seeking for higher rate of output, and they have found the
educational level were positively associated with increased efficiency
(Elshafie, 1992).
Table (3.1): Respondent family characteristic
Average
Characteristic
Farmers
Non farmers
Respondent Age
54.1
42.1
Family size
6.7
5.65
Years of Education
4.7
6.6
Source : Field survey, 2002
Table (3.2): Age distribution of respondent
Age interval
Farmers
Non farmers
Freq.
%
Freq.
%
22-34
3
3.8
27
33.8
35-47
23
28.8
28
35
48-60
27
33.8
18
22.5
61-73
23
28.8
7
8.8
74-86
4
5
0
0
Source : Field survey, 2002
Table (3.3): Respondent marital status:
Marital status
Farmers
Non farmers
Freq.
%
Freq.
%
Bachelor
6
7.5
22
27.5
Married with one wife
55
68.8
49
61.3
Married with two wife
19
23.8
6
7.5
Married with three wife
0
0
3
3.8
Source : Field survey, 2002
Table (3.4) shows that 70% & 85% of farmers and non-farmers
respectively have some sort of education, among those 67.9% & 82.4% of
farmers and non-farmers were received formal education and 32.1%
&17.6% with informal education (Khalwa) and 20% of farmer with
higher and university education, and 33.8% of non-farmer with the same
levels of education. However, only 30% & 15 % of farmers and nonfarmers respectively were illiterate. This result show that the non-farmers
engage in education more than farmers as a result of farmers demand for
family labor to participate in the agricultural activities which reduces the
chance for farmer family to continuous their education or in sometime to
engage in the schools. Also the average years of education of non-farmer
are more than farmer one's, table (3.1) show that farmers average years of
education is 4.6 years, although the non-farmer one is 6.6 years, the
difference may attributed to farmers need for more labor for different
agricultural activities and livestock care, which may force or not allow
them to attend schools. This results raising the probability that nonfarmer in this area have higher capability than farmer enabling them to
accept, adopt and participate in the environmental programme; this result
reflect the need for agricultural extension services and it is more
comparable with what was mentioned by Ruttan (1987) when he said "in
fact one of the major production constraints in the developing countries
was found to be the lack of knowledge about the importance of certain
modern inputs which was assumed to be due to lack of extension services
and farmer education programme as general".
Table (3.4): Respondent educational level:
Education level
Farmers
Non farmers
Freq.
%
Freq.
%
Illiterate
24
30
12
15
Khalwa
18
22.5
12
15
Elementary
22
27.5
29
36.3
Higher secondary
12
15
21
26.3
University
4
5
6
7.5
Source : Field survey, 2002
Table (3.5): Agricultural credit and extension services:
Type of service
Freq.
%
Received Credit services
21
26.3
Did not received Credit
59
73.7
Received Extension services
19
23.8
Did not received Extension services
61
76.2
Source : Field survey, 2002
Table (3.6): Project management:
Project management
Freq.
%
Good
52
65
Moderate
18
22.5
Bad
10
12.5
Source : Field survey, 2002
3.3. Institutional services:
Considering extension services table (3.5) show that 67.3% of
farmers interviewed farmers reported no existence of any sort of
extension services, and only 23.8% of them received extension services;
this result is comparable with what was mentioned by Ruttan (1987)
above. In addition, farmers reported that 73.8% of them did not receive
any credit, but only 26.2% have received some sort of credit. These
results reflect the inefficient role of the institution to providing
agricultural services, and this similar to what was reported by Elfeil
(1993) that he said, "the inefficient agricultural finance is one of the main
factors curtailing the agricultural production in north Sudan".
Table (3.6) show that the majority of farmers 65% reported that
their project management were good, and only 22.5% reported that their
project management were bad and 12.5% said their management were
moderate.
3.4. Environmental services:
All respondent in the area reported that there was no any forest
cultivation or trees planting in the recent years in the area. With regard to
farmers table (3.7) show that the main reasons for non-agroforestry
application were the shortage of irrigation 74% of farmers - 50% of them
report only the shortage of irrigation is the main causes of nonagroforestry and 24% refers the reasons to shortage of irrigation and they
afraid from been birds aviary, also 21% said that it did not include in the
rotation so they did not practice it and few farmers 5% reported that was
due to unprofitability and it was constraining cultivation.
Table (3.7): Reason of non-agroforestry application:
Reason
Freq.
%
Shortage of Irrigation
40
50
Not include in rotation
17
21.25
It constraint cultivation
2
2.5
Shortage of Irrigation and afraid from been Birds Nest
19
23.75
Not Profitable
2
2.5
Source : Field survey, 2002
Table (3.8): Source of cooking power:
Source
Freq.
%
Charcoal and Firewood
96
60
Gas
56
35
Animal dung
8
5
Source: Field survey, 2002
Table (3.9): Economic Activity:
Fundamental Job
Farmers
Non farmers
Freq.
%
Freq.
%
Merchant
6
7.5
3
3.75
Free work
2
2.5
8
10
Laborer
3
3.75
60
75
Governmental Officer
8
10
9
11.25
Farmer
61
76.25
0
0
Source : Field survey, 2002
Considering non-agroforestry practice with the result of table (3.8)
which shows that 60% of the respondents use forest products as cooking
power, which seem to be the main causes of disappeared trees cover in
the area and escape to have strong impact on desertification and
decreased productivity; 35% of respondent used gas and 5% used animal
dung as cooking power. This result is comparable with what Mann 2001
reported" it has been estimated that almost one- third of the world's
population does not have access to adequate energy services; many of
these rely on fuel wood and animal dung for the majority of their energy
need" and also he said that there are multiple links between energy and
the environment; between wood use and deforestation and desertification;
hence deforestation, soil erosion, desertification and pollution destroy the
means of subsistence in the study area and exacerbate the precarious
nature of existence.
3.5. Economic activities:
Table (3.9) shows that majority of farmers 76% the farm activity is
the main job for them and approximately 24% of them practice the
farming as secondary job. Nevertheless, the non-farmers most of them
75% were laborer in many field among them agriculture. This result
indicates that the agriculture has considerable role in the economic
activity in this area.
Considering the livestock ownership table (3.10) show that the farmers
owned livestock more than non-farmers 65% and 31.3%, respectively.
Table (3.10): Livestock Ownership:
Farmers
Marital status
Non farmers
Freq.
%
Freq.
%
Owned Livestock
52
65
25
31.25
Did not owned Livestock
28
35
55
68.75
Source : Field survey, 2002
Table (3.11): Kind of Livestock owned:
Kind of livestock
Farmers
Non farmers
Freq.
%
Freq.
%
Cow
23
44.23
6
24
Sheep
21
40.39
7
28
Goat
34
65.38
18
72
Donkey
32
61.52
6
24
Source : Field survey, 2002
Table (3.12): Impact of livestock on income:
Livestock affect
Freq.
%
Increase the income
71
92.2
Did not affect the income
6
7.8
Source : Field survey, 2002
Those who owned Cow were 44.23% and 24% for farmers and
non-farmers respectively and who owned Sheep were 40.39% and 28%
respectively and who owned Goats were 65.38% and 72% respectively
table (3.11) which indicate that the farmers were better than non-farmers
in diversifying their income sources, most of respondents who owned
livestock reported that the livestock has increased their income 92.2%
and only 7.8% reported that livestock did not affect their income table
(3.12).
Table (3.13) shows the production constraints, about 89% reported
that irrigation was among production constraints and 92.5% reported that
lack of finance constraining the agricultural production, 90% reported
that the lack of inputs, 11% reported extension services and few reported
that marketing and management among the factor that constraining
agricultural practices.
3.6. Nutritional Status:
Considering the numbers of meal per a day table (3.14) shows that
the majority of respondent in the area 77.5% had three meals per a day
and only 22.5% of them had two meals per a day. With regard to meal
component table (3.15) shows that there were only 38% with daily meat
in their meal, and 50% of them sometimes eat meat and 11.25% without
any meat in their meals. The result reflect only 27.5% of respondents
have meal with complete component, this small percentage indicate that
the people in this area were insufficient to make self satisfaction for their
basic nutritional needs by means of food affordability or\and
accessibility.
Table (3.13) Production constraints
Production Constraints
Freq
%
Shortage of irrigation
71
88.75
Lack of finance
74
92.5
Lack of inputs
72
90
Bad management
5
6.25
Extension services
9
11.25
Weak marketing
6
7.5
Freq
%
Two meals
36
22.5
Three meals
124
77.5
Freq
%
Meat, starch, vegetables, and sugar
44
27.5
Meat, starch and vegetables
18
11.25
Starch
12
7.5
Starch and vegetables
6
3.75
Starch and sometimes meats and vegetables
66
41.25
Sugar, starch and sometimes meats and vegetables
14
8.75
Source : Field survey, 2002
Table (3.14) Number of meals per day
Number of meals per day
Source : Field survey, 2002
Table (3.15) Meals components
Meals components
Source : Field survey, 2002
CHAPTER FOUR
RESULTS OF THE CROP PROFITABILITY
This chapter discusses the production costs, yields, farm gate
prices, estimation of the gross returns and gross margins and coefficient
of private profitability of the main field crops produced namely, dura,
wheat, tomato, okra and onion to assess the farmer attitude towards
farming practice and their rationality. In this chapter, average costs,
yields and prices were those of 2001-2002 season.
4.1. Production costs:
Production cost is the cost of producing a certain amount of
product in a particular period. For purpose of calculating production
costs, certain items are to be determined. These include land preparation,
seeds, irrigation, fertilizer, harvesting and threshing, sacks and strings,
Zakat and other costs (transportation and marketing). The average
production cost for dura, wheat, tomato, okra and onion is shown in table
(4.1).
4.1.1. Land preparation cost:
The land preparation is done by tractor, animal traction and
sometimes manually. The tendency is to use tractor for land preparation.
On the average, the cost of land preparation for dura, wheat, tomato, okra
and onion where found to be LS 35291/feddan, LS 23880/feddan, LS
47500/feddan, LS 47500/feddan and LS 52300/feddan, respectively. The
cost of land preparation for vegetables (tomato and okra) and onion are
higher than those of dura and wheat. This may be due to the fact that the
vegetables and onion require a good seedbed preparation (field survey,
2002).
The share of land preparation in the total cost of production was
found to be 22.44%, 8.27%, 21.74%, 25.82% and 16.63% for dura,
wheat, tomato, okra and onion, respectively table (4.2).
4.1.2. Seeds cost:
Due to the shortage of improved seeds, some farmers retain their
seeds from the previous harvest. Also in 2002 season, farmers obtain
seeds from the local market and State Ministry of Agriculture (field
survey, 2002). On average the cost of seeds was found to be Ls
5930/feddan, Ls 38150/feddan, Ls 54000/feddan, Ls 21500/feddan and
Ls 25000/feddan for dura, wheat, tomato, okra and onion, respectively
table (4-1). The highest seeds cost is that of tomato followed by that of
wheat, onion, okra and finally dura. The tomato seeds cost was found to
be the highest as its seeds become very expensive during sowing time.
This is also true for wheat and onion, which have higher cost of seeds
than okra and dura.
Dura seeds cost was found to be the lowest because of the low
price of its seeds than other crops. The percentage share of seeds cost was
found to be 3.77%, 13.22%, 24.71%, 11.68% and 7.95% for dura, wheat,
tomato, okra and onion, respectively table (4-2).
4.1.3. Irrigation cost:
Irrigation cost is positively related to the number of irrigations.
This cost includes cost of pump operation.
The average total cost of irrigation for dura, wheat, tomato, okra
and onion was found to be Ls 35640/feddan, Ls 113470/feddan, Ls
65000/feddan, Ls 52000/feddan and Ls 58000/feddan, respectively table
(4.1). The highest average cost of irrigation is that of wheat followed by
tomato, onion, okra and finally dura.
The wheat seems to have the highest irrigation cost than other
crops because wheat is highly sensitive to irrigation and need frequent
irrigation. Hence, it receives more number of irrigations per season.
The percentage share of irrigation cost in the total cost of
production was found to be 22.67%, 39.30%, 29.75%, 28.26% and
18.45% for dura, wheat, tomato, okra and onion, respectively table (4.2).
4.1.4. Fertilizer cost:
On average, the cost of fertilizer was found to be Ls 12330/feddan,
Ls 41670/feddan, Ls37000/feddan, Ls26000/feddan and Ls31700/feddan
for dura, wheat, tomato, okra and onion, respectively table (4.1). The
percentage share of fertilizer cost in the total cost of production was
found to be 7.84%, 14.43%, 16.93%, 14.13% and 10.08% for dura,
wheat, tomato, okra and onion, respectively table (4.2).
Table (4.1) the average production cost Ls/feddan
dura
Wheat
tomato
okra
Onion
Land preparation
35290
23880
47500
47500
52300
Seeds
5930
38150
54000
21500
25000
Irrigation
35640
113470
65000
52000
58000
Fertilizer
12330
41670
37000
26000
31700
Harvesting and threshing
36160
40180
10000
18000
40000
Sacks and strings
21250
17580
16000
85000
Zakat
2230
7410
Others
8400
6360
5000
Total
157230
288700
218500
Source : Field survey, 2002.
8450
3000
14000
184000 314450
Table (4.2): The percentage share of each item in the total cost of
production:
Dura
Wheat
Tomato
Okra
Onion
(%)
(%)
(%)
(%)
(%)
Land preparation
22.44
8.27
21.74
25.82
16.63
Seeds
3.77
13.22
24.71
11.68
7.95
Irrigation
22.67
39.30
29.75
28.26
18.45
Fertilizer
7.84
14.43
16.93
14.13
10.08
Harvesting and threshing
23.00
13.92
4.58
9.78
12.72
Sacks and strings
13.52
6.09
8.7
27.03
Zakat
1.42
2.57
Others
5.34
2.20
Source : Field survey, 2002.
2.69
2.29
1.63
4.45
4.1.5. Harvesting and threshing cost:
Dura, tomato, okra and onion were manually harvesting (cutting
and collection) and threshing but wheat was harvested and threshed
mechanically.
On average, the cost of harvesting and threshing was found to be
Ls 36160/feddan, Ls40180/feddan, Ls10000/feddan, Ls18000/feddan and
Ls40000/feddan for dura, wheat, tomato, okra and onion, respectively
table (4.1). The highest cost is that of wheat because it done
mechanically. The percentage share of harvesting and threshing were
found to be 23%, 13.92%, 4.58%, 9.78% and 12.72% for dura, wheat,
tomato, okra and onion, respectively table (4.2).
4.1.6. Sacks and Strings cost:
The cost of sacks per feddan is positively related to the yield per
feddan and the price of the sack. Accordingly the cost of sacks for dura,
wheat and onion was found to be Ls21250/feddan, Ls17580/feddan and
Ls85000/feddan, respectively table (4.1).The higher cost of sacks and
strings is that of onion because of its higher output per feddan compared
to other crops and the cost of sacks is positively related to the output as
mentioned. The percentage share of sacks and strings cost was found to
be 13.52%, 6.09%and 27.03% for dura, wheat and onion, respectively
table (4.2).
4.1.7. Zakat:
In the study area "Zakat" is usually not imposed on vegetables
(field survey, 2002). For dura, wheat and onion it paid about one-forty of
total production. Zakat cost varies according to yields and prices. On
average, the cost of zakat was found to be Ls2230/feddan, Ls7410/feddan
and Ls8450/feddan for dura, wheat, and onion, respectively table (4.1). In
this study, the highest cost of onion is due to the yield but in case of
wheat versus dura its attribute to the wheat prices. The percentage share
of zakat cost was found to be 1.42%, 2.57% and 2.69% for dura, wheat
and onion, respectively table (4.2).
4.1.8. Other cost:
The other cost included transportation and marketing costs. On
average, the other cost was found to be Ls8400/feddan, Ls6360/feddan,
Ls5000/feddan, Ls3000/feddan and Ls14000/feddan for dura, wheat,
tomato, okra and onion, respectively table (4.1). The percentage share of
the other cost was found to be 5.34%, 2.20%, 2.29%, 1.63% and 4.45%
for dura, wheat, tomato, okra and onion, respectively table (4.2).
4.1.9. Total variable cost of production:
The average total variable cost of production was found to be
Ls157230/feddan, Ls288700/feddan, Ls218500/feddan, Ls184000/feddan
and Ls314450/feddan for dura, wheat, tomato, okra and onion,
respectively.
The higher total cost of production was that of onion because of
high cost of sacks and irrigation. In addition, the higher cost of land
preparation and harvesting can be added to the first ones.
To identify the magnitude of each item in the total cost of
production for each crop the percentage itemized per feddan cost of
production was calculated table (4.2).
The main cost item for all crops is the irrigation cost, which
represented about 22.67%, 39.30%, 29.75%, 28.26% and 18.45% of the
total cost of production per feddan for dura, wheat, tomato, okra and
onion, respectively.
The highest cost items for dura is harvesting and threshing 23%
followed by irrigation 22.67%, land preparation 22.44%, sacks and
strings 13.52%, fertilizer 7.84%, others 5.34%, seeds 3.77% and finally
zakat (1.42%).
The highest cost item for wheat is irrigation 39.30% followed by
fertilizer 14.43%, harvesting 13.92%, seeds 13.22%, land preparation
8.27%, sacks 6.09%, zakat 2.57% and finally others (2.20%).
The highest cost item for tomato is irrigation 29.75% followed by
seeds 24.71%, land preparation 21.74%, fertilizer 16.93%, harvesting
4.58% and finally others (2.29%).
The highest cost item for okra is irrigation 28.26% followed by
land preparation 25.82%, fertilizer 14.13%, seeds 11.68%, harvesting
9.78% and finally other (1.63%)
The highest cost item for onion is sacks 27.03% followed by
irrigation 18.45%, land preparation 16.63%, harvesting 12.72%, fertilizer
10.08%, seeds 7.95% and finally others (4.45%).
4.2. Analysis of crop returns:
The average yield and price for 2001-2002 season were used in this
analysis.
4.2.1. Crop yield:
The average yield of dura, wheat, tomato, okra and onion were
found to be 6.39 sacks/feddan, 5.95sacks/feddan, 250baskets* /feddan, 32
bags**/feddan and 28.3sacks/feddan, respectively table (4.3).
The average yield mentioned by El-jak (2002) was 15 sacks/feddan,
10sacks/feddan, 350baskets*/feddan, 45bags**/feddan and 60sacks/feddan
for dura, wheat, tomato, okra and onion, respectively. Thus, the result
showed that the yield obtained was very low.
Solh (1996) reported that the average yield of wheat in Sudan is
generally low as it affected by many environmental and cultural practices.
The low yields could be attributed to low input use.
4.2.2. Farm gate prices:
Prices used in this study were the farm gate prices. Farm gate
prices are the price that the farmer receives for his crop when he sells his
product at the boundary of his farm. These prices vary considerably from
the market prices; the farmers always end up receiving price lower than
the market prices of their products. The farm gate prices used in this
study were collected during the field survey, 2002.
The average farm gate price obtained for all crops were found to be
Ls27800/sack, Ls49820/sack, Ls4000/baskets*, Ls25000/bags** and
Ls12000/sack
for dura, wheat, tomato, okra and onion, respectively table
*: Guffa
**:field
Internal
Kenana2002.
sugar polyethylene bags.
(4.4)
survey,
Intermediaries or local merchants usually buy the crops under the
study. The differences in farm gate prices for each crop among the
farmers was due to the time in which farmers sell their crops i.e. the farm
gate prices of the crops is unstable through out the year, depending on the
local supply and demand.
The highest farm gate price is that of wheat followed by dura, okra,
onion and tomato, respectively table (4.4). The tomato and onion crops
are highly sensitive to storage and because of lack of storage and
processing facilities farmers tend to buy these crops at low prices just
when they harvest.
4.2.3. The break-even yield:
The break-even yield is defined as the yield that just covers the
cost of production. It is equal to the total cost of production per feddan
divided by price per unit of yield.
Break even point (yield) =
Total cos t of production / feddan
Pr ice / unit of yield
Accordingly, the break-even yield of dura was 5.66 sacks/feddan.
This means that the average yield of dura per feddan in the study area was
more by 0.73 sacks/feddan. For wheat, the break-even yield was 5.79
sacks/feddan. This means that the average yield of wheat obtained by
farmer was more by 0.16 sacks/feddan.
Table (4.3): The average yield of crops per feddan season 2001-2002
Crop
Yield
Unit
Dura
6.39
Sacks
Wheat
5.95
Sacks
Tomato
250
Baskets*
Okra
32
Bags**
Onion
28.3
Sacks
Source : Field survey, 2002.
Table (4.4): The average farm gate price
Crop
Farm gate price Ls/feddan
Dura
27800
Wheat
49820
Tomato
4000
Okra
25000
Onion
12000
Source: Field survey, 2002.
The break-even yield for onion was 26.2 sacks/feddan. Therefore,
the average yield of onion per feddan in the study area was more by
2.1sacks/feddan table (4.5). For vegetables both okra and tomato the
break-even yield is less than the average yield of them in the study area.
From the above calculations, the break-even yield was less than the
average yield per feddan for all crops and this result indicates that the
output per feddan for all crops covers its actual cost of production in the
White Nile State in 2001-2002 season for the crops under the study.
4.2.4. Gross returns (Ls/feddan):
The yield and price analysis mentioned were used to calculate the
returns per feddan for all crops. On average, the gross returns for dura,
wheat, tomato, okra and onion were found to be Ls177642/feddan, Ls
292430 / feddan, Ls1000000 / feddan, Ls800000 / feddan and Ls 339600
/feddan, respectively table (4.6). The highest returns obtained in the study
area were that of tomato followed by okra, onion, wheat and dura,
respectively.
On average, the gross returns are higher than the total cost of
production for all crops under the study in 2001-2002 season.
4.2.5. Gross margins (Ls/feddan):
Gross margins are the difference between gross returns and the
total variable cost of production. In other words net income (profit) is
obtained by deducting expenses from revenue.
Table (4.5): The break-even yield of crops per feddan:
Crop
The break even yield
Unit
Dura
5.66
Sacks
Wheat
5.79
Sacks
Tomato
54.625
Baskets*
Okra
7.36
Bags*
Onion
26.2
Sacks
Source: Field survey, 2002.
Table (4.6) the average gross returns Ls/feddan
Crop
average gross returns Ls/feddan
Dura
177642
Wheat
292430
Tomato
1000000
Okra
800000
Onion
339600
Source: Field survey, 2002.
The gross margin for all the crops were found to be
Ls20412/feddan, Ls3730/ feddan, Ls 781500/feddan, Ls 616000/feddan
and Ls 25150 / feddan for dura, wheat, tomato, okra and onion,
respectively table (4.7).
The highest gross margins were that of the tomato followed by that
of okra, onion, wheat and dura, which scored the least gross margins.
However, wheat and dura have the least gross margins when compared to
other crops, farmers have exclusively grown them for food security i.e.
farmers grow food crops with less marginal returns as a measure against
risk to avoid supply shortage and prices fluctuations of food crops.
In general, the gross margins of vegetables (tomato and okra) were
higher than that of onion, wheat and dura because of the very high yield
of vegetables.
4.2.6. The coefficient of private profitability (CCP):
The coefficient of private profitability is the extent in which the
production of a crop is profitable or unprofitable for the producers i.e. it
is a decision criterion for the producer whether to produce a certain crop
or not.
The coefficient of private profitability is equal to the total returns
per feddan at farm gate price divided by the total cost per feddan.
Coefficient of private profitability =
Total returns / feddan at farm gate price
Total cos t / feddan
The private profitability coefficient is the same as the benefit/cost
ratio, if CCP is less than unity (1) it is unprofitable to produce that
product at present productivity level, and/or the present price level.
Table (4.8) shows that this ratio (CCP ratio) is greater than one for
all crops under the study. Hence, all crops are profitable at producer level.
The crops under the study can be ranked according to their CCP; tomato
comes first followed by okra, dura, onion and finally wheat, respectively.
This results revealed that inspite of high profitability of vegetables the
farmers cultivate food crops in their ways for seeking the food selfsufficiency which reflect the irrational attitudes of farmers; that call for
intervention so as to incentive the farmers to cultivate the more profitable
crops.
Table (4.7): The average gross margins Ls/feddan:
Crop
average gross margins Ls/feddan
Dura
20412
Wheat
3730
Tomato
781500
Okra
616000
Onion
25150
Source: Field survey, 2002.
Table (4.8): The coefficient of private profitability.
Crop
CCP ratio
Dura
1.13
Wheat
1.01
Tomato
4.58
Okra
4.32
Onion
1.08
Source: Field survey, 2002.
4.3 Respondent income and Poverty indicators:
Total income is the sum of farm income and non-farm income.
Considering the total income for farmers and non-farmers table (4.9)
represent the average farm and non-farm income of the respondents for
the farmers and non-farmers, the average farm income was Ls 3030.1937
represent 81.91% of the total income and the average non-farm income
was Ls 669.2563 and Ls 3077.375 representing 18.09% and 100% for
farmers and non-farmers, respectively.
Poverty indicators and distribution based on the poverty alleviation
strategy, which determines the subsistence level by one dollar per person
per day and the adequate level by 1.7 dollar per person per day (Poverty
workshop, 2000). Accordingly, the population distributed to the
following category:
•
Richest the lower limit of their income is above the adequate
level.
•
Non-poor their income is higher than the adequate level and
lower than the richest.
•
Poor their income is under the adequate level and above
subsistence level.
•
Very poor their income is under the subsistence level.
According to the indicators above, table (4.10) show that the most of the
respondents were very poor 82.5 and 86.25 for farmers and non-farmers
respectively, and the percentage of poor people under the poverty line
were found to be 96.25%.
Table (4.9) the respondent average income (per thousand Ls):
Farmer
Non-farmer
Average
%
Average
%
Farm income
3030.1937
81.91
0
0
Non-farm income
669.2563
18.09
3077.375
100
Total income
3699.45
100
3077.375
100
Source: Field survey, 2002
Table (4.10) the poverty indicator:
Farmer
Non-farmer
Freq
%
Freq
%
Richest
1
1.25
3
3.75
Non-poor
1
1.25
1
1.25
Poor
12
15.0
7
8.75
Very poor
66
82.5
69
86.25
Source: Field survey, 2002
CHAPTER FIVE
RESULTS AND DISCUSION OF REGRESSION EQUATIONS
This chapter presents the results, analysis and discussion of
regression equations for wheat and dura to investigate the factors that
curtailing agricultural production and calculate their return to scale. Also,
include time series analysis for food crop productivity to investigate the
trends of their productivity.
5.1. Theoretical Framework:
5.1.1. The production function:
Production function is normally estimated to investigate the impact
of some selected variables on yield. The production function is defined as
the relationship between quantities of various inputs used per unit time
and the maximum quantity of the output produced at that particular time
(Manfield, 1970). In addition, it can be defined as "a relationship or a
mathematical relationship between an output (Y) and different inputs
(Xs) used to produce it" (Ibrahim, 1993). Heady and Dillon (1961)
concluded that numerous algebraic equations can be used in deriving
production functions. No single form can be used to characterize
agricultural production under all environments, the algebraic form of the
function and the magnitude of its coefficient will vary with soil, climate
type and variety of crop or livestock resources being varied, state of
mechanization, magnitudes of others inputs in a fixed quantity for the
firm.
Upton (1976) reported that the production function in theory,
would include inputs of resources such as available soil nutrient, pest and
disease that might influence yield and because impossibility of specifying
all of these variables separately, some may be lumped together into a
board category, such as land and labor. Other variables, which are
considered unimportant, can be ignored. Production function can be
represented by tables' schedules, or mathematical equations, to determine
maximum output that can be produced from specified combinations of
inputs given the existing state of technology, the output will change when
the quantity of inputs changed. Mathematically the production function
can be represented as follow:
Qi = f (X1, X2.....Xn)
Where:
Qi = output of the product j.
Xi = inputs used.
i = 1 to n.
5.1.2. Some forms of production function:
5.1.2.1. Linear production function:
Is the straight-line relationship between certain levels of output
produced and given amount of inputs used. It is a process by which one
or more outputs are produced in a fixed proportion by the application of
one or more inputs in a fixed proportion, the general formula of linear
production function is:
Y = a + b1 X1 + b2 X2 +.........+bn Xn
Where:
Y = Yield.
a = constant term.
b1, b2,......,bn = coefficients.
X1, X2....Xn = explanatory variables.
The first derivative, which is the marginal product, is constant and
it does not show diminishing marginal returns. It represents only
situation, where the change in the dependent variable for a unit change in
the independents variables will be expected to be just the same regardless
of the larger or how smaller the independent variables were i.e. constant
slope.
5.1.2.2. The quadratic form:
The quadratic function allow for both declining and negative
marginal products. The elasticity of production is not constant as in the
power function but varies with the magnitude of inputs as indicated by
the elasticity equation for the function:
Y = a + bX – cX2
Where:
Y = Yield.
a = constant term.
b and c = coefficients.
X = input.
E (elasticity) =
bX − 2cX 2
a + bX − cX 2
The marginal products (MPs) do not bear a fixed ratio to each other
as in the case of Spillman function thus MP equation is:
dy
= b – 2cX
dx
Therefore, the marginal product curve is linear. The minus
significant before (c) indicate diminishing marginal returns, while (a)
represent the production forthcoming from the mix of fixed resources.
The advantage of the quadratic function is that besides being easy to
estimate it possesses a technical optimum beyond which the total product
fall. The possible disadvantage of the function is that it cannot show both
increasing marginal product at low levels of inputs and decreasing
marginal product at higher levels of inputs in the same equation i.e.
cannot show increasing and diminishing marginal returns in a single
response curve.
4.1.2.3. Cubic or New-classical production function:
The equation of this function with one exogenous variable is:
Y = a + bX + cX2 – dX3
Where:
Y = output.
a, b, c& d = coefficients terms.
X = input.
This type of production function shows the stages of production.
The first stage "stage 1" in which output increases at increasing rate as
input increased, the second stage where output increases at a decreasing
rate as more inputs is used and the third stage in which output decreased
as more inputs is used. The function shows the low of diminishing
marginal returns.
5.1.2.4. Cobb-Douglas production function:
The general form of Cobb-Douglas function is:
Y = a X1b1 X2 b2 ........Xnbn
Where:
Y = output (dependent variable).
X1, X2........Xn = inputs (independent variables).
a = constant term.
b1, b2.........bn = regression coefficient to be estimated which is the
partial elasticity of production with respect to the individual resources.
The sum of these elasticities determine the nature of returns to
scale which would indicate the percent by which the output will change if
all factors are changed at a given percent. If the sum of the elasticities
(∑bn) equals one, this means that one percent increase in all inputs will
result in one percent increase in the output i.e. constant returns to scale.
When the sum of the elasticities is less than one, one percent increase in
all inputs will result in less than one percent increase in the output i.e.
decreasing returns to scale, while with the a sum of elasticities greater
than one, output will be increased by a greater percentage than of input
increase i.e. increasing returns to scale.
As ordinary least square (OLS) can not be applied to non-linear
functions, Cobb-Douglas production function has to be transformed to
log-form by converting all variables measured, both inputs and output
into their logarithms, and then using OLS regression method to estimate
the coefficients(Upton,1987). The transformed function can be written as:
Log Y = log a + b1 logX1+ b2 log X2 +.........+ bn log Xn
The Cobb-Douglas production function is sometimes known as
logarithmic function.
The advantages of the Cobb-Douglas function stated by Upton
(1976) are:
1.
It is easy to estimate so it can be extended to include more
variables; it may show diminishing returns to scale.
2.
Its resemblance to reality better than linear form.
3.
It is easy to understand and easy to interpret.
4.
Its theoretical fitness to agriculture.
5.
The regression coefficient, immediately give the elasticities of
the product with respect to the factor of production( also called
flexibilities), that is we get answer to the question by how much
percentage will product increase on average if the given factor
increase by one percent.
6.
This form of production function permits the phenomena of
diminishing marginal returns, without using many degrees of
freedom.
Its possible disadvantage is that there is no technical optimum or
maximum total product, since there are no negative marginal returns (no
stage three). This may lead to overestimate the economic optimum of
high levels of inputs.
5.1.2. Model Specification:
The specification of the model depends on many consideration,
some are related to selection of exogenous (independent) variables that
are assumed to influence the variability of the dependent variable.
In specifying the economic model, Heady and Dillon(1961) stated
that, first a single equation or a system of equation is appropriate,
secondly, relevant set of variables have to be chosen and thirdly, a set of
hypothesis has to be made in appropriate algebraic forms of equations.
They also stated that the ideal model has two adjustments, first, the
number of variables has to be determined; secondly, the functional
representation should be statistically manageable. The choice between
different forms depends largely on subjective judgment, as does the
choice of variable inputs to be included in the function.
5.1.3. The econometric model estimation method:
The method used for the estimation of the econometric model is the
OLS estimation method. The OLS is mathematical technique use for
calculating the regression equation that summarizes and describes the
functional relationship between a set of variables. The technique based on
the principle of minimizing the sum of squared residuals has the desirable
property of mathematical objectivity. The criterion of OLS provides
estimates that possess many useful and desirable properties (El feil,
1993).
The OLS is extremely popular. This popularity stems from the fact
that the ordinary least estimator has a large number of desirable
properties making it the overwhelming choice for the "optimal" estimator
when the estimating problem is accurately characterized by the classical
linear regression model (El feil, 1993). From these properties are:
1.
The computation cost: because of the popularity of the OLS
estimator, many packaged computer routines exist and the
estimation of the OLS involves very little computation cost.
2.
The least square: because the OLS estimator is designed to
minimize the sum of the squared residuals, it is automatically
"optimal" on this criterion.
3.
The R-squared: Because the OLS estimator is "optimal" on the
least square criterion, it will automatically be "optimal" on the
R-squared criterion.
4.
Unbiasness: among all the linear unbiased estimators, the OLS
estimators have the smallest variance-covariance matrix. Thus,
OLS are the best linear unbiased estimators (BLUE).
5.1.4. The R-squared:
The R-square the coefficient of multiple regression is the
percentage variation in the dependent variable explained by the
regression portion of the equation. It expresses as how much of the
variation in the dependent variable is explained by the independent
variables in the regression equation. Computer packages calculate the Rsquared automatically. The R- square is the square of the correlation
coefficient between Y and its OLS estimate Ŷ. The OLS maximize the Rsquared and because the R-squared is used as an index of how well an
estimator fits the sample data, the OLS estimator is often called the best
fitting estimate and high R-squared is called a good fit. Good parameter
estimate are define in terms of R-squared and consequently the measure
of R-squared is not of much importance and is meaningless in economics,
unless the linear regression model classical assumptions are satisfied the
R-square could be low because of high disturbance term(Ibid, 1993).
5.1.5 The test of hypothesis:
For the validity of the estimated regression models and for the
regression coefficients to make any sense at all, there are many
hypotheses that have to be tested before any conclusions could be reached
these are:
5.1.5.1. The T-test:
The T-test is related to the individual coefficient in the regression
model. They are used to test whether each individual coefficient is
significantly different from zero or not i.e. whether if there is any
relationship at all. The T-values are calculated by the division of
regression coefficient of any variable by its standard error.
5.1.5.2. The F-test:
The F-test is the same as the T-test, but rather than testing the
individual coefficients, it test the whole regression model whether the
equation hold or not. The null hypothesis here assumes that all regression
coefficients are simultaneously equal to zero.
F-values are calculated in the following way:
F = (RSS/K)/ (ESS/ (n-(k+1))
Where:
RSS = Regression sum of squares.
ESS = Error sum of squares.
K
= numbers of independent variables.
K-1 = numbers of independent coefficients.
n = number of observations.
5.1.6. The selected production model:
In deriving production functions, numerous algebraic equations
and forms can be used. No single form can be used to characterize
agricultural production under all environment, types and variety of crops.
Hence, problem in each study is the selection of algebraic form functions,
which appear or is known to be constant with the phenomena under
investigation. However, some equations are more flexible than others
(Heady & Dillon, 1961). In this study to show the degree of influence,
level of significance and nature of relationship between the dependent
and independent variables, both the linear and double logarithmic form of
Cobb-Douglas function were proposed and tried in the first run of this
analysis. Based on both economic logic and statistical considerations, the
double logarithmic form of Cobb-Douglas function type was found to be
the best form that describes the relationship between the dependent and
independent variables. This type of function can be expressed as linear
and easy to fit by the model of OLS. The general form of the transformed
logarithmic Cobb-Douglas production function could be written as
follows:
Log Y = log a +b1 log X1 + b2 log X2 + ......... +bn log Xn
Where:
Y = the crop yield in sacks per feddan.
X1, X2 ........ Xn = are exogenous variables.
b1, b2.........bn = are the production elasticities with respect to
individual resources.
The above model is applied and estimated for the main food crops
in the area, wheat and dura for the season 2001/2002. The dependent
variable is the crop yield per feddan and the independent variables tried
for both crops included: irrigation availability, farm income, non-farm
income, cost of production, rainfall, population density, credit and
extension services received.
5.2. Regression analysis results:
The results of the regression equations for both dura and wheat are
represented in this section; the output per feddan for each crop represents
the dependent variable.
5.2.1. Dura regression result:
Table (5.1) shows the dura regression equation, the dependent
variable is the yield (sacks/feddan). The model includes two categories of
independent variables i.e. continuous variables include: farm income,
cultivated area, total cost of production and crop yield & dummy
variables include credit, extension services and stratification.
Table (5.1) Dura regression equation:
Variable
coefficient
Std. error
T-value
Significant.
Constant
-1.987
1.652
-1.89
*
Irrigation
0.543
0.917
9.521
***
Credit
-0.009
0.249
0.837
Extension
0.381
1.392
3.912
**
Farm income
0.617
0.006
4.913
***
Dura cost of production
0.328
0.062
7.624
***
Stratification
-0.635
0.876
5.497
***
R2
= 0.783
Adj. R2
= 0.728
Std. error
= 2.3278
F
= 18.271
Significant. = 0.000
The model specified gave R-square of 0.783 which mean that
78.3% of the observed variation in dura yield was explained by the
variations in the independent variables. The F-statistic of 180271which is
significant at all level of significance indicating that the model is highly
significance in explaining the variation in the dura yield.
The coefficient of independent variable in the model represents the
elasticities, which indicate the change in yield relative to the change in
the
inputs.
Among
the
variable
included
in
the
model
variables are significantly different from zero at 99%, 99%, 99%, 99%&
95% level of significance for irrigation, farm income, dura cost,
stratification and extension services, respectively. The credit variable
included in the model was not significantly different from zero at any
level of significance.
5.2.2. Wheat regression result:
Table (5.2) show the wheat regression equation, with wheat yield
as dependent variable; cost of production, area cultivated, time of
planting, dura yield, irrigation and population density as continuous
independent variables, while stratification and credit as dummy variables.
The result gave R- square of 0.943, which indicate that 94.3%of
the observed variation in the wheat yield was explained by the variation
in the independent variables. The F-statistic of 127.913which is
significant at all level of significance indicating that the model is highly
significance in explaining the variation in the wheat yield.
Table (5.2) Wheat regression equation:
Variable
coefficient
Std. error
T-value
Significant
Constant
3.271
0.736
4.512
**
Irrigation
0.517
0.213
-18.329
***
Credit
0.324
0.425
5.738
***
Extension
0.112
0.874
1.392
Farm income
0.269
0.293
6.128
***
0.316
0.021
3.293
**
-0.295
0.009
7.115
***
Wheat cost of
production
Stratification
R2
= 0.885
Adj. R2
= 0.877
Std. error
= 0.8330
F
= 113.685
Significant. = 0.000
The coefficients of independent variable in the model represent the
elasticities, which indicate the change in yield relative to the change in
the independent variables.
Irrigation, farm income, credit, stratification and wheat cost of
production variables among the model variables in the model are
significantly different from zero at 99%, 99%, 99%, 99% & 95% level of
significance, respectively. The extension variable included in the model
was not significantly different from zero at any level of significance.
5.3. Discussion of the two crops regression equations:
The effect of each independent variable in the yield of dura and
wheat will be discussed separately these independent variables are:
5.3.1. The irrigation variable:
The irrigation variable has coefficient (elasticities) of 0.543 and
0.517, which are significantly different from zero at 99% level of
significance for both wheat and dura, table (5.1) and (5.2). These
coefficients are the elasticities of yield with respect to irrigation variable
or wheat and dura production. These elasticities revealed that with
increasing the irrigation variable by a one percent will increase the
productivity of wheat and dura by 5.43% and 5.17%, respectively.
Many previous studies showed that irrigation shortage is
considered to be the most agricultural constraints in the irrigated scheme
(El feil, 1993).
The irrigation shortage is due to inadequate supply of irrigation
inputs (fuel, spare part.............etc.) and their unavailability in proper time
and at reasonable price. However, these high elasticities are enough to
explain how the problems associated with irrigation inputs are
constraining the production. This may have led the company in the White
Nile State to apply less number of irrigation than the recommended
because of their poor financial resources and unavailability of formal
credit on time and with adequate amount to purchase irrigation inputs
even when these inputs are available in the market.
5.3.2. The farm income variable:
The farm income is expected to have significant effect on the
output of the different crops because of the role that it can play on the
purchase of different agricultural inputs.
The farm income variable has got co-efficient of 0.617 and 0.269
which are significantly different from zero at 99% level of significance
for wheat and dura, respectively table (5.1) represent the elasticities
which indicate the change in yield relative to the change in inputs, a one
percent increase in the farm income will increase the yield of wheat and
dura by 6.17% and 2.69%, respectively.
5.3.3. Credit variable:
Credit has got a co-efficient of -0.009 &0.324 for dura and wheat
which is significantly different from zero for wheat at 99% level of
significance table (5.2). The significance may be due to the high variation
in the credit received by the farmers.
5.3.4. Extension services variable:
Extension services have got co-efficient of 0.381 & 0.112 this
coefficient is significantly different from zero at 95% for dura and not
significance for wheat.
5.3.5. The cost of production variable:
The cost of production has got a significant co-efficient of 0.328
&0.316 for wheat and dura at 95%&99%, respectively. Which indicate
that a one percent increase in cost of production will increase the yield of
wheat and dura by 3.28% &3.16%, respectively. This attribute to the low
level of inputs used.
5.3.6. The stratification variable:
The stratification variable has got a significant co-efficient of -0.635
& -0.295 for dura and wheat at 99%&99%, respectively. Which indicate
that the northern area of the study has a negative impact on the yield of
the both crops by 6.35% & 2.95% for dura and wheat, respectively.
5.4. The nature of returns to scale:
As mentioned above the sum of elasticities determine the nature of
returns to scale, the sum of elasticities of individual variables is 1.101 and
1.369 for wheat and dura, respectively. This means that a one percent
increase in the scale of inputs results in 11% &13.69% increase in wheat
and dura yield per feddan, respectively. Consequently, an increasing
return to scale existed for both crops since the summation of their partial
elasticities is greater than one.
5.5. Forecasting food crops productivity:
Time series data on productivity of food crops (wheat and dura) are
analyzed to arrive at the trends of productivity for the period 1990/91 to
1999/2000.
Table (5.3) shows the annual productivity of dura, it is clear that
the productivity of dura shows considerable fluctuations from one season
to another as can be seem from figure (5.1).
The real trend for dura productivity is decreasing. The negative
sign of the coefficient in the trend equation support this. The trend shows
that by the year 2044/2045 the productivity of dura will reach zero sack
per feddan.
Table (5.4) also shows the productivity of wheat which is
decreasing and has negative sign of the coefficient in the trend equation.
The trend show that by the year 2007/2008 the productivity of wheat will
reach zero sack per feddan
The instability in the wheat productivity as measured by the
coefficient of variation is quite high than dura.
It is interesting to note that the instability associated with the food
crops is lower in dura as compared to wheat. This mainly because dura
crop received almost full supervision by farmers because it is his main
food crop. The higher instability of wheat productivity attributed to that
wheat crop is very sensitive to environmental factors i.e. drought
condition, irrigation shortage as well as water logging.
Table (5.3): Trend for dura productivity (sacks/feddan)
Year
Actual productivity
Trend
1990/91
5
4.5825
1991/92
4
4.4975
1992/93
4
4.4125
1993/94
5
4.3275
1994/95
5
4.2425
1995/96
4
4.1575
1996/97
4
4.0725
1997/98
3
3.9875
1998/99
2
3.9025
1999/2000
6
3.8175
Trend equation
Y = 4.6675 – 0.085x
Table (5.4): Trend for wheat productivity (sacks/feddan)
Year
Actual productivity
Trend
1990/91
2.8
4.175
1991/92
3.0
3.925
1992/93
4.8
3.675
1993/94
4.9
3.425
1994/95
4.5
3.175
1995/96
2.8
2.925
1996/97
2.0
2.675
1997/98
2.0
2.425
1998/99
2.0
2.175
1999/2000
1.7
1.925
Trend equation
Y= 4.425 – 0.25x
CHAPTER SIX
SUMMARY, CONCLUSIONS AND RECOMMENDATIONS
6.1. Summary:
The study depended mainly on primary data, collected by means of
questionnaire and direct interview of the respondent in the White Nile
Scheme for the season 2001/2002. A multi-stage stratified random sample
of 160 respondents was selected (80 farmers and 80 non-farmers). In
addition, secondary data was used.
Descriptive statistics have been used throughout the study , the
statistical analysis of socio-economic characteristics of the respondent
revealed that, most of the respondents are literate and have some sort of
education which enable them to adopt the extension service and technical
package; the majority of them were within the productive age group. The
average family size was 6.7 and 5.65 persons for farmers and nonfarmers, respectively, and the average income was Ls 3699450 and Ls
3077375 for farmers and non-farmers, respectively.
The analysis of the crop budget shows that the crops had positive
marginal returns per feddan. 20412, 3730, 781500,616000 and 25150 for
dura, wheat, tomato, okra and onion, respectively. The analysis of cost
structure showed that the irrigation recorded the higher share relative to
the total cost per feddan followed by land preparation, harvest and
threshing, fertilizer and seeds respectively.
Cobb-Douglass production function (log-form) has been estimated
to test for crop yield and to see the effect of factors on the output of dura
and wheat. The estimated production function for both crops show that
the equation were estimated with good explanatory power the result
indicated that irrigation, credit, cost of production, stratification and farm
income explaining the variation in wheat yield for dura irrigation,
extension, cost of production, stratification and farm income were
significant variables. All variables have positive except credit and
stratification for dura and extension and stratification for wheat.
Generally, the interviewed respondents indicate that the major
problem facing them was irrigation, extension, credit, marketing and
inputs availability.
6.2. Conclusions:
The study revealed the following conclusions:
1.
All crops were found to be profitable since their average gross
returns exceeds the average cost of production. With respect to
profitability tomato, okra, onion, dura and wheat ranked from
first to fifth, respectively. Vegetables are more profitable than
food crops but inspite of that farmers were growing wheat and
dura to secure food. This indicated by the large area cultivated
by both crops in the season under study and the larger number
of farmers growing food crops.
2.
The cost structure analysis indicate that irrigation cost, land
preparation, harvesting and threshing and sack respectively
were the main item of cost for dura, for wheat irrigation,
fertilizer, harvesting and threshing and seeds respectively were
found to be the main cost items, whereas irrigation, seeds, land
preparation and fertilizers respectively accounts for the highest
share in the total cost of production for tomato, for okra
irrigation, land preparation, fertilizer, and seed respectively
were found to be the main cost items, on the other hand sacks,
irrigation, land preparation and harvest and threshing
respectively recorded the highest share in the total cost of
production of onion. For all crops under the study, irrigation
cost was found to be the main cost item.
3.
The highest total variable cost of production was scored by
onion followed by wheat, tomato, okra and dura.
4.
According to the regression analysis it could be argued that
irrigation, credit, cost of production, extension, stratification
and lag farm income are the main factors affecting the
production of food crops in White Nile Schemes.
5.
The sum of elasticities of the significant independent variables
determined the nature of returns to scale; wheat and dura are
characterized by increasing returns to scale since their
significant elasticities is more than one.
6.
The higher cost of irrigation relative to the other inputs and the
significance of irrigation for wheat and dura indicated that
irrigation is found to be the most important factor constraining
the agricultural production in the White Nile Schemes.
6.3. Recommendations:
For the purpose of the study, the following recommendations are
proposed:
1.
Reform the scheme management by putting the scheme under
governmental authority for period not less than five years
during this period there must be major policies to be conduct:
a.
Since irrigation is the main constrains of crop production
there is a need for rehabilitation of the irrigation system,
cleaning the canals and maintaining the regulators.
b.
Facilitate the extension service through farmer education
program, supply farmers with modern inputs and follow
the recommended technical packages, such as improved
seeds, recommended fertilizer rate, reasonable seed rate
and enough irrigation to increase the productivity and
profitability.
c.
Strengthening the farmer's financial abilities through an
efficient credit system that aims to finance the small
farmers at acceptable interest rate, easy terms of
repayment, simple procedures in obtaining credit and
encouragement of effective use of loans by farmers. Credit
should be appropriate both in time and amount to perform
agricultural operation at proper time.
d.
Incentives have to be provided to the farmers in terms of
good and stable farm get prices through improvement of
marketing system and storage facilities.
e.
Construct the agro-forestry program and keep attention to
the green belt of the scheme which is removed now and
there is a very need to establish this belt by conduct the
legal percent of the shelter belt for the irrigated schemes.
f.
Increase the area under vegetables and providing technical
package and finance them.
2.
Provide finance, veterinary and medicine services to improve
livestock wealth.
3.
Provide productive loans to alleviate poverty and supporting
the environment practice by avail alternative for forest product
used as energy source.
REFERENCES
Abdel Rahim, B.E. (1989). Factors associated with participation of rural
leadership in policies and programmes formulation of the White Nile
Agricultural Production Corporation and Duiem extension unit. M.Sc.
Thesis, Faculty of Agriculture, University of Khartoum.
Abdul-Hai, S. (1996). Food Security Training Course. A short manual.
Development Studies and Research Centre, University of Khartoum.
Atta Elfadil, Kh. A (1990) The Optimum Cropping Pattern in Zeidab Scheme
M.Sc thesis, Faculty of Agriculture, University of Khartoum. Sudan.
Bayoumi, A. (1984). Renewable natural resource management and desertification
in Sudan, El-Tashar Sudan journal of desertification Vol.2 Page 1-4.
Boon, C. J. (1990). Environmental Problems in Sudan. Institute of Social Studies
(ISS), The Netherlands part 1.
Brown, L.R and H. Kane (1994) Full House: Assessing the Earth's population
carrying capacity, World Watch Environmental Alert Series, London,
Earthscan.
Reid, David (1996). Sustainable development. Earthscan publications limited,
Oxford, London.
Desert Encroachment control and Rehabilitation programme (1979). Khartoum,
Sudan.
Ehrlich, P and A. Ehrlich (1990) The Population Explosion, London,
Hutehinson.
Elhot, J.A (1994) An Introduction To Sustainable Development, London and
New York, Routledge.
El jak, M. (2002). Personal interview. The Manager of Northern White Nile
Corporation.
Elfeil, M.A. (1993). Economic constraints of Agricultural production in the
Northern province of Sudan. Ph.D. Thesis. University of Khartoum.
Elgozouli, O.M. (1998). Resource productivity in irrigated agriculture with
emphasis in labor. Case study of Gezira scheme. M.Sc. Thesis. University
of Khartoum.
ElNayal, Idris E. (2002). Poverty and the Environment. Quated in Hassan AbdelAti (Sustainable Development in Sudan. Ten Years After Rio Summit).
Elshafie, B.M. (1992). Cropping pattern and its impact on Agricultural
efficiency. M.Sc. Thesis, Faculty of Agriculture. University of Khartoum.
Sudan.
FAO (1986). Irrigated forest plantation as an integral part of agriculture
including a proposal for a 5-year development plan for the central region
of the Sudan. Report for the government of the Sudan by FAO. Fuel
wood development programme.
FAO (1993). Rural poverty alleviation: Policy and trends .Rome Italy.
FAO (1997). Implications of economic policy for food security (A training
manual) by Anne Thomson and Manfred metz Rome,italy.
FAO (2001). Food, Agriculture and Rural Development: Current and Emerging
issues for economic analysis and policy research. Edited by Kostas, G.
Stamoulis, Rome, Italy.
Grainger, A. (1990). The Threating Desert. International Institute for
Environment and Development. Earth-scan publication, United Kingdom.
Page (7- 157).
Heady, E.O. and Dillon, J.L. (1961). Agricultural Production Functions. Iowa
State University Press, Ames, Iowa.
Ibrahim, O.I. (1993). Economic of crop production in the Northern region. M.Sc.
Thesis. University of Khartoum.
International Union for Conservation of Nature and Natural Resources "IUCN".
(1986). Along term strategy for environmental rehabilitation. The
SAHEL Report. Conservation for Development centert.
Mann, P. (2001). Sustainable energy for sustainable development. The courier,
magazine of ACP-EU Development cooperation. Issue No 189.
Maxwell, S. (1991). To care all hunger. Food policy and food security in Sudan.
Intermediate technology publications. London, United kingolom.
Neumann, K. and Hamp, M. (1999). Agriculture and rural development
magazine. Volume 6. No.2 Issue No 0343.6462.
Ngangue, Eyoum (2001). Agriculture and environment. The courier, magazine
of ACP- EU development cooperation. Issue No 189. Page 46.
Noordwijk, M. (1984). Ecology textbook for the Sudan. Khartoum University
Press.
Reed, D. (2001). The rural poor and their natural resource. The courier,
magazine of ACP-EU Development cooperation. Issue No 189. Page 35.
Solh, M.B.(1996). Wheat production and improvement in the Sudan, Agriculture
Research Corporation. ICARDA Syria.
United Nation Development Programme (1998) Sudan National Human
Development, Unpublished Report, Khartoum.
United Nation Environmental Programme (1985) In defence of the earth, the
basic text on environment page 26.
United Nations (1977) United Nations Conference on Desertification Control.
Desertification an over view, Nairobi.
Upton, M. (1976). African farm management published by Cambridge
University Press, Cambridge, page 182 – 185.
Ward Ford, J. and Partow, Z. (1989). Evaluation of World Banks Environment
policy in finance and development, Washington DC. U.S.A.
World Bank (1996). Poverty Reduction and the World Bank. Washington U.S.A.
World Commission on Environment and Development (1987). Our common
future. Oxford university press, London. U.K.
WRI (1985). Tropical forest a call for action. World Resource Institute.
Yassin, S.M. (1996). Education and training for environmental issues in
agriculture in Asia. Cited in training for agriculture and rural
development. FAO. Economic and Social Development Series No 54.
Rome, Italy. Page 52.
‫اﻟﻤﺼﺎدر اﻟﻌﺮﺑﻴﺔ‬
‫ﺻﺎﻟﺢ‪ ،‬ﻋﻠﻰ ﻋﺒﺪ اﻟﻌﺰﻳ ﺰ ؛ ﻣﺤﻤ ﺪ ﻋﻠ ﻰ ﺳ ﻼﻣﺔ ؛ﻋﺒ ﺪ اﻟﻘ ﺎدر ﺗﺮآ ﺎوى وﻋﻠ ﻰ إﺑ ﺮاهﻴﻢ اﻟﺨﻠﻴ ﻞ )‪ (1997‬ﺗﻘ ﻮﻳﻢ‬
‫اﻟﻌﻼﻗ ﺎت اﻻﻗﺘ ﺼﺎدﻳﺔ واﻹدارﻳ ﺔ وﻋﻼﻗ ﺎت اﻹﻧﺘ ﺎج ﺑ ﺸﺮآﺎت اﻟﻨﻴ ﻞ اﻷﺑ ﻴﺾ؛وزارة اﻟﺰراﻋ ﺔ‬
‫واﻟﻐﺎﺑﺎت‪ ،‬اﻟﺨﺮﻃﻮم‪ ،‬اﻟﺴﻮدان ‪.‬‬
‫ورﺷ ﺔ ﻋﻤ ﻞ اﻟﺒﺮﻧ ﺎﻣﺞ اﻹﺳ ﺘﺮاﺗﻴﺠﻲ ﻟﻤﻜﺎﻓﺤ ﺔ اﻟﻔﻘ ﺮ ﻓ ﻲ اﻟ ﺴﻮدان )‪ (2000‬ﻣ ﺴﻮدة ﻋﻨﺎﺻ ﺮ إﺳ ﺘﺮاﺗﻴﺠﻴﺔ‬
‫ﻣﻨﺎهﻀﺔ اﻟﻔﻘﺮ ﻓﻰ اﻟﺴﻮدان )‪ (2020 -2000‬ﻗﺎﻋﺔ اﻟﺼﺪاﻗﺔ ؛ اﻟﺨﺮﻃﻮم ؛ اﻟﺴﻮدان ‪.‬‬
Appendix (1)
Area and average production of cotton and Dura in White Nile Scheme
from season 1973/74 to 1997/98.
Crop
Season
1973/74
1974/75
1975/76
1976/77
1977/78
1978/79
1979/80
1980/81
1981/82
1982/83
1983/84
1984/85
1985/86
1986/87
1987/88
1988/89
1989/90
1990/91
1991/92
1992/93
1993/94
1994/95
1995/96
1996/97
1997/98
1998/99
1999/2000
2000/2001
Cotton
Dura
Productive area
1000 fed
Average
productivity/kantar/
fed
Productive area
1000 fed
Average
productivity/kantar/
fed
145
151
123
104
106
88
98
61
95
85
62
65
52
55
73
40
32
17
4
14
24
44
78
22
11
9
-
3.4
3.4
2.5
2.7
3.1
2.7
1.3
2.6
2.5
3
3.4
4
2.5
2.8
2.5
2.8
2.8
3.5
5.2
4.6
4.6
3.5
1.5
0.9
1.8
-
93
74
67
85
32
39
31
29
35
24
57
30
65
22
19
20
29
80
69
40
40
55
50
67
34
46
52
62
215
194
194
194
188
438
461
355
379
485
386
400
450
300
450
320
450
500
500
540
520
650
500
560
450
620
570
Source : statistic and information management, Ministry of Agriculture and Forest.